Download - Tecnical Education

Transcript

CHAPTER ONEInvestment in Human Capital Development: A Theoretical and Empirical Review

Human capital is a broad concept, covering many characteristics contributing to grow an individuals, firms or societys productivity. It includes not only knowledge and skills but also talents, leadership qualities, work ethics and health etc. According to economists, the ability of an economy to accumulate a high quality of human capital is an important factor of economic development. Human capital theory assumes that education is highly instrumental and necessary to improve the productive capacity of a population.

The aim of this chapter is to describe briefly the human capital theory, importance of education, mainly the Technical Education and Vocational Training (TVET), positive experiences gained by some developed countries and importance of TVET for developing countries like Sri Lanka in human capital development.

This chapter is divided into four sections. The first section is devoted to discuss the theoretical background of human capital and effects of human capital on economic development. The second section analyses the importance of education in human capital development. The third section presents definitions of the term Technical and Vocational Education and Training (TVET), and then examines the importance of Technical and Vocational Education and Training in human capital development and the relevant positive experiences of developed countries. The fourth section touches on the importance of TVET for developing countries in their development struggle.

1.1 Human Capital Theory

In general terms, human capital is considered as the investment an individual makes in him/herself to enhance his/her economic productivity. In a broader sense, human capital is the stock of competencies, knowledge, social and personality attributes, including creativity, embodied in the ability to perform labor so as to produce economic value. The definition of human capital is referred to as the knowledge, skills, competencies, and attributes embodied in individuals that facilitate the creation of personal, social and economic well-being (Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development OECD, 2001: 18).

British economists, Sir William Petty (1623-1687) and Adam Smith (1723-1790) are recognized as the developers of human capital theory. Petty in his Treatise of Taxes and Contributions (1662) examined the role of the state in the economy and presented the idea on the value of labor. Adam Smith established the basis of the economics of human capital (Becker, 1992). In his masterpiece, The Wealth of Nations (1776), Smith elaborated his theories with the prosperity or a wealth of a nation. According to Smith, the main cause of prosperity was increasing division of labor. He is recognized as the first to make a connection between the skill of the worker and higher wage levels (Becker, 1992). However, traditional economists considered land, labor and physical capital as factors of production. From the perspective of classical economic theory, human capital considers labor as a commodity which can be traded in terms of purchase and sale. In 1958, Schultz, in his essay on The Emerging Economic Science and its Relation to High School Education, elaborated people as the source of economic growth and described human capital as follows; Consider all human abilities to be either innate or acquired. Every person is born with a particular set of genes, which determines his innate ability. Attributes of acquired population quality, which are valuable and can be augmented by appropriate investment, will be treated as human capital (quoted in Fitz-enz, 2000: 21).

In the early 1960s increasing attention was paid to the level of education and training in the work place and it gave rise to the concept of human capital (OECD: 2001). Two schools of thought regarding human capital concept emerged, over the next two centuries. The first school of thought distinguished between acquired capacities that were classified as capital on the one hand and human beings themselves who were not capital on the other. The second school of thought claimed that human beings themselves were capital. In modern human capital theory, all human behavior is based on the economic self-interest of individuals operating within a freely competitive market (Barro, 1999).

According to modern economists, human capital is rooted in the field of macro-economic development theory (Schultz, 1993). The concept of human capital arose from a recognition that an individuals or firms decision to invest in human capital (i.e. invest in education and training) is similar to decisions on other types of investments as for example on machinery, building and land etc. by individuals or firms. Unlike the traditionally associated meaning of the term labor, human capital refers to the knowledge, expertise, skills and other attributes of individuals, which include a range of personal, economic and social values. Generally, one accumulates these largely through education and training, but may also reflect innate capacities. Some aspects of motivation and behavior, as well as attributes such as the physical, and mental health of individuals are also considered as human capital (OECD: 2001).

There are three main components of human capital: a) early ability (whether acquired or innate); b) qualifications and knowledge acquired through formal education and c) skills, competencies and expertise acquired through training on the job (Blundell et.al. 1999).

Beckers (1993) study on Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education further described the concept of human capital. According to him, there are different types of capitals which include schooling, training, fees on education and medical care etc. He considered the ethics such as honesty, punctuality, commitment, responsibility and hard work etc. also as human capital. Emphasizing the social and economic importance of human capital theory, Becker (1993) highlighted that the most valuable of all capital is investment in the human being. He distinguished firm/company specific human capital from general-purpose human capitals. Expertise gained through education and training in management, accounting, information technology and other expertise were taken by Becker as examples of company specific human capitals, while knowledge gained through education and training in areas of value to a variety of companies such as generic skills in human resource development considered general purpose of human capital. However, Becker (1993) considered education and training as the most important investment in human capital.

This theory has further been described by Garavan et.al. (2001) and they have pointed out four key attributes of human capital as follows: a) flexibility and adaptability; b) enhancement of individual competencies, c) the development of organizational competencies and d) individual employability. Rastogi (2000) also considered human capital as an important input of organizations, especially for continuous improvement of employees mainly knowledge, skills, and abilities.

Human capital is developed in the contexts of: learning within family and early child care settings; formal education (primary to tertiary, technical & vocational, labor market training and adult education etc.); work place training (in-service training, research, innovation participation in professional net-works etc.); informal learning (on-the-job and civic participation) (OECD: 2001).Measuring the economic impact of human capital can be done through the calculation of productivity or earnings-based rates of return on investments in learning. Private rates of return can be estimated using data on private costs and post-tax earnings over a life time. Such private rates of return should include the non-monetary benefits like pleasure of learning, and the job satisfaction etc. Social rates of return should include the public and societal costs and benefits involved in investing in more human capital. However, in practice, there are many difficulties in measuring correctly the full benefits of human capital (OECD, 2001).

The concept of human capital plays a major role in modern treatments of growth theory and of labor economics. In one sense, the distinction between the two is in levels of aggregation. At the macro-economic level, the social stock of human capital and its growth are central to the process of economic growth; at the micro level differences in human capital stock and in their growth can explain much of the observed variation in the wage structure and in the wage distribution among individuals and groups.

In a macro-economic approach, the development of human capital improves labor productivity, facilitates technological innovations, increases returns to capital and makes sustainable economic growth, which in turn, helps to reduce poverty. From a microeconomic perspective, education increases the probability of being employed in the labor market and improves earning capacity. At the micro level, human capital is regarded as the component of education that contributes to an individuals labor productivity and earnings while being an important component of firm production. In this sense, human capital refers to the ability and efficiency of people to transform raw materials and capital, into goods and services and the consensus is that those skills can be learned through the educational system. Therefore, human capital development is important for overall development of a country for its intrinsic value as a development goal in its own right (Cohen and Soto, 2007).

Although pursued independently these applications view human capital and its growth as a cause of economic growth: of the economy as a whole in the theory of growth, and of individuals in labor economics (Mincer, 1995). Human capital is implicated in the process of growth not merely as a cause but also as an effect of economic growth or of development generated by economic growth. However, the reciprocal relation between economic growth and the growth of human capital is likely to be an important key to sustained economic growth (Ibid.). , Rapid economic growth in many developed countries has been considered as a result of investment in human capital at both the macro and micro levels. For individuals, such investments were seen to provide returns in the form of individual economic success and achievement. Most economists agree that it is human resources of nation, not its physical capital nor its material resources, which ultimately determine the character and pace of it economic and social development. Human resources constitute the ultimate basis of the wealth of nations. Capital and natural resources are passive factors of production, human beings are the active agencies who accumulate capital, exploit natural resources, build social, economic and political organizations and carry forward national development (Psacharopoulos & Woodhall, 1997).

According to Babalola (2003), the rationality behind investment in human capital is based on three arguments:a) New generation must be given the appropriate parts of the knowledge which has already been accumulated by previous generations.b) New generations should be taught how existing knowledge should be used to develop new products, to introduce new processes and production methods and social services.c) People must be encouraged to develop entirely new ideas, products processes and methods through creative approaches.

1.1.1Effects of Human Capital on Economic Development

According to neo-classical economic theory, the effect of human capital on economic development is explained either through the impact on labor productivity or through the impact on total factor productivity. Economic development is not seen just as economic growth, it is concerned with various other indicators such as literacy rates, health status, life expectancy, poverty rates and income distribution etc. The original Solow (1956) growth model included, however, only two production factors: labor and capital, assuming that every employee is identical in terms of productivity. Uzawa (1965) introduced the idea of the education sector in the economy. The employment in this sector, which in addition to traditionally understood education included also health services and some other public services, conditioned labor productivity in the economy (Herbst & Rok, 2013).

In turn, Lucas (1988) considered human capital as an individual feature of every labor force member. In his model the employee with human capital equal to two is twice as productive as the individual with human capital that equals one. According to Lucass model the rate of Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita growth is equal to the rate of human capital accumulation.

The second explanation on the effect of human capital on economic development emphasizes the fact that human capital allows the creation and diffusion of technology. Nelson and Phelps (1966) identify two channels through which this effect works. First, a high level of human capital makes it possible to develop new technologies and increases the effectiveness of production, which develops the economy rapidly. Second, human capital allows developing countries to import technology from developed countries.

Among empirical studies on human capital and economic growth, Mankiw, Romer and Weils (1992) work, organized on Lucas model, is considered as the most important one. They illustrated that a 10% of increase in human capital stock was associated with a gain in GDP per capita of 6.7% to 7.6%, by using data on national economies from 1960-1985. Though this study paved the way to the debate on human capital and its relationship with economic growth, many researchers questioned this repeatedly. Bernanke and Gurkaynak (2001) who did two similar researches by using the data covering the period 1960-1985 and 1960-1995, gave a conclusion in accordance with the observations of Mankiw, Romer and Weil.

Barros (1999) study, based on Nelson and Phelpss concept, illustrated that continuing by one year the average duration of education after primary school has the effect of raising the future rate of economic growth by 0.7% points. He concluded that not only the level of formal education but also its quality has a strong influence on economic development.

Some cross- country studies also have shown positive relationship between human capital development and economic development. For example, Chen and Dahlman (2004), who used data from 92 countries for their study, concluded that extending the average number of years of study by one year has an effect on increasing the economic growth by 0.13%. Barro and Sala-i-Martins (2004) study, which used primary school data from 100 countries also has illustrated a significant impact of human capital on economic development during the period between 1965-1995. According to a comparative study done on human capital investment by the OECD (1998:91), for growth and prosperity to be sustainable, social cohesion is required; here too, the role of human capital is vital.

Moreover, conclusions of many studies done on regional development have supported the idea of positive influence of human capital on the regional development. A very important research study on Human Capital, Demographics and Growth across the US States 1920-1990 was done by Persson and Malmberg (1996), considering the factors which influenced economic development in the different states of the United States. They concluded that human capital had a strong positive relationship with state level development but emphasized that the level of human capital in different states had different influence on their growth. A similar study, done by Di Liberto and Symons (2001) on factors that influenced on regional development in Italy too illustrated that education had played a vital role in development of the southern parts of the country. The positive link between the human capital and regional development was emphasized by another study done by De la Fuente and Domenech (2002) in Spain. They mentioned that the equality in educational facilities and development of technology as main factors which influenced regional development of Spain. Badinger and Tondls (2002) study on regions of ten European Union (EU) countries, too found the positive influence of human capital at the higher education level on economic growth. However, this study did not find any clear relations between the secondary level education and the regional growth. Furthermore, this study illustrated that the regions where the economy was more open or liberal but with low levels of economic development and human capital, developed rapidly by importing or borrowing various knowledge and skills gained by developed regions. Japan, a case of study of this research provides evidence to prove this conclusion. The significance of human capital for regional economic development is also supported by another study done on some selected regions of EU countries in the period of 1995-2003 by Lesage and Fischer (2008). They demonstrated not only the positive impact of human capital on regional development but also a positive spatial effect which means that development occurs faster in regions with higher educational potential.

Some studies (Onyinyechi & Akamike, 2011; Iniobong, 2012) done on developing countries also suggested that human capital is the ultimate basis of wealth creation and key to the development of underdeveloped countries.

Investment in human capital has also been widely documented as a core component of each individuals human development, firm growth and aggregate productivity growth (Lucas, 1988). A large number of studies have been done on human capital and their implications for performance of organization and they have illustrated the positive relationship between human capital development and greater achievements of organizations (Agrawal, 2003; Guthrie et.al. 2002; Lumpkin et.al. 2005). Dearden et.al (2006) and Conti (2005) estimate the differential effect of training on productivity and wages. The former finds that training increases productivity by twice as much as it increases wages, while the latter finds only effects of training on productivity. Furthermore, there are some findings that incorporate human capital with higher performance and sustainable competitive advantage (Norudhaug, 1998); higher organizational commitment (Iles et.al. 1990); and enhanced organizational retention (Robertson et.al. 1991).

Although, human capital theory concludes that investment in human capital leads to greater economic outputs, the validity of the theory has been questioned. Some studies such as Benhabib and Spiegels (1994) and Kruger and Lindahls (1999) did not show a direct influence of human capital on economic development. Conclusions of such studies questioned of human capital on development. As a result, some researchers developed systems of data analysis by taking not only the quantity (or number of years of education) but also the quality of education into consideration. For example, introducing the international measuring systems of students abilities, such as Trends in International Math and Science Study (TIMSS) -1995 and Program for International Students Assessment (PISA) - (2000) improved the relevant data analysis (Herbst & Rok, 2013). However, many recent studies demonstrated that such conclusions were reached owing to the weakness of statistical data or poor quality of education and proved that development of human capital had immense influence on socio-economic development (Arnold; Bassanini et al. 2011; De la Fuente & Domenech, 2006). Moreover, researchers such as Hanushek and Woessmann (2007), who measured the quality of education by using the new test methods confirmed that the influence of the real skills of workers on their income level.

In the new global economy hard tangible assets such as land, machines and buildings etc. may not be as important as investing in human capital. As the global economy shifts towards more knowledge-based sectors, skills and human capital development have become a focal issue for policy makers and implementers engaged in development (OECD, 1966).

1. 2Education as an Investment in Human Capital Development

The human capital theory has undergone a rapid development. Within its development, greater attention has been paid to education, training and related aspects. Education, which is considered as an economic good, is an engine of growth and key to development in every society, based on its quality and quantity. Economists regard education as both a consumer and capital good, because it offers utility (satisfaction) to a consumer and also serves as an input to develop the human resources necessary for economic and social transformation. Human capital theory emphasizes how education increases the productivity and efficiency of workers by increasing the level of cognitive stock of economically productive human capability, which is a product of innate abilities and investment in human beings (Almendarez, 2010). Not only formal education but also informal education, training outside school and on the job training etc. are also ways to invest in human capital development. According to the human capital model presented by Zula & Chermanck (2007), there are four types of educational investments in human capital development, viz. formal education, general training at work place, specific training at work place and other knowledge. (See the Chart: 1)

There are two main ways of explaining how expansion of education accelerated socio-economic development. The first is to view education as an investment in human capital. The second view of the role of education in the economic success is that education has positive externalities; educate a part of the community and the whole of it benefits (Almendarez, 2010). Some classical economists such as Smith (1976) and Van-Dan-Berge (2001) too mentioned that there is a positive worldwide externality that society would gain from a more educated labor force and population. The studies on human capital theory and education can be divided in to two levels, viz. micro and macro level. At the Micro level, the theory explains that an individual bears the direct costs (school fees) as well the indirect cost (time) of education because he/she expects that this investment will create a future stream of benefits such as higher wages to him/her. At the macro level, education and the creation of human capital is responsible for both the differences in labor productivity and the differences in overall levels of technology.Chart:1

The importance of education as an investment in human capital development has been brought out in many studies mainly by Becker, Schultz, Lucas, Mincer, Denison and Psacharopoulos & Patrinos. According to Beckers explanation, human capital concept begins with the assumption that individuals decide on their, education, knowledge, training, skills, and health care by weighing the benefits and costs. Benefits include cultural and other non-monetary gains along with the improvement in earnings and productivity. Becker argued that education and training are the most important components of investments in human capital and income of a trained and educated person is generally higher than that of an uneducated individual. (Becker, 1962; 1992 & 1993). Both Schultz (1960 & 1961) and Becker, (1964) argued that based on rational expectations of returns on investments, individuals make decisions on the education and training they receive as a way of augmenting their productivity. In short, human capital theory identifies (Mincer, 1962; Becker, 1962 & 1992) that education and training bring benefits in higher productivity and higher wages. An OECD (2000) study done on human capital and growth also gives evidences of very high private returns to education, in the form of higher wages mainly for degree holders.

Employees who have more education, tend to have more rewarding occupations (Featherman & Hauser, 1978); better earnings (Dickens & Katz, 1987) and higher wages (Card, 1998). Gary (1993) emphasized that education as an investment has future benefits of creation of status, job security and other financial benefits. According to Mincer (1997), from the individual level, a greater human capital stock is associated with greater productivity and higher salaries. Yesufu (2000) indicated that education and job training as the most important direct means of upgrading the human intellect and skills for productive employment. Improving job performance and promoting management efficiency have been considered by him as advantageous of staff training. Gomez (2010) stated that educated individuals can adapt to latest technologies and production practices as well as become more mobile and entrepreneurial. According to Gomez (2010), education can impact on individuals saving capacity and reduces the dependency syndrome.

Research studies done on adult literacy in various countries also have shown a positive linkage between literacy skills and earnings though varies among countries. For example, Raudenbush & Kasims study (1998) demonstrated that economic returns to literacy skill increase with the knowledge intensity of jobs in the United States. OECD and Statistics Canada (2000) showed that education, literacy, experience, gender, parents education and ability to use native language are related positively to human capital, mainly in labor market earnings.

For example, some studies, done by Levy et al. (1992); Juhn, et al. (1993) and Nickell, (2004) also have concluded that skills have an increasing impact on the distribution of income and that the income distribution becomes more dispersed in reflection of growing rewards to individual skills. The studies done by McIntosh et al. (2001) and Finnie et al. (2002) respectively on British and Canadian wage patterns and educational levels also found strong returns to human capital investment. Psacharopoulos and Patrinos study on Human Capital and Rates of Return (2004) concludes that educational quality has a strong influence on individual earnings and economic growth, which is termed monetary benefits.

Several empirical studies support the idea on the aggregate effect of education and training on development by giving various evidences. For example, Griliches (1970) demonstrated that one third of the Solow (1957) residual (i.e. the portion of the output growth in the American economy that could not be attributed to the growth in labor hours or capital stock) could be accounted for by the increase in the labor forces educational attainments. In the same manner, Denison (1979) showed the effects of education upon per capita income in the United States. Baumol et al, (1989); Barro (1991) and Mankiw, et al. (1992) also confirmed these positive relationships between education/ and training and development by giving cross-country evidences.

Barro and Lee (2010) illustrated that increasing average years of schooling by one year increases per capita GDP by 1.7% to 12.1% depending on specification, Cohen and Soto (2007) estimated returns to years of schooling at 12.3% to 22.1%. Testing the impacts of schooling quality on development, it was found that a unit increase in countrys average cognitive test scores increase per capita GDP growth rate by 1.2 to 2.0 percentage points. Moreover, increasing average math and science scores by one unit increase per capita GDP growth rates by 2.0 points, and by 2.3 points for low-income countries. Denison, et al. (1976); Godo et al. (1999) and Miyazawa, (2011) have illustrated the direct positive relationship between increase in human capital in Japan and its economic growth. Investing in education not only raises GDP, but also reduces poverty and inequality. From a national perspective, educational expansion has significantly contributed to national economic growth (Jorgenson, 1984); an educated population of a country is more likely to attract foreign investment (Gomez, 2010). Persson (1994) and Fishlow (1995) agreed that inequality is negatively related to economic growth. Stiglz (1998) argued that successful development not only closes the gap in physical or even human capital but also closes the gap in knowledge.

Human capital theory also identifies the non-monetary benefits gained by the individuals as a result of investment in education. Villa (2000: 21) describes it in the following manner:The economic benefits that education bestows are not limited to higher expected production or lower production costs. They could also consist in direct additions to welfare possibilities in terms of longer life expectancy, less criminal behavior, stronger social cohesion or greater political participation.

McMahon (1999) argued that increasing the number of educated individuals in the society would lead to increase health status of the society, decrease crimes, improve democracy, maintain rule of law and strengthen political stability. According to Eyben (2004), education empowers people more to advance their interests and resist exploitation. Bassel (2008) emphasized that, educated individuals are more aware of how to avoid health risks and to live longer, have smaller families, exhibit better consumption and saving habits and more comfortable lives.

It is also widely accepted that education creates improved citizens and helps to upgrade the general standard of living in a society (Becker, 1962 & 1992). Several prominent studies have illustrated that education plays a pivotal role in increasing the production capacity of workers which finally leads to sustainable development (Schultz, 1971; Sakamoto & Powers, 1995). Babalola (2003) argued that the rationale behind schooling and human capital development is the need for people to be encouraged to develop entirely new ideas, products, process and method through creative approaches, so as to introduce new process, production and social services. Thus, education is considered as an investment in human capital, which proponents of the theory have regarded as equally or even more worthwhile than the of physical capital (Woodhall, 1997).

Education is an asset that generates not only earnings, but also a stream of non-market utilities involving learning and culture. As such, it can be viewed as a consumption good which, therefore, is directly related to income. The positive income effects apply also to the acquisition of education as an investment good, to the extent that imperfect capital markets necessitate a degree of self-financing of education. The positive effect of parental income on school enrollment of their children is documented in many micro-economic and inter-country comparative studies (Mincer, 1995). Doucouliagos (1997) also has elaborated human capital as a source not only to motivate workers and boost up their commitment but also to create expenditure in human resource development and eventually pave a way for the generation of new knowledge for the economy and society in general.

In addition to these positive influences, investment in education results in spillovers that benefit others who work with or near individuals who have made such investments. According to early models of economic growth, no explicit role of education or potential of human capital to generate externalities or spillover influences were not identified. However, with the development of the new growth models (Lucas, 1988; Romer, 1990; Barro & Sala-i-Martin, 1995) the role of education in innovation and developing technology was given more importance. They emphasize that such innovations, skills, knowledge and technology etc. will increase the productivity in other sectors, neighboring areas and regions. Spillovers provide the economic justification for public subsidies for education and motivate community interests in improving the educational attainment of the population (Babalola, 2003).

At the macro level, Robert (1991) developed a human capital model which shows that education and the creation of human capital is responsible for both the differences in labor productivity and the differences in overall levels of technology. According to him this explains the spectacular growth in East Asian countries that have given education and human capital their current popularity in the field of economic growth and development. Fagerlind and Saha (1997) emphasize that human capital theory provides a basic justification for large public expenditure on education both in developed and developing countries, because the theory is consistent with the ideologies of democracy and liberal progression found in most western developed societies.

From the organizational point of view, Galle et al. (1985) emphasized that the industries with more educated workers have greater productivity. Snell et al. (1999) and Seleim et al. (2007) found out that the human capital indicators, mainly the education and training of workers, had a positive relationship on a companys achievements. The industries and education and training are also linked to the longevity of companies (Bates, 1990) and greater tendency to business and economic growth (Goetz et. al. 1996). After reviewing the impact of technical and vocational education in various societies, Abramovitz (1986) concluded that education and vocational training as a part of a set of key ingredients sustaining societys growth, which he termed social capability. According to this literature it can be concluded that there is a great impact of education and training on human capital development and it has a positive correlation between the individual and organizational achievements and national development. Crouch (1999) has provided some evidences to prove that highly educated workers were more likely to be employed in sectors exposed to international competition. He also illustrated the close associations between educational and training levels of workers with their success in technological functions. Liu and Sakamotos (2002) study on the role of schooling in Taiwans labor market also clearly supports the view of education as productive human capital and provides limited backing for the notion of a mechanism for labor market screening.

Another way of looking at education in human capital development is to view it as a critical input for innovations, research and development activities. According to this approach, education is considered as an intentional effort to increase the resources needed for creating new ideas and then it leads to development technology. Some studies have shown the positive relations between the education and training and the technical skills. According to Nelson & Phelps (1966) a more educated and skilled workforce makes it easier for an industry/company to plan and implement new technologies. Furthermore, Bartel et al. (1987) and Wolff (1996) found that education and training levels are positively related with technological change in industries/companies. Altbach and Levy (2005) developed a human capital model, which shows that education and the creation of human capital was responsible for both the differences in labor productivity and the differences in overall levels of technology.

The World Bank (1993) found that improvement in education as a very significant explanatory variable for East Asian economic development. An international Adult Literacy Survey done by the OECD and Statistics Canada (2000) also showed a strong link between levels of literacy and outcomes in terms of labor market, civic participation and social outcomes. In considering the human capital theory, the OECD has stressed that the overall economic development of the OECD countries is more directly depend on their knowledge stock and learning abilities (OECD, 2001). All developed countries have not only considered education as a key determinant of development throughout their socio-economic performance, but also have re-theorized it recently under human capital theory as a major economic device. Human capital theory emphasizes the significance of education as the key to participation in the new global economy. However, it should be noted that education is a source of socio-economic development only if it liberates, stimulates and informs the individual and teaches him/her how and why to make demands. To contribute significantly to socio-economic development, education should be of high quality and also should meet the skill needs and labor market demands of the country. Without a quality education, developing nations will not be able to compete in the global market. Therefore it is an essential need to focus on education as a development strategy. A proper educational strategy will manifest itself in four major development-producing capacities. According to Bronchi (2003) those are: a) the development of a general trend (increase in literacy) favorable to economic growth; b) the development of complementary resources for factors which are relatively plentiful and substitute for relatively scarce factors; c) the durability of educational investment (education has more durability than most of non-human capital); and d) education is an alternative to consumption, for it transfers to round-about production the resources that would otherwise be consumed now.

1.3Importance of Technical and Vocational Education and Training (TVET) in Human Capital Development

Technical and Vocational Education and Training (TVET), which refers to education and training that prepare people for gainful employment (Finch & Crunkilton, 1999), is important as capital investment. Before explaining the relationship between the human capital development and TVET it is important to define the term since it is a complex field.

1.3.1Definition of Vocational and Technical Education and Training

Different countries have different terms to describe the elements of TVET. These include apprenticeship training, vocational education, industrial arts, technical education, technological-vocational education, occupational education, vocational training and career and technical education etc. There are also several different dimensions that can be used to define vocational and technical education and training, for example its venue (company based, school based) and character (initial, continuing) etc. (Maclean & Adlai, 2011). However, at the second International Congress on Technical and Vocational Education, held in the Republic of Korea in 1999, United Nations Education and Science Council (UNESCO) and the International Labor Organization (ILO) jointly agreed to use the term Technical and Vocational Education and Training (TVET) in order to bring all fields together. The 2001 UNESCO and ILO Revised Recommendations concerning Technical and Vocational Education uses technical and vocational education and training asa comprehensive term referent to those aspects of the educational process involving, in addition to general education, the study of technologies and related science, and the acquisition of practical skills, attitudes, understanding and knowledge relating to occupations in various sectors of economic and social life (UNESCO and ILO, 2002).The Revised Recommendation defines technical and vocational education as:a) an integral part of general educationb) a means of preparing for occupational fields and for effective participationin the world of workc) an aspect of lifelong learning and a preparation for responsible citizenshipd) an instrument for promoting environmentally-sound sustainable development.e) a method of facilitating poverty alleviation.f) It includes aspects of education that are technical and vocational in nature, provided either in educational institutions or under their authority, by public authorities, the private sector or through other forms of organized education, formal or non-formal, aiming to ensure that all members of the community have access to the pathways of lifelong learning. (Ibid.: 7)

1.3.1Importance of TEVT in Human Capital DevelopmentThe importance of TVET for social and economic development has been widely recognized. In explaining human capital theory, Schultz (1971) defined that human capital as knowledge and skills obtained by individuals as capitals in the process of vocational and technical education. Young people and adults increasingly recognize that vocational skills are needed for participation in the world of work. TVET is not only important in providing employment opportunities to individuals but also helps in enhancing the productivity of industry/companies. According to Caillods, (1994: 241):

Vocational education and training are indispensable instruments for improving labor market mobility, adaptability and productivity, thus contributing to enhancing competitiveness of firms and redressing labor market imbalances. For governments, public TVET is seen as essential for enhancing economic competitiveness and for contributing to social inclusion, poverty reduction and sustainable development. As well as responding to labor market trends, public TVET is expected to equip learners with basic skills and to support personal and social development. Employers are increasingly emphasizing the need for new soft skills, such as communication, negotiation and team working, in addition to technical knowledge and ability. The demand of the economy affects both industrialized and developing countries. In particular the need for technical personnel in developing countries is crucial and places great pressure on systems for TVET and the limited national resources.

At the end of the 20th century the need for a vocational, technical and educational knowledge and skills for the development of the worlds economy was clearly manifested in the improvement of diversity in industrial and service fields. As a result, it was felt that the world needed not only a workforce trained in technical and vocational skills but also a highly competent skilled workforce including technicians and technologists in specific areas in industries. From the beginning of the 21st century, the progress made in industrialization was due to the high capacity of the trained workforce. Therefore economic development in the world seems to have depended entirely on the knowledge based skill development. In any country that evolved into a technologically advanced one, TVET must have played an active and vital role, as skilled manpower would have been required, to ensure sustainability as well (Usman & Pascal, 2010).

Cosh et al. (2000) found a positive and significant effect of TVET on product quality in manufacturing firms in the United States. Ng and Siu (2004) found that job related TVET has a significant positive impact on productivity in manufacturing firms in China. Similarly, Jones (2011) has found that the effect of the share workers received TVET has a positive and significant effect on productivity in the manufacturing sector in Ghana.

The benefits of TVET for firms can appear in a wide range of other forms of economic performance too. First, TVET may have external effects through innovation and spill-over. This is emphasized by the new growth theories (Barro and Sala-I-Martin, 1995). New knowledge and competencies embodied in higher educated workers are often transferred to other workers. The same is true for new knowledge that is embedded in new products. A higher share of workers with a TVET background may be favorable for innovation and knowledge transfer. Baker and Thompson (1995) examined GP practices which were generally small organizations and found positive and significant effects of TVET on innovation. Similarly, if TVET adds to the skills of workers this may also affect product quality positively. If TVET has a stronger impact on product quality and productivity than on wage costs, it will improve competitiveness. Moreover, Hempell (2003) has found positive and significant effects of the share of workers with TVET on value added of firms in the business-related and distribution services sector in Germany.

TVET is important in other aspects such as alleviating mass unemployment, providing specific skills for self- employment, preventing mass movement of school leavers from rural to urban areas, and re-orientating student towards the rural society (Lillis & Hogan, 1983; Tilak, 2002). As Khalil Mahashi Director International Institute for Educational Planning) says the purpose of TVET is essential to promote and support the development of a country, facilitate transition from school to work for millions of school leavers, and foster equality of opportunity and social cohesion. It also has a key role to play in addressing current problems, such as the fight against poverty, the food crisis, and deterioration of the environment (www.iiep.unesco.org). According to King and Palmer (2010) the provision of TVET skills is often assumed to reduce both poverty and unemployment. It is assumed that someone with employable skills will find employment, leading in turn to earned income and a higher standard of living. It means the skills for poverty assumption is directly linked to the skills for employment assumption: both presuppose that work is a primary route out of poverty and that skills must result in work. Moreover, TVET has been considered as an integral part of a reintegration that creates and facilitates new opportunities and livelihoods for ex-combatants and for communities by enabling the possibility of building realities that differ considerably from pre-conflict ones. According to Kingombe (2012), TVET programing as a part of disarmament, demobilization and reintegration has the real potential to raise expectations and create livelihoods and employment.

1.3.2.Relevant Positive Experiences of Developed Countries

The level, type, effects and progress of TVET vary widely across countries, and this is not necessarily linked in similar ways to every countrys state of economic development. Different studies about the effect of TVET on individual and company achievements have found different effects. For example, MartInez & Levie et.al. (2010) argue that the impact of TVET training does vary according to the level of economic development of a country. They said that it appears to have greater effect on early stage entrepreneurial activity in countries with favorable institutional contexts. Furthermore, they concluded that the TVET was particularly effective in West European countries with low rates of early stage entrepreneurial activity, such as Belgium, Germany, France and the United Kingdom. However, the effect of the TVET depends on the contents, field training, teaching methodology, assessment and monitoring procedures of courses, ability and status of teachers, its relevance to a particular company, the group at which the TVET is directed and its performance etc. (European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training , 2011).

In practice, the outputs of a well-structured TVET system have led countries such as Australia, Canada, Germany and Japan to become global leaders in all aspects of their enterprise in a very short space of time (Iack, 2009). According to Iack (2009), these countries were successful mainly due to key strategies such as, promoting and marketing TVET as a viable alternative to the more traditional mode of advancement and education; developing industry-led standard-setting bodies; establishing labor market observatory; increasing the employability and participation of vulnerable groups in TVET; establishing national training funds; making legislations for the funding, accreditation, standard setting and quality assurance within the national training system; developing modern curriculum and providing information on careers and proper career guidance etc. used by them.

The dual system of TVET is well developed in Germany, integrating work-based and school-based learning to prepare apprentices for successful transition to full-time employment. Some studies point out that the gap between general unemployment and youth unemployment in Germany is comparatively small relative to other OECD countries. This is mainly due to the dual system of TVET, which opens up good possibilities for young adults to enter the world of work (Schanarr, at el. (2008); Hippach-Schneider at el. (2007); OECD, (2010). Not only has this system proved its success over a long period, and it still shows its ability to react quickly and effectively to the many changes currently affecting the German economy and society (The German Vocational Training System: An Overview, 2013).

Studies done on Australian TVET system show that it has played a critical role in creating individual and community confidence (Janelle at el. 2006). According to a report presented to the National Skills Standards Council (2013) the skills and education system of Australia plays a critical role in delivering sustainably higher living standards through forming one of the pillars of productivity (foot notes : As outlined in Australia in the Asian Contemporary White Paper Chp.5: key points, the five pillars of productivity: skills and education, innovation, infrastructure, tax reform and regulatory reform.) Moreover, the National Panel for Economic Reform (2013) states that the skills and education in Australia create economic benefits through enhancing civil society, providing greater opportunities and generally improving life outcomes.

Though Japan has few natural resources, it has very high productivity and a high per capita income. A key contributing factor to this is that Japan is less dependent on its natural resources and relies on its own trained human capital. According to a study done by the OECD on vocational education and training in several developed countries, such as Australia, Belgium, China, England, Germany, Mexico, Norway, and Switzerland have well developed TVET systems(OECD, 2010). This study shows a number of strengths of the TVET systems in the above mentioned countries. In Australia, the dual system with well-structured apprenticeships that integrate learning in schools and work place training, local autonomy and social partner involvement at all levels in TVET policy design and delivery, well-established National Vocational Qualification System (NVQ), catering for broad range of social needs and well-prepared and industry experienced teacher work force etc. have been identified as positive characteristics. In Germany too, the main features such as work based and school based dual system, offerings of qualifications in a broad spectrum of professions, high degree of engagement of ownership on the part of employers and other social partners, well- resourced with public and private funds and well-developed and institutionalized TVET research capacity have been emphasized as factors influence the TVET system to be successful. The TVET system in Switzerland has also been identified as a strongly employer and market driven system. School and work based learning, partnership between confederations, cantons, and professional organizations, well-resourced and up-to-date equipment, pathways to allow for mobility up-to tertiary levels, well-trained teachers, well-functioned quality control, systematic and professional career guidance services and institutionalized research and data collection system to support policy changes are recognized as positive factors which have influenced the Swiss TVET system to be a model (OECD, 2010).Moreover, the OECD study (Ibid.) emphasized that features such as flexibility, commitment of government mainly in funding and relevant policy designing and implementing, cooperation among various stake holders, catering to different strata of the society, well trained teachers, efficient evaluation systems, institutionalized career guidance systems and well-developed research facilities etc. in Chile, England, Mexico, Norway and China as lessons that can be learned by other countries in developing their TVET systems. Thus, availability of skilled man power is an essential factor for the success of socio-economic development of many developed countries, and developing countries can learn many lessons from such TVET systems.

Some East Asian countries are considered as best examples of the TVE system being well established (Tzannatos & Johnes, 1997). Newly Industrialized Countries (NIC) in East Asia have achieved a great advance, in spite of a shortage of natural resources, during recent decades, mainly by investing in developing the skills of the labor force. Among the East Asian countries, mainly Singapore, South Korea, Taiwan and Malaysia, the TVET systems have contributed significantly in the process of economic development (ADB, 2004; Cantor, 1985). Through mass literacy, better trained healthy workforce and investment friendly government policies, these countries have been able to achieve a rapid growth (Tzannatos & Jones, 1997). Ul-Haq and Haqemphasize this in the Human Development Report in South Asia (1998: 96) as follows:Vocational and technical education is a passport to better employment opportunities. This is the experience of Japan and the East Asian industrializing tigers where unemployment rates have remained consistently low, both because their populations possessed employable technical skills and because of the high economic growth rates that these skilled populations engineered.

Singapores TVE system has been considered as a world class model and it has played a vital role in industrialization and economic development (Sakellariou, 2003; Seng, 2008; Mun, 2008;). According to Mun (2008: 139),Education through polytechnics has been the backbone of Singapores industrialization. These polytechnics have a very clear mission: to train and produce technologists and middle level professionals to support the economic, social and technological development of the country.

Seng (2008) emphasized that the success of the Singapores TVET system is mainly due to the evolving nature of the system by responding to the various phases of economic development. He said:As the economy restructured and moved from labor intensive to capital intensive, and then to knowledge intensive, the TVET system responded to ensure that the workforce had the relevant knowledge, skills and values. The educational and training systems were reviewed, upgraded, and remodeled to stay relevant and responsive to the needs of school leavers, industry and community (Seng, 2008: 132, 133).

In South Korea TVET has contributed substantially to economic and social development (Westphal, 1990), though now facing various changes due to globalization and changes of economies (Chae & Chung, 2009; Chung, 2010).

A study on the role of vocational education in economic development in Malaysia too has revealed that vocational education and training has contributed to its economic development. It further concluded that vocational programs were more appropriate than general academic programs for developing new skills and the ability to use contemporary technologies (Mustapha & Greenan, 2002). Thus mainly due to the vital role played by the TVET sector, economies of some of these East Asian countries continued to grow for well over three decades.

Addressing this East Asian issue, in the 1980s, a new paradigm which is now commonly known as endogenous growth model was developed, mostly due to Paul Romer (1986). It proposed that if a firm which invests in capital also employs educated and skilled workers who are also healthy, then not only will the labor be productive but it will also be able to use the capital and technology more efficiently (Romer, 1986).

1.4Importance of Technical and Vocational Education and Training for Developing Countries

Literature on human capital development and technical and vocational education in less developed countries suggests that the development of those countries is related to their ability to develop and utilize their human resources effectively (Middleton et.al. 1993). During the 1960s and 1970s, TVET in less developed countries was looked upon with a great deal of enthusiasm by government and international donors. Human resource strategies in those countries embraced TVET as the main cure for the lack of skilled workers to meet the demand of the economy, reduce unemployment by providing individuals with employable skills, and enhancing attitudes towards mainly blue-collar workers (Middleton et.al. 1993; Middleton & Ziderman, 1997).

However, since the 1980s some studies have revealed that a large percentage of graduates of TVET programs were unable to find jobs that used their skills and the system was in crisis (Salmi, 1991; Lewin, 1993; Tilak, 1988). Foster (1987) argued that TVET was not suitable for developing countries but it would be successful in developed countries. Furthermore, compared with general education, some studies concluded that TVET is not only more expensive than general education (Psacharopoulos, 1987; Tsang, 1989), but also produces lower social and financial return on investment than general education (Grooteart, 1990; Salmi, 1991; Bennell, 1996). Psacharopoulos (1991) also presented several arguments such as the sociological argument, technological argument, lifetime argument, occupational replenishment argument, supply-response argument and cost argument, against the suitability of TVET for developing countries. However, he did not totally reject TVET in developing countries whilst suggesting that it should focus on peoples needs. His suggestions included, prioritizing the improvement of reading and writing skills, locating TVET outside the formal education system, motivating on-the-job training and minimizing the influence of the government in TVET education etc. in improving the TVET sector.

Evidence produced by such studies had some influence on the World Bank and other funding agencies to decrease their assistance to TVET in developing countries (IBRD, 1995). Instead, international organizations and many developing countries paid more attention on primary and secondary education (Salmi, 1991; Bennell, 1996). As a result, mainly due to lack of resources and support systems the TVET systems in developing countries could not afford qualified teachers, proper curriculum development, effective assessment systems, practical trainings, modern equipment and other facilities. Several studies have shown that the TVET systems in developing countries deteriorated mainly due to financial constraints and related factors (Salmi, 1991; Middleton et.al. 1993; Bennell, 1996).

However, in the early 1990s some arguments in favor of TVET in developing countries were put forward. For example Watson (1994) argued that the TVET would transmit certain values and attitudes necessary to perform in the economies of developing nations; would provide specific skills for people and alleviate unemployment; prevent mass movements of unemployed youth; help to improve job performance; promote work ethics and values; and would prepare people for technological change. UNESCO-UNEVOC International Centre (2003), supported that TVET could play an essential role in promoting economic growth and socio-economic development of countries, by helping to improve incomes, providing more choices in life, helping to alleviate poverty, empowering people and promoting good citizenship.

At present, TVET is very much back on the global educational agenda after its disappearance from international aid in the early 1980s when the World Bank radically shifted its policy from TVE support towards investment in primary education. Worldwide trends in the development of education show that considerable efforts have been made by many countries to expand and modernize TVET. TVET has been an important area of focus in the UNESCO development agenda. UNESCOs policy in TVET has been guided by the recommendation concerning TVET, which was adopted by the United National General Conference in 1962 and revised in 1974. Under objectives, the revised recommendation refers to the contribution of TVET to societys goals of greater democratization, social, cultural and economic development; at the same time it refers to developing the potentials of individuals for active participation in the life of the community. It has been suggested that TVET should exist as part of a system of lifelong education and that it should begin with a good foundation in general education and a broad basic technical and vocational education; in order to facilitate horizontal and vertical articulation within the education system and between school and employment as well as adaptation to scientific and technological progress. (UNESCO, 2000). Furthermore, UNESCO launched a TVET and skills strategy reflecting a growing interest in the skills agenda (King, 20019). The 2012 Education for All Global Monitoring Report also pays particular attention to the skill development, emphasizing strategies that increase employment opportunities for young people and marginalized groups. The report has identified three main types of skills that all young people need: foundations skills (literacy, numeracy); transferable skills (communicative, innovative, leadership and ability to sole conflicts); and technical and vocational skills (job specific knowledge and skills) (UNESCO, 2012).

Thus TVET is back on the development agenda of many developing countries after years of neglect, instigated by a complex set of reasons that included budgetary constraints and criticism of the World Bank in the early 1990s on its direction and focus (World Bank, 1991). A return of TVET to the development agenda is partly a reaction to the emerging skills divide with the least developed countries falling further and further behind, particularly in sub-Saharan Africa and South Asia (Maclean, et.al. 2011). Currently, TVET is regarded to be important in the agenda to achieve relevant and high-quality education for all, education for sustainable development and the Millennium Development Goals whilst being part of the lifelong learning agenda (King, 2011). According to King (2012), there is a recent trend that the university graduates enrolling at TVET institutions or community colleges to add occupation-specific credentials mainly to their Bachelor of Arts degrees, which have not led them to real employment. He emphasized that this trend, which is called reverse-transfer is important and is quite likely to become even more pronounced in the future.

There is recent evidence to illustrate that TVET can play and essential role in promoting sustainable poverty alleviation, human development and economic growth, with clear benefits for individuals, their families, local communities, industries or firms and societies in general (NORRAG, 2003; Maclean and Wilson, 2009). The World Bank (2010: 1) emphasizes the importance of skills for individuals and economies as skills are at the core of improving individual employment outcomes and increasing productivity and growth of a country as a whole. UNESCOS strategy on TVET (2008) states that more and more governments are calling for assistance in TVET development (UNESCO, 2011). Currently, Asian Development Bank (ADB) recognizes TVET as a priority area within its program agenda in the Asia Pacific region (Maclean, 2011).

A growing number of research studies have illustrated that when the labor market is expanding and training is closely linked to available jobs, financial returns on TVET in developing countries could be higher than that of general education (Neuman & Ziderman, 1991; Middleton et.al. 1993; Cox Edwards, 1994). Psacharopoulos and Velez (1992) using Colombian data, found a strong positive relation between training and years of formal education in determining earnings. They found that vocational training really has an effect on earnings after a worker has eight years of formal education. A study done on human resource development through vocational education in Saudi Arabia also has pointed out some positive contribution of vocational education and training, and more generally of the level of man power qualifications and skills, to firm productivity and competitiveness. Furthermore, strong links have been found between the human capital of the work place and its innovative capacity, as well as the adoption and adaptation of new technologies, in the case of Saudi Arabia, which did not have financial constraints in investing TVE (Mellahi, 2000). In a more macro level study, Mingat and Tan (1988) found that such vocational training was particularly productive when a countrys education system is highly developed.

It can be concluded that TVET is indeed important to developing countries but it must be noted that the importance depends on the way that TVET is planned, offered, monitored and assessed. A critical challenge that faces the South Asian region is the development of a competent workforce for sustained economic growth in the global economy. To meet the requirement for a skilled labor force, more emphasis has been given to the TVET programs. This issue has been at the center of the policy agenda of many national governments, particularly in the South Asian countries. Though governments in these countries have paid much attention to the TVET sector in the past few years, outcomes are still poor as correctly pointed out by Ul-Haq and Haq even in 1998:The vocational and technical education programs in South Asia are often inadequate, irrelevant, and qualitatively poor. There is perhaps no other field in education that required from South Asian policy-makers more fundamental rethinking, sweeping reforms, and extensive change (p.96). Furthermore, they say:The system of vocational and technical education in South Asia is thus characterized by low enrolment, high drop outs, poor quality of teachers, inadequate access for women and rural population, limited private sector involvement and very inadequate budgetary allocations. In other words, technical training in South Asia is neither supporting a high economic growth rate, nor expanding global markets, nor increasing employment opportunities. The whole system requires fundamental review and restructuring. (Ul-Haq & Haq, 1998: 100).

Thus the South Asian TVET systems are facing several challenges; quality of institutions and lack of linkages between TVET providers and industries are two major problems (Agrawal, 2013).

Human resource development through well planned education and vocational training initiatives can contribute significantly to promoting the interests of youth, unemployed, enterprises, economy and society within Sri Lanka. By helping individuals to gain access to decent work and sustainable jobs, and escape poverty and marginalization TVET can impact positively on the countrys economic development, achieving full employment and promoting social inclusion. A well-structured TVET system will enable productivity, enhance competitiveness and promote entrepreneural activity. Therefore, I argue in a country like Sri Lanka, which maintains a developed education system for more than six decades, if a correct TVET policy is implemented, if training is closely linked to available job market by establishing linkages with industries and if sufficient funds are invested in the system, definitely the financial returns on TVET system will be increased. At this juncture, the government of Sri Lanka should learn lessons from developed countries like Japan, Germany, Singapore and Australia to develop the TVET sector to be responsive to the needs of the labor market and the society.

ReferencesAbramovitz, M. (1986) Catching Up Forging Ahead, and Falling Behind, Journal of Economic History, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, Vol. 46, p. 385-406.

Agrawal, T. (2013) Vocational Education and Training Programs (VET): An Asian Perspective, Asia-Pacific Journal of Co-operative Education, Vol.14, No.1, p.15-26.

Agrawal, T. (2003) Innovative Human resource Practices and Organizational Commitment: An Empirical Investigation, International Journal of Human Resource Management, Vol. 14, No 2, p.175-197.

Almendarez, L. (2010) Human Capital Theory: Implications for Educational Development-(online) htttp://www.cavehill.uwi.edu/BNCCde/belize/conference/papers2010/almendarez.html (retrieved on 2013.08.22).

Altbach, P. & Levy, D. (eds.) Private Higher Education: A Global Revolution, Rotterdam: Sense Publishers.

Arnold, J.; Bassanini, A. et al. (2011) Solow or Lucas? Testing Speed or Convergence on a Panel of OECD Countries, Research in Economic, Vol. 65, No. 2, p. 11-123.

Asian Development Bank (ADB), (2004) Improving Technical Education and Vocational Training: Strategies for Asia, Manila, Philippines: Asian Development Bank.

Babalola, J. B. (2003) Budget Preparation and Expenditure Control in Education, in Babalola, J. B. (ed.) Basic Text in Educational Planning, Ibandan: Awemark Industrial Printers.

Badinger, H. & Tondl, G. (2002) The Empirics of Growth: An Update, Brookings Paper on Economic Activity, Vol. 2, p. 113-266.

Baker, R. & Thompson, J. (1995) Innovation in General Practice: Is the Gap Between Training and Non-training Practices Getting Wider? British Journal of General Practices, Vol. 45, No. 395, p. 297-300.

Bartel, A. P. & Lichtenberg, F. R. (1987) The Comparative Advantage of Educated Workers in Implementing New Technology, The Review of Economics and Statistics, Cambridge, M.A.: MIT Press Journals, Vol.69, Issue.1, p. 1-11.

Barro, R. J. (1999) Human Capital and Growth in Cross-country Regression, Swedish Economic Policy Review, Vol. 6, No. 2, p. 237-277.

Barro, R. J. (1991) Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Cambridge, MIT Press Journals, Vol. 106, p. 407 -443.

Barro, R. J. & Lee, J. W. (2010) A New Data Set of Educational Attainment in the World, 1950-2010, Working Paper, No. 15902, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Barro, R. J. & Sala-i-Martin, (2004) Economic Growth, Cambridge: MIT Press.

Bassel, L. (2008) Citizenship as Interpellation: Refugee Women and the State, Government and Opposition, Vol. 43, No. 2, p. 293-314.

Bates, T. (1990) Entrepreneur Human Capital Inputs and Small Business Longevity, The Review of Economic Statistics, Vo. 72, No. 4, p. 551-559.

Baumol, W.J.: Blackman, S.A.B. & Wolf, E.N. (1989) Productivity and American Leadership: The Long View, Cambridge, M.A.: MIT Press.

Becker, G.S. (1993) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education, (3rd ed.), Chicago: Chicago University Press.

Becker, G.S. (1992, Nov.) The Division of Labor, Coordination Costs and Knowledge, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 107, No.4, p. 1137-1160.

Becker, G.S. (1964) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Becker, G. (1962) Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 70, No 5, p. 9-49.

Benhabib, J. & Spiegel, M. (1994) The Role of the Human Capital in Economic Development, Journal of Monitoring Economies, Vol. 34, No. 2, p. 143-173.

Bennell, P. (1996) General versus Secondary Education in Developing Countries: A Review of the Rate of Return Evidence, Journal of Development Studies, Vol.33, p 230-248.

Bernanake, B. S. & Gurkaynak, R. S. (2001) Is Growth Exogenous? Taking Mankiw, Romer and Weil Seriously, NBER Working Paper, No. 8365, Massachusetts: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Blundel, R.; Dearden, L.; Meghir, C. & Sianeshi, B. (1999) Human Capital International: The Returns from Education and Training to the Individual, the Firm and the Economy, Fiscal Studies, Vol. 20, No.1, p.1-23.

Bronchi, C. (2003) The Effectiveness of Public Expenditure in Portugal, Working Paper, No. 349, Economics Department: Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development.

Caillods, F. (1994) Converging Trends amidst Diversity in Vocational Training Systems, International Labor Review, Vol. 133, No.2, p. 2241-257.

Cantor, L. (1985) Vocational Education and Training: The Japanese Approach, Comparative Education, Vol. 21, No. 1, p. 67-75.

Card, D. (1998) The Causal Effect of Education on Earning, Centre for Labor Economic, Working Paper No. 2, Berkeley: University of California.

Chae, C. & Chung, J. (2009) Pre-employment Vocational Education and Training in Korea, SP Discussion Paper, No. 0921, Washington: Social Protection Unit, The World bank and Korean Ministry of Labor.

Chen, D. H.C. & Dahlman, C. J. (2004) Knowledge and Development: A Cross-section Approach, The World Bank Policy Research Working Paper, Series: 3366, World Bank.

Chung, J. S. (2010) Lifelong Vocational Education and Training in Korea: The Vision and Tasks, Journal of Technical Education and Training, Vol. 2, No. 1, p. 77-88.

Cohen, D. & Soto, M. (2007) Growth and Human Capital: Good Data, Good Results, Journal of Economic Growth, Vol. 1, No.3, p. 173-207.

Conti, G. (2005) Training Productivity and Wages in Italy, Labor Economics, Vol. 12, No. 4, p. 557-576.

Cosh, A. et.al. (2000) The Relationship between Training and Employment Growth in Small and Medium-sized Enterprises, Shefield: Dept. of Education and Employment Research, Research Paper, No 245.

Cox Edwards, A. (1994) Chile: Strategy for Rural Areas - Enhancing Agricultural Competitiveness and Alleviating Rural Poverty, in Rural Labor Markets in Chile, Report 12776-Chile, Washington: World Bank.

Crouch, C; Finegold, D. & Sako, M. (1999) Are Skills the Answer? The Political Economy of Skill Creation in Advanced Industrial Countries, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

De La Fuente, A. & Domenech, R. (2002) Human Capital in Growth Regressions: How Much Difference does Data Quality Make? Journal of European Economic Association, Vol. 4, p. 1-36.

Denison, E.F. (1979) Accounting for Slower Economic Growth: The US in the 1970s, Washington, D. C.: Brookings Institution.

Denison, E. F. & William, K. C. (1976) How Japanese Economy Grew so Fast? The Sources of Post-war Experiences, Washington: Brookings Institute.

Dickens, W. T. & Katz, L. F. (1987) Inter-industry Wage Differences and Industry Characteristics in Unemployment and the Structure of Labor Market (ed.) K. Lang & J. S. Leonard, New York: Basil Blackwell, p. 48-89.

Di Liberto, A. & Symons, J. (2001) Education and Italian Regional Development, Centre for Economic Performance, London: London School of Economics and Political Science.

Doucouliagos, C. (1997) The Aggregate Demand for Labor in Australia: A Meta-analysis, Australian Economic Papers, Blackwell Publishing, Vol. 36, No. 69, p. 224-242.

European Centre for the Development of Vocational Training (2011) The Impact of Vocational Education and Training on Company Performance, Research Paper: No 19, Luxembourg: Publications Office of the European Union.

Eyben, R. (2004) Who Owns a Poverty Reduction Strategy? A Case Study of Power Instruments and Relationships in Bolivia, in Inclusive Aid: Changing Power and Relationships in International Development, (eds.) L Groves and R. Hinton, London: Earthscan.

Fargerlind, A. &Saha L. J. (1997) Education and National Development, New Delhi: Reed Educational and Professional Publishers Ltd.

Featherman, D. L. & Hauser, R. M. (1978) Opportunity and Change, New York: Academic Press.

Finch, C.R. & Crunkilton, J. R. (1999) Curriculum Development in Vocational and Technical Education, Needham Heights: Allan and Bacon.

Finnie, R. E. & Ronald, M. (2002) Minorities, Cognitive Skills and Incomes of Canadians Canadian Public Policy: A Journal for The discussion of Social and Economic Policy in Canada, Montreal, Vol. 28, No. 2, p. 257-273.

Fits-enz, Jac, (2000) The ROI of Human Capital- Measuring the Economic Value of Employee Performance, New York: AMACOM.

Foster, P. Technical and Vocational Education in the Less Developed Countries, International Journal of Educational Development, Vol. 7, No. 2, p. 137-149.

Galle, O. R.; Candace, H. Wiswell & Burr, J. A. (1985) Racial Mix and Industrial Productivity, American Sociological Review, Vol. 50, p. 20-33.

Garavan, T.N.; Morley, M.; Gunnigle, P.; & Collins, E. (2001) Human Capital Accumulation: The Role of Human Resource Development, Journal of European Industrial Training, Vol. 23, No. 2,3&4, pp.48-68.

Gary, S. B. (1993) Human Capital: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis with Special Reference to Education, Chicago: Chicago University Press.

Godo, Y. & Yujiro, H. (1999) Accumulation of Education in Modern Economic Growth: A Comparison of Japan with the United States, Asian Development Bank, Working Paper series, No.4, Washington: Asian Development Bank.

Goetz, S.J. & Hu, D. (1996) Economic Growth and Human Capital Accumulation: Simultaneity and Expended Convergence Tests, Economic Letter, Vol. 51, p. 355-362.

Gomez, M. (2010) An Education System for Sustained Growth and Economic Development, - http://www.cavehill.uwi.edu/BNCCde/belize/conference/papers2010/ gomez.html (retrieved on 26.09.2013).

Grootaert, C. (1990) Returns to Formal and Informal Vocational Education in Cote d Ivoire: The Role of the Structure of the Labor Market Economics of Education Review, Vol. 9 p. 309-319.

Griliches, Z. (1970) Notes on the Role of Education In Production Functions and Growth Accounting, in Hansen, W.C. (ed.) Education, Income and Human Capital, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research, Vol.35, - Studies in Income and Wealth).

Hanushek, E. A. & Woessmann, L. (2007) The Role of School Improvement in Economic Development, Program on Education Policy and Governance, Research Paper: 07-01.

Hempell, T. (2003) Do Computers Call for Training? Firm-level Evidence on Complementarities between ICT & Human Capital, Mannheim: Center for European Economic Research discussion paper.

Herbst, M. & Rok, J. (2013) Mobility of Human Capital and Its Effect on Regional Economic Development: Review of Theory and Empirical Literature, Munich: Munich Personal RePEC Archive.

Hippach-Schneider, U.; Krause, M.; Woll, C. and Panorama, C. (2007) Vocational Education and Training in Germany, Series: 138, Luxemburg: Office for Official Publications of the European Communities.

Iack, Arthur, L. (2009) Strategic Plan for Vocational Education Services in the CARRICOM Single Market and Economy-Navneet Boodhai, Concept Paper for the Development of a CARRICOM, Graduate School of Business: The University of the West Indies.

International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) (1995) Priorities and Strategies for Education: A World Bank Sector Review, Washington D. C.: World Bank Education and Social Policy Department.

Iles, P. A.; Mabey, C. & Robertson, I. T. (1990) HRM Practices and Employee Commitment: Possibilities, Pitfalls and Paradoxes, British Journal of Management, Vol. 1. p. 147-157.

Iniobong, Eknog, Nkang, (Oct. 2012) Higher Education and Human Capital Development in the Niger Delta Region of Nigeria, International Peer Reviewed Journal, Vol. 4, p. 1-18.

Janelle, A.; Scot, G. and Justine, L. (2006) Building Learning Communities: Partnership, Social Capital and VET Performance, A National Vocational Education & Training, Research and Evaluation Program Report, Australia: National Centre for Vocational Education and Research (NCVER).

Jones, D. C.; Kalmi, P. & Kauhanen, A. (2011) The Effects of General and Firm-specific Training on Wages and Performance: Evidence from Banking, Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 64 (2012), p. 151-175.

Jorgenson, D. W. (1984) The Contribution of Education to U.S. Economic Growth, in Education and Economic Productivity, (ed.) E. Dean, Cambridge: M. A.: Ballinger, p. 95-162.

Juhn, Chinhui; Kevin, M. Murphy & Brooks Pierce (1993) Wage Inequality and the Rise in Returns to Skill, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 101, No.3, p. 410-442.

King, K (2012) Skills and Education for All from Jomtien (1990) to the GMR of 2012: A Policy History, Journal of Training Research, Vol. 9, No. 1 & 2, p. 16-34.

King, K. (2011, Sep.) Towards a New Global World of Skill Development: TVET Turn to Make its Mark, NORRAG News, No. 46.

King, K. (2009) A Technical and Vocational Education and Training strategy for UNESCO: A Background Paper http://recoup.educ.cam.ac.uk/news/tvtsstrategyforunesco.pdf (retrieved on 2013.0924).

King, K & Palmer, R. (2010) Planning for Technical and Vocational Skills Development, Paris: UNESCO: International Institute for Educational Planning.

Kingombe, C. (2012) Lessons for Developing Countries from Experience with Technical and Vocational Education and Training, Working Paper 11/1017, London: International Growth Centre.

Kruger, J & Dunning, D. (1999) Unskilled and Unaware of It: How Difficulties in Recognizing Ones Own Incompetence Lead to Inflated Self-Assessments, Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, Vo. 77. No.6, p. 1121-1134. (CHECK)

Krueger, A. B. & Lindahl, M. (1999) Education for Growth in Sweden and the World, NBER Working Papers: 7190, Sweden: National Bureau of Economic Research Inc.

Lesage, J. P. & Fischer, M. M. (2008) Spatial Growth Regressions: Model Specification, Estimation and Interpretation, Spatial Economic Analysis, Vol. 3, No. 3, p. 275-304.

Lewin, K. (1993) Investing in Technical Education: A Review of the Evidence, Vocational Aspects of Education, Vol. 45, p.217-228.

Lillis, K. & Hogan, D. (1983) Dilemmas of Diversification: Problems Associated with Vocational Education in Developing Countries, Comparative Education, Vol. 19, No. 1, p. 89-107.

Liu, J. & Sakamoto, A. (2002) The Role of Schooling in Taiwans Labor Market: Human Capital, Screening or Credentialism? Taiwanese Sociological Review, Vol. 29, p. 1-56.

Lucas, R. E. (1988) On the Mechanics of Economic Development, Journal of Monitory Economics, Vol. 22, p. 3-42.

Lumpkin, G. G. & Dess, G. T. (2005) The Role of Entrepreneurial Orientation in Stimulating Effective Corporate Entrepreneurship, Academy of Management Executive, Vol. 19 No. 1, p. 244-255.

Maclean, R.; Jagannathan, S. & Jouko, S. (Eds.) (2011) Skills Development for Inclusive and Sustainable Growth in Developing Asia-Pacific, Technical and Vocational Education Training: Issues, Concerns and Prospects, Vol. 19, Manila: Asian Development Bank.

Maclean, R. &Adalai, C. (2011 April ) The Future of Vocational Education and Training: Global Challenges and Possibilities, International Journal of Training and Research, Vol. 9, No 1 & 2, p. 2-15.

Maclean, R. & Wilson, D. (Eds.) (2009) International Handbook of Education for the Changing World of Work: Bridging Academic and Vocational Learning, Dordrecht: Springer.

Mankiw, N. G.; Romer, D. & Weil, D. N. (1992) Contribution to the Empires of Economic Growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Cambridge, MIT Press Journals, Vol. 107, Issue.2, p.407-437.

MartInez, A.C.; Levie, J.; Donna, J. K.; Rognvaldur, J. S. E. & Schott, T. (2010) Global Entrepreneurship Monitor Special report: A Global Perspective on Entrepreneurship Education and Training.http://www.gemconsortium.org/download.asp?fid=1005 (retrieved on 2013.09.11)

McIntosh, S. & Vignoles, A. (2001) Measuring and Assessing the Impact of Basic Skills on Labor Market Outcomes, Oxford Economic Papers, No. 53, p. 453-481.

McMahon, W. W. (1999) Education and Development: Measuring the Social Benefits, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Mellahi, K. (2000) Human Resource Development Through Vocational Education in Gulf Cooperation Countries: The Case of Saudi Arabia, Journal of Vocational Education and Training, Vol. 52, No.2, p. 329-344.

Middleton, J. & Ziderman, A. (1997) Overview: World Bank Policy Research on Vocational Education and Training (Skills Training in Developing Countries: Financing and Planning Issues, International Journal of Manpower, Vol. 18, No. 1 & 2, p. 6-23.

Middleton, J.; Ziderman, A. & Van Adams, A. (1993) Skills for Productivity: Vocational Education and Training in Developing Countries, New York: Oxford University Press.

Mincer, J. (1997) The Production of Human Capital and the Life Cycle of Earnings: Variations on a Theme, Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 15, No. 1 p. 26-47.

Mincer, J. (Sep. 1995) Economic Development, Growth of Human Capital, and the Dynamics of the Wage Structure, Discussion Paper Series, No. 744, Columbia: Columbia University.

Mincer, J. (1962) On-the-job Training: Costs, Returns and Some Implications, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 70, No. 5, p. 50-79

Mingat, A. & Tan, J. P. (1988) The Economic Returns to Investments in Project-related Training: Some Empirical Evidence, International Review of Education, Vol. 34, No.2, p. 225-240.

Miyazawa, K. (2011, March) Measuring Human Capital in Japan, Research Institute of Economy, Trade and Industry, RIETI Discussion Paper Series 11-E-037-2011 March, Japan: Nihon University - http://www.rieti.go.jp/en/ (retrieved on 2013.08.26).

Mun, C. L. (2008) Polytechnic Education, in L. S. Kong; G. C. Boon; B. Fredriksen; & T. J. Peng (eds.) Toward a Better Future: Education and Training for Economic Development in Singapore Since 1965, Washington, The World Bank, p. 135-148.

Mustapha, R. B. & Greenan, J. P. (2002) The Role of Vocational Education in Economic Development in Malaysia: Educators and Employers Perspectives, Journal of Industrial Teacher Education, (Virginia Tech E Journals), Vol. 39, No.2. http://scholar.lib.vt.edu/ejournals/JITE/v39n2/mustapha.html (retrieved on 2013.08.22).

National Panel for Economic Reform, (29th Jan. 2013) Meeting Communique:http://www.pm.gov.au/press_office/national-panel-economic-reform---meeting---one---communique (retrieved on 2013.09.16).

National Skills Standards Council, (March, 2013) Improving Vocational Education and Training: The Case for a New System, Melbourne: Coag Consultation, www.nssc.natese.gov.au/_data/assets/pdf.../NSSCposition_paper.pdf (retrieved on 2013.09.17).

Nelson, R.P. & Phelps, E. (1966) Investment in Humans, Technological Diffusion and Economic Growth, American Economic Review, Nashville: American Economic Association, Vol. 61, No.2, p. 69-75.

Neuman, S. & Ziderman, A. (1991) Vocational Schooling, Occupational Matching and Labor Market Earnings in Israel, Journal of Human Resource, Vol. 26, p. 256-281.

Nickell, S. (2004) Poverty and Worklessness in Britain, Economic Journal, No.114, (March) (I No. 65-184 http://www.nber05/moretti.html (retrieved on 2013.08.26).

Ng, Y.C.; & Siu, N. Y. M. (2004) Training and Enterprise Performance in Transition: Evidence from China, International Journal of Human Resource Management, Vol. 15, Issue. 45, pp. 878-894.

Nordhaug, O. (1988) Competencies Specificities in Organizations, International Studies of Management and Organization, Vol. 28, No.1, p. 8-29.

NORRAG, (2003) Debates in Skills Development: Skills for Life and Work, Geneva: Working Group for International Cooperation in Skills Development.

Onyinyechi, O. S. & Akamike, O.J. (2011) The Emerging Myths and Realities of Human Resource and Capital Development in Nigeria, Proceedings of the 1st International Technology, Education and Environment Conference, Nigeria: African Society for Scientific Research and Human Resource Management Academic Research Society, p. 283-292.

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), (2010) Vocational Education and Training in Germany: Strengths, Challenges and Recommendations, Directorate for Education, Education and Training Policy Division, www.oecd.org/edu/skills-beyond-school/4598559.pdf. (retrieved on 2013.09.03).

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), (2001) The Well-being of Nations: The Role of Human Capital-Education and Skills, Centre for Education and Research and Innovation, Paris: OECD.

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), (2000) Human Capital and Growth: A Synthesis Report, written by Pissarides, C. A.- Research Program on Human Resource Development and Poverty Reduction, Working Paper: 168, Paris: OECD.

Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD), (1998) Human Capital Investment: An International Comparison, P


Top Related