tax competition - final

36
1 Assignment Attachment Form Provide ALL details requested on this form. Use one form for each assignment. Visit http://elearn.curtin.edu.au/oua/study/assignment.cfm for detailed assignment submission instructions. Post to: Distance and Open Learning Curtin University GPO Box U1987, PERTH WA 6845 Email: [email protected] Fax: (08) 9266 2777 Phone: (08) 9266 2102 In person: 6 Sarich Way, Technology Park, Bentley PART A to be completed by Student (please print clearly) PART B Office Use Only Name Katrina Murphy Received by Open Universities Returned to Student Address 10 Mars Street for Return Wilston QLD 4051 Email [email protected] Phone No. 0404055584 Unit Name Advanced International Taxation Curtin Student No. 16228681 Unit Code MT 660 Date Submitted 30-08-2013 Assignment No. One (1) Tutor’s Name Dale Pinto Assignment Title (where applicable) Tax Competition A two sided coin Students comments to Tutor or Open Learning (if any) Please read the following and sign where indicated [or type your name when submitting electronically]. DECLARATION: I declare the attached assignment is my own work and has not previously been submitted for assessment. This work complies with Curtin University rules concerning plagiarism and copyright. [Refer to http://www.policies.curtin.edu.au/documents/academic_misconduct.doc for plagiarism and copyright information.] I have retained a copy of this assignment for my own records. Signed: Katrina Murphy PART C to be completed by Tutor: Comments to Student Recorded Mark: Tutor:

Upload: katrina-murphy

Post on 22-Jan-2018

258 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

1

A s s i g n m e n t A t t a c h m e n t F o r m

Provide ALL details requested on this form.

Use one form for each assignment.

Visit http://elearn.curtin.edu.au/oua/study/assignment.cfm for detailed assignment submission instructions.

Post to: Distance and Open Learning Curtin University GPO Box U1987, PERTH WA 6845

Email: [email protected]

Fax: (08) 9266 2777 Phone: (08) 9266 2102

In person: 6 Sarich Way, Technology Park, Bentley

PART A – to be completed by Student (please print clearly) PART B – Office Use Only

Name Katrina Murphy Received by

Open Universities Returned to Student

Address 10 Mars Street

for Return Wilston QLD 4051

Email [email protected]

Phone No. 0404055584

Unit Name Advanced International Taxation Curtin Student No. 16228681

Unit Code MT 660 Date Submitted 30-08-2013

Assignment No. One (1) Tutor’s Name Dale Pinto

Assignment Title (where applicable) Tax Competition – A two sided coin

Students comments to Tutor

or Open Learning (if any)

Please read the following and sign where indicated [or type your name when submitting electronically].

DECLARATION: I declare the attached assignment is my own work and has not previously been submitted for assessment. This work complies with Curtin University rules concerning plagiarism and copyright. [Refer to

http://www.policies.curtin.edu.au/documents/academic_misconduct.doc for plagiarism and copyright information.] I have retained a copy of this assignment for my own records.

Signed: Katrina Murphy

PART C – to be completed by Tutor: Comments to Student

Recorded Mark: Tutor:

2

ABSTRACT: TAX COMPETITION – A TWO SIDED COIN

Written by: Katrina Murphy

There is to be sure, an apparent contradiction between, on the one hand, the fact that human activities are

becoming more and more globalized, whereas, on the other hand, tax systems remain strictly national (or

local)…in fact globalization can be defined as competition at a world level.1

Richard Teather’s tenuous statement that ‘Tax competition brings great benefits, to all society

and not just to those who directly take advantage of it,’ is a common belief, albeit, in the current

economic environment, this persuasion provokes great argument. It has been asserted that tax

competition is a key principle of any market economy and has the ability to promote and enhance

good tax policies, by reducing tax rates that can enhance economic performance through

investments, savings and the creation of jobs. ‘It is generally accepted within the international

society that sovereign states will adopt fiscal policies that do not impede or obstruct the

entrepreneurial spirit.’2 Tax competition under this philosophy however, can be seen to be a

vehicle for tax havens and advocates of tax competition do not denounce these practices but

rather see the opportunity for maximizing their own fiscal prospects through tax competition and

harnessing the benefits that it has to offer. Organizations such as the Centre for Freedom and

Prosperity (“CFP”) in America were set up to demobilize the anti-tax competition sentiment that

the Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (“OECD”) had embarked upon

by suggesting the OECD was a “bully” enforcing its right to restrict domestic tax laws and

eliminate financial privacy. The OECD has been classified as being domineering and powerful

against countries desperate to keep a “competitive” edge in an already very competitive world.

1P Salin, The Case Against “Tax Harmonization”: The OECD EU Initiatives (2007).

2T Butler, “David vs. Goliath : An Analysis of the OECD Harmful Tax Competition Policy” (2001) .

3

Divergent to the above rational, it is also argued that tax competition is harmful. Due to the

rapid emergence of electronic commerce and hyper-mobile capital markets accelerated by

globalization, organizations such as the United Nations (“UN”), the European Commission

(“EC”), and the OECD have prompted many discussions on transparency and the requirement for

greater boundaries to be set with regard to tax information exchange with a cross boarder focus.

In 1988, the OECD was enlisted to launch a report on harmful tax competition which was to

“develop measures to counter the distorting effects of harmful tax competition on investment and

financing decisions and the consequences for national tax bases.”3 The report embarked on

identifying preferential tax regimes and havens and thus pressurizing these nations to dismantle

their low tax regimes to restrict the revenue and capital flows to these countries from the high tax

nations, or consequently, face severe financial restrictions. This initiative by the OECD is also

upheld by high tax nations whom are strident in their condemnation of tax competition, as losing

tax revenue and wealth is a major current concern. The OECD’s initiative on information

exchange also became trendy after such events as 9/11, and the financial collapse of Enron.

These events, amongst others, rekindled the already smoldering sentiment that transparency and

information exchange were important issues that were required to be brought to the fore of tax

reform. The OECD’s initiative4 was not a new undertaking, however, the enthusiasm and

participation in tax exchange information agreements (“TIEAs”) gained momentum as rapidly as

tax havens and financial tax scandals started scaffolding the modern economic landscape.

TIEA’s are a high tax nations’ response to substantial tax base erosions and profit shifting

practices by some countries. This is mostly due to the flourishing virtual world, which has now

3OECD, Harmful Tax Competition, An Emerging Global Issue (1998).

4OECD, The Global Forum on Transparency and Exchange of Information for Tax Purpose (2011).

4

directed the OECD (which has been requested by the G20 ministers) to develop another initiative

addressing Base Erosion and Profit Shifting (“BEPS”). BEPS is a process that “identifies actions

needed to address BEPS, sets deadlines to implement these actions and identifies the resources

needed and the methodology to implement these actions.”5

5 OECD Action Plan on Base Erosion and Profit Shifting,(2013).

5

Introduction

…we see that competitive behavior manifests most frequently and intensely when there is a shortage of some

necessity, like water, food, shelter, sex or, with the animal called Man, money. Competitive behavior

manifests when we are threatened or our survival is at stake... Nature reveals that when there is no shortage

in the necessities of survival, there is less competitive, aggressive behavior.6

It is human nature to compete for survival in all facets of life, and this echoes across the finance

world particularly across many poor, undeveloped, and developing countries. In modern times,

the hunt for food and shelter has been usurped by the pursuit of material gain and higher

standards of living. Economic growth is a necessity to assuage poverty, but the question central

to government policy makers’ agendas and international organizations’ is how to support this

growth through “legitimate” avenues.

Globalization over the last 25 years is arguably the greatest factor that has changed tax

competition and contributed to dramatically transforming the landscape of the economic world.

Capital and labor movements, with the ‘shift of manufacturing bases from high cost to low cost

locations, the gradual removal of trade barriers, technological and telecommunication

developments, and the ever increasing importance of managing risks and of developing,

protecting and exploiting intellectual property, have had an important impact on the way cross-

border activities take place.’7 It has been noted that the developed countries who are the leaders

6<http://evolutionaryeducation.com/sections.pdf> .

7Ibid, above n5.

6

of technology are the ones driving the globalization process due to the opportunities that arise,

therefore, in effect promoting growth in economic competition.

Globalization may accelerate the treadmill of technological change and reinforce its bias against the use of

unskilled or low-skilled labor in higher income countries...nevertheless, globalization may reduce social

welfare if it results in considerable inequality of income, as seems to be occurring in more developed

countries.8

Global welfare, as implied by the OECD, is considered directly affected by harmful tax

practices, however, there seems to be very little explanation by the OECD to support this notion.

Equally, the claims to prove that global welfare is enhanced by tax competition, is also

unfounded, and with the ambiguity on this issue it seems both sides are arguing without any real

empirical evidence.

Advocates of tax competition believe in celebrating competitive tax regimes as this promotes

economic stimulation and supports the efficiency and fairness of wealth redistribution. As far

back as 1956, Charles Tiebout (although his assumptions aren’t proven) argued his support for

tax competition by stating, ‘when citizens can choose between many communities where to live,

with each community offering different mixes of public goods and taxes, the resulting

“competition” forces jurisdictions to collect and spend their taxes efficiently.’9 Modern day

activists such as Julie Novak (Senior Fellow at the Institute of Public Affairs), have strong views

on tax competition and how havens have empowered our fiscal society.

8C Tisdell and S Svizzero, “Globalization Social Welfare and labor market inequalities” Working Paper No. 20 (2003)

<http://ageconsearch.umn.edu/bitstream/90525/2/WP%2020.pdf>. 9C Tiebout, A pure theory of local expenditure (1956).

7

On balance tax havens have contributed to our global economic prosperity by encouraging tax competition,

enabling footloose capital and labor to move economically hospitable environments and thereby limiting the

worst fiscal excesses in high taxing countries. From the mid-1980s to the late 2000s Australia lowered its

economically inhibitive high corporate and personal income tax rates, encouraging tax competition and

allowing domestic workers and firms to keep more of their own earnings in their pockets. The best way for

Australia to now deal with the tax haven challenge is to join them by returning to the global tax competition

contest.10

This sentiment however, contrasts with members and supporters of the OECD’s policies who see

tax competition as distorting markets by cutting tax rates, approving tax evasion, offering

clandestine tax loopholes for tax breaks and incentives in the form of tax subsidies. The OECD’s

reasons for embarking on the initiative to counteract harmful tax competitive practices, were

based on the effects that globalization is having on the modern financial climate. Mr. Kondo, the

Deputy Secretary-General of the OECD in his press release address on April 18, 2002 stated that

The OECD’s project…is part of a wider initiative to promote good governance in a globalized economy.

Globalization has enormous potential to improve living standards around the world. But is also brings risks,

including the risk of abuses of the free market system. The activities of tax havens distort the free flow of

capital and undermine the ability of governments to finance the legitimate expectations of their citizens for

publicly provided goods and services. By providing a framework…all countries can work together to fight

harmful tax practices, as the OECD seeks to encourage transparent and fair tax competition.11

10

<http://www.abc.net.au/unleashed/4737468.html>. 11

<http://www.nytimes.com/2002/05/10/opinion/10iht-edkondo_ed3_.html>.

8

Other advocates against tax competition could see it as a way to ‘redistribute wealth upwards,’

by allowing the rich to get richer and the poorer to become impoverished.

As tax rates on capital fall in response to these ‘competitive pressures, governments make up shortfalls by

levying higher taxes on other, less wealthy sections of society, or by cutting back on essential public services.

So tax competition boosts inequality and deprivation. Tax havens are the sharpest edge of this ‘competitive

axe. Owners of capital shift profits into tax havens, paying zero or very low taxes there, then tell politicians

in the ‘onshore’ countries where the genuine wealth is being created that they will bring the money home into

the tax net only if the politicians cut their home taxes on capital some more. Too often the politicians quail,

and cut some more. Wealth shifts upwards.12

The European Union (“EU”) who has feebly grappled with tax competition is a perfect model of

the intensity tax competition plays between the various countries within the small continent of

the European Union. Mobility of capital, differing tax rates between countries, tax reform in the

way of implementing flat taxes (such as the Baltic countries outside of the EU such as Russia,

Georgia and Serbia where flat rates of 13% has created a wrangle of capital outflows with very

little regulation) and immeasurable debt have major roles to play in the arguments against tax

competition. Germany and France, who are the powerhouses of the EU, play watchdog to many

of the EU countries especially Switzerland and a variety of other tax havens. ‘Nicolas

Sarkozy…proposed that European subsidies not be given to those countries engaging in “harmful

tax competition…” since the countries who adopt low taxation have a better development

strategy that just waiting for subsidies…not giving subsidies was to be considered as a sanction

against governments which do not play by the rules of the game.’13

12

<http://www.taxjustice.net/cms/upload/pdf/TJN_NEF_130418_Tax_competition.pdf>. 13

Ibid, above n1.

9

The question of whether tax competition has contributed or been detrimental to tax base erosion

and profit shifting has as many supporters as critics, but from the fragmentary research in the

past and the heatedness of many debates, there isn’t any one simple solution to the multifaceted

topic of tax competition.

Why do countries become tax havens if the OECD is launching an attack on tax

competition?

The OECD in 1998 embarked on eliminating two forms of harmful tax competition. One being

“harmful preferential tax regimes” and the other being tax havens. The OECD has certain criteria

that they defer to when branding a country a tax haven,14 which is similar to the four key criteria

identified as “harmful preferential tax regimes” which are as follows:-

1. No or low effective tax rates15

2. “Ring Fencing” of Regimes 16

3. Lack of transparency17

4. Lack of effective exchange of information18

The OECD belief is that preferential regimes can cause harmful tax practices when certain

jurisdictions tailor their tax regimes to erode the tax bases of other countries. ‘The effects of tax

competition being that it can distort trade and investment patterns; alter the structure of taxation;

14

Ibid above n3, note 57-60. 15

Ibid, note 61. 16

Ibid, note 62. 17

Ibid, note 63. 18

Ibid, note 64.

10

undermine taxpayer confidence in the integrity of tax systems; undermine fairness and neutrality;

and hamper the application of progressive tax rates.’19 This erosion can occur when tax regimes

attract investment or savings originating elsewhere and when they facilitate the avoidance of

other countries’ taxes. The OECD also major concerns with the effects of globalization in how

the upsurge of capital from developed countries flows to the less developed countries. ‘The

OECD fear in communications technology, such as Internet, raise a general risk to the forward

estimates of revenue…posing a major challenge for tax system design.’20

There are distinct differences between developed and developing countries and their attitude

toward tax competition, and why some countries evolve to become tax havens. As much as

economic empirical theories do for enabling authorities to design tax systems, it is equally

important to understand human behavior and how a taxpayer makes decisions on their

investments. However, governments and authorities don’t always make decisions based on the

how it affects the people, but rather how their policies rate at the time of elections.

Developed countries with eminent social structures that require a vast amount of government

expenditure to maintain a high standard of living don’t like tax competition for a variety of

reasons. With investments in infrastructure, education and social security, these countries

require continuous volumes of revenue through capital and foreign investments to subsidize the

expenditure to maintain or enhance the living standards of their country, therefore, any revenue

leakage would be seen as detrimental to maintaining the living standards. Terry Dwyer,

however, states, ‘fear that tax competition will lead to a loss of domestic revenue does not

19

Ibid. 20

T Dwyer, ‘Harmful’ tax competition and the future of offshore financial centers such as Vanuatu (2000)

<http://www.vanuatu.usp.ac.fj/sol_adobe_documents/usp%20only/vanuatu/dwyer.pdf>.

11

amount to an argument that tax competition is harmful either to one’s own or other countries, no

matter how unpleasant it may be for the treasury concerned.’21

The problem for developed countries from an international perspective is that they generally

have higher tax rates which can be challenging for individual taxpayers seeking to reduce their

own domestic tax debt. Tax havens give them the ability to reduce their taxable income or they

receive tax incentives to subsidize their investments.

High tax rates are more difficult to sustain in this new economic environment. As economic integration

increases, individuals and businesses gain greater freedom to take advantage of foreign economic

opportunities. That increases the sensitivity of decisions about investment and location to taxation. As a

result, high tax rates cause large economic losses when borders are opened up, giving countries strong

incentives to reduce rates. International tax competition is increasing as capital and labor mobility rises.22

Developing countries also have a requirement for revenue, as much or if not more than the

developed nations, due to higher social security and demands that poverty places on a

government. Their attitudes differ as they welcome tax competition to stimulate and enhance the

economy through gaining more revenue than they produce. Most tax havens derive a significant

portion of their GDP from their own financial industry but from a global perspective ‘half of the

world trade appears to pass through tax havens, although they account for only 3% of the world’s

GDP.’23 The OECD has been markedly frank about how the open financial markets have

occasioned an economic stimulus, going so far as to state that tax havens are accountable for the

deregulation of the open markets.

21

Ibid. 22

C Edwards & V De Rugy, <http://www.cato.org/pubs/efw/efw2002/efw02-ch3.pdf>. 23

B Gurtner, Tax Evasion: Hidden Billions for development, Swiss Coalition of development Organizations (2004).

12

Tax havens have proven that they are on the increase in the last 25 years24 which would suggest

that vigorous tax competition is seen as operating healthily worldwide. The question of why

countries continue to become tax havens should be broken down to why the havens exist in the

first place. Michael Littlewood believes that ‘tax havens’ are not diminishing (which the OECD

would like to be happening) by suggesting that

The volume of transactions channeled through tax havens seems unlikely to be much reduced, therefore, until

all, or almost all, the havens cease to function as such…It seems likely that those who practice in tax

havens…will prove similarly mobile…and move on to the new haven of choice…as a result the new haven

will be bigger, richer, more sophisticated, and better able to resist the efforts of the OECD.25

Another reason might be that when an individual’s ambition is to evade taxes, then reasonably

they are not going to voluntarily notify the authorities. Also, ‘the OECD’s cooperation pledges

did not require tax havens to take any immediate or decisive action. Instead, these pledges

required only symbolic statements on behalf of the tax havens.’26

In order for a tax haven to compete amongst other tax havens, they require a certain ability to

entertain good governance at the backdrop of their tax system. It then proceeds that a tax haven

should have a risk-free currency, little or no governmental corruption and a fully functioning

financial industry for investors to have confidence in any investment that they make. Tax havens

evolve to attract international mobile capital and to stimulate a healthy financial economy to fund

public services such as welfare. Timothy Addison however is not convinced and announces

24

Dharmmika Dharmapala & James R. Hines, Which Countries become Tax Havens. 25

M Littlewood, Tax Competition: Harmful to whom? 26T V Addison, Shooting Blanks: The War on Tax havens, Indiana Journal of Global Legal Studies(2009).

13

“even if a developing state could credibly commit to becoming a tax haven, it would most likely

be unwise and disastrous for its future economic growth. Because of fierce competition among

other tax havens, many tax havens are “profitable” only by the thinnest of margins. Developing

states cannot adequately provide their citizens with necessary public goods.”27 However, other

commentators would see the immeasurable profitability that tax havens can produce with Bruno

Gurtner stating that,

The offshore industry is not an isolated phenomenon occurring only on exotic Caribbean islands. Offshore

centres are very closely linked to major financial centres like New York, London, Tokyo, Zurich, Hong Kong

and Singapore. Most of the world’s tax havens are actually located in the big financial centres. The offshore

industry has become the new and enormous global shadow industry. Companies for offshore purposes are

now being established at the rate of over 150,000 per year. Today there are more than one million offshore

companies worldwide. Enron for example had 881 offshore subsidiaries, 692 only in the Cayman Islands.

The world biggest oil trader companies are located in Switzerland, though Switzerland has no oil!28

Less developed countries don’t necessarily have the infrastructure to support the growth of

capital and technology therefore by reducing tax rates, they can attract foreign investment. ‘One

problem with this strategy is that it might lead to a “race to the bottom,” explained as, if one

country seeks to attract foreign investment by offering preferential tax treatment (that is by

taxing foreign investors less heavily than it taxes resident investors), then others may lower their

rates.’29 The consequence of other countries lowering their rates until there are no taxes, results

in a “zero” benefit, therefore, the competitive purpose is lost. However, Kristian Niemietz, takes

the view that there is no such thing as “harmful” tax competition through the lowering of tax

27

Ibid, above n26. 28Ibid, above n23. 29

Ibid, above n25.

14

rates. He states that tax competition ‘is an effective and necessary means of protecting

individuals against the insatiable tax appetites of their own governments.’30 When oppressed

taxpayers have the ability to shift resources from high-tax nations to low-tax jurisdictions,

politicians should begin to realize that it is not smart to abuse the geese that lay the golden

eggs.31

…competition between governments is as good for individuals as competition between firms is for

consumers. It keeps down tax rates, especially on labor and capital, which is good for growth and job

creation; states need to produce better services at the cheapest possible cost. And if governments become too

irritating or incompetent, it allows an exit strategy. It is strange how pundits who claim to want greater

competition in the domestic economy – for example, in banking – are so afraid of competition for people

between states, decrying it as a race to the bottom. Yet monopolies are always bad, in every sphere of human

endeavor, breeding complacency, curtailing innovation and throttling progress. …Globalization is not just

about buying cheap Chinese goods: it also limits the state’s powers to over-tax or over-control its citizens.32

The lowering of tax rates approach is not supported by the OECD, who wants to globally enforce

high taxes and implement tax harmonization. This can stifle innovation and progress and can be

seen to make governments look like quasi-monopolies enforcing high taxes where the by-product

in particularly poorer countries would be crime to pay for these taxes. This approach can be seen

as regressive and have negative impacts particularly in the short term for less developed

countries. Equally for the developed country, it is also a feasible argument that the increase in

taxable rates can lead to superfluous public spending on unnecessary expenditure.

30

K Niemietz, <http://www.iea.org.uk/blog/%E2%80%9Charmful%E2%80%9D-tax-competition-new-actors-same-old-plot>. 31

D Mitchell <http://www.insideronline.org/archives/2002/sept02/tax_harmonization.pdf>. 32

A Heath <Allistar Heath http://danieljmitchell.wordpress.com/2011/03/20>.

15

The quaint notion that a tax haven is a small under-developed country in the middle of an ocean

is most likely but also incongruous to reality. Australia in the past was considered a tax haven in

the area of funds management offering tax cuts in the form of withholding taxes whilst

maintaining one of the world’s highest domestic tax rates. America offered a preferential tax

regime in terms of tax incentives on interest on foreigner’s portfolios and government bonds.

Hong Kong is one of the biggest emerging economies of the 21st century and their policies have

been based on the single tier flat system tax to enhance their economy with offshore income from

interest and dividends, dubiously not observed by the OECD as conventions outside their

guidelines. Hong Kong also doesn’t have any Capital Gains Tax, which is bound to fuel vigorous

foreign investment, with variable consequences.

The United Kingdom is another powerhouse that shows signs of preferential tax regimes with

regard to domicile and the taxation of foreign income, which can be seen as similar to some of

the tax havens that are blacklisted by the OECD. There are many more member OECD countries

that practice questionable tax regimes under the guidelines stipulated by the OECD.

One the most interesting nations being Ireland, screams of a modern technological “tax haven.”

There are many countries that have higher tax rates that relish in investing in the Irish tax rate of

12.5%. Apple have utilized this avenue whereby the ‘US senate subcommittee recently heard

claims that about $22 billion, or 64 per cent, or Apple’s pre-tax income were recorded in Ireland

in 2011, saving the company $7.7 billion in US taxes…It is no coincidence that recent political

harassment of successful multinational corporations specialising in information technology and

16

communications products and services, such as Apple, Google and Amazon, for more revenue is

closely aligned with the significant fiscal troubles faced by advanced economies.’33

It is then questionable that the OECD was indeed living up to their ideology of a “fair tax

system” as it became apparent they were intensifying their attention on the less sophisticated

regimes by honing in on the smaller more economically vulnerable countries, such as those

countries situated within the pacific Islands and in the Caribbean. Marshall Langer has argued

that “without a doubt the OECD report is not as conclusive nor is it as far reaching in its attack

on so called preferential tax regimes.’34 The OECD targeted numerous countries within the

members of the Caribbean Community and Common Market (“CARICOM”), blacklisting their

economies and attacking their sovereignty.

CARICOM members (15 countries) were part of a group of countries within the Caribbean that

developed a strong banking and financial industry purely to ensure diversity as their other form

of industry being tourism was always marred by the environmental effects of hurricanes and

tornados. ‘Fostered by tax regimes with no or only nominal rates, and strict secrecy rules, the

offshore banking sector flourished in the Caribbean.’35 Likewise in the pacific Islands, with

Vanuatu being a natural tax haven, there is ‘little or no direct taxation’ and ‘enhanced privacy

provision’ where tourism and employment in this tax haven provides both benefits to the people

of Vanuatu36 and contributes to 15% of Vanuatu’s GDP.

33

Ibid, above n10. 34

M J Langer, Harmful Tax Competition: Who are the real tax havens? 35

T M Hoffman, The Future of Offshore havens (2001). 36

Vanuatu was removed from the OECD’s list of uncooperative tax havens in May 2003.

17

…Even though tax havens are harmful, it does not follow that it is necessarily desirable for the OECD (or

any other collective of countries) to attempt to eradicate them. The reason is that the cure may be worse than

the ailment. That is, if the matters on which a small group of rich countries can dictate policy to the rest of

the world are extended to taxation, this seems to represent a further erosion of national independence and

diversity.37

However by 2002 through bullying tactics of the OECD and the sheer size of its membership

of industrialized nations, fourteen of the fifteen CARICOM countries had signed the OECD

agreements. The sentiment carried throughout these island nations was that to do otherwise

would to be signing a death certificate in terms of sanctions to their industries. They were

forced into the realization that to survive in the expanding globalized community they had to

conform and ‘toe the line.’ Loaded statements by the powerful OECD have compelled tax

haven countries to yield to the OECD demands. The manipulation of the “all powerful” OECD

can be seen in the following statement that demonstrates how they can turn everything to their

advantage.

If tax havens are free to structure their tax systems however they wish, why not the OECD member states?

That is, if the tax havens are free to structure their tax systems so as to facilitate the avoidance of other

countries’ taxes, it seems to follow that other countries should be free to structure their systems so as to

discourage the use of havens. (e.g. by disallowing deductions to haven entities, levying withholding taxes on

payments to haven residents, and withholding “nonessential” aid.)38

37

Ibid, above n25. 38

D Ring, Backdoor Harmonization? Implications of the new era of tax information exchange.

18

Harmonization – is it really the way forward?

The tax competition problem is thus essentially a problem of coordination and trust. Each jurisdiction would

prefer to tax investors from abroad to gain the revenue, but is afraid that by doing so it would drive the

investors to other jurisdictions that do not tax them. If there was a way to coordinate actions among the

relevant jurisdictions, they all could gain added revenues without running the risk of losing the investment.39

Events such as 9/11, the financial recession that began in 2001, and also one of the biggest

financial scandals, Enron (which was one of many tax scandals at that time) became the much

desired trigger the OECD, and indeed the international community required to globally unite on

the issue of tax competition and harmonization.

Economists have however, heatedly debated the argument of tax coordination or harmonization,

but economic models developed by Peter Sorenson of the University of Copenhagen have found

that ‘tax coordination would lead to higher capital taxes, and higher income and wealth

distribution – but lower infrastructure spending, lower capital stocks, lower profits, lower real

wages, lower GDP, and higher real interest rates…It seems tax competition does not have any

downside, while tax coordination has no up-side.’ 40

There have been many proposals by economists such as Sorenson, Mintz, Bucovetsky and

Wilson who have tried to find solutions to overcome the inefficiencies caused by unregulated

economic outcomes, and ensure a unified tax system. One solution was to formulate a unilateral

tax rate on source capital income however source-based taxes would lead to a migration of

39

R.S Avi-Yonah, Globalization and tax competition :Implications for developing countries, cepal review 74 (2001). 40

S Davidson, Here is the truth about tax havens.

19

capital to other countries unless there was a global treaty in place (which is not realistic in the

short term). Another suggestion would be to strictly enforce the residency rules, but there are

loopholes that can be found in these areas as well. Ultimately, pure economic theories cannot

totally battle against human will, regardless of the rules and regulations. They can however

surmise what a majority of tax compliant individuals might adhere to.

So how does the OECD guarantee that tax harmonization will benefit those tax havens that are

incidental and don’t function with tax evasion as their intention? Is it even plausible that the

OECD can differentiate between havens based on intention? There are obvious tax havens that

embark on functioning purely with foreign profit as the intention and avoidance of taxes at the

epicenter of their structure. The other problem the OECD has with tax havens is that some

governments operate from an illegal vantage point by laundering money from guns and drugs,

and terrorist activists which presupposes that these countries “intentions” are not factored around

the tax system. The OECD has little control over these jurisdictions and drawing a line in the

sand with rigid criteria shows a firm stance, but trying to stamp out countries firmly entrenched

in illegal rackets is considered an uphill battle with regard to tax reform. Considering the

classification of a tax haven has proven difficult for the OECD as well as their attempts to

sanction countries involved in high crime with little effect, it demonstrates the highly ineffective

nature of tax harmonization. Furthermore, the OECD’s stance has contenders of tax

harmonization struggling to view this standpoint as anything other than a modern form of

intimidation and oppression.

An OECD-instigated cartel will lead to higher tax rates and more punitive treatment of capital. The OECD’s

tax harmonization campaign also could mean the death of tax reform. All proposals to simplify the tax code —

20

such as the flat tax—are based on common sense principles such as taxing income only one time and taxing

only income earned inside national borders. The OECD effort, by contrast, is designed to help governments

impose discriminatory taxes on capital income, even if the income is earned in other jurisdictio ns.41

What impact will TIEA’s and transparency have on the face of tax competition?

Although the original launching point for debate was the OECD work in tax competition, developing

concerns about OECD policy direction and power – often framed in the language of sovereignty and concern

for forced harmonization – helped shift the focus of the conversation and the action plan toward exchange of

information.42

After the many harmful global events that unveiled from 2001, the OECD was forced to change

its purpose of trying to establish a harmonized tax system. Their refocus no longer required tax

havens to substantiate domestic activity or to modify their tax systems to eliminate their “no

substantial activity” criteria. This change was brought about by a variety of factors, but largely

because there were so many global variables that became so overwhelmingly challenging and

just plainly unachievable in an international sense. How can you apply similar principles to every

country without having to deal with the differences that each country exhibits?

The tipping point for change was when some of the tax havens on the OECD’s black list, who

objected to these guidelines and for a variety of reasons the committee, took action and

downgraded the significance of the rule of “no substantial activity.” The OECD began to look

outside the square of taxation and into the area of transparency and exchange of information

41

Ibid, above n31. 42

Ibid, above n38.

21

because of the precipitous effects of many political, economic and climatic fluctuations that

transpired.

By refocusing on transparency, the OECD no longer pursued what tax rates a country should

adopt, or how any tax system should be structured. From a global perspective they attempted to

foster economic growth and efficiency, and the equitable flow of capital between countries by

closing any loopholes in the profit shifting game through multilateral means.

Transparency became a hot topic, with committee members explaining the requirements of

transparency in its 2001 report,43 ‘…by committing to transparency, a jurisdiction agrees that

there will be no non-transparent features of its tax system.’ With regard to Exchange of

Information agreements and the lack of signed agreements the OECD was compelled to reform

their prior objectives to overhaul the policies surrounding the accuracy and credibility of

information exchange.

At the dawn of information exchange revolution, Adrian Sawyer amongst other commentators

also rained on the OECD’s TIEA initiative parade, by stating that from the empirical evidence

‘there is an emerging critical literature on the potential effectiveness of the OECD’s TIEA

initiative from both practitioners and various monitoring organizations.’44 ‘The common theme is

the unexpected ineffectual nature of TIEA’s along with their failure to deal with the real issues

surrounding tax havens, such as bank secrecy and highly protective domestic legislation.’45 The

Tax Justice Network also proclaimed that the OECD’s philosophy toward information exchange

43

The OECD’s Project on Harmful Tax Practices: The 2001 Progress report. 44

A Sawyer, Tax Havens “Coming in from the Cold.” A sign of changing times? 2010. 45

A Sawyer, The OECD’S Tax Information exchange Agreements: An Example of (In)Effective Global Governance?

22

was entrenched in black, white and a variety of shades of grey guidelines that were not realistic

or forward thinking.

The issue surrounding transparency and exchange of information were the protagonists that gave

birth to The Model Agreement on Exchange of Information on Tax matters (“Model TIEA”).

The model TIEA is based upon Article 26 of the OECD’s Model of Tax Convention on Income

and on Capital,46 which came into effect April 2002 and was created with a view to a long term

commitment from the OECD to persuade tax havens to embrace the information exchange

agreements and cease cross border tax evasion and avoidance. TIEAs were put in place to

streamline relevant information such as bank accounts, and company shareholders with

registered companies, investigations in tax matters and any ensuing prosecutions that might

result.

The aim of the OECD’s Model TIEA is to establish effective exchange of information in a manner that is not

binding. Supplementary purposes include an intention to reduce evasion and treaty shopping. The Model

TIEA contains multilateral and bilateral formats, together with Commentary, the interpretation of which is to

be determined by principles of international law.47

Hence, from this time onwards the TIEA Model was labeled the “internationally agreed tax

standard,”48 but there were concerns regarding its effectiveness and the lack of transparency the

TIEAs actually upheld. The drawback came with the fact that the TIEAs were only used “upon

request,” therefore there was no obligation to make documentation municipal. This assumption

that all OECD membership countries voluntarily complied with the OECDs requirement is

46

OECD, Model Tax Convention on Income and on Capital 2008 (updated July 2010). 47

Ibid, above n45. 48

M. Meinzer, TJN; Tax Justice Briefing, The Creeping Futility of the Global Forum’s Peer Reviews, March 2012.

23

farcical, and only undermined the essence of what the OECD was trying to achieve –

transparency and exchange of information. Timothy Addison asserts that TIEAs are of limited

benefit.49 This is because the TIEAs won’t disable the domestic bank secrecy laws of the tax

haven and also that they have to identify the actual taxpayer involved, which will prove to be just

another “needle in a haystack” quest or a “fishing expedition,” as quoted by the OECD.

The OECD’s work on double taxation and tax treaties is instructive…there are currently about 1,500 tax

treaties in the world…almost all of them are based on a model devised by the OECD. The Organization’s

aim, in devising this model, and in revising it from time to time, was to meet the needs of its members.

Consequently, the model treaty, although representing some sort of optimal satisfaction of the OECD’s

members, is widely perceived as biased in favor of the developed countries and against the less-developed.50

The Global Forum on Transparency and Exchange of Information for Tax purposes ‘was created

in the early 2000s in the context of the OECD’s work to address the risks to tax compliance

posed by tax havens. The original members of the Global Forum consisted of OECD countries

and jurisdictions that had agreed to implement transparency and exchange of information for tax

purposes.’51It consisted of a multilateral framework with a two phase peer review that monitored

transparency and exchange of information standards, and the strengths and weaknesses that some

countries were facing with regard to the exchange of information systems. ‘Among developed

economies, perhaps the most significant of the three areas of concern in tax information

exchange is the requested country’s de facto capacity to collect and release the information

sought.’52 The major obstacle touted here though, has been the domestic bank secrecy rules.

49

Ibid, above n26. 50

Ibid, above n25. 51

<http://www.oecd.org/tax/transparency/>. 52

Ibid, above n38.

24

Some countries ‘impose legal obligations of financial secrecy on certain fiduciaries or other third

parties, but then lift those restrictions if information is being requested pursuant to an exchange

of information agreement.’53

Exchange of tax information in its “fullness” can be obstructed by a countries willingness to

comply or simply how a definition is tacit to the exchange agreement. Words and phrases such as

“tax fraud” or “crime” can be lost in translation or confused through concepts not clearly

explained. Most OECD countries, except Switzerland with regard to the meaning of “tax fraud”,

have agreements on the common understanding of words. Switzerland had exempted themselves

as well by enshrouding their tax systems in bank secrecy laws and limiting information sharing.

Other problems that some of these exchange agreements have presented is how they are

perceived by the taxpayers themselves and the uncertainty of “shared” information and whether

the authorities are using this information confidentially. “Upon request” exchange and

subsequently, “automatic” exchange is still fraught with loopholes, and whether this information

is being used in the correct format required by the OECD guidelines. Understanding how to use

the extensive amount of information is challenging for some countries whose tax systems are

parochial at best and are unable to successfully accommodate the intensity of information desired

in the exchange of information requests.

On the other hand, exchange of information has positively contributed to areas of Controlled

Foreign Companies (“CFC”), Transfer Pricing, and reducing international conflicts that arise due

to lack of knowledge. A CFC could become more efficiently implemented with more accurate

and reliable information, and hence promote a healthier tax system. International conflict is

53

Ibid, above n4.

25

always heightened when there is in inherit ignorance and information sharing could help

overcome some of these barriers.

Regardless of their drawbacks, TIEAs were being signed in abundance.

A series of banking scandals beginning in 2006 shifted the tenor of the discussion and by 2007 and then again

in 2008 and 2009, the number of TIEAs being signed dramatically increases (between 9 and 11 TIES had

been signed annually from 2003-2006, then the number rose to 23 by 200, in 2008 to 50 in 2009 to 250 and

2010 to 404 signed TIEAs).54

By 2009, the OECD with renewed vigor brought out another report, Tax Co-operation 2009:

Towards a Level Playing Field,55 which highlights the standards of the OECD and the relevance

that transparency and exchange of information agreements play in revenue collection.

International banking has become commonplace and it is no longer extraordinary for taxpayers to reside in

one country, hold assets in another and have them managed from a third location…but regardless of why

taxpayers situate their assets beyond the boundaries of their own residence country, the result is that tax

administrations around the world face more and greater challenges to the proper enforcement of their tax

laws than ever before. To meet these challenges, tax authorities must increasingly rely on international co -

operation based on the implementation of international standards of transparency and effective exchange of

information.56

This renewed energy together with increased commitments from various countries, lead the

Global Forum in 2012 to again reform its process by initiating a program that consisted more in-

54

OECD, Global Forum on Transparency and Exchange of Information for Tax purposes, “A background Information brief “ (2010). 55

OECD, Tax Co-operation 2009: Towards a Level Playing Field, (2009). 56

Ibid, above n55.

26

depth peer review. ‘This 2012 Report on Progress publication describes the progress made since

the Global Forum launched its peer review mechanism in 2010… and reported the findings of

the peer review reports to the G20 Leaders in June 2012, showing a high level of cooperation

among members and a good level of compliance with the international standard, while also

identifying a number of unresolved deficiencies. …’57

In an article posted on August 2, 2013 Hong Kong Now Allowed to Sign Standalone Tax

Information Exchange Agreements, the following except is addressed to demonstrate that Hong

Kong (a notoriously developed tax haven) is attempting to conform to international standards.

Further, the latest international exchange of information standards set by the Global Forum requires that all of

its members – in addition to various other jurisdictions identified by the Global Forum – pass a review based

on the quality and practical implementation of their respective legal and regulatory frameworks regarding

information exchange. To pass the reviews, a jurisdiction must have both a CDTA and a TIEA in effect as

instruments for information exchange…. Only through [passing this Bill] will Hong Kong be able to continue

with its efforts in negotiating CDTAs with existing as well as potential partners, whilst providing in place a

legal framework for TIEAs for Hong Kong to meet its international obligations,” noted Professor K.C. Chan,

Hong Kong’s Financial Services and Treasury Bureau Secretary58

Recently, Australia has been forced to revise its tax treaty in the area of income tax with

Switzerland the only tax haven that Australia has a Double taxation agreements (“DTA”) with.

In the case of tax havens, Australia usually uses exchange of information agreements. The

assistant Treasurer, The Honorable David Bradbury MP stated that ‘The revised treaty will

strengthen administrative assistance between Australian and Swiss revenue authorities, in

57

H J Ault, Some reflections on the OECD and the Sources of International Tax Principles. 58

<http://www.china-briefing.com/news/2013/08/02/hong-kong-now-allowed-to-sign-standalone-tax-information-exchange-agreements.html>/.

27

particular by permitting them to exchange taxpayer information, including information held by

banks and other financial institutions, in order to address tax evasion.’59 This new DTA contains

provisions on the exchange of information in accordance with international standards and ‘would

contribute to the further positive development of bilateral economic relations between them.’60

Australia has a strong commitment to ensure that their national tax system is upheld with

integrity and not frivolously eroded away. On 13 February 2013, Australian government

introduced The Tax Laws Amendment (Countering Tax Avoidance and Multinational Profit

Shifting) Bill 2013 contains amendments to the general anti avoidance rule Part IVA, and also to

the Transfer Pricing regime. The honorable David Bradbury MP stated that

The amendments will protect revenue of over $1 billion per year. The amendments also modernize

Australia's transfer pricing rules and provide a comprehensive and robust transfer pricing regime that is

aligned with internationally accepted principles, as set out by the OECD. Tran sfer pricing rules are critical to

the integrity of the tax system. They seek to ensure that an appropriate return for the contribution of

Australian operations of a multinational group is taxable in Australia for the benefit of the broader

community.61

Regardless of most OECD member countries trying hard to uphold their own fiscal proficiency

there are always uncertainties in the area of transparency and exchange of information, but it

seems Australian practices are in line with the OECD current philosophies.

Pascal Saint-Amans (new head of OECD tax department) does not concede that transparency and

exchange of information is of central importance, rather ‘transparency is of course key, and we

59

<http://www.swissinfo.ch/eng/culture/Taxation_agreement_signed_with_Australia.html?cid=36573476>. 60

Ibid. 61

<http://ministers.treasury.gov.au/DisplayDocs.aspx?pageID=003&doc=../content/pressreleases/2013/010.htm&min=djba>.

28

do have an agenda there…but for me, the core business of the OECD is tax treaties, transfer

pricing, and the elimination of double taxation. We should be back to our core business, I’m not

sure we’ve left it, but we could strengthen that to make sure.’62

Base Erosion Profit Shifting - going forward

We are entering an exciting and challenging time for multinationals. The OECD has made it very clear that it

wants to drive a fundamental re-write of the principles of international taxation that were laid down almost a

century ago. The challenge for multinationals will be to ensure that their existing structures evolve in

parallel and are fit for purpose for the next century. The challenge for each of the sovereign states involved

will be putting the stated principles into practice in a way that balances tax revenue an d political

considerations with each country’s presumed desire to remain competitive as both a source country and

residence country with respect to multinational direct investment.63

Part of the subsequent plan that originated from the 1998 report was the OECD’s base erosion

and profit shifting project, with the BEPS report being expounded at the G20 summit in Moscow

in February 2013. Due to the topic of BEPS being high on the international agenda, it was noted

by the communique in Moscow that, ‘in the tax area, we welcome the OECD report on

addressing base erosion and profit shifting and acknowledge that an important part of fiscal

sustainability is securing our revenue bases. We are determined to develop measures…take

necessary collective actions and look forward to the comprehensive action plan the OECD will

present to us in July.’

62

Ibid, above n48. 63

<http://www.lexology.com/library/detail.aspx?g=374cd3e4-4a3b-403c-943c-e54b1bca4ab0>.

29

The BEPS report, which has been driven by the G20, pinpoints a variety of issues whereby

‘fundamental changes are needed to effectively prevent double taxation, as well as cases of no or

low taxation associated with practices that artificially segregate taxable income from the

activities that generate it.’64 The report looks at a ‘realignment of taxation and relevant

substance…to restore intended effects and benefits of international standards,’65 to modernize

alongside of the globalization of technology. As Pascal Saint-Amans stated on 17th August 2013

‘the action plan ‘represents a unique opportunity that comes along once in a century to rewrite

the principles of international taxation…that will last for the next 100 years.’66

It is also an initiative by the OECD/G20 for the major purpose of ‘an inclusive and effective

process: launching the OECD/G20 BEPS project and involving developing countries…this

action plan requires an effective and comprehensive process that involves all relevant

stakeholders.’67

The BEPS project came into effect because of the political force that transpired from many

countries concerns because some multinationals were paying little or no effective tax, due to the

loopholes in the current international tax regulations. Multinationals such as Google, Apple,

Starbucks have all been under recent media scrutiny because ‘some multinationals are exploiting

the transfer pricing or treaty rules to shift profits to places with no or low taxation, allowing them

to pay as little as 5 percent in corporate taxes while smaller businesses are paying up to 30

percent. This distorts competition, giving larger companies an advantage over smaller, more

64

Ibid, above n5. 65

Ibid, above n5. 66

Ibid, above n63. 67

Ibid, above n5.

30

domestic companies. In this difficult economic climate, it cannot be right that larger companies

can avoid paying tax, with families and small businesses ending up paying more.’68

In a highly globalized environment, with tax arbitrage, tax havens, and developments in information

technology making transactions on the internet increasingly popular, tax revenues from corporate income tax

are dwindling even without the various allowances introduced by politicians favoring particular industries

and particular activities. Raising revenues from the profits tax is posing an increasingly daunting task; and tax

evasion is distorting activities and causing deadweight loss for society.69

Tim Cook, CEO of Apple openly defends Apples offshore tax policy by stating that they have

paid the US government 6 billion dollars of profits tax, and ‘subsidiaries in Ireland had funded

much of Apple’s R&D. He claims that the company has done nothing wrong, because the tax

avoidance was lawful and was necessary because the American tax system was outdated. This is

prime case of a massive multinational exploiting (and in their words) a “lawful” tax system.

Digital Companies such as Google and Amazon, two of the fastest internet based growing

multinationals are currently exploiting loopholes in the area of “permanent establishments.”

Companies pay corporation tax on their profits, not their sales. But the current debate revolves around the

apparent ability of multinationals to move their profits from country to country with little obvious relationship

to where the sales are generated.70 In an era where non-resident [corporate] taxpayers can derive substantial

profits from transactions with customers located in another country, questions are being raised as to whether

68

H Lok Sang, Tax Reform : Toward a simpler, more progrowth tax regime (2013). 69

Ibid, above n68. 70

<http://www.bbc.co.uk/news/business-22878460>.

31

the current rules ensure a fair allocation of taxing rights on business profits, especially where the profits from

such transactions go untaxed anywhere.71

Tensions have appeared in the ‘OECD working party looking at how to address the permanent

establishment rules in the light of the burgeoning internet economy. This working party is being

jointly led by US and French teams – representing the extremes of opinion among G20

nations…France has been among the most aggressive in responding to online businesses that

target French customers but pay little or no French tax… In the case of Google, in 2011 French

tax officials demanded €1.7bn in back taxes. In February this year Google settled the case,

agreeing to pay €60m to help France with digital innovation and other issues.’72

The OECD has fifteen proposed actions to address BEPS and has strong visions in regard to the

aggressive tax planning required to combat internet multinationals by largely targeting its sights

on “six key pressure areas" some of which are summarized as follows.

Action 1 - Addresses the challenges of the digital economy. This is aimed at identifying ‘the

significant challenges posed by the digital economy in relation to the current application of

international tax rules and develop detailed options to address these problems.’ Permanent

establishments will be under scrutiny because of the risks they are exposed to, and because the

way global business has significantly changed with the emergence of the digital economy.

Companies whose business models involve no physical presence but heavy interaction with local customers -

- who’s freely uploaded information they sell to advertisers -- have been in the sights of tax administrators in

71

<http://www.theguardian.com/business/2013/jul/14/us-tax-avoidance-google-amazon>. 72

Ibid.

32

France and other countries. None of them pay much tax to customer countries. The actio n plan promises to

take a holistic approach that will consider both direct and indirect taxation. 73

The crackdown on changing the loopholes with regard to permanent establishments has

already started (such as the tax audit of Microsoft in France) but stringent rules are required to

ensure that any ambiguity with regard to associated subsidiaries is covered. The Dell Case in

Spain has become a precedent for the first “online permanent establishment,” but these cases

may be more than the OECD can deal with at the moment as the action plans will not be

“actioned” for a few more months if not years.

Action 2 – Neutralize the effects of hybrid mismatch arrangements. Under this banner the focus

on hybrids is based on the apparent gaps between some domestic laws. The use of double non-

taxation, double deduction and long term deferral will be scrutinized. ‘Considered by some

observers as the most challenging aspect of this action plan, this action may require changes to

the OECD Model Tax convention and domestic law and substantial cooperation among

countries,’74 particularly in the area of deductibility. The challenge lies with those countries that

might find that the benefits outweigh the losses that emanate from tax breaks associated with

Multinational-enterprises (“MNEs”).

Action 3 – Strengthen CFC Rules so that taxpayers incentives to shift profits to low jurisdictions

are reduced.

The OECD wishes to see uniform CFC rules to counter BEPS in a more comprehensive manner, with the aim

that tax payers would have a much reduced incentive to shift profits into a low tax jurisdiction. The action

73

< http://www.taxanalysts.com/www/features.nsf/Articles/686B11ADF362660985257BB9004C216E?OpenDocument>. 74

<http://www.lexology.com/library/detail.aspx?g=956cccd4-0978-4b69-8025-02e31e66e0d3>

33

point is to develop recommendations regarding the uniform design of CFC rules which could then be

considered by the sovereign states. 75

CFC legislation is exceptionally significant to the claw back rules, and its presumptuous nature is

what makes this challenging for the OECD with particular regard to interest payments that are

excessive as compared the debt levels.

The action plan merely says that the OECD will develop model CFC rules, without indicating any direction

for them. The sense of direction is that we want effective CFC rules. Issues of compatibility with European

Union law will be taken into account. There are already some EU member states with pretty tight CFC rules,

Saint-Amans told Tax Analysts.76

Action 4 – Limit base erosion via interest deductions and other financial payments. This action

plan indicates that a “model domestic law” which the OECD proposes, will disallow deductions

for related party interest that is not being taxed in the hands of the receiver. This is associated

with inbound and outbound circumstances. With regard to inbound, the concern lies with how

excessive the interest deduction is for debtor as compared to the taxed interest for the financier.

The outbound scenario is viewed from the debt to finance perspective.

The action point is to develop best practice recommendations for the design of rules to prevent BEPS through

the use of interest deductions and other financial payments. Transfer pricing guidance will also be developed

in relation to the pricing of related party financial transactions.77

There’s eleven other action plans not listed here, but they are equally just as important and

requiring attention and action. It has been noted by cynics that the BEPS plan ‘reflects nothing

75

<http://www.pwc.com/en_SG/sg/tax-bulletin/assets/taxbulletin20130730.pdf> 76

Ibid, above n73. 77

Ibid, above n75.

34

more than a political response to several high profile international cases involving MNEs such as

Google, Apple and Starbucks having minimal tax liabilities in jurisdictions where these

companies had significant operations. In other words, there was a public outcry the MNEs were

not paying their fair share of tax and the politicians had to act now.’78

Conclusion

‘Globalization has boosted trade and increased foreign direct investments in many countries. Hence it supports

growth, creates jobs, fosters innovation, and has lifted millions out of poverty.’79

The OECD’s crusade to rid the world of tax havens and harmful preferential tax regimes is

endorsed by the primary motivation of the members of the OECD. The OECD has debated

against tax competition and the reasons tax havens should be dismantled for many years with

heatedness and a desire to improve or world economically. The dubiety with regard to some of

their opinions such as the reduction in global welfare and the distortion of markets due to

harmful tax competition has seen the OECD’s credibility under scrutiny with empirical data

proving that these facts are not always proven. The idea that every country has to abide by

similar if not the same rules is at best theoretically sound, however, realistically impractical.

‘Naturally most countries try to protect their tax basis. But only the successful way to counter

harmful tax practices and international tax competition is through global initiatives.’80 The

initiatives put in place by the OECD such as the Model TIEA’s and more currently BEPS have

78

Ibid, above n74. 79

Ibid, above n5. 80

Ibid, above n23.

35

their fair share of criticisms and limitations. But the question is and will continue to be, how far

does the OECD have to go in terms of initiatives before the economic world merges into one,

and is this what everyone wants? Michael Littlewood has noted that

diversity among nations may be an inherently desirable phenomenon – and worth preserving and fostering,

even at a cost. The homogenizing of the world’s legal systems and tax systems is therefore, not necessarily a

good thing, especially if it is effectively imposed by some countries on o thers….The OECD project has an

uncomfortable but pervasive fell of Big Brother to it.81

One of the many problems that the OECD have had difficulty with initially was The harmful tax

competition report in 1998 which was perceived to be nothing more than a tax cartel disguised,

for the benefit of the richer more powerful countries, and to the detriment of the developing

poorer nations. This report is at least an attempt to harness the illegalities of money laundering

and fraudulent behavior, however, there are many limitations with this report and a rethink is a

necessity to ensure tax competition isn’t impeding other potentially suitable economic outcomes.

The OECD has also had their fair share of success with regard to the number of TIEA’s

emerging onto the international tax arena which suggests that there is a momentum for a global

change. Whether this momentum continues is a focus the OECD will have to promote, however,

the new head of the tax department for the OECD has challenged all the previous workings of

the OECD and stated that exchange of information is not key but rather that his focus lies with

‘tax treaties, transfer pricing, and the elimination of double taxation.’ This does not bid well for

81

Ibid, above n25.

36

their aim in reducing tax competition, as altering perceptions on tax competition is generally in

alignment with the trajectory of information exchange and transparency.

Regardless of the success or failure of the OECD to date, they have had at least the fortitude to

attempt many economic pilgrimages through initiatives to find global harmony and to reduce

preferential tax regimes. To achieve this requires strength and determination (which they have)

and an unbridled passion to at least in their minds, try to make the economic world a better place

for ALL mankind.

In concluding, the following statement by Michael Littlewood is a reflection on how the OECD

should maybe take its direction in terms of tax competition,

Maximizing global welfare seems a noble objective, but it also does not seem to be a principle upon which

international relations are usually based. Perhaps it would be a good thing if they were. If so, however,

foisting tax reform on unenthusiastic developing countries seems an oblique way to go about it. It would

seem more effective for the OECD and its members to address the goal more directly – for example, by

reducing the restrictions they put on immigration from less -developed countries, or by simply increasing the

aid they make available to them.

…Tax Competition can be as good for the goose as it is for the Gander…because there are many

ways to skin a cat…