predictability of the us dollar index

Upload: jasonyu

Post on 14-Apr-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    1/17

    Predictability of the U.S. Dollar Index using a U.S.

    export and import price index-based relative PPP model

    Axel Grossmann & Marc W. Simpson

    # Springer Science + Business Media, LLC 2009

    Abstract We use U.S. export and import price indexes to construct a relative

    purchasing power parity-based model of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index. The model

    is successful in predicting the future direction of change in the U.S. Dollar Index

    over a six-month period up to 68% of the time. Finally, the model, in combinationwith a simple linear, recursive technique, is able to statistically significantly

    outperform the random walk in predicting the value of the U.S. Dollar Index at

    terms of less than four months for the period from 1996 to 2005. The paper provides

    important implications for investors who are interested in the direction of change in

    the Dollars value, forecasting the level of the U.S. Dollar Index, as well as the

    extent of over- and undervaluation of the U.S. Dollar, in general.

    Keywords Relative PPP. Equilibrium Exchange Rate .Nominal U.S. Dollar Index .

    Half-Lives . Forecasting

    JEL Classification F31 . F47

    1 Introduction

    Multinational corporations and international investors alike have long been

    interested in either speculating with or hedging foreign currency exposures. While

    A. Grossmann (*)

    Department of Accounting, Finance and Business Law, Radford University, Radford, VA 24142, USA

    e-mail: [email protected]

    M. W. Simpson

    Department of Finance, Northern Illinois University, DeKalb, IL 60115, USA

    e-mail: [email protected]

    J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433

    DOI 10.1007/s12197-009-9102-6

    Published online: 3 September 2009

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    2/17

    many speculators or hedgers are interested in the specific bilateral exchange rates

    between two currencies, others may be interested, broadly, in the general level of the

    U.S. Dollar. The general level of the U.S. Dollar is also of interest to policymakers,

    as it influences the overall level of economic activity, the competitiveness of U.S.

    businesses, and the prices that U.S. consumers pay.All of these market participants and policymakers would find it useful to have a

    guide to the general equilibrium level of the Dollar that perhaps could be used in

    predicting future changes in the Dollars value. Although the last two and a half

    decades have produced innumerable attempts to understand the underlying behavior

    of exchange rates, the academic literature is replete with studies that demonstrate the

    inability of economic models to outperform a random walk in forecasting exchange

    rates (e.g. Meese and Rogoff 1983; Mark 1995; MacDonald and Marsh 1997; Kilian

    1999; Mark and Sul 2001; Qi and Wu 2003; Xu 2003; Nucci 2003).

    Morey and Simpson (2001a), however, demonstrate that a relative purchasingpower parity (PPP)-based model, first proposed by Hakkio (1992), could be useful in

    predicting the direction of change in several bilateral exchange rates. Given the

    importance of the U.S. Dollar Index for investors and policymakers the aim of this

    paper is to: 1) construct a relative PPP-based equilibrium index, or equilibrium

    exchange rate (EER) for the U.S. Dollar over the post-Bretton Woods period (1973

    to 2005) that could allow agents to determine the extent to which the nominal U.S.

    Dollar is over- or undervalued; 2) to investigate, using two different methodologies,

    if deviations from the constructed EER provide any information about the future

    path of the U.S. Dollar. First, following the approach by Hakkio (1992) and Moreyand Simpson (2001a), probabilities of convergence of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index

    towards its constructed EER are calculated. Probabilities higher than 50% would

    indicate that the constructed EER provides investors with some information about

    the future change of the U.S. Dollar. Second, a linear recursive forecasting technique

    is utilized to determine the horizon over which such a relative PPP-based model is

    able to outperform a pure random walk in forecasting the nominal U.S. Dollar Index

    out-of-sample.

    The paper provides the following interesting results. First, the constructed EER

    seems to perform well as a model of the equilibrium level of the U.S. Dollar index as

    we find half-lives of less than 0.60 years for the early post-Plaza Accord period.

    Second, the constructed relative PPP-based EER is successful in predicting the

    direction of change in the nominal U.S. Dollar Index up to 68.4% of the time, which

    indicates that the EER is able to provide investors with some information about the

    future movement of the value of the U.S. Dollar. Finally, we provide evidence that a

    simple, linear, recursive technique that uses the EER is able to statistically

    significantly outperform the random walk in predicating the value of the U.S.

    Dollar index over terms of less than four months.

    2 Background

    PPP has often been suggested by economists as a means to determine the

    fundamental value of a currency. Yet, the empirical evidence of the efficacy of

    PPP, especially with respect to its validity in the medium- and short-run is mixed at

    418 J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    3/17

    best (e.g. Breuer 1994; MacDonald 1995; Froot and Rogoff 1995; Xu 2003).1 Other

    more complex models that have been put forward to construct EERs, particularly

    relating to effective exchange rates, are: 1) the fundamental equilibrium exchange

    rate, which is based on simultaneous attainment of external and internal balance

    (Williamson 1994; Montiel 1999; Wren-Lewis 2003), and 2) the natural realexchange rate, which is based on simultaneous attainment of balance of payments

    equilibrium and a natural rate of unemployment (Stein 1994; Allen 1995; Montiel

    1999). Although those more complex equilibrium models provide promising

    alternatives to PPP (Montiel 1999), they are based on fundamentals for which data

    are only available at quarterly or annually frequencies; hence, they provide little help

    if one wants to determine the aggregate value of the Dollar at shorter frequencies.

    Furthermore, Montiel (1999) acknowledged that:

    [the more complex EERs] have yet not been shown to deliver the robustness

    and precision that would be required for a nonstructural approach. .

    Thus, according to Montiel (1999), despite its limitations, the PPP-based model

    appears to be the most promising approach to constructing an EER.

    A common way to test the appropriateness of an EER is to demonstrate that

    exchange rate reverts towards the constructed equilibrium over time. While many

    academic researchers focus on real exchange rates, this paper uses an alternative

    representation of the relative PPP equilibrium to construct an equilibrium value of

    the nominal U.S. Dollar Index over the post-Bretton Woods period. This alternate

    model was first developed by Hakkio (1992).

    3 The U.S. Dollar equilibrium exchange rate

    Hakkio (1992) uses an approach based on the concept of relative PPP to establish an

    EER, and defines deviations from PPP as the difference between the actual spot

    exchange rate and the constructed EER. The difference between the use of the real

    exchange rate and the Hakkio style equilibrium rate is that: with the real exchange

    rate, one is concerned about the deviation of the real exchange rate from its long-run

    mean, while, with the Hakkio relative PPP EER, one is focusing on the deviation of

    the actual exchange rate from the implied equilibrium rate.

    While Hakkio (1992), who investigates bilateral exchange rates, uses consumer

    price indexes to account for the relative inflation rates in two countries, we use in

    this paper the U.S. export price index in place of a domestic goods price index, and

    we use the U.S. import price index in place of an aggregate foreign goods price

    index that accounts for the price levels of all trading partners. By focusing on the

    prices of traded goods exported from and imported into the U.S., we are more

    accurately capturing the spirit of the PPP hypothesis, which states that only prices of

    those goods that are traded can be arbitraged and therefore affect exchange rates.

    Along those lines, Hinkle and Nsengiyumva (1999) suggested the use of export price

    indexes as proxies for traded goods price indexes, instead of aggregate goods price

    1 For example Rogoff (1999) summarizes that the general consensus in the literature provides evidence

    that the half-lives of deviation of real exchange rates from its long-run value are about 4 to 5 years.

    J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433 419

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    4/17

    indexes. Furthermore, Xu (2003) illustrates that the forecasts of a PPP model based

    on traded goods indices are more accurate than those of models based on either CPI

    or WPI.

    One of the problems with relative PPP, which postulates that the percent change

    in the rate of exchange between two countries currencies should be equal to theinflation rate differentials between the two countries, is that it does not tell us the

    level of the EER. If, however, one assumes that the spot exchange rate is in

    equilibrium at a specific point in time, one could construct the EER in the period t +

    1 as follows:

    EERt1 ffi St 1 pt p*t

    ; 1

    where EERt+1 is the equilibrium exchange rate at time t+1,St is the nominal

    exchange rate, andpt

    and p

    *t are the percentage changes in inflation of the domesticand foreign country, respectively.2

    Instead of assuming that the exchange rate is in equilibrium at a given point in

    time, which obviously biases the level of the EER, it is more realistic to assume that

    PPP holds, on average, over a longer time span. Hence, Hakkio (1992) constructed

    36 EER series using each of the 36 monthly observations in the base period from

    1980 to 1982 as a starting point.3 After these 36 different equilibrium exchange rates

    series are created, an average across all 36 series at each observation represents the

    EER (see Appendix A for a more detailed explanation on how the equilibrium

    exchange rate is constructed).

    Of course, any such constructed EER could be biased by the choice of the base

    period. Morey and Simpson (2001a, b), Simpson (2003), and Grossmann et al.

    (2009) all use a Hakkio-style relative PPP-based equilibrium exchange rate like the

    one used in this study. These researchers carry out their analyses, each using a

    number of different base periods, and find little qualitative differences in the results

    of their studies. For robustness, this study reports its main results utilizing different

    base periods as well as a rolling base period. For example, the EER, using a rolling

    base period of the entire post-Bretton Woods period, is created by constructing the

    first EER using the base period from 1973 to 1975 and then moving the base period

    forward by 1 year. Following this approach 31 EERs are constructed over the entiresample period. Finally, the average of the 31 EERs represents the EER using a

    rolling base period spanning the entire post-Bretton Woods period.

    Figure 1 shows the constructed relative PPP-based EER of the nominal U.S.

    Dollar Index using the rolling base period spanning the entire post-Bretton Woods

    period. Additionally, Fig. 2 graphs the percent misalignments of the nominal U.S

    Dollar Index from its constructed EER. Both figures demonstrate the wide initial

    misalignment of the U.S. Dollar after the collapse of the Bretton Woods system, as

    2 In our case, the nominal exchange rate is the major nominal U.S. Dollar Index obtained from the Federal

    Reserve web-page, and the inflation rate differentials are calculated using import and export price indexes

    from DataStream, where they are quoted (?I74F) and (?I75F), respectively. The index is constructed

    in such a way that, as the U.S. Dollar appreciates, the index level rises.3 Hakkio (1992) claimed that the world economy was in equilibrium during that time. Furthermore, the

    period coincides with the beginning of the Reagan administration, during which the U.S. initially did not

    intervene in the foreign exchange rate market.

    420 J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    5/17

    well as, the success of the Plaza Accord at the end of 1985 in bringing the highlyovervalued U.S. Dollar back to its equilibrium.

    4 Predictability of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index

    Lagged U.S. export and import price indexes and a rolling base period spanning the

    period from 1973 to 1985 are utilized in the subsequent predictions of the nominal

    U.S. Dollar Index. This ensures that we only use information available at the time

    forecasts are made. Consequently, predictions are made over the entire post-PlazaAccord period (1986 to 2005), as well as the two sub-periods (1986 to 1995 and

    1996 to 2005). For robustness, the analysis is also done using the base period from

    1973 to 1975, as well as the base period from 1980 to 1982.

    4.1 Mean reversion of the U.S. Dollar Index

    If one wants to analyze the predictability of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index based on

    a constructed EER, one needs to show the appropriateness of such a perceived

    equilibrium. The literature generally defines a proper EER by the reverting behavior

    of the exchange rate towards the constructed equilibrium.

    The most common approach in the literature to show that any exchange rate

    converges towards its equilibrium is to calculate half-lives using the estimated roots

    60

    70

    80

    90100

    110

    120

    130

    140

    150

    74 77 80 83 86 89 92 96 99 02 05

    U.S. Dollar Index Rolling PPP-based EER

    Fig. 1 U.S. Dollar Index and rolling PPP-based equilibrium

    -30%

    -20%

    -10%

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    74 77 80 83 86 89 92 96 99 02 05

    Fig. 2 U.S. Dollar Index percent under-and overvaluation

    J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433 421

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    6/17

    of constructed real exchange rates from stationary tests or EngleGranger

    cointegration tests. The literature reports half-lives of around 2 to 5 years using

    consumer price indexes (e.g. Rogoff1996; Xu 2003); while Xu (2003), using traded-

    goods price indexes and the roots from a trivariate EngleGranger cointegration test,

    finds half-lives of around 1 year for some of the countries in his analysis. 4 In thisstudy, we suggest an alternative way to calculate half-lives, which does not rely on

    any stationarity test of the real exchange rate. That is to say, we use the obtained

    misalignments to calculate the mean lifetimes it takes the nominal U.S. Dollar Index

    to converge to its constructed EER. Second, half-lives are derived from the

    calculated mean lifetimes based on Eq. (2):

    T1=2 ln2t; 2

    where T1/2 represents the half-lives and t the mean lifetime (see Appendix B for a

    detailed explanation how mean lifetimes can be converted into half-lives). Table 1reports the half-lives of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index over the whole Bretton

    Woods period, as well as the four sub-periods. Remarkably, the half-lives are less

    than 2.2 years for the entire post-Plaza Accord Period and even less than 0.6 years

    for the sub-period from 1986 to 1995, which provides strong evidence in favor of the

    relative PPP-model utilized in this study.

    4.2 Probabilities

    Hakkio (1992) and Morey and Simpson (2001a) show how one can use constructedPPP-based EERs to calculate the probability that a nominal exchange rate will

    converge towards its equilibrium over a given future time period. A probability of

    50% or higher would suggest that the constructed EER provides useful information

    about the future movement of the nominal exchange rate, while any probability of

    less than 50% would leave investors with the suggestion that any guess of the future

    exchange rate path provides the same predictive power as PPP. Based on the

    approach proposed by Hakkio (1992) the probabilities are calculated as follows:

    PROB NOHEERNOLEERNTO

    100;NOHEER stk < st and st > EERt ;NOLEER stk > st and st < EERt ;

    3

    where NOHEER represents the number of observations where nominal U.S. Dollar

    Index (St) is higher than the EER and moves towards the EER over a given future

    horizon; NOLEER represents the number of observations where the nominal U.S.

    Dollar Index (St) is lower than the EER and moves towards the EER over a given

    future horizon; while NTO represents the number of total observations.

    4 There are two problems that arise with estimating roots of constructed real exchange rates from

    stationary tests or EngleGranger cointegration tests. First, these tests seem to provide low power over

    short-time periods, which makes it difficult to determine if the real exchange rate is stationary (Froot and

    Rogoff 1995). Second, the trivariate EngleGranger cointegration tests fail to incorporate the symmetry

    and proportionality restrictions, which are implied if PPP holds (e.g. Breuer 1994). Therefore, one may

    conclude that the commonly used methodologies suggested in the literature do not provide appropriate

    tools to test if PPP holds, and especially not during the post-Bretton Woods period.

    422 J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    7/17

    Furthermore, since the literature points out that there might be a threshold band

    around the EER in between which forces of PPP are rather weak (Hakkio 1992;

    Sercu et al. 1995; MacDonald 2000), we also calculate probabilities using only large

    deviations from the EER. In this case one can expect that forces of PPP are stronger

    when the exchange rate goes beyond the threshold band; hence, the success rate to

    predict the future nominal exchange rate should increase. We define large deviations

    as those which are larger than the moving average of the absolute values of the

    misalignments over the past 5 years.

    Table 2 reports the success rates of correctly predicting the direction of the future

    spot exchange rates over the entire post-Plaza Accord Period (Panel A), the period

    from 1986 to 1995 (Panel B), and the period from 1996 to 2005 (Panel C), over

    horizons of 1 month, 3 months, and 6 months, respectively. Table 2, column 2,

    Table 1 Half-lives of the U.S. Dollar Index. This table reports the half-lives it takes for the nominal

    effective U.S. Dollar exchange rate to converge to the constructed equilibrium exchange rate. The half-

    lives are calculated based on mean lifetimes as shown in the appendix

    Number of Observations Half-Lives

    73-05 (whole sample period) 396 2.20

    73-85 (pre-Plaza Accord) 156 1.75

    86-05 (post-Plaza Accord) 540 2.56

    86-95 (post-Plaza Accord; first subperiod) 120 3.95

    96-05 (post-Plaza Accord; second subperiod) 120 0.57

    Table 2 Probability that the nominal U.S. Dollar Index will converge towards its EER. This table reports

    the probabilities that the nominal U.S. Dollar Index will revert towards the constructed equilibrium

    exchange rate over a given future time horizon. A probability higher than 50 percent indicates that the

    constructed equilibrium exchange rate provides useful information about the future movement of the U.S.

    Dollar Index

    Future Time Horizon Rolling Base Period Rolling Base Period Base Period Base Period19731984 19731984 Large 19731975 19801982

    Panel A: 1986 to 2005

    1 month 51.0% 50.0% 51.5% 54.8%

    3 months 58.2% 61.2% 54.4% 61.2%

    6 months 59.4% 62.1% 55.6% 63.2%

    Panel B: 1986 to 1995

    1 month 47.5% 50.0% 45.0% 51.7%

    3 months 53.3% 65.5% 50.8% 60.8%

    6 months 50.8% 67.2% 48.3% 61.7%

    Panel C: 1996 to 2005

    1 month 54.6% 50.0% 58.0% 58.0%

    3 months 63.2% 55.0% 58.1% 61.5%

    6 months 68.4% 54.1% 63.2% 64.9%

    J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433 423

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    8/17

    shows that the success rates are all higher than 50% for all three sub-periods, with an

    exception for the 1-month prediction horizon during the 1986 to 1995 period.

    Moreover, during the second half of the post-Plaza Accord period (Panel C), the

    success rate reaches over 68% for the 6-month prediction horizon. This means, for

    example, that once the U.S. Dollar is undervalued one may be able to predict that thevalue of the Dollar will increase over the next 6 months. Focusing only on large

    misalignments increases the success rate even further, with exception for the period

    from 1996 to 2005 (column 3). Columns 4 and 5 indicate that the calculated

    probabilities are robust with respect to the choice of different base periods, since the

    success rates differ only slightly from those reported in column 2.

    4.3 The recursive linear forecasting methodology

    The forecasting methodology in this study encompasses two main steps. The firststep relates the change of the actual nominal U.S. Dollar Index to the misalignment

    of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index in the previous period. The second step simply

    models the misalignments as an AR(1) process.

    For example, to find the one-month ahead forecast of the nominal U.S. Dollar

    Index at any time, where t is any date in between and including December 1985

    through November 2005, the following OLS regression is fit using all of the

    available monthly observations from January 1973 to time t:

    st st1 ab st1 eerPPP

    t1 "t; 4where st is the log of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index at time t, and eer

    PPPt is the log of

    the relative PPP-based EER at time t. Given the coefficients from Eq. (4), the one-

    month ahead forecast at time of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index, denoted Et[s

    t+1], is:

    Et st1 st bat bbt st eerPPPt h i; 5where ba

    t is the intercept coefficient from estimating Eq. (4) using all available

    observations from January 1973 up to, and including, those at time t, and bbt is theslope coefficient from estimating Eq. (4) using all available observations from

    January 1973 up to, and including, those at time t.

    To forecast the one-month ahead forecast at time t + 1, i.e., Et+1[st+2], Eq. (4) is

    re-estimated using all available observations from January 1973 to time t + 1, and

    the variables substituted into Eq. (5), with updated time subscripts.

    The forecast of the n-month ahead nominal U.S. Dollar Index is done via an n-step

    process where forecasts at later steps depend on forecasts generated in earlier steps. For

    example, to forecast the two-month ahead U.S. Dollar Index at time t one must first

    forecast the one-month ahead U.S. Dollar Index at time t. In addition to the forecastof the U.S. Dollar Index from earlier steps, the model also requires a forecast of the

    nominal U.S. Dollar Index misalignments. Therefore, we fit the following OLS

    regression using all available observations from January 1973 to time t:

    st eerPPPt m g st1 eer

    PPPt1

    ht: 6

    424 J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    9/17

    Given the coefficients from Eq. (4), the two-month ahead forecast at time t,

    denoted Et[s

    t+2], is:

    Et st2 Et st1 bat

    bb

    tEt st1 eer

    PPPt1 h i

    ; 7

    where the one-month ahead forecast of the nominal U.S. Dollar Index misalign-

    ments, Et st1 eerPPPt1

    , is found by using the coefficients from Eq. (6), as follows:

    Et st1 eerPPPt1

    bmt bgt st eerPPPt : 8

    where bmt is the intercept coefficient from estimating Eq. (6) using all availableobservations from January 1973 up to, and including, those at time t, and bgt is theslope coefficient from estimating Eq. (6) using all available observations from

    January 1973 up to, and including, those at time t.To forecast the nominal U.S. Dollar Index, three, or more, months into the future,

    the process becomes one of recursively substituting the appropriate coefficient

    estimates and previous forecasts into the following two formulas:

    Et stn Et stn1 bat bbtEt stn1 eerPPPtn1 h i; for all n ! 3; 9and

    Et

    stn

    eerPPPtn bmt bgtEt stn1 eerPPPtn1 ; for all n ! 3: 10

    Given that the nominal U.S. Dollar Index has been converted into logs for the

    estimation procedures, before calculating the forecast error, we first convert the

    forecasts back into common numbers by taking the antilog of the forecast:

    Et Stn eEt stn for all n 1; 2; 3; . . . 24: 11

    Next, for each forecast, we calculate the n-month ahead squared error of the

    relative PPP-based model:

    SEPPPtn Stn Et Stn

    2

    for all n 1; 2; 3; . . . 24: 12

    Finally, using all of the n-month ahead squared errors in each sample period we

    compute the mean squared error (MSE):

    MSEPPPtn Xxi1

    SEPPPtn

    i

    xfor all n 1; 2; 3; . . . 24; 13

    where SEPPPtn

    iis the squared error of the ithn-month ahead forecast of the PPP-

    based model in the sample period containing x such forecasts.

    The forecast accuracy measured by the mean squared errors (MSE) of the aboverelative PPP-based model is compared to that of a nave random walk. If the nominal

    U.S. Dollar Index follows a random walk, then one would expect the value of future

    U.S. Dollar to be simply the value of the exchange rate today:

    ERWt Stn St; for all n 1; 2; 3; . . . 24: 14

    J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433 425

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    10/17

    The squared error MSE of the random walk model is given by Eqs. (15) and (16)

    SERWtn Stn St 2; for all n 1; 2; 3; . . . 24; 15

    MSERWtn Xxi1

    SERWtn

    i

    x: 16

    The comparisons of the forecast accuracy of the relative PPP-based model and the

    random walk are structured in such a way that all of the out-of-sample tests have the

    same number of observations. Thus, the estimations of the one-month forecasts

    begin with the one-month forecast generated, given all of the data up to, and

    including, December 1985 (thus, it is a forecast of the exchange rate in January

    1986), while the two-month forecasts begin with the forecast generated, given all ofthe data up to, and including, November 1985 (thus, it also is a forecast of the

    exchange rate in January 1985), and so forth.

    Tables 3 and 4 report the percent difference between the MSE of the relative PPP-

    based model against the random walk model, which is measured as follows:

    %DMSE MSEPPP MSERW

    MSERW; 17

    whereMSEPPP represents the MSE of the forecast from the relative PPP-based model,

    and MSE

    RW

    is the MSE of the random walk model for the specific time period andforecast horizon. By construction, a negative percent change MSE indicates that the

    relative PPP-based model provides better forecast accuracy than the random walk

    model. Tests of statistical significance of the percent change MSE are performed

    using a one tailed t-test with the null hypothesis that the MSEs are equal for the

    relative PPP-based model and the random walk model, against an alternate hypothesis

    that the MSEs of the relative PPP-based model are less than the MSEs of the random

    walk model. The forecasts are made over horizons of 1 month to 24 months.

    Table 3 illustrates that for the period immediately following Plaza Accord (1986

    to 1995) the relative PPP-based model is not able to outperform the random walk

    model over any of the 24-month horizon. The results do not change if we use the

    1973 to 1975 base period (column 3) or the1980 to1982 base period (column 4)

    instead of the rolling base period spanning from 1973 to 1985 (column 2).

    Table 4 reports the percent change MSE covering the period from 1996 to 2005,

    which provides very encouraging results. Using the rolling base period (column 2), the

    relative PPP-based model statistically significantly (at the 5% level) outperforms the

    random walk model at terms of less than 4 months. Columns 3 and 4 of Table 4

    demonstrate that the finding is fairly robust with respect to the choice of the base period.

    5 Conclusion

    Market participants and policymakers have long searched for a tool to determine the

    equilibrium value of the U.S. Dollar. In this paper, we investigate a relative PPP-

    based model using U.S. import and export price indexes. Moreover, while the literature

    426 J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    11/17

    on exchange rate forecasting has found that models based on pure macroeconomic

    fundamentals are not very helpful in providing information for the path of exchange

    rates, this paper reports promising results for the nominal U.S. Dollar Index.

    The constructed EER provides strong evidence in favor of the relative PPP-model, as the half-lives deviations from the equilibrium are less than 2.2 years for

    the entire post-Bretton Woods period. Notably, half-lives are less than 0.60 years for

    the later post-Plaza Accord period.

    This paper illustrates that the constructed relative PPP-based EER is able to

    provide a rule of thumb for investors in predicting the future movements of the U.S.

    Table 3 Percent difference in forecast errors for 1986 to 1995. This table reports the percent difference in

    mean squared errors of the out-of sample forecasts of the export and import price index PPP-based model

    and the mean squared errors of the random walk model. A negative number indicates that the PPP-based

    model has a lower mean squared error by the given percentage. The tests for statistical significance come

    from a one tailed T-test with a null hypothesis that the mean squared errors are equal for the PPP-based

    model and for the random walk, against an alternate hypothesis that the mean squared errors of the PPP-based model are less than the mean squared errors of the random walk model

    Forecast Horizon Rolling Base Period Base Period Base Period

    19731983 19731975 19801982

    19861995 19861995 19861995

    1 month 0.86 0.73 4.54

    2 months 1.16 1.04 6.59

    3 months 1.36 1.19 8.71

    4 months 1.51 1.34 11.13

    5 months 1.74 1.54 13.68

    6 months 2.02 1.68 16.73

    7 months 2.86 2.32 21.04

    8 months 4.07 3.32 26.00

    9 months 5.10 4.16 30.68

    10 months 7.70 6.47 38.94

    11 months 10.04 8.62 47.17

    12 months 11.11 9.68 52.32

    13 months 11.67 10.33 56.21

    14 months 12.11 10.83 59.62

    15 months 12.69 11.46 64.09

    16 months 13.26 12.10 68.66

    17 months 13.75 12.70 72.83

    18 months 14.32 13.42 77.76

    19 months 14.91 14.21 82.07

    20 months 15.33 14.85 85.87

    21 months 15.78 15.51 89.31

    22 months 16.40 16.27 92.78

    23 months 16.91 16.88 96.18

    24 months 17.28 17.35 99.89

    J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433 427

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    12/17

    Dollar Index, as the rate of success in predicting the future direction of the nominal

    U.S. Dollar Index is more than 68% for the 6-month term, during the 1995 to 2005

    period. Furthermore, the paper provides evidence that a simple, linear, recursive

    technique applied to the relative PPP-based model is able to statistically significantlyoutperform the random walk in predicting the value of the U.S. Dollar Index at

    horizons of less than 4 months.

    Consequently, this paper fills an important void in the literature with respect to the

    misalignment of the U.S. Dollar Index, as well as predictability of its future path.

    This information may be important for any participant in the foreign exchange rate

    Table 4 Percent difference in forecast errors for 1996 to 2005. This table reports the percent difference in

    mean squared errors of the out-of sample forecasts of the export and import price index PPP-based model

    and the mean squared errors of the random walk model. A negative number indicates that the PPP-based

    model has a lower mean squared error by the given percentage. The tests for statistical significance come

    from a one tailed T-test with a null hypothesis that the mean squared errors are equal for the PPP-based

    model and for the random walk, against an alternate hypothesis that the mean squared errors of the PPP-based model are less than the mean squared errors of the random walk model

    Forecast Horizon Rolling Base Period Base Period Base Period

    19731983 19731975 19801982

    19962005 19962005 19962005

    1 month 0.73 0.55 0.66

    2 months 1.67 1.43 1.56

    3 months 2.59a 2.22 2.44a

    4 months 3.54b 3.07a 3.37a

    5 months 4.55b 3.96b 4.41b

    6 months 5.62c 4.84b 5.55c

    7 months 6.56c 5.54c 6.56c

    8 months 7.31c 6.06c 7.34c

    9 months 7.97c 6.54c 8.02c

    10 months 8.56c 7.04c 8.63c

    11 months 9.17c 7.72c 9.30c

    12 months 9.81c 8.46c 10.00c

    13 months 10.34c 9.14c 10.61c

    14 months 10.88c 9.74c 11.23c

    15 months 11.51c 10.40c 11.98c

    16 months 12.12c 11.04c 12.71c

    17 months 12.59c 11.64c 13.28c

    18 months 12.99c 12.18c 13.80c

    19 months 13.28c 12.66c 14.18c

    20 months 13.55c 13.12c 14.54c

    21 months 13.87c 12.60c 14.97c

    22 months 14.19c 14.06c 15.41c

    23 months 14.41c 14.37c 15.75c

    24 months 14.59c 14.62c 16.07c

    a, b, c indicate statistical significance at the 10%, 5%, and 1% levels, respectively

    428 J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    13/17

    market (i.e. investors trading U.S. Dollar Index future contracts or exchange traded

    funds based on these contracts) and to foreign and domestic policymakers.

    Appendix A

    Construction of the Hakkio based equilibrium exchange rate

    To illustrate exactly how the relative PPP equilibrium rate is constructed, assume we

    use the nominal U.S. Dollar Index in January 1980 of 94.750. Now further assume

    the inflation for the U.S. based on the U.S. export price index was 3.5% and the

    inflation for the foreign countries based on the U.S. import price index was 2.4%. In

    this case, the implied change in the relative PPP equilibrium exchange rate between

    January and February 1980 would be (3.5%2.4%) = 1.1 percent, meaning that the

    relative PPP equilibrium exchange rate for the U.S. Dollar Index for February 1980

    is 95.792 [i.e., 94.750 (1 + 0.0350.024) = 95.792]. One could then use the

    percent changes in the U.S. export price index and the U.S. import price index to

    construct the implied relative PPP equilibrium rate for each month in the entire

    sample period. The next step would be to construct 36 such equilibrium rate series

    using different actual exchange rates as the starting point. For example, the next

    actual exchange rate to be used would be the U.S. Dollar Index in February 1980.

    Once these 36 different equilibrium exchange rate series were created one could take

    an average across all 36 series at each observation to come up with the equilibrium

    exchange rate. Note that once the level of the equilibrium exchange rate is establishedin the base period, the only thing that causes a change in the equilibrium exchange rate

    in periods subsequent to the 36-month base period is the difference in the percent

    change of the U.S. export and import price index. That is, once the base period is used

    to establish the level of the equilibrium exchange rate, any subsequent changes in the

    level of the equilibrium exchange rate is driven entirely by relative inflation rates.

    1 2 3 35 36 Average

    Jan-73 / 36

    Feb-74 / 36

    / 36

    / 36

    Jan-80 94.750 93.314 91.663 / 36

    Feb-80 95.792 94.375 92.706 / 36

    Mar-80 100.250 98.941 97.191 / 36

    99.818 / 36

    118.527 117.624 / 36

    Nov-82 117.435 116.541 / 36

    Dec-82 116.568 115.686 / 36/ 36

    / 36

    Nov-05 / 36

    Dec-05 / 36

    Fig. 3 Construction of the relative equilibrium exchange rate

    J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433 429

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    14/17

    Appendix B

    Calculating half-lives5

    A general approach in the literature to calculate half-lives is to obtain the coefficientfrom an EngleGranger cointegration test. This can be done in two different ways.

    One can test whether the real exchange rate follows a stationary process or if the

    residuals of the regression of the log spot exchange rates on domestic and foreign

    log price indexes are stationary. In either case, the following relationship is obtained:

    M0=2

    M0 bT; A:1

    where Trepresents the half-life, andM0=2M0

    is the ratio with which the deviations from

    the exchange rate decay on average to a stationary process over the half-life T.Rearranging Eq. (A.1) allows one to derive the half-life from the obtained

    coefficient as shown in Eq. (A.2):

    T ln 0:5

    ln b : A:2

    For example, if is equal to 0.7071 the half-life (T) would be two time periods

    (2t), if is equal to 0.5 the half-life (T) would be one time period (1t), and if is

    equal to 0.25 the half-life (T) would be half a time period (1/2t), and so on.

    The general decaying pattern can be graphed as shown in Fig. 4, where one canderive the following relationship:

    M M02tT : A:3

    Further, assuming that T = 2tand substituting it into Eq. (A.3) one gets after one

    time period or half a half-life the following:

    M

    M0 2

    12 0:7071: A:4

    This means that after one-time period, or half a half-life, the deviations decay onaverage to 70.71% of their previous values, which is the same as obtaining a of

    0.7071. This can easily be shown by substituting = 0.7071 and T = 2 into

    Eq. (A.1).

    bT M0=2

    M0 0:70712 0:5 A:5

    Moreover, the change in the decay of the exchange rate deviations from its

    equilibrium in any given time interval t can be expressed as follows:

    DM lMDt; A:6

    5 Part of the presented material in this appendix, which follows the approach of calculating the decaying of

    particles in chemistry, can be found at the following web-page:http://hyperphysics.phy-astr.gsu.edu/hbase/nuclear/meanlif.html

    4 J Econ Finan (2011) 35:41743330

    http://hyperphysics.phy-astr.gsu.edu/hbase/nuclear/meanlif.htmlhttp://hyperphysics.phy-astr.gsu.edu/hbase/nuclear/meanlif.html
  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    15/17

    where 1 is the decaying constant. Writing Eq. (A.6) in differential form one gets:

    dM lM dt ordM

    M ldt: A:7

    Integrating Eq. (A.7) leads to lnM lt C and taking the exponent of bothsides one gets:

    M eCelt A:8

    with M

    eC

    M

    0at time t = 0, Eq. (A.9) is derived:

    M M0elt: A:9

    Given Eqs. (A.3) and (A.9) one can write the following:

    M

    M0 2

    tT elt: A:10

    Taking the logarithm of Eq. (A.10) and rearranging it leads to the following

    expression:

    1l

    Tln2 : A:11

    Calculating the mean lifetime

    Given Eq. (A.9) the probability of decay can be expressed as the following

    distribution function:

    fdecayt Melt: A:12

    To normalize this distribution function:

    Z10

    fdecaytdt

    Z10

    Meltdt 1

    lMelt j

    1

    0

    M

    l 1 thus; M l A:13

    The probability of decay within a time period t is given by the integral of the

    decay distribution function from 0 to t. To obtain the mean lifetime, however, one

    0 1 2 3 4 5 6 T

    Time as a multiple of the halflife T

    AbsoluteMisalignment

    M0

    M0/2

    M0/8

    M0/16M0/32

    M0/4

    Fig. 4 Graph of decaying absolute misalignments

    J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433 431

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    16/17

    needs to calculate the average time the deviation will exist without decaying. Hence,

    the probability of no decay at time t can be expressed as follows:

    Pt 1 Zt

    0le

    lt

    dt 1 elt

    j

    t

    0 elt

    : 14

    The average survival time is now the mean value (mean lifetime) of the above

    probability:

    t

    Z10

    teltdt: 15

    Integrating by parts:

    d (uv) = udv + vdu

    u = t so that du = 1 and dv eltdt so that v 1l

    elt

    t

    Z10

    t eltdt 1

    lelt j

    1

    0

    Z10

    1

    leltdt

    1

    lelt j

    1

    0

    1

    l: A:16

    Substituting Eq. (A.16) into Eq. (A.11) one can calculate mean lifetimes as shown

    in Eq. (A.17):

    t Tln2

    : A:17

    Rearranging Eq. (A.17) allows the calculation of the half-lives, once the mean

    lifetime of the absolute misalignments is calculated:

    T ln2t: A:18

    References

    Allen PR (1995) The economic and policy implications of the NATREX approach. In: Stein JL, Allen PR

    et al (eds) Fundamental determinants of exchange rates. Clarendon, Oxford, pp 137

    Breuer J (1994) An assessment of the evidence on purchasing power parity. In: Williamson J (ed)

    Estimating equilibrium exchange rates. Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC, pp

    245277

    Froot KA, Rogoff K (1995) Perspective on PPP and long-run real exchange rates. In: Grossman G,

    Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of international economics, vol III. Elsevier Science B. V., Amsterdam, pp

    16471688

    Grossmann A, Simpson MW, Brown CJ (2009) The Impact of Deviation from Relative Purchasing PowerParity Equilibrium on U.S. Foreign Direct Investment. Q Rev Econ Finance 49:521550

    Hakkio CS (1992) Is purchasing power parity a useful guide to the dollar? Economic Review, Federal

    Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp 3751

    Hinkle LE, Nsengiyumva F (1999) External real exchange rates: purchasing power parity, the Mundell-

    Fleming model, and competitiveness in traded goods. In: Hinkle LE, Montiel PJ (eds) Exchange rate

    misalignment: concepts and measurement for developing countries. Oxford University Press, New

    York, pp 4198

    432 J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433

  • 7/30/2019 Predictability of the US Dollar Index

    17/17

    Kilian L (1999) Exchange rates and monetary fundamentals: what do we learn from long-horizon

    regressions? Journal of Applied Econometrics 14:491510

    MacDonald R (1995) Long-run exchange rate modeling: a survey of the recent evidence. IMF Staff Paper

    42:437487

    MacDonald R (2000) Concepts to calculate equilibrium exchange rates: an overview. Discussion paper 3/

    00, Economic Research Group of the Deutsche Bundesbank, Frankfurt, GermanyMacDonald R, Marsh IW (1997) On fundamentals and exchange rates: a casselian perspective. Review of

    Economics and Statistics 79:655664

    Mark NC (1995) Exchange rates and fundamentals: evidence on long-horizon prediction. American

    Economic Review 85:201218

    Mark NC, Sul D (2001) Nominal exchange rates and monetary fundamentals: evidence from a small post-

    bretton woods panel. Journal of International Economics 53:2952

    Montiel PJ (1999) The long-run equilibrium real exchange rate: conceptual issues and empirical research.

    In: Hinkle LE, Montiel PJ (eds) Exchange rate misalignment: concepts and measurement for

    developing countries. Oxford University Press, New York, pp 4198

    Morey MR, Simpson MW (2001a) Predicting foreign exchange directional moves: can simple

    fundamentals help? Journal of Investing 10:4351

    Morey MR, Simpson MW (2001b) To hedge or not to hedge: the performance of simple strategies forhedging foreign exchange risk. Journal of Multinational Financial Management 11:213223

    Meese RA, Rogoff K (1983) Empirical exchange rate models of the seventies: do they fit out of sample?

    Journal of International Economics 14:324

    Nucci F (2003) Cross-currency, cross-maturity forward exchange premiums as predictors of the spot rate

    changes: theory and evidence. Journal of Banking and Finance 27:183200

    Qi M, Wu Y (2003) Nonlinear prediction of exchange rates with monetary fundamentals. Journal of

    Empirical Finance 10:623640

    Rogoff K (1996) The purchasing power parity puzzle. Journal of Economic Literature 647668

    Sercu P, Uppal R, Van Hulle C (1995) The exchange rate in the presence of transaction costs: implication

    for tests of purchasing power parity. Journal of Finance 50:13091319

    Simpson MW (2003) Selectively hedging the U.S. dollar with foreign exchange futures contracts. Journalof International Financial Markets, Institutions, and Money 14:7586

    Stein J (1994) The natural real exchange rate of the U.S. dollar and determinants of capital flows.

    Estimating Equilibrium Exchange Rates. Institute for International Economics, Washington

    Williamson J (1994) Estimates of FEERS. In: Williamson J (ed) Estimating equilibrium exchange rates.

    Institute for International Economics, Washington

    Wren-Lewis S (2003) Estimates of equilibrium exchange rates for sterling against the Euro. HM-Treasury,

    London

    Xu Z (2003) Purchasing power parity, price indices, and exchange rate forecast. Journal of International

    Money and Finance 22:105130

    J Econ Finan (2011) 35:417433 433