are excise taxes on beverages fully passed through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/bergmanhansen.pdf ·...

30
Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence U. Michael Bergman ** University of Copenhagen, Denmark Niels Lynggård Hansen Danmarks Nationalbank, Denmark April 5, 2010 Abstract The purpose of this paper is to study tax shifting of excise taxes on alcoholic and non–alcoholic beverages at the micro–level in Denmark. We focus on six episodes of tax changes. Taxes on liquor were cut in 2003, taxes on soft drinks were raised in 1998 and 2001 and cut in 2003 whereas taxes on beer were increased in 1997 and cut in 2005. We find a considerable heterogeneity across products, brands, types of stores and regions. In general the empirical evidence suggests overshifting of tax hikes and undershifting of tax cuts. Our results suggest that it is very important to condition estimates of revenue gains or losses and public–health outcomes on specific market conditions for different brands and products. JEL: H22, D40 Key Words: Tax incidence; excise tax; beverages. ** We thank Bo William Hansen and Jakob Egholt Søgaard for excellent research assistance. We are also grateful to Klaus Kristensen, Brigitte Sloth, Peter Birch Sørensen and seminar participants at the University of Copenhagen and at the Danish Economic Society Conference in Kolding 2010 for helpful comments, discussions and suggestions. Financial support from EPRN is gratefully acknowledged. Corresponding author: Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Øster Farimagsgade 5, build- ing 26, DK–1353 Copenhagen K, Denmark. Email address: [email protected] –1–

Upload: others

Post on 03-Feb-2020

5 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed

Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

U. Michael Bergman!!

University of Copenhagen, Denmark

Niels Lynggård Hansen

Danmarks Nationalbank, Denmark

April 5, 2010

Abstract

The purpose of this paper is to study tax shifting of excise taxes on alcoholic and

non–alcoholic beverages at the micro–level in Denmark. We focus on six episodes of

tax changes. Taxes on liquor were cut in 2003, taxes on soft drinks were raised in

1998 and 2001 and cut in 2003 whereas taxes on beer were increased in 1997 and cut

in 2005. We find a considerable heterogeneity across products, brands, types of stores

and regions. In general the empirical evidence suggests overshifting of tax hikes and

undershifting of tax cuts. Our results suggest that it is very important to condition

estimates of revenue gains or losses and public–health outcomes on specific market

conditions for di!erent brands and products.

JEL: H22, D40

Key Words: Tax incidence; excise tax; beverages.

!!We thank Bo William Hansen and Jakob Egholt Søgaard for excellent research assistance. We arealso grateful to Klaus Kristensen, Brigitte Sloth, Peter Birch Sørensen and seminar participants at theUniversity of Copenhagen and at the Danish Economic Society Conference in Kolding 2010 for helpfulcomments, discussions and suggestions. Financial support from EPRN is gratefully acknowledged.Corresponding author: Department of Economics, University of Copenhagen, Øster Farimagsgade 5, build-ing 26, DK–1353 Copenhagen K, Denmark. Email address: [email protected]

– 1 –

Page 2: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

1 Introduction

Cross–border shopping between Denmark and three of its closest neighboring countries is

considerable. Around 1.5 percent of private consumption is estimated to come from cross–

border shopping, and beverages represent an important item in that respect. According

to estimates by the Danish tax authorities cross–border shopping amounts to around 20

percent of beers bought by Danish households. For soft drinks the figure is about 10

percent, whereas for liquor it approaches 50 percent. While foreign trading with goods

exploiting comparative advantages is considered welfare enhancing, the Danish government

and tax authorities view cross–border shopping driven by higher taxes than abroad as a

problem. It implies a loss of revenue to the Danish state, while Danish households benefit

only from the di!erence to the foreign country in taxes and duties and furthermore face

extra costs related to transportation and stocking of goods. Hence cross–border shopping

is associated with significant negative externalities. These are even further accentuated,

when the impact on public health and the environment is taken into consideration.

In order to decrease cross–border shopping, the Danish government has implemented

a number of changes of excise taxes on beverages, both alcoholic and non–alcoholic bever-

ages. The excise taxes on soft drinks was cut by 0.29 DKK per bottle on average in October

2003 when also the excise tax on liquor was cut by 125 DKK per bottle of 100 percent pure

alcohol corresponding to an excise tax cut by 33.25 DKK on a bottle of Gammel Dansk.

In January 2005 the tax on beer was cut by 0.16 DKK per bottle on average. These tax

cuts were motivated by the expiry of the 24–hour rule by end–2003 implying a phasing out

of quantitative restrictions for cross–border shopping, since this was expected to lead to a

sharp increase in cross–border shopping with Germany where the prices on these products

are considerably lower. Furthermore, Danish tax authorities estimated strong e!ects on

the cross–border shopping if these tax changes were implemented and also suggested, using

– 2 –

Page 3: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

cost–benefit analyzes, that they were welfare enhancing. These estimates were all based on

the assumption of full tax–pass through, i.e., that the after–tax price would fall in accor-

dance with the tax change. The evidence provided by the Danish tax authorities following

these tax changes are not fully consistent with the prior that cross–border shopping should

fall as a result of the tax cuts. Most strikingly, and in sharp contradiction with the initial

prediction, the amounts of soft drinks bought outside Denmark increased significantly in

the years following the reduction of excise taxes. The same picture, though less marked,

holds for beers.

In this paper we provide a detailed account of the e!ects of prices caused by the three

tax cuts mentioned above. Our analysis is based on micro data collected on a monthly basis

by Statistics Denmark and comprise detailed prices of brand name items, the outlet chain

including zip codes allowing us to identify and track the price on each individual brand in

a specific store. We first estimate the average tax–pass through across all stores for each

brand in our sample and then we turn to the question whether the pass through is constant

across stores and whether it is related to the proximity to the German border. This latter

aspect is interesting to study since it may be hypothesized that any tax change should be

fully passed to prices the closer to the border the retailer is located. The cross–border

shopping with Germany would also tend to increase the downward pressure on after tax

prices and, if this argument is correct, we should find lower after tax prices on average in

stores located close to the German border. Our results will also have implications for the

cost–benefit analyzes that Danish tax authorities use to motivate adjustments of excise

taxes. If taxes are not fully passed on to prices, this will potentially have strong e!ects on

the estimates of costs and benefits from reduced cross–border shopping.

There have been three other excise tax changes on these products during the last 20

years. The excise tax on beer was increased in May 1997 corresponding to an increase

in the tax by 0.04 DKK per bottle on average and there have been two tax hikes on soft

– 3 –

Page 4: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

drinks, in January 1998 when the tax was increased by 0.13 DKK per bottle on average

and in January 2001 when the excise tax was further increased by 0.41 DKK per bottle

on average. We will compare our findings on the tax pass–through on prices when taxes

are cut with these three cases of tax hikes. This allows us to examine whether there are

asymmetric e!ects of tax hikes and tax cuts.

From economic theory we know that sales and excise taxes are fully shifted onto con-

sumers in a model with full competition and constant marginal costs (Kotliko! and Sum-

mers (1987) and Fullerton and Metcalf (2002)). These predictions do not hold under

imperfect competition (Bishop (1968), Stern (1987) and Delipalla and Keen (1992)), how-

ever. There could, in theory, be both overshifting and less than full shifting on markets

with imperfect competition (the pass–through of sales and excise taxes may be less than,

equal to or greater than 100%).

Despite the attention paid in the theoretical literature, there are surprisingly few empiri-

cal studies of the e!ects of excise tax changes on prices.1 The main result from these studies

is that tax incidence is heterogeneous across products, for some types of goods there is less

than full shifting whereas for other products the evidence suggests over–shifting. Poterba

(1996) and Besley and Rosen (1999) examine a limited number of goods prices, three com-

modity groups and 12 specific goods, respectively. Carbonnier (2005) studies three VAT

reforms in France focusing on the asymmetric e!ects of tax hikes and tax reductions. There

are also case studies mainly focusing on tobacco and gas prices, see, e.g., Delipalla and

O’Donnel (2001) and Doyle and Samphantharak (2008). Young and Bieli"ska–Kwapisz

(2002) examine whether beer taxes are good proxies for the price of alcohol and analyze

also how taxes on alcoholic beverages are passed through to consumers. They find that

beer taxes are poor predictors of alcohol prices and the excise taxes are overshifted to con-1Poterba (1996) reviews the early empirical studies going back to the 1930s whereas Fullerton and

Metcalf (2002) review both theory and more recent empirical results.

– 4 –

Page 5: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

sumers using US data. Kenkel (2005) collects data on several brands of alcoholic beverages

in Alaska and estimates the tax pass–through of the tax hike in October 2002. The main

result is that excise taxes are overshifted (except for Miller beer), prices increase between

1.40–4.9 times the tax change. He also observes a high degree of heterogeneity both across

brands and di!erent products. Common to these two latter studies is that they only ex-

amine the e!ects of tax hikes and that they do not distinguish between types of stores

or the location of stores, two aspects that may be of potential interest. We find that tax

hikes are overshifted whereas tax cuts in general are undershifted except for the tax cut

on liquor. The tax pass–through is not constant across types of stores or across zip codes

and we fail to find a significant German and Swedish border e!ect, except possibly for tax

cuts on beer where our empirical evidence suggests a weak e!ect.

The paper is organized in the following way. In section 2 we provide a very brief

discussion of the expected e!ects of changes in excise taxes on after tax prices under

di!erent market conditions. Section 3 describes the data in more detail. Section 4 contains

our empirical analysis. Finally, section 5 concludes.

2 Background

It is well–known that within a model with full competition, taxes are fully passed on to

prices leading to a one–for–one change in after tax prices if there is a change in taxes.

This result holds for ad valorem as well as for excise taxes. Under imperfect competition,

however, excise taxes may be overshifted (or maybe also undershifted) as shown by Delipalla

and Keen (1992). They analyze the conjectural variations model of an oligopoly with both

fixed number of firms and with free entry.2 The model as it is formulated encompasses2See also Katz and Rosen (1985), Stern (1987) and Besley (1989) for similar analysis of the conjectural

variations model. Anderson, de Palma and Kreider (2001) show that all results discussed in these paperscan also be obtained in a model with heterogenous goods. Bishop (1968) provides an analysis of taxincidence of both ad valorem and excise taxes under full competition and monopoly. Fullerton and Metcalf

– 5 –

Page 6: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

both the Cournot–Nash model where a firm takes prices as given and chooses the quantity

such that the profit is maximized and the Bertrand model where a firm takes quantities

supplied as given and chooses prices in order to maximize profits. The adjustment of

output in a representative firm in response to a change in total output is, as is well–known,

of particular interest. When a firm decides how much to produce, it must make a guess

about how other firms in the same industry will react. The conjectural variations model

provides a unified and convenient framework for discussing the behavior of firms in an

oligopoly.

Delipalla and Keen (1992) find that overshifting may occur under oligopoly, a result

di!erent from the case when there is full competition where overshifting cannot occur

and further demonstrates that overshifting of excise taxes is a necessary but not su#cient

condition for overshifting of ad valorem taxes. The reason why there may be overshifting of

excise taxes is that when there is a tax increase, output will fall as a result of a reduction in

demand. In some cases firms decide to increase the price by more than the tax increase to

compensate for the loss of revenue.3 It can be shown that if we assume constant elasticity

of demand, overshifting will always occur and the degree of overshifting increases as the

demand becomes less elastic. In case both the cost function and the demand function are

linear we find that there is no overshifting but undershifting.4

These results are not a!ected if we allow for free entry and exit. In this case the number

of firms may change as a result of tax changes. Under the assumption that firms enter

until the marginal firm earns zero profit, Delipalla and Keen (1992) show that overshifting

of excise taxes is more likely with free entry than in the case the number of firms is fixed,

the di!erence between the tax e!ect under fixed number of firms and with free entry is

(2002) survey the literature.3The e!ect of the tax change on profits is uncertain. If demand is Cobb–Douglas, there will be no

change in profits if there is a marginal increase in the excise tax even if there is overshifting, see Fullertonand Metcalf (2002).

4These results can also be found for monopolies, both undershifting and overshifting may occur.

– 6 –

Page 7: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

negative. The reason for this result is that the tax also a!ects the number of firms, a higher

tax tends to reduce the number of firms giving remaining firms more market power.

These results in the literature also suggest that empirical findings suggesting full shifting

of excise taxes cannot be used to infer that the market under consideration is character-

ized by full competition as it may be the case that there is full pass–through even under

oligopoly. From an empirical point of view it is also noteworthy that we should find less

evidence of overshifting of ad valorem taxes than for excise taxes since overshifting of ex-

cise taxes is a necessary but not su#cient condition for overshifting of ad valorem taxes.

This suggest that the likelihood of finding overshifting in empirical studies increases when

studying excise taxes than when analyzing the e!ects of ad valorem taxes. In the next

sections we will focus on the e!ect of excise tax changes on after tax prices on beverages.

3 Data

We employ a unique data set of micro data collected on a monthly basis by Statistics Den-

mark used to compute the Danish CPI. The available sample is January 1997 to December

2005. The data is very detailed, for each price record we have the following information:

The price of the item, the year and month, the brand name of the item, the name of the

product category, a numeric code for a given outlet chain and a numeric outlet code. This

information allows us to identify and track the price of each individual item, i.e., a specific

product in a specific outlet. The product category code corresponds to the Classification

of Individual Consumption (COICOP) 5–digit code. In addition to these series we also

have zip codes for each specific outlet allowing us to study for example border e!ects in

more detail.

The data is collected by Danish Statistics each month but the number of collected prices

for each good varies considerably over time. For example, before January 2000 Danish

– 7 –

Page 8: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Statistics collected 200 prices on the Danish liquor Gammel Dansk but from October 2003

they only collect 11 prices. Furthermore, for some specific brands only very few prices are

collected. We have decided to focus on brands where, in general, more than five prices

are collected but we also report some statistics for all brands regardless of how many

prices are collected. This implies that we focus on at most six brands of beer (the Danish

brands Carlsberg and Tuborg dominate the market), six brands of soft drinks (including

international brands such as Coca–Cola as well domestic brands like Tuborg Squash) and

seven brands of liquor.

There are in total 6 episodes of changes in excise taxes during the period 1997–2005,

two tax changes on beer, three on soft drinks and one on liquor. For soft drinks the excise

tax was increased on January 1, 1998 from 0.80 DKK per liter to 1.00 DKK per liter

corresponding to 0.13 DKK on average per bottle and then further increased on January

1, 2001 to 1.65 DKK per liter (corresponding to 0.41 DKK per bottle on average) and on

October 1, 2003 the excise tax was cut to 1.15 DKK per liter (corresponding to 0.29 DKK

per bottle on average). This allows us to study the symmetry of e!ects of excise taxes on

prices on soft drinks. The tax on beer was increased by 0.04 DKK per bottle on average on

May 1, 1997 and on January 9, 2005 the tax was cut by on average 0.16 DKK per bottle.5

The tax on liquor was cut by 125 DKK per 100 percent pure alcohol on October 1, 2003.

4 Empirical analysis

4.1 Excise tax pass–through across brands

In Table 1, we describe the data and compute the average tax incidence (the total e!ect

from a change in the excise tax on the after tax price including ad valorem taxes) per brand5The excise tax on beer was also changed on October 1, 2004 so that the tax reflected the strength of

alcohol. This change was neutral such that prices on beer was not a!ected.

– 8 –

Page 9: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

for the di!erent episodes of interest. The first five columns show the number of collected

prices for each product and the total number of collected prices in each category. Then

we show the average price, average price change, the actual tax change conditional on the

amount of alcohol in each product and the computed tax pass–through (which is equal to

the price change divided by the tax change).

Looking at the fifth column it is evident that the average tax pass–through for each

category of goods is above one (>1.35) when taxes are increased on soft drinks and beer.

There is thus evidence of overshifting for these products. This result can be compared to

the e!ect of tax cuts. From Table 1 we find that there is on average undershifting for soft

drinks and a slight overshifting for liquor when taxes are cut. For beer we find that average

prices increased after the tax cut (the tax pass–through is negative but below one). This

result is explained by the very sharp price increase on Tuborg Grøn registered in the data.

Excluding this brand from the sample, we find that the pass–through on average is 0.27

indicating undershifting of prices. An important observation when comparing tax cuts and

tax increases is that overshifting appears more likely when taxes are increased compared

to when they are cut. Tax pass–through for soft drinks is above 2 when taxes are increased

and below one when taxes are cut. The same holds for beer where the pass–through is 0.27

when taxes are cut but 1.35 when they are raised.

When comparing the tax pass–through across products we find considerable variation,

see Table 1. For some brands we find undershifting but for others overshifting. This is not

surprising since we have shown in section 2 that the elasticity of demand determines the

extent of tax shifting. The large di!erences in pass–through across brands therefore reflect

di!erent demand elasticities.

The last four columns of Table 1 report the tax pass–through across stores. We report

the fraction of stores with undershifting (defined as a tax pass–through less than 0.9), frac-

tion of stores with full pass–through (tax pass–through between 0.9 and 1.1) and fraction

– 9 –

Page 10: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

of stores with overshifting (pass–through exceeds 1.1). The last column reports the fraction

of stores with zero pass–through, i.e., the fraction of stores leaving prices unchanged. Also

across storers, we find large di!erences and very di!erent results for the three categories of

beverages. Consider first the results for beer. From Table 1 we observe that the number

of stores that leave prices unchanged is higher on average when there is a tax cut (68%

versus 47%). At the same time we find that there is much more variation across products

when taxes are cut. For some brands very few stores leave the price unchanged (Tuborg

Grøn) whereas many stores leave prices unchanged for other brands (Carlsberg Sort Guld).

When the tax is increased almost 50% of the stores leave their prices unchanged. Similarly

we find large di!erences for the number of stores with overshifting, from zero to above

30% of the stores overshift their prices when the tax is cut compared to more than 38% of

the stores when taxes are raised. There is a somewhat higher fraction of stores with full

pass–through when taxes are raised compared to when they are cut (10% versus 2%).

The results for soft drinks very much confirm this general picture. A larger fraction of

stores leaves their prices unchanged when there is a tax cut compared to when taxes are

increased and there is a larger fraction of stores with undershifting when taxes are cut than

when they are increased. A larger number of stores overshift prices when there is a tax

increase. However, there is one notable di!erence between the price setting of soft drinks

and beer. There are a considerably larger number of stores with full pass–through when

the tax was cut in 2003 compared to the two tax increases in 1998 and 2001. For beer we

found the opposite result even though the di!erence was minor.

Finally, for liquor we find that almost no stores left their prices unchanged when the tax

was cut in 2003. The majority of stores cut their prices in full accordance to the tax cut

whereas one fourth of the stores undershifted and overshifted prices, respectively. There is

also one interesting result when comparing brands. The price on Gin was cut more than

the tax cut in all stores and there was full pass–through in all stores for Ålborg Ta!el

– 10 –

Page 11: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Akvavit and Gammel Dansk, two Danish brands.

In Table 2 we test whether the average tax pass–through for our focus brands are

complete, i.e., testing whether average pass–through reported in Table 1 is unity. The

table only reports the p–value from these tests. There is no uniform result from these

tests. Comparing tax hikes with tax cuts for soft drinks and beer we find that there are

fewer cases of full tax pass–through for beer for a tax hike but the opposite results for soft

drinks. Looking more closely at the results in Table 2 and the point estimates reported in

Table 1 we find that for beer there is one case (out of four cases) of overshifting in case

there are a tax hike and two cases when there is undershifting when taxes are cut.6 Turning

to soft drinks, the empirical evidence suggests that taxes are overshifted to consumers for

almost all brands when taxes are raised and undershifted for three out of six cases. One

conclusion that can be drawn from these tests is that the beer market seems to be more

competitive than the market for soft drinks. There are only a few cases where tax changes

are not fully passed on to consumers. For liquor we find three cases (out of seven cases)

of overshifting and one case of undershifting. Even though the tests suggest over and

undershifting, the point estimates are very close to unity suggesting that the market for

liquor is very competitive, at least in comparison to the market for soft drinks.

Next we test whether the tax pass–through is complete for the three di!erent types of

beverages distinguishing between tax hikes and tax cuts. Since the data for Tuborg Grøn

suggest very di!erent behavior of the tax pass–through, we will exclude these observations

in the remaining part of the empirical analysis. Table 3 reports the results from these tests.

For tax hikes we can always reject the null hypothesis that the tax pass–through is full.

This suggests that retailers increase their after tax prices by more than the tax increase.

The lower panel of this table reports the results when testing the null of full pass–through

during tax cuts. Here the evidence shows that we reject full pass–through for soft drinks6The results also suggest that there is overshifting for one additional brand, Tuborg Grøn.

– 11 –

Page 12: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

and for beer whereas we cannot reject full pass–through for liquor. Given the very strong

rejection of this null for soft drinks and beer it is not surprising that the joint null is also

rejected at conventional significance levels.

Another way to further explore the relations between excise taxes and the pass–through

of such taxes is to run regressions of the type

!pt = !0 + !1pt!1 (1)

where pt,i is the price change following a change in the excise tax and pt!1 is the baseline

price prior to the excise tax change. According to economic theory discussed in section

2, we know that the tax pass–through should be independent on the price suggesting

that the parameter !1 = 0. The estimate of !0 then provides an estimate of average

tax pass–through (if we divide !0 with the tax change). We may also extend this simple

regression, for example, by distinguishing between di!erent brands. The results when

running regressions for the three di!erent types of beverages and for all six episodes of tax

changes are reported in Table 4. Consider first the regressions where we do not distinguish

between brands. For tax hikes we find that stores that charged higher baseline prices,

passed on more of the tax hike on to customers (for tax hikes on soft drinks but not for

beer) whereas for tax cuts we find the opposite result, stores that charged higher prices

passed on less of the tax hike to their customers (except for the tax cut on soft drinks in

2003). This pattern also hold when we allow for di!erent brand e!ects. These parameters

are very often significant and lend support to the hypothesis that baseline price also is an

important determinant of the tax pass–through.

It may be the case that an excise tax change on beer, for example, also has an e!ect on

pre–tax prices on soft drinks and liquor, stores may use strategic price adjustments when

the excise tax on one type of beverage is altered. To examine whether the frequency of price

– 12 –

Page 13: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

changes is related across types of beverages, we run simple regressions of the frequencies

in Figure 1 on a constant and dummies indicating excise tax changes on other beverages.

These regressions show that we cannot reject the null hypothesis that the frequency of price

changes on one type of beverage is una!ected when the excise tax is changed for the other

two types of beverages. This indicates that retailers do not engage in strategic pricing

when there is an excise tax change. However, as was mentioned above, the frequency of

price changes on each type of beverage is significantly higher than on average during the

month when there is an excise tax change.

The analyzes above focus only on the particular month when the excise tax was altered.

As a sensitivity check, we have computed and compared the average price inflation up to

two months after the tax change. These calculations reveal that (as is also indicated in

Figure 1) that prices on the three di!erent types of beverages did not change much during

the next two months after a tax change. The only exception is after the tax cut on beer in

2005. In February 2005, price inflation on beer was on average 0.5% but in March prices

fell again with on average 0.6%. Our estimate of the tax pass–through is not, therefore,

a!ected when considering the price change up to three months after this tax change. For

all other excise tax changes we find a very minor tendency that our estimates of the tax

pass–through is understated. This holds both for tax hikes as well as for tax cuts. Tax

hikes overshoot whereas tax cuts undershoot when computing the price change over the

following three months instead of over only one month.

4.2 Excise tax pass–through across chains of stores and across zip

codes

The data base available has records of the particular store where the price is collected. This

allows us to distinguish between di!erent stores, for example between a store in a national

– 13 –

Page 14: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

chain or if the store is independent. We have, in our sample, 17 di!erent chains of stores

and they are numbered accordingly. We have also full information about the location of

all stores where prices are collected, implying that we can also study the pattern of tax

pass–through across zip codes. The zip codes are described in Appendix A.

In Table 5 we show the results of testing whether the tax pass–through is constant

across types of stores and constant across zip codes. The table reports p–values of Wald

tests testing whether the parameters associated with types of stores (zip codes) are equal

across all types (zip codes) for each type of beverage and also distinguishing between tax

hikes and tax cuts. We find considerable heterogeneity. For tax hikes (see the upper panel

of Table 5) we always reject, at the 10 percent level, the null hypothesis that the tax pass–

through is constant across types of stores and across zip codes. These results do, however,

change when considering tax cuts as can be seen in the lower panel of Table 5. In this case

we only reject the null for beer (both for types of stores and for zip codes). It seems as if

retailers of di!erent types and located possibly far apart do react similar to an excise tax

cuts on soft drinks and on liquor. For beer we find the same result as for the case of tax

hikes, retailers typically react individually to tax cuts on beer.

Looking more closely at the underlying data we find that there are stores raising the

after tax price following a tax cut or (less seldom) cutting the after tax price following a

tax hike. There seem to be large di!erences across di!erent chains of stores suggesting

that the responses to excise tax changes in general are not identical, a result we found for

tax hikes. This may indicate that certain chains of stores have considerable market power.

It is also interesting to note that there seems to be more conformity in their response to

the tax cut on liquor, there are only very small di!erences across chains of stores, and not

only across brands as was illustrated above in Table 1.

Returning to the question about symmetry we compare the results for beer and soft

drinks across stores. There is no uniform result across the two products except that the

– 14 –

Page 15: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

fraction of stores with undershifting is higher when there is a tax cut. A majority of stores

with undershifting do not change their prices at all. In particular, it is surprising that

65% of the stores do not change the price when the tax on beer was cut in 2005. At the

same time, 41% of the stores did not change the price when the tax was increased in 1997.

Similar results are found for soft drinks even though a much smaller fraction of stores did

not adjust their prices. As a comparison we find that only 1% of the stores kept their

prices unchanged on liquor when the tax was cut in 2003 and that 62% of the stores fully

adjusted their prices.7

Comparing the tax hike and tax cuts on beer we find a higher frequency of overshifting

for the tax hike and a higher frequency of undershifting of the tax cut, a result also evident

in Table 1 above. A surprising result is that stores in Southjutland (zip code 6) undershifted

the tax cut in 2005. Beer prices are much lower across the border in Germany and it could

have been expected that Danish stores took the opportunity of reducing prices further in

order to compete better with German stores. On the other hand, the price di!erence fell

as a result of the tax cut and it may be the case that stores located close to the border

counted on increased sale after the tax cut.

Turning to soft drinks we find that the tax hike in 1998 in particular but also the tax

hike in 2001 was overshifted to consumers. The fraction of stores increasing prices less than

the tax hike increased somewhat in 2001 compared to after the tax change in 1998. This

may reflect competition from both Germany and Sweden where prices on soft drinks in

general are lower. This was also recognized by the government and in 2003 the excise tax

was cut resulting in lower prices and many stores also cut their prices more than what was

motivated by the tax cut, except for Northjutland (zip code 9). There is less competition

from cross–border shopping in this region.

For liquor we find that a very large fraction of stores in zip code 1 (Copenhagen City)7These results are not shown here for brevity.

– 15 –

Page 16: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

cut their prices more than the tax cut. This may reflect a highly competitive market for

liquor. Such a conclusion is also supported by the absence of stores where prices were cut

less than what was motivated by the tax cut. Stores located in zip code 4 (North Zealand

and Bornholm) reduced the price less than the reduction in the tax or fully adjusted their

prices. The market in these regions seems to be somewhat less competitive. It could also

be noted also that stores in North Zealand compete with the Swedish state monopoly

where alcohol taxes are much higher. It is likely that stores close to the Swedish border

already are competitive in relation to the Swedish monopoly which could explain why the

adjustment of prices in response to the tax cut in 2003 was fully shifted or even overshifted

to consumers, some of them Swedish residents.

This analysis reveals that there are significant di!erences across regions and types of

stores which indicate that the amount of cross–border shopping may explain the behavior.

We will turn to this issue in the next section.

4.3 Excise tax pass–through and border e!ects

In order to study the e!ects of cross–border shopping in more detail, we now focus on

the existence of a border e!ect. One underlying argument for excise tax cuts used by

the government was to prevent and limit cross–border trade with Germany where excise

taxes on alcoholic beverages are considerably lower. This same argument also applies to

the excise tax cuts on soft drinks. Historically, retail prices on soft drinks are very high

in Denmark, much higher than in most other European countries including Germany. In

Sweden, on the other hand, excise taxes on alcoholic beverages are much higher than in

Denmark resulting in a higher demand in regions close to the Danish border. Prices on soft

drinks are, in general, lower in Sweden. Cross–border trade with Sweden is particularly

high in the Greater Copenhagen Region which may a!ect the general price level in this

region and therefore also potentially a!ect the tax pass–through. From these observations

– 16 –

Page 17: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

we conjecture that the tax pass–through of a tax hike (tax cut) should be smaller (larger)

as the distance to the German border decreases. The opposite e!ects can be expected for

retailers located close to the Swedish border.

In order to examine if this is the case we run regressions similar to the ones discussed in

the previous sections, i.e., we regress the actual tax pass–through on dummies associated

with each type of beverage and an interaction term which is the product of the type of

beverage and the shortest distance to the German border measured in km’s (the distance

from the center of the zip code to the nearest town in Germany). We also add interaction

terms indicating the proximity to the Swedish border. We use two di!erent classifications,

one where zip codes 1, 2, 3 and 4 are regarded as bordering to Sweden and one where we

only consider zip codes 1 and 3.

The results are shown in Table 6. We run three regressions for each tax hikes and

three for tax cuts. First we only include the distance to the German border, and then

we include also an interaction term indicating whether a particular store is located close

to the Swedish border. We expect the parameter associated with the German border to

be negative when we estimate the regressions for tax hikes and positive for tax cuts. For

stores located close to the Swedish border we expect the opposite signs.

Looking at the first three columns of this table reporting the parameter estimate of

the exact distance to the German border measured in km’s we find very limited evidence

supporting the prior that the tax pass–through is a!ected. There is no significant e!ects

for tax hikes and for tax cuts we find that the tax pass–through on beer is significantly

higher than average if a store is located close to the German border. When also including

dummies indicating that a store is located close to the Swedish border we find only one

case where there is a significant e!ect, for beer when we only use zip codes 1 and 3. The

e!ect is strongly positive indicating that the tax pass–through in these stores exceeds the

average, the opposite result from what we may expect given that prices on beer is generally

– 17 –

Page 18: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

much higher in Sweden compared to in Denmark.

5 Conclusions

This paper, studying six episodes of excise tax changes on beverages in the Danish economy,

finds that taxes are more than fully passed through to consumers when there is a tax hike

while there is undershifting when taxes are cut. The former result is consistent with earlier

empirical evidence, for example Kenkel (2005) analyzing the Alaskan tax hike in October

2002. The latter results complement these findings.

Our results also suggest large di!erences across brands and across di!erent types of

beverages. For liquor we find that the tax pass-through is very close to unity, on average

across all brands we cannot reject full tax pass–through. Furthermore, our point estimates

are much smaller than the point estimates in Kenkel. We also find undershifting for one

brand out of seven brands studied in more detail. For soft drinks and beer we typically find

higher point estimates suggesting that excise tax hikes on these products are overshifted

(or undershifted in case of a tax cut), full tax pass–through is rejected in nine out of 13

cases (and in six out of 12 cases when the tax is cut).

These results suggest that there is no clear and uniform e!ect of changes in excise

taxes on prices. This is an important finding as it has consequences for the links from

tax policy to alcohol consumption and further on to public–health outcomes even though

such arguments were not used by the Danish government when they decided to change

taxes. Instead, the main argument for the tax cuts was to prevent cross–border shopping

with Germany. Tax hikes were not motivated explicitly. One would anticipate that the

pass–through of tax cuts therefore should di!er across regions with less pass–through for

regions in the proximity to the German border.

Our empirical results suggest that the distance to Germany or Sweden cannot signif-

– 18 –

Page 19: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

icantly explain the extent of the after tax price change, except possibly for tax cuts on

beer. There are large di!erences between the tax pass–through across regions (and types

of stores) but there is no strong empirical result suggesting a German border e!ect. The

same result holds for regions close to the Swedish border, there is no e!ect of the proximity

to the Swedish border and the extent of tax pass–through.

The conclusion from our empirical analysis is that the market for beverages in Den-

mark is segmented and that di!erent types of stores apply di!erent price strategies. One

observation is that establishments do not seem to change prices uniformly across the price

spectra and across brands. When comparing the tax pass–through of tax hikes on beer and

soft drinks, we find no clear evidence that the same price setting strategy is used within

the same type of stores or chains of stores. The same result holds for tax cuts. There is a

high degree of heterogeneity across time. Our interpretation of these results is that retail-

ers in Denmark have substantial local market power. The findings in this paper also have

consequences for policy makers. As there is a considerable variation in tax pass–through

across products, across brands, across types of stores and across regions it is very di#cult

to evaluate the e!ects of tax changes on alcohol consumption and therefore also on public-

health outcomes. Our results provide an explanation to why the Danish tax authorities

overestimated the e!ects of the tax cuts and possibly also overestimated the welfare e!ects

of these tax cuts. These estimates can be improved if these take into account our finding

that tax cuts usually are undershifted whereas tax hikes are overshifted.

References

Anderson, S. P., A. de Palma and B. Kreider, (2001), “Tax Incidence in Di!erentiated

Product Oligopoly,” Journal of Public Economics, 81, 173–192.

– 19 –

Page 20: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Besley, T., (1989), “Commodity Taxation and Imperfect Competition: A Note on the

E!ects of Entry,” Journal of Public Economics, 40, 359–367.

Besley, T. J. and H. S. Rosen, (1999), “Sales Taxes and Prices: An Empirical Analysis,”

National Tax Journal, 52, 157–178.

Bishop, R. L., (1968), “The E!ects of Specific and Ad Valorem Taxes,” Quarterly Journal

of Economics, 82, 198–218.

Carbonnier, C., (2005), “Who Pays Commodity Taxes? Evidence of a Double Asymmet-

rical E!ect on Tax Shifting, France 1995–2000,” EHESS and PSE, manuscript.

Delipalla, S. and M. Keen, (1992), “The Comparison Between Ad Valorem and Specific

Taxation under Imperfect Competition,” Journal of Public Economics, 49, 351–367.

Delipalla, S. and O. O’Donnel, (2001), “Estimating Tax Incidence, Market Power and Mar-

ket Conduct: The European Cigarette Industry,” International Journal of Industrial

Organization, 19, 885–908.

Doyle, J. J. J. and K. Samphantharak, (2008), “$2.00 Gas! Studying the E!ects of a Gas

Tax Moratorium,” Journal of Public Economics, 92, 869–884.

Fullerton, D. and G. E. Metcalf, (2002), “Tax Incidence,” in, Auerbach, A. J. and M. Feld-

stein, (eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, Volume 4, pp. 1787–1872. North–Holland,

Amsterdam.

Katz, M. L. and H. S. Rosen, (1985), “Tax Analysis in an Oligopoly Model,” Public Finance

Quarterly, 13, 3–19.

Kenkel, D. S., (2005), “Are Alcohol Tax Hikes Fully Passed Through to Prices? Evidence

from Alaska,” American Economic Review, 95, 273–277.

– 20 –

Page 21: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Kotliko!, L. and L. Summers, (1987), “The Theory of Tax Incidence,” in, Auerbach, A.

and M. Feldstein, (eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, North–Holland, Amsterdam.

Poterba, J. M., (1996), “Retail Price Reactions to Changes in State and Local Sales Taxes,”

National Tax Journal, 49, 165–176.

Seade, J., (1980), “The Stability of Cournot Revisited,” Journal of Economic Theory, 23,

15–27.

Stern, N., (1987), “The E!ects of Taxation, Price Control and Government Contracts in

Oligopoly and Monopolistic Competition,” Journal of Public Economics, 32, 133–158.

Svizzero, S., (1997), “Cournot Equilibrium with Convex Demand,” Economics Letters, 54,

155–158.

Young, D. J. and A. Bieli"ska-Kwapisz, (2002), “Alcohol Taxes and Beverage Prices,”

National Tax Journal, 55, 57–73.

– 21 –

Page 22: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Appendix A: Zip codes in Denmark

Zip code Region

1 Copenhagen City

2 Greater Copenhagen Region

3 North Zealand and Bornholm

4 South Zealand

5 Funen

6 Southern Jutland

7 Western Jutland

8 Eastern Jutland

9 Northern Jutland

– 22 –

Page 23: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Tabl

e1:

Tax

pass

–thr

ough

for

beve

rage

s.B

eer

!ob

sB

ase

pric

eP

rice

chan

ge

Tax

incr

ease

(DK

R)

Tax

pass

-thr

ough

Stor

esw

ith

unde

rshi

ftin

g(<

0.9)

Stor

esw

ith

full

pass

-thr

ough

(0.9

-1.1

)

Stor

esw

ith

over

shifti

ng(>

1.1)

Stor

esw

ith

zero

pass

-thr

ough

Eve

nt:

May

1997

Car

lsbe

rgH

of48

4.63

0.07

0.04

1.84

54%

0%46

%52

%Tu

borg

Grø

n87

4.71

0.06

0.04

1.46

53%

0%47

%51

%Tu

borg

Gul

d10

16.

700.

050.

051.

0855

%7%

38%

51%

Car

lsbe

rgSo

rtG

uld

536.

740.

080.

051.

5753

%2%

45%

53%

Tota

l42

05.

140.

060.

041.

3250

%10

%40

%47

%Eve

nt:

Janu

ary

2005

Car

lsbe

rgC

an9

6.48

-0.1

9-0

.14

1.31

67%

0%33

%56

%Tu

borg

Can

195.

89-0

.01

-0.1

40.

0479

%21

%0%

74%

Car

lsbe

rgH

of17

4.46

0.00

-0.1

4-0

.01

71%

0%29

%47

%Tu

borg

Grø

n73

3.51

0.64

-0.1

4-4

.46

93%

1%5%

27%

Tubo

rgG

uld

727.

19-0

.05

-0.1

80.

2593

%0%

7%81

%C

arls

berg

Sort

Gul

d22

6.99

-0.0

8-0

.18

0.45

91%

0%9%

82%

Tota

l36

55.

450.

08-0

.16

-0.5

390

%2%

7%68

%

– 23 –

Page 24: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Tabl

e1:

Con

tinue

d.So

ftD

rink

s

!ob

sB

ase

pric

eP

rice

chan

ge

Tax

incr

ease

(DK

R)

Tax

pass

-thr

ough

Stor

esw

ith

unde

rshi

ftin

g(<

0.9)

Stor

esw

ith

full

pass

-thr

ough

(0.9

-1.1

)

Stor

esw

ith

over

shifti

ng(>

1.1)

Stor

esw

ith

zero

pass

-thr

ough

Eve

nt:

Janu

ary

1998

Coc

a–C

ola

557.

230.

350.

132.

8227

%0%

73%

24%

Fant

a17

7.39

0.33

0.13

2.61

18%

0%82

%12

%Pe

psiC

ola

277.

130.

360.

132.

8415

%0%

85%

11%

Tubo

rgSq

uash

527.

150.

370.

132.

9217

%0%

83%

17%

Tota

l21

26.

560.

330.

132.

6420

%0%

80%

17%

Janu

ary

2001

Coc

a–C

ola

868.

211.

010.

412.

4934

%0%

66%

29%

Fant

a21

8.28

1.14

0.41

2.81

24%

0%76

%24

%Fa

xeK

ondi

27.

501.

730.

414.

250%

0%10

0%0%

Peps

iCol

a18

8.13

1.28

0.41

3.14

22%

0%78

%17

%Tu

borg

Squa

sh29

8.49

1.05

0.41

2.58

17%

0%83

%14

%To

tal

206

7.37

0.94

0.41

2.31

36%

0%64

%24

%O

ctob

er20

03C

oca–

Col

a10

35.

70-0

.23

-0.3

10.

7345

%40

%16

%21

%Fa

nta

76.

49-0

.24

-0.3

10.

7657

%29

%14

%29

%Fa

xeK

ondi

135.

36-0

.28

-0.3

10.

9146

%31

%23

%31

%Pe

psiC

ola

47.

06-0

.35

-0.3

11.

1250

%0%

50%

50%

Tubo

rgSq

uash

55.

92-0

.13

-0.3

10.

4360

%40

%0%

60%

Coc

a–C

ola

Can

337.

08-0

.09

-0.2

10.

4464

%27

%9%

64%

Tota

l21

16.

06-0

.21

-0.2

90.

7354

%30

%16

%33

%

– 24 –

Page 25: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Tabl

e1:

Con

tinue

d.Liq

uor

!ob

sB

ase

pric

eP

rice

chan

ge

Tax

incr

ease

(DK

R)

Tax

pass

-thr

ough

Stor

esw

ith

unde

rshi

ftin

g(<

0.9)

Stor

esw

ith

full

pass

-thr

ough

(0.9

-1.1

)

Stor

esw

ith

over

shifti

ng(>

1.1)

Stor

esw

ith

zero

pass

-thr

ough

Eve

nt:

Oct

ober

2003

Jæge

rmei

ster

:9

150.

62-3

8.48

-38.

281.

0311

%89

%0%

0%C

ogna

cD

eLu

zeV

SOP

527

2.99

-44.

70-4

3.75

1.02

0%80

%20

%0%

Gam

mel

Dan

sk11

136.

23-4

3.11

-41.

561.

040%

100%

0%0%

Gin

,Gor

don

Dry

1016

8.76

-40.

03-4

3.75

0.91

20%

80%

0%0%

Liqu

eur,

Coi

ntre

au5

168.

78-3

4.20

-18.

591.

840%

0%10

0%0%

Whi

sky,

Bal

lent

ine

519

9.92

-47.

75-4

3.75

1.09

20%

40%

40%

0%Å

lbor

gTa

!elA

kvav

it10

153.

54-5

0.32

-49.

221.

020%

100%

0%0%

Tota

l15

517

1.75

-38.

81-3

7.30

1.04

21%

56%

23%

1%

– 25 –

Page 26: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Table 2: Testing whether tax pass–through is constant across brands.

BeerProduct May-97 Jan-05Carlsberg Hof 0.07 0.24Tuborg Grøn 0.10 <.0001Tuborg Guld 0.72 0.11Carlsberg Sort Guld 0.10 <.0001Carlsberg can na. 0.62Tuborg can na. 0.00Soft DrinksProduct Jan-98 Jan-01 Oct-03Coca–Cola <.0001 <.0001 0.02Fanta 0.00 0.00 0.50Faxe Kondi na. 0.13 0.74Pepsi Cola 0.00 0.00 0.86Tuborg Squash <.0001 <.0001 0.09Coca–Cola can na. na. <.0001LiquorProduct Oct-03Jægermeister: 0.80Cognac De Luze VSOP 0.59Gammel Dansk 0.00Gin, Gordon Dry 0.03Liqueur, Cointreau 0.02Whisky, Ballentine 0.56Ålborg Ta!el Akvavit 0.06

Note: Results are based on regressions of tax pass–through on a constant and branddummies. Only p–value of tests whether brand dummy variable is equal to unity arereported in the table.

– 26 –

Page 27: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Table 3: Testing full tax pass–through.

Tax hikesBeer Soft drinks Liquor Joint0.002 0.000 — 0.000

Tax cutsBeer Soft drinks Liquor Joint0.008 0.021 0.628 0.000

Note: Only p–values from Wald tests are reported in the table. Joint refers to a test thatthe tax pass–through is equal to unity for all types of beverages and equal refers to a testwhether tax pass–through is equal across types of beverages. Tuborg Grøn is excludedfrom the sample of tax cuts.

– 27 –

Page 28: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Table 4: Regression results: Price change explained by base price.

BeerMay-97

!0 !1 !2 !3 !4 !5 !6 !7

0.047 0.002(0.019) (0.003)0.270 -0.028 -0.032 -0.043 -0.046

(0.079) (0.012) (0.012) (0.017) (0.017)Jan-050.220 -0.025

(0.037) (0.004)2.270 -0.337 -0.321 -0.505 -0.469 -0.383 -0.376

(0.184) (0.029) (0.026) (0.046) (0.051) (0.035) (0.035)Soft drinks

Jan-980.101 0.035

(0.068) (0.010)0.315 0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000

(0.052) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)Jan-01-0.080 0.138(0.187) (0.024)-5.122 0.667 0.687 0.666 0.647 0.742(0.387) (0.042) (0.043) (0.040) (0.041) (0.054)Oct-03-0.318 0.018(0.107) (0.018)-0.862 0.121 0.115 0.113 0.082 0.126 0.109(0.156) (0.029) (0.036) (0.034) (0.029) (0.034) (0.023)LiquorOct-03-25.932 -0.068(3.279) (0.018)-16.510 -0.146 -0.219 -0.102 -0.195 -0.138 -0.107 -0.159(6.374) (0.044) (0.043) (0.024) (0.048) (0.039) (0.037) (0.034)

Note: All regressions are based on equation (1) in the text. Standard errors are shownbelow each estimate within parentheses.

– 28 –

Page 29: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Table 5: Testing heterogeneity of tax pass–through across types of stores and across zipcodes.

Tax hikesType of store Zip code

Beer Soft drinks liquor Beer Soft drinks Liquor0.010 0.000 — 0.099 0.018 —

Tax cutsBeer Soft drinks Liquor Beer Soft drinks Liquor0.008 0.341 0.979 0.000 0.754 0.997

Note: Only p–values from Wald tests are reported in the table. All regressions includedummies for type of beverage. Tuborg Grøn is excluded from the sample of tax cuts.

Table 6: Testing for border e!ects.

Tax hikesDistance to German border Swedish border (zip 1,2,3,4) Swedish border (zip 1,3)Beer Soft drinks Liquor Beer Soft drinks Liquor Beer Soft drinks Liquor-0.099 -0.221(0.220) (0.229)0.165 -0.234 -0.430 0.043

(0.279) (0.246) (0.280) (0.287)0.007 -0.283 -0.652 0.766

(0.229) (0.233) (0.399) (0.545)Tax cuts

Beer Soft drinks Liquor Beer Soft drinks Liquor Beer Soft drinks Liquor0.534" 0.134 -0.030(0.185) (0.282) (0.404)0.272 0.036 1.234 0.409 0.122 -0.921

(0.250) (0.390) (2.659) (0.263) (0.332) (1.916)0.359+ 0.058 -0.065 0.970" 0.447 0.158(0.194) (0.294) (0.414) (0.331) (0.472) (0.459)

Note: All regressions include dummies for type of beverage. Tuborg Grøn is excludedfrom the sample of tax cuts. Standard errors are shown within parentheses below eachpoint estimate. ! denotes significance at the 0.05 level and + at the 0.10 level.

– 29 –

Page 30: Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to ...web.econ.ku.dk/okombe/BergmanHansen.pdf · Are Excise Taxes on Beverages Fully Passed Through to Prices? The Danish Evidence

Figure 1: Frequency of price reductions and price increases.

(a) Beer

(b) Soft drinks

(c) Liquor

– 30 –