economic research on the determinants of immigration · 1. emigration and inmmigration-economic...

44
WORLD BANK TECHNICAL PAPER NO. 438 Europe and Central Asia Poverty Reduction and Economicn Ailanagement Series Work in progress WTP438 for public discussion September 1999 Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration Lessonsfor the European Union George J. Borjas Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Upload: others

Post on 25-Jul-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

WORLD BANK TECHNICAL PAPER NO. 438

Europe and Central Asia Poverty Reduction and EconomicnAilanagement Series

Work in progress WTP438for public discussion

September 1999

Economic Researchon the Determinantsof ImmigrationLessonsfor the European Union

George J. Borjas

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Pub

lic D

iscl

osur

e A

utho

rized

Page 2: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Recent World Bank Technical Papers

No. 370 Dejene, Shishira, Yanda, and Johnsen, Land Degradation in Tanzania: Perception from the Village

No. 371 Essama-Nssah, Analyse d'une repartition du niveanu de vie

No. 372 Cleaver and Schreiber, Inverser la spriale: Les interactions entre Ia population, I'agricultuire et l'environnementen Afrique subsaharienne

No. 373 Onursal and Gautam, Vehicular Air Pollution: Experiencesfrom Seven Latin American Urban Centers

No. 374 Jones, Sector Investment Programs in Africa: Issues and Experiences

No. 375 Francis, Milimo, Njobvo, and Tembo, Listening to Farmers: Participatory Assessment of Policy Reform inZambia's Agriculture Sector

No. 376 Tsunokawa and Hoban, Roads and the Environment: A Handbook

No. 377 Walsh and Shah, Clean Fuelsfor Asia: Technical Optionsfor Moving toward Unleaded Gasoline and Low-SuilfuirDiesel

No. 378 Shah and Nagpal, eds., Urban Air Quality Management Strategy in Asia: Kathmandu Valley Report

No. 379 Shah and Nagpal, eds., Urban Air Quality Management Strategy in Asia: Jakarta Report

No. 380 Shah and Nagpal, eds., Urban Air Quality Managemenlt Strategy in Asia: Metro Manila Report

No. 381 Shah and Nagpal, eds., Urban Air Quality Management Strategy in Asia: Greater Mumbai Report

No. 382 Barker, Tenenbaum, and Woolf, Governance and Regulation of Power Pools and System Operators: AnInternational Comparison

No. 383 Goldman, Ergas, Ralph, and Felker, Technology Institutions and Policies: Their Role in DevelopingTechnological Capability in Industry

No. 384 Kojima and Okada, Catching Up to Leadership: The Role of Technology Support Institutions in Japan's CastingSector

No. 385 Rowat, Lubrano, and Porrata, Competition Policy and MERCOSUR

No. 386 Dinar and Subramanian, Wnter Pricing Experiences: An International Perspective

No. 387 Oskarsson, Berglund, Seling, Snellman, Stenback, and Fritz, A Planner's Guidefor Selecting Clean-CoalTechnologies for Power Plants

No. 388 Sanjayan, Shen, and Jansen, Experiences with Integrated-Conservation Development Projects in Asia

No. 389 International Commission on Irrigation and Drainage (ICID), Planning the Management, Operation, andMaintenance of Irrigation and Drainage Systems: A Guidefor the Preparation of Strategies and Manuals

No. 390 Foster, Lawrence, and Morris, Groundwater in Urban Developmenit: Assessing Management Needs andFormulating Policy Strategies

No. 391 Lovei and Weiss, Jr., Environmental Management and Institutions in OECD Countries" LessonsfromExperience

No. 392 Felker, Chaudhuri, Gybrgy, and Goldman, The Pharmaceutical Industry in India and Hungary: Policies,Institutions, and Technological Development

No. 393 Mohan, ed., Bibliography of Publications: Africa Region, 1990-97

No. 394 Hill and Shields, Incentivesfor Joint Forest Management in India: Analytical Methods and Case Studies

No. 395 Saleth and Dinar, Satisfying Urban Thirst: Water Supply Augmentation and Pricing Policy in Hyderabad City,India

No. 396 Kikeri, Privatization and Labor: What Happens to Workers When Governments Divest?

No. 397 Lovei, Phasing Out Leadfrom Gasoline: Worldwide Experience and Policy Implications

No. 398 Ayres, Anderson, and Hanrahan, Setting Prioritiesfor Environmental MAnagement: An Application to theMining Sector in Bolivia

No. 399 Kerf, Gray, Irwin, L6vesque, Taylor, and Klein, Concessionsfor Infrastructure: A Guide to Their Design andAward

No. 401 Benson and Clay, The Impact of Drought on Sub-Saharan A,frican Economies: A Preliminary Examinationt

No. 402 Dinar, Mendelsohn, Evenson, Parikh, Sanghi, Kumar, McKinsey, and Lonergan, Measuring the Impact ofClimate Change on Indian Agriculture

No. 403 Welch and Fremond, The Case-by-Case Approach to Privatization: Techniques and Examples

No. 404 Stephenson, Donnay, Frolova, Melnick, and Worzala, Improving Women's Health Services in the RussianFederation: Results of a Pilot Project

(List continues on the inside back cover)

Page 3: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

WORLD BANK TECHNICAL PAPER NO. 438

Europe and CentralAsia Poverty Reduction and EconomicManagement Series

Economic Researchon the Determinantsof ImmigrationLessonsfor the European Union

George J. Borjas

The World BankWashuington, D.C

Page 4: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Copyright (C 1999The International Bank for Reconstructionand Development/THE WORLD BANK1818 H Street, N.W.Washington, D.C. 20433, U.S.A.

All rights reservedManufactured in the United States of AmericaFirst printing September 1999

Technical Papers are published to communicate the results of the Bank's work to the developmentcommunity with the least possible delay. The typescript of this paper therefore has not been prepared inaccordance with the procedures appropriate to formal printed texts, and the World Bank accepts noresponsibility for errors. Some sources cited in this paper may be informal documents that are notreadily available.

The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of theauthor(s) and should not be attributed in any manner to the World Bank, to its affiliated organizations,or to members of its Board of Executive Directors or the countries they represent. The World Bank doesnot guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this publication and accepts no responsibility for anyconsequence of their use. The boundaries, colors, denominations, and other information shown on anymap in this volume do not imply on the part of the World Bank Group any judgment on the legal statusof any territory or the endorsement or acceptance of such boundaries.

The material in this publication is copyrighted. The World Bank encourages dissemination of itswork and will normally grant permission promptly.

Permission to photocopy items for internal or personal use, for the internal or personal use ofspecific clients, or for educational classroom use is granted by the World Bank, provided that theappropriate fee is paid directly to Copyright Clearance Center, Inc., 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA01923, U.S.A., telephone 978-750-8400, fax 978-750-4470. Please contact the Copyright Clearance Centerbefore photocopying items.

For permission to reprint individual articles or chapters, please fax your request with completeinformation to the Republication Department, Copyright Clearance Center, fax 978-750-4470.

All other queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to the World Bank at the address aboveor faxed to 202-522-2422.

ISBN: 0-8213-4504-4ISSN: 0253-7494

George J. Borjas is Pforzheimer Professor of Public Policy at the John F. Kennedy School of Govern-ment at Harvard University and research associate, National Bureau of Economic Research.

Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data

Borjas, George J.Economic research on the determinants of immigration: lessons forthe European Union / George J. Borj as.

p. cm. - (World Bank technical paper; no. 438. Europe andCentral Asia poverty reduction and economic management series)

Includes bibliographical references.ISBN 0-8213-4504-41. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research.

2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration andimmigration-Government policy. I. Title. II. Series: World Bank technical paper.Europe and Central Asia poverty reduction and economic managementseries.JV6217.B67 1999325'.1-dc2l 99-28650

CIP

Page 5: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Contents

Foreword ........................................ v

Acknowledgments ........................................ viiExecutive Summary ......................................... I

1. The Migration Decision: A Review of the Theory ............ ........................... 2The Link between Immigration and Trade ....................................... 7

2. Evidence from the United States ...... 8.................................8

3. The Economic Impact of Immigration ....................................... 12

4. Implications for the European Union ................................... 16Implications of Research on Immigration ................................... 18Additional Implications ................................... 22

5. Conclusion ................................... 23

Notes .................................... 24

References .................................... 25

GraphsFigure 1 Trends in California's Population, 1950-1998 .15

TablesTable 1 Emigration Rate to the United States from Selected Countries, 1970-90 . 9

Table 2 The Impact of Immigration on the Wage of Native Workers in the UnitedStates .13

Table 3 Economic Characteristics of Selected Countries in the European Union and inCentral and Eastern Europe, 1996 .24

iii

Page 6: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government
Page 7: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Foreword

The Poverty Reduction and Economic Management Unit in the World Bank's Europe and

Central Asia Region has been undertaking a series of analytical work on issues pertinent tothe economies in the region. These issues include: transition issues; issues of economic inte-

gration pertinent for the Central and Eastern Europe countries which are candidates foraccession to the European Union; poverty issues; and other economic management issues.The analytical work has been conducted by staff of the unit, other Bank staff as well as spe-

cialists outside of the Bank.This technical paper series was launched to promote wider dissemination of this analytical

work, with the objective of generating further discussions of the issues. The studies publishedin the series should therefore be viewed as work in progress.

The findings, interpretations and conclusions are the authors' own and should not beattributed to the World Bank, its Executive Board of Directors, or any of its member countries.

Pradeep Mitra

DirectorPoverty Reduction and Economic Management Unit

Europe and Central Asia RegionThe World Bank

v

Page 8: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government
Page 9: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Acknowledgments

The following study was prepared by GeorgeJ. Borjas, Pforzheimer Professor of Public Policy,

John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, and Research Associate, Na-

tional Bureau of Economic Research.

vii

Page 10: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government
Page 11: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Executive Summary

There has been a resurgence of immigration in many developed countries. Over 120 million

people, or 2 percent of the world's population, now reside in a country where they were not

born (Martin, 1998). Although most immigrants choose a "traditional" destination (two-

thirds typically go to the United States, Canada, or Australia), many other countries are re-

ceiving relatively large immigrant flows. About 9 percent of the population in Austria, 6

percent in France, and 9 percent in Germany is foreign-born.' Even Japan, which is thought

of as being very homogeneous and geographically immune to immigrants, now reports ma-

jor problems with illegal immigration.

As a result of these changes in the "immigration market," the economic impact of immi-gration-is now being heatedly debated in many potential host countries. The policy discus-

sion is typically centered on three substantive questions. First, how do immigrants perform in

the host country's economy? Second, what impact do immigrants have on the employmentopportunities of native-born workers? And, finally, which immigration policy would most

benefit the host country?

The practical significance of these questions is evident. For example, highly skilled immi-

grants who adapt rapidly to conditions in the host country's labor market can make a signifi-cant contribution to economic growth. Native workers need not be concerned about the

possibility that these immigrants will increase expenditures on social assistance programs.Conversely, if immigrants lack the skills that employers demand and find it difficult to adapt,

immigration may significantly increase the costs associated with maintaining many programsin the welfare state as well as exacerbate the wage inequality that might already exist in thehost country.

Similarly, the debate over immigration policy has long been fueled by the widespreadperception that immigrants have an adverse effect on the employment opportunities of na-tive workers. Do immigrants enter the host country and "take awayjobs" from natives? Whichnative workers are most adversely affected by immigration and how large is the decline in the

native wage?Finally, there is great diversity in immigration policies across countries. Some countries,

such as the United States, award entry visas mainly to applicants who have relatives already

residing in the country. Other countries, such as Australia and Canada, award visas to per-

sons who have a desirable set of socioeconomic characteristics, and still other countries, such

as Germany, encouraged the migration of "temporary" guest workers in the 1960s, only tofind that the temporary migrants became a permanent part of the German population. The

choice of the "right" immigration policy can obviously have a significant impact on economic

activity, both in the short run and in the long run.A central question underlies all of these policy concerns: what factors motivate some per-

sons to leave the country where they were born and move to a different country, a country

that may have a very different culture and where the bulk of the population speaks a differ-

ent language?

The past decade witnessed an explosion in research on many aspects of the economics ofimmigration. This literature is mainly motivated by the various policy concerns and provides

valuable insights into all these issues. In this paper, I summarize some of the key findings of

1

Page 12: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

this literature, and apply them to the context of the potential migration problem faced by

countries in the European Union (EU). As the EU expands beyond its original boundaries,

there has been rising concern that wage differences among the existing countries in the EU

and new entrants, such as Hungary and Poland, may motivate many workers to migrate into

the European Union. These concerns are sufficiently serious that they may play an impor-

tant role in the negotiations between the European Commission and a number of the coun-

tries in Central and Eastern Europe that are applying for accession.

A key objective of the paper is to present a review of existing economic theory and empiri-

cal evidence to evaluate the likelihood of migration flows from acceding countries (and neigh-

boring countries) toward the current EU member states. In particular, the analysis will derive

the implications of the existing evidence for the size and skill composition of the migration

flows that might occur between the acceding countries and the current EU member states.

The paper will also briefly review the migration policies that are currently in place, and make

policy recommendations to allay the serious concerns raised by the migration issue in thecontext of the European Union.

1. The Migration Decision: A Review of the Theory

There are three sets of players that jointly determine the size and direction of population

flows across countries: the people contemplating whether or not to leave the source coun-tries, the governments of these source countries, and the governments of the potential coun-tries of destination. 2 These players in the "immigration market" typically have different ob-

jectives, and it is the interaction among these players that leads to a particular sorting of personsamong countries.

Persons residing in any particular country of origin will often consider the possibility ofremaining there or of migrating elsewhere. They make the migration decision by comparingthe "offers" made by the various alternative destinations, and presumably choose the country

that makes them best off given the financial and legal constraints that regulate the interna-

tional migration process.The "offer" made by a particular country obviously includes economic considerations,

such as income opportunities and the likelihood of long-term unemployment spells. Eachcountry offers a specific set of economic opportunities. These income and employment op-portunities can be described in terms of the existing income distribution where certain typesof skills are highly rewarded and other types are not; wherejobs in some industries are easilyavailable, but jobs in other industries are scarce; where some occupations are in high de-mand, but high levels of unemployment persist in others; and where persons who experi-

ence relatively poor labor market outcomes are subsidized by the welfare state, while persons

who experience favorable outcomes may be heavily taxed. These differences in income and

employment opportunities by skill, industry, and occupation imply that the attractiveness ofthe offer made by a particular host country will, in general, differ among potential migrants.

Some potential migrants may find the offers lucrative; others may not.

It is instructive to think of the offer made by a particular country in much broader termsthan the economic considerations detailed above. The offer's value will also depend on po-

litical conditions in the particular country, and on the cultural and social networks that might

link the source country with the destination country. These "non-economic" characteristics

2

Page 13: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

are obviously important determinants of the attractiveness of any particular country to a

potential migrant. There is obviously a great deal of variation in the value of the offers made

by different countries, simply because economic opportunities, as well as well as cultural,

social, and political conditions, vary greatly across countries.

In the absence of any constraints on the migration process, all persons would simply move

to the country that makes the best offer.3 There exist a number of constraints, however, that

lower the chances that persons can move to the country offering the best opportunities. The

constraints include the potential migrant's financial resources. After all, migration is costly.

The costs include direct expenditures (such as the out-of-pocket expenses of transporting

the immigrant and family to their new home), as well as indirect costs (such as the income

losses associated with unemployment spells that occur as immigrants look for work in the

new country). Because only those persons who have accumulated sufficient savings and wealth

can afford to migrate, the potential migrant's financial resources obviously restrict the immi-

gration decision. Moreover, immigration also imposes so-called "psychic costs" on the poten-

tial migrant because the migrant is often leaving behind friends, family, language, and cul-

ture, and starting life over in an alien environment. These psychic costs are probably lower

the more extensive the cultural and social links between the source and destination coun-tries. These social networks have been found to be important determinants of the source of

migration flows in the U.S. context. 4

The immigration policies pursued by the potential host countries also play an importantrole in the migration decision. These policies can encourage, discourage, or altogether pre-

vent the entry of certain groups of persons. Host countries typically regulate the size and skillcomposition of the immigrant flow by imposing restrictions on entry according to the poten-tial migrant's skills, wealth, occupation, political background, moral rectitude, national ori-

gin, or familial relationships with current residents. In one sense, these regulations generatedifferences in migration costs among potential migrants. For example, current immigrationpolicy in the United States makes immigration costs almost prohibitive for persons who donot already have relatives residing here (since few visas are allotted to persons without these

family connections). Other host countries, such as Australia and Canada, have a "point sys-tem" in which potential immigrants are screened and graded on the basis of their educa-

tional attainment, age, occupation, and other demographic characteristics, and only thoseindividuals who pass the test can enter the country. Immigration policies, by their very na-

ture, impose different costs on different people, and act as a screening device to filter out"less desirable" persons from the entry pool.

The home countries of potential migrants are the last major players in the immigrationmarket. Their economies also provide a certain set of income and employment opportuni-

ties to their residents, and their emigration policies sometimes regulate the size and skill

composition of the outgoing flow. In some countries, like the United States, citizens are free

to leave the country whenever they wish, for any duration, and for whatever reason. In othercountries, emigration statutes impose large costs and penalties on potential emigrants, some-

times through the tax system or through the "threat" of losing one's nationality (and what-

ever rights derive therefrom) if the potential migrant becomes a citizen of another country.

Although I have emphasized that the value of a country's offer can be interpreted in terms

of both economic and non-economic considerations, most of the empirical studies that at-

tempt to analyze migration flows typically focus on the economic determinants of migration.

3

Page 14: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

As a result, it is traditionally assumed that the migration decision is motivated by a person's

desire to maximize his or her economic opportunities. After a potential migrant compares

all of the feasible opportunities, therefore, he or she chooses to reside in the country that

maximizes income net of migration costs-subject to the constraints imposed by the immi-

gration policies of the various countries.

This approach to the migration decision, therefore, immediately implies that interna-

tional differences in incomes are a prime determinant of the size and direction of immigrant

flows. Put simply, immigrants tend to gravitate from low-income countries to high-income

countries. Furthermore, the larger the income differential between the countries, the larger

the size of the population flow. For instance, the wage differential between Mexico and the

United States is perhaps the largest income gap between any two contiguous countries in the

world. It should not be too surprising, therefore, that large migration flows originate in Mexico

and move towards the United States, rather than the other way around.

The size and direction of international population flows also depend on the costs of leav-ing the source country and of entering a particular host country. Distance is probably an

important determinant of the "direct" costs of migration-although many of the advances in

transportation during the twentieth century have greatly weakened the link between dis-

tance and migration costs. Nevertheless, it is likely that persons have more (and better) infor-mation-as well as more extensive social and cultural links-with countries that are closer tohome. As a result, migration flows will typically be larger among countries that are geographi-

cally (and culturally) close to each other.As I noted earlier, one can interpret the restrictions placed by immigration policy as part

of the migration costs. In some cases, income differentials between two countries are suffi-ciently large that persons may be willing to incur the costs of migration-even if no visas are

available-by entering the host country illegally. In the United States, for example, there are

5 million permanent illegal aliens, and this population increases by around 300 thousandpersons annually.5 To deter this type of illegal migration, many countries impose penalties on

residents who break the immigration statutes. The penalties typically include sanctions on

the employers who hire illegal aliens, and sometimes may also include a fine on the illegalaliens themselves. If these penalties are sufficiently high-which they obviously are not in the

U.S. context-one might expect that the illegal alien flow would be relatively small becausefew persons can afford to bear such costs.

In other cases, such as migration flows within the territories of the United States, there are

no migration policies to restrict the size, direction, and skill composition of population flows.Persons born in any part of the United States, including its territories, such as Puerto Rico,for instance, are free to move to and work in any other location within the United States.Similarly, persons residing in any European Union country that adheres to the Schengen

Agreement are entitled to move and work in any other member country. These cases exem-plify a policy of "open migration," and the particular sorting of persons across countries that

occurs in these cases will reflect only the differences in the net values of the offers made by

the member states within each political grouping.

In addition to the implications about the size and direction of international population

flows, the economic approach to immigration can also tell us much about the skill composi-tion of the immigrant pool. Consider, for example, the migration of Mexicans to the United

4

Page 15: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

States. Even though it is very large (7 million Mexican-born persons were living in the United

States in 1997), it is still small when compared to the Mexican population. In 1997, there

were about 105 million Mexican-born persons, which means fewer than 7 percent of the

Mexican population had chosen to move to the United States.

It would be hard to blame restrictive immigration policies for Mexico's relatively low out-

migration rate. The U.S.-Mexico border is notoriously porous, and can be crossed illegally by

almost anyone who really wants to. Moreover, per-capita income in the United States is more

than three times that of Mexico, even after adjusting for differences in purchasing power.6

The fact that only 7 percent of Mexico's population had chosen to migrate to the United

States in 1997 raises two interesting points.

First, it is clear that even very large income differentials across contiguous countries with a

very porous border are not sufficient to motivate a large bulk of the population to move to a

different country.Second, it is not sufficient to know that only 7 percent of Mexicans find it beneficial to

migrate to the United States. Perhaps more important is the question which 7 percent? Are

the immigrants drawn from the pool of skilled Mexican workers, or are they drawn from the

unskilled? Any assessment of the economic impact of immigration on the host country (as

well as on the source country) will obviously depend on the answer to this question.

The subsample of persons who choose to emigrate from a particular country is self-se-lected from that country's population. The fact that some persons choose to migrate, while

others do not, implies that immigrants differ in significant ways from the rest of the popula-tion. Moreover, the immigrant flow that eventually reaches any particular country of destina-

tion is filtered through a form of "double" self-selection. The immigrant flow in the UnitedStates, for example, contains only those persons who found it profitable to leave their homecountries and who found it unprofitable to migrate to an alternative host country. The self-selection of immigrants implies that the average immigrant residing in a particular host countrydiffers from the average person in the host country and in the source country they came

from.The economic impact of immigration is clearly affected by the type of skill sorting that

takes place. The immigration of unskilled workers, for instance, may allow manufacturers inthe host country to fill menial jobs that require few skills with relatively low-wage labor. Onthe other hand, the immigration of skilled workers helps staff universities, hospitals, and

scientific laboratories. In addition, the immigration of the unskilled may have a differentimpact on native labor market conditions, on tax revenues, and on the costs of social pro-grams than the immigration of the skilled. To a large extent, therefore, the economic impactof immigration is largely determined by the nature of the self-selection that takes place as

persons decide in which country to reside.

To illustrate how the self-selection process generates a particular type of immigrant flow, it

is instructive to consider the situation faced by a particular host country, such as the UnitedStates. We can then ask, does the United States attract the most skilled workers from any

given source country, or the least skilled workers?7

Suppose that persons make their migration decision by comparing only the economic

opportunities provided by a particular source country with those provided by the United

States. Also, consider a group of workers who currently live in a country where the payoff to

D

Page 16: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

human capital is relatively low, so that skilled workers do not earn much more than less

skilled workers. This situation may be common in some Western European countries, such as

Sweden and Germany, where the welfare state and other social policies tend to equalize the

income distribution, taxing the highly skilled and subsidizing the less skilled. As long as

persons migrate to the countries that provide the best economic opportunities, the workers

who have the most to gain by moving to the United States are the workers who have above-

average skills. The United States would then benefit from a brain drain; immigrants, in ef-

fect, are "positively selected" from the population of the countries of origin.

Alternatively, consider workers living in countries where the payoff to human capital is

relatively high. The rewards to skills are often quite high in many developing countries, such

as Mexico and the Philippines. 8 These high rewards to skills partly account for the very un-

equal distributions of incomes observed in these countries, where the skilled earn substan-

tially more than the less skilled. Highly skilled workers residing in these countries often face

better economic opportunities than they would face if they migrated to the United States,

while less skilled workers can barely rise above the subsistence level. As long as persons mi-

grate to countries that provide better economic opportunities, the skilled workers in these

countries have little incentive to leave. It is the least skilled who want to emigrate, and theimmigrant flow will be composed of workers with below-average skills. Immigrants, in effect,are "negatively selected" from the population of the countries of origin.

In short, as long as economic considerations matter in the migration decision, skills tendto flow to those markets that offer the highestvalue. Immigrants originating in countries that

offer relatively high rewards to human capital will tend to be less-skilled, while immigrantsoriginating in countries that offer relatively low rewards to human capital will be relativelyhighly skilled. From the perspective of any potential host country, such as the United States,

the country will likely attract highly skilled workers from some source countries (the coun-

tries where the returns to skills are low), and unskilled workers from other source countries(the countries where the returns to skills are high).

In the end, persons participating in the "immigration market" are matched with the coun-

tries that reward the specific skill characteristics they have to offer. This is the central implica-tion of the economic approach to the analysis of immigration. As long as individuals migrateto take advantage of differential economic opportunities among countries, there is no rea-

son to presume that any particular host country will always attract the "best and the bright-est," or to presume that this country will be continually flooded with the least skilled persons

of the source countries.It is worth summarizing the lessons implied by the economic approach to the analysis of

immigration in terms of a few simple propositions:

1. The greater the differences in economic opportunities between a sending country

and a receiving country, the larger the number of persons who will migrate fromthe low-income country to the high-income country.

2. The more expensive it is to migrate from one country to another, the smaller the

number of persons who will choose to do so. The migration costs will typically

include the actual dollar costs associated with the move, the psychic costs imposedby moving to an alien social and cultural environment, and the penalties imposed

on those who facilitate the entry and employment of illegal aliens.

6

Page 17: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

3. The greater the rewards to human capital offered by a particular country of

destination, the more likely that the persons who choose to move there are

relatively skilled.

The Link between Immigration and Trade

The discussion of the factors that underlie the decision to immigrate has implicitly been

conducted in what economists call a "partial equilibrium" framework. In particular, the in-

come opportunities in the host and source countries are taken as given, and potential mi-

grants respond to-and do not affect-these income opportunities. As we will see below, how-

ever, by shifting the supplies of workers from one country to another, the process of migra-

tion will itself change the income opportunities available in each country in the long run,

helping equalize incomes across countries.

There are, however, other links across the two economies that can help equalize economic

opportunities even in the absence of migration flows. This fact is quite important in the

context of the European Union since capital, goods, and services can flow unimpeded among

the member states.

In one important sense, immigration and trade are substitutable ways in which countries

can respond to the relative abundance or the relative lack of particular factors of production.In fact, standard models of trade and immigration suggest that immigration and trade alternational output and the distribution of income through the same mechanism-by increas-ing the nation's effective supply of relatively scarce factors of production. 9

Suppose, for instance, that country A has a relative abundance of skilled labor, while coun-try B has a relative abundance of less skilled workers. In the absence of any links between the

two countries, this distribution of skill endowments across countries would suggest that the

skilled-unskilled wage ratio would be far higher in country B. Immigration between the twocountries would help equalize the skilled-unskilled wage ratio because the less skilled work-

ers would tend to move from country B to country A, while the more skilled workers wouldmove in the other direction. But this change in the wage ratio could also be accomplished

through trade-even in the absence of any migration flows. After all, country A would want

to import the goods produced by less skilled workers, increasing the wage of these workers in

country B; while country B would want to import the goods produced by skilled workers,increasing the wage of these workers in country A. In the end, trade flows would help equal-

ize economic opportunities for each skill group across countries.

In fact, it is not even necessary for trade flows to actually occur in order for the equaliza-

tion process to take place. Suppose, for instance, that a Portuguese firm begins producing

Tower of London souvenirs and informs the London souvenir stands that it can provide the

product at a lower price than English producers. The souvenir stands will then inform the

English manufacturers that they have to meet the new price to keep their business. The

English firms, in turn, will tell their workers that they can stay competitive only if the workers

take a pay cut. If the workers accept the pay cut, the English firms maintain their hold on the

Tower of London souvenir market-and the wages of these workers were effectively set by

the economic conditions existing in Portugal. If the workers do not accept the pay cut, the

English companies will no longer be competitive, and the English workers lose their jobs as

the production of Tower of London souvenirs moves to Portuguese factories. In short, the

7

Page 18: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

threat of trade flows can help equalize economic opportunities across countries about as wellas actual trade flows can.

It is useful to recognize that both trade and immigration increase the "effective" labor

supply of particular groups of workers in a particular labor market. Every time the United

States imports an automobile from Japan, for example, the country is effectively importing

say 350 man-hours of engineering know-how, 250 man-hours of less skilled labor, and so on.In other words, one can interpret the entry of this automobile into the U.S. market as theimmigration of workers with particular skills.

Regardless of how the "globalization" process takes place-through labor flows, capitalflows, or trade-the end result is the same. By increasing the links across distinct economies,these flows help to equalize economic opportunities across markets. The presence of one ofthese flows, in effect, reduces the incentives for the other types of flows to occur. In the

context of the European Union, this implies that the capital and goods flows that occurunimpeded within the community will, in the long run, help reduce the income differentialsthat serve as the impetus for migration flows in the first place.

2. Evidence from the United StatesImmigration to the United States is an important demographic factor in some source coun-tries, and a relatively unimportant one in others. Table 1 reports the number of immigrantsto the United States between 1970 and 1990 originating in a particular source country as apercent of the source country's population in 1980. There is a great deal of variation in this(rough) measure of the emigration rate across source countries.'" Over 10 percent of thepopulation of Guyana andJamaica migrated to the United States between 1970 and 1990, ascompared to less than 1 percent of the population in Denmark, Greece, or Italy.

A number of studies have uncovered a strong correlation between the rate of emigrationand economic conditions in the source and host countries. The following equation summa-rizes the statistical relationships that are typically discussed in the academic literature:"

Emigration Rate = 13.0 - .2 (per-capita GDP in the source country, in $1000s)-. 7 (distance from the United States, in 1000s of miles)

The per-capita income of the source country is measured as of 1985 and gives the (purchas-ing-power-parity adjusted) per-capita GDP of the source country. There is clearly a stronglink between the emigration rate and per-capita income in the source country: a five thou-sand dollar increase in per-capita GDP reduces the emigration rate by one percentage point.There are huge differences in per-capita GDP across source countries. For instance, per-capita GDP is only $911 in Haiti, $5,621 in Mexico, and over $15,000 in Canada. The statisti-cal correlation between the emigration rate and per-capita income suggests that interna-tional differences in income levels can generate substantial differences in the emigration

rate.

The empirical analysis also illustrates how migration costs deter population flows acrosscountries. The out-migration rate falls by almost 1 percentage point for every 1000-mile in-crease in the distance between the source country and a gateway city in the United States.This measure of migration costs probably ignores a large part of what truly deters persons

8

Page 19: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Table 1 Emigration Rate to the United Statesfrom Selected Countries, 1970-90

Number of immigrantsas percent of 1985 Per-capita GDP Distancefrom the

population in in sending country United StatesCountyy of origin sending country (in 1985 dollars) (lOOOs of miles)

Australia 0.15 13583 7.6Austria 0.13 11131 4.2Barbados 11.64 6131 1.6Belgium 0.12 11285 3.7Canada 0.84 15589 0.4China 0.04 1262 6.3Costa Rica 1.07 3184 1.1Czechoslovakia 0.12 3920 4.1Denmark 0.22 12969 3.9Dominican Republic 4.26 2111 0.8El Salvador 9.27 1831 1.0France 0.09 12206 3.6Germany 0.12 12535 3.8Greece 0.71 6224 4.9Guyana 13.38 1265 1.8Haiti 3.25 911 0.7HongKong 2.11 10599 7.3Hungary 0.20 5278 4.4Ireland 1.28 7275 3.2Italy 0.20 10808 4.3Jamaica 11.41 2215 0.6Lao, PDR 5.52 1340 8.0Mexico 4.34 5621 1.3Nicaragua 4.65 1790 1.1Philippines 1.36 1542 7.3Poland 0.46 4177 4.3Portugal 1.13 5070 3.4Spain 0.11 7536 3.6Swveden 0.22 13451 3.9Trinidad 7.55 9701 1.6United Kingdom (.09 11237 3.5Former Soviet Union 0.07 7049 4.7

Sour(e: The emigration rate is calctilated by combining counts of immigrants from the U.S. Census wvith sourcecountry population data. The per-capita GDP data are drawn from Stummers and Heston (1992). The distancedata are drawn from Fitzpatrick and Madlin (1986).

from moving across international boundaries, such as the pain of separation from friends

and family, and differences in cultures and languages.

The overall point of the statistical equation, however, is to show that differences in per-

capita income across countries play an important role in determining migration flows. As a

result, the number of migrants can be expected to fall considerably if an ongoing process of

trade and development (such as the one in place in the European Union) helps equalize

economic opportunities across countries over time.

An interesting example of 'international" migration flows when there are no policies re-

stricting entry into the United States arises in the case of Puerto Rico. In fact, the relationship

9

Page 20: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

between Puerto Rico and the United States-in the context of the migration issue-is of

particular relevance to the European Union and to studies of migration flows across member

states.

The island of Puerto Rico was ceded to the United States by Spain in 1898, and became a

commonwealth in 1952. All persons born in Puerto Rico are U.S. citizens by birth and as suchcan move freely within the territories under U.S. jurisdiction. In other words, there are no

legal restrictions on the number or type of persons who can migrate between Puerto Rico

and the United States. In an important sense, however, Puerto Rico and the mainland United

States resemble different countries. They offer very different economic opportunities, have

different cultures, and the population speaks different languages. Because of the special

political relationship between Puerto Rico and the United States, the population flows will

likely provide a clear-cut example of the types of immigration that will occur when countries

enact "open migration" policies.

The differences in economic opportunities betwveen Puerto Rico and the United States

are quite large. In 1990, for example, median family income was $35,225 in the United States,but only $9,988 in Puerto Rico. Similarly, the unemployment rate was 6.3 percent in the

'United States, but 20.4 percent in Puerto Rico.)2

Ramos (1992) presents a detailed analysis of the population flows generated by these largedifferences in economic opportunities. In 1980, almost 1 million out of the 4 million persons

born in Puerto Rico were living in the United States-generating an emigration rate of about25 percent. Although the Puerto Rican migration to the United States is obviously large bothin absolute and relative numbers, it is still worth considering why more Puerto Ricans did not

choose to emigrate. After all, the income differences between Puerto Rico and the UnitedStates are quite large. Second, there are no legal restrictions preventing Puerto Ricans frommoving to and working in the mainland United States. Third, there exist large and vibrantethnic communities of Puerto Ricans in many American cities, and these ethnic communi-ties should help provide information about the opportunities offered by the United States as

well as lower the adjustments costs of migration. Finally, the direct costs of migration are

quite low; air travel on the competitive routes between Puerto Rico and many of the largecities in the U.S. eastern seaboard is inexpensive. In short, the remarkable thing is not that

25 percent of Puerto Ricans migrated to the United States, but that 75 percent of PuertoRicans did not.

The Puerto Rican case study, in fact, provides unambiguous evidence that important non-economic factors help to restrain migration flows. These restraining factors may include

differences in language and cultures across the localities, and the "psychic costs" of leavingbehind a familiar environment and entering a new alien environment.

As an alternative example of migration flows when there are "open migration" policies,consider the migration of workers within the United States. There exists a huge academic

literature analyzing the factors that motivate workers in the United States to move across

regions (see Greenwood, 1975, for a survey).13 The United States is a very mobile country. In

any given year, roughly 3 percent of the population move across counties within a given state

and an additional 3 percent move across state lines. 4 As noted earlier, the migration flows of

workers across areas of the United States are not regulated in any way. However, the cultural

and linguistic differences across states in the United States are relatively minor when

10

Page 21: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

contrasted to those that exist between Puerto Rico and the United States, or among the

member states of the European Union.

One key lesson from the academic literature on U.S. internal migration flows is that inter-

state differences in economic opportunities help determine the size and direction of these

migration flows. Internal migrants are more likely to originate in states that have relatively

low incomes and to migrate to states that have relatively high incomes. Similarly, internal

migrants are more likely to originate in states that have relatively high unemployment rates,

and to migrate to states that have relatively low unemployment rates.

Much of the research effort in the U.S. internal migration literature has been devoted to

describing the socioeconomic characteristics of the population of internal migrants. Inter-

nal migrants in the United States tend to be relatively young. For instance, 5 percent ofAmericans aged 20-24 years old move across states in any given year, as compared to only I

percent of Americans aged 45 to 64.15 Moreover, there is a strong positive correlation be-

tween the probability of internal migration and education. This correlation probably arises

because educated workers have more (and better) information about labor market condi-

tions in other parts of the country. Moreover, the geographic "extent" of the labor market is

probably larger for more educated workers. In other words, more educated workers are moreapt to sell their skills in a national labor market, whereas the demand for less educated work-ers is more localized."6

A number of studies of the U.S. experience also attempt to test the theoretical insight thatinternational differences in the rewards to skills help determine the skill composition of theimmigrant population. For example, Borjas (1987) reports that measures of income inequal-ity in the source country, which are a rough proxy for the rate of return to skills, are nega-tively correlated with the earnings of immigrant men in the United States.'7 Holding con-

stant a vector of observable socioeconomic characteristics (including educational attainmentand age), the point estimates suggest that Mexican immigrant men earn about 4 percent less

than British immigrants simply because of the selectivity effect resulting from Mexico havinga higher rate of return to skills than the United Kingdom. Cobb-Clark (1993) finds a similar

negative correlation between the earnings of immigrant women in the United States andmeasures of the rate of return to schooling in the source countries. Finally, Edward Taylor's(1987) case study of migration in a rural Mexican village concludes that Mexicans who mi-

grated illegally to the United States are less skilled, on average, than the typical person resid-

ing in the village. This type of selection is consistent with the fact that Mexico has a relatively

high rate of return to skills.Ramos (1992) also used the Puerto Rican experience to analyze some of these selection

issues. The data reveal that Puerto Rican "immigrants" in the United States are relativelyunskilled. The typical Puerto Rican who migrated to the United States prior to 1975 had 9.4years of schooling, as compared to 10.8 years for a Puerto Rican who never left Puerto Rico.

The Puerto Rican migration flow, therefore, is negatively selected. This is precisely what onewould expect to find if the rewards to skills were larger in Puerto Rico than they were in theUnited States, and in fact this is the case. An additional year of schooling raises earnings by

about 30 percent more in Puerto Rico than in the United States. This differential in the

rewards to skills gives skilled workers in Puerto Rico little incentive to emigrate and hence

the immigrant flow is disproportionately less skilled.

11

Page 22: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

The empirical evidence on the self-selection of immigrants, in fact, provides an interest-

ing explanation of what is perhaps the most important fact about immigration to the United

States: the relative economic performance of immigrants in the United States has worsened

considerably since 1970. For example, in 1970 the typical immigrant in the country had 10.7

years of schooling, as compared to 11.5 vears for the typical native worker. By 1990, the

typical immigrant had 11.6 years of schooling, as compared to 13.2 years for natives. The

relative decline in the educational attainment of immigrants is partly responsible for a sub-

stantial increase in the wage gap between immigrants and natives. In 1970, the typical immi-

grant earned about 1 percent more than natives; by 1990, the typical immigrant earned 15.2

percent less than natives.

Prior to changes in immigration policy enacted in 1965, the allocation of entry visas was

determined mainly by the eihnic composition of the U.S. population in 1920, and thus fa-vored immigration from a small number of Western European countries. The 1965 Amend-

ments repealed the "national-origins quota system" and greatly increased the number ofimmigrants originating in Asian and Latin American countries. The new immigration, there-

fore, is more likely to originate in countries where the population tends to be less skilled and

where the rate of return to skills is relatively high. These factors should contribute to a de-cline in the relative skills of successive immigrant waves.

3. The Economic Impact of Immigration

A key part of the debate over immigration in most host countries is the concern that immi-grants have an adverse impact on the economic opportunities of native-born workers. Re-markably, there was little empirical study of these important questions prior to the 1980s.

When Greenwood and McDowell (1986, p. 1750) first surveyed the literature in 1986, theyconcluded that "substantive empirical evidence regarding the effects of immigration is gen-erally scarce.... Little direct evidence is available on immigration's impact on the employ-ment opportunities and wages of domestic workers." The situation has changed dramaticallysince. And although much of the existing literature documents the impact that immigrants

have on the native labor market in the United States, a growing number of studies extend the

analysis to other countries.There are two opposing views about how immigrants affect the native labor market. One

approach asserts that immigrants have a harmful effect because immigrant and native work-ers are easily substitutable by employers in the host country. That is, immigrants and nativestend to have similar skills and are suited for similar types ofjobs. An influx of immigrantsthus reduces the wage of native-born workers. In addition, because of the lower wages nowpaid to native workers, some native workers find it worthwhile to withdra-W from the laborforce and native employment also falls.

It is possible, however, that immigrants and natives are not interchangeable types of work-

ers, but that they complement each other in the production process. For instance, some

immigrant groups may have very low skill levels and have a comparative advantage in agricul-

tural production. The presence of immigrants increases native productivity because natives

can now specialize in tasks where they too have a comparative advantage. This makes nativesmore valuable to firms and increases the firm's demand for native-born labor, bidding up thenative wage. In addition, some natives who previously did not find it profitable to work will

12

Page 23: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

now see the higher wage rate as an additional incentive to enter the labor market, and native

employment also rises.

This conceptual approach suggests a way in which the impact of immigration on native

employment opportunities can be measured. If we could observe a number of closed labor

markets that immigrants penetrate randomly, we can then relate the change in the wage of

natives to the proportion of immigrants in the population. The estimated parameters would

summarize the impact of immigrants on native employment opportunities.

Practically all empirical studies in the literature, beginning with Grossman (1982), at-

tempt to replicate this experiment by treating a city or metropolitan area in the United States

as the empirical counterpart of the closed labor market in the conceptual analysis. The typi-

cal study then correlates a measure of the native wage in the locality on the relative quantity

of immigrants in that locality (or the change in the wage in the locality over a specified time

period on the change in the number of immigrants in the locality).

Table 2 summarizes the results of the "spatial correlation" approach in the economics

literature. The spatial correlations in the United States generally indicate that the averagenative wage is slightly lower in labor markets where immigrants tend to reside. 9 A typical

study finds that if one city has 10 percent more immigrants than another, the native wage inthe city with more immigrants is only about .2 percent lower. The evidence also indicates that

the numerically weak relationship between native wages and immigration is observed across

all types of native workers, white or black, skilled or unskilled, male or female.Studies of specific labor markets confirm the finding that immigration seems to have little

impact even when the market receives very large immigrant flows. On April 20, 1980, Fidel

Castro declared that Cuban nationals wishing to move to the United States could leave freelyfrom the port of Mariel. By September 1980, about 125,000 Cubans, mostly unskilled work-

ers, had chosen to undertake the journey. Almost overnight, Miami's labor force had unex-pectedly grown by 7 percent. Card's (1990) influential analysis of the data indicates that the

time-series trend in wages and employment opportunities for Miami's workers, including its

Table 2. The Impact of Immigration on the Wage of Native Workers in the United States(Predicted impact of a 10 percent increase in the number of immigrants residing in a particularlocality)

Impact of Percentage changeStudy Imnmigrants on: in native wage

Altonji and Card Less Skilled Natives +.l(1991,p. 220)

Bean. Lowell, and Native Mexican Men -.05 to +.5Taylor (1988, p. 44) Black Men -.03 to +.6

Borjas (1990, p. 87) W'hite Native Men -.1Black Native Men +.2

Grossman (1982, p. 600) All Natives -.2

LaLonde and Topel Young Black Natives -.6(1991, p. 186) Young Hispanic Natives -.1

Source: Boijas (1994).

13

Page 24: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

black population, was barely nudged by the Mariel flow. The trend in the wage and unem-

ployment rates of Miami's workers between 1980 and 1985 was similar to that experienced by

workers in such cities as Los Angeles, Houston and Atlanta, cities which did not experience

the Mariel flow.

In short, the estimated correlations between native wages and the immigrant share in

local labor markets do not support the hypothesis that the employment opportunities of

U.S.-born workers are strongly and adversely affected by immigration. Moreover, the evi-

dence for other host countries is similar. Pischke and Velling's (1994) study of the German

labor market estimates the same types of spatial correlations that dominate the U.S. litera-

ture, and finds aweak negative correlation between the native wage and the fraction of immi-

grants in the work force; and Hunt (1992) reports that, even though 900,000 persons re-

turned to France within one year after the 1962 independence of Algeria (increasing the

French labor force by 2 percent), there was little impact on the affected localities.2 0

Recent research, however, has begun to argue that the spatial correlation approach does

not replicate the conceptual experiment described earlier and hence does not answer the

question of whether native-born workers are adversely affected by immigration. In particular,

the comparison of economic conditions in different metropolitan areas, as well as the pre-and post-immigration comparison in a particular metropolitan area, presumes that the labor

markets are closed (once immigration takes place) and that the migration flow is exogenous.

Metropolitan areas in the United States or in other countries are not closed economies;

labor, capital, and goods often flow freely across localities and tend to equalize factor pricesin the process. As long as native workers and firms respond to the entry of immigrants by

moving to areas offering better opportunities, there is no reason to expect a correlation

between the wage of native-born workers and the presence of immigrants.Suppose, for example, that immigration into California lowers the earnings of natives in

California substantially. Native workers are not likely to stand idly by and watch their eco-nomic opportunities evaporate. Many will move out of California into other regions, and

persons who were considering moving to California will now move somewhere else instead.

As native workers respond to immigration by 'voting with their feet," the adverse impact ofimmigration on California's labor market is transmitted to the entire economy. In the end,

all native workers are worse off from immigration, not simply those residing in the areaswhere immigrants cluster.2 ' The same type of labor market re-equilibration can occur as a

result of capital flows. Immigration of less-skilled workers into California might encouragecapitalists who were planning to open up a manufacturing plant in Detroit to move to Cali-fornia instead.2 2

In short, the comparison of local labor markets may be masking the "macro" effect ofimmigration. Because native-born labor and native-owned capital respond to immigration,

the labor market impact of immigration cannot be measured by looking at what happens to

local labor markets, but instead must be measured at the national level. A recent study of

time-series data by Borjas, Freeman, and Katz (1997) provides indirect evidence of this macro

impact of immigration. Between 1979 and 1995, immigration increased the supply of work-

ers who were high school dropouts by 21 percent, but increased the supply of workers with atleast a high school diploma by only 4 percent. In short, immigration changed the factor

proportions in the American economy-generating a relative "abundance" of less-skilled

workers. The existing evidence on how relative wages respond to changes in relative supplies

14

Page 25: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

implies that immigration reduced the relative wage of high school dropouts by about 5 per-

centage points.2 2 As a result, about 44 percent of the widening wage gap between high school

dropouts and high school graduates can be attributed to the large impact of immigration on

the relative number of high school dropouts.2 4

To reconcile the finding that local labor markets in the United States do not seem to be

affected by immigration with the possible existence of an economy-wide impact, Filer (1992),

Frey (1995), Card (1997) and Borjas, Freeman, and Katz (1997) have analyzed the possibility

that the internal migration flows of U.S.-born workers respond to immigration. There is

clear and unambiguous evidence of a potential relation between immigration and native

migration decisions (see figure 1).25 The resurgence of immigration in the United States

began about 1968, when the policy changes enacted in 1965 became effective. It seems natu-ral, therefore, to contrast pre-1970 changes in the residential location of the native-born

population with post-1970 changes to assess the effects of immigration on native location

decisions.Not surprisingly, the share of natives who lived in California, the major immigrant receiv-

ing state, was rising rapidly prior to 1970. What is surprising, however, is that the share of

natives living in California barely budged between 1970 and 1990, and declined somewhatduring the 1990s.2 " Nevertheless, California's share of the total population kept rising con-

tinuously until 1990, from 7 percent in 1950, to 10 percent in 1970, to 12 percent in 1990.

Figure 1 Trends in California's Population, 1950-1998

Percent of U.S. population living in California.

13

12Total Population

10

9

7

6

1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000

YearSource: Borjas, Freeman, and Katz (1997), p. 27, and additional calculations from the 1995-1997 CurrentPopulation Surveys (Annual Demographic Files).

15

Page 26: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Put differently, an extrapolation of the population growth that existed before 1970-before the

resurgence of immigration-would have predicted the state's 1990 share of the population quite

accurately. But while natives pouring into the state fueled California's population growth

before 1970, immigrants alone fueled the post-197 0 growth.

How should one interpret this fact? One interpretation is that around 1970, for reasons

unknown, Americans simply changed their mind and stopped moving to California. In other

words, if it were not for immigration, California's rapid population growth would have stalled

in the 1970s and 1980s. An alternative interpretation is that immigration into California

essentially "displaced" the population growth that would have occurred in the immigrants' ab-

sence, and this displacement effectively diffused the economic impact of immigration from

California to the rest of the country.

The response of California's population trends to immigration is not unique. Considerwhat happened to Miami's population after the entry of the Mariel flow in 1980.27 Miami's

population grew at an annual rate of 2.5 percent in the 1970s, as compared to a growth rate

of 3.9 percent for the rest of Florida. After the arrival of the Marielitos, Miami's annual growth

rate slowed to 1.4 percent, as compared to 3.4 percent in the rest of Florida. As a result of this

slowdown in the relative number of persons moving to the Miami area, the actual populationof Dade County in 1986 was roughly the same as the pre-Mariel projection made by the

University of Florida.In both the California and the Miami case, therefore, an observer who was familiar with

the demographic trends of the region prior to the entry of immigrants could have almostperfectly predicted what the state's population would have been at some future time. Re-markably, the observer did not need to know that each of these regions was to experience anunexpected and sizable increase in immigration.

Because native workers vote with their feet in the U.S. context, it is likely that comparisonsof local labor markets is not the right approach to estimate the economic impact of immigra-

tion on the host country's labor market. This fact has important implications for the analysisof the economic impact of migration flows across the member states of the European Union.

The flows of capital, goods, and services will effectively help diffuse the impact of immigra-tion away from the areas most directly affected. A migration flow of less-skilled workers from

country A to country B, for instance, might induce capitalists in country C to open up a

manufacturing plant in country B-effectively increasing the opportunities available to less-skilled workers in country B, while reducing them in country C. Because of the extensive

economic ties that exist across the member states, it would be futile to uncover the effects ofmigration from one member state to another by simply looking at economic conditions inonly those two states. In short, the economic ties that link the members of the European

Union help to diffuse the impact of an "immigrant supply shock" over the entire community.

4. Implications for the European UnionThe freedom of movement of persons-together with the freedom of movement of capital,goods, and services-is a general right within the European Union. In theory, the creation of

a single market should create many additional employment and earnings opportunities forthe workers in the member states of the EUT. In addition, the unimpeded flows of labor,

16

Page 27: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

capital, goods, and service should greatly reduce inter-country differences in economic op-

portunities within the community.

Migration policy has been and will continue to be an important issue in negotiations be-

tween the European Commission and countries applying for accession to the European Union.

There is, for instance, the obvious concern that migration flows into the richer member

states from the acceding countries would cause downward pressures on wages in the richer

states and further exacerbate the serious unemployment problem that already exists in many

countries of the EU. In the past, these concerns encouraged EU negotiators to propose a

"transition period" during which citizens from the acceding countries would face some re-

strictions if they wished to migrate within the EU. This transition period, in fact, was part of

the agreement that enabled the entry of Greece, Portugal, and Spain into the community.

The same concerns over the potential economic impact of migration flows are being raised

during the negotiations between the European Commission and acceding countries from

Central and Eastern Eirope (CEE). And, again, there has been some mention of a transition

period during which there would be some restrictions on migration from the CEE countries

to the current member states of the European Union.The concern over the impact of migration flows enters the accession negotiations in less

direct ways. It is likely, for example, that the negotiations will have to address the possibility of

migration flows originating in third countries. Some of the countries belonging to the first

wave of accession from CEE countries (the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Poland, and

Slovenia) could become transit countries for migration flows originating in countries thatmight be part of the second wave of accession, or perhaps from countries even further east or

in Asia. And, in fact, there has been some recognition that a tightening of the external bor-

ders might be a required part of the accession agreement.

Other migration issues that might come up during the accession negotiations include:

What should be the EU policy towards the migration of third-country nationals now living in

the acceding countries? Will the acceding countries be required to sign the Schengen Agree-

ments (which currently have been signed by 13 out of the 15 member states)? The Schengen

Agreements obligate the signing member states to remove all border controls among mem-

ber states of the EU, and to enforce the external borders.

While some of the acceding countries may not object to transition periods or to other

types of migration restrictions (very small migration flows, for example, will likely' originate

in Estonia or Slovenia), other countries, such as Hungary or Poland, may react strongly for

both economic and political reasons. There have been significant (legal and illegal) migra-

tion flows from Poland towards Western countries in recent years. For example, in 1995

Germany granted 181,600 work permits (for a first employment) to Poles, and an additional

22,000 Poles were recruited under bilateral agreements.2 8 Moreover, while migration from

Hungary to countries in the EU has been limited in the past, there are regular labor flows

between Hungary and the neighboring countries where large numbers of ethnic Hungar-

ians reside. And these migration flows might "spill over" into the European Union soon after

accession.All of these concerns over the link between the accession of countries from the CEE and

migration flows into the European Union will play an important role in the accession nego-

tiations. What insights does the existing research in the economics of immigration provide

17

Page 28: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

about the possible size and impact of the migration flows that might either originate in or

pass through the first wave of acceding countries in the CEE?

Implications of Research on Immigration

In my view, the key implication of the existing research is that migration flows that follow the

first wave of accession from the CEE countries will probably be relatively small.

The empirical evidence, for instance, suggests that differences in per-capita income are a

key determinant of the size and direction of migration flows. As we have seen, migration

flows into the United States originate mainly in countries where per-capita GDP is substan-

tially below that of the United States. The (purchasing-power-parity adjusted) per-capita GDPof the United States, for example, is about 3.5 times that of Mexico, 8 times that of the

Philippines, and 25 fimes that of Haiti.2 9

It is instructive to contrast these huge differences in economic opportunities with those

that exist between France or Germany, on the one hand, and some of the acceding countries

from the CEE. As table 3 shows, (purchasing-power-parity adjusted) per-capita GDP in France

or Germany in 1996 was over $21,000. In contrast, per-capita GDP in the Czech Republic wasaround $11,000, and in Hungary and Poland was between $6,000 and $7,000. The importantpoint is that the income differences between the European Community and the accedingcountries tend to be smaller (and often, much smaller) than those that generate sizablemigration flows to the United States. The negative link between per-capita GDP and emigra-tion rates, therefore, suggests that there is little reason to expect a large bulk of the popula-

tion in the acceding countries to take advantage of the opportunity to migrate to the currentmember states of the EU.

The research on the economics of migration also concludes that migration costs create animportant disincentive in the migration decision. Even though the acceding countries arerelatively near many of the potential destination countries in the EU, there are huge cultural

and linguistic differences among these countries. These differences increase the costs of

Table 3 Economic Characteristics of Selected Countries in the European Union and in Central and

Eastern Europe, 1996

Percent rate of growthCountry Per-capita GDP of per-capita GDP Unemployment rate

European UnionFrance 21,150 1.3 12.7Germany 21,110 1.4 10.8Portugal 13,450 3.0 7.0Spain 15,290 2.2 22.0United Kingdom 19,960 2.2 6.7

Central and Eastern EuropeCzech Republic 10,870 4.1 3.3Hungary 6,730 1.3 11.0Poland 6,000 5.9 13.3

Sources: The GDP data are drawn from World Bank (1998), and give the purchasing-power-parity adjusted per-capita GDP. The unemployment rate data is drawn from U.S. Central Intelligence Agency (1997).

18

Page 29: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

migration for persons originating in the CEE countries substantially, and generate an impor-

tant "brake" on any migration flow that might arise.An additional factor that might deter migration from the acceding countries to the cur-

rent member states of the Union is the severe unemployment problem that already exists in

many of the countries that might be potential countries of destination. In 1998, the unem-ployment rate was 10 percent in the 15-member European Union, 10 percent in Germany,

and 12.4 percent in France. The differences in per-capita income, therefore, do not accu-

rately reflect the differences in "expected" economic opportunities because the chances of

landing a job within a reasonable time period after migration are relatively small. Because

migration flows respond to differences in economic opportunities, the unemployment prob-

lem faced by many EU problems will further discourage migration from the acceding coun-

tries. It is important to note, however, that the existing unemployment problem in the EU

might not be an important deterrent of migration if the unemployment problem in the CEE

countries becomes more severe than in the EU countries. In 1996, the unemployment rate

was 11 percent in Hungary, 13 percent in Poland, and 3 percent in the Czech Republic.

The research literature provides some evidence on the role that cultural factors play in

generating or limiting migration flows. It is well known, for example, that large ethnic en-claves in the receiving countries act like "magnets," providing information to potential mi-

grants and lowering the costs of separating from the social networks that the migrants haveestablished in the source countries. There are few such magnets in current members of theEuropean Union that could serve to attract immigrants from the acceding countries. Fur-

thermore, a number of opinion polls suggest that most Hungarians would not leave theircountry under current economic and political conditions. A recent summary of these poll-ing data concludes: "According to the results of public opinion polls carried out repeatedly

since 1992, only 3 to 4 percent of the Hungarians would like to work abroad and only 1 to 2percent to emigrate. "'I Although the findings of public opinion polls regarding migration

incentives should be interpreted cautiously, it is of interest that the emigration rate sug-gested by these polls is relatively small (implying at most 200,000 adult migrants), and that

this emigration rate is roughly of the same magnitude as the emigration rate from most of

the poorer source countries that feed into the United States.It would be of interest to use the research findings to determine which types of persons

would be the ones who are most likely to migrate from the acceding countries to the current

member states. After all, the economic impact of migration on both the sending and receiv-ing countries will depend crucially on the types of persons who choose tojoin the migrationflows. As we have seen, economic research suggests that the skill composition of the migrantflow is determined mainly by differences in the rewards to skills across countries. The varia-

tion in the rewards to skills among European countries is relatively small, particularly when

compared to the differences in the rewards to skills between the United States and some of

the main sending countries to the United States, such as Mexico or the Philippines. Therelatively minor differences that exist in the returns to skills between countries in the Euro-

pean Union and the countries in the CEE would tend to suggest that the skill composition of

the immigrant flow would then be determined mainly by the costs of migration: only those

immigrants who can afford to move would join the population flow.3" Under most circum-

stances, this would suggest that the migrant flow would typically be composed of relatively

skilled workers, who typically have the resources to fund the move.

19

Page 30: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

In addition to the empirical evidence provided by analysis of migration flows to the United

States, there is also some existing evidence with respect to migration flows in the context of

the European Union. In particular, note that the income differences between the acceding

countries in the CEE and France, Germany, and the United Kingdom are only slightly larger

than the pre-accession income differences that existed between the original members of the

EU and Greece, Portugal, and Spain. In 1990, for instance, per-capita GDP in France was 80

percent greater than in Greece, 70 percent greater than in Portugal, and 44 percent greater

than in Spain.3 2

Although there was a great deal of concern that the accession of Greece, Portugal, and

Spain might generate substantial flows, the potential migration flow from the poorer acced-

ing countries never materialized. Consider, for example, what happened to migration to

Germany-one of the EU countries with the largest per-capita GDP-after the initial expan-

sion of the EU. The number of Greek nationals living in Germany grew from 356,000 to

363,000 between 1994 and 1996; the number of Spanish nationals remained at about 132,000;and the number of Portuguese nationals grew from 117.5 thousand to 130.8 thousand.3 3

Moreover, the number of foreign-born nationals from the acceding countries was roughlystable in the other EU countries. It seems, therefore, that the income differences betweenthe EU and the initial wave of acceding countries, large as they were, were not sufficientlylarge to generate substantial migration flows. In sum, there is little evidence that migration

flows within the (enlarged) European Union have risen rapidly in the past decade, despitethe elimination of national borders across countries that offer different economic and socialopportunities. 3 4

Finally, and perhaps most important, the process of accession into the EU will itself helpto self-regulate the migration flows originating in the first wave of acceding CEE countries.

Membership in the EU implies not only the free movement of persons, but also the freemovement of capital, goods, and services. As I stressed earlier, these additional economiclinks among member states can significantly speed up the convergence process, that is, the

equalization of economic opportunities across member states. In an important sense, there-fore, accession into the EU implies that persons need not move to take advantage of better

economic opportunities elsewhere. The movement of capital and goods can perform thisjobjust as well. The convergence process, therefore, will further reduce the income differentialsthat help drive the migration process, and further lower the chances that accession to the EU

will generate sizable migration flows in the long run.Although the implications of the existing research for potential migration flows from the

acceding country to the EU are clear, there are a number of issues that must be taken intoaccount and that may qualify the nature of these conclusions.

For example, the discussion has not taken into account the possibility that the acceding

countries might serve as "transit stops" for persons who now reside in countries further east

to gain a foothold that they can use to enter the European Union. Two distinct issues fuel thisparticular concern. First, there are relatively large populations of "ethnic Hungarians" nowresiding outside Hungary (particularly in Romania), and of "ethnic Poles" now residing out-

side Poland (particularly in the Ukraine). If the ethnic background of these persons entitles

them to certain citizenship or residence rights in the acceding countries, ethnic Hungarians

or ethnic Poles could potentially use these rights to establish residence in Hungary or Po-

20

Page 31: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

land, and then migrate to other members states of the European Union, countries that offer

far better economic opportunities than the places where they now live.

Although a complete evaluation of the potential for such types of ethnic flows to occur

requires a detailed discussion of the history of these types of population flows and an analysis

of the cultural and social links that connect the ethnic populations in Romania and the

Ukraine with the populations of Hungary and Poland, respectively, it is relatively easy to

evaluate the case of the ethnic Hungarians. There are probably 3 million ethnic Hungarians

(persons who have a Hungarian mother tongue) living in countries surrounding Hungary,with about 2 million of these ethnic Hungarians living in Romania. It is worth noting that the

bulk of these ethnic Hungarians could have chosen to move to Hungary after the collapse of

the East Bloc and the destabilizing period that followed the fall of Ceaucescu. But the largebulk of the ethnic Hungarians chose not to move at that time. Part of this reluctance to

migrate can be attributed to the fact that they ethnic Hungarians living in Romania are, in

fact, living in the areas where they were bom and grew up, and have little "connection" with

the physical territories that make up modern Hungary. In other words, they are ethnic Hun-

garians not because they were born in modern-day Hungary, but because of the way that

maps were drawn in Central Europe. It also seems to be the case that incomes are narrowing

between Hungarians in Hungary and ethnic Hungarians in Romania. It seems to be the case,therefore, that there are important factors at work that deter the migration of ethnic Hun-

garians into Hungary, and presumably into the European Union. Moreover, the EU candevelop policies designed to minimize the potential of this problem. For example, the nego-

tiations might wish to formalize the idea that the "freedom of movement" extends only the

Hungarian and Polish nationals living only in Hungary or Poland, and do not extend topersons who do not have such citizenship, regardless of their ethnic background.

There also exists the possibility that the Central and Eastern European countries in thefirst wave of accession might be used by persons from "third" countries, either further East or

in Asia, as transit points. There are a number of factors to suggest that one should be con-cerned about this possibility. For instance, there seems to be an increasing tendency to trafficin the smuggling of illegal aliens in the region. The available evidence is much too sparse toallow a serious investigation of whether there would be an increase in the unauthorized entryof third-country nationals into the European Union through this mechanism. After all, bytheir very nature, these illegal flows are hard to detect and to analyze statistically. Neverthe-

less, a number of policy options, noted below, may be available to the European Union and

to the acceding countries to restrict this type of migration flow, such as requiring much morecareful enforcement of external borders.

Finally, any analysis of the link between accession and migration must take into account

the special situation of the Gypsy population in Hungary. About 4 percent of the Hungarian

population is of Gypsy origin, roughly 400,000 persons.3 5 Although the stereotypical percep-tion is that Gypsies are quite mobile within a particular geographic data, there is little data orempirical analysis documenting and investigating the existing migration patterns of this popu-

lation. By law, the Hungarian government does not collect any data on ethnic backgroundthat can be used to identify the number, let alone the location or migration behavior, of theGypsy population.

Despite our lack of information about this population, one should recognize that the

accession of Hungary into the European Union creates a "window of opportunity" for the

21

Page 32: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Gypsy population to expand its migratory behavior over a wider territory. The dearth of

research on the socioeconomic characteristics of the Gypsy population, and on the cultural

and social networks that link the Gypsies with other groups, suggest that any predictions of

the migration patterns of Gypsies in the post-accession period will likely contain a great deal

of error. It is clear, however, that the Gypsy population raises a number of potentially impor-

tant questions that should be documented and researched closely as the accession process

continues.

In fact, the data problems that hamper research on migration in the context of the Euro-

pean Union extend far beyond the Gypsy population. In comparison to the United States,

there has been relatively little effort either in terms of data collection or in terms of ongoing

research activity, to document and analyze the migration flows that occur within the Euro-

pean Community. The migration data are often not comparable across countries, and some

of the key data, such as data cn the skill composition of the migrant flows, simply does not

exist. Moreover, many of the research questions that have driven the immigration literature

in the United States have yet to be analyzed seriously in the context of the European Union.

Part of this data problem arises because most of the member states have not had as long a

history of receiving immigrants-and analyzing the impact of immigration-as Canada andthe United States. In fact, one key policy recommendation is to initiate a more systematic

effort to collect (standardized) migration data in the context of the European Union and to

develop a research program that provides an ongoing analysis of the impact of these flows onboth sending and receiving countries. This research effort would greatly advance our under-

standing of the role that migration plays in the economic life of the European Union.

Additional ImplicationsThe Schengen Agreement effectively permits member states in the European Union to de-sign their own type of "guest worker" programs by engaging in bilateral contracts with othercountries. In theory, these temporary immigrants can travel freely within the EU, but their

work permit is only valid in the country that negotiated their entry.In an important sense, the temporary employment arrangements allowed by the Schengen

Agreement are not completely consistent with the spirit of economic cooperation that lies at

the heart of the European Union. A defacto (and unregulated) temporary worker program,

after all, gives the member country that chooses to import large numbers of temporary mi-

grants from other countries a certain type of economic advantage in the market place. After

all, the guarantees made by the social welfare system of the member states do not typicallyextend to the temporary immigrants, so that it is cheaper to use these migrants to produce

some goods and services.The accession into the EU of the countries that are now the source of many of these

temporary workers (such as Poland) raises an important question. Since the economic links

between the acceding countries and the EU will help to equalize opportunities across the

member states, will the countries that want to continue to import (cheaper) temporary work-

ers have to recruit in countries that lie further east (or perhaps in other continents)? A

second long-run problem is that temporary migration flows-such as the flows of guest work-

ers into Germany and other European countries in earlier decades-are seldom temporaryRegardless of the many precautions taken by the receiving countries, many temporary work-

22

Page 33: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

ers often become permanent workers. Since the Schengen Agreement lets each member

country develop its own temporary worker policy, it is reasonable to suspect that particular

types of temporary worker policies can have a substantial impact on migration flows within

the European Union in the future.

There is yet another way in which different migration policies pursued by different mem-

ber states can have a substantial impact on long-run migration flows within the European

Union. Each member state, after all, is free to choose the level of resource it wishes to devote

to controlling their external borders and to the detection of illegal workers in the labor

market. By deciding on the level of enforcement that will be used to address the problem,

the member states can effectively choose an "optimal" number of illegal immigrants. In ef-

fect, these de facto immigration policies give the member states an additional "degree of

freedom" for competing in the market place.

5. ConclusionThere has been a growing research interest on the economics of immigration in the past two

decades. This renewed interest can be traced back to the resurgence of large immigrant

flows in many parts of the world, particularly the United States. The growing research litera-

ture has greatly increased our understanding of the factors that induce persons to migrate

across countries, and of the impact that this population flow has on economic conditions inthe receiving countries.

This paper summarized some of the key research findings, and applied the lessons from

this research to the potential migration problem faced by countries in the European Union.As the EU expands, there is some concern that wage differences among the current memberstates and the new entrants, such as Hungary and Poland, may motivate many workers tomigrate into the European Union. These concerns are sufficiently serious that they may playan important role in the negotiations between the European Commission and some of theCentral and Eastern European countries applying for accession. Overall, the research evi-

dence suggests that the size and direction of migration flows are strongly determined byinternational differences in economic opportunities, and that the migration flows from the

acceding countries to the current member states of the European Union will likely be rela-

tively small.It is worth concluding by re-emphasizing that the European Union links the member

states not only through population flows, but also through flows of capital, goods, and ser-

vices. These additional flows accelerate the trend towards equalization of economic opportu-

nities among the member countries. In effect, these additional flows help remove one of the

key reasons that motivate persons to migrate in the first place. In the presence of these flows,therefore, it seems that the concern over the potential of large migration flows has been

overly exaggerated.

23

Page 34: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Notes

1. OECD (1997), p. 29.2. A detailed technical discussion of the migration decision is given in Borjas (1994).3. This behavioral assumption does not imply that all persons would choose to move to the same

country. Because different persons might value the cultural and political characteristics offered by aparticular country differently and because different labor market conditions will probably reward dif-ferent types of workers differently, the "optimal" migration sorting implies that different types of peoplewill move to different types of countries.

4. Massey and Espania (1987).5. U.S. Immigration and Naturalization Service (1997), p. 197.6. WAorld Bank (1998). The (purchasing-power-parity adjusted) per-capita GDP of the United States

in 1996 was $28,023, while that of Mexico was $7,983.7. Borjas (1987) provides a technical discussion of the type of selection generated by income-maxi-

mizing behavior on the part of potential migrants.8. Psacharopoulos (1973) estimates the rate of return to education for many countries.9. Borjas, Freeman, and Katz (1997) give a more detailed discussion of the link between immigra-

tion and trade.10. To calculate the rate of emigration to the United States, the denominator has to include the

entire population of persons born in a particular source country, including those that have migratedelsewhere. These types of data are difficult to obtain.

11. The regression equation is estimated in a sample that contains 75 source countries, and is weightedby the size of the immigrant flow from each country. The standard error of the per-capita GDP variableis .06; the standard error of the distance variable is .09; and the R-squared of the regression is .48. SeeBorjas (1987) andJasso and Rosenzweig (1987) for more detailed analyses of these types of statisticalmodels. The more detailed studies expand the regression equation to incorporate many other factors,including measures of English language proficiency in the source country's population and indices oftrade between the source country and the United States. The key results stressed here are not affectedby the use of a more general regression specification.

12. U.S. Department of Commerce (1997, p. 813).13. More recent studies include Borjas, Bronars, and Trejo (1992) and Dahl (1997).14. U.S. Department of Commerce (1997, p. 32).15. U.S. Department of Commerce (1997, p. 32).16. Borjas, Bronars, and Trejo (1992) provide evidence that there is also some self-selection going

on, in the sense that the most skilled workers tend to migrate to states that offer the relatively highestrewards to skills.

17. Barrett (1993) shows that immigrants who enter the United States using a family reunificationvisa have relatively lower earnings when they originate in countries where the income distribution hasa large variance.

18. These data are drawn from Borjas (1995).19. Many of these studies also find a significant negative correlation between immigration and the

immigrant wage. For instance, Grossman (1982) reports that a 10 percent increase in the number ofimmigrants reduces the immigrant wage by 2 percent, while Altonji and Card (1991) conclude that a10 percent increase in the number of immigrants reduces the immigrant wage by at least 4 percent.

20. Carrington and de Lima (1994) report inconclusive results wvhen they analyze the impact of the600,000 refugees who entered Portugal after the country lost the African colonies of Mozambique andAngola in the mid-1970s, increasing Portugal's population by almost 7 percent.

21. Note also that immigrant flows are unlikely to be exogenous because immigrants probably chooseto enter the localities where they have the best opportunities.

22. In other words, the spatial correlations typically estimated in the literature have no structuralinterpretation; they do not estimate the demand function for native workers, nor do they estimate thereduced-form impact of immigrants on native employment opportunities. Some studies use the indus-try, rather than the local labor market, as the unit of observation and analyze native employment andwages as immigrants penetrate a particular industry (DeNew and Zimmermann, 1994; WAaldinger, 1993).The correlations are sometimes interpreted in terms of a displacement effect. As with studies of locallabor markets, these correlations have no structural interpretation as long as workers and firms canmove across industries.

24

Page 35: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

23. Studies of labor demand suggest that the wage ratio of unskilled to skilled workers falls by 32.2percent when the ratio of unskilled to skilled workers increases by one unit (from, say, one unskilledworker per skilled worker to two unskilled workers per skilled worker). To obtain the impact of immi-gration on the relative wage, one multiplies this "relative wage elasticity" of -.322 by the change in factorproportions, which is approximately 15 percentage points. See Borjas, Freeman, Katz (1997), pp. 58-50, for additional details.

24. The relative wage of high school dropouts fell by 11 percentage points during the period.25. See Borjas, Freeman, and Katz (1997), pp. 25-38, for more details.26. The decline in the 1990s is mainly attributable to the deep recession that hit California around

1990.27. Card (1990), p. 255.28. OECD (1997), p. 106.29. World Bank (1998).30. Hars (1997, p. 18).31. Because the starting point in Eastern European countries was a very compressed earnings struc-

ture, there has been a gradual (relative) increase in the returns to skills and a widening of incomeinequality in these countries in the 1990s. It is likely that over time the returns to skills and incomeinequality in the CEE will more closely resemble what currently exists in Western European countries.

32. World Bank (1998).33. Fr6hlich (1997), p. 6.34. The historical experience of the United States also suggests that relatively large migration flows

can occur when there are important political shocks in sending countries. The immigration of 572,000Cuban refugees and 644,000 Vietnamese refugees in recent decades, for instance, can be traced di-rectly to the political upheavals in these countries. Barring such cataclysmic political shocks, therefore,there is little reason to suspect that huge numbers of refugees will originate in the acceding countriesand move into the European Union.

35. U.S. Central Intelligence Agency (1997).

References

Altonji,Joseph G. and David Card. 1991. "The Effects of Immigration on the Labor Market

Outcomes of Less-Skilled Natives." In Abowd, John M. and Richard B. Freeman, eds.,

Immigration, Trade, and the Labor Market. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Barrett, Alan M. 1993. "Three Essays on the Labor Market Characteristics of Immigrants."

Ph.D. Dissertation, Michigan State University.

Bean, Frank D., B. Lindsay Lowell, and Lowell J. Taylor. 1988. "Undocumented Mexican

Immigrants and the Earnings of Other Workers in the United States." Demography 25(1),

35-52.

Borjas, George J. 1987. "Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immigrants." American Economic

Review 77(4): 531-553.

.1990. Friends orStrangers: TheImpact of Immigrants on the U.S. Economy. NewYork: Basic

Books.

. 1994. "The Economics of Immigration." Journal of Economic Literature 32(4): 1667-

1717.

. 1995. "Assimilation and Changes in Cohort Quality Revisited: What Happened to

Immigrant Earnings in the 1980s?"Journal of LaborEconomics 13(2): 201-245.

Borjas, GeorgeJ., Stephen G. Bronars, and StephenJ. Trejo. 1992. "Self-Selection and Inter-

nal Migration in the United States."Journal of Urban Economics September pp. 159-185.

Borjas, GeorgeJ., Richard B. Freeman, and Lawrence F. Katz. 1997. "How Much do Immigra-

tion and Trade Affect Labor Market Outcomes." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 1-67.

25

Page 36: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Card, David. 1990. "The Impact of the Mariel Boatlift on the Miami Labor Market." Industrial

and Labor Relations Review 43 (2): 245-257.

. 1997. "Immigrant Inflows, Native Outflows, and the Local Labor Market Impacts of

Higher Immigration." NBER Working Paper 5927.

Carrington, WilliamJ. and Pedro de Lima. 1994. "Large-Scale Immigration and Labor Mar-

kets: An Analysis of the Retornados and Their Impact on Portugal."Johns Hopkins Univer-sity.

Cobb-Clark, Deborah A. 1983. "Immigrant Selectivity and Wages: The Evidence for Women."

American Economic Review 83(4): 986-993.

Dahl, Gordon B. 1997. "Mobility and the Returns to Education: Testing a Roy Model with

Multiple Markets." Unpublished paper. Princeton University.

DeNew, John P. and Klaus F Zimmermann. 1994. "Native Wage Impacts of Foreign Labor: ARandom Effects Panel Analysis." Journal of Population Economics. Forthcoming.

Filer, Randall K 1992. "The Impact of Immigrant Arrivals on Migratory Patterns of NativeWorkers." In Borjas, George J. and Richard B. Freeman, eds., Immigration and the Work

Force: Economic Consequencesfor the United States and Source Areas. Chicago: University of Chi-

cago Press.

Fitzpatrick, Gary L. and Marilyn J. Madlin. 1986. Direct Line Distances, US. Edition. London:

The Scarecrow Press.Frey, William. 1995. "Immigration and Internal Migration 'Flight' from US Metropolitan

Areas: Toward a New Demographic Balkanization." Urban Studies 32 (4-5): 733-757.Fr6hlich, Barbara. 1997. "SOPEMI Report for Germany." Preliminary draft.

Greenwood, MichaelJ. andJohn M. McDowell. 1986. "The Factor Market Consequences ofU.S. Immigration."Journal of Economic Literature 24(4): 1738-1772.

Grossman, Jean Baldwin. 1982. "The Substitutability of Natives and Immigrants in Produc-tion." Reviewv of Economics and Statistics 54(4): 596-603.

Hars, Agnes, 1997 "Migration." Processed.

Hunt,Jennifer. 1992. "The Impact of the 1962 Repatriates from Algeria on the French LaborMarket." Industrial and Labor Relations Review 45 (3): 556-572.

Jasso, Guillermina and Mark R. Rosenzweig. 1986. "What's in a Name? Country-of-Origin

Influences on the Earnings of Immigrants in the United States." Research in Human Capital

and Development 4: 75-106.LaLonde, RobertJ. and Robert H Topel. 1991. "Labor Market Adjustments to Increased

Immigration." In Abowd,John M. and Richard B. Freeman, eds., Immigration, Trade, and

the Labor Market. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Martin, Phillip. 1998. Migration News (January). University of California, Davis.

Massey, Douglas and Garcia Espafia Felipe. 1987. "The Social Process of International Migra-tion." Science 237: 733-738.

Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. 1997. Trends in International Mi-

gration, Annual Report 1996. OECD.Pischke,J6rn-Steffen andJohannes Velling. 1994. "Wage and Employment Effects of Immi-

gration to Germany: An Analysis Based on Local Labor Markets." Massachusetts Institute

of Technology, January.Psacharopoulos, George. 1973. Returns to Education: An International Comparison. San Fran-

cisco, CA:Jossey-Bass.

26

Page 37: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Ramos, Fernando. 1992. "Out-Migration and Return Migration of Puerto Ricans." In Borjas,

George J. and Richard B. Freeman, eds., Immigration and the Work Force: Economic Conse-

quencesfor the United States and Source Areas. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Summers, Robert and Alan Heston. "The Penn-World Tables (Mark 5): An Expanded Set of

International Comparisons, 1950-1988." QuarterlyJournal of Economics.

Taylor,J. Edward. 1987. "Undocumented Mexico-U.S. Migration and the Returns to House-

holds in Rural Mexico." AmericanJournal of Agricultural Economics 69(3): 626-638.

U.S. Central Intelligence Agency. 1997. CIA World Factbook.

U.S. Immigration and Naturalization Service. 1993. Statistical Yearbook of the Immigration and

Naturalization Service, 1992. Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office.

Waldinger, Roger. 1993. "Who Gets the 'LousyJobs'? New Immigrants and African-Ameri-

cans in NewYork, 1940-1990." University of California, Los Angeles, October.

World Bank. 1998. World Development Indicators on CD-ROM, 1998. Washington, D.C.: The

World Bank.

27

Page 38: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government
Page 39: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Distributors of World Bank Group Publications

Prices and credit terms vay from CZECH REPUBLIC INDIA Euyoos Publishing CO., Ltd. PERU SWEDENcountry tn country. Csssult year USIS, NIS Prodejna Allied Publishers Ltd. 46-1, Sussng-Dssg Edatorial Desarrollo SA Wennergren-Wdliams ASlocal distributor betore placing an Havelkova 22 751 Mount Road Jongro-Gu Apartado 3824, Ica 242 OF. 105 P. 0. BoX 1305order. 130 00 Prague 3 Madras - 600 002 Seoul Ua 1 S-171 25 Solna

Tel: (420 2124231486 Tel: (9144) 852-3938 Tel: (822) 734-3515 Tel: (51 14) 285380 Tel: (46 8 705-97-50ARGENTINA Fax: (420 2 24231114 Fax: (9144)852-0649 Fax: (8272) 32-9154 Fax: (51 14) 286628 Fax: (468) 27-00-71World Publications SA URL: ittp:/twww.nis.cM INDONESIA LEBANON PHIUPPINES E-mail: mailwwi.se1s20 Ciudad de Duenas Aires DENMARK Pt. Indira Limited Librairie du Liban International Booksource Center Inc. SWITZERLANDTe11 C54d11 Saua-8156 SamfundsLitteratur Jalan Borobudur20 PO. Box 11-9232 1127-A Antipolo St, Barangay, Librairie Payot Service InstitutonnelFaT: (54 11(4815-8156 Rosenoems A6tt 1 PRD. Box 181 Beirut Venezuela CIlm)tes-de-Mustbesaa 30

mail: W books@inovia com ar DK-l970 Frededksberg C Jakarta 10320 Tel: (961 9) 217 944 Makati City 1002 LausanneE-mail: mpbsnksSntsvia.csm.sr Tel: (45 351351942 Tel: (62 21 390-4290 Fax: (961 9) 217 434 Tel: (63 2) 896 6508; 6505: 6507 Tel: (41 21) 341-3229AUSTRALIA, FUI, PAPUA NEW Fa: (45 35) 357822 Fax: (62 213,0-4289 E-mail: hsayegh2librairie-du- Fax: (63 2) 896 1741 Fax: (41 21) 341-3235GUINEA, SOLOMON ISLANDS, UJRL tttp/Amwwat.cbs.dk IA 39(libancom.ibVANUATU, AND SAMOA URL: http:/Ivw-ww.ib.rairie-du- POLAND ADEC Van DiermenD.A. Intormation Services ECUAiOR Ketab Sara CO. Publishers L.banc.com .b International Publishing Service EditionsTechniques648 Whitehorse Road Libr Mundi Khabed Eslamboli Ave., 6th Street Ul. Piekna 31/37 Ch. de Lacuez 41

eham 3132 VIcta Libreia lnternacional Delatrooz Alley No.8 MALAYSIA 00-677 Warzawa CH1807 BlonayTelc (613 9210 7777 P.O. Box 17-01-3029 P.O. Box 15745-733 University ot Malaya Cooperative Tel: (48 2) 628-6089 Tel: (41 21) 943 2673FaxT: (61 3 9210 7788 Juan Leon Mera 851 Tehran 15117 Bookshop, Limited Fax: (48 2) 621-7255 Fax: (4121) 9433605

E-madQSeN @dadrectcomau ttuito Tel: (9821) 8717819; 8716104 P.O. Box 1127 E-mail: books%[email protected] THAURmL:. srieddrccoa Tel: 193 2) 521-606; (593 2) 544- Fx 92' 8712479 Jatan Pantai Bare URL: CeTrAILASNosDisbto18s E-mail: ketab-saaraneda.net.ir 59700 Kuala Lumpar http://www.ipscg.wawplfips/export 306 Silom RoadAUSTRIA Faa: (593 2) 504-209 Kowkab Peblishers Tel: (60 31 756-5g0g PORTUGAL Bangkok 10500Gerold and Co. E-mail: [email protected] F'DaBxe 19575-S11 Fa: (60 3) 755-4424 PortuGAL Tel: (00 0WeiAbbr99asse 26 E-mail: librimu2@1i brimundi.COmeC Tehran E-mail: [email protected] Apartado 26B , Rua Do Carm Fax: (66 2) 237-8321Ae: 4 101 512 Wren CODOEU Tel; (9 21? 258-3723 MEXICO a 70-74TRNDD&OBGlen ~~~~~~~Ruiz de Castilla 763, Edif. Expocolor Fax: (98 21)) 258-3723 IMNEFXOTECE 270-74bo TRlINIDAD & TOttAGOPay: (43 1) 512-47-31-29 RureCsi49738dt2Epclr28-73IFTC 20Lce ANID THE CARIRIBBEANURL: http:lwww gero1doo/at.or1ine DuPrimer piso, 0f. t2 IRELAND AV. San Fernando No. 37 Tel: (11 347-4982URL hllp:/Iwww.gerold.cn/at.osline Quito Col. Torielle Guerra Fax: (3 Systematica Studies Ltd.BANGLADESH Tel/Fa:X (593 2) 507-383; 253-091 Govemment Supplies Agency 140 Muscs,D4St. Augustine Shopping CenterMicro Ieduetries Developpment E-mail: [email protected] DUfg an tSogathair Tel:052 624-2800 D.Easters Main Road, St. AugustineAssistance Society 4fIDAS4-5 Harcourt Rd Tel: (52 Ra 5-82 RUtAN8 Trinidad & Tobago, West nadiesEGYFIT, ARAB REPUBLIC OF Dublin 2Fax: (52 )624 Tel:28681O65-846Hause 5, Road 16 (MDS GP,AA EULCO uln2E-mail: [email protected] Compani De Libruri Btucuresc S.A. Faa: (800) 645-8467Dhanmondi RArea At Ahram Distribution Agency Tel: (353 1(61-3111 Fax (8- 6458467Dhaka 1209 Al Galaa Street Fa: (3531 ( 475-2670 URL: httpM/rtn.net.mxStr. Lipscani no. 26, secter 3 E-mail: tobe ittinidad.netTel: (.002 326427 Cairo E ul:royi Mexico S.A. de H GUh2PGFax: http://w8 w.uol r FRANCEl P5 3 YOzt Lit9 eraturemLtd. c/Pin Panuco, 141-CAlsEna Tel: (40 12 313 9645 UGANDAFAWA:D(88 Faa:ions (2) 5 3 Tmel: L r Ld 6 2Cuauhemoc Faa: a s0 The000 Gustro Ltd.BELGIM R. 3 4 P Bee 56055 FEDE0 RRL ATION PD Bee 9997, Madhvani BuildingJELanoL The Middle East Observer 3 Yohanan tHaandlar Street 0 c, D.Y. RUSSIAN FEDER Plot14inja Rd.Jea de roLa0no 41, Sherif SteeS Tel Aviv 6156 4 Tel (52 5E533Z5658 IadataleJstvo <s Mur>1

Av uRoitplwl.rnubosco 3tBn 2023B564-5 Newax rket)51-69 9-a,Kolpansk@vets Teci-CenaLa bo .

1060 Brusels Cairo Tel:(972 3) 5285-397 Faa: (5 (16999,Kahniy Pereulok Kapla2Tel: (32i2) 536-516 Tel: (20D2 393H9732 Fa: (972 (s 5285-37 NEPAL Mscow 101031 Tel: '256o41' ZAM

Td: (6610) 6401-7365 Epp Books BexROY Tel n Everest Media Intesatiosal Services Tel: (7 095 917 87 49 Faa: (256 41iv251f468Fax: (32 2) 538-0841 P.O.Box44 Fax:576-9774243YntemarnaR) Ltd. Faee ( (o9179259 E-mail: gusia switugandacomBRAZIL FINLAND PD Bus 13056 G 0 Box 5443 ozi [email protected] UNITED KINGDOMPublicac6os Tecnicas Internacisnla Akateeminen Kir)akauppa Tel Aviv 61130 Kahad IGPR;TIA,CIA Microints Ltd.Ltda.ORO. Boe 128 Tel: (972 3) 6499460 TElaman 97du 12 416 02O6EMYA,RUND PDO. Son 3, Dmega Park, Allan,Ltda. ~~~~~FIN-00101 Helsinki Faa: (972 3) 6863 e-(7 1 2 YMA;BUERea Poixota Gomide, 209 Tel: (358 01121 41E-al rui 3 H 03 9 Baku : (977 1) 224 431 Hemisphere Publication Services Hampshire GU34 2PG

01409 Sae Paula, 1. (3SR t 3 4135 E @ai tvision.netli 41 Ka P R C04-03 EnglandTel: (55 11 259-66044 Fax: (358 0121-45 URL: http:/twww.royint.co.iI NE4EL Goldng Wheel Buiding Road040 Tel: (44142086848

Fax: (55 IAT eb EFax:l aklus234mnnf NEHELAD 4;-2056 Wheel iss is.c.ziHaar

Fa:(5 (258-6990 E-al k([email protected] Palestinian Authority/Meiddle East De Lindebnom/lnternafonnale Singapore 349316 Faa: (414089889E-mail: postmastor@i- ul.tbr U,RL: httpoiswmwakateeminon.cum Indea Intormatin Services Publicatiee bN.- Tel: (65) 741-5166 E-mail: wbankFmicrointo.co.ukURL: http://wwwuol.hr PRANCE P.0.B. 19502 Jerusalem RD. Bay 202, 7480 AE Haaksbergen Faa: (65 742-9356 URL: ht4tp:/Awwwrmicrsinto.co.ukCANADA Editions Eska; OB A Tel: (972 2) 6271219 Tel: (31 53) 574-0004 E-mail: [email protected] The Stationery OfficeReouf Publishing Cs. Ltd. 40, rue Guy Lussac Faa: (972 2) 6271634 Faa: (31 5) 572-929 51 Nine Elms Lane5369 Canoeo REad 7ITALY, LIBERIA E-mail: lindebooworldonline.nt Department egacy Oxtord Londen SWB SDROttawa, Ontario K2 0i Tel:(3311 55-42-730Ln URL: h3p:/2ww.woddonIe.nI1-cin- G i v i PTel: (44 171' 873-0400Ottasaa OntarioMK1Jaxgt3gt 43-29-91-67 Licos a Bon-D oni La GroupTel: (613) 745-2665 Fa:(3Via Duca Di Calabria, 1/ deboo Ouna(oska costa 5 Faa: (44 171 i873-8242Fax: (81 745-7668 GERMANY Casella Pt 550 NEW ZEALAND 1000 Ljubljana URLe http:cA.c ww.the-sLH@solaryeE-mail: UNO-Verlag 50125 Pirenze Tel: hu 61 133 ) [email protected] Poppeladorter AlleoSS5 Tel: (3955(645-415 EBSOD NZ Ltd. Tel: (38661,1338347VE132123URL: http://wwwrrenoufbooks.com 53115 Boon Faa: (3955641-257 Private Mail Bag 99914 EFaal: (386 se 61(1338030cniieci VENEZUELA.A

CHINA Tel: (49228(~~~~~~~949020 E-mal [email protected] Centre Cuidad Comercial TamancoCHINA Fnnil&Euac .Faa: (49 228) 217492 URL: htlp:/twww.Otbcc.it/ticosa Auckland SOUTH AFRICA, ROTS WANANieC2CaaaChina Financial & Economic ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~Tel: (64 9) 524-8118 Fu sngle titles:NveC2Cacs

Publishing House URmal uno/Ivoeragno-rla.dom JAMAICA PFa: (64 9) 524-8007 Dxtord University Press Southern Tel: (58 2) 959 5546 535:018, Da Pa Si Dong Jie E-al svraralcm Ian Randle Publishers Ltd. AfricaFa:(8)9953Beijing GHANA 208 DId Hoe Road, Kingsoto 6 Oasis Ottic'ial Vasco Boulevard, GoDdwood ZAMBIATel: (86 1016401-7365 Epp Books Services Tel: 876-927-2085 RDO. Box 3627 RDO. Box 12119, NI City 7463 University BooksIop, University atPee (0610) 6401-7365 RD. Box 44 Pus: 876-977-0243 Wellington Cape Town ZambiaChina Boak Impart Contre TCE-mail: irpl@colioscsm Tel: (64 4) 499 1 551 Tle: (27 21) 595 4400 Great East Road CampusRD. Boa 2025 Pcr AA axrc (64 4) 499 t972 Faa: (2721) 595 4430 P.O. Bee 32379

Beijing Tel: 223 21 778843 ~~~~Eastem Book Service E-mail: [email protected] E-mail: [email protected] LusakaBei(ing ~~~~~~~~~Fax: 223 21 779099 1R'ht:/wwossok.o.z e:(6 252 576Chinese Corporation lor Promotion ~3-13 Hong 3-hmeBunkyo-ku U:htp/w .aisekc.n/ Far subscription orders: Tel: (2600 235ot HumanitiesGEC Tv1aC'm''52, You Fang Ho Tong, PaaoinI A.Tl (91 3(318081NIGERIA Iotersationul Subscription Service Fa:(6 (2592

Xaan Nei On Jie ~~~~~~~35, Stournara Str. Pea: (1 3818-06 University Press Limited R.Bo405ZMAWXuan Nei Da Jie 8 381~~~~~~~~~ 8O64Three Crowns Buildini Jericho Craighall Academic and Baobab Beaks (Pvt.)Beijin 162AhaE-alode@vtescJp Private Mail Bag 5095 Johannesburg 2024 Ltd.Tel: (86 101 660 72 494 Tel: (3011364-1826 URL: Ibadan Tel: (27 111880-1448 4 Cenald Read, GranitesideFaa: (86 id) 660 72 494 Fax.: (3011))304-8354 http:/,vww.bekkoame.or.jp/-svt- Tel: (234 22) 41-1358 ax (71 ~ M28P.O. Bee 567COLOMBIA1 HAITI ohs Fax: (234 22) 41 -2056 EFaal: iss7s4coza-Hararloloenlace Ltda. Culture Diffuoioa KENYA SPAIN Tel: 263 4755035Carretu 6 No. 51-21 5, Rue Caposi Atrica Book Service (E.A.) Ltd. PAKISTAN Mundi-Prensa Libros, S.A. Faa: 262 4781913Apartadu Aoreu 34270 CRP 257 Ouarao Hoace, Mlangano Street Mirza Beak Agency Castello 37Sanetatti do Buoult, D.C. Port-au-Ptoce RDO. Bos 45245 65, Shahrah-e-Duaid-e-Azam 28001 Madrid

Te:(712529 Tel: (509) 23 9260 Nairobi Lahore 94000Te:349)4670Tel: (57 1) 28 -2798~~~) 42Pus: (57 1) 285-2700 Faa: (509) 23 4858 Tel:'254 2' 223 641 Tel: (92 4)735 3601Fa:349)5798

COTE D'IVUIRE ~HONG KONG, CHINA; MACAD Faa: (254 2) 330 272 Faa: (92 42) 576 3714 E-mail: [email protected] DIVOIRE . ~~~~~Asia 2000 Ltd. Legacy Books OxodUiest rs uRn: tPrerwsamuBdrpelonaacmCeoter d'Editino et do Ditfusron SalsL&CIrulaionOopesowwmoianHuseprerdnnivrsiyoFee

A0ricaPo (CE4 A 302 Soabird House Mezanoine 1 Sharae Faisal089Bacln04bidRa 941 22-28 Wy'ndham Street, Ceotral RDO. Boo 68077 50B8gao9eTowaroo eldoCnt,39Ael:d(a252 6510 2 651 aHo Kag Chioa Nairobi PD Bone 13033 Tel: (343) 488-3492Tox: (225) 24510;5467 Tel (82) 530-1 409 Tel: (294(2-330853, 221426 Karachi-75350Fa:(438765

Faa: (22s( 25 0567 ~~~~~Faa: (052( 2526-1107 Pus: (254( 2-330854, 561654 TeE-ail b9c2m21@mndi463a07CYPtrU E-maiie esach Ul: heapewwwasia200.c0M.hk Emi:Lgctt-e,o E-mail: [email protected] SRI LANKA, THE MALDIVESCenturiConlpliede Rsac URho wai20cm.k KOREA, REPUBLIC OP Lake House BookshopCymru Diogene retEgm HUNGARY Dayang Books Trading Co. Pak Beak Corporation 100, Sir Chtitampalam Gardiner6,O Diogee trot,E06 m Euro Inot Service Intemational Division Azia Chambers 21, Queenns Read MawathaNicosia Margloszoeti Europa Haz 783-20, Pangba Bon-Dong, Lahore Colombo 2Tel: (357 2i 5940730 H-1 138 B udapest Socho-ku Tel: (92 42) 636 3222: 636 0885 Tel: (94 1(32105Faa: (3571I)66-2051 Tel: (36 1(350 80 24, 350 80 25 Seoul Faa: (92 42( 636 2328 Faa: (94 1(432104Faa: (36 1( 350 90 32 Tel: (82 2) 536-9555 E-mail: [email protected] E-mail: L [email protected]

E-mail: [email protected] Fax: (82 2) 536-0025E-mail: [email protected]

Page 40: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government
Page 41: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government
Page 42: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

I

Page 43: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

Recent World Bank Technical Papers (continued)

No. 405 Onorato, Fox, and Strongman, World Bank Group Assistancefor Minerals Sector Development and Reform inMember Countries

No. 406 Milazzo, Subsidies in World Fisheries: A Reexamination

No. 407 Wiens and Guadagni, Designing Rulesfor Demand-Driven Rural Investment Funds: The Latin AmericanExperience

No. 408 Donovan and Frank, Soil Fertility Management in Sub-Saharani Africa

No. 409 Heggie and Vickers, Commercial Management and Financing of Roads

No. 410 Sayeg, Successfil Conversion to Unleaded Gasoline in Thailanld

No. 411 Calvo, Optionsfor Managing and Financing Rural Transport Infrastrctilre

No. 413 Langford, Forster, and Malcolm, Toward a Financially Sustainable Irrigation System: Lessonsfrom the State ofVictoria, Australia, 1984-1994

No. 414 Salman and Boisson de Chazournes, International Watercourses: Enhancing Cooperation and ManagingConflict, Proceedings of a World Bank Seminar

No. 415 Feitelson and Haddad, Identification of Joint Management Structiresfor Shared Aquifers: A CooperativePalestinian-Israeli Effort

No. 416 Miller and Reidinger, eds., Comprehensive River Basin Development: The Tennessee Valley Authority

No. 417 Rutkowski, Welfare and the Labor Market in Poland: Social Policy during Economic Transition

No. 418 Okidegbe and Associates, Agriculture Sector Programs: Sourcebook

No. 420 Francis and others, Hard Lessons: Primary Schools, Community, and Social Capital in Nigeria

No. 421 Gert Jan Bom, Robert Foster, Ebel Dijkstra, and Marja Tummers, Evaporative Air-Conditioning: Applicationsfor Environmentally Friendly Cooling

No. 422 Peter Quaak, harrie Knoef, and Huber Stassen, Energyfrom Biomass: A Review of Combusion and GasificationTechnologies

No. 423 Energy Sector Unit, Europe and Central Asia Region, World Bank, Non-Payment in the Electricity Sector inEastern Europe and the Former Soviet Unioni

No. 424 Jaffee, ed., Southern African Agribusiness: Gaining through Regional Collaboration

No. 425 Mohan, ed., Bibliography of Publications: Africa Region, 1993-98

No. 426 Rushbrook and Pugh, Solid Waste Landfills in Middle- and Lower-Income Countries: A Technical Guide toPlanning, Design, and Operation

No. 427 Marifio and Kemper, Institutional Frameworks in Successfil Water Markets: Brazil, Spain, and Colorado, USA

No. 428 C. Mark Blackden and Chitra Bhanu, Gender, Growth, and Poverty Reduction: Special Program of Assistancefor Africa, 1998 Status Report on Poverty in Sub-Saharan Africa

No. 429 Gary McMahon, Jos6 Luis Evia, Alberto Pasc6-Font, and Jose Miguel Sanchez, An Environmental Study ofArtisanal, Small, and Medium Mining in Bolivia, Chile, and Peru

No. 430 Maria Dakolias, Court Performance around the World: A Comparative Perspective

No. 431 Severin Kodderitzsch, Reforms in Albanian Agriculture: Assessing a Sector in Transition

No. 432 Luiz Gabriel Azevedo, Musa Asad, and Larry D. Simpson, Management of Water Resources: Bulk WaterPricing in Brazil

No. 433 Malcolm Rowat and Jose Astigarraga, Latin American Inisolvency Systems: A Comparative Assessment

No. 434 Csaba Csaki and John Nash, editors, Regional and International Trade Policy: Lessonsfor the EU Accession inthe Rural Sector-World Bank/FAO Workshop, June 20-23, 1998

No. 435 lain Begg, EU Investment Grants Review

No. 436 Roy Prosterman and Tlme Hanstad, ed., Legal Impediments to Effective Rural Land Relations in EasternEurope and Central Asia: A Comparative Perpective

No. 437 Csaba Csaki, Michel Dabatisse, and Oskar Honisch, Food and Agriculture in the Czech Republic: From a"Velvet" Transition to the Challenges of EU Accession

No. 443 Luc Oecuit, John Elder, Charistian Hurtado, Francois Rantrua, Kamal Siblini, and Maurizia Tovo,DeMIStifying MIS: Guidelinesfor Management Information Systems in Social Funds

No. 444 Robert F. Townsend, Agricultural Incentives in Sub-Saharan Africa: Policy Challenges

No. 445 Ian Hill, Forest Management in Nepal: Economics of Ecology

No. 447 R. Maria Saleth and Ariel Dinar, Evaluating Water Institutions and Water Sector Performance

Page 44: Economic Research on the Determinants of Immigration · 1. Emigration and inmmigration-Economic aspects-Research. 2. European Union. 3. European Union countries-Emigration and immigration-Government

THE WORLD BANK

1818 H Street, N.W

WN'ashington, D.C. 20433 USA

Telephone: 202-477-1234

Facsimile: 202-477-6391

Telex: MCI 64145 WORLDBANK

MCI 248423 WORLDBANK

Internet: wwvv.worldbank.org

E'-mail: [email protected]

I38ISBN 0-8213-4504-4