explaining policy bandwagons with markov models · potential! explanations! for! this!unbalanced...

41
"Explaining Policy Bandwagons with Markov models" Charlotte Jourdain 1 , Simon Hug and Frédéric Varone ECPR Joint Sessions Salamanca 2014, April 115 Workshop "Methodological Challenges and Contradictory Results in the Study of Interest Groups" Abstract: The distribution of lobbying activities across policy issues seems to be highly skewed: most issues attract very little attention from interest groups ("interest niches"); vice versa, very few issues attract much attention and lead to lobbying extravaganzas ("policy bandwagons"). What are the potential explanations for this unbalanced pattern of interest groups mobilization? This paper addresses this question by analyzing the bandwagons dynamics in four California policymaking processes: regulation of stem cell research, construction of the high speed rail, promotion of renewable energies and immigrants' access to higher education. It investigates interest groups mobilization in all the institutional venues (i.e. parliamentary, administrative, judicial and direct democracy) activated during a policymaking process. Using Markov transition models to grasp the policy bandwagons dynamics, this empirical study shows that mobilization in a particular venue is dependent on mobilization in preceding venues. Furthermore, these venues differ in terms of mobilization and continued mobilization. While the direct democracy venue is much more likely to bring IGs on the bandwagon, this venue is not quite as hospitable for continuing mobilization. Jumping on the bandwagon (or remaining there) depends on advancement through the policy making process. While the probability of mobilization over time increases slowly, the likelihood of staying on the bandwagon is higher both at the beginning and towards the end of the process. In addition, these differences are especially marked in the administrative and legislative venues. Also, we do not find any significant differences between business and occupational groups (i.e. sectional IGs) on the one hand, and the remaining types of groups (i.e. cause IGs) on the other in terms of their mobilization efforts. Finally, we find that following up on a direct democracy initiative increases the likelihood of mobilization, provided the next venue is not the judicial system. 1 Ch. Jourdain and F. Varone acknowledge the financial support of the Swiss National Science Foundation (funding of project 100017_149689). F. Varone is also grateful to the Center for the Study of Law and Society (CSLS) at UC Berkeley where he was a visiting scholar in 20122013. (Corresponding author: [email protected]).

Upload: truongcong

Post on 06-Sep-2018

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

   

"Explaining  Policy  Bandwagons  with  Markov  models"  

 

Charlotte  Jourdain1,  Simon  Hug  and  Frédéric  Varone  

 

ECPR  Joint  Sessions  -­‐  Salamanca  -­‐  2014,  April  1-­‐15  

Workshop  "Methodological  Challenges  and  Contradictory  Results  in  the  Study  of  Interest  Groups"  

 

Abstract:  The  distribution  of  lobbying  activities  across  policy  issues  seems  to  be  highly  skewed:  most  

issues  attract  very  little  attention  from  interest  groups  ("interest  niches");  vice  versa,  very  few  issues  

attract   much   attention   and   lead   to   lobbying   extravaganzas   ("policy   bandwagons").   What   are   the  

potential   explanations   for   this   unbalanced   pattern   of   interest   groups   mobilization?   This   paper  

addresses   this   question   by   analyzing   the   bandwagons   dynamics   in   four   California   policy-­‐making  

processes:   regulation   of   stem   cell   research,   construction   of   the   high   speed   rail,   promotion   of  

renewable   energies   and   immigrants'   access   to   higher   education.   It   investigates   interest   groups  

mobilization   in   all   the   institutional   venues   (i.e.   parliamentary,   administrative,   judicial   and   direct  

democracy)  activated  during  a  policy-­‐making  process.  Using  Markov   transition  models   to  grasp   the  

policy   bandwagons   dynamics,   this   empirical   study   shows   that  mobilization   in   a   particular   venue   is  

dependent   on   mobilization   in   preceding   venues.   Furthermore,   these   venues   differ   in   terms   of  

mobilization  and  continued  mobilization.  While   the  direct  democracy  venue   is  much  more   likely   to  

bring   IGs   on   the   bandwagon,   this   venue   is   not   quite   as   hospitable   for   continuing   mobilization.  

Jumping   on   the   bandwagon   (or   remaining   there)   depends   on   advancement   through   the   policy-­‐

making  process.  While   the  probability   of  mobilization  over   time   increases   slowly,   the   likelihood  of  

staying  on   the  bandwagon   is  higher  both  at   the  beginning  and   towards   the  end  of   the  process.   In  

addition,   these  differences  are  especially  marked   in  the  administrative  and   legislative  venues.  Also,  

we  do  not  find  any  significant  differences  between  business  and  occupational  groups  (i.e.  sectional  

IGs)  on  the  one  hand,  and  the  remaining  types  of  groups  (i.e.  cause  IGs)  on  the  other  in  terms  of  their  

mobilization  efforts.  Finally,  we  find  that  following  up  on  a  direct  democracy  initiative  increases  the  

likelihood  of  mobilization,  provided  the  next  venue  is  not  the  judicial  system.    

                                                                                                                         1  Ch.  Jourdain  and  F.  Varone  acknowledge  the  financial  support  of  the  Swiss  National  Science  Foundation  (funding  of  project  100017_149689).  F.  Varone  is  also  grateful  to  the  Center  for  the  Study  of  Law  and  Society  (CSLS)  at  UC  Berkeley  where  he  was  a  visiting  scholar  in  2012-­‐2013.  (Corresponding  author:  [email protected]).  

 

"Explaining  Policy  Bandwagons  with  Markov  models"  

 

1.  Introduction  

Frank  Baumgartner  &  Beth  Leech   (2001)  proposed   the  concept  of   “policy  bandwagons”   to   capture  

policy   issues   that   become   the   "object   of   veritable   lobbying   extravaganzas"   (Baumgartner  &   Leech  

2001:   1200).   These   authors   have   analyzed   more   than   19'000   lobbying   disclosure   reports   filed   by  

organized   interests   in   1996   at   the   US   federal   level.   Each   report   declares   the   lobbying   activities  

undertaken  by  an  interest  group  (IG)  to  influence  a  member  of  the  Congress,  his/her  staff  or  a  high-­‐

level  civil  servant.  The  distribution  of  these  lobbying  activities  across  a  random  selection  of  137  policy  

issues   shows   that  5%  of  all  policy   issues  attract  more   than  45%  of  all   lobbyists'  attention.   In   sharp  

contrast   to   these   "policy   bandwagons"   involving   hundreds   of   lobbyists   on   Capitol   Hill,   50%   of   all  

policy   issues   do   not   mobilize   more   than   3%   of   all   lobbying   activities.   IGs   that   are   active   in   such  

"interest  niches"  face  almost  no  rival.  

This  remarkably  skewed  distribution  of  lobbying  activities  is  also  observable  in  other  political  

systems.  For  instance,  Darren  Halpin  (2011)  replicated  the  US  study  by  mapping  the  mobilization  of  

IGs  during  1'691  public  consultations  organized  by  the  Scottish  government  from  1982  to  2007.  The  

180'000  responses   filed  by   IGs   to   these  official  consultations  about  draft  bills,   regulations,  national  

transposition   of   European   Union   directives   etc.   are   considered   functional   equivalents   to   the   US  

lobbying   disclosure   reports.   The   1'691   consultation   procedures   correspond   to   the   diverse   policy  

issues  at  stake.  The  distribution  of  responses  to  official  consultations  across  policy  issues  has  a  similar  

pattern  to  the  imbalance  previously  identified  by  the  US  scholars:  The  50%  of  issues  with  the  lowest  

mobilization   levels   accounts   for   about   5%   of   all   responses,   while   the   top   10%   of   issues   generate  

more  than  40%  of  all  consultation  activities  (Halpin  2011:201-­‐211).  Thus,  in  Scotland  too,  few  policy  

bandwagons  co-­‐exist  with  many  "quiet  corners".  

This   paper  builds  upon   these   findings   and   investigates   the   level   of   IGs  mobilization   in   four  

California  policy-­‐making  processes.  The  first  objective  is  to  empirically  measure  IG  mobilization  levels  

and  to  locate  them,  for  each  of  the  four  policy  issues,  on  a  continuum  ranging  from  "interest  niches"  

to  "policy  bandwagons".  This  study  also  aims  at  identifying  the  dynamics  underlying  the  (more  or  less  

extravagant)   mobilization   of   IGs   across   policy   sectors.   In   sharp   contrast   to   the   previous   studies  

focusing   on   IGs   mobilization   in   one   single   institutional   venue   (i.e.   the   legislative   venue   in  

Baumgartner  &  Leech  2001;  the  executive  venue   in  Halpin  2011),  the  present   investigation   is  more  

encompassing.   It  considers  simultaneously  all   institutional  venues  activated  by   IGs  during  an  entire  

   

policy-­‐making  process.  To  influence  successive  policy  decisions,  an  IG  can  lobby  the  Parliament  (law-­‐

making)  and/or  the  Executive  (rule-­‐making);  it  can  also  bring  a  case  to  a  Judicial  Court  (litigation);  or  

it  can  launch  a  Popular  Initiative,  as  the  California  political  system  provides  for  this  direct-­‐democracy  

instrument.  The  first  innovation  of  this  paper  is  thus  to  grasp  (potential)  policy  bandwagon  dynamics  

across  the  successive  steps  of  a  policy-­‐making  process.  This  study  has  a  second  value  added  to  the  

existing   literature,   as   it   gathers   new   empirical   material   through   the   comparative   analysis   of   four  

California   case   studies:   the   regulation   of   human   embryonic   stem   cell   research   (STEM);   the  

construction   of   the   California   High   Speed   Rail   running   from   Sacramento   to   San   Diego   (HSR);   the  

Renewable   Portfolio   Standards  which   are   obligations   on   electricity   retail   sellers   to   include   in   their  

portfolios  a  certain  amount  of  electricity  from  renewable  energy  sources  (RPS);  and  access  to  state-­‐

funded  financial  aid  for  higher  education  to  children  who  were  brought  to  the  United  States  illegally  

before   the   age   of   16   (IMMIG).   Last   but   not   least,   the   methodology   applied   to   capture   IGs  

mobilization   relies   on   Markov   transition   models   and,   to   the   best   of   our   knowledge,   is   rather  

uncommon  within  the  IGs  literature.  The  third  contribution  of  this  study  is  thus  to  offer  a  first  step  in  

the  direction  of   Jones  and  Baumgartner's   (2005:142)  recommendation  to  rely  on  Markov  switching  

models  for  grasping  the  consequences  of  attention  cascades  among  policy  actors,  mimicry  and  other  

self-­‐reinforcing  processes  that  eventually  translate  into  the  emergence  of  policy  bandwagons.  

The   paper   is   structured   as   follows:   Section   2   explains   the   theoretical   framework   and  

expectations   regarding   policy   bandwagon   dynamics.   The   description   of   the   four   scrutinized   cases  

studies   follows.   Section   4   presents   descriptive   statistics   as   the   first   step   to   test   the   theoretical  

hypotheses.  The  Markov  transition  models  are  then  introduced  and  the  results  of  the  global  model  

are   commented.   After   summarizing   the   main   findings,   the   concluding   section   put   them   into  

perspective.  

 

2.  Theoretical  framework  

If   the   skewed   pattern   of   IGs   mobilization   is   observable   in   different   institutional   venues,   political  

systems  and   time  periods,  what   are   the  potential   explanations  of   this  phenomenon?  Baumgartner  

and  Leech   (2001)  mention   first   the  size  and  scope  of   the  policy   issue:   "issues  costing  more  money,  

involving   a   greater   departure   from   status   quo,   and   affecting   more   people   will   attract   more  

attention"(2001:  1205).  Second,   the  conflict  expansion  strategy   (Schattschneider  1960)   followed  by  

some   interest   groups   is   an   alternative   explanation.   As   some   first-­‐movers  mobilize   to   put   an   issue  

(high)  on  the  agenda,  the  level  of  visibility  of  this  policy  issue  increases  and  induces  the  followers  to  

enter  the  political  debate.  These   late-­‐comers  monitor  what  other  organized   interests  do,   take  cues  

 

from  the  lobbying  behavior  of  others  and,  eventually,   imitate  them.  Mimicry  and  attention  cascade  

are   by   definition   self-­‐reinforcing   processes,   based   on   positive   feedbacks,   and   translate   into   the  

emergence  of  a  policy  bandwagon  (2001:  1206;  see  also  Jones  &  Baumgartner  2005:140-­‐142).  

While   Baumgartner   and   Leech   do   not   systematically   test   these   two   research   hypotheses,  

Halpin   (2011)   demonstrates   that   the   size   and   scope   hypothesis   is   inaccurate.   The   number   of  

invitations   to  answer  a   consultation,   the   level  of  government  expenditures   concerned  by   the   issue  

submitted  to  consultation,  and  the  stage  of  this  issue  in  the  policy  cycle  (i.e.  three  indicators  for  the  

scope  and  size  of  the  issue)  do  not  explain  the  response  rates  to  the  governmental  consultations  in  

the   Scottish   context.   Therefore,   to   understand   bandwagons   dynamics,   Halpin   (2011)   further  

differentiates  the  mimicking  and  attention  cascade  hypothesis.  Concretely,  he  identifies  four  agents  

who  shape  policy  attention  and  potentially   contribute   to  cascades.   (1)  Media   can  be  cue  givers,  at  

least  for  individuals  and  IGs  that  are  not  specialized  in  the  policy  issue  at  stake.  (2)  Keystone  groups  

(i.e.  umbrella  or  peak  groups,  but  also  informal  coalition  of  interest  groups)  may  foster  the  attention  

of   organized   interest   towards   an   issue.   However,   it   is   worth   noting   that   such   keystone   groups  

potentially   play   two   opposite   roles:   either   they   aggregate   the   lobbying   activities   of   their  

organizational  members,  act  as  a  sponge  and  thus  slow  down  or  even  hinder  the  policy  bandwagons  

chain-­‐reaction;  or,  on  the  contrary,  they  stimulate  the  active  mobilization  of  their  members  and,   in  

doing  so,  accelerate  and  amplify  the  cascade  process.  (3)  Mass-­‐members  campaign  groups  can  also  

work  as  amplifiers  by  asking  their   individual  members  to  send  (amended)  standard  letters  to  policy  

makers.  Grassroots  mobilization  is  one  mechanism  underlying  the  emergence  of  policy  bandwagons.  

(4)   Finally,  civil   servants   themselves  may   foster   advocacy  activities  by   interest   groups,   for   instance  

during   the   pre-­‐parliamentary   consultation   or   rule-­‐making   procedures.   Promoting   the   feedbacks   of  

many  organized  interests   is  an  appealing  strategy  to  public  servants   in  order  to  assess  the  practical  

feasibility  and  political  acceptability  of  their  policy  proposal.  In  addition,  this  also  allows  for  reducing  

the  strong  pressure,  "clientelistic"  relationships  or  even  the  capture  of  a  public  administration  unit  by  

some   powerful   lobbies.   While   all   these   mechanisms   seem   plausible,   Halpin   (2011)   unfortunately  

does  not  test  their  respective  empirical  validity  for  the  Scottish  governmental  consultations.  

According   to   this   very   brief   literature   review,   no   strong   and   conclusive   empirical   evidence  

exists   about   the   hypotheses   formulated   so   far.   In   addition,   the   theoretical   expectations   remain  

rather   vague.   For   instance,   they   are   not   calibrated   at   all   to   address   the   (potentially   different)  

dynamics  of  policy  bandwagons   in  various   institutional  venues   in  which   IGs  mobilize.  Facing  such  a  

knowledge   gap,   this   paper   proposes   three   research   hypotheses   regarding   the   level   of   IGs  

mobilization   in  different  venues  and,   furthermore,  explanatory   factors   for   the  emergence  of  policy  

bandwagons  dynamics.  

   

The   first   expectation   concerns   the   differentiated   levels   of   bandwagons   that   should   be  

observed  in  alternative  institutional  venues.  It  reads  as  follows:  the  mobilization  of  interest  groups  

and   the   policy   bandwagons   dynamics   are   stronger   in   the   direct   democracy   venue   than   in   the  

administrative  and  parliamentary  venues  and,  finally,  in  the  judicial  venue  (hypothesis  1).  

Several   arguments   support   this   expectation.   First,   the   four  mechanisms   defined   by   Halpin  

(2011,  see  above)  to  explain  policy  bandwagons  are  not  all  at  work  in  all  venues,  at  least  not  to  the  

same  extent.  They  are  obviously   less  prevalent   in   the   judicial   venue,  as   the  access   to   the  courts   is  

strongly   regulated   by   formal   rules   defining   who   has   standing   (“justiciability”)   to   be   a  

plaintiff/defendant,   who   can   introduce   an   amicus   brief,   etc.   The   direct   impacts   of  mass  media   or  

members'   campaign   are   thus   probably   limited   in   the   judicial   venue.   By   contrast,   these   factors   are  

absolutely   decisive   in   the   direct   democratic   venue.  Media   attention   and   demonstrative   actions   by  

mass  members  IGs  are  at  the  very  heart  of  every  voting  campaign.  For  what  concerns  the  two  other  

venues,   the   access   rules   regarding   rule-­‐making   procedure   and   parliamentary   lobbying   –   i.e.  

disclosure   report   –   are   apparently   stricter   than   the   conditions   to   be   fulfilled   for   contributing  

financially  to  a  ballot  campaign  coalition.  In  one  word,  the  mobilization  of  IGs  is  more  or  less  strongly  

constrained  by  formal  rules  depending  upon  the  institutional  venue.  

A  second  argument  is  related  to  the  initial  resources  (e.g.  money,  expertise,  manpower,  etc.)  

necessary  to  fully  engage  in  specific  advocacy  activities  (Walker  1991,  Heinz  et  al.  1993,  Baumgartner  

and  Leech  1998  and  2001,  Beyers  2008,  etc.)  It  has  been  argued  that  the  advocacy  costs  are  lower  for  

lobbying   than   for   litigation;   this   seems   to   hold   true   even   for   business   groups   (i.e.   IGs   with   the  

presumably   highest   resource   endowment)   that   choose   lobbying   the   Parliament   or   the  

Government/Administration  more  frequently  than  litigation  (Bouwen  and  McCown  2007).  One  could  

thus  expect  that  IGs  display  a  higher  level  of  mobilization  in  venues  characterized  by  lower  advocacy  

costs.  As  a  matter  fact,  it  is  quite  easy  to  spend  500  US  $  for  a  voting  campaign,  but  more  challenging  

to  hire  a  lobby  firm  to  influence  law-­‐  or  rule-­‐making  procedure  and,  even  more  costly  to  have  either  

an  in-­‐house  counsel  or  to  hire  an  attorney  in  order  to  become  a  party  in  a  judicial  suit  or,  at  least,  to  

introduce  an  amicus  brief.  

In  addition  to  this  classical  “resources  count”  argument,  litigation  is  also  frequently  perceived  

as  the  weapon  of  the  weakest  IGs  according  to  the  seminal  "political  disadvantage"  theory  (Cortner  

1968:   287).   Bringing   a   case   to   the   court   is   a   fall   back   option   used   only   if   the   IG   has   no   privileged  

access   to  Congress,  Governor  or   rule-­‐making  Agencies.  Outsider   IGs  will  engage   in   litigation   if   they  

have   no   best   alternative   venue   or   when   everything   else   has   already   failed.   However,   it   is   worth  

noting   that   this   argument   has   been   recurrently   invalidated   by   empirical   studies,   in   various  

 

institutional  setting  (e.g.  Olson  1990;  Hansford  2004;  Binderkrantz  2005;  Kriesi  et  al.  2007).  Some  of  

these  studies   rather  concluded  that  all   IGs  use  the   litigation  strategy,  not  only   the  weakest  one.   In  

any   case,   and   even   if   this   strategy   is   used   by   (potentially)   all   IGs,   we   do   not   expect   to   observe  

bandwagons  dynamics  in  the  judicial  venue  as  the  formal  access  rules  and  advocacy  costs  represents  

important  barriers  here.  

Finally,   while   only   few   studies   compare   advocacy   activities   by   IGs   across   several   venues,  

some   interesting   –   but   partial   –   results   tend   to   support   the   first   hypothesis   proposed   here.   For  

instance,   a   similar   level   of   IGs   mobilization   and   dynamic   of   policy   bandwagon   is   expected   in   the  

parliamentary  and  in  the  governmental/administrative  venues:  Boehmke  et  al.  (2013)  have  recently  

demonstrated  that  the  level  of  IGs  lobbying  in  one  of  these  two  venues  is  strongly  related  to  its  level  

in  the  other  venue.  These  authors  came  to  this  conclusion  after  having  analyzed  the  lobbying  reports  

filled   by   IGs   in   the   State   of   Minnesota   and   at   US   federal   level.   Their   empirical   findings   are   also  

congruent   with   previous   studies   based   on   survey   data   (i.e.   advocacy   activities   self-­‐reported   by  

lobbyists   and   IG   leaders)   showing   that   the  most   important   venues   for   IGs   are   the   Legislature,   the  

Governor   and   Executive   agencies,   while   the   Courts   tend   to   play   a   marginal   role   (Nownes   and  

Freeman  1998;  McKay  2011).  

The   second   expectation   relates   to   the   successive   phases   of   the   policy-­‐making   process   (in  

addition  to  the  type  of  institutional  venues  activated,  as  addressed  by  the  first  hypothesis).  It  claims  

that  the  mobilization  of  interest  groups  and  the  policy  bandwagons  dynamics  are  stronger  towards  

the  end  than  at  the  beginning  of  the  policy-­‐making  process  (hypothesis  2).  

A   double   logic   of   policy   influence   and  membership   (as   proposed  by   Schmitter   and   Streeck  

1999)   characterizes   the   strategic   behavior   of   IGs   involved   in   a   policy-­‐making   process.   The  

implementation  of  this  dual  strategy  by  IGs  is  the  main  rationale  for  the  second  hypothesis.  On  one  

hand,   if   an   IG  mobilizes   during   the   initial   or   early   stages   of   the   policy   process   and   unfortunately  

looses,   then   this   IG   will   not   "give   up"   the   policy   battle   afterwards.   On   the   contrary,   the   IG   will  

probably  follow  the  issue  across  the  different  steps  of  the  policy  cycle  (i.e.  within  the  same  venue  or  

across   different   venues,   depending   upon   the   evolution   of   the   policy   process   itself),   as   long   as   it  

cannot  realize   its  preferred  outcome.  The  same  strategic  behavior  should  also  be  observed   if  an   IG  

wins  a  first  policy  battle  during  the  initial  policy  step:  in  order  to  concretize  the  substantive  content  

of   the  policy   and,   furthermore,   to   avoid  a  major  policy   change,   the   IG   stays  mobilized  and  acts   as  

repeat  player.  

   

For   instance   the   winners   of   a   direct   democracy   ballot   (i.e.   legislative   or   constitutional  

initiative)  want  to  avoid  that  their  opponents  "steal"  their  initiative  through  a  judicial  review  process  

(Gerber  et  al.  2001).  As  a  matter  of  fact,  the  judicial  review  of  voter-­‐approved  initiative  is  very  high  in  

California   (Miller   2009:104ff):   Opponents   challenged   about   69%   of   all   accepted   initiatives   and  

(mainly  state)  courts   invalidated  about  38%  of   these   initiatives   from  1970  to  1990.  Going  one  step  

further,  the  joint  application  of  the  first  and  second  hypotheses  to  the  direct  democracy  and  judicial  

venues  leads  to  the  formulation  of  the  following  hypothesis:  the  mobilization  of  interest  groups  and  

the   policy   bandwagons   dynamics   are   stronger   if   the   judicial   venue   follows   directly   the   direct  

democracy  venue  in  the  policy-­‐making  process  (Hypothesis  2  bis).  

The   logic   of   policy   influence   is   highly   plausible   -­‐   for   both   losers   and  winners   -­‐   even   if   the  

policy  issue  at  stake  moves  from  one  institutional  venue  (e.g.   law-­‐making  in  Legislature)  to  another  

venue  (e.g.  veto  by  Governor  and  then  rule-­‐making  by  Agencies).  As  a  matter  of  fact,  most  IGs  do  not  

specialize   in   one   specific   venue   but   use   complementary   strategies   along   the   policy   process,  

alternating  for  instance  cooperative  and  confrontational  advocacy  activities  (Binderkrantz  2005).  

On   the   other   hand,   the   logic   of   membership   is   also   a   strong   impetus   for   IGs   to   closely  

monitor   the  entire  policy-­‐making  process.  To  secure  the  survival,  maintenance  or   reinforcement  of  

its   own   organization   (e.g.   membership,   financial   resources,   reputation,   etc.),   an   IG   has   to  

demonstrate   to   its   (potential)  members   that   it   is   resilient  warrior   and   repeat   player   (Olson   1990;  

Solberg   and  Waltenburg   2006;   Lowery   2007).   Faced  with   competition   for  members,   an   IG   has   an  

incentive   to  mobilize   in   all   venues   (in  which  opposing  or   competing   IGs  are  mobilized   too),   or   risk  

loosing  members  and  the  ability  to  attract  potential  ones.  This   leads  to  a  high  mobilization  of  most  

IGs,  even  if  their  advocacy  activities  have  no  real  chance  of  success  and  are  purely  symbolic  (Holyoke  

2003).  In  addition,  a  third  "logic  of  reputation"  could  also  be  a  strong  incentive  for  IGs  to  be  active  in  

institutional  venue  with  high  media  coverage  (Berkhout  2013).  All   in  all,  once  they  enter  the  policy  

battleground,   IGs   do   not   leave   it   easily   and,   as   the   number   of   IGs  mobilized   gradually   cumulates  

along  the  successive  of  stages  policy  cycle,  then  the   logical  consequence   is  that  policy  bandwagons  

shall  be  rather  observed  towards  the  end  of  the  policy  process2.  

The  third  hypothesis  focuses  neither  on  the  type  of   institutional  venue,  nor  on  the  stage  of  

the  policy  cycle,  but  on  the  type  of  Interest  groups.   It  claims  that  sectional  IGs  mobilize  more  than  

                                                                                                                         2  Note  that  the  logic  of  policy  influence  applies  to  all  types  of  IGs,  but  that  the  logic  of  membership  applies  to  all  IGs  except  business.  For  this  category,  the  logic  of  membership  applies  to  peak-­‐level,  sector-­‐wide  and  technical  associations  but  not  to  individual  firms.  It’s  of  course  hard  to  say  which  of  the  two  logics  (influence  or  membership)  has  the  strongest  effect.    

 

cause   IGs   over   the   whole   policy   process   and   thus   contribute   more   to   the   dynamics   of   policy  

bandwagons  (hypothesis  3).  

Using  a  categorization  of  IGs  initially  developed  by  Scholzman  et  al.  (2008)  and  then  adapted  

by  the  Interarena  (A.  Binderkrantz,  Aahrus)  and  Intereuro  (J.  Beyers,  Antwerp)  projects,  the  present  

study   distinguishes   between   business   associations,   occupational   groups,   unions,   public   interest  

groups,  identity  groups,  religious  groups  and  institutional  groups  (i.e.  public  authorities  as  members).  

These  seven  categories  are  then  aggregated  in  two  broader  types  of  IGs:  Business  and  occupational  

interests   are   defined   as   "sectional   IGs",   while   all   other   categories   merge   into   the   type   "cause  

groups".  This  aggregation  (based  on  Stewart   typology  1958;  see  also  Klüver  2013,  Klüver  and  Giger  

2014)  makes   sense  as   sectional   groups  aim  at   represent   the   interest  of   a   very   specific   segment  of  

society   (i.e.   business,   professionals)   and   delivering   private   goods   to   their   members,   while   cause  

groups  are  open  to  anyone  and  fight  for  public  goods  (e.g.  human  rights,  environmental  protection,  

etc.)  or  principle  (i.e.  union  advocating  for  fair  wages  and  safe  working  conditions).  Furthermore,  we  

expect  different  behavior  for  these  two  types  of  IGs.  

Sectional   IGs  are  expected  to  be  strongly  mobilized  and  to  significantly  contribute  to  policy  

bandwagons.  This  is  due,  first,  to  the  goals  they  pursue,  namely  the  provision  of  private  benefits  for  

their  own  members.  Examples  from  the  case  studies   investigated  here  include  research  funding  for  

universities   working   on   stem   cells,   new  market   share   for   the   private   firms   constructing   the   High  

Speed   Rail,   State   support   for   the   producers   of   renewable   energies,   etc.   They   face   thus   no  major  

problem  of  collective  action.  Second,  most  of  these  IGs  are  de  facto  peak  associations  or  sector-­‐wide  

associations   at   least.   In   line  with   the   argument  developed  by  Halpin   (2011),   such   keystone   groups  

should   stimulate   the   active   mobilization   of   their   individual   members   and,   thus,   sustain   the  

mobilization   cascade.   Third,   these   IGs   absolutely   need   to   mobilize   in   order   to   promote   a   policy  

change   that   will   translate   into   material   rewards   for   themselves.   Baumgartner   et   al.   (2009:113)  

showed  that  there  is  generally  a  strong  inertia  towards  the  status  quo  (i.e.  no  stem  cell  research,  no  

high   speed   rail,   no   increase  of   renewable  energies  etc.)   and   that  pro   change   IGs   shall   invest  more  

resource   to  overcome   the  bias   in   favor  of   the   status  quo.   Finally,   sectional   groups  are  active   in  all  

venues   and,   as   suggested   by   Binderkranz   et   al   (2012),   benefit   for   the   "cumulativity   or   spill-­‐over  

effect"   between   institutional   venues.   In   Denmark,   for   instance,   a   small   number   of   IGs   (mainly  

business  groups)  are  de  facto  present  in  all  venues  and  account  for  about  two-­‐third  of  all  advocacy  

activities.  By  opposition,  cause  groups  are  expected  to  mobilize   less  along  the  whole  policy  making  

process,   despite   the   fact   that   in   some   specific   venue   they   can   significantly   contribute   to   sustain  

policy   bandwagons:   this   should   be   the   case   for   mass   member   campaign   groups   in   the   direct  

democracy  venue  (see  also  Halpin  2011).  

   

To   test   these   three   hypotheses,   four   empirical   cases   are   investigated   and   compared.   The  

next  section  introduces  the  issues  at  stake  as  well  as  the  chronology  of  the  policy-­‐making  process.  

3.  The  four  policy  issues  at  stake  

The  present  study  is  based  on  four  cases  studies  concerning  very  different  policy  issues.  This  diversity  

means   that   the   IGs   mobilized   in   the   four   policy-­‐making   processes   are   extremely   diverse   too.  

However,   in  order  to  control  for  the  hypothesis  formulated  by  Baumgartner  and  Leech  (2001:1205)  

about   the   scope   and   size   of   a   policy   issue,   the   research   design   compares   four   cases   that   are   all  

characterized  by  a  high  public  and  political   saliency,   scope  and  size.  As  mentioned   in   the   following  

case  descriptions3,  each  issue  has  important  budgetary  impacts  and  potentially  affects  many  people  

in   California.   In   one  word,   the   comparison   focuses   on   completely   different   but   equally   important,  

and  thus  comparable,  California  policies.  

(1)   Regulating   Research   on   Stem   Cells   (STEM):   In   2002,   the   California   Legislature   passed  

Senate  Bill  (SB)  253  allowing  research  on  human  embryonic  stem  cells  (hESC.)  One  year  later,  SB  771  

established   an   anonymous   registry   of   embryos   for   research   purposes.   California   thus   became   a  

haven  for  hESC  research,  but  public  funding  was  still  unavailable.  Robert  Klein,  board  member  of  the  

Juvenile  Diabetes  Research  Foundation  and  father  of  a  diabetic  son,  took  control  of  Proposition  71,  

which  (1)  makes  conducting  hESC  research  a  state  constitutional  right,  (2)  allocates  $3  billion  over  a  

period   of   10   year   to   hESC   research,   and   (3)   creates   a   public   agency,   the   California   Institute   for  

Regenerative  Medicine  (CIRM)  and  an   Independent  Citizen’s  Oversight  Committee  (ICOC)  to  oversee  

it.   In   2004,   California   voters   approved   Proposition   71.   In   2005,   plaintiffs   People's   Advocate   and  

National  Tax  Limitation  Foundation   filed  an  action   in  Superior  Court  against   the   ICOC,  arguing  that  

the   disbursement   of   state   funds   by   a   private   entity   not   under   the   exclusive   control   of   the   state  

violates  the  California  Constitution.  Shortly  after,  plaintiff  California  Family  Bioethics  Council,  LLC  (the  

Council)   filed   another   complaint   against   CIRM,   contending   that   Proposition   71   concealed   the   true  

scope,  meaning  and  costs  of  the  initiative  from  the  voters.  These  two  actions  were  consolidated  and  

in   2006   the   Court   ruled   that   plaintiffs   failed   to   show   that   Proposition   71  was   unconstitutional.   In  

2007,   the  California  Court  of  Appeal,   confirmed  once  again   that  Proposition  71  did  not  violate   the  

Constitution   and   did   not   mislead   the   voters.   In   2006,   the   Legislature   passed   SB   1260,   which  

indefinitely  extends  the  duration  of  existing  law4.  Finally,  the  CIRM,  endowed  by  Proposition  71,  has  

                                                                                                                         3  See  the  appendix  1  to  4  for  a  chronology  of  all  policy  decisions  than  were  made  in  all  institutional  venues  during  the  policy-­‐making  process  of  each  case  study.  

4  i.e.  S.B.  252  and  771,  supposed  to  be  repealed  on  January  1,  2007  

 

launched   several   rule-­‐making   procedures   about   medical   and   ethical   standards,   and   Intellectual  

Property  and  Revenue-­‐Sharing  Requirements  for  Non-­‐Profits  and  For-­‐Profit  Grantees.  

(2)   Non-­‐resident   aliens’   access   to   higher   education   (IMMIG):   In   1999   the   California  

Legislature   approves   AB   1197,   requiring   that   an   alien   precluded   from   establishing   California  

residency   due   to   federal   law   be   exempt   from   paying   non-­‐resident   tuition   when   pursuing   higher  

education  in  California.  Governor  Davis  vetoed  AB  1197  in  2000,  citing  a  revenue  loss  to  the  state  of  

over   USD   63.7   millions.   In   2001,   AB   540   allows   specific   non-­‐residents   to   meet   state   residency  

requirements  for  the  purposes  of  establishing  higher  education  tuition  level,  if  the  student  graduated  

from  a  California  high  school,  continues  his/her  education  within  one  year  after  graduation,  and  signs  

an  affidavit  that  he/she  has  filed  an  application  to  legalize  his/her  immigration  status.  In  2005  SB  160  

provides  alien  students  eligible  for  in-­‐state  tuition  with  access  to  all  available  financial  aid  programs,  

including  public  ones.  But  Gov.  Schwarzenegger  vetoed  this  bill  in  2006,  arguing  that  such  legislation  

would  reduce  the  financial  aid  available  to  legal  California  residents.    

In   2005,   plaintiff   Robert   Martinez,   represented   by   the   University   of   Missouri   Immigration  

Reform  Law   Institute   (amongst  other  counsels),   challenged  the  constitutionality  of  AB  540,  arguing  

that   it   discriminates   against   U.S.   citizens   legally   present   in   California,   who   must   pay   out-­‐of-­‐state  

tuition.  The  Superior  Court  ruled  in  favor  of  defendants  the  Regents  of  the  University  of  California  et  

al.,  upholding  AB  540.  But  in  2008,  the  California  Court  of  Appeals  overturned  this  ruling,  voiding  the  

law  passed  by  AB  540.  This  decision  was  appealed  and  the  California  Supreme  Court  grants  petition  

for   review   in   2008.   In   2010,   the  California   Supreme  Court   reversed   the   judgment   of   the   Court   of  

Appeals,  finding  that  AB  540  did  not  violate  federal  immigration  law.  Opponents  attempted  to  appeal  

again,  but  the  U.S.  Supreme  Court  denied  petition  for  certiorari  in  20115.    

In  2007  the  Legislature  passed  SB  1,  to  allow  eligibility  for  state-­‐funded  financial  aid  to  high  

school   graduates   who   meet   the   non-­‐resident   in-­‐state   tuition   requirements.   However   Gov.  

Schwarzenegger  vetoes  the  bill,  citing  budgetary  concerns.  In  2008,  the  Legislature  enrolls  SB  1301,  

which   requires   that   the   state’s   institutions   of   high   education   provide   institutional   financial   aid   to  

students  exempt  from  nonresident  tuition.  Gov.  Schwarzenegger  vetoed  the  bill  for  fiscal  reasons.  In  

2010  SB  1460  would  have  expanded  eligibility  for  state-­‐administered  financial  aid  to  students  exempt  

from  paying  nonresident   tuition.  Gov.  Schwarzenegger  vetoes   the  bill.  The  Legislature   follows  with  

                                                                                                                         5  In  this  and  all  other  cases,  we  treat  judicial  petition  for  review  as  self-­‐standing  decisions.  If  the  petition  is  denied,  the  lower  court’s  ruling  stands.  

   

SB   1460   and  AB  14136   in   2010,   both   of  which  were  vetoed   again   later   that   year.   In   2011  AB  130  

enacts  the  California  DREAM  Act.  All  students  exempt  from  nonresident  tuition  pursuant  to  AB  540  

shall  be  eligible  to  receive  non-­‐state  funded  scholarships.  Subsequently  AB  131  expands  eligibility  for  

state-­‐administered   student   financial   aid   programs   to   include   AB   540   students.   Governor   Brown  

signed  these  two  bills  into  law  the  same  year.  

(3)  The  California  High-­‐Speed  Rail   (HSR):   In  2002   the  Legislature  passes  SB  1856,   the  Safe,  

Reliable   High-­‐Speed   Passenger   Train   Bond   Act   of   the   21st   century.   Providing   USD   9.95   billion   in  

general  obligation  authority,   the  Act  was   required  to  be  submitted  to  California  voters   in   the  2004  

general   election.   In   early   2004,  SB   1160   delays   the   scheduled   vote   on   the   Bond  Act   to   2006.   The  

state’s   structural  budget  deficit   is   cited  as  explanation.   In  2006,  AB  713   further  delays   the  vote   to  

2008.  That  year,  AB  3034  revises,  updates  and  expands  the  Bond  Act  to  be  placed  on  the  ballot,  and  

designates  it  as  Proposition  1A.  Voters  approve  it  at  the  November  2008  general  election.      

  In   2011,   individuals   and   the   County   of   Kings   challenge   the   California   High   Speed   Rail  

Authority   (CHSRA)   in   Superior   Court.   The   court   finds   that   the   agency   abused   its   discretion   by  

approving  a  funding  plan  that  did  not  comply  with  the  requirements  of  the  law.  In  2012  the  City  of  

Palo   Alto,   the   Community   Coalition   on   High   Speed   Rail   and   the   mid-­‐peninsula   residents   for   Civic  

Sanity  obtain   from   the   court   that   the  CHSRA   rescind  and   set   aside   its  determination   certifying   the  

Environmental  Impact  Report  and  approval  of  the  project  for  the  Bay  Area  to  Central  Valley.  During  

these  judicial  proceedings,  in  2012  the  Legislature  approves  construction  financing  for  an  initial  stage  

of   the  project  with  SB  1029,   including  4.5  billion   in  bonds  previously  approved  by  voters,  which   in  

turn,  freed  up  USD  3.2  billion  in  federal  funding.  

In  2013  the  Court  finds,  in  Town  of  Atherton,  the  Planning  and  Conservation  League,  the  City  

of  Menlo  Park,  Transportation  Solutions  Defense  and  Education  Fund,  the  California  Bayrail  Alliance  

v.  CHSRA,  that  the  agency’s  approval  of  the  Bay  Area  to  Central  Valley  project  failed  to  comply  with  

requirements  of  California  Environmental  Quality  Act   for  the  Bay  Area  to  Central  Valley  part  of   the  

project.  These  last  two  cases  were  appealed  together  and  parties  are  awaiting  the  Court’s  decision  as  

of  March   2014.   Still   in   2013,   the   County   of  Madera,   Preserve   our   Heritage,  Madera   County   Farm  

Bureau,  Merced  County  Farm  Bureau,  Chowchilla  Water  District  and  Valley  Calf  LLC,  after  preliminary  

court   proceedings,   reach   a   binding   settlement   with   the   CHSRA.   Finally,   in   2013   the   CHSRA   brings  

legal  action  against  the  County  of  Kings,  Union  Pacific  Railroad,  Howard  Jarvis  Taxpayers  Association,  

                                                                                                                         6  The  language  of  SB  1460,  which  passed  both  chambers  in  2010,  was  placed  into  AB  1413  to  restore  funding  that  was  taken  out  by  the  Assembly  Appropriations  Committee.  We  therefore  consider  these  two  bills  as  a  single  decision,  and  their  vetoes  as  a  single  veto.  Letters  requested  or  opposing  vetoes  support  this  choice.  

 

and  several  other  groups.  The  agency  seeks  validation  of  its  authorizing  the  issuance  of  USD  8  billion  

in  bond.  The  Court  denies  the  request  and  finds  no  evidence  to  support  the  plaintiff’s  determination  

that  the  issuance  of  bonds  was  necessary  and  desirable.    

(4)  Renewables  Portfolio  Standard  (RPS):  In  2002,  the  California  Legislature  adopts  SB  1078,  

which   introduces   the   RPS   scheme   by   requiring   investor-­‐owned   utilities   (IOUs)   and   private   energy  

service  providers  (ESPs)  to  increase  their  annual  purchase  of  electricity  from  renewable  resources  by  

at   least  1%  per  year,   so   that  20%  of   their   sales  would  come   from  renewables  by  2017.   In  2004  SB  

1478  accelerates  the  20%  requirement  to  2010,  however  Gov.  Schwarzenegger  vetoes   the  bill.  The  

same  bill  is  reintroduced  in  2006  with  the  passage  of  SB  107  and  the  20%  requirement  by  the  end  of  

2010  makes   the  books.   In   2007   the   Legislature  passes   S.B.   1036   “recasts   the   renewables   Portfolio  

Standards”  by  implementing  organizational  changes.    

  In   2008   the   voters   defeat   Proposition   7,   which   would   have   increased   the   target   of  

renewables  to  40%  in  2020  and  50%  in  2025.  Shortly  following  the  vote,  Gov.  Schwarzenegger  issues  

an  Executive  Order7  expanding  the  RPS  to  33%  by  2020.  In  2009  AB  64  and  SB  14  are  adopted  by  the  

Legislature.   Together   these   bills   require   that   33%   of   the   IOUs   and   ESPs   retail   sales   come   from  

renewable   sources   by   2002.   However   Gov.   Schwarzenegger   vetoes   them   both,   arguing   that   they  

impose  too  strict   limits  on   in-­‐California  renewable  energy  production  versus  out-­‐California   imports.  

Instead,  the  Governor  issues  another  Executive  Order5  directing  the  California  Air  Resources  Board  to  

adopt   regulations   increasing   RPS   to   33%   by   2020.   Finally   in   2011,   the   Legislature   passes   SBX1-­‐2  

which  maintains  the  33%  by  2020  requirement  but  no  longer  requires  that  renewable  energy  come  

from  generation   in  California.  On  the  other  hand,   it  mandates  RPS  compliance  on  publically  owned  

utilities  (POUs)  for  the  first  time.    

  This  latest  legislation  (SBX  1-­‐2)  mandates  the  California  Public  Utilities  Commission  (CPUC)  to  

oversee   IOUs  and   the  California  Energy  Commission   (CEC)  oversees  POUs.  The  CEC  posts  proposed  

RPS   regulations   in   the   Notice   Register   in   March   2013.   The   CPUC,   which   conducts   unique,   semi-­‐

judicial,   semi-­‐legislative   rule-­‐making   proceedings,   conducts   five   rule-­‐making   proceedings   to  

implement  and  administer  the  RPS,  to  which  dozens  of  groups  participate.  

 

 

                                                                                                                         7  Both  Executive  Orders  are  excluded  from  our  analysis  due  to  a  lack  of  access  to  data.  

 

   

4.  Descriptive  statistics  

To  address  our  first  hypothesis  about  the  level  of  IGs  mobilizations  and  policy  bandwagons  dynamics  

in   the   legislative,   governmental/administrative,   judicial   and   direct   democracy   venues,   Table   1  

recapitulates,   for   each   case   study,   the   number   of   binding   decisions   per   venue,   the   absolute   and  

relative   number   of   IGs   mobilized   to   influence   these   decisions   and,   finally,   the   distribution   of   IGs  

mobilization  over  venues.    

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Table  1:  Institutional  venues,  binding  decisions  and  IGs  mobilization  for  each  case  study  

Cases  study  

Legislature  (bill  enrolled)  

Government  and  Administration  (veto  and  rule-­‐making)  

Judiciary  (court  decision)  

Direct  democracy  (popular  vote  on  initiative)  

Total  for  all  venues  of  the  policy-­‐making  process  

Stem  cell  (STEM)  

 

#  binding  decisions  per  venue     3   5   2   1   11  

#  IGs  mobilized  per  venue   41   51   35   48   154  

 #  IGs  mobilized  /  #  decisions   13.6   10.2   17.5   48   14  

#I  Gs  mobilized  in  the  venue  /  all  IGs  mobilized  in  case  (in  %)  

 

26.6%  

 

33.5%  

 

22.7%  

 

31%  

 

100%  

Immi-­‐gration  (IMMIG)  

 

#  binding  decisions  per  venue     9   4*   5   0   18  

#  IGs  mobilized  per  venue   162   85   119   n/a   298  

 #  IGs  mobilized  /  #  decisions   18   21.3   23.8   n/a   16.6  

#I  Gs  mobilized  in  the  venue  /  all  IGs  mobilized  in  case  (in  %)  

 

54.3%  

 

28.5%  

 

39.9%  

 

n/a  

 

100%  

Renew-­‐ables  Port-­‐folio  

(RPS)  

 

#  binding  decisions  per  venue     6   7**   0   1   14  

#  IGs  mobilized  per  venue   252   227   n/a   7   400  

#  IGs  mobilized  /  #  decisions   42   32.4   n/a   7   28.6  

#I  Gs  mobilized  in  the  venue  /  all  IGs  mobilized  in  case  (in  %)  

 

63%  

 

56.8%  

 

n/a  

 

0.02%  

 

100%  

HSR   #  binding  decisions  per  venue     5   0   4   1   10  

#  IGs  mobilized  per  venue   106   n/a   42   71   203  

 #  IGs  mobilized  /  #  decisions   21.2   n/a   10.5   71   20.3  

#I  Gs  mobilized  in  the  venue  /  all  IGs  mobilized  in  case  (in  %)  

52.2.%   n/a   20.7%   45%   100%  

Note:  the  sum  of  the  IGs  mobilized  in  all  venues  does  not  correspond  to  the  #  of  IGs  mobilized  for  the  whole  case  study  (see  last  column)  as  one  IGs  may  mobilize  in  more  than  one  venue.  

*There  are  5  vetoes  but  one  of  them  is  excluded  due  to  lack  of  access  to  data  

**There  are  9  administrative  decisions,  but  2  of  them  are  excluded  due  to  lack  of  access  to  data.    

   

The   data   collected   for   the   four   policy   issues   under   investigation   lead   to   the   following  

observations.   First,   only   the  HSR   case   tends   to   support,   at   least   partially,   our   first   hypothesis:   the  

number  of   IGs  mobilized  per  decision   is  71   for   the  direct  democracy  venue,  21.2   for   the   legislative  

venue   and   10.5   for   the   judiciary   venue.   This   decreasing   ranking   perfectly   matches   with   our  

expectation.   However,   the   ranking   across   venues   looks   quite   different   as   soon   one   focus   on   the  

percentage   of   IGs  mobilized   in   one   venue   in   comparison   to   all   IGs   engaging   in   advocacy   activities  

over   the  entire  policy  process   (i.e.   45%   in  direct  democracy   versus  52.2%   in   the   legislative   arena).  

Second,  most  of  the  cases   invalidate  the   ideas  that  policy  bandwagons  should  be  more  frequent   in  

voting  campaign  than  in  other  institutional  venues.  The  opposite  is  true  for  the  RPS  case.  Third,  the  

judiciary  cannot  always  be  qualified  as   interest  niche.  The  contrary   is  observed   in   the   IMMIG  case:  

the  judicial  venue  displays  the  highest  number  of  IGs  mobilized  per  decision  (23.8)  within  this  policy  

process.  Fourth,  and  this  is  apparently  also  running  against  our  hypothesis,  the  intensity  of  advocacy  

activities  is  not  identical  in  both  the  legislative  and  the  governmental/administrative  venues.  Figures  

from  the  STEM  and  IMMIG  cases  demonstrate  it.  All  in  all,  no  systematic  pattern  emerges  from  Table  

1.   The  mobilization   levels   of   IGs   are   apparently   contingent   upon   each   policy   issue   at   stake   or   are  

inherent  to  the  chronology  of  the  policy  process  for  each  case.    

To  follow  this  path,  the  succession  of  binding  decisions  (made  within  the  same  venue,  or   in  

different  venues)  has  to  be  scrutinized.  For  each  case,  Table  2  presents  thus  the  mobilization  of  IGs  

according   the   chronological   order   of   the   decisions   punctuating   the   policy   process.   This   diachronic  

perspective  allows  testing  the  second  hypothesis  formulated  in  the  theoretical  framework.      

   

 

Table  2:  Number  and  %  of  IGs  mobilized  per  decision,  ordered  in  time  for  each  case  study.    

  STEM  (154  IGs)   IMMIG  (298  IGs)   RPS  (400  IGs)   HSR  (203  IGs)  

Decision  1   23   15%   18   6%   31   8%   40   20%    (Bond  Act)  

Decision  2   16   10%   49   16%   36   9%   10   5%  

Decision  3   48   31%  (Prop  71)   50   17%   31   8%   11   5%  

Decision  4  

7   5%   25   8%   50   13%   71  

35%  (AB  3034  to  revise  Bond  

Act)  

Decision  5   26   17%   4   1%   18   5%   71   35%  (Prop  1A)  

Decision  6   8   5%   20   7%   44   11%   9   4%  

Decision  7   18   12%   53   18%   7   2%   8   4%  

Decision  8  31  

20%  (Appellate  Court)  

22   7%   165   41%  (Prop  7)   11   5%  

Decision  9   12   8%   30   10%   96   24%   9   4%  

Decision  10   8   5%   10   3%   37   9%   3   1%  

Decision  11   6   4%   2   1%   106   27%    (SB  X1-­‐2)   9   4%  

Decision  12  

   n/a  

21   7%   64   16%   27   13%  

Decision  13   28   9%   110   28%  (CPUC  )  

   n/a  

Decision  14  

118  

40%    (CA  

Supreme  Court)  

25   6%  

Decision  15  6   2%   99  

25%    (CPUC,  still  on-­‐going)  

Decision  16   79   26.5%  (AB  130)    

n/a  Decision  17   83   28%  

(AB  131)  N.B.  The  decisions  do  not  take  place  at  the  same  time  across  cases.  This  is  a  simple  chronological  order  per  case.  Not  also  that  the  Highs  Speed  Rail  (HSR)  and  the  Renewable  Portfolio  Standards  (RPS)  cases  are  still  on-­‐going.    

 

The  empirical  evidence  yield  mixes  evidence  with  respect  to  our  second  expectation.  On  one  

hand,  two  cases  are  obviously  characterized  by  higher  mobilization  and  bandwagons  towards  the  end  

of  the  policy  process,  namely  IMMIG  and  RPS.  On  the  other  hand,  the  two  other  cases  show  either  a  

concentration  of   IGs   advocacy   in   the  early   stages  of   the  policy-­‐making  process   (i.e.  HSR)  or   a   very  

fragmented  mobilization  over   time   (STEM).   Finally,   Table  3   changes  once   again   the  perspective  by  

showing   the   diversity   of   IGs   categories   that   tried   to   influence   policymaking   in   the   four   policy  

domains.    

 

   

Table  3:  Diversity  of  IG  mobilized  in  the  three  case  studies  

Case  study  

(#  IGs)  

#  of  IGs  mobilized  per  type  of  IGs  

Unions     Business  groups    

Institutional  groups    

Occupational  groups  

Identity  groups  

Religious  groups  

Public  Interest  groups  

STEM  

(154  IGs)  1        

(0.6%)  42  

(27.3%)  7                  

(4.5%)  30                  

(19.5%)  6            

(3.9%)  18        

(11.7%)  50            

(32.5%)  

RPS  

(400  IGs)  21      

(5.3%)  249  

(62.3%)  66          

(16.5%)  7                          

(1.8%)  1              

(0.3%)  2              

(0.5%)  54                

(13.5%)  

IMMIG  

(298  IGs)  17    

(5.7%)  13        

(4.3%)  22              

(7.4%)  84                  

(28.2%)  99  

(33.2%)  9                  

(3%)  54                      

(18%)  

HSR    

(203  IGs)  21  

(10.3%)  84          

(41.4%)  56          

(27.5%)        3                    

(1.5%)  0                  

(0%)  1                    

(0.4%)  38                

(18.7%)  

Note:  Section  groups  (i.e.  business  and  occupational  IGs)  are  in  grey;  all  other  IGs  are  cause  groups.  

 

The  types  of  IGs  that  get  involved  in  the  Stem  Cells,  Renewable  Energies,  High  Speed  Rail  and  

Immigrants’   Rights   policy-­‐making   processes   vary   greatly.   In   a   nutshell,   business   groups   (e.g.  

Biotechnology  Industry  Organization  of  California,   Invitrogen  Corporation,  BIOCOM,  Stem  Cells   Inc.)  

and   public   interest   groups   (e.g.   Alzheimer’s   Association,   Juvenile   Diabetes   Research   Foundation,  

Planned  Parenthood  Affiliates  of  California)  are  dominant   in  STEM.  Business  groups  (e.g.  CH2M  Hill  

(cement),   Associated   General   Contractors   of   California)   are   also   key   players,   together   with  

institutional   groups   (e.g.   Santa   Clara   Valley   Transportation   Authority,   Sacramento   Regional   Transit  

District),   in   HSR.   A   similar   profile   characterizes   RPS   (e.g.   Sempra   Energy,   Pacific   Gas   and   Electric  

Company,  and  Sacramento  Municipal  Utility  District,  Southern  California  Public  Power  Authority).  By  

contrast,   business   interests   are   not   so   preeminent   at   all   in   IMMIG,   where   occupational   (e.g.   Los  

Angeles   Community   College   District,   California   State   University)   and   identity   groups   (e.g.  Mexican  

American  Legal  Defense  and  Education  Fund,  Asian  Americans  for  Civil  Rights  &  Equality)  appear  to  

be  the  most  relevant  lobbying  actors.  

The  data  in  Table  4  shows  that  while  sectional  groups  do  drive  mobilization  levels  for  RPS,  in  

support  of   the   third  hypothesis   (i.e.  higher  mobilization  of  sectional  groups  and,  at   the  same  time,  

the   highest   numbers   of   IGs   participating   to   the   policy-­‐process),  mobilization   drivers   in   IMMIG   are  

almost   symmetrically  opposite,  with   cause  groups   leading   in   this  policy-­‐process.   For   the   two  other  

case   studies,   STEM   and   the   HSR,   sectional   and   cause   groups   actually   mobilize   with   very   similar  

 

intensity  (See  Appendix  5  &  8.)  We  thus  cannot  conclude  that  business  and  occupational  groups  drive  

the  bandwagon  dynamics.   Instead,  our  results  only   illustrate  the   importance  of  contextualizing  any  

analysis  of  mobilization  levels.    

If  we   take   a   closer   look   at   the   IG  mobilization   at   the   decision   level   (see  Appendix   5   to   8),  

cause   groups   drive   the  mobilization   levels   for   6   out   of   11   decisions   in   STEM  and   in   almost   all   the  

decisions  in  IMMIG,  RPS  and  HSR.  Furthermore,  after  placing  the  decisions  on  a  continuum  from  low  

mobilization   to   high   mobilization   and   examining   sectional   and   cause   groups   relative   to   the   total  

number  of  groups  on  each  decision,  we  see  that  cause  groups  drive  high  mobilization  decisions  for  

IMMIG   and   the   HSR,   with   the   notable   exception   of   the   highest   mobilized   decision   in   the   HSR,  

Proposition  1A,  where   sectional  groups  dominate  as   suggested   in  our  hypothesis   rationale.  On   the  

other  hand,  and  as  identified  above,  sectional  groups  lead  in  high  mobilization  decisions  for  RPS.  No  

clear   pattern   emerges   in   STEM,   even   in   the   highest   mobilized   direct   democracy   decision,   where  

sectional   and   cause   groups   are   quasi-­‐identically   represented   with   44%   and   56%   respectively   (see  

Appendix  5).    

 

   

   

Table   4:   Sectional   versus   Cause   groups  mobilized   in   RPS   and   IMMIG,   as   a  %   of   total   number   of  

groups  on  each  decision.    

RPS   IMMIG  

Venue  Total  #  of  IGs  per  decision:  

Sectional  IGs   Cause  IGs   Venue  Total  #  of  IGs  per  decision  

Sectional  IGs   Cause  IGs  

D   7   71%   29%   J   2   100%   0%  L   18   72%   28%   J   4   100%   0%  A   25   48%   52%   J   6   50%   50%  L   31   45%   55%   J   10   50%   50%  A   31   32%   68%   L   18   22%   78%  L   36   42%   58%   L   20   30%   70%  A   38   68%   32%   L   21   48%   52%  A   45   62%   38%   L   22   41%   59%  L   50   44%   56%   A   25   68%   32%  A   65   68%   32%   J   28   50%   50%  A   96   58%   42%   A   30   43%   57%  A   100   70%   30%   L   49   37%   63%  L   106   63%   37%   L   50   40%   60%  A   111   72%   28%   A   53   42%   58%  L   165   53%   47%   L   79   38%   62%  

Total  #  of  IGs  across  case:  400    

L   83   37%   63%  

J   118   25%   75%  

Total  #  of  IGs  across  case:  298  

 

5.  Markov  transition  models  

As  the  purpose  of  this  paper  is  to  explain  why  interest  groups  become  active  in  a  particular  

venue   and   contribute   to   policy   bandwagons,   a   dichotomous   choice  model   is  most   appropriate   to  

evaluate  the  hypotheses.  For  each  of   the   four  policy  processes  we   look  at  various  venues   followed  

more  or  less  in  sequence,  thus  it  is  likely  that  having  been  active  in  one  venue  will  make  mobilization  

in  the  next  venue  more  probable.  Consequently,  past  activation  should  positively  influence  activation  

in   the   next   venue.   Such   a   hypothesis   can   easily   be   evaluated   by   considering   a   lagged   dependent  

variable   in   a   logit   or   probit   setup.   However,   when   adding   additional   explanatory   variables,   the  

question   arises   of   whether   a   particular   independent   variable,   for   instance   the   number   of   venues  

already   “visited”   by   the   policy-­‐making   process,   will   affect   the   probability   of   activation   equally,  

independent  of  whether  an  interest  group  has  been  active  or  not  (for  a  detailed  discussion  of  binary  

time-­‐series  cross-­‐section  data  and  their  analysis,  see  Beck,  Katz  &  Tucker  1998).  This  equal  effect   is  

 

unlikely   to   hold   in   practice.   To   assess   this   question,   binary  Markov  models   focus   on   four   relevant  

transitions  probabilities  for  transitions  from  activity  in  the  preceding  venue  to  activity  in  the  present  

venue,  from  activity  in  the  last  venue  to  non-­‐activity  in  the  present  venue,  etc.  (for  an  introduction  to  

such  basic  Markov  models,  see  Markus  1979,  8f).  

Table  5:  Markov  transition  matrix  

 

  activet-­‐1   non-­‐activet-­‐1  

activet   p   q  

non-­‐activet   1-­‐p   1-­‐q  

 

Table  5  presents  a  basic  Markov  transition  matrix.  More  specifically,  it  depicts,  for  each  possible  

state  at  t-­‐1,  how  likely  it  is  to  stay  in  the  same  state  at  t  (i.e.  p,  respectively  (1-­‐q)),  or  to  switch  state  

(i.e.   (1-­‐p),   respectively   q).   Under   the   assumption   of   independence   p   and   q   should   be   equal.   In  

addition  to  relaxing  this  assumption  of  independence,  it  is  also  possible  to  allow  p  and  q  to  change  as  

a   function   of   independent   variables,   for   instance   the   type   of   venue   or   the   type   of   interest   group.  

Thus,  we  can  model  how  these  probabilities  change  as  follows:  

𝑙𝑜𝑔𝑖𝑡 𝑝 =  𝛽! + 𝛽!𝑥! +⋯  

𝑙𝑜𝑔𝑖𝑡 𝑞 =  𝛽!! + 𝛽!!𝑥! +⋯  

To  estimate  the  parameters  related  to  p,  respectively  q,  we  can  only  use  observations  that  have  

seen   previous   activation,   respectively   no   activation.   In   the   end,   however,   we   are   interested   in  

knowing  the  overall  probability  of  seeing  an  interest  group  become  active,  and  thus  we  combine  the  

two  equations  above.  Doing  so  is  possible,  but  we  have  to  take  into  account  that  we  assume  the  two  

sets  of  parameters  to  be  different.  Thus:  

𝑙𝑜𝑔𝑖𝑡 𝑝! = 𝛽! + 𝛽!!𝑎𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒!,!!! + 𝛽!𝑥! + 𝛽!!𝑎𝑐𝑡𝑖𝑣𝑒!,!!!𝑥! +⋯  

where   𝛽!! = 𝛽! + 𝛽!!   and   𝛽!! = 𝛽! + 𝛽!!   etc.   Consequently,   the   model   above   can   be  estimated   on   the   whole   set   of   observations.   Based   on   the   estimated   parameters   the  transition  probabilities  in  the  table  above  can  be  estimated  as  follows:    

  𝑝 = 𝑙𝑜𝑔𝑖𝑡!! 𝛽! + 𝛽!𝑥! +⋯  

𝑞 = 𝑙𝑜𝑔𝑖𝑡!!(𝛽! + 𝛽!! + (𝛽! + 𝛽!!)𝑥! +⋯ )  

 

   

Such  a  model  allows   for   testing   the  hypotheses  stated  above   (for   studies  using  such  models   in  

varying   empirical   settings,   see   Przeworski   &   Vreeland   2000,   Beck,   Epstein,   Jackman   &   O’Halloran  

2001,  Epstein,  Bates,  Goldstone,  Kristensen  &  O’Halloran  2006,  Powell  &  Mitchell  2007,  Mitchell  &  

Powell   2011,   Hug  &  Wegmann   2012,  Wegmann   2012).   Thus,   in   Table   6  we   report   the   estimation  

results  of  a  series  of  Markov  models  with  increasing  complexity  allowing  us  to  test  our  hypotheses.8  

Model   1   in   Table   6   serves   as   a   sort   of   baseline   model,   as   it   assumes   that   the   probability   of  

mobilization  is  simply  dependent  on  whether  an  IG  was  active  in  the  preceding  venue.  The  estimated  

coefficients  clearly  suggest  that  having  been  active  in  the  preceding  venue  increases  the  probability  

of  mobilization.  The   substantive  effects   for   this  model  are  presented   in   figure  1.  This   figure   shows  

that  the  predicted  probability  of  being  active  in  a  venue  if  an  IG  was  inactive  in  the  preceding  one  is  

slightly  above  0.1  with  quite  a  narrow  confidence  interval.  If  an  IG  was  active  in  the  preceding  venue,  

however,  the  chances  of  mobilization  increase  to  almost  a  quarter  with  a  slightly  broader  confidence  

interval.   The   two   probabilities   that   we   depict   in   this   figure   correspond   to   q,   respectively   p,   from  

Table  5,  namely  the  probability  of  being  active  given  that  an  IG  was  inactive  in  the  preceding  venue,  

respectively   the   probability   of   mobilization   given   that   the   group   was   mobilized   in   the   preceding  

venue.   The   differences   in   these   two   estimated   probabilities   clearly   suggest   that   mobilization   is  

influenced  by  mobilization  in  the  preceding  venue.  

 

                                                                                                                         8  For  simplicity's  sake  we  estimated  these  models  without  taking  into  account  interdependencies  across  cases,  e.g.,  that  the  same  interest  group  appears  multiple  times  in  our  dataset.  Only  2.4%  of  our  IGs  are  active  in  more  than  1  case  study,  and  of  these,  only  2  groups  are  active  in  three  cases.  No  group  is  active  in  all  four  cases.    

 

Table  6:  Results  of  Markov  models  

  Model  1   Model  2   Model  3   Model  4   Model  5   Model  6  intercept   -­‐2.04  *   -­‐1.99  *   -­‐2.34  *   -­‐2.33  *   -­‐2.33  *   -­‐2.30  *     (0.03)   (0.05)   (0.11)   (0.11)   (0.12)   (0.14)  active  in  preceding  venue   0.97  *   1.00  *   1.66  *   1.65  *   1.63  *   1.57  *     (0.06)   (0.09)   (0.24)   (0.24)   (0.25)   (0.25)  direct  democracy  venue     0.48  *   0.51  *   0.54  *   0.55  *   0.52  *       (0.11)   (0.11)   (0.11)   (0.11)   (0.12)  judiciary  venue     -­‐0.39  *   -­‐0.42  *   -­‐0.34  *   -­‐0.35  *   -­‐0.26  *       (0.08)   (0.09)   (0.09)   (0.09)   (0.10)  legislative  venue     -­‐0.02   0.02   0.05   0.04   0.09       (0.07)   (0.07)   (0.07)   (0.07)   (0.07)  active  in  preceding  venue    ×  direct  democracy  

  -­‐1.47  *   -­‐1.39  *   -­‐1.44  *   -­‐1.42  *   -­‐1.35  *  

    (0.33)   (0.33)   (0.33)   (0.34)   (0.34)  active  in  preceding  venue    ×  judiciary  

  -­‐1.45  *   -­‐1.54  *   -­‐1.46  *   -­‐1.50  *   -­‐1.45  *  

    (0.25)   (0.25)   (0.28)   (0.28)   (0.28)  active  in  preceding  venue    ×  legislative  

  0.50  *   0.37  *   0.34  *   0.32  *   0.38  *  

    (0.13)   (0.14)   (0.14)   (0.14)   (0.14)  venue  counter       0.07  *   0.06  *   0.06  *   0.05         (0.03)   (0.03)   (0.03)   (0.03)  venue  counter2       -­‐0.00   -­‐0.00   -­‐0.00   -­‐0.00         (0.00)   (0.00)   (0.00)   (0.00)  venue  counter    ×  active  in  preceding  venue  

    -­‐0.23  *   -­‐0.21  *   -­‐0.22  *   -­‐0.22  *       (0.06)   (0.06)   (0.06)   (0.06)  

venue  counter    ×  active  in  preceding  venue  

    0.01  *   0.01  *   0.01  *   0.01  *       (0.00)   (0.00)   (0.00)   (0.00)  

preceding  venue:  direct  democracy         0.33  *   0.33  *   0.28           (0.15)   (0.15)   (0.15)  active  in  preceding  venue:    direct  democracy  

      -­‐0.96   -­‐0.96   -­‐0.90         (1.09)   (1.09)   (1.09)  

preceding  venue:    direct  democracy  ×  judiciary  

      -­‐0.90  *   -­‐0.90  *   -­‐0.95  *         (0.35)   (0.35)   (0.36)  

active  in  preceding  venue:    direct  democracy  ×  judiciary  

      0.75   0.80   0.78         (1.31)   (1.31)   (1.31)  

business  group           -­‐0.02   -­‐0.11             (0.06)   (0.07)  occupational  group           0.04   0.12             (0.09)   (0.09)  active  in  preceding  venue:    business  group  

        0.05   0.07           (0.14)   (0.14)  

active  in  preceding  venue:  occupational  group  

        0.20   0.22           (0.19)   (0.19)  

policy:  immigration             -­‐0.21  *               (0.10)  policy:  renewables             0.09               (0.09)  policy:  stem  cells             0.01               (0.11)  N   14195   14195   14195   14195   14195   14195  AIC   10947.62   10736.12   10706.97   10704.63   10710.17   10701.53  BIC   11008.10   10978.06   11069.88   11188.51   11315.03   11397.11  logL   -­‐5465.81   -­‐5336.06   -­‐5305.48   -­‐5288.31   -­‐5275.09   -­‐5258.77    Standard  errors  in  parentheses  *  indicates  significance  at  p<0.05    

 

   

In  model  2  we  introduce  as  additional  independent  variable  the  type  of  venue.  As  we  expect  

the   effect   of   a   venue   to   depend   also   on   the  mobilization   in   the   preceding   venue,  we   interact   the  

resulting  dichotomous  variables  with  the  indicator  of  mobilization  in  the  preceding  venue.  Referring  

back  to  Table  5,  this  implies  that  we  will  have  the  transition  probabilities  p  and  q  vary  as  a  function  of  

the   venue.   Consequently,   we   predict   eight   such   probabilities,   two   for   each   venue.   As   the   results  

presented  in  Table  6  for  model  2  nicely  show  the  first  hypothesis  finds  strong  support  provided  an  IG  

was   inactive   in   the  preceding   venue.   In   that   case   the  probability   of  mobilization   is   highest   for   the  

direct   democratic   venue,   followed   by   the   administrative,   the   legislative   and   finally   the   judiciary  

venue.  The  picture  changes,  however,   if  an  IG  was  active  in  the  preceding  venue.  This  is  due  to  the  

fact   that   the   effect   of  mobilization   in   the   preceding   venue   has   different   effects   as   figure   2   nicely  

illustrates.  While   for   the   administrative   and   legislative   venues,   previous  mobilization   increases   the  

probability   of   mobilization,   it   depresses   it   in   the   direct   democracy   and   judiciary   venue.   As   the  

confidence   intervals  of   the  average  predictive  differences   in  probabilities   for  these  two   last  venues  

straddle  zero,  these  differences  fail  to  reach  statistical  significance.  This  leads  to  a  situation  in  which,  

after  mobilization  in  the  preceding  venue,  the  order  in  which  venues  attract  mobilization  by  interest  

groups   changes.   Given   mobilization   in   the   preceding   venue   mobilization   is   most   likely   in   the  

legislative  venue,  followed  by  the  administrative,  the  direct  democratic  and  finally  the  judicial  venue.  

These  differences  are  a  powerful  illustration  for  the  adequacy  of  Markov  models  for  explaining  these  

dynamics  in  a  policy  process.  

 

 Figure   1:   Predicted   probability   of  mobilization   as   a   function   of  mobilization   in   preceding   venue  (based  on  model  1)  

 

Hypothesis  2  suggests   that  as   the  policy-­‐making  process  moves  on  through  various  venues,  

mobilization  becomes  more   likely,   i.e.  more  and  more   IGs   jump  on   the  bandwagon.   To  assess   this  

hypothesis  we   introduce   in  model  3  a   simple  counter  of   the  venues.   It   simply   indicates  how  many  

preceding   venues   the   policy-­‐making   process   has   already   “visited.”   To   allow   for   a   more   flexible  

functional  form  linking  this  counter  to  the  probability  of  mobilization,  we  introduce  this  counter  also  

as   its   square   and   interact   both   variables   with   our   indicator   of   whether   an   interest   group   was  

mobilizing  in  the  preceding  venue  (as  we  did  for  all  other  variables  as  well).  The  results  for  this  model  

3   show   that,   in   the   absence  of  mobilization   in   the  preceding   venue,   the   likelihood  of  mobilization  

increases   largely   in   a   linear   fashion,   thus   supporting   our   second   hypothesis.   For   the   interaction  

0.00

0.05

0.10

0.15

0.20

0.25

0.30

mobilization in preceeding venue

Pred

icte

d pr

obab

ility

of m

obiliz

atio

n (a

nd 9

5% c

onfid

ence

inte

rval

)

no yes

   

terms,  however,  we  find  one  negative  and  one  positive  coefficient.  Thus,  if  mobilization  has  occurred  

in  the  preceding  venue,  the  effect  of  the  venue  counter  appears  to  be  curvilinear.  We  depict  these  

relationships   in   figure   3.   Again   we   find   quite   considerable   differences,   also   as   a   function   of   the  

venue,   highlighting   again   the   usefulness   of   the   Markov   models.   The   four   panels   show   that  

independent   of   venue   type,   and   in   the   absence   of   mobilization   in   the   preceding   venue,   as   the  

process   moves   through   the   venues   the   likelihood   of   mobilization   increases,   but   the   changes   are  

marginal  and   from  the   first   to   the   last  venue   (we  used   for  all  decision  making  process  sixteen  as  a  

maximum)   not   statistically   different   from   each   other.   If   we   consider,   however,   how   the   venue  

counter   affects   mobilization   for   those   groups   active   in   the   preceding   venue   we   find   a   marked  

curvilinear  relationship.  More  specifically,  at  the  beginning  of  the  process   increasing  the  number  of  

venues   decreases   mobilization,   but   then   mobilization   picks   up   after   half   a   dozen   venues.   These  

curvilinear   effects   are   strongest   in   the   direct   democracy   venue   and   legislative   one.   In   the   former,  

however,   this   curvilinear   relationship   is   estimated  with   considerable   uncertainty,  making   it   largely  

undistinguishable   from   the   linear   trend   we   found   for   interest   groups   without   mobilization   in   the  

preceding  venue.  This  is  not  at  all  the  case  for  the  legislative  venue  where  the  two  curves  are  clearly  

distinct.  Finally  for  the  administrative  and  judicial  venue  mobilization  in  the  preceding  venue  appears  

in  the  middle  of  the  process  even  to  depress  mobilization.  

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Figure   2:   Average   predictive   difference   in   probability   of   mobilization   due   to   mobilization   in  preceding  venue  (based  on  model  2)  

 

In  model   4   we   introduce   in   addition   information   on  whether   the   preceding   venue  was   direct  

democracy,  and   interact   this  variable  with   the   judicial  venue   type  and  also  preceding  mobilization.  

This  allows  us   to  assess  hypothesis  2bis.   The  estimated  coefficients   suggest   that   following  up  on  a  

direct  democracy  venue  actually  increases  the  likelihood  of  mobilization,  provided  the  current  venue  

is   not   the   judicial   one.   If   the   venue   is   the   judiciary,   however,  mobilization   is   less   likely.   This   holds  

independent   of   whether   an   IG  was   active   in   the   preceding   direct   democratic   venue   or   not.   Thus,  

hypothesis  2bis  does  not  find  support  in  our  analyses.  

Next  in  model  5  we  add  an  indicator  for  business  and  occupational  groups  (indicators  which  are  

again   interacted  with   the   indicator   of  mobilization   in   the   preceding   venue).   Contrary   to   our   third  

hypothesis  we  find  no  evidence  that   these  two  types  of   IGs   (i.e.  sectional  groups)  are  more  or   less  

−0.1

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

venue

chan

ge in

pre

dict

ed p

roba

bilit

y du

e to

mob

ilizat

ion

in p

rece

edin

g ve

nue

administrative direct democracy judiciary legislative

   

likely  to  mobilize  than  the  remaining  IGs  (i.e.  cause  groups),  and  this  independent  of  mobilization  in  

the  preceding  venue.  

Finally   in  model  6  we  add  as  control   indicators  for  three  of  our  decision-­‐making  processes.  The  

estimated   coefficients   suggest   that   the   immigration   policy-­‐making   process   saw   on   average   less  

mobilization,  the  other  three  processes  appear  to  be  quite  similar  in  terms  of  degree  of  mobilization.  

This  final  model  suggests  also  that  our  previous  models  are  very  robust  to  the  additional  variables  we  

introduced.   Thus,   our   conclusions   drawn   from   the   various   simpler   models   also   hold   in   the   more  

comprehensive  model.  

Figure   3:   Average   predictive   difference   in   probability   of  mobilization  as   a   function   of   number   of  preceding  venues  (based  on  model  3)  

 

0 5 10 15

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

administrative venue

venue counter

Pred

icte

d pr

obab

ility

of m

obiliz

atio

n (a

nd 9

5% c

onfid

ence

inte

rval

)

no mobilization in previous venuemobilization in previous venue

0 5 10 15

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

direct democracy venue

venue counter

Pred

icte

d pr

obab

ility

of m

obiliz

atio

n (a

nd 9

5% c

onfid

ence

inte

rval

)

0 5 10 15

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

legislative venue

venue counter

Pred

icte

d pr

obab

ility

of m

obiliz

atio

n (a

nd 9

5% c

onfid

ence

inte

rval

)

0 5 10 15

0.0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5

0.6

0.7

judicial venue

venue counter

Pred

icte

d pr

obab

ility

of m

obiliz

atio

n (a

nd 9

5% c

onfid

ence

inte

rval

)

 

6.  Conclusion  

The  aim  of  this  paper  was  to  identify  potential  explanations  of  differentiated  mobilization  of  

interest  groups  and  the  dynamics  of  so-­‐called  policy  bandwagons.  The  analyses  of  the  mobilization  of  

IGs   in   four   policy-­‐making   processes   in   California   have   shown   that   policy   bandwagons   are   more  

complex  phenomena  than  commonly  assumed.  Using  as  rather  basic  empirical  strategy  the  Markov  

transition   models,   this   paper   shows   that   mobilization   in   a   particular   venue   is   dependent   on  

mobilization  in  preceding  venues.  We  were  also  able  to  show  that  the  various  types  of  venues  differ  

in  terms  of  mobilization  and  continued  mobilization.  While  the  direct  democracy  venue  is  much  more  

likely   to   bring   IGs   on   the   bandwagon,   this   venue   is   not   quite   as   hospitable   for   continuing  

mobilization.  

We  also  could  demonstrate  that  jumping  on  the  bandwagon  (or  remaining  there)  depends  on  

the  advancement   through   the  policy-­‐making  process.  While   in   all   four  policy  processes   considered  

we  could  identify  slow  increases  in  the  probability  of  mobilization  over  time,  we  also  found  that  the  

likelihood  of  staying  on  the  bandwagon  is  smaller  in  the  middle  of  a  process,  while  being  higher  both  

at   the   beginning   and   towards   the   end  of   the   process.   In   addition,   these   differences   are   especially  

marked   in   the   administrative   and   legislative   venues,   but  much  more  muted   in   the   two   remaining  

venues.  

Empirical   support   for   our   other   hypotheses   is   much  more   limited.   Despite   Gerber   et   al.'s  

(2001)   claim  we   find   no   strong   continuing  mobilization   in   the   judicial   venue   if   the   latter   follows   a  

direct  democracy  one.  Similarly,  once  we  consider  a  whole  host  of  explanatory  variables,  we  do  no  

longer  find  any  significant  differences  between  business  and  occupational  groups  (i.e.  sectional  IGs)  

on   the  one  hand,  and   the   remaining   types  of  groups   (i.e.   cause   IGs)  on   the  other   in   terms  of   their  

mobilization  effort.  

Clearly   these   analyses   leave   considerable   room   for   improvement.   First   of   all,   we   assessed  

only   the   simplest   hypotheses   and   did   not   explore   in   detail   the   more   intricate   interdependencies  

linked   to   the   hierarchical   nature   of   our   dataset.   Second,   we   have   not   taken   into   account   two  

important  elements  of  relevance  for  policy  bandwagons,  namely  the  success  in  the  preceding  venue  

and   the   intensity   of   the   mobilization.   Taking   the   former   element   into   account   would   render   the  

analyses   more   complex   but   also   more   insightful.   The   second   element   would   require   a   more  

complicated   empirical   strategy.   More   specifically,   and   going   in   the   direction   of   Jones   and  

Baumgartner's  (2005:142)  suggestion,  one  might  consider  interest  groups  as  transitioning  in  and  out  

of   mobilization,   and   during   their   mobilization   the   degree   of   their   involvement   (e.g.,   monetary  

contributions,  etc.)  could  be  modeled  in  a  time  series  framework  (for  such  models,  see  Cai,  1994  and  

   

Park,  2009).  Proceeding  like  this  would  allow  for  much  more  detailed  insights  into  the  (bandwagon)  

dynamics  of  policy-­‐making  processes.  

 

Bibliography  

Baumgartner,  F.  &  B.  Leech  (1998).  Basic  Interests:  The  Importance  of  Groups  in  Politics  and  in  

Political  Science.  Princeton,  NJ:  Princeton  University  Press.    

Baumgartner,  Frank  and  Beth  Leech  (2001).  Interest  Niches  and  Policy  Bandwagons:  Patterns  of  

Interest  groups  Involvement  in  National  Politics,  The  Journal  of  Politics  63  (4):1191-­‐1213.  

Baumgartner,  Frank  et  al.  (2009).  Lobbying  and  Policy  Change.  Who  wins,  Who  Loses  and  Why.  

Chicago:  Chicago  University  Press.  

Beck,  Nathaniel,  David  Epstein,  Simon  Jackman  &  Sharyn  O’Halloran  (2001)  Alternative  Models  of  

Dynamics  in  Binary  Time-­‐Series-­‐Cross-­‐Section  Models:  The  Example  of  State  Failure.  Paper  Prepared  

for  delivery  at  the  2001  Annual  Meeting  of  the  Society  for  Political  Methodology,  Emory  University  

Atlanta.  

Beck,  Nathaniel,  Jonathan  Katz  &  Richard  Tucker.  1998.  “Taking  Time  Seriously:  Time-­‐Series-­‐Cross-­‐

Section  Analysis  with  a  Binary  Dependent  Variable.”  American  Journal  of  Political  Science  42(4):1260–

1288.  

Berkhout,  Joostr  (2013).  Why  interest  organizations  do  what  they  do:  Assessing  the  explanatory  

potential  of  “exchange”  approaches.  Interest  groups  and  Advocacy  2(2):227-­‐250.    

Binderkrantz,  Anne  S.  (2005).  Interest  groups  strategies:  navigating  between  privileged  access  and  

strategies  of  pressure,  Political  studies  53:694-­‐715.  

Binderkrantz,  Anne  S.  et  al.  (2012).  Assessing  political  arenas.  Interest  group  access  to  the  

administration,  parliament  and  media  (unpublished  manuscript?).  

Beyers,  J.  (2008).  Policy  issues,  organisational  format  and  the  political  strategies  of  interest  

organisations.  West  European  Politics  31  (6):  1188-­‐1211.  

Boehmke,  Frederick  &  Sean  Gailmard,  John  Wiggs  Patty  (2013).  Business  as  usual:  Interest  groups  

access  and  representation  across  policy-­‐making  venues.  Journal  of  Public  Policy,  2013  33(1):  3-­‐33.  

Bouwen,  Pieter  &  Margaret  McCown  (2007).  Lobbying  versus  litigation:  Political  and  Legal  strategies  

of  Interest  Representation  in  the  European  Union,  Journal  of  European  Public  Policy,  14(3):  422-­‐443.  

Cai,  Jun  (1994).  A  Markov  Model  of  Switching-­‐Regime  ARCH.  Journal  of  Business  &  Economic  

Statistics  12(3):309–316.  

   

Cortner,  Richard  C  (1968).  Strategies  and  Tactics  of  Litigants  in  Constitutional  Cases.  Journal  of  Public  

Law  17:287-­‐307.  

Epstein,  David  L.,  Robert  Bates,  Jack  Goldstone,  Ida  Kristensen  &  Sharyn  O’Halloran  (2006).  

Democratic  Transitions.  American  Journal  of  Political  Science  50(3):551–569.  

Gelman,  Andrew  &  Jennifer  Hill.  2007.  Data  Analysis  Using  Regression  and  Multilevel/Hierarchical  

Models.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Gerber,  Elisabeth  &  Arthur  Lupia,  Mathew  D.  McCubbins,  D.  Roderik  Kiewiet  (2001).  Stealing  the  

initiative.  How  State  government  responds  to  direct  democracy.  Upper  Saddle  River,  NJ:  Prentice-­‐Hall.  

Halpin,  Darren  (2011).  Explaining  Policy  Bandwagons:  Organized  Interest  Mobilization  and  Cascades  

of  Attention,  Governance:  An  International  Journal  of  Policy,  Administration,  and  Institutions  24  (2):  

205-­‐230.  

Hanmer,  Michael  J.  &  K.Ozan  Kalkan.  2013.  Behind  the  Curve:  Clarifying  the  Best  Approach  to  

Calculating  Predicted  Probabilities  and  Marginal  Effects  from  Limited  Dependent  Variable  Models.  

American  Journal  of  Political  Science  57(1):263–277.  

Hansford,  Thomas  G  (2004).  Lobbying  strategies,  venue  selection,  and  organized  interest  

involvement  at  the  U.S.  Supreme  Court,  American  Politics  Research  32  (2):  170-­‐197.  

Heinz,  John  P.  et  al.  (1993).  The  Hollow  Core:  Private  Interests  in  National  Policy  Making.  Cambridge,  

MA:  Harvard  University  Press.  

Holyoke,  Thomas  T.  (2003).  Choosing  Battlegrounds:  Interest  Groups  Lobbying  across  Multiple  

Venues,  Political  Research  Quarterly  56(3):325-­‐336.    

Hug,  Simon  &  Simone  Wegmann.  2012.  Complying  with  human  rights.  Paper  prepared  for  

presentation  at  the  Annual  Meeting  of  the  Midwest  Political  Science  Association,  Chicago,  April  12  -­‐  

15,  2012.  

Imai,  Kosuke,  Gary  King  &  Olivia  Lau.  2007.  “Zelig:  Everyone’s  Statistical  Software.”  

http://GKing.harvard.edu/zelig.  

Jones,  Bryan  and  Frank  Baumgartner  (2005).  The  politics  of  attention.  How  government  prioritizes  

problems,  Chicago:  Chicago  University  Press.    

Klüver,  Heike  (2013).  Lobbying  in  the  European  Union:  Interest  Groups,  lobbying  coalitions  and  policy  

change.  Oxford:  Oxford  University  Press    

 

Klüver,  Heike  &  Nathalie  Giger  (2014).  Voting  against  constituents?  How  lobbying  affect  

representation.  Paper  presented  at  the  Symposium  "Disenchanted  Swiss  Democracy",  Zurich,  23-­‐24  

January  2014.  

Kriesi,  H.  et  al  (2007).  Going  public  in  the  European  Union.  Action  repertoires  of  Western  European  

Collective  Political  Actors,  Comparative  Political  Studies  40(1):48-­‐73.    

Lowery,  David  (2007).  Why  do  organized  interests  lobby?  A  multi-­‐goal,  multi-­‐context  theory  of  

lobbying.  Polity  39  (1):  29-­‐54.  

McKay,  Amy  M.  (2011),  The  decision  to  lobby  bureaucrats.  Public  Choice  147:123-­‐138.  

Markus,  Gregory  B.  1979.  Analyzing  Panel  Data.  Beverly  Hills:  Sage  Publications.  

Miller,  Kenneth  (2009).  Direct  Democracy  and  the  Courts.  New  York:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Mitchell,  Sara  McLaughlin  &  Emilia  Justyna  Powell.  2011.  Domestic  law  goes  global:  Legal  traditions  

and  international  courts.  Cambridge:  Cambridge  University  Press.  

Nownes,  Anthony  J.  &  Patricia  Freeman  (1998).  Interest  group  activity  in  the  States,  The  Journal  of  

Politics  60  (1):86-­‐112.    

Olson,  S.  (1990).  Interest-­‐group  litigation  in  Federal  district  Court:  Beyond  the  Political  Disadvantage  

Theory,  The  Journal  of  Politics,  52  (3):  854-­‐882.  

Park,  Jong  Hee.  2009.  Joint  Modeling  of  Dynamic  and  Cross-­‐Sectional  Heterogeneity:  Introducing  

Hidden  Markov  Panel  Models.  Department  of  Political  Science  University  of  Chicago.  

Powell,  Emilia  Justyna  &  Sara  McLaughlin  Mitchell.  2007.  “The  International  Court  of  Justice  and  the  

World’s  Three  Legal  Systems.”  Journal  of  Politics  69(2):397–415.  

Przeworski,  Adam  &  James  R.  Vreeland.  (2000).  The  Effect  of  IMF  Programs  on  Economic  Growth.”  

Journal  of  Development  Economics  62(2):385–421.  

Schattschneider,  E.E.  (1960).  The  Semi-­‐Sovereign  People,  New  York:  Holt,  Reinhart  &  Winston.  

Schmitter,  Philippe  C.  &  Streeck,  Wolfgang  (1999).  The  Organization  of  Business  Interests:  Studying  

the  Associative  Action  of  Business  in  Advanced  Industrial  Societies.    Koeln:  Max-­‐Planck-­‐Institut  fuer  

Gesellschaftsforschung  Discussion  Paper  99/1.  

Scholzman,  Kay  .L.  (2008).  Who  sings  in  the  heavenly  chorus?  Political  inequality  and  the  pressure  

system.  Paper  presented  at  the  APSA  2008,  Boston  MA.  

   

Solberg,  Rorie  Spill  &  Eric  N.  Waltenburg  (2006).  Why  do  IG  engage  the  judiciary?  Policy  wishes  and  

structural  needs,  Social  science  quarterly  87(3):558-­‐57.  

Stewart,  John  David  (1958).  British  Pressure  Groups:  Their  role  in  relation  to  the  House  of  Commons.  

Oxford:  Clarendon  Press.  

Walker,  Jack  L  (1991).  Mobilizing  Interest  Groups  in  America:  Patrons,  Professions,  and  Social  

Movements.  Ann  Arbor,  MI:  University  of  Michigan  Press.  

Wegmann,  Simone.  2012.  Regional  Human  Rights  Systems.  A  Comparative  Analysis.  Geneva:  Geneva  

Laboratory  of  Political  Science.  

 

   

 

Appendix  1:  Venues  and  binding  decisions  concerning  research  on  human  embryonic  stem  cells  (hESC)  

Chronology  of  the  policy  process  

Legislature  (bill  enacted)   Government  and  Administration  (veto  and  rule-­‐making)  

Judiciary  (court  decision)  

Direct  democracy  (popular  vote  on  initiative)  

2002   (1)  SB  253:  Law  allowing  research  on  hESC  

     

2003   (2)  SB  771:  Law  requiring  an  anonymous  embryos  registry  and  regulating  informed  consent  of  embryos'  donors  

     

2004         (3)  Proposition  71:  Research  on  hESC  is  a  constitutional  right,  $3  billion  investment  over  30  years  and  creation  of  the  California  Institute  for  Regenerative  Medicine  (CIRM)  

2006   (6)  S.B.  1260:  Law  extending  the  duration  of  previous  legislation  and  requiring  a  biannual  reporting  on  hESC  research  

(5)  CIRM  I:  Rules  on  medical  and  ethical  standards  

(4)  Alameda  County  Superior  Court:  Prop  71  is  constitutional  and  the  bonds  issued  are  valid  

 

2007     (7)  CIRM  II:  Rules  on  Intellectual  Property  (IP)  Policy  for  Non-­‐profit  Organisations  

(8)  Court  of  Appeal,  First  District:  Prop  71  is  constitutional  

 

2008     (9)  CIRM  III:  Rules  on  IP  and  Revenue-­‐Sharing  for  For-­‐Profits  

   

2009     (10)  CIRM  IV:  Rules  on  IP  and  Revenue-­‐Sharing  Requirements  for  Non-­‐Profits  and  For-­‐Profit  Grantees  

(11)  CIRM  V:  Rules  on  medical  and  ethical  standards  

   

 

   

   

Appendix  2:  Institutional  venues,  binding  decisions  for  non-­‐resident  aliens’  access  to  higher  education  (DREAM  Act)  

Chronology  of  the  policy  process  

Legislature  (bill  enrolled)  Government  and  Administration  (veto  and  rule-­‐making)  

Judiciary  (court  decision)  

Direct  democracy  (popular  vote  on  initiative)  

2000  (1)  AB  1197  exempts  certain  aliens  from  non-­‐resident  fees  

Veto  of  AB  1197  these  aliens  must  pay  out-­‐of-­‐state  tuition  (no  data,  hence  not  included  in  this  analysis)  

   

2001  

(2)  AB  540  allows  specific  non-­‐residents  to  meet  state  residency  for  establishing  tuition  levels  

     

2005          

2006  

(3)  SB  160  allows  aliens  eligible  for  state  tuition  to  access  all  available  financial  aid  programs  

 

(4)  Veto  of  SB  160:  No  access  to  financial  aid  program  

(5)  Yolo  County  Superior  Court,  Martinez  v.  UC  Regents:  upholds  AB  540:  it  does  not  violate  state  and  federal  law  

 

 

2007   (6)  SB  1  allows  aliens  eligible  for  state  tuition  to  access  to  the  Cal  Grant  program  

(7)  Veto  of  SB  1:  no  access  to  Cal  Grant  program  

   

2008  

(8)  SB  1301  requires  the  CSU  and  CSU,  and  requests  the  UC  to  provide  institutional  financial  aid  to  students  exempt  from  non-­‐resident  tuition.  

(9)  Veto  of  SB  1301:  no  access  to  institutional  financial  aid  

(10)  CA  Court  of  Appeals,  Martinez  v.  UC  Regents:  overturns  Superior  Court:  in-­‐state  tuition  for  “illegal  aliens”  is  preempted  by  federal  law  

 

(11)  CA  Supreme  Court,  Martinez  v.  UC  Regents  petition  for  review  granted  

 

 

2009          

2010  

(12)  AB  1413  &  (13)  SB  1460:  expands  eligibility  for  state-­‐administered  financial  aid  to  students  exempt  from  paying  non-­‐resident  tuition  (and  extends  nonresident  tuition  exemption  to  graduates  of  adult  education  and  technical  schools)  

(13)  Veto  of  SB  1460  &  AB  1413:  no  access  to  financial  aid  programs  

(14)  CA  Supreme  Court,  Martinez  v.  UC  Regents:  verdict  pro  DREAM  Act:  AB  540  holds  

 

 

2011  

(16)  AB  130  all  AB  540  students  are  eligible  for  non-­‐state  derived  scholarship  funds  

(17)  AB  131  expands  eligibility  for  state-­‐administered  student  financial  aid  programs  to  AB  540  students.  

 (15)  SCOTUS,  Martinez  v.  UC  Regents  (petition  denied):  AB  540  holds  

 

 

 

Appendix  3:  Institutional  venues  and  binding  decisions  for  the  California  High  Speed  Rail  (HSR)  

Chronology  of  the  policy  process  

Legislature  (bill  enrolled)  

Government  and  Administration  (veto  and  rule-­‐making)  

Judiciary  (court  decision)   Direct  democracy  (popular  vote  on  initiative)  

2002   (1)  SB  1856  creates  the  bond  Act  to  provide  $9.95  billion  in  bonds  

     

2004   (2)  SB  1169  delays  the  vote  

     

2005          

2008   (3)  AB  713  delays  the  vote  

(4)  AB  3034  revises,  updates  and  expands  the  Bond  Act  

    (5)  Prop  1A:  legislature  –referred  voting  on  the  issuance  of  the  $9  billions  of  bonds:  approved  

2010          

2011          

2012   (7)  SB  1029  approves  construction  financing  for  initial  stage  

  (6)  Superior  Court  679  CHSRA  must  correct  the  defects  identified  in  the  Court’s  ruling  prior  to  reconsidering  the  Environmental  Impact  Report  and  approval  of  the  project    

(8)  Superior  Court  165:  different  groups  settle  with  the  CHSRA  

 

2013       (9)  Superior  Court  002:  CHSRA  must  correct  the  defects  identified  in  the  Court’s  ruling  prior  to  reconsidering  the  Environmental  Impact  Report  and  approval  of  the  project  

(10)  Superior  Court  919:  The  CHSRA  abused  its  discretion,  the  identification  of  the  sources  of  all  funds  and  the  certification  of  environmental  clearance  did  not  comply  with  Prop  1A  

(11)  Superior  Court  689:  CHRSA  seeks  a  validation  of  its  actions,  but  no  evidence  that  it  was  necessary  and  desirable  to  authorize  the  issuance  of  bonds  

(12)  Appellate  Court  877:  Cases  002  &  679  were  appealed  together,  ruling  is  pending  (as  of  March  2014)  

 

 

 

   

   

Appendix  4:  Institutional  venues  and  binding  decisions  for  the  renewables  Portfolio  Standards  (RPS)  

Chronology  of  the  policy  process  

Legislature  (bill  enacted)   Government  and  Administration  (veto  and  rule-­‐making)  

Judiciary  (court  decision)  

Direct  democracy  (popular  vote  on  initiative)  

2002   (1)  SB  1078:  20%  by  2017        

2003          

2004   (2)  SB  1478:  20%  by  2010   (3)  Veto  of  SB  1478      

2006   (4)  SB  107:  20%  by  2010        

2007   (5)  SB  1036  :  implementation  of  RPS  

     

2008     (6)  CPUC  R  04-­‐04-­‐026  

 

Executive  Order  S  1-­‐14-­‐08:  no  data,  therefore  not  included  in  analysis  

  (7)  Prop  7:  40%  by  2020  and  50%  by  2025.  Defeated  

2009   (8)  SB  14  &  AB  64   (9)  Veto  of  SB  14  &  AB  64  

 

Executive  Order  S-­‐21-­‐09:  33%  by  2020.  No  data,  therefore  not  included  

   

2010          

2011   (11)  SB  X1-­‐2:  33%  by  2020,  but  not  only  from  within  CA.  Also  mandates  RPS  compliance  on  POUs  

(10)  CPUC  R  06-­‐05-­‐027      

2012     (12)  CPUC  R  08-­‐08-­‐009      

2013     (13)  CPUC  R  06-­‐02-­‐012  

(14)  CEC  13-­‐RPS-­‐01  

   

 

   

 

Appendix  5:  Sectional  versus  Cause  groups  mobilized  in  Stem  Cells,  as  a  %  of  total  number  of  groups  on  each  decision,  and  organized  along  a  continuum  of  low-­‐  to  high-­‐mobilization  decisions  

 

Venue   Decision  #   Decision   Sectional   Cause  Total  #  of  groups  on  

each  decision  

A   Decision  11   CIRM  V   67%   33%   6  

J   Decision  4   Superior  Court   14%   86%   7  

L   Decision  6   SB  1260   25%   75%   8  

A   Decision  10   CIRM  IV   88%   13%   8  

A   Decision  9   CIRM  III   75%   25%   12  

L   Decision  2   SB  771   6%   94%   16  

A   Decision  7    CIRM  II   78%   22%   18  

L   Decision  1   SB  253   26%   74%   23  

A   Decision  5   CIRM  I   73%   27%   26  

J   Decision  8   Appellate  Court   35%   65%   31  

D   Decision  3   Prop  71   44%   56%   48  

Total  #  of  groups  in  the  policy-­‐process:   154    

 

   

   

Appendix  6:  Sectional  versus  Cause  groups  mobilized  in  Renewables  Portfolio  Standards,  as  a  %  of  total  number  of  groups  on  each  decision,  and  organized  along  a  continuum  of  low-­‐  to  high-­‐mobilization  decisions  

 

Venue   Decision  #   Decision   Sectional   Cause   Total  #  of  groups  per  decision:  

D   7   Prop  7     71%   29%   7  

L   5   SB  1036   72%   28%   18  

A   14   CEC  13-­‐RPS-­‐01   48%   52%   25  

L   1   SB  1078     45%   55%   31  

A   3   Veto  of  SB  1478   32%   68%   31  

L   2   SB  1478     42%   58%   36  

A   10   CPUC  06-­‐05-­‐027   68%   32%   38  

A   6   CPUC  R  04-­‐04-­‐026   62%   38%   45  

L   4   SB  107     44%   56%   50  

A   12   CPUC  R  08-­‐08-­‐009     68%   32%   65  

A   9   Veto  of  SB  14  &  AB  64   58%   42%   96  

A   15   CPUC  R  11-­‐05-­‐005   70%   30%   100  

L   11   SB  X1-­‐2     63%   37%   106  

A   13   CPUC  R  06-­‐02-­‐012   72%   28%   111  

L   8   SB  14  &  AB  64     53%   47%   165  

Total  #  of  groups  across  case:   400  

 

   

 

Appendix  7:  Sectional  versus  Cause  groups  mobilized  in  Immigration,  as  a  %  of  total  number  of  groups  on  each  decision,  

and  organized  along  a  continuum  of  low-­‐  to  high-­‐mobilization  decisions  

 

Venue   Decision  #  (in  time)   Decision   Sectional   Cause  

Total  #  of  groups  on  

each  decision)  

J   11   CA  Supreme  Court  petition   100%   0%   2  

J   5    Superior  Court   100%   0%   4  

J   14   SCOTUS  Writ  of  Certiorari  denied   50%   50%   6  

J   10   Court  of  Appeals   50%   50%   10  

L   1   AB  1197     22%   78%   18  

L   6   SB  1   30%   70%   20  

L   17   AB  1413  &  SB  1460   48%   52%   21  

L   8   SB  1301   41%   59%   22  

A   4   Veto  of  SB  160     68%   32%   25  

J   12   Veto  of  SB  1460   50%   50%   28  

A   9   Veto  of  SB  1301   43%   57%   30  

L   2   AB  540     37%   63%   49  

L   3   SB  160     40%   60%   50  

A   7   Veto  of  SB  1     42%   58%   53  

L   15   AB  130   38%   62%   79  

L   16   AB  131   37%   63%   83  

J   13   CA  Supreme  Court   25%   75%   118  

Total  #  of  groups  across  case:   298  

 

   

   

Appendix  8:  Sectional  versus  Cause  groups  mobilized  in  HSR,  as  a  %  of  total  number  of  groups  on  each  decision,  and  

organized  along  a  continuum  of  low-­‐  to  high-­‐mobilization  decisions  

 

Venue   Decision  #  in  time   Decision   Sectional   Cause  

Total  #  of  groups  on  per  

decision:  

J   10   Superior  Court  #113919   0%   100%   3  

L   7   SB  1029   25%   75%   8  

J   6   Superior  Court  #679   0%   100%   9  

J   9   Superior  Court  #002   0%   100%   9  

J   11   Superior  Court  #140689   11%   89%   9  

L   2   SB  1169   50%   50%   10  

L   3   AB  713   64%   36%   11  

J   8   Superior  Court  #1165   64%   36%   11  

J   12   Appellate  Court   4%   96%   27  

L   1   SB  1856   38%   63%   40  

L   4   AB  3034   24%   76%   71  

D   5   Prop  1A   75%   25%   71  

Total  #  of  groups  across  case:   203