jongha-lim paper distressed

Upload: chris-trampe

Post on 09-Apr-2018

216 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    1/63

    1

    The Role of Activist Hedge Funds in Distressed Firms

    Jongha Lim1,2

    Fisher College of Business

    The Ohio State University

    This Version: September 13st, 2010

    Abstract

    Frictions to efficient bargaining provide an opportunity for a hedge fund to invest in distressed firms, facilitatereorganizations, and capture some of the rents from doing so. This paper considers a sample of 184 financiallydistressed firms for the period from 1998 to 2009, and finds that distressed investing has become an importantavenue for activism by hedge funds. Distress-focused hedge funds utilize a fulcrum investment strategy so as tomaximize their influence on the reorganization process. Empirical evidence is consistent with the view that hedgefunds capture some of the rents they create by reorganizing the distressed firms. First, distress-oriented hedge fundstend to target economically healthy firms in which contracting difficulties are likely to prevent efficientreorganization. Second, hedge funds presence as creditors leads to effective restructuring through both debt-equityswaps and pre-packaged filings. In addition, when hedge funds inject new equity capital into targeted firms, theduration of distress is significantly reduced. Both debt and equity investments by hedge funds are associated withsignificantly higher probabilities of successful restructuring. Lastly, distress-focused funds in my sample have

    produced an annual compounded return of 8.6% over the 1998-2009 period, which is economically significant,compared to 3.2% generated by the stock market over the same period.

    1 Contacts: Jongha Lim, Doctoral student, Fisher College of Business, The Ohio State University, 2100 Neil Ave,Columbus, Ohio, 43210; E-mail:[email protected] I greatly appreciate the helpful comments and advice from Anil Makhija, Bernadette Minton, Ren Stulz, andMichael Weisbach. I am also grateful for valuable discussions with Jack Bao, Itzhak Ben-David, Ji-woong Chung,Isil Erel, Kewei Hou, Berk Sensoy, and Yingdi Wang. I thank seminar participants at the Ohio State University. Ithank Wonik Choi for his great support. All errors are mine.

    mailto:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]:[email protected]
  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    2/63

    2

    I. Introduction

    According to the Coase Theorem, when a firm goes into financial distress, parties can costlessly

    recontract and reemerge from distress without any real consequences. In the Coasian world, bargaining

    among parties will always lead to an efficient outcome. However, it is likely that in practice, the

    assumptions underlying the Coase Theorem do not hold. In practice, restructuring the liabilities of a

    distressed firm involves substantial costs, if it is even possible at all. Information asymmetries, different

    incentives, coordination problems between debt holders, illiquidity in both the markets for real and

    financial assets, together with a reluctance on the part of banks and public debt holders to accept equity

    for debt, all contribute to the difficulties that firms have reorganizing when in financial distress.3 In that

    sense, financial distress is a situation in which contracting problems cause deviations from first-best

    allocation of resources, creating real costs for the parties involved.

    These contracting difficulties present a market opportunity for an active investor, who can

    strategically choose to take positions in distressed companies for whom a restructuring would create

    efficiencies, facilitate these firms reorganization, and capture some of the rents arising from these

    efficiencies. Hedge funds, whose managers have strong performance-related incentives and a great

    degree of flexibility as to the securities they can hold, provide such a possible active investor. An

    individual with financial resources and a specialty in distress resolution can form a hedge fund, purchase

    securities that enable the investor to finesse the contractual problems preventing a profitable restructuring,

    and share in the efficiency rents from a successful restructuring. This paper argues that distress-oriented

    hedge funds are an institution that has evolved around these contracting difficulties, and that the returns to

    these hedge funds come from rents associated with the reorganization of economically sound but

    financially distressed firms.

    3 See, for example, Gertner and Scharfstein (1991), Shleifer and Vishny (1992), Giammarino (1989), James (1995),Bulow and Shoven (1978) for a theoretical discussion of the way in which these factors contribute to the costs ofresolving distress, and Jensen (1991) for the opposite Coasian view that distress is relatively costless. Amongempirical studies, Gilson (1997), James (1996), Asquith, Gertner, and Scharfstein (1994), Brown, James, andMooradian (1994), Pulvino (1998) provide evidence that these obstacles to bargaining generate real costs, whileAndrade and Kaplan (1998b, 1994a, and 1998) provide evidence that financial distress is relatively costless.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    3/63

    3

    This view of distress-oriented hedge funds contains a number of empirically-verifiable predictions.

    First, it predicts that the strategy executed by hedge funds will be the acquisition of positions that allow

    them to have the largest influence on the restructuring and to maximize the rents from successful

    reorganization. Institutionally, these positions are known as the fulcrum point, which is defined as the

    point in the capital structure where the enterprise value no longer fully covers the claim, and therefore is

    most likely to receive equity in the reorganized company. Second,firms targeted by hedge funds are those

    for which contracting problems are likely to prevent efficient reorganization. These firms are likely to be

    those with relatively high transaction costs and complicated capital structures made up of securities held

    by a number of different institutions with different incentives, but also those firms whose fundamental

    value is such that the firm will likely be profitable conditional on restructuring. Third, this view predicts

    that the presence of a hedge fund will affect the restructuring process and outcome positively. Hedge

    funds can facilitate the restructuring efforts by enhancing the use of flexible means of restructuring such

    as debt-equity swaps and pre-packaged filings. Also, reduced frictions in bargaining will lead to a faster

    restructuring as well as to a higher probability of a successful restructuring.

    I examine these hypotheses for a sample of 184 distressed firms which either restructured their debt

    privately out-of-court or formally under Chapter 11 for the period from 1998 to 2009. I find evidence that

    hedge funds actively participated in distressed-firm restructuring, suggesting that distressed investing has

    become an important avenue for activism by hedge funds. Based on information available in news

    reports, various documents filed to the U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), and bankruptcy

    documents, I identify hedge funds involvements in the troubled firms restructuring in 119 firms (64.7%

    of the sample). In extreme cases, hedge funds were involved in all distressed firms in my sample in year

    2006.

    Empirical findings are consistent with the predictions described above. First, hedge funds acquire the

    so-called fulcrum position to strategically obtain a measure of control over the course of a companys

    turnaround, and at the same time to seek upside potential in the reorganized firm via post-restructuring

    ownership.Hedge funds achieve this fulcrum position in various ways; they purchase fulcrum securities

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    4/63

    4

    in 69 cases (37.5% of the sample), inject new equity capital in 35 cases (19% of the sample), and pursue

    loan-to-own strategy in 32 cases (17.4% of the sample). Hedge funds often increase leverage to influence

    the restructuring process by taking a seat on the creditors committee (54 cases, 45.4% of the sample)

    and/or by leading negotiations of a pre-packaged deal (28 cases, 66.7% of all pre-packs). These positions

    vest hedge funds with 34.5% ownership on average in the reorganized firms.

    Second, I find that hedge funds target firms in which contracting problems are likely to be more

    severe but potential profitability is higher, if the firm is successfully restructured. Firms targeted by hedge

    funds have more debt classes than other similar firms and more often have both public and bank debt

    outstanding, both of which increase the difficulties of restructuring. Furthermore, target firms are more

    likely to suffer from an imminent liquidity crunch because they tend to have relatively high current debt

    due and low cash holdings. Target firms, however, do not seem to suffer from severe economic distress

    compared to non-targeted distressed firms and by industry standards. Target firms have had better

    operating performance than non-target firms and similar performance to the industry median firm in the

    years prior to distress. Such characteristics of target firms are consistent with the hypothesis that hedge

    funds capture some of the rents arising from the reorganization of economically sound but financially

    distressed firms.

    Third, evidence in this paper suggests that hedge funds can help facilitate reorganization. As

    creditors, hedge funds enhance the use of debt-equity swaps and pre-packaged deals. Meanwhile, by

    bringing fresh equity capital into a distressed firm, hedge funds facilitate the reorganization process. All

    types ofhedge funds investments, with the exception of the purchase of old equity securities, lead to a

    significantly higher probability of emergence from distress.

    Interpretation of the results about the hedge funds influence on the restructuring process and

    outcome is complicated because of selection bias. It is possible that hedge funds invest in firms that, even

    without their investment, would be more likely to swap debt into equity in the restructuring process, more

    likely to achieve faster resolution, and therefore more likely to emerge successfully from distress. I

    address this selection issue in three ways. First, I use an instrumental variable approach using one-year

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    5/63

    5

    lagged weighted average recovery rates on all defaulted debt as an instrument. Second, I estimate a

    selection model in which I use the residuals from regressions of the magnitude of hedge fund involvement

    on the determinants of involvement as the selection correction term. I also provide analyses of the impact

    of an unobservable confounding variable to present the severity of the potential omitted variable problem.

    The main results hold even after taking selection effects into account, and therefore it appears that results

    about the impact of hedge funds on the restructuring process and outcome are not purely driven by

    selection.

    Stock prices of the target firm move upward upon the announcement of hedge funds involvement,

    especially when hedge funds buy common stocks or bring new capital into the distressed firms. Average

    buy-and-hold abnormal stock returns (BHAR) for seven trading days around the announcement date are

    3.3%, while stock prices go up by 23.7% and by 12.7% when hedge funds inject new equity and purchase

    existing common stock, respectively.

    Hedge funds seem to make attractive profits by investing in distressed firms. Based on Lipper TASS

    data, distressed hedge funds in my sample produced a cumulative return of 151.2% from 1998 to 2009,

    while the overall hedge fund industry and the stock market produced 132.4% and 41.5%, respectively.

    Altogether, empirical evidence in this paper is consistent with the hypothesis that hedge funds capture

    rents they help create by helping distressed firms reorganize.

    This paper is closely related to the work of Hochkiss and Mooradian (1997) and Li, Jiang, and Wang

    (2010). Using a sample of 288 firms that defaulted on their public debt between 1980 and 1993, Hochkiss

    and Mooradian examine the role of vulture investors, who are predecessors of distress-oriented hedge

    funds, in the market for control of distressed firms. They primarily focus on the vultures governance-

    related roles, and find evidence suggesting that vulture investors can add value by reducing agency

    problems and disciplining managers of distressed firms. Li et al. (2010) is, to the best of my knowledge,

    the only study that sheds light on hedge funds presence in financially distressed firms using a recent

    sample. They primarily focus on the hedge funds role as an emerging force underlying the changing

    nature of Chapter 11 over the past decade. Using a sample of 474 Chapter 11 filings from 1996 to 2007,

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    6/63

    6

    they find that hedge funds play an active role in shaping bankruptcy outcomes, in terms of a higher

    probability of emergence, more frequent and larger deviations from the absolute priority rule (APR), more

    CEO turnovers, and more frequent adoptions of keep employee retention plans (KERP). This paper adds

    to the understanding of the nature of firms that are targeted by hedge funds and the nature of hedge funds

    strategy in distressed firms. Moreover, this paper provides new insight about the role that distress-

    oriented hedge funds can play in resolving contracting problems and facilitating reorganization of

    distressed firms. This paper also contributes to the growing literature on hedge fund activism by

    examining a different aspect of hedge fund activism executed in a different type of target firm. Evidence

    in this paper suggests that hedge fund activism is no longer confined to a companys shareholders but

    distressed-investing is an additional avenue for activism.

    The remainder of the paper proceeds in the following manner: Section II provides institutional

    background on the issues involved in resolving financial distress, the manner in which hedge funds are set

    up and operate, and the associated academic literature on each. Section III describes the manner in which

    I constructed my sample and collected data as well as the overview of the sample and hedge fund

    involvement. Section IV presents the empirical tests of my hypotheses. Section V presents an event study

    by examining buy-and-hold abnormal stock returns of target firms around the announcement date of

    hedge fund involvement. Section VI provides returns to distress-focused hedge funds. Section VII

    concludes.

    II. Institutional background and empirical predictions

    A. Contracting problems in resolving financial distress

    Coasian bargaining can fail because of a number of frictions. Major impediments to efficient

    bargaining documented in the previous literature include coordination problems between lenders,

    information asymmetries, conflicts of interest among parties involved, a reluctance on the part of lenders

    to accept equity for debt, and costs of selling assets.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    7/63

    7

    Bulow and Shoven (1978), and Giammarino (1989) demonstrate how information asymmetries and

    conflicts of interest among various claimholders can lead to inefficiencies when a firm is in financial

    distress. The impediment to efficient renegotiation in these models is the assumption that the firm cannot

    renegotiate with public debt holders, and banks or equity holders (or both) have the bankruptcy

    (liquidation) decision power and act in their own interest. In the Bulow and Shoven (1978) model, a firm

    can be forced into liquidation because information problems prevent it from raising necessary funds for

    continuation. Giammarino (1989) models the resolution of financial distress as a non-cooperative game of

    incomplete information played by a firm and its creditor. The bargaining problems occur because of

    information asymmetries between a firm and creditor, and such asymmetric information can lead creditors

    to choose to incur significant dead weight costs in the resolution of financial distress.

    Gertner and Scharfstein (1991) explain why investment inefficiencies still occur even when firms

    can renegotiate with public debt holders because of coordination problems among public debt holders.

    The inefficiency in the bargaining process arises because individual debt holders fail to take into account

    their effect on the firms investment decisions. In the Gertner and Scharfstein (1991) model, a firm has to

    offer more senior debt or cash to mitigate coordination problems; an offer of more junior debt or equity

    will not be accepted by creditors. Empirically, Asquith, Gertner, and Scharfstein (1994), Gilson (1997),

    and Gilson, John, and Lang (1990) use the number of debt classes as a proxy for the creditors

    coordination problem and document its importance in the outcome of debt restructuring.

    Given the difficulties of renegotiation with public debt holders due to the Trust Indenture Act and

    coordination problems, financially distressed firms can restructure their debt by persuading private

    (mostly institutional) lenders to swap their debt for stock or to forgive debt principal. However, several

    papers have documented institutional lenders reluctance to make either type of concession. James (1995)

    presents a model illustrating factors that influence a bank lenders incentive to scale down its debt. The

    model implies that, with public debt outstanding, a bank lender never takes equity in debt restructuring

    unless public debt holders also restructure their claims. In doing so, bank lenders sometimes forgo safe

    investment projects in favor of liquidation. Diamond (1993) and Gertner and Scharfstein (1991) argue

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    8/63

    8

    that because bank lenders are generally secured, they have little incentive to make concessions when a

    firm also has public debt outstanding. Gilson (1997) argues that regulatory restrictions on banks holding

    common stock limit the ability of banks to scale down their debt in distressed firms.4 In support of this

    view, it has been empirically documented that banks scarcely make concessions (Asquith et al (1994),

    James (1995)), but pressure a firm to sell assets to pay down their debt (Gilson (1990), Brown, James, and

    Mooradian (1994)).

    Selling assets under financial distress, however, can be quite costly if assets are sold at fire-sale

    prices. Shleifer and Vishny (1992) argue that when a firm in financial distress needs to sell assets, its

    industry peers are likely to be experiencing problems themselves, leading to asset sales at prices below

    value in best use. Pulvino (1998), using commercial aircraft transactions, provides empirical evidence that

    asset fire sales exist especially when a firm is capital constrained.

    B. Hedge funds investing in distressed firms

    Theoretically, the presence of active investors who are willing as well as able to finesse the above-

    mentioned contracting problems can enhance efficient bargaining in the resolution of financial distress.

    Hedge funds can be qualified to be such possible investors due to their nature and organizational

    structure.

    First, hedge funds are more motivated to make profits than any other institutions, which provide

    them with the willingness to get actively involved in a distressed situation in pursuit of upside potential.

    A hedge fund manager usually receives both a management fee and performance fee (also known as an

    incentive fee) from the fund. A typical manager charges fees of "2 and 20", which refers to a management

    fee of 2% of the fund's net asset value each year and a performance fee of 20% of the fund's profit. The

    range of performance fee is wide and can be well above 20%. For example, among hedge funds in my

    4 For example, the Glass-Steagall Act of 1933 and the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 restrict financialinstitutions from holding equity stakes in non-financial corporations. Also, risk-based regulatory capital guidelinesrequire banks to set aside more capital for riskier assets like stocks.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    9/63

    9

    sample, Steven Cohens SAC Capital Partners charges a performance fee as high as 50% .5 Such monetary

    compensation structure provides strong incentives to seek profit-making opportunities so hedge funds will

    actively and strategically choose to get involved. In contrast, many other institutions just do not have the

    proper incentives to deal with the procedural complexity and hassle associated with distressed debt

    restructuring. None of the traditional institutions, such as banks, insurance companies, and mutual funds,

    see gains generated from clearing inefficiencies in distressed situations as an integral part of their

    business success, and none of them pay their professionals incentive fees similar to the ones paid by

    hedge funds ((Kahan and Rock (2009)). When these institutions find their previous investments perform

    poorly, they have an incentive to cut their exposure to a risky firm rather than to stick with a firm hoping

    for uncertain upside potential. Even when they remain active in the restructuring process, their activism is

    more incidental and designed to recoup some of the losses rather than to make gains.

    Second, hedge funds have great amount of flexibility as to the securities they can hold and

    investments they can make. Such flexibility comes from several reasons. First of all, unlike conventional

    financial institutions, hedge funds are not burdened by regulatory schemes, oversight, or reporting

    requirements due to the fact that they open to only a limited range of accredited or qualified

    investors. For example, unlike other investment advisers, hedge funds do not have diversification

    requirements. This freedom from diversification requirements provides a great advantage to hedge funds

    since using an activist strategy in distressed firms requires taking a position meaningful enough to

    influence the restructuring process. Moreover, unlike other financial institutions, especially banks that are

    required to keep their balance sheet high quality and set aside additional capital for risky assets, hedge

    funds have no restriction on the riskiness of their portfolios. Second, hedge funds have higher risk

    tolerance, partly due to their inherently less risk-averse nature, and partly due to the freedom to use

    various hedging strategies, such as shorting securities or investing in derivatives. Third, distress-focused

    hedge funds are better equipped with a specialized skill set. Investing in distressed securities, especially

    as an activist, requires a highly specialized skill set; the sophistication to properly assess the value of a

    5 The Most Powerful Trader on Wall Street Youve Never Heard Of, Business Week, July 21, 2003.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    10/63

    10

    distressed company or its likely evolution through the restructuring process, strong negotiating skills,

    industry expertise, legal background, rich experience in the bankruptcy process, a large network, financial

    resources to acquire substantial amounts of claims, and so forth. Not many investors, even large

    institutional investors, meet such qualifications.

    Such flexibility of hedge funds gives them the ability, and the incentive schemes give them the

    willingness, to participate actively in debt renegotiation and to lessen contracting difficulties. The

    existence of such investors can mitigate coordination problems prevailing in distressed firms. In the

    extreme, in the Gertner and Scharfstein (1991) model, all inefficiencies are eliminated if a firm can

    directly bargain with a small number of public debt holders who take into account their effect on the

    firms investment decision. Hedge funds flexibility can also help a more flexible resolution take place.

    Many practitioners testify that hedge funds are more willing and able to take junior debt or even equity in

    exchange for debt claims than are other investors.6 Such flexibility regarding the distribution method may

    counterbalance traditional lenders strong preferences for debt or cash. Moreover, hedge funds can bring

    new capital that otherwise would not have been available. In an effort to obtain some measure of control

    or influence over a companys turnaround, hedge funds often make second-lien loans and even equity

    infusions. Such fresh capital can provide other resources beyond costly asset sales to be used to repay

    debt.

    C. Empirical predictions

    This view of distress-focused hedge funds contains a number of empirical predictions. First, it

    predicts that the investment strategy executed by hedge funds will be acquiring positions that allow them

    to have the largest influence on the restructuring and also to maximize the upside potential in the firm.

    Institutionally, these positions are known as fulcrum points. The fulcrum is the point in a companys

    capital structure at which its liabilities exceed its assets. Investors at the fulcrum point can have a bigger

    6 See, for example, When Hedge Funds Invest in Distressed Debt, New York Law Journal, October 15, 2007,Riding Fulcrum Seesaw: How Hedge Funds Will Change the Dynamics of Future Bankruptcies, The BankruptcyStrategist, October 2007.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    11/63

    11

    say over the negotiation and the formation of restructuring plans compared to more senior creditors who

    are deep in-the-money (they will be fully satisfied anyway) or more junior creditors and/or equity holders

    who are deep out-of-the money (they will have no significant power anyway). By acquiring the fulcrum

    position in a corporate capital structure, hedge funds can seek an opportunity to have a measure of control

    over the companys turnaround, and an opportunity to increase the upside potential in the firm. Therefore,

    empirically I expect to observe a widespread use of fulcrum investment strategies by hedge funds.

    Second, it predicts that hedge funds will target firms that are likely to suffer more severe contracting

    problems but whose fundamental value is such that the firm will be profitable conditional on

    restructuring. A firm is expected to suffer more contracting difficulties when it has a relatively

    complicated capital structure with many different classes of debt outstanding. In addition, the

    combination of secured bank debt and numerous public debt issues will impede successful restructurings

    even further (Asquith et al. (1994), James (1995), etc.) since the presence of public debt exacerbates the

    debt-overhang problem and therefore cuts banks incentive to engage in restructuring efforts. For

    example, Gertner and Scharfstein (1991) and Blow and Shoven (1978) theoretically show that banks will

    be less willing to extend the maturity of their debt or provide a new loan with public debt outstanding,

    since by doing so, the banks becomes effectively junior to public debt holders. Furthermore, banks have

    to share the rents arising from restructuring with public debt holders who contribute no efforts to facilitate

    the restructuring. Efficient bargaining is even harder when a firm faces a more imminent liquidity crisis,

    such as when a large portion of long-term debt liabilities are due but cash holdings are low. While hedge

    funds are expected to target firms with more contracting problems, they are also expected to target

    relatively economically sound firms to make their investment profitable. If this is so, we will observe that

    firms targeted by hedge funds exhibit sound operating performance prior to distress compared to non-

    targeted distressed firms and other industry peers.

    Third, it predicts that hedge funds presence will affect the restructuring process and outcome

    positively, at least to some extent. I consider the impact of hedge funds on the means, duration, and the

    likelihood of restructuring.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    12/63

    12

    Hedge funds flexibility can enhance the prospects of reorganization by enhancing the use of flexible

    means of restructuring. Such flexible means of restructuring can be efficient but are often thwarted by

    frictions to bargaining. This paper considers two such means of restructuring: debt-equity swaps and pre-

    packaged filings.

    Bryan (1984) describes debt-equity swaps as an innovative financing transaction and a solution to

    falling profits and debt-laden balance sheet. However, in practice debt-equity swaps face considerable

    friction, although they are not non-existent. First, debt-to-equity exchanges are hard to execute because of

    coordination problems among public debt holders. In extreme cases, as in the Gertner and Scharfstein

    (1991) model, an offer of equity for debt is not even feasible at all due to coordination and holdout

    problems among public debt holders. Negotiating with private lenders to swap their debt for stock is also

    not without frictions, given institutional lenders reluctance to receive equity instead of making

    concessions.7 Compared with traditional bank lenders, hedge funds are known to be more willing and able

    to accept equity or subordinated securities under a plan of reorganization. The presence of such flexible

    investors can enhance the use of debt-equity swap as a mean of debt restructuring.

    The second means of restructuring is pre-packaged filings. Several studies document that pre-

    packaged filings can be a quicker and more efficient alternative to formal Chapter 11 or to private

    workouts. For example, Tashjian, Lease, and McConnell (1996) claim that pre-packs can be a cheap and

    fast substitute for traditional Chapter 11 filings, as well as an inexpensive solution to free-rider/holdout

    problems in an out-of-court restructuring. Although pre-packs can significantly reduce the time that

    firms spend in court and obviate the need for costly creditors committees, in practice successful pre-

    packaged filings were extremely rare until the 1980s. 8 The major reason why pre-packs are hard to

    execute is difficulties in negotiation and bargaining. By nature, pre-packs require the presence of

    7 See, for example, Gilson (1997), Brown et al (1994), Asquith et al.(1994), Frank and Torous (1994), and James(1996).8 Gilson et al. (1990) find only one pre-packaged filing in their sample, and quote professional bankruptcyconsultants saying that only 5% to 10% of the largest bankruptcies begin as pre-packaged filings and fewer than halfof these are successful. The frequency of pre-packs has been growing since the late 1980s. For example, Tashijian etal (1996) find 49 pre-packs over the period of 1980-1993.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    13/63

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    14/63

    14

    process leads to an initial sample of 2,190 cases for 1,875 firms.9 This list is likely to contain a relatively

    large number of financially troubled firms. Second, I search Factiva news for reference to each firm, for a

    five-year period centered on the year(s) in which the firm was sampled to determine whether there was a

    default, bankruptcy filing, or attempt at debt restructuring to avoid such events. I supplemented Factiva

    with the Mergent Corporate Manual, S&P Market Insight, and Bankruptcy DataSource. This process

    leads to a sample of 815 cases of financial distress. Third, I restrict the sample to firms that are not

    missing 10-K filing at the fiscal year-end prior to distress, which reduces the sample to 658 cases. Fourth,

    I restrict the sample to large firms with total assets over $500 million to ensure that the search process can

    identify hedge fund involvement to a meaningful degree, resulting in a final sample of 220 cases, of

    which, 184 cases are complete by the end of 2009.

    The largest difficulty in selecting a sample of financially distressed firms following the above

    procedure is that, unlike Chapter 11 bankruptcy, there is no formal definition of debt restructuring and

    therefore one must determine the beginning and the end of such events. Following Gilson (1990) and

    Gilson et al. (1990) again, I define a debt restructuring as a transaction in which an existing debt contract

    is replaced by a new contract, with one of the following consequences: 1) required interest or principal

    payments on the debt are reduced; 2) the maturity of the debt is extended; or 3) creditors are given equity

    securities (common stock or securities convertible into common stock). Additionally, I also include new

    capital infusions (loans, equity investment, placement of new securities, etc.), into a distressed firm.

    Moreover, I require that the restructuring be undertaken in response to an anticipated or actual default, or

    to avoid bankruptcy. To ensure that, I require that restructuring transactions be accompanied with phrases

    such as going concern qualification, possibility of bankruptcy, looming bankruptcy, possible

    default, cash crunch, credit crunch, financially distressed, financial troubles, insufficient

    liquidity to repay debt, etc. What I do not include in my sample is mere covenant violations or actions

    taken to remedy such violations (e.g. giving waivers, amending credit agreement), although the

    restructuring process could have started from such events. This is to ensure that the sample includes only

    9 If a firm comes in in the bottom 5% stratum for two or more consecutive years, I count it as one observation.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    15/63

    15

    restructuring that is undertaken by a financially-distressed firm, since non-financially distressed firms also

    frequently violate covenants and restructure their debt quite often (Roberts and Sufi (2009), Nini, Smith,

    and Sufi (2009)).

    The following timeline illustrates the dating convention that I use:

    D represents the beginning of restructuring, which is the date on which a firm either filed for

    bankruptcy or starts to restructure its debt privately. A private debt restructuring is assumed to begin on

    the date it is first mentioned in Factiva news, unless an earlier date can be determined from other source

    documents. Beginning events include a bankruptcy filing or default concerns mentioned, going-concern

    qualifications, the downgrade of a credit rating that leads to a severe cash crunch, the hiring of an

    investment banker as a financial advisor to review financial restructuring, the initial announcement of a

    debt restructuring plan, and technical/payment default. If a firm restructures its debt through several

    transactions, I take them as a single restructuring if the next transaction occurs within one year of the

    previous one.

    R represents the resolution date. For Chapter 11, it is the date on which the firms reorganization

    plan becomes effective. For private restructuring, it is either the date on which a restructuring agreement

    is formally consummated or the date of the last reference in Factiva news, unless a more accurate date can

    be found from other sources.

    I determine the restructuring outcomes from Factiva searches, Lopuckis Bankruptcy Database, New

    Generation Researchs Bankruptcy DataSource, Mergent Corporate Manual, 10-K filings, and 8-K filings.

    If a troubled firm emerges from the distressed situation and continues to operate as a stand-alone

    company or as a subsidiary of an acquirer without losing its identity, it is considered successfully

    reorganized and Emerged. I consider a firm Acquired if it is acquired as a result of a bankruptcy plan

    or a private workout and assimilated into the acquirer. If a firm sold substantially all of its assets through

    Year

    DD-1 R R+1

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    16/63

    16

    363 sales, I also classify that as an acquisition. If an investor took a majority stake in a reorganized firm

    (like in buyouts) but the firm continues its business operations without losing its identity, then I dont

    classify that as an acquisition but as an emergence. If a distressed company ceased business and its assets

    were sold in a piecemeal fashion, or if a firm filed for Chapter 7, or if a case is converted to Chapter 7 or

    settled under the plan of liquidation within Chapter 11, I classify that as Liquidation.

    A2. Identifying hedge fund involvement

    To identify hedge fund involvement in distressed firms, I start by compiling a list of hedge fund

    managing firms that are known to be specialized in distressed investing. 10 I obtain 292 hedge fund

    managers from Altmans personal compilation (Altman (2007, 2008)), after screening out mutual funds

    and traditional investment banks. I add 70 from the constituents of the distressed hedge funds index

    constructed by HedgeFund.net. I additionally obtain 57 managers from DealScan and Preqin, by adding

    lenders (investors) whose identities are specified as distress-focused hedge funds or private equity firms.

    After eliminating overlapping managers, I have a list of 301 distress-oriented hedge fund managers.

    Second, I examined the sample of 184 financially distressed firms and identify hedge fund

    involvement by searching various sources including Factiva news, SEC filings, Bankruptcy DataSource

    from New Generation Research Inc., and bankruptcy documents such as plans of reorganization and

    disclosure statements over the period [D-1, R+1]. A hedge fund is considered actively involved in the

    restructuring process if one of the following criteria are met: 1) news stories describe the hedge funds

    involvement; 2) the hedge fund provides fresh capital, either equity or debt, to the target firm; 3) the

    hedge fund buys securities of the distressed firms during the period [D-1, R]. In the case of security

    purchases,I consider hedge funds activities to be involvements in the target firm only when hedge funds

    are believed to have stayed in the firm, at least partially, over the entire restructuring process. Therefore, I

    do not include cases in which hedge funds had built up positions earlier but liquidated later before the

    10In this study, I do not distinguish distress-focused private equity firms from hedge funds.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    17/63

    17

    restructuring took place. Also, mere trading or transfers of claims during distressed periods are not

    included since hedge funds can be in and out without any influence.

    I search for news stories about hedge funds involvement in the target firm from Factiva and Lexis-

    Nexis. Information on the new financing is obtained from Factiva news, DealScan, Loan Agreement

    filings or Material Contract filings to the SEC, and Mergent Corporate Manual. Information on the claim

    purchases is obtained from a variety of sources. Information on the claims holdings is from the news

    stories, SC-13Ds, 13Fs, N-30Ds (N-CSRs), 10-Ks, proxy statements, and the list of the largest unsecured

    creditors available from the Bankruptcy DataSource. I keep the dollar amount they paid to acquire such

    claims (or the market value of their holdings) whenever it is available from the news and the filings.

    Information on equity holdings is relatively straightforward to obtain, since hedge funds should file

    13Ds (for active investors) or 13Gs (for passive investors) if they acquire more than 5% of th e firms

    equity, and 13Fs if it exercises investment discretion over $100 million or more in 13F securities.11 I can

    also get information on equity interest from the firms 10-Ks or proxy statements.

    Information on debt holdings is more complicated to obtain, since hedge funds are barely required to

    file any documents when they acquire debt securities. Occasionally, news stories contain information

    about hedge funds debt holdings, especially if they are significantly large. If the debt securities acquired

    are on the list of 13(f) securities, they will show up in 13F filings. If a firm restructures its debt through

    the Chapter 11 process, more information is available since the firm makes the list of the largest

    unsecured creditors and their holdings, and reveals important investors holdings in court documents and

    disclosure statements. If the hedge fund received more than 5% equity interest in the reorganized firm

    over the course of restructuring, then the fund should file a 13D filing and I can obtain information on the

    original debt positions that vest the fund with such equity ownership from Item 3: Source and Amount of

    Funds or Other Consideration. Finally, if the hedge fund is a registered investor,12 it has to file N-30D

    11 13F securities are mostly equity securities, but also include some convertible bonds and notes. The official list of13(f) securities is published quarterly and is available for free on the SEC's website.12 Usually hedge funds are exempt from the registration requirements, but some register voluntarily. Also, inDecember 2004, the SEC adopted the new registration requirements that required most hedge fund advisers to

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    18/63

    18

    (N-CSR), a semi-annual shareholder report containing information about the funds portfolio and

    performance.

    A3. Other variables

    Other firm-level accounting data are from Compustat. Detailed information about a firms debt

    structure, including bank debt portion, the number of debt classes, and the existence of public debt is from

    the Mergent Corporate Manual. To determine if a bankruptcy is pre-packaged, I refer to Factiva,

    Bankruptcy DataSource, Lopuckis Bankruptcy Research Database, plans of reorganization, and

    disclosure statements. The weighted average recovery rate on defaulted debt is from Altman (2008).

    B. Overview of the sample firms and hedge fund involvement

    The sample studied in this paper consists of 184 large, 13 publicly traded US firms that either

    restructured their debt privately out-of-court or formally under Chapter 11 protection over 1998-2009.

    Panel A of Table 1 shows the distribution of distressed firms by year. The sample consists of 146 Chapter

    11 cases and 38 private workout cases. The annual distribution of distressed firms is consistent with the

    historical patterns of corporate defaults and bankruptcies. Observations are especially concentrated in the

    period from 2000 to 2002, when corporate accounting scandals and the dotcom bubbles yielded a record

    high corporate failure rate. By contrast, the number of observations is very small over the 2006-2007

    period, when the credit market was characterized by historically low default rates. The number of

    observations for year 2008 and 2009 is low, since many cases that began in 2008 and 2009 were still

    pending as of the end of 2009. Twenty six cases that occurred out in 2008 and 2009 are dropped from the

    final sample due to that reason. Panel B of Table 1 presents the summary statistics for the sample. The

    size of firms in my sample is much larger than those in other studies, due to the $500 million size cut-off

    register with the SEC by February 1, 2006 as investment advisers under the Investment Advisers Act, although inJune 2006, the U.S. Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia overturned it.13 Those firms contain total assets over $500 million prior to distress.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    19/63

    19

    restriction imposed on the sample construction. Other than the size, however, other firm characteristics

    are comparable to the sample characteristics of previous studies that examine financially distressed firms.

    The right three columns in Panel A of Table 1 show the annual distribution of hedge fund presence in

    the sample firms. It is evident in this panel that hedge funds have actively participated in the restructuring

    of large, publicly traded US firms during the past decade. Hedge funds have been actively involved in 119

    of the total 184 financially distressed firms (64.7% of the sample), suggesting that distressed investing has

    become an important avenue for activism by hedge funds. Hedge funds presence is observed more often

    in Chapter 11 cases than in private workouts; hedge funds were involved in 100 out of 146 Chapter 11

    cases (68.6% of all Chapter 11 cases), and in 19 out of 38 private workout cases (50% of all private

    workout cases). Table 2 presents a list of Top 20 players. Reorganization activities are highly

    concentrated among a small number of hedge funds; the ten most active hedge funds account for over

    30%, and the top 20 accounts for 45% of total involvement. It is consistent with the practitioners

    observation that, even among the universe of hedge funds, only very specialized and dedicated funds can

    and actually do use activist strategies in distressed firms, likely because of the high quantity of risk

    involved and specialized skills required.

    IV. Empirical results

    A. Characteristics of hedge funds investment strategy

    This section describes the characteristics of hedge funds investment strategies. Table 3 provides a

    detailed picture of hedge funds activities in distressed firms, and suggests the large evidence of a so-

    called fulcrum investment strategy executed by hedge funds. Hedge funds employ a fulcrum strategy in

    various ways.

    The most popular way hedge funds become involved in a distressed firm is to purchase existing

    securities that are most likely to be converted into interests in new equity - in practitioners words, the

    fulcrum securities. Hedge funds seem to be very good at determining which layer of a companys capital

    structure is the fulcrum security; hedge funds in my sample bought claims of a distressed firm in 95 cases

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    20/63

    20

    (51.6%), and more than 70% of the time ultimately received equity distributions. Hedge funds are not

    only good at picking a fulcrum security but also sometimes seem to take actions to make their holdings a

    fulcrum security. Even when hedge funds purchase secured debt such as bank debt, which is less likely to

    be swapped for equity due to its secured status, hedge funds received equity distribution for 69.6% of the

    purchases they made. Also, anecdotal evidence suggests that hedge funds often choose to receive equity

    in lieu of cash or new debt that other investors in the same class were to receive.14

    The next popular way to achieve a fulcrum position is to inject new equity into the distressed firm. In

    36 cases (19% of the sample), hedge funds made an equity infusion in various forms, such as right

    offering back-stops or plan sponsorships, which rendered them the reorganized debtors controlling

    stockholder with an average of 64.4% ownership.

    Third, hedge funds frequently use loan-to-own strategies, in which they make loans, typically senior

    secured ones, with the intention of acquiring an equity interest. A loan-to-own strategy is advantageous to

    an investor who wants to exert influence over the course of restructuring, because through the secured

    creditor position the investor can have significant leverage with respect to the negotiation and the ultimate

    formation of the restructuring plan.

    I classify a hedge fund as having executed the loan-to-own strategy if one of the following conditions

    is met: 1) the hedge fund made loans attached with some equity provisions, such as warrants or

    convertible provisions, 2) the hedge fund made loans accompanied by new equity investments, 3) the

    hedge fund made loans and at the same time held equity securities, such as common stocks or preferred

    stocks, 4) the hedge fund made loans and held debt securities that ended up receiving interests in new

    equity, 5) the hedge fund made loans and led pre-packaged filings to receive controlling shares.

    According to this definition of loan-to-own strategy, hedge funds executed a loan-to-own strategy in 31

    14 For example, ESL Investment acquired significant stakes (as high as 51% of the class) in various claims ofKmarts debt, including pre-petition loans, unsecured bonds, and trade claims. Besides the $200 million new equityinvestment, ELS also agreed to swap its holdings of Kmart debt for new Kmart stocks in lieu of the cash that theother members in that class were to receive. In the other extreme example, Elliott Management and Silver PointCapital purchased a large share of Delphi's debtor-in-possession financing in the secondary market, and forgavetheir loans (more than $3.4bill) in exchange for control of the company.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    21/63

    21

    cases (16.8% of the sample) in my sample, and ended up getting 58.1% equity ownership via such a

    strategy.

    Finally, hedge funds actively participate in pre-negotiations of the restructuring plan to achieve their

    goal. In my sample, hedge funds are actively involved in 31 out of 42 pre-packaged deals. Among those

    31 cases, hedge funds took a leading role in sculpting the restructuring plan or strongly supported the plan

    in all cases except for three (Finova, Conseco, Guilford Mills). In those three cases, hedge funds actually

    balked at the restructuring plan, which would have given controlling shares to other investor, had it gone

    through.

    Hedge funds often strengthen their position by serving on or forming by themselves a committee

    representing their interests. Moreover, unlike other money managers that are required to maintain

    diversified portfolios, hedge funds often take a large portion in a single firm. In my sample, when hedge

    funds purchase existing securities, the average holding is 27.7% of the class. Such highly concentrated

    positions give leverage to hedge funds in alchemizing their investments into a significant, even

    controlling, stake in a reorganized firm.

    In summary, the evidence in this section is consistent with the argument that hedge funds actively seek

    the fulcrum positions, which render them the largest influence on the restructuring and at the same time

    maximize their shares in efficiency rents arising from the successful restructuring.

    B. Characteristics of targeted firms

    This section examines the characteristics of firms that are targeted by hedge funds to see if hedge

    funds tend to invest in a firm that is expected to have more contracting difficulties but is economically

    healthier. To measure economic soundness, I consider a firms EBITDA prior to distress, which has been

    used in various forms by different studies.15 I employ positive (or negative) EBITDA as a categorical

    15 For example, Hotchkiss (1995) uses negative EBITDA prior to Chapter 11 filing as evidence of economic distress,while Andrade and Kaplan (1998) consider highly leveraged transactions (HLTs) not to be economically distressedbased on the above industry median EBITDA/Sales ratio, and Lemmon, Ma, and Tashjian (2009) employ the firmspre-bankruptcy industry-adjusted EBITDA/Total assets ratio as a proxy for viability as a going concern.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    22/63

    22

    variable, and industry-adjusted EBITDA/Total assets as a continuous variable. EBITDA normalized by

    total assets is preferred to EBITDA normalized by sales, since distressed firms often report a tiny sales

    volume, which leads to an extreme value of the EBITDA/Sales ratio.

    The first proxy I use for contracting difficulties is the number of long-term debt contracts, measured

    by the number of different headings in the long-term debt section of the Mergent Corporate Manual

    report. This measure is employed as a proxy for the degree of coordination problems and conflicts of

    differing incentives among debt holders by many previous studies including Gilson (1997), Gilson et al.

    (1990), and Asquith et al. (1994). The second measure of contracting difficulties is an indicator variable

    that takes a value of one if a firm has both bank and public debt outstanding and zero otherwise. This

    measure stems from the previous theoretical and empirical studies documenting that the combination of

    secured bank debt and numerous public debt issues makes restructuring bargaining harder, due to secured

    bank lenders reluctance to make concessions with public debt outstanding together with the generic

    difficulties of public debt restructuring (Asquith et al. (1994), James (1995), etc.). Finally, I construct a

    debt complexity by combining these two measures, which takes a value of one if the number of debt

    classes is above the median number in the sample and a firm has both bank and public debt outstanding.

    Table 4 provides a comparison of firm characteristics between targeted and non-targeted firms in

    univariate analyses. In terms of the size, two groups have no statistically significant difference. However,

    operating cash flow characteristics show a significant difference. Consistent with the prediction that

    hedge funds will choose economically healthier firms, the target firms show much better EBITDA

    profiles prior to distress; 26.3% more of the target companies generated positive operating cash flow, and

    the industry-adjusted operating cash flow ratio is 5.5% higher.

    Meanwhile, target firms seem to suffer from more contracting difficulties than other firms. Target

    firms have 2.5 more debt contracts on average and three more by median than the non-targeted firms.

    Also, 31.1% more of the target firms have both bank debt and public debt outstanding than non-targeted

    firms. Finally, targeted firms debt complexity is 21.9% higher than those of non-targeted firms.

    Moreover, target firms have much lower levels of cash holdings and higher (although statistically not

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    23/63

    23

    significant) levels of current debt due now, which implies a more imminent liquidity crunch. A more

    imminent liquidity crunch, together with more tangible assets and more bank debt, can lead to more costly

    asset fire sales. Such evidence is consistent with the prediction that hedge funds will target those firms in

    which contracting problems are larger.

    Table 5 examines the determinants of each type of hedge fund involvement to see if the predictions

    hold in multivariate tests. Overall, the results from multivariate analysis support the results from

    univariate analysis. Most hedge fund involvements are significantly positively associated with the

    measure of economic health.16 Also, debt complexity is significantly positively related to hedge funds

    presence on the debt side. Another noteworthy pattern is that hedge funds are more likely to use a pre-

    packaged filing but less likely to buy unsecured debt or equity securities when a firm has bigger current

    debt due, which suggests a more imminent liquidity crisis. This finding is plausible, since hedge funds

    would need quicker and more effective means of resolution when the problems are more impending.

    Coefficients on debt complexity, under-collateralized bank debt, and lagged recovery rate in Table 5

    suggest that hedge funds carefully choose their entry point to maximize the control over restructuring

    bargaining while paying as little as possible to obtain such control.

    Debt complexity is positively related to hedge funds involvement as creditors while negatively related

    to equity infusions by hedge funds. When debt structure is relatively complicated, a firm is likely to suffer

    from more contracting problems and the role of creditors becomes more essential to efficient bargaining.

    In such a case, it makes more sense for hedge funds to choose to be creditors than equity holders. When

    debt structure is relatively simple and differing incentives among debt holders is a not large problem,

    hedge funds can play a more important role by bringing in fresh equity capital.

    When bank debt is under-collateralized, measured by whether bank debt exceeds the value of fixed

    assets, hedge funds are more likely to choose secured claims. Under-collateralized bank debt implies that

    bank debt (which accounts for most of secured debt) is more likely to be impaired and therefore more

    16 The results using the indicator variable of positive EBITDA are reported in the table. When the industry-adjustedEBITDA/Total assets ratio is used, the results are the same.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    24/63

    24

    likely to be the fulcrum point. When secured bank debt is at risk of impairment, it provides an opportunity

    for hedge funds not only to acquire secured claims at discount prices but also to achieve a fulcrum

    position. Accordingly, we observe that under-collateralized bank debt increases the likelihood of hedge

    funds involvement as secured creditors. In contrast, hedge funds involvement as new equity providers is

    significantly negatively related to the under-collateralized bank debt. To the extent that banks rights are

    impaired and therefore banks have a bigger say at the bargaining table, the degree of control that hedge

    funds can enjoy as new equity providers will be reduced. Therefore hedge funds are less likely to choose

    to be equity investors in such cases. These findings correspond to Li et al. (2010), who find that hedge

    funds strategic choices of the entry point allow them to have a big impact on reorganization.

    Lagged recovery rate on defaulted debt is positively related to hedge funds presence on the debt side ,

    while negatively related to their presence on the equity side. The recovery rate on defaulted debt in the

    previous year would affect the price of defaulted debt in the following year. A high recovery rate on

    defaulted debt in the previous year is likely to boost overall demand for defaulted debt, which in turn will

    drive the price level up. A higher price of defaulted debt means less of an opportunity to purchase

    distressed debt at an attractive bargaining price. Then the equity side might provide a more profitable

    investment opportunity to distressed investors. Accordingly, we observe more investment on the equity

    side when the previous years recovery rate was high, or vice versa.

    In sum, the results in this section support the hypothesis that hedge funds strategically choose firms

    in which contracting problems are likely to prevent efficient reorganization but economic potential is

    substantial if successful restructuring could take place, thereby maximizing their influence on the

    restructuring process and the rents from reorganization.

    C. Impact on restructuring process and outcome

    C1. Means of restructuring

    This section investigates the relationship between hedge funds presence and the use of flexible

    means of restructuring. The first four columns of Table 6 show the results of probit estimation of the

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    25/63

    25

    likelihood of debt-equity-swap as a function of hedge fund presence, controlling for asset tangibility, cash

    holdings, leverage, having bank debt outstanding, under-collateralized bank debt, and pre-packaged

    filings. Tangibility is expected to decrease the information asymmetries regarding the firms true value

    and therefore increase the probability of using debt-equity swaps. Cash holdings are expected to be

    negatively associated with the likelihood of using debt-equity swaps, if cash provides an alternative

    distribution method to equity. Leverage is expected to be positively related with the likelihood of using

    debt-equity swaps, since high leverage signals the need to cut debt level. Having bank debt outstanding is

    expected to decrease the probability of using debt-equity swaps, if bank lenders are reluctant to receive

    equity. Having under-collateralized bank debt is expected to increase the use of debt-equity swaps if it

    implies the severity of financial distress to the degree that secured bank debts are at risk of impairment.

    Pre-packaged filings are expected to increase the likelihood of using debt-equity swap, since parties can

    customize distribution methods more flexibly through private negotiations before filing.

    Consistent with predictions, hedge funds involvement as creditors increases the probability of using

    a debt-equity swap by 28.2%, while new equity infusion by hedge funds decreases such probability by

    29.3%, all else equal. The associations are strongly significant at the 1% significance level. Hedge funds

    as old equity holders, however, are not significantly related to the probability of using debt-equity swaps.

    The fact that the likelihood of using debt-equity swaps varies significantly depending on the type of hedge

    fund involvement suggests that hedge funds play a considerable role in determining the means of

    restructuring.

    Table 7 presents probit estimates of the likelihood of pre-packaged filings. Following Chatterjee,

    Dhillon, Ramirez (1996), I control for the amount of current debt due, the amount of bank debt, debt

    complexity, and pre-distress operating performance. As predicted, hedge funds involvement is

    significantly positively related to the likelihood of pre-packs; the presence of a hedge fund increases the

    probability of pre-packs by 13.4%, all else equal. Such effects mostly come from hedge funds presence

    as creditors, supporting the hypothesis that hedge funds can have a role in resolving contracting problems

    among debt holders.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    26/63

    26

    C2. Duration of restructuring

    This section investigates if hedge funds presence is associated with a shorter or longer duration of

    distress. The first four columns of Table 8 report the base-case results from Poisson regressions of the

    duration of distress on hedge funds presence and other firm characteristics. The dependent variable is the

    number of months that elapsed from the onset of distress until resolution. I control for size, operating

    performance prior to distress, leverage, the number of debt classes, portion of bank debt, pre-packaged

    filings, and Chapter 11 filings. As expected, variables measuring the complexity of the bankruptcy case

    show significant effects. The number of debt contracts significantly extends a firms stay in the

    restructuring process. Restructuring under the formal Chapter 11 process takes longer than the private

    workouts due to procedural complexity and legal requirements. A pre-packaged filing has a significantly

    negative effect on the duration, again supporting that pre-packs can be fast and efficient means of

    restructuring.

    Overall, hedge funds presence neither lengthens nor shortens the duration of restructuring,

    controlling for the complexity of the case. Hedge funds presence as creditors is positively associated with

    the duration, but is not statistically significant. However, a new equity infusion by hedge funds is

    associated with a significantly shorter duration of restructuring. When hedge funds inject new equity,

    duration is shortened by 27.8% (1exp (-0.325)), which is significant at the 5% significance level. This

    value is also economically significant given that the average duration of firms without new equity

    infusion from hedge funds is 15 months. New financings, regardless of whether they come from hedge

    funds, will facilitate the restructuring process since a financially distressed firm desperately needs fresh

    capital. However, financially distressed firms often face serious challenges in obtaining financing, and

    hedge funds are likely to be the only kind of investors who are willing to make new equity investment in

    a troubled firm. Therefore, findings in this section suggest that hedge funds can help facilitate a distressed

    firms restructuring by supplying a firm with critically needed capital.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    27/63

    27

    C3. Likelihood of restructuring

    This section investigates the effect of hedge funds on the likelihood of restructuring. Table 9 shows

    in univariate tests that firms in which hedge funds are involved are significantly more likely to be

    successfully reorganized and emerge as a stand-alone company while significantly less likely to cease to

    exist as a business and be liquidated.

    The first four columns of Table 10 report the results from base-case probit regressions of the

    likelihood of restructuring on hedge funds presence and other firm characteristics. The dependent

    variable is an indicator variable that takes a value of one if a firm restructured its debt successfully and

    emerged from distress as a stand-alone company, and takes a value of zero if liquidated or acquired. The

    results in Table 10 show that all kinds of hedge fund presence, except holdings in old equity, lead to a

    significantly higher probability of emergence from distress. Overall, the probability of successful

    restructuring is 34.8% higher with hedge funds presence. Hedge funds presence as creditor and new

    equity investor increases the probability of emergence by 30.1% and 15%, respectively.

    One noteworthy fact from Table 10 is the significantly negative coefficients on the over-

    collateralized bank debt variable, an indicator variable that takes a value of one if the ratio of bank debt to

    fixed assets is less than one. A firm is more likely to be sold in a piece-meal fashion or to be sold to

    another company when bank debt (mostly secured) is over-collateralized. This result is consistent with

    previous studies that find Chapter 11 cases are more likely to result in a sale if secured lenders are over-

    secured (Ayotte and Morrison (2009)), and asset fire sales are often driven by over-secured lenders

    (Gilson (1990), Brown et al. (1994)). It makes an interesting contrast to hedge funds, since hedge funds

    presence is significantly positively related to more emergences, even when they are secured creditors

    (unreported).

    C4. Selection vs. Treatment

    A concern when interpreting the above estimates is that some potential unobservable confounding

    variables (omitted variables) affect both hedge fund involvement and the outcome variables. Because of

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    28/63

    28

    such a possibility, the observed significant relationship between hedge fund involvement and the outcome

    variables does not necessarily arise from hedge funds treatmenteffects on the outcome, but may arise

    from hedge funds selection of firms. Econometrically, selection bias can arise because the treatment was

    correlated with the error term in the outcome equation through the error terms of the selection equation. In

    other words, selection bias would occur ifiand i are correlated in the following system of equations:

    )3(00

    )2(01

    )1(

    *

    *

    iiii

    iiii

    iiii

    ZWW

    ZWW

    uWXY

    Yi denotes outcome variable, Xi denotes variables explaining outcomes, Wi is an indicator variable

    showing hedge fund involvement in firmi, and Zidenotes observable variables influencing hedge funds

    participation in firmi. Yi is observed only when hedge funds choose either to participate or not to

    participate, but not both. In this case, simple probit (or Poisson, in case of duration) estimates of will

    overestimate the treatment effect of hedge funds involvement.

    In this section, I try to address selection bias concerns in three ways. First, I use the instrumental

    variable (IV) approach to estimate average treatment effects of hedge fund involvement. Second, I use the

    control function approach using the magnitude of involvement as the dependent variable in the first stage.

    Third, I provide analyses of the impact of unobservable confounding variables to present the severity of a

    potential omitted variable problem.

    First, I estimate IV regressions using lagged recovery rate on defaulted debt as an instrument for

    hedge funds involvement.17 More precisely, I use the fitted probability of selection, i , as an IV, not a

    regressor.18 To get an IV estimator of average treatment effect (ATE), I do the following: First, I estimate

    17The markets weighted average recovery rate on defaulted debt in the previous year is expected to affect hedgefunds choice of participation (or choice of entry point) this year but is unlikely to affect specific firms restructuring

    outcome. Consistent with this prediction, we can observe coefficients on the lagged recovery in Table 5 aresignificant and have different signs for different type of hedge fund involvement.18 This is not the same as using i

    as a regressor like in the typical two-step IV estimation. The first stage, when

    i is used as an IV is 210

    iii xW . Using i

    as an IV, not a regressor, is recommended because (a) it is

    robust to having the model for ),1( zxWP wrong, (b) no need to account for generated instruments in standard

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    29/63

    29

    )1( ZWP for each type of hedge fund involvement using a probit regression and obtain the first stage

    fitted probability, )( ii Z . Next, I estimate

    )4(00 iiii uXWY

    by IV using instruments (1, i , xi), where the coefficient estimates ATE. To test the appropriateness of

    the instrument, I also provide selected diagnostic tests. For the under-identification test, I provide

    Kleibergen-Paap LM statistics, which provide a robust version of a test for the rank of matrix E(z'x). The

    null hypothesis is that the system of equations is under-identified. Kleibergen-Paap Wald F-statistics are

    provided for a weak instrument test. The null is weak instruments. In conjunction, Stock-Yogo critical

    values for the weak instrument test based on 10% maximal IV size are provided (at 5% significance

    level). Anderson-Rubin Wald 2-statistics are provided for a weak-instrument-robust test of the

    significance of endogenous regressor. The null is that endogenous regressor is insignificant in the main

    outcome equation. Lastly, I provide Anderson-Rubin Wald F-statistics for the test of endogeneity of the

    allegedly endogenous regressor. The null is exogeneity of the regressor being tested. IV estimation

    results are reported in the Column 5-8 of Table 6, 8, and 10.

    In the second way to address selection bias, I estimate a selection model. The remedy I use here is

    similar to the traditional Heckman estimation in the sense that I use residuals from the first stage selection

    equation as the selection control function term in the second stage estimation of the main outcome

    equation. However, unlike in the traditional Heckman model in which the first stage selection function is

    usually a binary response model, I utilize the fact that I can observe the magnitude of the hedge fund

    involvement. As a proxy for the magnitude of involvement, I use the dollar amount of investment when

    hedge funds inject new capital, and the amount of purchase as a percentage of the corresponding class

    when hedge funds buy existing securities. The availability of the magnitude of involvement is beneficial

    since it allows me to introduce an independent source of variation in the selection correction term, and

    errors, (c) estimator is efficient IV estimator if )(),( oo uVarzxuVar and probit model for Wis correct. For more

    explanation, see Wooldridge (2002, Chapter 6, 18)

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    30/63

    30

    thereby to work around the thorny near-multicollinearity issue of the Heckman estimation 19 . The

    procedural steps are as follows: In the first stage, I run regressions of the magnitude of hedge fund

    involvement on the observable determinants of involvements reported in Table 4 and obtain the residuals.

    Then in the second-stage outcome regressions, I use the residuals from the first stage as the selection

    correction term in lieu of the inverse Mills ratio. The results from the two-step selection model estimation

    are reported in the last three columns of Tables 6, 8, and 10.

    In the third way to address the concern about selection bias, instead of trying to estimate a selection-

    corrected estimator, I alternatively examine how large the endogeneity problem has to be in order to

    change a statistical inference. To do so, I analyze the potential impact of unobserved confounding

    variables using the approach in Frank (2000). This method is based on the notion that for an unobserved

    variable to affect the results it needs to be correlated with both the treatment variable and the outcome

    variable (controlling for the other variables). Frank (2000) derives the Impact Threshold for a

    Confounding Variable (ITCV), indicating the minimum impact of a confounding variable that would be

    needed to render the coefficient statistically insignificant. The ITCV is defined as the product of the

    correlation between the endogenous variable and the confounding variable ( rxcv) and the correlation

    between the outcome variable and the confounding variable (rycv). High ITCV means the OLS results are

    robust to omitted variable concerns. Table 11 presents the analysis of the impact of unobservable

    confounding variables. Columns 1 and 2 of each type of hedge fund involvement show the coefficients

    and t-statistics from OLS regression of the outcome variable on the corresponding type of involvement

    and other control variables.20 Column 3 of each type of hedge fund involvement provides the ITCV for

    the corresponding type of hedge fund involvement. To develop a benchmark for the size of likely

    correlations involving the unobserved confounding variable, in Column 4 of each type of hedge fund

    19 Strictly speaking, the model can be estimated even when there are no exclusion restrictions since Inverse MillsRatio (IMR) is non-linear functionZ. However, if IMR has very little variation relative to the remaining variables inthe main outcome regression, it is very possible that it becomes roughly linear in parts of its domain. Theidentification issue arises mainly because of the binary nature of the selection variable Wi, which implies that we donot observe the error term i and we must take its expectation, which is the IMR. For more explanation, see Li andPrabhala (2007).20I use OLS regressions as base-case regressions here, since ITCV can be calculated only for linear models.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    31/63

    31

    involvement I calculate the impact of the inclusion of each independent variable on the coefficient on the

    variable of interest. The impact is defined as the product of the partial correlation between the variable of

    interest (the potentially endogenous variable) and the control variable and the correlation between the

    outcome variable and the control variable (partialling out the effect of the other control variables).

    Column 5 of each type of involvement shows a more conservative measure of impact, the product of the

    simple correlation between the potential endogenous variable and the control variable and the simple

    correlation between the outcome variable and the control variable.

    Overall, the inferences from the base-case results hold even after trying different remedies for

    potential endogeneity concerns. Column 5-8 in Table 6 show that the same inference about the impact of

    hedge funds on the likelihood of debt-equity swap holds in the IV estimation; as in the base-case probit

    estimation, the coefficient is significantly positive for HF Creditorand significantly negative for HF

    Equity infusion. The diagnostics provided at the bottom of Column 5-8 suggest the validity of IV

    estimation. The last three columns of Table 6 provide the results from the selection model estimation, and

    restate the previous results. Regarding the severity of the potential endogeneity problem, the endogeneity

    test at the bottom of IV estimation and the coefficients on the residuals (selection control function) from

    the selection model estimation suggest that the potential endogeneity problem is not big. To be more

    conservative, I examine the impact of unobservable confounding variables presented in Panel A of Table

    11. ITCVs are fairly high for all types of hedge fund involvement. For example, ITCV is 0.213 for HF

    Creditor, implying that the correlation between HF Creditorand DEswap with the unobservable

    confounding variable each needs to be about 0.462(= 213.0 ) for the base-case result to be overturned.

    Columns 4-5 providesbenchmarks to determine how likely it is to have such a confounding variable. The

    variable with the largest impact on the coefficient for HF Creditoris Tangibility, with a value of 0.034.

    This suggests that we would need a confounding variable with a stronger impact than Tangibility to

    overturn the results on HF Creditor. Specifically, the unobserved confounding variable must be more

    highly correlated with HF Creditorand DEswap than Tangibility. Under the assumption that I have a

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    32/63

    32

    good set of control variables, this provides some confidence in the estimates of the effect of hedge fund

    involvement on the likelihood of debt-equity swap.

    Results in Table 8 and Panel B of Table 11 suggest that hedge funds presence as creditors is

    associated with a longer duration of distress once endogeneity concerns are taken into account. The

    coefficient on the residuals from the selection model and ITCV suggest that HF Creditoris endogenous,

    and the selection-corrected estimate of the effects of HF Creditoron duration becomes significantly

    positive. However, the impact of HF Equity infusion on duration is robust to potential endogeneity

    concerns. Consequently I can conclude that new equity capital injected by hedge funds help a firm

    emerge from distress more quickly.

    With regard to the impact of hedge funds on the likelihood of restructuring, results in Table 8 and

    Panel C of Table 11 show that the base-case results are robust to potential endogeneity concerns.

    Endogeneity tests from IV estimation, coefficients on the residuals from the selection model, and ITCV of

    HF Equity infusion in Table 11 suggest that the potential endogeneity of hedge fund involvement

    variables are not ignorable. However, the coefficients on HF Creditor are strongly significant even after

    corrections for selection bias. The coefficient on HF Equity infusion loses significance in IV estimation.

    However, the diagnostic implies that instruments are weak in the case of HF Equity infusion, so we

    cannot rely on the IV estimation results much. In selection model estimation, HF Equity infusion remains

    strongly significant.

    Based on the results in this section, our inference about the impact of hedge funds on the process and

    outcome of restructuring seems to be robust to endogeneity concerns, and it is hard to conclude that the

    relationships between hedge funds presence and the restructuring process and outcome are purely driven

    by selection effects.

    V. Event study

    This section presents an event study that analyzes the target firms buy-and-hold abnormal stock

    returns around the announcement of hedge fund involvement. Stock price data are from CRSP. I lose

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    33/63

    33

    some observations due to firms whose stock is delisted prior to hedge funds involvement. Also, I restrict

    the sample to clean events for which there is no concurrent news about bankruptcy filing or default

    during the event window, since such news is normally accompanied by a big drop in stock prices and

    therefore can mask the impact of an announcement of hedge fund involvement. This process produces a

    final sample of 75 firms for the event study. I calculate buy-and-hold abnormal stock returns (BHAR)

    following Barber and Lyon (1997);

    )5(])(1[]1[11 t

    it

    t

    it RERitBHAR

    , using a value-weighted market index as the expected return for each stock.

    Table 12 provides means and t-values of BHAR for [-3, +3] and [-1, +1] window around the

    announcement date. Overall, the announcements of hedge fund involvement in distress firms are

    accompanied by positive BHAR, although its significant only when hedge funds buy common stocks or

    bring new capital into firms. Figure 2 shows such patterns graphically. Around the announcement date,

    stock prices jump, especially when hedge funds inject new equity capital or buy common stocks. These

    results on the stock price reaction to the equity side investment are consistent with Hotchkiss and

    Mooradian (1997). However, unlike Hotchkiss and Mooradian (1997) and Jiang et al (2010) who find

    significantly positive stock price reaction to vultures (hedge funds) purchases of public debt, I do not

    find significant effect on hedge funds public debt purchases. This may be due to the small number of

    observations. However, actual stock prices do not need to react positively upon hedge funds debt

    purchase even though hedge funds add value to the restructuring process, given that debt securities held

    by hedge funds are oftenespecially in Chapter 11 - swapped for new equity and old common stocks are

    cancelled. If the market expects that hedge funds presence on the debt side would facilitate debt-equity

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    34/63

    34

    swap and that existing common stocks are likely to be cancelled in the course of restructuring, prices of

    the current stocks would rather move negatively on the announcement of debt purchases by hedge funds.

    VI. Returns to hedge funds

    In this section, I examine the returns to hedge funds on distressed investing. Figures 3 and 4 show

    the performances of the CSFB Distressed Index (solid black line), CSFB Hedge Fund Index (solid gray

    line), and S&P 500 Index (dotted gray line) over the period 1998-2009. Data are from Lipper TASS.

    Figure 3 tells us that while distressed hedge funds showed steady growth over the period 1998-2009, the

    significant growth of this hedge fund strategy occurred during the period from 2002 to 2007. Distressed

    hedge funds performed much better than the overall hedge fund industry and stock market during this

    period. Figure 4 shows that distressed hedge funds tend to outperform traditional investment vehicles,

    especially in bear markets such as the 2001-2002 and 2008-2009 periods.

    Table 13 shows the statistics underlying Figure 3 and 4. Column 1 shows reported returns of distress-

    oriented funds managed by hedge fund managers in my sample. Distress-oriented is defined as funds

    whose reported investment focus in TASS is either Bankruptcy, or Distressed bond, or Distressed

    market. Column 2 of Table 13 shows returns to CSFB Distressed Index, which represents the overall

    performance of hedge funds investing in distressed firms. Columns 3 and 4 provide performance of the

    overall hedge fund industry (represented by CSFB Hedge Fund Index) and of the stock market

    (represented by S&P 500 Index), respectively. Panel A provides overall risk and return characteristics,

    and Panel B provides annual returns from 1998 to 2009. According to Table 13, distress-focused hedge

    funds tend to deliver higher returns while maintaining better risk-return profiles: Both distressed funds in

    my sample and CSFB Distressed Index generated higher returns than aggregate hedge funds and the stock

    market while having lower volatility. As a result, distressed hedge funds exhibit much higher Sharpe

    ratios.

  • 8/8/2019 Jongha-Lim Paper Distressed

    35/63

    35

    The numbers in Figure 3, Figure 4, and Table 13 are based on returns to the entire fund, not deal-

    specific returns. They also contain returns to passive investing in distressed firms securities, whereas

    hedge funds in my sample are executing activist strategies. Returns to investment in a specific firm are

    not available from any commercial database. To get a sense of the deal-specific returns to hedge funds in

    my sample, I calculate hypothetical returns on investments made by hedge funds. I present returns on

    securities purchases, equity infusion, and debt financing separately. For securities purchases, returns on

    investment are calculated as the recovery rate for the corresponding class divided by purchase price

    (measured in cents on the dollar). Recovery rates are obtained from plans of reorganization. Purchase

    prices are collected from 13D, 13F, and N-30D (N-CSR) filings whenever available. When exact

    purchase price is not available, I assume that hedge funds bought securities at the market prices around

    the announcement date of hedge fund involvement. Market prices of securities are collected from

    TRACE, High Yield/Distressed Bank Loan Pricing, Trends and Prices of Leveraged Syndicated Loans,

    and Factiva news. Annualized returns are provided, assuming a two-year investment horizon. For new

    equity infusion, returns on investment are calculated as the reorganization equity value times equity

    shares received due to such equity infusion divided by the dollar amount of equity infusion. Again,

    annualized returns are provided, assuming a two-year investment horizon. For debt financing, spreads

    over LIBOR are provided as proxies for returns on investment. The hypothetical returns confirm that

    returns to distressed hedge funds are considerable. Among security purchases, public debt is the most

    popular as well as the most profitable choice. Equity infusions are not as frequently used as security

    purchases, but they provide the highest returns in my sample.

    Res