affordable for all -...

332
AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO Final Report February 2018 Dr. Gordon Cleveland, University of Toronto Scarborough

Upload: others

Post on 31-Dec-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

AFFORDABLE FOR ALL:

MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

Final Report

February 2018

Dr. Gordon Cleveland,

University of Toronto Scarborough

Page 2: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

i

Table of Contents

Executive Summary ............................................................................................................... 1

CHAPTER 1: Introduction, Objectives and Principles ............................................................. 22

1.1 People and Methods Used for This Study .......................................................................... 23

1.2 What characteristics should a reform of the early learning and child care

system have? ...................................................................................................................... 25

CHAPTER 2: Child Care Services, Governance and Funding.................................................... 27

Chapter Summary ...................................................................................................................... 27

2.1 Overview and Provincial Governance ................................................................................ 29

2.2 The Municipal Role in Child Care ....................................................................................... 31

2.3 Overview of Province-Wide Spending on Child Care, 2015 ............................................... 33

2.4 Funding ............................................................................................................................... 36

2.5 First Nations Child Care ...................................................................................................... 39

2.6 Child Care in Francophone Communities in Ontario ......................................................... 41

2.7 Child Care for Children with Special Needs ....................................................................... 42

2.8 Child Care Centre Services ................................................................................................. 44

2.9 Auspice – For-Profit and Not-for-Profit Centre Care ......................................................... 50

2.10 Child Care Fees .................................................................................................................. 50

2.11 Subsidies ............................................................................................................................ 53

2.12 Ontario’s Licensed Home Child Care Services – In Numbers ............................................ 59

2.13 Subsidies in Home Child Care ............................................................................................ 63

2.14 Fees by Region and Age Category in Home Child Care ..................................................... 64

2.15 Centre and Home Enrollment by Municipality ................................................................. 65

2.16 Child Population ................................................................................................................ 68

CHAPTER 3: The Municipal Role in Managing The Child Care System .................................... 71

Chapter Summary ...................................................................................................................... 71

3.1 Interviews with Municipalities ........................................................................................... 74

Page 3: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

ii

3.2 Centre-Based Care ............................................................................................................. 74

3.3 Home Child Care................................................................................................................. 78

3.4 Accessibility ........................................................................................................................ 80

3.5 Administration of the Subsidy System ............................................................................... 86

3.6 Auspice Of Operators ......................................................................................................... 89

3.7 Relationships with School Boards ...................................................................................... 90

3.8 Expansion Plans .................................................................................................................. 93

3.9 Challenges to Expansion .................................................................................................... 96

3.10 Suggested Solutions to the Affordability Crisis ................................................................. 98

CHAPTER 4: Why Public Funding of Child Care Makes Sense ............................................... 100

Chapter Summary .................................................................................................................... 100

4.1 Why Public Funding of Child Care Makes Sense. ............................................................. 101

4.2 Conclusions ...................................................................................................................... 111

CHAPTER 5: The Affordability Problem ............................................................................... 112

Chapter Summary .................................................................................................................... 112

5.1 Child Care Fees in Ontario are High and Rising ................................................................ 113

5.2 Child Care is Unaffordable for Most Families .................................................................. 117

5.3 Affordability of Child Care Affects Parent Decisions ........................................................ 121

5.4 The Current Level of the Demand for Child Care ............................................................. 125

5.5 Why Affordability of Child Care is Also a Women’s Issue ................................................ 127

5.6 The Size of Parents’ Share ................................................................................................ 128

CHAPTER 6: Different Child Care Funding Approaches – The Theory ................................... 131

Chapter Summary .................................................................................................................... 131

6.1 What Are the Goals of Child Care Funding? .................................................................... 132

6.2 How Does the Child Care Market Work? ......................................................................... 133

6.3 Funding Tools ................................................................................................................... 135

6.4 Supply-Side vs. Demand-Side Funding ............................................................................. 136

6.5 Types of Sliding Scale ....................................................................................................... 139

Page 4: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

iii

6.6 Funding Lessons from the Quebec Experience ................................................................ 140

6.7 The Child Care Expense Deduction .................................................................................. 143

6.8 Conclusions About Alternative Funding Approaches ...................................................... 144

CHAPTER 7: What Other Jurisdictions Do ........................................................................... 146

Chapter Summary .................................................................................................................... 146

7.1 General Funding Approaches ........................................................................................... 151

7.2 England ............................................................................................................................. 153

7.3 Australia ........................................................................................................................... 154

7.4 New Zealand ..................................................................................................................... 156

7.5 Denmark ........................................................................................................................... 158

7.6 Norway ............................................................................................................................. 159

7.7 Sweden ............................................................................................................................. 160

7.8 Jurisdictions in Canada ..................................................................................................... 161

7.9 Summary .......................................................................................................................... 167

CHAPTER 8: Different Funding Approaches – The Evidence ................................................. 169

Chapter Summary .................................................................................................................... 169

8.1 Different Funding Approaches ......................................................................................... 172

8.2 Model #1 (Spreadsheet Model) – Returns to Employment ............................................. 174

8.3 Alternative Funding Models ............................................................................................. 179

8.4 Model #2 (Behavioural Model) – Demand for Child Care, Employment, and

Other Impacts................................................................................................................... 194

8.5 Child Care Demand and Employment .............................................................................. 204

8.6 Affordability Measures ..................................................................................................... 206

8.7 Net Child Care Costs ......................................................................................................... 207

8.8 Costs and Revenues ......................................................................................................... 208

8.9 Summary of Evidence from Simulations .......................................................................... 209

8.10 Conclusions ...................................................................................................................... 211

CHAPTER 9: Workforce Issues, Compensation and Costs .................................................... 213

Chapter Summary .................................................................................................................... 213

Page 5: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

iv

9.1 Workforce Issues, Compensation and Costs .................................................................... 214

9.2 How Much Do Child Care Workers Earn in Ontario? ....................................................... 216

9.3 How High Are Hourly Wages in Competing Industries? .................................................. 225

9.4 Costs and Fees in Ontario Child Care Centres .................................................................. 228

9.5 Solving the Staff Shortages Problem ................................................................................ 230

9.6 Conclusions ...................................................................................................................... 234

CHAPTER 10: Transitions - How to Manage Growth in the Child Care System ...................... 236

Chapter Summary .................................................................................................................... 236

10.1 Physical Capacity ............................................................................................................. 241

10.2 Development and Management of The Expanded System ............................................ 241

10.3 Staff Shortages ................................................................................................................ 243

10.4 Rationing and Phasing-In ................................................................................................. 243

10.5 Maintaining Quality and the Role of the For-Profit Sector ............................................. 253

10.6 Conclusions ...................................................................................................................... 254

CHAPTER 11: Recommendations ........................................................................................ 257

Main Recommendations ......................................................................................................... 257

REFERENCES ...................................................................................................................... 269

APPENDIX A: Glossary ....................................................................................................... 283

APPENDIX B: What Factors Affect Costs In Ontario Child Care Centres? .............................. 285

APPENDIX C: The Evolution of Child Care and Child Care Policy in Ontario .......................... 302

APPENDIX D: Taxes and Benefits for Ontario Families ........................................................ 312

APPENDIX E: People Who Helped Us .................................................................................. 317

Page 6: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

v

List of Tables and Charts

Table 1 Regional Breakdown of Expenditures by General Function, 2015 (millions of

dollars and percent) ................................................................................................... 35

Table 2 Amount of Child Care Subsidy Available to Families at Different Incomes, For

Different Assumed Fee Levels with One Child, Ontario 2017 ................................... 37

Table 3 Amount of Child Care Subsidy Available to Families at Different Incomes, For

Different Assumed Fee Levels with Two Children, Ontario 2017.............................. 38

Table 4 Licensed Child Care Centres Serving All Ages of Children, by Region or First

Nations, Ontario 2017 ............................................................................................... 45

Table 5 Number of Licensed Centre Spaces for All Ages of Children, by Region or First

Nations, Ontario 2017 ............................................................................................... 46

Table 6 Number and Percent of Licensed Centre Spaces for Children 0-4 Years, by

Region or First Nations, Ontario 2017 ....................................................................... 47

Table 7 Number of Licensed Centre Spaces by Age Category and by Region or First

Nations, Ontario 2017 ............................................................................................... 48

Table 8 Number and Percent of Licensed Centres by Age Categories Served, Considering

Only Spaces for Children 0-4 Years, Ontario 2017 .................................................... 49

Table 9 Number and Percentage of Licensed Child Care Centres by Auspice, by Region or

First Nations, Ontario 2017 ....................................................................................... 50

Table 10 Median Daily Fees for Full-Day Infant, Toddler and Preschool Centre-Based

Child Care and Before-and-After School Care for Kindergarten and School

Age Children, by Region, Ontario 2017 ..................................................................... 52

Table 11 Total Number of Subsidized Children in Centres, All Ages and Children 0-4, By

Region and First Nations, Ontario 2017 .................................................................... 54

Table 12 Total Number of Subsidized Children in Centres by Age Category, By Region or

First Nations Ontario 2017 ........................................................................................ 55

Table 13 Percentage of Children in Centres who are Subsidized, by Age Category, By

Region or First Nations, Ontario 2017 ....................................................................... 56

Table 14 Percentage of Children Subsidized in Child Care Centres, All Ages and Children

0-4, By Region and First Nations, Ontario 2017 ........................................................ 57

Table 15 Total Number of Unsubsidized Children in Centres by Age Category, By Region,

Ontario 2017 .............................................................................................................. 58

Page 7: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

vi

Table 16 Total Number of Children (Both Subsidized and Unsubsidized) in Centres by

Age Category, by Region or First Nations, Ontario 2017 ........................................... 59

Table 17 Distribution of Home Child Care Agencies by Region or First Nations, 2017 ................ 60

Table 18 Number of Approved Homes and Active Homes Operating by Region or First

Nations, 2017 ............................................................................................................. 61

Table 19 Number of Children Using Home Child Care in Different Age Categories by

Region or First Nations, 2017 .................................................................................... 62

Table 20 Total Subsidies in Home Care for Infants, Toddlers, Preschoolers, Kindergarten

Children, and School Age Children, by Region, March 2017 ..................................... 63

Table 21 Total Children in Home Care without Subsidy, by Age Category and by Region,

March 2017 ................................................................................................................ 64

Table 22 Median Daily Fees in Child Care Homes for Full-Day Infant, Toddler and

Preschool Child Care and Before-and-After School Care for Kindergarten and

School Age Children, by Region, Ontario 2017 .......................................................... 65

Table 23 Children 0-4 Years of Age in Child Care Centres and Home Care by Municipality,

2017 ........................................................................................................................... 66

Table 24 Number of Children and Child Care Spaces 0-4 Years of Age in each Region,

Ontario 2017 .............................................................................................................. 68

Table 25 Change in Fee Structure in Manitoulin-Sudbury DSSAB -- 2016 to 2017 ...................... 95

Table 26 Median Monthly Fee for Care in Child Care Centres and Homes, Selected

Ontario Cities and Rural Areas, 2017 ....................................................................... 114

Table 27 Median Annual Fee for Full-time Care in Child Care Centres and Homes,

Selected Ontario Cities and Rural Areas, 2017 ........................................................ 115

Table 28 Median Daily and Annual Fees for Full-time Care in a Child Care Centre, by Age

Category and Region of Ontario, 2017 .................................................................... 116

Table 29 Percent Change in Median Full-Time Fee in a Child Care Centre, by Age

Category and Region of Ontario, 2015-2017 ........................................................... 117

Table 30 Affordability of Licensed Child Care in Ontario in 2017 for Families with at

least One Child Younger than Kindergarten Age (i.e., 0-4 Years) based on the

Family Income Affordability Measure (FIAM) ......................................................... 119

Table 31 Affordability of Licensed Child Care in Ontario in 2017 for Families with at least

One Child Younger than Kindergarten Age (i.e., 0-4 Years) Based on the

Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure (CPAM) ................................................... 120

Page 8: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

vii

Table 32 Probability of Using Licensed Child Care and Full-Time Employment by

Affordability of Licensed Child Care (Measured By FIAM) ...................................... 122

Table 33 Probability of Using Licensed Child Care and Full-Time Employment by

Affordability of Licensed Child Care (Measured By CPAM) ..................................... 122

Table 34 Number of Families, by Family Income in Ontario with Children 0-5 Years of

Age, 2015 ................................................................................................................. 124

Table 35 Affordability by Expected Family Income Level in Ontario Families with Children

Younger than Compulsory School Age .................................................................... 125

Table 36 Projected Demand for Child Care Arrangements by Age Category, 2017 ................... 126

Table 37 Calculation of Parental Share of Total Cost of Child Care amongst Current

Users of Licensed Child Care .................................................................................... 129

Chart 1 Percent of Quebec children 18-66 months attending care of either inadequate or

good/excellent quality, in three types of care ........................................................ 142

Table 38 Fee subsidy as a % of Family Income ........................................................................... 155

Chart 2 Growth in Out-of-Pocket Child Care Costs as Compared to Rise in General Price

Level ......................................................................................................................... 156

Table 39 Average Monthly Fees in Selected Cities, 2017 .......................................................... 161

Table 40 Child Care Fee Subsidy Relief as a % of Family Income ............................................... 163

Chart 3 Returns from Employment After Child Care: With and Without Child Care Costs,

With and Without Subsidy - Lone Parents .............................................................. 178

Chart 4 Returns from Employment After Child Care with Alternative Sliding Scales - Lone

Parents ..................................................................................................................... 181

Chart 5 Returns from Employment with $20 Per Day and Tax Credit Policies- Lone

Parents ..................................................................................................................... 183

Chart 6 Returns from Employment After Child Care With Alternative Possible Child Care

Policies - Lone Parents ............................................................................................. 184

Chart 7 Returns from Employment After Child Care: With and Without Child Care Costs,

With and Without Subsidy - Two Parent, Two Child Family .................................... 188

Chart 8 Returns from Employment After Child Care: Sliding Scales and Free Child Care

Options - Two Parent, Two Child Family ................................................................. 189

Chart 9 Returns from Employment After Child Care: $20 per day and Tax Credit Policies

- Two Parent, Two Child Family ............................................................................... 190

Page 9: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

viii

Chart 10 Returns from Employment After Child Care With Alternative Possible Child

Care Policies - Two Parent, Two Child Family .......................................................... 191

Table 41 Child Care Demand and Employment in Six Simulations ............................................. 199

Table 42 Affordability Measures in Six Simulations ................................................................... 200

Table 43 Net Child Care Costs in Six Simulations ........................................................................ 201

Table 44 Costs and Revenues in Six Simulations ........................................................................ 203

Table 45 Summary Table: Median Wage Levels in Ontario Child Care Centres by

Occupational Category, by Region, 2017 ................................................................ 218

Table 46 Number and Percent of All Child Care Workers Paid in Each Hourly Wage

Category, by Region, 2017 All Staff ......................................................................... 219

Table 47 Number and Percent of Qualified Program Staff in Each Hourly Wage Category,

by Region, 2017 ....................................................................................................... 221

Table 48 Number and Percent of Unqualified Program Staff in Each Hourly Wage

Category, by Region, 2017 ....................................................................................... 222

Table 49 Number and Percent of Child Care Supervisors in Each Hourly Wage Category,

by Region, 2017 ....................................................................................................... 223

Table 50 Number and Percent of Non-Program Staff in Each Hourly Wage Category, by

Region, 2017 ............................................................................................................ 224

Table 51 Average Hourly Wage of Female Workers in Selected Occupations, by Age

Category of Workers, Ontario 2016 ........................................................................ 227

Table 52 Prince Edward Island Wage Grid ................................................................................. 232

Table 53 Number of Additional Child Care Spaces Needed for Full Implementation of

Alternative Child Care Funding Policies ................................................................... 240

Table 54 Demand and Employment – Effects of Phasing-In Free Preschool Child Care ........... 246

Table 55 Affordability Measures - Effects of Phasing-In Free Preschool Child Care ................. 247

Table 56 Net Child Care Costs – Effects of Phasing-In Free Preschool Child Care ..................... 249

Table 57 Costs and Revenues – Effects of Phasing-In Free Preschool Child Care ..................... 251

Table 58 Number of Additional Child Care Spaces Needed as New Funding Policies Are

Phased-In ................................................................................................................. 252

Table B-1 Hourly Wage Ranges of Median Workers by Region for Different Categories of

Staff in Child Care Centres, Ontario 2017 ............................................................... 289

Page 10: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

ix

Table B-2 Calculated Annual Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child

Care Centres, by Region, Ontario 2017 ................................................................... 291

Table B-3 Calculated Daily Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child

Care Centres, by Region, Ontario 2017 .................................................................. 292

Table B-4 Median Full Fees Charged for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child

Care Centres, by Region, Ontario 2017 ................................................................... 293

Table B-5 Calculated Daily Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child

Care Centres with a 10% rise in Wages above Current Levels, by Region,

Ontario 2017 ............................................................................................................ 296

Table B-6 Calculated Daily Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child

Care Centres with a Rise in Employee Benefits to 25% of Wages, by Region,

Ontario 2017 ............................................................................................................ 297

TableB-7 Calculated Daily Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child

Care Centres with All Program Staff Having Qualifications, by Region,

Ontario 2017 ............................................................................................................ 299

Table C-1 Licensed Child Care Spaces Available in Ontario 1992-2015 ...................................... 310

Table C-2 Provincial/Municipal Expenditure on Licensed Child Care, Ontario ........................... 311

Page 11: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

1

EXECUTIVE SUMMARY

This study seeks to answer the question “What is the best way to improve the affordability of

licensed child care for infants, toddlers and preschoolers in Ontario?” It seeks to provide a

comprehensive analysis of alternative funding and policy options and to recommend steps

forward that can dramatically improve child care affordability for families.

After much consideration of evidence and ideas, our main recommendation is that the

Government of Ontario should implement free child care for preschool-aged children (30

months to kindergarten age) as an immediate priority. As physical and staffing capacity are

ramped up over the next few years, increased affordability for other ages should be phased in.

Making child care free for all children of preschool age will improve affordability for all families

in the one or two years before kindergarten. As physical capacity for preschoolers is expanded,

the Ministry will have to ensure that physical and staffing capacity for services to infants and

toddlers expands as well.

In the near term, the Ministry of Education should continue, and fund more generously, the

existing subsidy system. Restrictive regulations on activity requirements should be loosened.

When additional licensed child care capacity is available and qualified staff shortages have been

reduced or eliminated, the child care subsidy system should be replaced with a sliding scale of

payments - a $50,000 to $150,000 sliding scale - to make licensed child care affordable for

children of other ages. Family income would determine the percent of full fee a family would

have to pay. For children other than preschool age, families with earnings less than $50,000

would pay nothing; and families earning over $150,000 would pay 80% of the full fee. In

between, families pay an increasing percentage as family income rises. We call this a $50K-

$150K sliding scale.

Chapter 1: Introduction, Objectives and Principles

The first chapter introduces the study by describing the objectives and providing background

information about the Government of Ontario's commitments related to child care. Chapter 1

also addresses the methods used in the study and sets out the characteristics that a reform of

the early learning and child care system should have.

Chapter 2: Child Care Services in Ontario

There are over 5,300 licensed child care centres in Ontario with over 406,000 spaces for

children 0-12 years. Just over 161,000 of these centre spaces are for infants, toddlers and

preschoolers, often described as children 0-4 years. Nearly 106,000 of these spaces (as of

Page 12: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

2

March 2017) are for children of preschool age. There are also 124 licensed home child care

agencies. These agencies co-ordinate and monitor nearly 7,600 family homes (3,765 currently

active) that provide care for nearly 16,000 children. Nearly 76% of Ontario’s licensed child care

centres are not-for-profits.

Across Ontario, there are enough licensed spaces in centres and homes for infants, toddlers and

preschoolers to accommodate about 23% of all children 0-4 years of age, inclusive. In Toronto

and Central Region, there is space for about 26%-27% of 0-4-year-olds.

Child care is the responsibility of the Ministry of Education, Early Years and Child Care Division.

The role of the Ministry is to develop policy, to provide funding, and to update and enforce

legislation and regulations in relation to child care and early years services. The Ministry

licenses child care centre programs and home child care agencies.

Ontario is unique amongst Canada’s provinces and territories in having a central role for

municipalities in the planning, funding and administration of funding for licensed child care

services. There are 37 Consolidated Municipal Service Managers and 10 District Social Service

Administration Boards (CMSMs and DSSABs) that are the municipal service system managers

for child care. Child care services are managed by CMSMs and DSSABs through a local service

planning process. School boards and child and family programs are also important local

partners in the planning and delivery of child care and early years services.

First Nations are an important partner in the delivery of on-reserve child care. First Nations can

administer and operate child care and early years programs on reserve and many do. First

Nations can also make agreements to exercise any powers of a service system manager on

reserve.

In the spirit of the Truth and Reconciliation Commission and with funding from the

Ministry, Indigenous-led projects are being established in communities across the province to

increase spaces for the Indigenous population and to develop culturally-relevant programming

off reserve under the auspices of The Journey Together: Ontario’s Commitment to

Reconciliation with Indigenous Peoples On reserve, First Nations are mainly using the funding

under the Journey Together program to build new early years child and family centres.

Off reserve, CMSMs and DSSABs are participating in Journey Together projects led by local

Indigenous partner organizations, to provide new culturally-appropriate stand-alone child care

centres accessible and accountable to the local Indigenous population, to develop both child

care centre and home child care services that are accessible to both on and off reserve

children, to extend culturally-sensitive services to all residents off reserve as well as

collaborating on professional development and training both on and off reserve. In recognition

of the unaffordable cost of child care in urban centres across the Province, several communities

Page 13: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

3

are planning to establish Indigenous-focused centres with base funding so that the Indigenous

population can afford to attend.

Governments in Ontario spent over $1.3 billion on child care and early years services in 2015.

Allocations are provided to CMSMs and DSSABs through the Child Care Funding Formula which

is designed to provide an equitable funding allocation for municipal child care service managers

across the province.

The primary source of funding for child care services is parent fees. Child care fees vary by

region and by child’s age. For child care centres, the regional median infant fee varies from

$51.00 per day in the North to $85.00 per day in Toronto. For toddlers, the range is from

$42.00 to $66.00. For preschoolers, the range is from $38.00 to $52.00 per day.

The main government funding policy that affects the affordability of licensed child care services

is the Ontario child care subsidy system. There are income and activity requirements to be

eligible for child care subsidy; even then, subsidies may not be available if annual funding has

been exhausted. Families earning less than $20,000 may be able to get a full subsidy, and

families earning between $20,000 and $40,000 will pay 10% of income above $20,000. Families

earning over $40,000 will pay $2,000 plus 30% of their income that is over $40,000. In general,

parents need to be employed or seeking employment, or in training or education, to be eligible

for child care subsidy, although there are exceptions according to child or family need. Most

families earning above $100,000 per year are not eligible for financial assistance through the

Ontario subsidy system under its current rules.

There are over 111,000 children 0-12 years of age who receive child care subsidies for centre-

based care in Ontario. About 40% of infants who are using licensed centre care receive a

subsidy, about 34% of toddlers and about 31% of the preschool-aged children who are in

centres. There are nearly 260,000 children 0-12 years using licensed centre care who do not

receive child care subsidy. The total number of subsidies in family home child care in Ontario in

2017 was nearly 12,000.

Chapter 3: Municipal Issues and Feedback

Municipal representatives told us that the prime challenges to the viability and stability of

centres are wages, staff recruitment and retention. The expansion of full-day kindergarten has

attracted many qualified child care staff where wages, benefits, and working conditions are

generally better than in child care centres. This has made recruitment and retention issues in

the child care sector more acute.

Across Ontario, home child care is 4%-6% of all licensed care. Municipalities are pleased with a

recent supplement of $20 per day to home providers, however, there are still serious

challenges in the recruitment of adequate numbers of home providers.

Page 14: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

4

Affordability is the main barrier to access for parents. There are a number of other accessibility

issues identified by municipalities: rural access and transportation, part-time opportunities,

care for children with special needs, and care during non-traditional hours such as evenings,

weekends and overnight. A further issue of accessibility is lack of parental awareness of child

care subsidy funding. Public education about available funding is an important priority.

Journey Together funding on First Nations reserves is mainly being used to establish new child

and family centres. Accessibility to services that provide culturally-appropriate programming

for the off-reserve Indigenous population is so far extremely limited, despite the fact that the

large majority of Indigenous families live off-reserve.

CMSMs and DSSABs have grown into the role as caretakers of quality. Most of them have hired

quality assurance coordinators, are working in the community to improve quality in their

programs, introducing significantly more professional development opportunities as well as

mentoring programs. About half of all CMSMs and DSSABs are using a quality measurement

tool.

Municipalities were almost unanimous in suggesting that the income test for child care subsidy

be made more generous. Most CMSMs and DSSABs support the provincial thresholds for for-

profit funding but there needs to be some recognition that this will be more difficult to

implement in areas with very high levels of for-profit operators.

The most persistent irritant between schools and municipalities concerns the “rental” or “cost

recovery” rate for space in schools. In too many cases, these charges are prohibitively high,

which violates the spirit of the Schools First directives. A consistent policy that allows child care

to flourish in schools should be adopted.

CMSMs and DSSABs have embraced the challenge posed by the Ministry to work on expansion

and are putting considerable effort into achieving their targets, often with limited staff, short

timelines and absence of planning resources. The priorities to increase accessibility, expand

access to fee subsidy, and work on affordability are being achieved by reducing the subsidy lists,

expanding capacity through capital expansion, Journey Together and collaboration with school

boards . Other initiatives include attempts to expand home child care, access to non-traditional

hours, rural programs and infant programs. Some CMSMs and DSSABs are assisting

affordability by using general operating grants to prevent or reduce fee increases.

The major barrier to expansion of centre-based care is the shortage of Registered Early

Childhood Educators occasioned by low wages and lack of interest in the occupation by

potential professionals because of those low wages.

Page 15: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

5

Chapter 4: Why Public Funding of Child Care Makes Sense

Increased public funding for child care affordability has widespread support in Ontario, partly

because affordable child care will help parents balance the demands of work and family life.

Affordability of child care is particularly important to mothers as child care responsibilities are

often a barrier to employment and equal treatment for women.

The net cost of government child care assistance is substantially lower than its gross cost,

because increases in parental employment cause increases in tax revenue and reductions in

social assistance and other benefits. There may also be increased growth and productivity,

multiplying the revenue effects.

The years from birth to age five are crucial ones for children’s development. There is

substantial and widespread evidence that early childhood education and care can be positive

for children’s cognitive and language development, completed education levels, employment

and wages, as well as making them happy in the short run.

There is also substantial and widespread evidence that the effects of early childhood education

and care are not uniform, but are heterogeneous. Policy needs to be directed towards making

positive effects as strong as possible. In particular, children from lower-income backgrounds

are likely to have stronger positive effects, if they are not excluded from access and quality

services. Multiple dimensions of quality are key factors in child care’s effects on children.

Chapter 5: The Affordability Problem

Child care fees in Ontario range from about $9,000 to over $20,000 per child per year for

children 0-4 years. There is substantial regional and age variation in fees, but they are high

everywhere relative to incomes, and have been rising faster than inflation.

For families that have at least one child 0-6 years and want to access licensed child care, we

find the average family in Ontario would have to spend 20.8% of after-tax family income on

child care or nearly 60% of the net income contribution of the main caregiving parent when

employed. For families with at least one child 0-4 years, the average family would have to

spend nearly one-quarter (23.5%) of after-tax family income on child care or just over two-

thirds (67%) of the net income contribution of the main caregiving parent.

We consider licensed child care to be “affordable” if a family can access it for their 0-6 year-old

children for less than 10% of after-tax, after-benefit family income. If licensed child care costs

10% to 19.99% of net family income, we call it “unaffordable”. If purchasing licensed child care

costs 20% or more of total family income after taxes and benefits, licensed child care is

“completely unaffordable” for that family.

Page 16: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

6

For the Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure, licensed child care is “affordable” if a family

can access it for their 0-6 year-old children for less than 30% of the after-tax, after-benefit

earnings contribution that the main caregiving parent would make to family income if

employed (i.e., less than 30% of her net contribution). If licensed child care costs 30% to

59.99% of her net contribution, we will call it “unaffordable”. If purchasing licensed child care

costs 60% or more of her earnings contribution after taxes and benefits, licensed child care is

“completely unaffordable” for that family. The affordability of licensed child care is closely

related to child care and employment behaviour.

Using two different measures, we find that fewer than 22% of Ontario families find licensed

child care to be affordable – 19% by one measure and 21.8% by the other. Affordability

matters for family decisions. For families that find child care affordable, there is over 63%

probability of using licensed child care and over 80% probability that the main caregiving parent

is employed; for families that find child care unaffordable or completely unaffordable, the

probability of being employed and using licensed child care are much lower.

Affordability is strongly related to family income, despite the efforts of the subsidy system to

make licensed child care affordable for low-income families. This table shows the current

situation in Ontario, taking existing funding into account.

Affordability by Family Income Level

When Using Licensed Child Care for Children 0-6 Years of Age

Expected Annual Income of the Household

Net Child Care Costs as % of After-Tax After-Benefit Family Income

Net Child Care Costs as % of After-Tax After-Benefit Income Contribution of the Main

Caregiving Parent

Less than $50,000 30.8% 61.7%

$50,000 - $99,999 21.2% 69.5%

$100,000 and more 12.7% 44.2%

Total 20.8% 58.1%

With current policies and levels of affordability in Ontario, about 8% of infants use licensed

child care services, about 30% of toddlers and about 37% of children of preschool age.

Considering only families with employed mothers, over 12% of infants, over 42% of toddlers

and 50% of preschool-aged children currently use licensed child care.

Page 17: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

7

Many families combine parental care of children with employment of all parents in the

household. Parents may arrange their work shifts so that this is possible (off-shifting). In these

cases, the main caregiving parent will often work part-time or be self-employed in the

household. There is evidence that these care decisions are strongly affected by the

unaffordability of paid child care.

The unaffordability of child care affects many aspects of women’s employment, hours, and pay.

Across the system, parents pay between 50%-63% of the total cost of licensed child care

services in Ontario. Governments pay the rest.

Chapter 6: Different Funding Approaches (The Theory)

The objectives of a funding program for child care are multiple and complex. A child care

system must be affordable, accessible and offer services and experiences of good quality.

Funding should permit and promote parental employment. It should make available

convenient and accessible services with hours and location that correspond to needs. The

quality of early childhood education and care (ECEC) provided to children is always a central

issue, because we believe that the quality of care is directly and substantially related to the

effects of ECEC on children’s multi-faceted development in the early years.

Quality is not easy to describe or measure, but it can be seen in curriculum frameworks to

support early childhood education and care, in staff-child ratios, group sizes, training levels of

early childhood educators, in the quality of the leadership and mentorship provided by senior

staff, in the interactions between parents and educators and in many more ways. Quality is

reflected in the resources available to educators, in the way that children from different

backgrounds and with different abilities are integrated into the group, in the low rate of

turnover of qualified staff.

Another dimension of government’s objectives is to make sure that lower income families are

particularly enabled to access quality child care services. This is important to mention for two

reasons. One is that the benefits to both children and parents in lower income families can be

especially large. The second reason is that lower income families are sometimes less likely than

other families to be first in line when enhanced child care funding arrangements become

available. Families from higher-income families should also receive their fair share of financial

assistance to access good quality child care. Nearly all families have difficulty affording child

care.

The discussion about supply-side vs demand-side funding is an important one. Should

assistance go directly to parents, or should governments finance services, reducing the cost to

parents? Should governments play an important role in enhancing the quality of services, or

should governments rely on consumer choice to deal with issues of service quality?

Page 18: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

8

The biggest problem with demand-side subsidies is that they provide inadequate mechanisms

to ensure that parents purchase high quality care that will support children’s optimal

development. Since quality is the key determinant of child care’s effects on children, this is a

central problem.

Supply-side subsidies can be provided in a variety of ways. ECEC services can be provided

directly through the public sector by various levels of government (e.g., directly-operated

municipal centres) or child care services can be provided by not-for-profit providers who are

rigorously monitored to encourage the maintenance of quality standards and financial

reporting standards. When the services are provided by not-for-profit operators, the provision

of supply-side funding for services acts to stabilize the financial position of the small

organizations that are frequently the typical providers.

When services are not free, a sliding scale of fees (adjusted to family income) is often

considered to be both equitable and efficient. There are two major types of sliding scale. One

uses family income to determine the percent of family income that a family should pay. The

second type of sliding scale uses family income to determine the percent of the full fee that a

particular family has to pay.

We seek a funding approach that improves affordability of 0-4-year-old child care for families,

while giving special assistance to lower-income families and maintaining or improving quality

and accessibility.

The market for child care is a mix of public and private, but there is a growing public interest in

keeping fees low and quality high in order to remove barriers to parental employment and

increase children’s access to good services.

Governments who fund child care on the demand side seek to use market mechanisms to

stimulate supply and enhance quality of services.

Supply-side funding recognizes child care as a substantially regulated market, with private

(largely not-for-profit) service providers, but regulated supply, quality, staff compensation and

fees.

Quebec created a network of high quality not-for-profit services called CPEs (Centres de la

Petite Enfance, or Early Childhood Centres). These have had important positive effects on

children’s development. However, because of very substantial supply shortages in the early

days of Quebec’s child care reforms, Quebec’s system has developed in negative ways. This

provides a crucial reminder that problems of phase-in and transition are at least as important as

initial funding policy plans.

Page 19: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

9

The Child Care Expense Deduction is a measure originally designed to provide fairer taxation of

employed mothers: it shelters from taxation the part of income that pays for a legitimate work

expense. Taxation of mothers would be unfair without it.

Chapter 7: What Other Jurisdictions Do

This chapter describes and analyzes funding methods and policies in other jurisdictions,

highlighting positive and negative examples of interest to Ontario. The chapter discusses

funding arrangements in England, Australia, New Zealand, Denmark, Norway, Sweden, Quebec,

Prince Edward Island, and Manitoba.

Early years education and child care are treated separately in England. The new sliding scale in

Australia is generous and has an activity requirement. New Zealand uses supply-side measures

as the base of its funding of early childhood education. Denmark and Norway have very

effective supply-side funding with strong municipal involvement. Sweden has a sliding scale in

which the first child costs 3% of family income. There are important lessons to learn from

Quebec about how funding and policy plans can go awry. There are significant examples of

policy and workforce innovations in Prince Edward Islandand Manitoba.

England

England’s early childhood services are systematically divided into education, on the one hand,

and care, on the other. Education services for children younger than compulsory school age are

largely in the public sector and often in schools. They mostly serve children 3 to 5 years of age.

The central government provides funding to local authorities (i.e., municipalities) to ensure that

every 3 and 4-year-old has access to a part-time nursery education.

In England, child care services are largely in the private sector, with the lion’s share being for-

profit services and a smaller share being not-for-profit. Child care services are viewed as being a

support for parental employment, not as education, and are typically quite expensive.

Australia

Australia has a sliding scale of child care fees where families earning less than about

Can$65,000 get 85% of costs covered, falling to 50% at about Can$170,000. Beyond

Can$350,000 there is no child care fee assistance: assistance for fees is capped at Can$11.55

per hour, higher than most current fees. There are activity requirements to be eligible for this

fee assistance. Low-income families who do not meet the activity requirements are eligible for

12 hours per week child care for each child.

Page 20: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

10

Median full-time fees in Australia for children 0-5 are about Can$20,000 annually. Increased

generosity of funding over the years has lowered the fees that parents have to pay, but only

temporarily – the general trend is up.

New Zealand

There are a number of different types of ECEC services in New Zealand. The predominant type

of teacher-led service is centre-based ECEC, which children can attend either part-time or full-

time and which caters for children from birth to school age. In New Zealand, children can

choose to start school any time after their fifth birthday and must start school by the time of

their sixth birthday.

Most child care funding in New Zealand is provided on the supply side in order to keep parent

fees low. There is also 20 hours of “free” ECEC provided to all 3- and 4-year-old children. All

supply-side funding is provided through the Ministry of Education according to formulas based

on cost-drivers.

Denmark

Most child care funding in Denmark is supply-side funding, provided by municipalities to child

care providers. Local authorities are required to ensure that there is a child care place for every

child over 26 weeks of age whose parents want one (within 4 weeks of turning 26 weeks). The

central government provides block grants to local municipalities and local governments raise

tax money as well to fulfill these obligations.

Most child care funding in Denmark is designed to keep parent fees relatively low. Parent fees

are set annually by municipalities, and municipalities are required to fund child care providers

so that parents pay no more than 25% of the actual cost of the service. There are also

discounts for siblings.

Norway

There are three types of child care (known as kindergartens) in Norway. Ordinary kindergartens

(barnehager) can be public or private. They offer half-day or full-day service all year round for

children between 0 and 5 years of age. Family kindergartens (familiebarnehager) are based in

private homes, where an assistant works with a maximum of five children, supervised and

mentored by a qualified kindergarten teacher on a weekly basis. Open kindergartens (åpne

barnehager) are part-time drop-in centres with programs for parents and children to participate

in together, led by a qualified kindergarten teacher.

Page 21: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

11

Obtaining a place in kindergarten is a statutory right for every child, but participation in ECEC is

voluntary. About 50% of the centres in Norway are municipally owned and operated; the other

50% are run by private operators, most of them not-for-profit.

Most child care funding in Norway is supply-side operating funding. The government imposes a

statutory fee cap on the parental fee for centre-based or family child care (NOK 2,655 per

month in 2016 or about Can$418 per month or Can$4,600 per 11-month year). This means that

parents cover about 15% of the cost of ECEC through parent fees. The bulk of the operating

costs of ECEC are covered by government funding, that is about 85% of operating costs. About

90% of children 1-5 years of age attend child care.

A new plan provides 20 hours of free child care per week to 3-, 4- and 5-year-old children from

families earning less than about Can$66,000 annually. Parents have to engage in some activity

(e.g., Norwegian language courses) in order to be eligible.

Sweden

Sweden has an integrated and largely universal child care system for children younger than

school age, considered as a part of the education system (but voluntary). It is designed to

support employment and study activities as well as providing play-based education for children

at low or zero cost to parents.

The main type of child care in Sweden is centre-based preschool or förskola. Preschool is also

available as home child care. Preschool serves children 1-5 years of age (children younger than

one year of age are nearly all cared for by parents receiving relatively generous parental

payments). Preschool is intended to be safe, fun and instructive, and it promotes a philosophy

of the equality of all individuals, particularly of girls and boys. Municipalities are responsible for

ensuring that children who want to attend are provided a place in preschool – within four

months of the request. Most of the preschools (81%) are municipally owned and operated.

About 19% of centres are independently operated – run by parents, staff or as a business.

Central government defines goals and objectives of child care, such as the national curriculum.

Municipalities play the main role in implementing policy, planning and delivering ECEC services.

Municipalities also determine working conditions and pay of child care staff locally.

Municipalities receive annual quality reports and pedagogical documentation from child care

services

In Sweden, the parent fee depends on parental income in a scheme known as Maxtaxa. Under

this scheme, parents are charged no more than 3% of household income for one child in

preschool/child care up to a maximum monthly household income. The maximum a family

Page 22: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

12

could have to pay per month for one child in preschool is approximately Can$209 per month.

For the second child, the maximum charge is another 2% of household income, and another 1%

for the third.

Quebec

Quebec has a network of Early Childhood Centres and family homes that were the original heart

of their system of reduced-fee child care services. The base rate for this child care is now $7.75

per day for families earning less than about $50,000. For other families, there is a sliding scale

of payments rising to $21.20 per day at about $160,000 and above.

For families not using reduced-fee child care in Quebec, there is a tax credit for child care

expenses – a different sliding scale of payments. Families earning less than about $35,000 will

be reimbursed through the tax system for 75% of the full fee; families earning more will be

reimbursed less; and families earning above about $155,000 will be reimbursed 26% of the full

fee. This funding compensates parents using informal unlicensed care, as well as other types of

care.

Prince Edward Island

Recently, Prince Edward Island has reorganized existing licensed child care programs into a

publicly-managed network of Early Years Centres and Infant Homes in which fees are regulated,

wages are based on a common salary scale, and there is sector planning, professional

development and management support.

Manitoba

Manitoba has pioneered many innovations in management of a child care system. Manitoba

provides base funding to services willing to become a funded facility. Funded facilities are not-

for-profit centres and family homes that are willing to cap fees. Two-thirds of staff are required

to have an ECE diploma, however, there are important problems recruiting sufficient staff.

Chapter 8: Different Funding Approaches – The Evidence

Which funding model would be best for Ontario? We consider several alternatives:

1. A generous sliding scale of child care fees, where all families with earnings less than

$40,000 pay nothing, all families with incomes above $240,000 pay 80% of the full cost

of the child care they use and, in between, families pay an increasing percentage of the

full fee as their income is higher. We call this a $40K-$240K sliding scale.

Page 23: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

13

2. Free licensed child care for preschool children between 2½ years of age and

kindergarten. For other ages, fees are charged based on family income. For children

other than preschool age, families with earnings less than $50,000 will pay nothing; and

families earning over $150,000 will pay 80% of the full fee. In between, families pay an

increasing percentage as family income rises. We call this a $50K-$150K sliding scale.

3. The maximum fee for child care is capped at $20 per day per child. The existing Ontario

subsidy system provides financial assistance to lower-income families that cannot afford

$20 per day.

4. Kevin Milligan has recently recommended adopting a tax credit for child care expenses

similar to one of the types of funding that is currently available in Quebec. We model a

version of his idea, with families having to pay from 25% of the full-fee at low incomes

to 74% at high levels of income.

We use two different approaches to assess these policy options. One calculates the returns to

employment for a parent that uses licensed child care at different levels of income. We draw

charts that show how the returns to employment, after child care costs, are affected at

different levels of earnings by the four policy options above, in comparison to the current

subsidy system. A policy that gives higher returns to employment after child care costs is one

that lowers child care cost barriers for parents.

Returns to Employment – Lone Parent Families

We look at two sample families. One is a lone parent family with a toddler, facing full child care

fees of $17,000 annually. The second is a two-parent family in which one spouse is employed

earning $40,000. They have two children – 2 and 3 years of age – and full child care fees would

be $30,000 annually.

The existing Ontario subsidy system is important in lowering the barriers to employment for

lone parent families able to access subsidies; however, this financial assistance disappears

above about $85,000. For lone parent families, either of the sliding scales we are considering -

$40K-$240K or $50K-$150K combined with free preschool child care - provides much stronger

employment incentives than the existing subsidy system, spendable income after child care

costs is equivalent (i.e., for sliding scales vs. subsidy) at very low levels of income for lone

parents, and higher at all other levels of income for both lone parent and two parent families.

The Milligan tax credit for child care expenses is negative for low-income lone parent families –

they do much worse than with the subsidy system. Above about $50,000, the tax credit

improves employment returns, but not generally by as much as the sliding scale options.

Page 24: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

14

The $20 per day per child flat fee combined with a fully-funded subsidy system improves

employment returns for many families compared to the current situation. However, between

about $20,000 and $90,000, it does not boost employment returns by as much as the sliding

scale funding models.

Returns to Employment – Two-Parent Families

The results of these funding policies are broadly similar to the pattern seen for lone parent

families when we consider the employment returns available to a parent in a two-parent family

with two children who is considering a return to work.

When this parent enters the labour force she gains employment income. But as her earned

income rises, her family will be eligible for less Canada Child Benefit, less Ontario Child Benefit,

and she will have to pay income taxes, Canada Pension Plan payments and Employment

Insurance payments. Her spouse will lose the value of the Spousal Credit, as a credit against his

taxes. And, of course, she will face substantial fees for licensed child care. All of this reduces

the percentage of her gross earnings that contributes to an increase in spendable income for

the family, and affects the employment returns from taking a paid job.

If this family faces the full child care cost, her employment returns are likely to be negative. If

she cannot earn at least $60,000 per year, there is no obvious financial reason to be employed.

The existing Ontario subsidy system will improve these returns, but for a low-earning main

caregiving parent, she will still only increase the family’s spendable income by 20%-30% of her

gross earnings. The Ontario child care subsidy system is less helpful to this two-parent family

than to a lone-parent family, largely because this family is only eligible for partial subsidy.

The tax credit performs poorly for this two-parent family – it is worse than the existing subsidy

system for our two-parent family with two children unless the main caregiving parent earns

$35,000 or more. And it provides lower employment incentives than other funding policies for

other levels of her gross earnings.

The $20 per day per child policy, combined with a well-funded subsidy system, improves

employment returns for a two-parent family better than other policies if her gross earnings are

over $55,000. However, for earnings below about $40,000, this policy fares much worse than

either of the sliding-scale options, and is only a modest improvement over the existing subsidy

system.

Both the $40K-$240K sliding scale, and the provision of free child care for children of preschool

age combined with a $50K-$150K sliding scale for children of other ages, do quite well in

increasing employment incentives (reducing barriers to employment) for the main caregiving

Page 25: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

15

parent in a two-parent family. Free child care for preschool ages plus a sliding scale for other

ages is noticeably better than the $40K-$240K sliding scale when the main caregiving parent’s

income is quite low.

Our strong conclusion is that either one of the sliding scale policy options is strongly preferred

to either the $20 flat fee or the tax credit for child care expenses. If we care particularly

strongly about lower-income families, the free preschool child care plus $50K-$150K sliding

scale gets the nod.

Results from Child Care Demand and Employment Model

The second approach we use to assess these four child care funding options required the

building of a software model using Statistics Canada data. This model resides in the Research

Data Centre at the University of Toronto. The model forecasts child care and employment

decisions of families across Ontario who responded to the National Household Survey of 2011.

Child care and employment decisions are modelled statistically, so that variations in family and

child characteristics as well as changes in parental incomes, child care fees, and child care

policies can be used to predict child care and employment decisions. In addition, the model

allows us to calculate the taxes a family will pay, the affordability of child care, the net child

care price a family will have to pay, as well as the total governmental cost of any child care

policy and the total tax revenue government will raise.

Simulations using this model confirm that licensed child care is distinctly unaffordable right now

for many families. Families with young children (0-4) now have to spend over 23% of their

after-tax family income to access licensed child care services. As compared to the income

contribution that the main caregiving parent can make when she returns to employment, child

care spending would be on average over two-thirds of her income.

The $40K-$240K sliding scale would transform the child care system into one that is affordable

to virtually all families. Demand for all age categories of licensed child care increases

dramatically in this simulation, more than doubling overall and rising to nearly six times its

current level for infants. The average percent of family income that a family with children 0-4

would spend on licensed child care would now be 2.7%, and the average percent of the main

caregiving parent’s income contribution would be 9.5%. The gross cost to government would

be $4.5 billion. Government revenues are predicted to rise by $1.3 billion in the near-term,

including both federal and provincial revenues.

Making child care services free of charge for children from 2½-4 years of age would also have

dramatic effects. This is combined with a $50K-$150K sliding scale for infants, toddlers and

kindergarten children. Affordability is substantially improved for families in all income

categories, particularly lower-income families. On average, families with children 0-4 would

Page 26: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

16

now pay 2.7% of after-tax family income to access licensed child care services. There are

substantial increases in the demand for infant and toddler child care, and an especially large

increase in the demand for preschool care in this simulation. Overall child care demand would

more than double. The gross cost to government would be $4.4 billion. Government revenues

are predicted to rise by $1.3 billion in the near-term, including both federal and provincial

revenues.

Lowering the full fee to $20 per day per child for infants, toddlers, preschoolers and

kindergarten children is combined with the maintenance and expansion of the subsidy system

to provide extra assistance to low-income families. This simulation substantially improves

affordability – to 3.7% of after-tax family income on average for families with children 0-4.

There are substantial increases in the demand for infant and toddler care and overall demand

for licensed care more than doubles. The gross cost to government would be $3.9 billion.

Government revenues are predicted to rise by $1.1 billion in the near-term, including both

federal and provincial revenues.

The final simulation would adopt a new provincial tax credit for child care expenses. We have

chosen to model this with a continuation of the existing subsidy system; without this, as we

have seen, the tax credit would have very negative effects for low-income families. Even so, this

tax credit has effects on affordability that are notably less effective than for alternative funding

policies. With this tax credit, families with children 0-4 would pay, on average, 7.8% of their

after-tax family income to access licensed child care. Families with incomes below $50,000

would pay 8.0% of net incomes, families between $50,000 and $100,000 would pay 7.3% of

income and families at $100,000 and above would pay out 6.0% of net family income. This

pattern (i.e., higher % for low-income families) is opposite to those of other alternative policies.

The gross cost to government would be $3.2 billion. Government revenues are predicted to

rise by $0.8 billion in the near-term, including both federal and provincial revenues.

Only two of these simulations are ones that we think should be considered seriously for

implementation. Both the $40K-$240K sliding scale and free child care for preschool children

plus a $50K-$150K sliding scale have very positive effects on affordability and desirable

distributional effects in terms of income groups and lone parent/two parent affordability.

There are, however, important problems of phase-in. There are not yet enough licensed spaces

to meet all the demand that would be created. Dealing effectively with these transition issues

will make it clear that the option that provides free child care for children of preschool age is

the best one.

Page 27: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

17

Chapter 9: Workforce Issues, Compensation and Costs

It is not possible to solve child care affordability problems without considering workforce

compensation. Wage and benefit payments are by far the largest component of child care

costs and, for many reasons, compensation of child care staff will rise. The government needs a

strategic plan to address workforce issues in order to manage rapid expansion of the sector.

A workforce strategy would include establishing target levels of education and training, the

design of a salary ladder, target compensation packages, and would deal with recruitment

issues.

Taking all workers in child care centres together, the median wage level in Ontario (before

minimum wage rises) is between $15 and $20 per hour. In most parts of the province,

unqualified staff receive (in 2017) a wage which is very low ($11.40-$15 per hour at the median

– effectively $13.40-$15 per hour because of the $2 Wage Enhancement Grant). Qualified staff

receive between $15 and $20 per hour. Even supervisors’ wages are not particularly high

across most of the province at $20-$26.68 per hour at the median. Toronto is an exception,

with hourly wages for unqualified and qualified program staff and supervisors being higher, at

the median, than in the rest of the province. Ottawa is a partial exception, too.

If we compare hourly wages in other occupations to those in child care, we get a sense of the

difficulties of recruiting additional qualified workers at current wages. Current child care wages

appear to be competitive with other occupations when workers are 15-24 years of age.

However, child care wages are distinctly uncompetitive with hourly wages paid to female

workers who are 25-54 years of age in many occupations across the province.

Compensation levels need to rise in child care if expansion is going to be possible. In particular,

compensation levels need to rise so that the staff that are recruited will be capable, well-

qualified staff who will decide to stay in the sector.

We have developed a spreadsheet-based costs model for child care centres in Ontario that

allows us to analyze different child care cost issues. Research has shown that wages and

benefit costs can make up 80% or more of the cost of providing child care. However, it is

important to see that staff costs are a bigger fraction of infant care costs, than of toddler or

preschool costs. When we look at the low end of current wage ranges, it is a good

generalization that the percent of staff costs is in the 80’s for infants, the 70s for toddlers and

the high 60s for preschoolers. The percentages are somewhat higher if overall wage levels are

higher, but the principle remains. In other words, staff costs (wages and benefits of program

staff and supervisor) are a considerably lower percentage of the cost of preschool child care

than they are of infant child care.

Page 28: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

18

We use the costs model to calculate the impact of a 10% increase in wages, a 5 percentage-

point increase in benefits, and the impact of reaching a desirable target level of compensation

for all child care workers. We also model the effect of having all contact staff as qualified

Registered Early Childhood Educators.

This type of costs modelling has an important role to play in controlling costs, determining

appropriate fees, and capping fees.

Manitoba, Prince Edward Island, and Saskatchewan have created policy models with some

useful lessons – about salary grids, benefit packages, professional development, and caps on

fees.

Chapter 10: Transitions - How to Manage Growth in the Child Care

System

Based on the issues raised in this chapter, together with the analysis in the rest of this report,

we recommend that implementing free child care for preschool-aged children is the immediate

priority to improve affordability of licensed child care in Ontario. As physical and staffing

capacity are ramped up, increased affordability for other ages should be phased in.

Ontario is in a good position to take the next steps in expanding the licensed child care system

and in making it much more affordable. However, expansion will not be easy; it will bring some

very large challenges.

With full implementation of either one of the sliding scales modelled, the increase in the

number of children 0-4 years of age using licensed care would be nearly 200,000 and for

children 0-6 (not yet in school), demand would increase by at least 275,000 children.

Immediately after the announcement of a new funding policy, there is likely to be a substantial

shortage of capacity relative to demand, unless the government is able to find a way to phase-

in affordability over time.

There are (at least) five distinct problems of transition (or phase-in) that are important to

consider:

Physical capacity in licensed centres and homes;

Development and management of the expanded system;

Shortages of trained qualified staff and even of unqualified staff;

How to ration scarce spaces and/or phase-in demand; and

Maintaining and improving quality during the transition, including the role of for-profit

child care providers in the transition and after.

Page 29: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

19

Even if capacity can be rolled out very quickly, there will be some capacity constraints (i.e.,

shortages or excess demand) over the next five years.

Municipalities will play a central role in capacity expansion, in a development role. For this,

they will need extra resources and clear targets and timelines with both capital and operating

funding.

The management capacity in the sector is in some cases weak. The majority of child care

centres in Ontario are managed by small- to medium-sized non-profit boards of directors,

usually composed of parents. Many directors of programs have little management expertise or

management qualifications.

We recommend that existing centres and home child care agencies be required to apply to

have the right to provide free or reduced-fee services and receive substantial public funding

from government. Existing centres and home child care agencies would sign contracts agreeing

on terms such as provision of services, conditions of service, and rights to inspect in exchange

for payments from municipalities for services provided. In a similar situation in Prince Edward

Island, centres with such contracts were designated as Early Years Centres as a mark of

recognition of this new status. Ontario would have to develop a similar designation, as a signal

of quality and regulation to parents.

As demand expands, operators will struggle to find enough qualified staff, or indeed enough

staff at all. Compensation will have to rise in order to attract sufficient new staff. The province

(and municipalities) have a strong interest in structuring higher compensation to provide

incentives for continuous upgrading, apprenticeships, basic training for unqualified staff, and

incentives for qualified staff to make licensed child care into a career choice.

There are a number of ways of rationing spaces when there is excess demand (e.g. by

geography, age of child, income group) but rationing (i.e., allocating services in a managed way)

will be easier if access to dramatically improved affordability can be phased-in. Careful

management of the timing of funding reforms could help with excess demand issues.

Free Preschool Child Care

In earlier chapters, we have concluded that the two sliding scale policy alternatives – a $40K-

$240K sliding scale, or free child care for preschool children plus a $50K-$150K sliding scale –

are better at reducing barriers to employment and improving affordability than either the flat

fee ($20 per day) or tax credit approach. The free child care for preschool children policy has a

distinct advantage – it would be easier to phase in. The Government of Ontario should decide,

as an immediate priority, to make preschool-aged child care free for Ontario families.

Preschool-aged child care is already very popular and most families seek out good quality group

Page 30: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

20

experiences for their children in the year or so before kindergarten. Making child care free

would help all families with child care affordability in the years immediately before

kindergarten.

Starting with preschool age makes sense in other ways. There is already a large licensed

capacity of child care available to serve children of this age, so shortages would be less acute

than for other age groups. Because the required staff:child ratio for preschoolers is 1:8,

expansion of services requires fewer new staff than if, for instance, expansion was

concentrated among children of toddler age, where the staff: child ratio is 1:5. It will take time

and effort to ramp up both physical capacity and staff capacity. These efforts will bear more

fruit more quickly for children of preschool age.

During the phase-in period for free preschool child care, the existing child care subsidy system

would continue for children younger or older than preschool. As licensed capacity and staffing

capacity increase, the Government should increase funding available for subsidy, and loosen

some of the restrictive regulations on activity requirements so that more funding is available to

improve affordability, particularly for infants and toddlers. When there is sufficient physical

and staff capacity, a $50K-$150K sliding scale of funding should be implemented.

The gross cost to government of free preschool child care together with continuation of the

subsidy system would be $1.6 billion. This cost is reached only when all new preschool demand

is satisfied. Government revenues are predicted to rise by about $500 million in the near-term,

including both federal and provincial revenues. As the restrictions and stigma of the subsidy

system are loosened and as it becomes fully funded, more families would be helped and costs

would rise. This option with a fully-funded subsidy system where financial assistance was

available as a right would have gross costs to government of $2.6 billion with additional

government revenues of about $700 million in the near-term.

Making preschool child care free will require that licensed capacity for preschool-aged children

be expanded rapidly. The development and licensing of this expansion needs to be carefully

managed by municipalities, so that new capacity for infants, toddlers and other ages is

incorporated into newly built or renovated centres. As infant and toddler capacity is expanded,

the Ministry of Education can increase funding and loosen rules on subsidy so that more

families are able to afford this child care. When there is sufficient physical and staff capacity,

the Government can amend legislation to provide a $50K-$150K sliding scale of funding as a

right to parents.

It is highly problematic to rely on the for-profit sector as a major provider of services if you are

seeking to build a quality service, and what is essentially a public service. The Ministry of

Education has made it clear that coming expansion will be focused in the not-for-profit and

public sectors. This is appropriate, but may be difficult.

Page 31: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

21

The Government of Ontario, through the Ministry of Education, has invested substantially in

improving legislation, regulations, institutions and funding of early learning and child care as

well as child and family centres in Ontario over the last decade. Ontario, with the support of its

capable municipalities, is in a good position to take the next steps in expanding the licensed

child care system and in making it much more affordable.

Page 32: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

22

CHAPTER 1: INTRODUCTION, OBJECTIVES AND

PRINCIPLES

This study seeks to answer the question “What is the best way to improve the affordability of

licensed child care for infants, toddlers and preschoolers in Ontario?” It seeks to provide a

comprehensive analysis of alternative funding and policy options and to recommend steps

forward that can dramatically improve child care affordability for families. Seemingly simple,

this topic is more complicated than it first appears. This study includes a number of parts:

A review of the evidence showing the ways in which public investment in licensed child

care services makes sense if it is well-planned and implemented.

A detailed description of child care services in Ontario, and of the funding systems that

currently affect access and affordability. This includes a description and analysis of

federal child benefits, of provincial child care policies and of the important role of

municipalities in administering the subsidy and funding systems. It also includes a

discussion of current issues related to Ontario’s child care workforce.

An analysis of the issue of child care (un)affordability and the role of current funding

instruments in addressing it. An analysis of alternative instruments for addressing child

care affordability and their advantages and disadvantages. This includes examining

policies to improve affordability in other jurisdictions - in Canada and around the world.

Calculation of the effects of alternative policies that could be used to improve

affordability of licensed child care in Ontario. We look at the expected effects on

affordability, on parental incomes, on employment, and on the costs of and revenues

from different policy approaches.

Transitioning towards new policies for improving child care affordability may not be

straightforward. We discuss difficulties associated with moving towards a more

affordable child care future for Ontario families and suggest remedies.

Recommendations are discussed throughout the report and grouped at its end.

On September 12, 2016, the Government of Ontario committed itself in the Speech from the

Throne to helping 100,000 more children, aged 4 and under, to access licensed child care over

the next five years starting in 2017. As part of this effort, the Ministry of Education developed a

Renewed Early Years and Child Care Policy Framework and Expansion Strategy. The goal of the

renewed framework is to support an integrated system of child care and early years programs,

guided by the principles of access, responsiveness, affordability and quality. The expansion

Page 33: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

23

strategy is targeted towards the child care needs of infants, toddlers and preschoolers (i.e.,

children from birth, or the end of parental leave, to kindergarten age).

From Fall 2016 to Winter 2017, the ministry conducted province-wide discussions with Ontario

families and citizen groups. During the consultation period, families and stakeholders identified

access to and affordability of licensed child care as the biggest barriers facing the system. The

high cost of child care fees, and a lack of spaces have put pressure on families and parents

wanting to enter or return to the labour force.

The Government, therefore, wishes to dramatically improve the affordability of early learning

and child care services (licensed child care services) and to move towards an integrated and

accessible system of child care and early years programs across Ontario. It has appointed me,

with help from my associates, to review existing methods and consider improved methods of

funding that are appropriate to a system of early learning and child care services that is

affordable, accessible, of high quality, and that is available as a right to those families who wish

to use it. In particular, the Government has asked me to consider the design of funding that

would permit fees to be scaled to income, affordable for parents, and would encourage

employment and education or training activities, taking into account activity-disincentives of

the existing tax and benefit systems.

The Government wishes to hear recommendations for changes that will support an affordable,

accessible, integrated, high quality system of early learning and child care services for Ontario.

1.1 People and Methods Used for This Study

Dr. Gordon Cleveland, Associate Professor Emeritus of Economics in the Department of

Management, University of Toronto Scarborough was commissioned by the government to

conduct this study. He has been fortunate to have the capable assistance of social policy

consultant Sue Colley, M.B.A. and Economics Professor Michael Krashinsky, Ph.D., from the

Department of Management, University of Toronto Scarborough.

Different methods have been used in this study to analyze the child care system in Ontario and

to develop recommendations for the government on how to improve affordability. We have

interviewed officials knowledgeable about child care policies and circumstances in nearly all of

the municipalities that act as Service System Managers in Ontario. Most of these thorough

interviews took 1-2 hours to complete.

We have also interviewed or had meetings with representatives of the Ontario Municipal Social

Service Association, the Association of Early Childhood Educators Ontario, the Ontario Coalition

for Better Child Care, the Home Child Care Association of Ontario, the College of Early

Page 34: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

24

Childhood Educators, Nipissing First Nation, George Brown College, and Ministry of Education

Program Advisors and Early Years Advisor.

The scope of this Report does not fully extend to First Nations Child Care. It is understood that

the Government of Ontario is planning to engage directly in a Government to Nation

negotiation with the First Nations to establish a plan for Early Learning and Child Care on

Reserve. Some statistics and information have been included for clarification purposes but we

explicitly do not address the funding reforms necessary for On Reserve First Nations Child

Care. Indigenous families off reserve are extensively affected by the existing early learning and

child care system. The Truth and Reconciliation Commission paved the way for new ways to

fund and deliver child care services to the Indigenous population. Under the auspices

of the Journey Together program together with Government funding, many Indigenous-led

organizations (with the support of the municipalities) are creating new child care centres and

child and family programs that are culturally-appropriate and dedicated to meeting the needs

of the off-reserve Indigenous population.

We have analyzed data provided by the Ministry of Education to draw a picture of the

component parts of the licensed child care system in Ontario. We have accessed data from a

number of other sources as well, including the Childcare Resource and Research Unit’s regular

and detailed reports on child care in Canada (e.g., Friendly et al., 2015) as well as data in the

Early Childhood Education Report and its profiles from 2014 (Akbari and McCuaig, 2014).

We have constructed a child care demand and parental employment model in the University of

Toronto’s Research Data Centre, using National Household Survey data on Ontario families.

This model contains actual data on nearly 120,000 families that have children younger than

compulsory school age in the province and who are representative of nearly 700,000 such

children. The model uses data from the 2016 Labour Force Survey to project the incomes that

could be earned in families with employment support from affordable child care services. The

model uses the Canadian Tax and Credit Simulator (Milligan, 2016) to calculate all of the income

and payroll taxes payable by these families and the child benefits for which they would be

eligible. Therefore, the model allows us to calculate the disposable (i.e., after-tax, after-

benefit) incomes that families have to potentially spend on child care and the net child care

prices they are likely to face in different parts of the province.

This complex model allows us to calculate the affordability of licensed child care for different

families in different situations and to analyze the conditions that affect the affordability of child

care. We are able to run different simulated policy changes through the model. The model

allows us to calculate the expected effects of each policy alternative on affordability, on

parental incomes, on employment, and on the overall costs to government and the effects of

increased employment on net tax revenues.

Page 35: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

25

1.2 WHAT CHARACTERISTICS SHOULD A REFORM OF THE

EARLY LEARNING AND CHILD CARE SYSTEM HAVE?

We begin our quest for improved child care affordability with certain principles in mind. These

principles apply broadly to the nature of child care services, not just to principles of financing.

It may not be possible to fully respect each one; there will likely be trade-offs. However, it is

important to state the principles, because they describe the goals of our quest. In our plan for

dramatically improving the affordability of licensed child care in Ontario:

1. Most (or all) families should be able to benefit from reforms.

2. No family should be made worse off.

3. Lower-income families should receive at least their proportionate share of new services.

Reforms should positively promote greater access to scarce high-quality child care

services for lower-income children and families and children facing different

disadvantages.

4. Reforms should encourage and promote high quality child care services for children.

5. Services need to recognize the diversity of cultures, races, religions as well as sexual

orientation and disability in the province of Ontario. All services should be inclusive and

welcoming to the broad tapestry of origins, beliefs and experiences.

6. All the expansion should take place in non-profit or public facilities/services, with

grandfathering of existing for-profit operations.

7. Reforms should make services more affordable and better quality, but should also, as

much as possible, give parents more time with children.

8. Child care reforms should encourage (but not compel) parental employment or

study/training.

9. Rising service costs should lead to rising quality of services (not just more expensive

services).

10. Reforms should improve parents’ knowledge and investments in their children; they

should not primarily substitute for parental investments. Father participation should be

encouraged.

11. Parents should have considerable opportunities to influence child care experiences of

their children.

Page 36: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

26

12. Services need to be sufficiently rich in quality and programming to support children’s

development.

13. Reforms should promote higher levels of compensation for child care staff both on

grounds of equity and to attract the large numbers of trained and experienced staff that

will be required as the system expands.

Page 37: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

27

CHAPTER 2: CHILD CARE SERVICES, GOVERNANCE AND

FUNDING

Chapter Summary

This chapter provides detailed information about the child care services available to

families across Ontario, the funding available to families and services, and the

mechanisms and responsibilities for governance.

Child care is the responsibility of the Ministry of Education, Early Years and Child Care

Division under the Minister of Education, Indira Naidoo-Harris. The role of the Ministry

is to develop policy, to provide funding, and to update and enforce legislation and

regulations in relation to child care and early years services. The Ministry licenses child

care centre programs and home child care agencies.

Ontario is unique amongst Canada’s provinces and territories in having a central role for

municipalities in the planning, funding and administration of funding for licensed child

care services. There are 37 Consolidated Municipal Service Managers and 10 District

Social Service Administration Boards (CMSMs and DSSABs) that are the municipal

service system managers for child care. Child care services are managed by CMSMs and

DSSABs through a local service planning process. School boards and child and family

programs are also important local partners in the planning and delivery of child care and

early years services. First Nations are an important partner in the delivery of on-reserve

child care.

Governments in Ontario spent over $1.3 billion on child care and early years services in

2015. Allocations are provided to CMSMs and DSSABs through the Child Care Funding

Formula which is designed to provide an equitable funding allocation for municipal child

care service managers across the province. A portion of the spending requires a

minimum cost-share requirement from municipalities; however, since 2005, new

provincial investments have not required additional CMSM or DSSAB cost-sharing.

The primary source of funding for child care services, however, is parent fees. Currently,

the main funding policy that affects the affordability of licensed child care services is the

Ontario child care subsidy system. There are income and activity requirements to be

eligible for child care subsidy; even then, subsidies may not be available if annual

funding has been exhausted. Families earning less than $20,000 may be eligible for a

full subsidy; families earning between $20,000 and $40,000 will pay 10% of income

above $20,000. Families earning over $40,000 will pay $2,000 plus 30% of their income

that is over $40,000. In general, parents need to be employed or seeking employment,

Page 38: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

28

or in training or education, to be eligible for child care subsidy, although there are

exceptions according to child or family need.

First Nations can administer and operate child care and early years programs on reserve

and many do. First Nations can also make agreements to exercise any powers of a

service system manager. There is a large Indigenous population across the Province

living off-reserve. For many years it has been alienated from the mainstream Early

Learning and Child Care system - as documented in the Truth and Reconciliation

Commission’s Final Report. This is largely because the majority of child care programs in

Ontario lack the cultural sensitivity to serve Indigenous children and because fees have

been too high to afford or subsidies too hard to get. Under the auspices of a Ministry

funded Journey Together program, Indigenous-led community organizations (such as

Friendship Centres) are now establishing new culturally-appropriate programs (child

care centres, home child care and child and family centres) under their own leadership,

together with programs to provide culture sensitivity training programs across the

sector. This is being accomplished with the cooperation and collaboration of the

CMSM/DSSABs.

The French Language Services Act requires the provision of French-language services to

Francophone families in areas of Ontario where at least 10% of the population is

francophone or where at least 5,000 Francophones are resident. Municipalities are

required to follow the act in the delivery of child care funding and services.

The Ministry of Education provides funding for Special Needs Resourcing. Special Needs

Resourcing provides staff, equipment, supplies or services to support inclusion of

children with special needs in licensed child care settings including home child care,

camps and authorized recreation programs at no additional cost to parents / guardians.

CMSMs and DSSABs are required to spend a minimum of 4.1 % of their total child care

allocation on special needs resourcing. In 2015, the average percentage spent on special

needs resourcing was 13.6%.

There are over 5,300 licensed child care centres in Ontario with over 406,000 spaces for

children 0-12 years. Just over 161,000 of these centre spaces are for infants, toddlers

and preschoolers, often described as children 0-4 years. Nearly 106,000 of these spaces

are for children of preschool age (from 30 months to kindergarten age).

Nearly 76% of Ontario’s licensed child care centres are not-for-profits.

Child care fees vary by region and by child’s age. The regional median Infant fee varies

from $51.00 per day in the North to $85.00 per day in Toronto. For toddlers, the range

is from $42.00 to $66.00. For preschoolers, the range is from $38.00 to $52.00 per day.

Page 39: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

29

There are over 111,000 children who receive child care subsidies in Ontario. About 40%

of infants who are using licensed centre care receive a subsidy, about 34% of toddlers

and about 31% of the preschool-aged children who are in centres.

There are nearly 260,000 children using licensed centre care who do not receive child

care subsidy.

There are 124 agencies who co-ordinate the provision of home child care in nearly 7,600

approved homes. There are nearly 16,000 children in home child care. Daily fees are

generally lower in home child care than in centre care. Of course, educational and

training requirements as well as child-staff ratios are very different in home child care

than they are for centre care.

Across Ontario, there are enough licensed spaces in centres and homes for infants,

toddlers and preschoolers to accommodate about 23% of all children 0-4 years of age.

In Toronto and Central Region, there is space for about 26%-27% of 0-4-year-olds.

2.1 OVERVIEW AND PROVINCIAL GOVERNANCE

Ontario has 5,351 child care centres across the province with over 406,000 spaces available for

children 0-12 years of age. There are also 124 licensed home child care agencies. These

agencies co-ordinate and monitor 7,579 family homes that provide care for nearly 16,000

children. Nearly 12,000 of these children are in receipt of child care subsidy.

The legislation under which child care centres and licensed home agencies are governed is the

Child Care and Early Years Act, 2014 (CCEYA), which came into effect on August 31, 2015. This

replaced the Day Nurseries Act which had been the governing legislation for child care services

since 1946. The CCEYA also regulates maximum numbers of children permitted in unlicensed

child care services provided by non-relative caregivers outside the child’s home. The CCEYA

does not regulate nannies or sitters providing care in the child’s home. Nor does it regulate

private schools that provide care only for children aged 4 and older.

Historically, child care was the responsibility of the Ministry of Community and Social Services

and, later, the Ministry of Children and Youth Services, but in 2010, the Ontario Government

moved the policy, regulatory and funding responsibility for child care to the Ministry of

Education. Reflecting the importance of early years and child care, the government appointed

Page 40: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

30

an Associate Minister of Education (Early Years and Child Care) – Minister Indira Naidoo-Harris –

now known as the Minister Responsible for Early Years and Child Care.1

The role of the Ministry of Education, Early Years and Child Care Division, is to develop policy

and programs in relation to child care and early years services, including child and family

centres, to provide funding, update and amend legislation and regulations under the CCEYA and

other related legislation such as the Education Act as required, and to monitor compliance with

those acts and regulations. Centre-based child care programs and home child care agencies are

licensed by the Ministry; these licences are renewed on regular basis and can be revoked for

violations of child care regulations. The CCEYA also introduced stronger enforcement tools,

including financial penalties associated with not meeting regulations, to support safety and

quality in licenced child care programs. The duration of a licence depends on the licensing

compliance history of the licensee. The licences specify the number of children in infant,

toddler, preschool, kindergarten and school age groups that a program is allowed to serve at

any one time.

The CCEYA also governs various types of funding available either to support child care programs

in the provision of services to children, or funding to families and children who need support in

purchasing licensed child care services for their children. Some of the funding (known as wage

enhancement) is explicitly directed to support the wage and benefit levels of those child care

staff and providers who currently receive a relatively low level of compensation.

The CCEYA regulates the minimum staff-child ratio permitted in centre care and the maximum

group size; both of these vary by age category of children served. The CCEYA gives the Minister

of Education the power to set regulations and standards and to periodically update regulations

for health and safety, staff training, program planning and characteristics of licenced child care

environments. The Ministry enforces these regulations through licensing inspections and a

combination of enforcement actions such as compliance orders, administrative penalties and

reclassifying a program into provisional licence status or revocation of a licence.

There are regional program advisors in seven area offices of the Ministry who are responsible

for carrying out inspections of licensed child care programs and for recommending licence

issuance and renewal. These program advisors follow up on complaints and serious

occurrences, and monitor compliance with the legislation and regulations. The regional

program advisors work under the supervision of regional managers who are appointed as

directors under the legislation. Regional managers may refer files to an Enforcement Unit in

1 As of January 2018, Minister Naidoo-Harris is the Minister of Education as well as continuing to be the Minister

Responsible for Early Years and Child Care.

Page 41: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

31

cases where stronger enforcement measures are required to bring the licensee into compliance

with the legislation. The Ministry’s Enforcement Unit is composed of designated provincial

offences officers with the authority to investigate contraventions of the CCEYA. Investigators

may exercise the powers of an inspector to enter licensed or unlicensed premises providing

child care services to investigate their operations, or in more serious cases, the investigators

may obtain and execute search warrants in order to collect evidence to lay charges.

In addition to full-day and part-day care in child care centres and home child care, the Ministry

of Education funds municipalities, First Nations, school boards and non-profit organizations

across the province to provide a range of child and family programs. These child and family

programs are currently being transformed into EarlyON Centres effective January 1, 2018.

2.2 THE MUNICIPAL ROLE IN CHILD CARE

Ontario is unique amongst Canada’s provinces and territories in having a central role for

municipalities in the planning, funding and administration of funding for licensed child care

services. There are 444 municipalities in Ontario, but the municipal role in child care is

exercised through 37 Consolidated Municipal Service Managers (known as CMSMs) and 10

District Social Services Administration Boards (DSSABs). These bodies form the membership of

the Ontario Municipal Social Services Association (OMSSA) and the Association of Municipalities

of Ontario (AMO).

The consolidation of municipal service management that was begun in 1998 by the provincial

government resulted in the creation of 47 CMSMs and DSSABs across Ontario. These are made

up principally of upper tier municipalities in southern Ontario and District Social Service

Administration Boards in northern Ontario. An upper-tier municipality is one that provides

services to residents of two or more lower-tier municipalities. The upper-tier is usually either a

county (such as Oxford or Wellington) or a regional municipality (such as Halton or Waterloo).

Some CMSMs are single-tier municipalities such as Toronto, Ottawa or Hamilton. The CMSMs

and DSSABs act as service system managers. Although most funding comes from the province,

these CMSMs and DSSABs also contribute to funding. They manage the funding for, plan,

manage and deliver human services including child care and early years and child care services,

employment and income supports, integrated human services, and housing and homelessness

prevention programs. Municipalities also influence child care locally through by-laws and

requirements related to the provision of care that go beyond provincial legislation and

regulatory requirements.

Child care services are managed by CMSMs and DSSABs through a local service planning

process that reflects current child care legislation, regulations and policies/directives, funding

guidelines outlined by the province, as well as engagement with local licensees. CMSMs and

DSSABs are major decision-makers in child care delivery and child care funding, however,

Page 42: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

32

school boards and child and family programs are also important local partners in the planning

and delivery of child care. School boards work closely with CMSMs and DSSABs in particular

when planning for before- and after-school care and in determining priorities for capital

investments to build new, or retrofit, school-based child care spaces. First Nations, as

described later, are important partners in the delivery of child care and early years services on-

reserve.

Effective January 1, 2018, child and family centres – known as EarlyON Child and Family Centres

- will be managed by CMSMs and DSSABs as part of their responsibility for the service system

management of child care and other human services.

For licensing purposes, the 47 CMSMs and DSSABs can be grouped into regions and it is useful

to use these regions to report on main elements of Ontario’s child care services system.

- The City of Toronto is so large that it forms its own region.

- The West Toronto region includes Regional Municipality of Peel, Regional Municipality

of Halton, County of Dufferin and County of Wellington.

- The Central region includes Regional Municipality of Durham, York, City of

Peterborough, City of Kawartha Lakes, County of Bruce, County of Grey, County of

Northumberland, County of Simcoe, and the District Municipality of Muskoka.

- The Southwest region includes City of Hamilton, City of London, Regional Municipality of

Waterloo, City of St. Thomas, City of Brantford, City of Stratford, City of Windsor, Huron

County, County of Lambton, County of Oxford, Municipality of Chatham-Kent, Norfolk

County and Regional Municipality of Niagara.

- The East region includes City of Ottawa, City of Kingston, City of Cornwall, County of

Hastings, County of Lanark, County of Renfrew, County of Lennox and Addington, United

County of Leeds and Grenville, and United County of Prescott and Russell.

- For the North region, we have grouped together municipalities in the North west and

the North east. The North region includes Kenora DSSAB, Rainy River DSSAB, Thunder

Bay DSSAB, Algoma DDSAB, Sault Ste. Marie DSSAB, City of Greater Sudbury,

Manitoulin-Sudbury DSSAB, Parry Sound DSSAB, Nipissing DSSAB, Timiskaming DSSAB,

and Cochrane DSSAB.

Page 43: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

33

2.3 OVERVIEW OF PROVINCE-WIDE SPENDING ON CHILD

CARE, 2015

In 2015, $1.312 billion was spent by governments in Ontario on child care. Most of the funds

come from the provincial government, but some is provided by municipalities. Allocations are

provided to CMSMs and DSSABs through the Child Care Funding Formula which is designed to

provide an equitable funding allocation for municipal child care service managers across the

province. A portion of the spending requires a minimum cost-share requirement from

municipalities; however, since 2005, new provincial investments have not required additional

CMSM or DSSAB cost-sharing. Table 1 shows totals and breakdowns of spending. The Toronto

Region stands out from others both in terms of the amount and distribution of spending.

$408.4 million was spent in Toronto – 31.1% of the total. Spending in the West Toronto region

summed to $184.5 million or 14.1% of the province-wide total. Spending in Central Region was

$202.7 million, and in Southwest was $273.0 million; these amount to 15.4% and 20.8% of the

provincial total. In the East region, a total of $158.0 million was spent on child care and in the

North, $85.9 million. These are 12% and 6.5% of the provincial total.

Table 1 also shows a broad functional breakdown of expenditures for each region and in total.

More detail than this is available, but this grouping facilitates a broad assessment of patterns.

All factors that contribute to operating funding of centres and homes or which serve to reduce

the wage burden for centres and homes are grouped under “Operating and Wages Support”,

except for the Wage Enhancement Grant (the allocation of which is not under municipal

discretion). All types of subsidies to parents and families are grouped under “Subsidies (all)”.

Administration and Special Needs Resourcing are kept as stand-alone categories. Everything

else is grouped in “All Other”.

As Table 1 shows, municipalities in different regions both spend different amounts and allocate

funding differently by function. Toronto devotes nearly 72% of its funding to subsidies. The

East region allocates 56% to subsidies. All other regions allocate from 39%-47% of funding to

subsidies. It is worth noting that these figures are from 2015, so patterns may be somewhat

altered now.

The allocation of funds is affected by municipal priorities, but also by the number of families

eligible for subsidy and needing subsidy in the local area. Toronto spends correspondingly less

than other regions (a smaller share) on operating grants/wages support and more on subsidies.

In 2015, Toronto allocated about 13% to operating and wages and nearly 72% to subsidies,

whereas in other regions more than 20% goes to wage support and operating funding, but from

about 40% to 55% to subsidies. Note that, in addition to the money shown under “operating

and wages support”, the province allocates funds to a Wage Enhancement Grant. In 2015, this

provided $1 per hour to program staff earning less than $26.27; in 2017, this has risen to $2 for

program staff earning less than $26.68.

Page 44: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

34

The Wage Enhancement Grant funding also provided income support to Home Child Care

Providers; providers received an increase of up to $10 per day if operating full-time or $5 per

day if operating part-time, in 2015. In 2016, these amounts increased to $20 per day and $10

per day for providers operating full-time or part-time, respectively. The intent of the wage

enhancement for centres and home child care is to help close the wage gap between registered

early childhood educators (RECEs) working in full-day kindergarten (FDK) and in licensed child

care settings, and to stabilize licensed child care operators by helping them retain RECEs and

other child care program staff.

Page 45: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

35

Table 1 Regional Breakdown of Expenditures by General Function, 2015

(millions of dollars and percent)

Source: Ministry of Education

Operating and

Wages Support

Wage Enhancement

Grant

Fee Subsidies including Ontario Works

Administration Special Needs

Resourcing

All Other

Total

Toronto $52.5 $14.2 $292.6 $30.4 $13.7 $4.9 $408.4

West Toronto

$43.7 $10.7 $85.6 $18.0 $16.9 $9.5 $184.5

Central $43.6 $13.7 $94.1 $17.7 $26.0 $7.4 $202.7

Southwest $76.7 $13.5 $128.8 $20.9 $24.8 $8.4 $273.0

East $34.8 $8.3 $88.2 $11.0 $10.6 $5.1 $158.0

North $43.1 $3.2 $33.1 $7.7 $9.2 $5.3 $85.9

Total by Function

$294.4 $63.6 $722.4 $105.7 $101.3 $40.7 $1,312.4

Toronto 12.9% 3.5% 71.6% 7.4% 3.4% 1.2% 100.0%

West Toronto

23.7% 5.8% 46.4% 9.8% 9.2% 5.1% 100.0%

Central 21.5% 6.8% 46.4% 8.7% 12.9% 3.7% 100.0%

Southwest 28.1% 4.9% 47.2% 7.7% 9.1% 3.1% 100.0%

East 22.0% 5.3% 55.8% 7.0% 6.7% 3.2% 100.0%

North 50.2% 3.7% 38.5% 9.0% 10.7% 6.2% 100.0%

Total 22.4% 4.8% 55.0% 8.1% 7.7% 3.1% 100.0%

Page 46: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

36

2.4 FUNDING

Parent fees are the primary source of funding for child care operations in the province.

The main funding policy that influences the affordability of licensed child care for some families

is the subsidy system. There is a uniform set of income and activity requirements across the

province that determine whether a family is eligible for subsidy, and, if so, for how much

assistance. A family may be eligible for full-subsidy or partial-subsidy, depending on the level of

family income. Municipalities administer the child care fee subsidy system and specific rules

and practices vary from municipality to municipality to meet local need.

Full subsidies are available to families with adjusted income that is less than or equal to $20,000

(adjusted income is very similar to total pre-tax income for most families). Partial subsidies are

available at incomes above $20,000 according to a formula (i.e., the family must pay 10% of

incremental income up to $40,000 and then 30% of incremental income above $40,000 up to

the full price of care for all children combined). Tables 2 and 3 show the amounts of subsidy

that a family would benefit from at different levels of family income and different levels of child

care fees.

There are also special categories of families that may receive fee subsidy. Some families are

eligible for fee subsidy because they are receiving Ontario Works. Some families are eligible for

fee subsidy because they are referred by a social worker. First Nations families are not subject

to the same fee subsidy requirements. There are no financial eligibility tests on reserves so that

all families on reserve are eligible for subsidy.

Not all centres provide services to subsidized children. Municipalities (CMSMs and DSSABs) can

restrict subsidies and/or other operating funding to centres with which they have purchase-of-

service agreements and some centres choose not to enter into purchase-of-service agreements.

These purchase-of-service agreements are a contractual arrangement that allows municipalities

to require centres to meet accountability requirements such as certain financial, reporting and

quality requirements in order to care for subsidized children or receive operating funding.

Page 47: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

37

Table 2 Amount of Child Care Subsidy Available to Families at Different Incomes,

For Different Assumed Fee Levels with One Child, Ontario 2017

Family Income One Infant @ $21,000/year

One Toddler @ $17,000/year

One Preschooler @ $13,000/year

One Kindergartener @ $6,000/school year

Amount of subsidy

Cost as % of income

Amount of subsidy

Cost as % of income

Amount of subsidy

Cost as % of income

Amount of subsidy

Cost as % of income

$20,000

$21,000 0.0% $17,000 0.0% $13,000 0.0% $6,000 0.0%

$40,000 $19,000 5.0% $15,000 5.0% $11,000 5.0% $4,000 5.0%

$60,000 $13,000 13.3% $9,000 13.3% $3,000 13.3% - - 10.0%

$80,000 $7,000 17.5% $3,000 17.5% - - 16.3% - - 7.5%

Source: Calculations by authors

Page 48: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

38

Table 3 Amount of Child Care Subsidy Available to Families at Different Incomes,

For Different Assumed Fee Levels with Two Children, Ontario 2017

Family Income

Two Infants @ $42,000/year Two Toddlers @ $34,000/year Two Preschoolers @ $26,000/year

Two Kindergarteners @ $12,000/school year

Amount of subsidy

Cost as % of income

Amount of subsidy

Cost as % of income

Amount of subsidy

Cost as % of income

Amount of subsidy

Cost as % of income

$20,000 $42,000 0.0% $34,000 0.0% $26,000 0.0% $12,000 0.0%

$40,000 $40,000 5.0% $32,000 5.0% $24,000 5.0% $10,000 5.0%

$60,000 $34,000 13.3% $26,000 13.3% $18,000 13.3% $4,000 13.3%

$80,000 $28,000 17.5% $20,000 17.5% $12,000 17.5% - - 15.0%

$100,000 $22,000 20.0% $14,000 20.0% $6,000 20.0% - - 12.0%

$120,000 $16,000 21.7% $8,000 21.7% $0 21.7% - - 10.0%

$140,000 $10,000 22.9% $2,000 22.9% - - 21.4% - - 8.6%

$160,000 $4,000 23.8% - - 21.3% - - 18.8% - - 7.5%

$180,000 - - 23.3% - - 18.9% - - 16.7% - - 6.7%

$200,000 - - 21.0% - - 17.0% - - 15.0% - - 6.0%

Source: Calculations by authors

Page 49: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

39

2.5 FIRST NATIONS CHILD CARE

Ontario has legislative authority to fund, regulate, and develop policy for child care in First

Nation communities on reserve.

The Child Care and Early Years Act, 2014 (CCEYA) authorizes a First Nation or group of First

Nations to establish, administer, operate and fund child care and early years programs and

services. The CCEYA also authorizes the Minister and a First Nation to enter into an agreement

to exercise and perform any powers or duties of a service system manager provided for under

the Act.

Pursuant to O. Reg. 138/15 under the CCEYA, most fee subsidies for licensed on-reserve child

care programs are cost shared on an 80% provincial / 20% First Nations basis. First Nations

manage the fee subsidy system in their respective communities. The province covers 100% of

other child care costs under the CCEYA.

The Ministry of Education (EDU) has transfer payment agreements with 74 First Nations and 3

transfer payment agencies for:

Licensed child care:

o Currently, 57 out of 133 First Nations have provincially-funded licensed child care

in their communities, with a total capacity of 3,175 licensed child care spaces.

There are also two licensed home-based child care agencies on reserve

supporting a total of 31 homes (Licensing data as of March 31, 2017). These are

in Akwesasne and Six Nations.

o Ontario has increased child care funding to the 57 First Nations with existing

child care programs from $17.7M in 2011-12 to $27.7M in 2017-18 ($30.8M with

wage enhancement funding).

Ontario Works recipients: Funding to support formal and informal child care costs for

individuals participating in the full Ontario Works (OW) Program. EDU provided

$964,237 in 2016-17 to 17 First Nations without licensed child care on reserve, and 30 of

the 57 First Nations with licensed child care on reserve.

Child and family programs: EDU currently provides approximately $712,000 to five First

Nations currently delivering child and family programs on reserve.

Ontario shares some First Nations child care costs with the federal government pursuant to the

1965 Indian Welfare Agreement (IWA). The IWA is a cost-sharing agreement between the

provincial and federal governments that provides for reimbursement to the province for a

Page 50: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

40

portion of the costs that Ontario incurs for on reserve child care (Ministry of Education), child

welfare (Ministry of Child and Youth Services), Ontario Works (Ministry of Community and

Social Services), and Homemakers and Nurses (Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care).

Under the IWA, the federal government reimburses Ontario for federally-approved child care

costs at a notional rate of 93%. However, owing to a federal cap on total child care funding

under the IWA at 1995 rates, and a narrow interpretation of ‘eligible child care expenses’, the

federal government actually reimburses the province for only about 43% of Ontario’s total

expenditures.

Since 2011-12 the government has increased First Nations child care funding from $17.7 million

to $30.8 million in 2017-18, including $2.9 million in wage enhancements.

The Ministry provides for fee subsidies for First Nations but unlike off-reserve, there is no

financial eligibility test and all children receive a full subsidy. In effect, the programs are base-

funded rather than families being individually income-tested. Individual First Nations may also

charge a nominal fee at their discretion.

First Nations are funded partially based on historical amounts, with some types of funding

allocated through a funding formula and there are restrictions on the ability to transfer funds

among categories. Unlike CMSMs/DSSABs, they do not receive the general operating grant per

se but retain the historical funding formula that allocates funding separately for historical wage

subsidy and pay equity, wage enhancement grants, special needs resourcing, capacity building,

etc. 100% of this funding is covered solely by the Ontario Government.

Included in Ontario plans to invest more than $250 million over the next three years on

programs and actions focused on reconciliation, which will be developed and evaluated in close

partnership with Indigenous partners, is a commitment to:

Increase the number of licensed child care spaces and culturally relevant

programming off-reserve and to

Expand child and family programs on-reserve and, through Indigenous and federal

partners, make supports available in more communities.

The Journey Together program has been the vehicle to achieve these goals. It is derived from

the Truth and Reconciliation Commission's (TRC) final report which shone a light on Canada's

residential school system - a dark chapter in our history with lasting impacts that are still felt by

Indigenous people today. As a result, Ontario is working with Indigenous partners to address

the legacy of residential schools, close gaps and remove barriers, create a culturally relevant

and responsive justice system, support Indigenous culture, and reconcile relationships with

Page 51: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

41

Indigenous peoples. True reconciliation goes beyond the Truth and Reconciliation’s 'Calls to

Action'. The Province will continue to look to Indigenous partners for guidance and leadership.

Journey Together is available to both on-reserve First Nations and for off-reserve Indigenous-

led organizations in communities across the province. On reserve, First Nations are establishing

new early years child and family centres. Off-reserve, CMSM/DSSABs are participating

in Journey Together projects led by local Indigenous partner organizations to provide new

culturally-appropriate stand-alone child care centres accessible and accountable to the local

Indigenous population. They are also developing both child care centre and home care services

that are accessible to both on and off reserve children, to extend culturally-sensitive services to

all residents off reserve as well as collaborating on professional development and training both

on and off reserve. In recognition of the unaffordable cost of child care in urban centres across

the Province, several communities are planning to establish centres with base funding so that

the Indigenous population can afford to attend.

There is no capital funding available to First Nations on reserve at the present time. First

Nations are awaiting the announcement of the Indigenous Early Learning and Child Care

Agreement, which will be allocated solely to First Nations.

2.6 CHILD CARE IN FRANCOPHONE COMMUNITIES IN

ONTARIO

The French Language Services (FLS) Act, passed in 1986, guarantees access to Government of

Ontario services in French in head offices and government agencies located in or serving one or

more of 26 designated areas of the province. Designated areas are those with a significant

Francophone population. The Office of Francophone Affairs considers a significant

Francophone population to be at least 10% of the local population or a population of over 5,000

Francophones.

In addition to offices of the Ontario government, services delivered by third parties on behalf of

a government agency must be provided in accordance with the FLS Act. Although

municipalities are excluded from the application of the Act for their own services, there is a

transfer of responsibility regarding FLS when they deliver services “on behalf of” the Ontario

government to designated areas. CMSM/DSSAB agreements with Ontario require them to have

the capacity to provide services in French to Francophone parents applying for fee subsidy in

designated areas. They must also have capacity to provide services in French to Francophone

organizations with agreements for fee subsidy and/or operating funding and ensure that special

needs resourcing services are available in French to Francophone organizations, as well as

Francophone parents/guardians and their children. Where a CMSM/DSSAB does not have full

capacity to provide services in French, they must submit a plan to build capacity.

Page 52: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

42

Child care operators, as independent organizations, are not subject to the FLS Act. They may

offer services wholly or partially in French at their discretion, regardless of whether they are

located in a designated area. Some may voluntarily seek to be designated as a public service

agency under the FLS Act as an expression of their commitment to providing services in French.

2.7 CHILD CARE FOR CHILDREN WITH SPECIAL NEEDS

The Ministry of Education provides funding for Special Needs Resourcing (SNR). SNR provides

staff, equipment, supplies or services to support inclusion of children with special needs in

licensed child care settings including home child care, camps and authorized recreation

programs at no additional cost to parents / guardians. CMSMs and DSSABs are required to

spend a minimum of 4.1% of their total child care allocation on SNR. In 2015, the average

percentage spent on special needs resourcing was 13.6%.

CMSMs and DSSABs are encouraged to collaborate in the planning and provision of services and

supports with SNR service providers, licensees, parents/guardians, schools/school board

personnel, and other professionals and community service programs and agencies. CMSMs and

DSSABs are encouraged to maintain strong partnerships with relevant community organizations

to facilitate smooth transitions and referrals, including special needs coordinating agencies and

local steering committees related to coordinated service planning and the integrated delivery of

rehabilitation services, key initiatives under Ontario’s Special Needs Strategy.

The CCEYA sets out the following definition for a child with special needs: a child whose

cognitive, physical, social, emotional or communicative needs, or whose needs relating to

overall development, are of such a nature that additional supports are required for the child.

What is now called the Special Needs Resourcing (SNR) program was established in the late

1970s by the Ministry of Community and Social Services to support children with special needs

in licensed child care at no additional cost to parents/guardians. At the inception of SNR,

children were in segregated programs. In the early 1990’s, the province moved towards an

inclusion model where children with and without special needs attended the same program.

When child care was transferred to the Ministry of Education beginning in 2010, the funding

and operational policies associated with SNR (guided by the Day Nurseries Act (DNA) and the

Service Management Guidelines) transferred over from the Ministry of Children and Youth

Services (MCYS) as is. Since the transfer of SNR, the Ministry of Education has taken steps to

examine SNR and address urgent issues including research, stakeholder conversations,

development of a funding formula for child care, development of a draft SNR framework,

gathering of SNR service delivery information from CMSM/DSSABs, and revised regulations

under the CCEYA. Further work is underway as a part of the renewed approach to supporting

inclusion under Ontario's’ Renewed Early Years and Child Care Policy Framework.

Page 53: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

43

Services and supports purchased through SNR funding are for children with special needs 12

years of age or under. SNR funding is intended to:

1. Hire or acquire the services of a resource teacher/consultant or supplemental staff

where necessary (including salary and benefits) to support the inclusion of children with

special needs;

2. Provide training for staff in regulated child care settings working with children with

special needs to support inclusion; and

3. Purchase or lease specialized/adaptive equipment and supplies to support children with

special needs.

Ontario EarlyON Centres (EOs) provide important special needs resources. These EarlyON Child

and Family Centres (previously known as Ontario Early Years Child and Family Centres) are a

place for parents and caregivers to seek information and advice about the children in their

care. All EarlyON Centres are welcoming and accessible to children of varying abilities, and

opportunities for early identification, screening and surveillance must be made available as

required and/or requested. EarlyON Centres provide parents and caregivers with current

information about available community programs and specialized services to ensure that

children have access to the supports they need.

Beginning January 1, 2018, CMSMs and DSSABs may use EarlyON Child and Family Centre

funding to hire or acquire the services of a special needs resource consultant to support the

delivery of core services to children with special needs and their families/caregivers, specifically

making connections for families to specialized services (e.g., screening, early intervention,

resources and supports).

Resource teachers/consultants typically provide a wide range of services and supports for

children with special needs and their families. They may support several children in multiple

locations and can also provide professional learning experiences for individuals working with

children with special needs in licensed child care settings and approved recreation programs.

These supports may include providing child care staff with program adaptation strategies and

professional development, supporting the development of individualized support plans (per O.

Reg. 137/15 – section 52), conducting developmental screens, providing referrals to community

agencies, providing information and resources for parents and obtaining specialized equipment

as required.

A resource teacher should be a member in good standing of the College of Early Childhood

Educators and have completed a post-secondary program of studies that is both theoretical and

practical and that relates to the needs of children with special needs. Every licensee shall

ensure that every resource teacher has a valid certification in standard first aid, including infant

Page 54: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

44

and child CPR, issued by a training agency recognized by the Workplace Safety and Insurance

Board or otherwise approved by a director.

Under Ontario Regulation 137/15 (section 52), every holder of a license to operate a child care

centre or to be an agency co-ordinating home child providers shall ensure that an up-to-date

individualized support plan is in place for each child with special needs, and that the plan

includes:

A description of how the child care centre or the home child care provider will

support the child to function and participate in a meaningful and purposeful manner

A description of any supports or aids, or adaptations or other modifications to the

physical, social and learning environment

Instructions relating to the child’s use of the supports or aids

The plan must be developed in consultation with a parent of the child, the child (if appropriate

for the child’s age) and any regulated health professional or other person who works with the

child in a capacity that would allow the person to help inform the plan.

2.8 CHILD CARE CENTRE SERVICES

As of March 31, 2017, there were 5,351 child care centres licensed to provide child care

services in Ontario. About 36% of centres are located in either Toronto or the West Toronto

region (including Halton and Peel). The Central (including York and Durham) and Southwest

regions each have about 22% of all centres in the province. About 12% of all centres are in the

East region, just over 6% are in Northern Ontario. There are 76 centres (about 1.5% of all

centres) located on First Nations reserves and managed by the First Nations.

Page 55: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

45

Table 4 Licensed Child Care Centres Serving All Ages of Children,

by Region or First Nations, Ontario 2017

Region or First Nations Number of Child Care Centres Percent of All Centres

Toronto 1,010 18.9%

West Toronto 912 17.0%

Central 1,195 22.3%

Southwest 1,180 22.1%

East 641 12.0%

North 337 6.3%

First Nations 76 1.4%

Total 5,351 100.0%

Source: Ministry of Education

The same basic distribution by region appears if we consider child care spaces rather than

centres. About 38% of centre spaces are in Toronto or West Toronto. Another 45% are in the

Central and the Southwest region. About 12% of spaces are in the East and about 5% in the

North. There are over 406,000 licensed child care centre spaces across Ontario.

Page 56: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

46

Table 5 Number of Licensed Centre Spaces for All Ages of Children,

by Region or First Nations, Ontario 2017

Region or First Nations Number of Child Care Spaces – Licensed Capacity

Percent of All Spaces

Toronto 79,727 19.6%

West Toronto 74,873 18.4%

Central 101,470 25.0%

Southwest 79,816 19.6%

East 47,815 11.8%

North 19,519 4.8%

First Nations 3,175 0.8%

Total 406,395 100.0%

Source: Ministry of Education.

Note that licensed capacity is not identical to enrollment. See Table 16 for centre enrollment figures.

Page 57: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

47

Table 6 Number and Percent of Licensed Centre Spaces for Children 0-4 Years,

by Region or First Nations, Ontario 2017

Region or First Nations Number of Child Care Centre Spaces – Licensed Capacity

Percent of All Spaces

Toronto 39,870 24.8%

West Toronto 25,012 15.5%

Central 35,989 22.3%

Southwest 30,120 18.7%

East 19,134 11.9%

North 8,391 5.2%

First Nations 2,570 1.6%

Total 161,086 100.0%

Source: Ministry of Education

Note: 0-4 Years means spaces for children in Infant, Toddler or Preschool child care and not yet in Kindergarten before-and-

after school child care.

Page 58: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

48

Table 7

Number of Licensed Centre Spaces by Age Category and by Region or First Nations, Ontario

2017

Source: Ministry of Education

Centres do not necessarily serve all age categories. Table 8 shows a breakdown of centres in

Ontario by which age categories of children 0-4 are served. This table does not consider ages

other than 0-4 years. In other words, a centre might serve only preschoolers and kindergarten

children; it would be listed in this table as only serving preschool children, because we ignore

services other than infant, toddler and preschool. The table tells us whether centres that serve

one of these ages also serve the others or not.

There are very few centres that serve infants only, or toddlers only, or infants and toddlers only

or infants and preschoolers only (in total this is less than 2% of all centres). Presumably, this

happens partly because the cost of providing infant and toddler care is high and centres who

specialize in these age groups are likely to face a cost/price squeeze. Further, the demand for

infant and toddler care is likely to be thinner than the demand for preschool-aged care, partly

because of the high fees.

As a result, most centres that provide any care for children 0-4 include the provision of care for

children of preschool age (i.e., 30 months to kindergarten age). 17.5% of all centres in the

province provide preschool care only; another 25.7% provide toddler and preschool care and

20.6% provide care for infants, toddlers and preschoolers. Over 34% of all centres provide no

care for children 0-4 years at all.

Region or First Nations

Infant Spaces Toddler Spaces

Preschool Spaces

Kindergarten B/A Spaces

School Age B/A Spaces

Total Spaces

Toronto 3,554 10,003 26,313 16,664 23,193 79,727

West Toronto 1,722 7,030 16,260 19,168 30,693 74,873

Central 2,281 9,230 24,478 23,019 42,462 101,470

Southwest 2,375 8,180 19,565 18,429 31,267 79,816

East 1,237 5,323 12,574 10,896 17,785 47,815

North 772 2,407 5,212 3,667 7,461 19,519

First Nations 290 727 1,553 192 413 3,175

Total 12,231 42,900 105,955 92,035 153,274 406,395

Page 59: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

49

Table 8

Number and Percent of Licensed Centres by Age Categories Served, Considering Only Spaces

for Children 0-4 Years, Ontario 2017

Age Categories Served by Centre Number of Centres Percent of All Centres

Infants only 9 0.2%

Toddlers only 22 0.4%

Preschool only 934 17.5%

Infants and Toddlers only 44 0.8%

Infants and Preschoolers only 22 0.4%

Toddlers and Preschoolers only 1,377 25.7%

Infants, Toddlers and Preschoolers 1,104 20.6%

No Spaces for Children 0-4 Years 1,839 34.4%

Total 5,351 100.0%

Note: This table refers only to spaces for 0-4-year-old children. In other words, a centre with infants only could also have

kindergarten or school aged children, but we do not record this.

Current Ontario regulations stipulate minimum staff-child ratios, minimum proportions of

qualified staff, and maximum group sizes that apply to different age categories for centre care.

For instance, minimum staff-child ratios are 3:10 for infants, 1:5 for toddlers, and 1:8 for

children of pre-school age. Minimums for qualified staff are that one out of three must be

qualified in infant rooms, one out of three in toddler rooms, and two out of three in pre-school

rooms. Qualified staff must have a two-year ECE diploma from community college and be a

registered member of the professional body (the College of Early Childhood Educators).

Maximum group sizes are 10 for infants, 15 for toddlers, and 24 for pre-schoolers.

Page 60: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

50

2.9 AUSPICE – FOR-PROFIT AND NOT-FOR-PROFIT CENTRE

CARE

Most child care centres in Ontario are not-for-profit – nearly 76% of all centres. This

percentage is slightly lower in Toronto, West Toronto and the Central region, where not-for-

profits make up about 70% of all centres2. In other regions, this percentage is 80% and above.

Beginning in 2017, a For-Profit- Maximum Percentage Threshold has been added to the Budget

Schedule of the Service Agreement between the Ministry and the CMSM/DSSABs. The

expansion of funding for for-profit centres will be limited over time.

Table 9

Number and Percentage of Licensed Child Care Centres by Auspice, by Region or First Nations,

Ont

ari

o

201

7

Sour

ce:

Mini

stry

of

Educ

ation

2.10 CHILD CARE FEES

Fees for licensed child care are not uniform across the province and are not uniform even

within regions or municipalities. The fee data shown below is based on the Child Care

Operators’ Survey of 2017. Not every centre serves every age category of children, and not

every centre responded to the survey. There is not enough data on fees from First Nations on-

2 The data source from which these figures come does not identify municipally-operated centres separately from other not-for-

profits. Friendly et al. (2015) indicate that their best estimate of the number of publicly-operated centre spaces in 2014 is

5,389.

Region or First Nations Number of For-Profit Centres

Number of Not-for-Profit Centres

Percent of Centres in Region or First Nations that are Not-For-Profit

Toronto 301 709 70.2%

West Toronto 300 612 67.1%

Central 371 824 69.0%

Southwest 169 1,011 85.7%

East 131 510 79.6%

North 25 312 92.6%

First Nations 1 75 98.7%

Total 1,298 4,053 75.7%

Page 61: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

51

reserve centres to publish results for First Nations centres, but response rates are good in other

areas.

Table 10 below shows the median full fee for infants, toddlers and preschoolers in each region.

Kindergarten and school age fees refer to before-and-after school child care. In Table 10, for

Toronto, we can observe that the median infant fee is $85.00 per day (or $425 per week, or

over $22,000 per year). Full-day infant fees are substantially lower in other regions. Median

infant fees outside Toronto range from $51.00 per day in the North to $66.95 in the West

Toronto region. In other words, median weekly fees for infants outside Toronto range from

$255 per week to nearly $335 per week. And, median annual full-time fees for infants range

from just over $13,300 in the North to nearly $17,500 in West Toronto.

Page 62: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

52

Table 10

Median Daily Fees for Full-Day Infant, Toddler and Preschool Centre-Based Child Care and

Before-and-After School Care for Kindergarten and School Age Children, by Region, Ontario

2017

Infants Toddlers Preschool Kindergarten School Age*

Toronto $85.00 $66.00 $52.00 $31.00 $26.00

West Toronto $66.95 $52.55 $46.25 $24.44 $23.10

Central $57.50 $48.86 $42.84 $23.50 $21.00

Southwest $55.45 $48.40 $42.00 $20.00 $19.20

East $61.00 $51.00 $43.34 $20.00 $19.42

North $51.00 $42.00 $38.00 $17.75 $18.00

Source: Ministry of Education

Note: There were too few responses to provide reliable average fees on First Nations reserves

* Children 6-9 years of age.

For each age category, Toronto fees are the highest, although the gap is greatest for infant care.

For instance, with toddler care, the median Toronto fee is $66.00 per day or $330 per week or

about $17,200 per year. Median fees for toddler care elsewhere in the province range from

$42 to $53 per day, or $210 to $265 per week or just over $10,900 to nearly $13,800 per year.

For preschool age children, not yet in kindergarten, Toronto’s median daily fee is $52.00 per

day (or $260 per week, or just over $13,500 per year). The range across the rest of the province

is from $38.00 per day to $46.25 per day (or from $190 per week to just over $230 per week, or

from about $9,900 per annum to about $12,000 per annum).

Our main concern is with children younger than kindergarten age, but other child care fees are

relevant for the family’s ability to afford licensed child care. Table 10 shows medians for

kindergarten and school age fees by region. In each case, the fee is for before and after school

care.

The median 200-day fee for before and after kindergarten care is $6,200 in Toronto and

between $3,550 and about $4,888 in the rest of the province. On a daily basis, that is just over

$30 per day in Toronto and between $17 and about $25 in the rest of the province.

Page 63: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

53

Before and after school child care for school age children 6-9 years of age is a bit less expensive.

As Table 10 shows, across the province, the median fee ranges from $18 to $26 per day (or $90

to $130 per week, or $3,600 to $5,200 per 200-day year.

2.11 SUBSIDIES

Subsidies provide substantial financial assistance for the costs of child care to tens of thousands

of children in Ontario. The tables below indicate the total number of subsidies that are being

used in licensed child care centres, by age category. The data is valid as of March 30, 2017.

There may be slight undercounting because the data is provided by survey, with approximately

95% of centres responding to the survey. These totals do not include subsidies that are used to

access licensed home child care.

Table 11 shows that, as of March 30, 2017, there were nearly 111,600 children receiving

subsidies for licensed centre-based child care in Ontario. Of these, 44,253 were children

younger than kindergarten age (0-4).

Page 64: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

54

Table 11

Total Number of Subsidized Children in Centres, All Ages and Children 0-4,

By Region and First Nations, Ontario 2017

Source: Ministry of Education

Table 12 shows the breakdown of subsidies in centres by the age category of children. There

are about 4,060 subsidies for children less than 18 months of age in centres across the

province. There are nearly three times that number of subsidies for children between 18 and

30 months of age (12,061). And there are more than twice that number (28,132) of subsidies

for children of preschool age. There are approximately 24,700 subsidies for kindergarten age

children and over 42,600 subsidies for school age children.

Region or First Nations Child Care Subsidies for Children 0-12 Years

Child Care Subsidies for Children 0-4 Years

Toronto 35,583 13,988

West Toronto 17,029 5,940

Central 18,545 6,244

Southwest 21,664 9,565

East 10,686 4,496

North 6,335 2,832

First Nations 1,727 1,188

Total 111,569 44,253

Page 65: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

55

Table 12

Total Number of Subsidized Children in Centres by Age Category, By Region or First Nations

Ontario 2017

Region or First Nations

Infants Toddlers Preschoolers Kindergarten B/A School

School Age B/A School

Total Subsidized

Children

Toronto 1,715 3,786 8,487 9,098 12,497 35,583

West Toronto 476 1,682 3,782 3,390 7,699 17,029

Central 423 1,594 4,227 4,348 7,953 18,545

Southwest 792 2,625 6,148 4,087 8,012 21,664

East 307 1,262 2,927 2,157 4,033 10,686

North 244 765 1,823 1,337 2,166 6,335

First Nations 103 347 738 267 272 1,727

Total 4,060 12,061 28,132 24,684 42,632 111,569

Source: Ministry of Education

We find that the percentage of children in centres that is subsidized varies substantially across

age categories, as shown in Table 13. In Toronto, for instance, about 45%-46% of children in

centres are subsidized, but that varies from 59% of infants to 40% of preschool-aged children.

Across the province about 30% of all children in child care centres are currently receiving

subsidy, but about 40% of all infants in centre care receive subsidy.

Page 66: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

56

Table 13

Percentage of Children in Centres who are Subsidized, by Age Category,

By Region or First Nations, Ontario 2017

Source: Ministry of Education

Table 14 summarizes data on the receipt of subsidy by age category of children. The two

columns show the percent of all centre-based children 0-12 who are receiving subsidy, and the

percent of all children in centres 0-4 years of age who are receiving subsidy. Overall, according

to this data on subsidies, about 30% of children of all ages in licensed centre-based child care

have their fee lowered by the receipt of subsidy. Subsidies affect the fees of about 33% of all

children younger than kindergarten age (0-4 years) using centre care.

Region or First Nations

Infants Toddlers Preschoolers Kindergarten B/A School

School Age B/A School

Total Subsidized

Children

Toronto 59.1% 47.3% 40.3% 48.8% 45.4% 45.5%

West Toronto 32.8% 29.3% 27.0% 25.7% 26.8% 27.0%

Central 23.4% 21.4% 21.2% 20.3% 21.1% 21.0%

Southwest 35.5% 33.7% 31.8% 23.9% 25.4% 27.8%

East 31.6% 30.9% 28.0% 23.0% 22.3% 24.9%

North 42.1% 39.5% 37.4% 33.6% 32.1% 34.9%

First Nations 68.7% 84.8% 86.8% 93.0% 93.5% 86.9%

Total 40.2% 34.1% 31.1% 29.4% 28.3% 30.1%

Page 67: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

57

Table 14

Percentage of Children Subsidized in Child Care Centres, All Ages and Children 0-4,

By Region and First Nations, Ontario 2017

Source: Ministry of Education

Of course, child care subsidies are only part of the story. There are many more children using

licensed child care without subsidy than those children with subsidy. Table 15 shows the

number of children in each region or on First Nations reserves who are using licensed centre-

based child care and are not receiving a child care subsidy. There are nearly 260,000 children

paying full fees across the province. The largest number of these are using school age care,

followed by children of preschool and kindergarten ages.

% of children subsidized 0-12 years (centre care only)

% of Children Subsidized 0-4 Years of Age (Centre Care Only)

Toronto 43.7% 45.5%

West Toronto 28.0% 27.0%

Central 21.4% 21.0%

Southwest 32.6% 27.8%

East 29.0% 24.9%

North 38.3% 34.9%

First Nations 84.3% 86.9%

Total 30.1% 32.5%

Page 68: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

58

Table 15

Total Number of Unsubsidized Children in Centres by Age Category,

By Region, Ontario 2017

Source: Ministry of Education

Finally, we tabulate the number of children in each age category and by region or First Nations

reserve who are using licensed child care in 2017. This is shown in Table 16. In total in March,

2017, there were over 370,500 using licensed centre-based child care, with about 150,000 of

them being school age children. About 175,000 more use preschool or kindergarten-aged

centre-based child care. The remainder are in infant and toddler child care.

Region or First Nations

Infants Toddlers Preschoolers Kindergarten B/A School

School Age B/A School

Total Children

Toronto 1,185 4,214 12,593 9,563 15,013 42,568

West Toronto 976 4,053 10,240 9,776 21,051 46,096

Central 1,387 5,859 15,711 17,077 29,704 69,738

Southwest 1,436 5,158 13,209 12,991 23,496 56,290

East 665 2,819 7,541 7,203 14,015 32,243

North 336 1,170 3,047 2,648 4,590 11,791

First Nations 47 62 112 20 19 260

Total Children 6,032 23,335 62,453 59,278 107,888 258,986

Page 69: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

59

Table 16

Total Number of Children (Both Subsidized and Unsubsidized) in Centres

by Age Category, by Region or First Nations, Ontario 2017

Source: Ministry of Education

2.12 ONTARIO’S LICENSED HOME CHILD CARE SERVICES – IN

NUMBERS

According to the 2017 Child Care Operators’ Survey, there are 124 agencies licensed to co-

ordinate, organize and monitor the provision of home care in Ontario. The 124 agencies are

distributed across the province, as Table 17 shows.

Region or First Nations

Infants Toddlers Preschoolers Kindergarten B/A School

School Age B/A School

Total Children

Toronto 2,900 8,000 21,080 18,661 27,510 78,151

West Toronto 1,452 5,735 14,022 13,166 28,750 63,125

Central 1,810 7,453 19,938 21,425 37,657 88,283

Southwest 2,228 7,783 19,357 17,078 31,508 77,954

East 972 4,081 10,468 9,360 18,048 42,929

North 580 1,935 4,870 3,985 6,756 18,126

First Nations 150 409 850 287 291 1,987

Total Children 10,092 35,396 90,585 83,962 150,520 370,555

Page 70: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

60

Table 17

Distribution of Home Child Care Agencies by Region or First Nations, 2017

Source: Ministry of Education

Again, according to licensing data, there are 7,579 homes organized by those 124 agencies,

each one capable of providing care for up to six children at a time. However, the number of

homes actually active as of March 31, 2017 (as reported by the agencies) was a much smaller

number – 3,765 homes.

Table 18 shows the total number of approved homes and the actual number operating in each

of Ontario’s regions.

Region or First Nations Number of Home Child Care Agencies

% of Home Child Care Agencies

Toronto 19 15.3%

West Toronto 15 12.1%

Central 24 19.4%

Southwest 23 18.6%

East 30 24.2%

North 11 8.9%

First Nations 2 1.6%

Total 124 100.0%

Page 71: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

61

Table 18

Number of Approved Homes and Active Homes Operating by Region or First Nations, 2017

Approved Homes Active Homes Average Active Homes/Agency

Toronto 1,599 926 51.4%

West Toronto 745 396 26.4%

Central 958 407 18.5%

Southwest 1,588 883 40.1%

East 2,324 1,002 35.8%

North 334 145 13.2%

First Nations 31 6 3.0%

TOTAL 7,579 3,765 30.4%

Source: Ministry of Education

In most regions, the typical (i.e., median) size of an agency is between 25 and 50 homes.

Toronto is an exception with the typical size being 70 homes.

However, there are some agencies that are much larger, licensed for many more homes. This

pulls the average size up; as a result, the average size of an agency varies across regions from

30 homes to 84 homes. In Toronto, there are seven agencies licensed to have 100 homes or

more. There is one such agency in West Toronto, one in the Central Region, and three in the

Southwest region. There are seven of these large home child care agencies in the Eastern

Region and none in the North or on First Nations reserves. About 15% of all licensed home

agencies are licensed for 100 homes or more. However, it is also true that most agencies

actually co-ordinate services through fewer homes than they are licensed for. Eight home

agencies across the province currently have more than one hundred active homes.

The typical (i.e., median) size of agencies measured by the number of active homes is between

11 and 26 across the different regions in Ontario.

Page 72: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

62

Most of the agencies are not-for-profit3 agencies. Only 15 agencies across the province, or just

over 12% are for-profit agencies. Further, only about 7% of approved homes and 5% of the

homes actually operating are part of for-profit agencies. This varies across regions. About 40%

of agencies in the West Toronto Region are for-profit and about 17% of agencies in the Central

Region

Agencies have reported on how many of their homes provide care for infants, toddlers,

preschoolers, kindergarten-age children and school age children. This data is summarized by

region in the table below.

Table 19

Number of Children Using Home Child Care in

Different Age Categories by Region or First Nations, 2017

Infants Toddlers Pre-

Schoolers Kindergarteners

School Age

Children 0-4 Years

All ages

Toronto 451 521 761 1,617 991 1,733 4,341

West Toronto 345 226 297 255 347 868 1,470

Central 237 491 584 360 378 1,312 2,050

Southwest 464 566 956 797 568 1,986 3,351

East 505 675 1,080 735 843 2,260 3,838

North 90 200 224 182 147 514 843

FN 2 8 7 5 8 17 30

Total 2,094 2,687 3,909 3,951 3,282 8,690 15,923

Source Ministry of Education

Regulations for Home Child Care require qualifications (i.e., RECE) for home visitors, who must

visit each home at least 4 times per year. However, individual home child care providers have

no requirement for qualifications in early childhood education. The maximum number of

children that can be cared for in a home is 6 children under 13 years of age (including the care-

giver’s children not yet attending full-day kindergarten or grade school). In general, there

cannot be more than two of those children who are less than two years of age.

3 Directly operated agencies are included in not-for-profit.

Page 73: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

63

2.13 SUBSIDIES IN HOME CHILD CARE

The total number of subsidies in family home care in Ontario in 2017 was 11,928. There were

3,995 children using home care without subsidy; in total (in March 2017) 15,923 children were

in home child care.

Of the total subsidies, 5,545 were held by children younger than kindergarten age. Over 1,100

were infants, about 1,700 were toddlers and 2,692 were of preschool age.

Table 20

Total Subsidies in Home Care for Infants, Toddlers, Preschoolers, Kindergarten Children, and

School Age Children, by Region, March 2017

Source: Ministry of Education

Infant Subsidies

Toddler Subsidies

Preschool Subsidies

Kindergarten Subsidies

School Age Subsidies

Total Subsidies 0-4

Total Subsidies 0-12

Toronto 273 368 589 1,516 963 1,230 3,709

West Toronto 183 139 180 222 311 502 1,035

Central 89 289 356 276 313 734 1,323

Southwest 292 378 722 663 538 1,392 2,593

East 247 407 710 558 767 1,364 2,689

North 57 130 128 147 98 315 560

FN 0 1 7 5 6 8 19

Total 1,141 1,712 2,692 3,387 2,996 5,545 11,928

Page 74: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

64

Table 21

Total Children in Home Care without Subsidy, by Age Category and by Region, March 2017

Source: Ministry of Education

2.14 FEES BY REGION AND AGE CATEGORY IN HOME CHILD

CARE

Fees in regulated home child care appear to be considerably lower than in centre-based care,

particularly for infant care. As Table 20 shows, the median daily fee for full-time care in a home

for an infant is just over $50 in Toronto and the median fee is between $41 and $44 per day in

other regions. That amounts to about $13,500 for a full year of infant care in Toronto and less

than $11,500 outside Toronto. Of course, educational and training requirements as well as

staff-child ratios are very different in home child care and centre care.

Infants - No

Subsidy

Toddlers – No

Subsidy

Preschoolers – No

Subsidy

Kindergarten – No Subsidy

School Age – No Subsidy

Children

0-4 – No Subsidy

Children

0-12 – No Subsidy

Toronto 178 153 172 101 28 503 632

West Toronto

162 87 117 33 36 366 435

Central 148 202 228 84 65 578 727

Southwest 172 188 234 134 30 594 758

East 258 268 370 177 76 896 1,149

North 33 70 96 35 49 199 283

FN 2 7 0 0 2 9 11

Total 953 975 1,217 564 286 3,145 3,995

Page 75: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

65

Table 22

Median Daily Fees in Child Care Homes for Full-Day Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care

and Before-and-After School Care for Kindergarten and School Age Children, by Region,

Ontario 2017

Infants Toddlers Preschool Kindergarten School Age*

Toronto $51.80 $51.80 $42.33 $31.38 $34.40

West Toronto $44.00 $43.00 $42.00 $30.00 $27.28

Central $42.00 $41.00 $38.00 $26.00 $36.25

Southwest $43.00 $42.58 $40.00 $23.30 $30.00

East $44.50 $43.10 $42.79 $21.30 $22.20

North $41.00 $37.00 $35.53 $17.00 $30.00

Source: Ministry of Education

* Children 6-9 years of age.

Table 22 shows that the median fee in a child care home for toddlers is very nearly the same as

for infant care, either in Toronto or in other regions.

The median fee for full-time home child care for preschool aged children (between 30 months

and kindergarten eligibility) is lower. The median fee in Toronto is a little over $42, or about

$11,000 on an annual basis. In other regions, the median fee is between $35 per day and $43

per day, or between about $9,100 and $11,300 annually.

Before and after school care in home child care for kindergarten-aged children costs just over

$31 per day at the median in Toronto (about $6,300 for the school year). In other regions, the

median kindergarten before and after school fee for home care is between $17 a day ($3,400

for the school year) and $30 a day ($6,000 for the school year).

The median fees are broadly similar for before and after school home child care for children

aged 6-9 years, varying from $22 to $36 by region. On a school year basis, that is $4,400 to

$7,200 per year.

2.15 CENTRE AND HOME ENROLLMENT BY MUNICIPALITY

Reporting by region obscures details at the municipal level. It is useful to tabulate the total

number of children currently (i.e., March 31, 2017) in centres or home child care in each of the

47 CMSM/DSSABs in Ontario. Table 23 does so.

Page 76: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

66

Table 23

Children 0-4 Years of Age in Child Care Centres and Home Care by Municipality, 2017

Region Municipality Children 0-4 years in Centres

Children 0-4 years in Homes

Toronto Toronto 39,870 1,733

West Toronto

Dufferin 603 22

Halton 9,474 126

Peel 13,047 677

Wellington 1,888 43

Total 25,012 868

Central

Bruce 556 134

Durham 7,875 519

Grey 791 190

Kawartha Lakes 518

Muskoka 359 30

Northumberland 628 28

Peterborough 1,245 172

Simcoe 3,982 273

York 20,035 290

Total 35,989 1,636

Southwest

Brantford 1,244 152

Chatham-Kent 1,172

Hamilton 5,931 283

Huron 483 36

Lambton 1,131 40

London 5,034 255

Niagara 4,066 193

Norfolk 588 51

Oxford 635 28

St. Thomas 711 37

Page 77: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

67

Stratford 502 15

Waterloo 4,402 775

Windsor 4,221 121

Total 30,120 1,986

East

Cornwall 774 36

Hastings 1,113 103

Kingston 1,835 40

Lanark 526 30

Leeds and Grenville 741 45

Lennox and Addington 282 42

Ottawa 12,268 1,822

Prescott and Russell 885 107

Renfrew 710 35

Total 19,134 2,260

North

Algoma 456

Cochrane 969 71

Greater Sudbury 2,260 44

Kenora 548

Manitoulin – Sudbury 278 11

Nipissing 1,098 117

Parry Sound 190 73

Rainy River 199

Sault Ste. Marie 854 79

Thunder Bay 1,151 39

Timiskaming 388 80

Total 8,391 514

GRAND TOTAL 158,516 8,997

Note: In addition, there are 2,570 children 0-4 years of age in centres on First Nations Reserves and 17 children in home child

care on reserve.

Page 78: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

68

2.16 CHILD POPULATION

If we take the number of 0-4 year-old children across Ontario (that is the number of children

less than five years of age), they are divided by regions approximately as shown below in 2017.

Taking the data on licensed spaces and children in centres and homes, we can calculate the

percent of young children in each region and in total that can be served in licensed care. On

average, 23% of infants, toddlers and preschoolers can be served in licensed child care.

Toronto and Central regions have capacity to serve more than this percent, other regions less.

Table 24

Number of Children and Child Care Spaces 0-4 Years of Age

in each Region, Ontario 2017

Source: Ontario Population Projections Update 2015-2041, Ontario Ministry of Finance (2016), calculations by authors; and

space data provided by Ministry of Education.

Note: In the population figures, the number of children 0-4 means the number of children younger than their fifth birthday.

The number of child care spaces 0-4 means the number of spaces available for children not yet in kindergarten. Some children

enter kindergarten as early as three years, eight months. Others do not enter kindergarten until four years, seven months.

*This is the sum of licensed capacity in centres and enrollment in active homes as of March 31, 2017

The figures in the table are from a population projection from the Ontario Ministry of Finance

(2016). Since then, some data on population has become available from the 2016 Census,

collected by Statistics Canada. The count of 0-4 children in Ontario from the Census is lower

than the Ministry of Finance projection at 695,875 (or 139,175 on average in every birth year

cohort). 582,240 of these children are in two parent families and 107,090 are in single parent

families (there are a few in "other" families).

Regions Number of Children 0-4 Years of Age

Number of Licensed Spaces for Infants,

Toddlers and Preschoolers*

Number of Spaces for Infants, Toddlers and Preschoolers as a % of

Number of Children 0-4 in Each Region

Toronto 153,329 41,603 27.1%

West Toronto 134,316 25,880 19.3%

Central 146,622 37,301 25.7%

Southwest 171,634 32,106 18.7%

East 93,312 21,394 22.9%

North 39,676 8,905 22.4%

Total 738,889 169,776 23.0%

Page 79: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

69

We need to ask whether the number of children between birth and age four inclusive is truly

the population group we are interested in. If our purpose is to determine the number of

children who are potential users of infant, toddler and preschool child care in Ontario, there are

some important caveats.

Children do not typically move beyond the age for preschool child care precisely at the moment

they cease being four years of age. Some children enter Junior Kindergarten at 3 years, eight

months old. Others enter Junior Kindergarten at up to 4 years, seven months of age. All

children become eligible to enter JK in September of the calendar year in which their fourth

birthday occurs.

Because children enter Junior Kindergarten at only one point in the year, the size of our

population base of interest (i.e., the number of children in Ontario not yet eligible for Junior

Kindergarten) varies over the year. On September 1st, all children who already are 4 years of

age or will be 4 years of age by December 31st will enter Junior Kindergarten. That is one year’s

worth of children – nearly 140,000 children in 2017 in Ontario. This means that on September

1st, all children who are less than 3 years 8 months of age, will still be eligible for child care for

infants, toddlers or preschoolers. That would be about 510,300 children.

Anyone older than that is eligible for kindergarten and therefore generally does not stay in

preschool child care (there are some exceptions). Each month of the next twelve months,

nearly 11,600 children would be born and soon could potentially enter licensed child care. By

the time of the next August 31st, that would amount to nearly 140,000 additional children.

Therefore, the total of children eligible for pre-kindergarten child care would, by the next

August 31st, mount up to nearly 649,500 children.

In essence, over the course of the year and in any month, there would be about 209,000

children eligible for infant care (although many would be cared for by parents on

maternity/parental leave4). In every month, there would be nearly 140,000 children eligible for

toddler care. However, the number of children eligible to be in preschool child care classrooms

(i.e., from 30 months of age till JK eligibility) would vary over the year from a minimum of about

162,400 in September to about 301,500 by the next August.

4 CANSIM data from August 2017 shows that in every month of the last year, from 80,000-82,000 parents in Ontario have been

receiving EI Benefits for maternity or parental leave. Others will take unpaid maternity or parental leave.

Page 80: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

70

Note however, that the detail involved in this section is not completely reflected in the

common terminology used in the child care sector. When people are referring to children who

are younger than kindergarten age who are potential users of infant, toddler and preschool

child care, they are typically called children 0-4 years of age. The terminology is not exact but it

is convenient. We will often use it. It is more precise to refer to “children younger than

kindergarten age” and sometimes we will use this terminology.

Page 81: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

71

CHAPTER 3: The Municipal Role in Managing The Child Care

System

Chapter Summary

Municipalities are central to the administration of funding, planning, and development

of licensed child care services in Ontario. There are 47 Service System Managers –

Consolidated Municipal Service Managers (CMSMs) and District Social Service

Administration Boards (DSSABs) – who carry these responsibilities. We have conducted

lengthy interviews with representatives of 44 out of these 47 municipalities.

This chapter describes experiences, experiments, ideas and concerns of these

municipalities. It summarizes information about centre-based care, home child care,

accessibility, quality, administration of the subsidy system, auspice of operators,

relationships between municipalities and school boards, expansion plans, problems

associated with expansion, and municipal opinions about solutions to affordability

problems.

Municipal representatives told us that the prime challenges to the viability and stability

of centres are wages, staff recruitment and retention. The expansion of full-day

kindergarten has attracted many qualified child care staff; wages, benefits, and working

conditions are generally better than in child care centres. This has made recruitment

and retention issues in the child care sector more acute. Too many staff positions are

filled currently with “Director’s Approvals”, meaning staff that do not have all of the

regulated training or experience requirements.

The Wage Enhancement Grant is recognized as a major step forward in this context,

providing a wage boost of $2 per hour to many staff. Many CMSM/DSSABs would like to

see a standardized salary scale (perhaps with regional variation), with provincial funding

to support it. Municipalities had many suggestions to reduce the difficulties of

recruitment.

Across Ontario, home child care is 4%-6% of all licensed care. Municipalities are pleased

with a recent supplement of $20 per day to home providers, however, there are still

serious challenges in the recruitment of adequate numbers of home providers. New

regulations under the Child Care and Early Years Act 2014 have increased costs of

provision and paper work, affecting recruitment efforts. However, these regulatory

changes are expected to be important for quality enhancement. CMSM/DSSABs are

working hard with providers to overcome regulatory and financial barriers. Many

municipalities believe that to succeed, they are going to have to offer more funding to

Page 82: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

72

attract providers. Base funding is one proposed solution. Incentive funding for taking

infants, and for taking children evenings, overnights and on weekends will likely also be

needed.

Affordability is the main barrier to access. CMSM/DSSABs thought the Ministry’s

commitment to expansion of spaces was welcome and crucial, but expansion without

addressing affordability is a problem.

There are a number of accessibility issues identified by municipalities: rural access and

transportation, part-time opportunities, care for children with special needs, and care

during non-traditional hours such as evenings, weekends and overnight. A further issue

of accessibility is lack of parental awareness of child care subsidy funding; public

education about available funding is an important priority.

Currently 57 First Nations administer and operate child care and early years programs

on reserve. The Ministry provides funding to child care on reserve but, unlike off-

reserve, there is no financial eligibility test and all children receive a full subsidy. The

programs are, in effect, base-funded; individual First Nations may charge a nominal fee.

First Nations are awaiting the announcement of the Indigenous Early Learning and Child

Care Agreement for the allocation of funding dedicated to First Nations.

Journey Together funding on First Nations reserves is mainly being used to establish

new child and family centres. Accessibility of services that provide culturally-

appropriate programming for the off-reserve Indigenous population has been extremely

limited. The impetus for innovation and expansion of services off reserve has been

developed under the auspices of the Journey Together program. Many CMSM/DSSABs

with indigenous families both on and off reserve are working on expansion plans

through their Journey Together submissions in collaboration with their indigenous

partners in the community.

CMSM/DSSABs have grown into the role as caretakers of quality. Most of them have

hired quality assurance coordinators, are working in the community to improve quality

in their programs, introducing significantly more professional development

opportunities as well as mentoring programs. About half of all CMSM/DSSABs are using

a quality measurement tool.

Municipalities were almost unanimous in suggesting that the income test for child care

subsidy be made more generous; Many CMSM/DSSABs believe that $40,000 would be a

more realistic minimum as a turning point (i.e., income level below which the family

pays nothing). Others mentioned the need to engage in outreach to middle-income

families - to reduce the stigma associated with “subsidy” by changing the relationship

between social assistance and child care subsidy. Some CMSMs said they would be

Page 83: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

73

interested in receiving technology funding to develop their centralized waiting lists and

application processes.

Most CMSM/DSSABs support the provincial thresholds for for-profit funding but there

needs to be some recognition that this will be more difficult to implement in areas with

very high numbers of for-profit operators. Setting rates and establishing systems of

accountability are all important but are also areas where CMSM/DSSABs would

appreciate provincial direction.

The relationship between schools and municipalities in the child care sector has

improved substantially in recent years. However, some school boards need more

direction from Ministry on the importance of relationships with child care centres in

schools. Specific directives to principals, teachers and janitors would help to improve

the day-to-day experience for child care and EarlyON centres. School Board Early Years

Leads are a critical link between municipalities and the school system; in some cases

these Leads are not given sufficient time allocation to play this important role. The

Ministry should consider giving child care the same status in schools as grade school

education has so that child care programs would not have to pay rent or cost recovery.

The most persistent irritant between schools and municipalities concerns the “rental” or

“cost recovery” rate for space in schools. In too many cases, these charges are

prohibitively high, which violates the spirit of the Schools First directives. A consistent

policy that allows child care to flourish in schools should be adopted.

CMSM/DSSABs have embraced the challenge posed by the Ministry to work on

expansion and are putting considerable effort into achieving their targets, often with

limited staff, short timelines and absence of planning resources. The priorities to

increase accessibility, expand access to fee subsidy, and work on affordability are being

achieved by reducing the subsidy lists, and through expanding capacity through capital

expansion, Journey Together and collaboration with school boards. Other initiatives

include attempts to expand Home Child Care, access to non-traditional hours, rural

programs and infant programs. CMSM/DSSABs are assisting affordability by using

general operating grants to prevent fee increases but initiatives such as those of

Manitoulin-Sudbury DSSAB suggest possible future directions.

The major barrier to expansion in centres is the shortage of RECEs occasioned by low

wages and disinterest in the occupation by potential professionals because of those low

wages. Other key issues are the lack of guaranteed funding, inadequate capital funding

for expansion in the community by CMSM/DSSABs, the need for more realistic funding

timelines (it takes 2-3 years to build a child care centre), management of the for-profit

issue, more funding for administration, development and management of a new system

Page 84: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

74

including the need to examine new, more workable models. Other issues/barriers are

the need to develop a strategy to overcome barriers to rural expansion, the reluctance

of some operators to expand where need exists, and the overall need to make the goals

and importance of early childhood education clearer to all through robust public

education campaigns.

3.1 INTERVIEWS WITH MUNICIPALITIES

Municipalities are central to the administration of funding, planning and development of

licensed child care services in Ontario. Historically and, to some extent, currently,

municipalities have had an important role in funding child care services, as well. They are the

Service System Managers for child care.

The previous chapter has described child care services, funding and governance in Ontario in an

overall, aggregated, and frequently statistical way. That is only half the reality of child care in

Ontario.

There are 47 Consolidated Municipal Service Managers/District Social Service Administration

Boards (CMSM/DSSABs) in Ontario. These are the Service System Managers of the previous

paragraph; we will refer to them here as the municipalities. The other half of the reality of child

care in Ontario is what is happening at the municipal level – the variation in the challenges and

solutions across these municipalities.

In order to convey this other half, interviews were conducted by the study team with 44 of the

47 CMSM/DSSABs, a critical exercise in understanding the realities faced by the service system

managers on a day-to-day basis. Service system managers were universally enthusiastic about

the recent developments in the Ministry’s commitment to and funding of early childhood

education and care but also wanted to make us aware of the challenges.

This chapter summarizes some of the unity and diversity of child care across the province. It

will describe experiences, experiments, ideas and concerns reported to us by service system

managers. We have organized this information under the following topics: Centre-Based Care;

Home Child Care; Accessibility; Quality; Administration of the Subsidy System; Auspice of

Operators; Relationships with school boards; Expansion Plans; Problems Associated with

Expansion; and, Solutions to the Affordability Problem. Detailed background tables based on

municipal responses are available from Cleveland Consulting Inc.

3.2 CENTRE-BASED CARE

The majority of child care is offered through centre-based care (94%-96%). 76% of licensed

centre care is offered by non-profit organizations (this includes municipal directly-operated

Page 85: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

75

centres) and 24% for-profit companies (some of them being small owner-operated enterprises

and some being corporate chains). More recently a few school boards are directly operating

before-and-after school programs in the schools.

There are 15 CMSMs and DSSABs that have directly-operated (i.e., municipally-operated)

programs - Durham, Toronto, Niagara, Hamilton, Stratford, Dufferin, Halton, Hastings,

Peterborough, Cochrane, Kenora, Cornwall, Ottawa, Waterloo and Wellington. School boards

directly operate before-and-after school programs in Waterloo, Ottawa and some Francophone

Boards.

According to municipal representatives, viability, sustainability and stability are the three key

issues defining the challenges facing child care centres today. The viability and stability of child

care centres (and home child care providers) is a major concern for a majority of

CMSM/DSSABs. The number one problem in child care centres is attracting and retaining staff

in low-paying centres. The wages, for both qualified and unqualified staff, range from over $13

per hour to over $27, averaging about $17 per hour. Wages over $26 per hour are usually only

paid in unionized settings. There are few employee benefits (i.e., fringe benefits) available to

the majority of staff in child care centres that are not part of a larger agency or unionized or a

directly-operated centre.

The child care sector has been substantially affected by the expansion of full day kindergarten

(FDK) and the hiring by school boards of registered early childhood educators (RECEs) into those

programs (estimated as at least 9,000 RECEs). Several children’s services staff remarked that

the job rate for school board RECEs is usually above $26.68 (the sector benchmark). In addition

to having a well-paid job in the school system, RECEs who work there work shorter hours,

receive good employee benefits, get holiday time at Christmas and March Break, have summers

off (unpaid, but usually eligible for Employment Insurance), and they feel their teaching role is

valued.

In contrast, we were told that RECEs and non-qualified staff in child care centres are expected

to work in less desirable conditions. In some cases, they are asked to work long hours; in other

cases, they are only working part-time, often irregular, hours because the operators can only

afford to pay them for a few shifts in order to sustain the centre; or, they are being asked to

work split shifts (early in the morning and late in the evening) to accommodate the hours of the

before-and-after school programs. They do this job for relatively low wages and few (if any)

benefits above the legislated minimums; they have a large administrative and reporting burden

as well as additional responsibilities created with the new regulations. CMSM/DSSABs noted

that they have observed a significant level of staff demoralization and turnover in centres. As a

few CMSM/DSSABs reminded us, child care staff are nearly always eligible for fee assistance

(i.e., child care subsidy) if they have children.

Page 86: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

76

CMSM/DSSABs are acutely aware that there aren’t enough qualified staff to go around and

there is substantial turnover. Frequently, new graduates will move first into relatively low-

paying jobs and quickly move on when they find a higher paying job. Or, they may leave the

centre and/or the sector altogether because the level of stress is a burden. Many qualified and

talented staff have moved to the school boards leaving existing centres with problems of

leadership and capacity. Across the province, one third of all staff positions are not filled with

the required qualified RECEs resulting in a “director’s approval” at these centres, allowing

centres to operate without the required number of qualified staff (October 2017). A further

20% of supervisors in centres across the Province do not have the required qualifications

resulting in “director’s approvals”. The College of Early Childhood Educators of Ontario, along

with other organizations, have expressed concern over this situation and suggest that the

Ministry should exercise tighter controls over these director’s approvals. They suggest that

there should be a stronger requirement to demonstrate that qualified RECEs are not available

and that there should be a limit on the length of time centres are permitted to operate under

“director’s approvals”.

At a minimum, the College recommends that any individual working in the place of an RECE

(e.g., individual working under Director Approval in a licensed child care setting or a Letter of

Permission for RECE positions in school boards, etc.) be regulated by the College and subject to

the same requirements and accountabilities to practice in accordance with the Code of Ethics

and Standards of Practice as RECEs.5

Currently, unqualified staff are not subject to the Ethical Code and Standards of Practice of the

College and therefore there is no complaints mechanism for families. In a significant number of

cases, supervisors are working in the program to cover for the shortage of qualified staff, taking

their administrative work home with them at night. The Community Colleges confirm the

majority of the students enrolled in the two-year diploma programs are not electing to work in

child care centres after graduation.

One community college professor estimated that only one-third to one-half of students will end

up working in child care centres: one-third go on to take university courses and the other third

seek jobs in school boards or other related children’s service sectors.

5 College of Early Childhood Educators. Letter to Honourable Indira Naidoo-Harris, Minister Responsible for Early Years and

Child Care, in January 2017.

Page 87: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

77

All CMSM/DSSABs believe that dealing with the issue of the low-wage environment is crucial for

stabilizing and growing the sector. CMCSM/DSSABs had no shortage of suggestions to resolve

these critical problems – both in terms of the wages of the staff and with regard to recruitment.

The CMSM/DSSABs were very positive about the wage enhancement grant recognizing it as a

major step forward. But all service system managers appealed for more funding for wages.

Many reminded us that the sector had alerted them to the fact that the minimum wage

increases will not be limited to staff earning minimum wage but will reverberate throughout

the sector. Most believed that increased wages cannot be sustained by raising parent fees and

it would not be possible for the centres to absorb the increases as they are generally operating

on thin margins.

Some system service managers referred to the developments in other provinces such as

Quebec, PEI, Manitoba and most recently Newfoundland and Labrador. In each of these

provinces, fees are capped and the provincial governments provide grants to centres to cover

the difference between the fee charged and the actual cost.

Many of them suggested that the province must introduce a standardized salary scale (perhaps

weighted by region).

In terms of recruitment and retention, the following suggestions emerged:

Expand Ministry’s Upgrade Program to also be used for unqualified staff engaged in

part-time, day release or apprenticeship programs as well as more on-line courses that

would be accessible to staff in their non-working hours.

Provide a staff replacement (substitute) grant so that operators may hire supply staff to

cover for unqualified staff while attending a recognized college training program in early

childhood education. The lack of supply staff everywhere was a common refrain. The

school boards are paying $14 per hour for supply staff, in many cases more than staff in

early learning and child care centres earn in their full-time jobs and consequently staff

are opting to “supply” for school boards rather than work in or be a supply staff in

community child care centres. Raising rates for supply staff, as well as overall wages,

would seem to be a solution to this problem.

Organize and fund extra professional development and training in this sector to

encourage professionalism and encourage RECEs to feel valued. It was said that there

can never be too much professional development and training in this sector.

One CMSM/DSSAB suggested introducing an apprenticeship program so unqualified

staff did not need to go off-site (and not get paid) to do placements. One municipality

Page 88: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

78

stressed the need to not forget about opportunities for the unqualified staff because

without them, in many, many cases, the system could not survive.

Permit payment for training of current staff out of General Operating Grant (GOG)

dollars.

Implement an incentive grant of up to $5,000 for ECEs with approved ECE diplomas or

degrees who return to work in a non-profit centre after having been away from the

sector for at least two consecutive years.

Support and fund creative solutions by community colleges. For example, St. Clair

College in Chatham is running a school age certificate program and operates classes

from 9 to 3 so that students can go and work in the after-school programs after classes.

Some CMSM/DSSABs with managers who have knowledge of systems in other provinces, such

as Manitoba, Quebec, PEI and Saskatchewan, pointed out that to attract staff it would be

necessary to introduce a new job classification system from the unqualified to the

supervisor/director in order that those considering careers can see that there is room for

professional progress within the sector. Right now, there are really only three job

classifications: unqualified, RECE, supervisor. This would effectively create a “career ladder”.

Colleges such as Conestoga and George Brown are offering an apprenticeship program for

unqualified staff and Waterloo CMSM is paying for staff to go to college in the daytime.

The number one challenge to the viability and stability of centres are the issues of wages, staff

recruitment and retention. Without solving these problems, it will be impossible to expand the

system. CMSM/DSSABs would like to see a province-wide salary scale funded by the Ministry as

well as new and bolder efforts to reduce the difficulties of recruitment.

3.3 HOME CHILD CARE

The CMSM/DSSABs (in addition to the Home Child Care Association) welcomed the Ministry’s

initiative to increase the rates to providers by $20 per day and hoped that this would make a

large difference. CMSM/DSSABs are still concerned that in many areas, however, providers are

being charged high administration fees by the Home Child Care Agencies and that this is

becoming a disincentive to participating in licensed Home Child Care programs.

In the majority of municipalities, Home Child Carre (HCC) constitutes between 4% and 6% of

licensed child care. This conforms to the provincial Home Child Care average range. At the

extremes, Kenora and Rainy River do not offer licensed Home Child Care at all and, at the other

end of the spectrum, in Prescott-Russell, 60% of licensed child care is in Home Child Care –

mostly in rural areas.

Page 89: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

79

There are serious challenges in home care, however. Nineteen CMSM/DSSABs stated that they

had experienced a distinct decline in the number of providers willing to offer care through

agencies in recent years, especially since recent regulation changes. Niagara, for example, lost

25-30 providers; Lanark reported that they are licensed for 43 homes but only 15 are now

operational; Cochrane is an example of a DSSAB where they have 50-60 children on the waiting

list for Home Child Care but can’t get the providers to deliver the service. Several

CMSM/DSSABs (Bruce, Cochrane, Cornwall, Durham, Grey, Huron, Muskoka, Niagara, Parry

Sound, Prescott-Russell, Renfrew, Thunder Bay, Waterloo and Wellington) directly-operate

home agencies (sometimes the only agency in their region) and in some cases, they have taken

on this role because existing home agencies have become less viable or even closed down.

Only three CMSM/DSSABs – Kawartha Lakes, Muskoka and Renfrew – reported a growth in the

number of providers. Almost all of the remaining CMSM/DSSABs reported that the sector was

struggling or standing still. Among many others, Bruce is trying to expand but reported that it

had been a lot of work to retain their providers. Halton indicated that there had not been a

decline but that parents preferred centre care.

While noting that the licensed home child care sector has not been growing in recent years,

there was concern that their ability to retain and recruit providers had further declined since

the introduction of the regulations under the new Child Care and Early Years Act 2014 (CCEYA).

CMSM/DSSABs offered the following reasons (not all of them related to new regulations):

Requirements for police checks for everyone in their household;

Evaluation of premises and subsequent changes required

Extra policies to follow and more paperwork to do.

Extra administration: too many forms to complete

Having to collect information about all children in their care as well as information

about their families, not just the fee-assisted families.

$100,000 liability insurance – a perceived increase

Start-up costs, such as costs involved in meeting building, fire and public health

standards, having sufficient toys to rotate, building cubbies, etc. – such costs have been

estimated to cost between $2,000 and $4,000.

Not wanting to pay income tax

In many cases, the extra $20 per day received through the Home Enhancement Grant

apparently does not sufficiently compensate for these perceived negatives.

The Home Child Care Association is, however, extremely supportive of the regulatory changes

and believes that this is the correct way to offer quality licensed home care. Their suggested

Page 90: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

80

solutions, supported by most service system managers, are to provide base funding to the

agencies. This would cover all administrative costs so the providers did not have to pay admin

fees to the agencies. Also, start-up costs and minor capital grants for providers are needed to

assist them to meet the regulatory requirements.

CMSM/DSSABs are working hard with their providers to assist them to overcome any barriers

they are experiencing. Examples include situations where CMSM/DSSABs have helped provide

fencing around water; arranged for the building of cubbies, or brought fire doors up to code.

Renfrew has a new agency just starting and they immediately realized that providers needed

financial support in the form of start-up, ongoing equipment (cots, gates, open-ended toys) and

supplies and ensuring that health and safety is maintained. Brantford has given money from

the GOG to the agency - Wee Watch - to launch a publicity and recruitment campaign.

Manitoulin-Sudbury is base-funding the service. Cochrane is providing a $1,500 start-up grant

to cover business licenses, first aid training, fire extinguishers, equipment, supplies and toys.

Despite these initiatives, however, recruitment is either going slowly or is in decline.

Durham CMSM is launching a strategy this Fall to promote licensed HCC to operators in schools

with the idea that if the operators became home child care agencies they could utilize the staff

currently working split shifts in before-and-after school (B/A) programs in the schools to take

on the roles of home visitors; the staff would then have a full day’s workload. Durham is

optimistic and believes that more and more parents are looking for the “licensed sticker” which

bodes well for the development of the licensed home child care sector. Durham will be offering

information sessions to promote the service to providers.

One suggested provider-recruitment strategy is to get the parents using unlicensed providers to

try to recruit their providers to the licensed system. Many CCSM/DSSABs are conducting

extensive information and training campaigns in their regions.

Most CMSM/DSSABs are still anticipating growth in the HCC system despite resistance to the

rules and regulations. Many of them believe that to succeed, they are going to have to offer

more funding to attract providers. Base funding was a solution suggested by several

CMSM/DSSABs in addition to start-up and minor capital grants. Incentive funding for taking

infants, and for taking children evenings, overnights and on weekends will likely also be

needed.

3.4 ACCESSIBILITY

3.4.1 Are there enough spaces?

Most CMSM/DSSABs believe that there are not enough child care spaces in their area and

several of them used the ratio of child care spaces to child population to demonstrate this.

Page 91: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

81

Even those who thought that there was sufficient supply now, thought that if it was affordable

and if there was increased demand, supply would definitely be a problem. Examples included:

Durham has a waiting list for subsidy and they only have enough spaces to serve 23% of

the child population;

Using all of its child care spaces, Kingston is only able to serve 32% of the child

population 0-12;

Wellington has enough spaces to cover 16% of 0-4 year olds and for infants that figure

drops to 3%;

Waterloo only has enough spaces for 22% of children of child care age;

St. Thomas can provide licensed care for 19%-20%;

Nipissing has sufficient spaces for 26% of their child population 0-12. In contrast, Kenora has

almost enough spaces to reach their definition of universal accessibility – 50% of the child

population. It should be noted, however, that the municipalities comprising the Kenora DSSAB

provide deficit funding to the child care centres so they can keep the fees low enough.

There are anomalies however. For example, vacancies exist in Thunder Bay mainly because the

child population has moved to different locations and the centres have not adapted to these

demographic shifts. In rural areas, there is generally a lack of child care but when it exists, the

centres sometimes have vacancies because there is not a high enough concentration of children

in the area to fill all the spaces; in some places, there are waiting lists because there are not

enough children to enable an operator to hire additional staff to accommodate them and still

keep the centre financially viable.

3.4.2 Access to rural, part-time, extended hours and care for children

with special needs

CMSM/DSSABs identified other common types of shortages: rural access (and transportation

for both families and staff), part-time opportunities, care for children with special needs and

care during non-traditional hours such as evenings, overnights and weekends. Across the

province, there are very few initiatives that address the issue of providing care during non-

traditional hours. For example:

St. Thomas has a child care centre that is open 23 hours out of 24.

Cornwall, Simcoe and Prescott-Russell have one centre each that is open 24/7

Chatham-Kent has a centre with extended hours till 10:00 p.m.

Sudbury has a centre with extended hours till midnight

Page 92: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

82

Unevenly and rarely, some operators will keep their centres open for longer hours in the

evening or early in the morning.

In Brantford, WeeWatch, a Home Child Care Agency, offers 23-hour care;

Some Home Child Care providers will provide service in these hours but this is not a

major trend and CMSM/DSSABs are considering providing incentives to providers to

offer extended-hours care.

Because of the lack of affordable child care, the use of unlicensed child care is still the most

prevalent form of care in most communities. Again, affordability was cited as the major reason

for this. A Director of Children’s Services in the West Toronto Region indicated that even

though the majority of families used unlicensed child care, they would prefer licensed.

Affordability is most acute at the level of infant care. Despite the fact that the vast majority of

parents cannot afford infant care, there are still waiting lists and shortages almost everywhere

in the province.

Awareness of child care availability and particularly awareness about eligibility for child care

subsidies was cited as a problem for access also. Nearly all CMSM/DSSABs have conducted

advertising and public awareness campaigns or, if not, are planning to in the future. Many of

them hoped that the Ministry would pursue ongoing outreach and public education campaigns.

Also articulated was the concern that many children did not have access to any early learning

and child care experiences. Many CMSM/DSSAB representatives believe that eventually the

activity requirement to receive government assistance (i.e. working or studying) should be

dispensed with so that all children would have these opportunities. In the meantime, they

thought that the CMSM/DSSABs should have more discretion to offer subsidy spaces to children

who did not qualify because their parents were not working or studying and did not have a

referral from a social services or health agency but would, in their view, be of benefit to the

child.

3.4.3 Free Programs

Experience in the area of operating free programs for all preschoolers is not new to Ontario.

Lambton, Chatham-Kent and Timiskaming described the merits of their universal programs free

of charge for children in the year before kindergarten. These programs are not identical but

they each offer set hours for all children of that age to participate in an early learning program

for 2.5 to 3 hours. All these programs originated as part of the demonstration sites when Best

Start was introduced in 2005. These three programs are struggling to continue today. In

Lambton, the funding hasn’t been cut but it has been flat-lined so the program will inevitably

have a limited life. Chatham-Kent and Timiskaming are making the best use they can using

their own reserves together with the general operating grant to keep these programs alive.

Page 93: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

83

They all believe that the programs are extremely successful and important as they permit all

children access to some early child development opportunities before entering school –

especially children in rural areas. “It’s a huge return on investment” according to one

CMSM/DSSAB manager. These claims are backed up by the analysis they do using EDI scores

and administering the “Ages and Stages” questionnaire at entry and exit into the programs. The

call for universal child care - if not now, then eventually - was a frequent refrain from many of

the CMSM/DSSABs.

3.4.4 Accessibility of Child Care to Indigenous Population

Journey Together funding, as discussed in Chapter 2, is now a major vehicle for promoting

Indigenous-led child care, culturally-appropriate child care and culture sensitivity generally to

all child care programs in the Province.

On Reserve, the Journey Together funding is being used to establish and/or expand child and

family centres. There is recognition, however, that more funding is urgently needed to address

issues of crumbling infrastructure and staff shortages.

Accessibility of services that provide culturally-appropriate programming for off-reserve

Indigenous child care has been extremely limited. In response to the the Ministry’s

Development of an Indigenous Early Learning and Child Care Framework, the Ontario

Federation of Indigenous Friendship Centres (OFIFC) urged the Ministry to move towards

Indigenous-led and culturally-appropriate child care centres across Ontario.

“Understanding the disruption and looking for paths to reconnect children to

culture is critical as more is understood about the capacity for culture-based

approaches to act as preventative/protective models for Indigenous early

learning and child care.”

The OFIFC also stressed the need for more Friendship Centres to house and run child care in

order to utilize their well-established culture-based approaches to programming, training,

policy, research, and administration. The OFIFC provides the example of Timmins Native

Friendship Centre (TNFC) as a model for future development. They say that it is:

"A very successful model of a Friendship Centre utilizing culture-based

approaches to early learning and child care. The TNFC was recognized in 2016

under Ontario’s Enabling & Celebrating Community Hubs: One Year Progress

Update for its innovative use of a public property to enhance its capacity and

to respond to unique community needs. The TNFC houses many child-centered

programs including its Oppekehawaso Wekamik centre-based daycare

program, which has offered a unique holistic child care environment that

promotes Indigenous culture and language for over 10 years. Many Friendship

Page 94: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

84

Centres are now moving towards the provision of child care and child and

family programming.” (OFIFC, 2017)

The impetus for innovation and expansion of services off-reserve has been developed under the

auspices of the Journey Together program. Many local Indigenous organizations are working

on plans to extend and enhance child care services with the collaboration of the

CMSM/DSSABs. Examples of these plans include:

Creating new stand-alone base-funded child care centres oriented to local indigenous

population including pilot projects in areas where programs can be available to all

children (on and off reserve).

Expanding spaces so that on-reserve children who come into the CMSMs and DSSABs to

work or go to school can access services;

Expanding provision of Home Child Care (if they can recruit enough providers)

Directly operating new OEYCFCs by 2018;

Working with Systems Integration Networks to do strategic planning;

Lots of proposals for outreach, including culturally-led programming off reserve and

funding for Friendship Centres to extend culturally-sensitive services to all residents off

reserve, including funding cultural ambassadors to provide cultural sensitivity training

programs across the entire sector. Hiring extra staff to do culturally-sensitive

workshops in the region - always in demand.

Proposal for new builds to include child care and early learning in community hubs

including indigenous specialists to educate all child care centres and EarlyON Child and

Family Centres;

Hiring language teachers and organizing new programs for indigenous families at

OEYCFCs.

Creating a cultural immersion camp - recreational camp; as well as Homeward Bound

projects.

Partnerships between CMSMs and DSSABs and First Nations to do professional

development for early learning and child care staff. Developing a plan for both on and

off reserve;

Hosting an indigenous position (with DSSAB directly) to transfer cultural knowledge

throughout programs in DSSAB;

Page 95: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

85

There is also Journey Together funding available for on reserve projects. This is mainly

being used to establish new EarlyON Centres. There is recognition, however, that more

funding is urgently needed to address issues of crumbling infrastructure.

Affordability is the main barrier to access. CMSM/DSSABs thought the Ministry’s commitment

to expansion of spaces was welcome and crucial, but expansion without addressing

affordability is a problem.

3.4.5 Maintaining Quality

All CMSM/DSSABs believe that high quality child care has to be the basis on which an early

learning and child care system is built and expanded. Many CMSM/DSSABs are extremely

proud of the work they have done and continue to do to improve quality. Sault Ste. Marie City

Council, for example, voted to make the City’s child care one of the best in Canada within five

years and other municipalities are also striving to constantly improve the quality of the

programs.

Most CMSM/DSSABs have a quality assurance program. Many municipalities have appointed a

quality coordinator to visit centres regularly to help with capacity development, assessment

and planning and suggesting how to fill the gaps in quality programming. Whether they do

regular monitoring, administer a tool, or both, all CMSM/DSSABs encourage and support

extensive professional development and capacity building for the centres. The allocation of

funding for professional development and capacity development has been welcomed and well

used by the system service managers.

Many of them also support supervisor and mentor networks to promote and improve quality.

For example, Prince Edward-Lennox & Addington has a staff person supporting centres through

communities of practice and professional learning. All centres in the county must participate in

4 of those professional sessions a year in order to get the general operating grant (GOG).

Some of the service system managers mentioned that they didn’t have the resources to do the

quality work themselves but relied on a community network or mentoring group that

supported each other to improve quality. Most of the CMSM/DSSABs, including Brantford and

Windsor, not currently engaged in quality assurance programs are in the course of developing

them for 2018.

About half of centres administer a quality measure such as ITERS/ECERS, Raising the Bar, or an

adapted version of Toronto’s Assessment for Quality Improvement (AQI) tool (often renamed

to fit their own circumstances). The following CMSM/DSSABs are involved in quality initiatives

as well as administering a quality tool: Toronto, Halton, Wellington, Durham, Greater Sudbury,

Nipissing, Sault Ste. Marie, Timiskaming, Thunder Bay, Kawartha Lakes, Peterborough,

Hamilton, Lambton, Niagara, St. Thomas, Stratford, Cornwall, Lanark and Hastings.

Page 96: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

86

Many mentioned that some of the current tools were no longer appropriate with the new

program guidelines outlined in How Does Learning Happen – Ontario’s pedagogical document

for the early years. Most of the system service managers would welcome a provincially-

designated measurement tool. Several suggested that the Assessment for Quality

Improvement tool (Toronto) should be provincially adopted because it is the only tool that has

been verified and works across all pedagogies and philosophies.

Several CMSM/DSSABs survey their community, their operators, or their fee-assisted parents

annually to ask about the quality and the users’ experiences. Some have found the results and

feedback useful and are planning to administer a more comprehensive survey in the future.

The majority of CMSM/DSSABs believe that parents are satisfied with the quality even though

many of them think that parents have a different perception of quality from the early childhood

professionals. As an example, parents often do not understand the changes involved in the

new curriculum, How Does Learning Happen. In the past, programs offered a theme-based

approach and parents would expect children to bring home specific things on, for example,

Mother’s Day or St. Patrick’s Day. Parents do not yet understand why this no longer happens

and how this relates to the new curriculum. More education is required here.

CMSM/DSSABs have grown into the role as caretakers of quality. Most of them have hired

quality assurance coordinators, are working in the community to improve quality in their

programs, introducing significantly more professional development opportunities as well as

mentoring programs. About half of all CMSM/DSSABs are using a quality measurement tool.

3.5 ADMINISTRATION OF THE SUBSIDY SYSTEM

CMSM/DSSABs appeared to be very pleased that the Ministry has expanded funding to enable

them to eliminate or significantly reduce their waiting lists for child care subsidies.

They are concerned that the income test used as part of the subsidy system administration is

out-of-date. The income test hasn’t been updated since its inception in 2007. Some are

concerned that the income eligibility rules for child care subsidy do not take into account the

number of children in a family. Also discussed was the problem of the rapid jump in payback

rates after $40,000, (i.e., parents must pay 30% of their additional income over $40,000, which

is a big jump from the 10% of additional income they must pay between $20,000 and $40,000).

Many CMSM/DSSABs recognize that there are many middle-income families that may be

eligible for subsidy but either don’t know about the system or don’t think they would be

eligible. Even child care centre operators are often unaware that middle-income families may

be eligible for subsidy. There was generalized concern that the stigma associated with child care

subsidy could dissuade families from accessing it. There was discussion about the fact that

Page 97: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

87

parents have to go to the “Social Service” or the “Ontario Works” office for their interviews and

how this is not conducive to making parents feel comfortable about applying for fee assistance.

Sometimes accessing subsidy approval can take a long time because families don’t have the

required documentation available: birth certificate(s); social insurance numbers; letter from

employer or educational institution; Notice of Assessment (NOA)(s); Canada Child Benefit (CCB)

notice; and if applicable, receipts for disability-related expenses, not previously reimbursed.

Having their NOAs or CCB notices readily available seems to be the main barrier for parents.

Several CMSM/DSSABs indicated that they have asked the province to enter into a

Memorandum of Understanding with Canada Revenue to allow them to download their client’s

NOA. This has already been done for Ontario Works (OW) clients. So far, not much progress

has been made on this issue through the Ministry of Finance and most CMSM/DSSABs find it

frustrating that Ontario Works can have this facility but that it cannot be arranged for early

learning and child care services.

There was mixed reaction to the idea of an automated and centralized application process for

subsidy. Despite the recognition that stigma is attached to a visit to the welfare office,

CMSM/DSSABs also think that the interview is an important way to explain the child care

benefits to parents, to link them to other services and to provide them with a personal contact

for any future difficulties. It was, however, recognized by some that an automated process

might be preferable and that other ways could be found to link parents to services and provide

them with information.

Some CMSM/DSSABs are beginning to move into a digital experience, corresponding with

clients by email, accepting electronic copies of documents, etc. This appears to have speeded

up the process considerably. Some CMSM/DSSABs currently take applications on line or by

email but then create a service request and follow-up with a face-to-face interview e.g.,

Toronto, Wellington, Bruce, Simcoe, Windsor, Halton, Peel and Hamilton. In a few

CMSM/DSSABs, staff meet subsidy clients in locations convenient to the client.

Only Waterloo, Ottawa, and Cochrane, from the municipalities we interviewed, do not require

all parents to attend a face-to-face meeting. Cochrane conducts its intake process entirely by

telephone with no face-to-face interview. Many CMSM/DSSABs would be interested in

streamlining the process further, making it more simplified and systematic but indicate that so

far there are no funds for the requisite technology. Several service system managers have

dispensed with the interview for all families for the annual review process.

CMSM/DSSABs identified centralized waiting lists as a mechanism for improving both

accessibility and fairness. The centralized waiting lists have enabled some municipalities to

prioritize children approved for subsidy in centres with a purchase-of-service (POS) agreement

or at least to have more control over the intake.

Page 98: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

88

Most CMSM/DSSABs determine the allowable fee paid by the CMSM/DSSAB under a purchase-

of-service agreement according to a market rate, but require services to submit a budget with

full financial disclosure and then limit annual increases to 2%-3% or less, unless there’s an

exceptional reason for an increase.

The method for selecting this market rate varies. Some CMSM/DSSABs do market research and

compare average rates within their area; some scout rates in neighbouring CMSM/DSSABs;

Waterloo determines the high and low rates in the market and allows for rates within a range.

Windsor requires centres to complete a Utilization Agreement report demonstrating how the

funds were spent. Lanark sets a cap on the rates with annual increases; Prescott-Russell Council

votes and adopts a specific rate; Niagara requires that centres demonstrate viability; Chatham

pays the market rate with a limit; Greater Sudbury determines a baseline based on the rates of

their 4-5 largest operators and then permits rates to be paid at the 80th percentile of that rate;

Wellington pays within 20% of the average researched rate; Stratford is redoing its purchase-of-

service agreements to ensure that staff wages rise to $26 and incorporate this into the rates.

There is no systematic method of determining appropriate fees applied across the province.

Some service system managers, such as Toronto and Ottawa, have set up a tool (called a

“benchmarking”) tool. Based on individual costs, this tool estimates the exact amount that

individual centres should be spending on every budget item (e.g., wages, benefits, occupancy

costs, food and nutrition, supplies and administration, etc.) and calculates the cost of the

service based on the numbers and ages of the children and the hours of operation. This is then

used to help educate supervisors and boards of directors about effective financial

management. But it is also used to determine the rate that will be paid to the child care

operator. With this tool, CMSM/DSSABs are able to put more stringent requirements on

operators. Wellington, for example, describes their process as a “budget for quality”. It

requires that all centres pay wages of $20/hour before they receive the general operating

grant.

Most CMSM/DSSABs thought that this was a good example of an area where it would be

appropriate to receive more provincial direction. Receiving provincial guidelines for setting

rates, monitoring financial practices and ensuring accountability for government funds would

be helpful and very important to ensure that new funding doesn’t just result in a rise in prices

without a matching rise in quality.

As one Chief Administrative Officer states:

When you're funding more than 80% of costs, you have a right to tell

programs how they should spend the money - even for-profit centres.

Therefore, we held them to it by addendum to contract; the Province should

give a lot of policy direction in this area and make it easier for CMSMs.

Page 99: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

89

3.6 AUSPICE OF OPERATORS

The Ministry of Education has introduced a policy to prioritize funding to the non-profit and

public sectors. To achieve this goal, the Ministry has introduced a “For Profit Maximum

Percentage Threshold” for spending in the for-profit sector. Each CMSM/DSSAB has been given

a threshold level to aim for. Most CMSM/DSSABs support the thresholds for for-profit spending.

One Director of Children’s Services let us know that their CMSM was thrilled with the threshold

announcement. Previously, the Director said, they were always doing a balancing act between

their knowledge about the problems with the for-profit child care sector for delivering quality

child care on the one hand and the desire by local municipal councilors not to seem anti-

business on the other hand. This kind of provincial direction is therefore seen as very useful.

But there is some concern that they will not be able to meet those thresholds where the

commercial sector is more dominant, for example, in Durham, York, Peel, and Halton. One

director also reported that the for-profit operators were willing to be more flexible in their

hours of opening and pointed out that often a majority of infants were in centres operated by

for-profit companies. However, across the province, there is considerable nervousness

concerning the growth of for-profit chain child care. This phenomenon has grown rapidly since

2010. (e.g., Bunny Hoppers, Busy Bees, and Kids and Company). Kids and Company, for

instance, now has 31 programs across the province.

To establish a clear direction in the area of auspice, sixteen service system managers now have

a moratorium on future purchase-of-service agreements with new for-profit operators (i.e.,

Toronto, Durham, Norfolk, Peterborough, Simcoe, Hamilton, Niagara, Northumberland, Ottawa,

Prescott-Russell, Greater Sudbury, Manitoulin-Sudbury, Nipissing, Kenora, Rainy River and

Renfrew). In effect, the existing for-profit centres are grand-parented and continue to receive

purchase-of-service agreements with CMSM/DSSABs (where they exist) but there are no

contracts with new for-profits. All for-profit operators are permitted to receive the wage

enhancement grants for their staff if they apply and meet the criteria. The administration of the

general operating grant (GOG) to for-profit centres is inconsistent: some CMSM/DSSABs don’t

give for-profit operators any GOG; some give 50%; others give the full 100% - the same as non-

profit centres. This is another area where provincial guidelines might be appropriate.

For example, Ottawa, Renfrew, Kenora and Sault Ste. Marie do not give general operating

grants to for-profit operators; Toronto, Niagara and Durham give 50% of the general operating

grant; the remainder provide 100% of the general operating grants to them. Peel pays the GOG

to for-profit centres if they’re paying average wages or raising the wages; Wellington requires

that centres pay a minimum of $20 per hour before any grants are given; Lennox and Addington

requires all centres to complete four professional development workshops per year in order to

qualify to receive GOGs. One for-profit operator decided not to do the professional

development so does not receive the grant money.

Page 100: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

90

Municipalities were almost unanimous in suggesting that the income test for child care subsidy

be made more generous; many CMSM/DSSABs believe that $40,000 would be a more realistic

minimum as a turning point (i.e., income level below which the family pays nothing). Others

mentioned the need to engage in outreach to middle-income families; to reduce the stigma

associated with “subsidy” by changing the relationship between social assistance and child care

subsidy. Some CMSMs said they would be interested in receiving technology funding to

develop their centralized waiting lists and application processes, as well as making

arrangements to access NOAs. Most CMSM/DSSABs support the provincial thresholds for for-

profit funding but there needs to be some recognition that this will be more difficult to

implement in areas with very high levels of for-profit operators. Setting rates and establishing

systems of accountability are all important but are also areas where CMSM/DSSABs would

appreciate provincial direction.

3.7 RELATIONSHIPS WITH SCHOOL BOARDS

CMSM/DSSABs were universally complimentary about the improvement in most relationships

with school boards, while recognizing that there are definite outliers where relationships are

not so healthy. School boards are usually working closely with CMSM/DSSABs to construct new

child care centres in the schools, to retrofit existing schools to accommodate more programs

and to construct new centres on school board land.

The Ministry of Education Schools First policy is unanimously supported by CMSM/DSAABs

many of whom are hoping to move stand-alone operations into schools. Examples of excellent

collaborative relationships flowed from many municipalities. Most CMSM/DSSABs deal with

four school boards – a few only two, and one as many as eleven. This results in varying quality

of relationships. For example, some service system managers identified school boards that

came to them at the last minute to ask them to sign requests for capital consideration without

any prior consultation and with very short notice. Subsequently, the CMSM/DSSABs find it

difficult to find information on the status of these projects and this makes ongoing planning

extremely difficult. In another instance, a DSSAB could not conclude negotiations with the

school board and decided to use its own municipal money to build a new child care centre right

beside the school. The CMSM/DSSABs identified the issue of communication as an area that

continues to need a lot of work.

A more typical example, however, is that of Manitoulin-Sudbury which has an excellent

relationship with one school board, works well with 2 others but has not communicated with

the other eight. CMSM/DSSABs involved in the Best Start program in the 2000’s talked about

the fact that the collaboration had been an ongoing tradition since the inception of Best Start in

2005; consequently, these municipalities got off to a good start in the process several years

ago.

Page 101: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

91

A significant number of CMSM/DSSABs are concerned about the fact that space in schools is

tapped out and that so far there is very little alternative capital funding for system service

managers to access for community construction.

CMSMs and DSSABs indicate that the majority of schools in their regions have B/A programs –

in many areas all the schools have B/A programs. Almost everywhere, the B/A programs are

operated by third party operators. The exceptions are Ottawa, Waterloo and some of the

Francophone boards in a number of different CMSM/DSSABs where programs are directly-

operated by the school boards.

All CMSM/DSSABs mentioned the importance of the School Board Early Years Leads as a critical

link between the CMSM/DSSABs and the school system. However, a few CMSM/DSSABs

mentioned that their Early Years Leads no longer had a 100% allocation of their time to work on

child care issues and as a result the effectiveness of their work has diminished. It was pointed

out that the Ministry provides funding for this role for a full-time person and that it would be

important to mandate this in the future. Some CMSM/DSSABs talked about the lack of

authority of participants at the planning table resulting in a lot of frustration, lack of

information and inability to ultimately plan and budget. It was suggested by many

CMSM/DSSABs that the Ministry of Education should mandate Early Years Leads to attend

monthly planning meetings with the community partners and dedicate their position exclusively

to relations between child care and the schools.

CMSM/DSSABs still have concerns about the day-to-day attitudes towards child care centres in

the schools. Successful integration of child care and EarlyON centres into the school

environment depends upon the acceptance by the principal and individual teachers in

individual schools. In some schools, there are no problems and the relationships are excellent.

But, a lot of CMSM/DSSABs made the point that the messaging from the Ministry about Schools

First and the importance of integrating child care hasn’t made its way down to the classroom

teacher and school staff and so a high percentage of CMSM/DSSABs talked about the

reluctance of some principals, teachers and janitors to really embrace the Schools First

objectives. There were numerous examples of these experiences:

Teachers being reluctant to share their space, referring to “my children” in “my room”.

Janitor locked the washroom after he had cleaned it not permitting access for the

children.

One child care centre was told on the Thursday before March Break that they couldn’t

access the child care centre over March break because of planned renovations. This was

a serious problem for the parents who were counting on the child care to enable them

to work during March Break, for fee-assisted parents who had to pay the price of private

Page 102: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

92

sitters, and for the actual child care centre that lost a significant amount of their

anticipated operating revenue during the March Break period.

Similarly, child care centres are frequently being told they have to close down for two

weeks at Christmas because there is no way to keep the school open.

Most CMSM/DSSABs are also concerned about whether there would be support from the

schools if they want to expand the hours of access to the child care centres. “We’re still in

silos”, one person commented and a DSSAB Chief Administrative Officer said, “We’ve worked

on our relationships for years now, it’s time that the Ministry provided clear directions to the

school boards and schools.”

Perhaps the most persistent criticism raised in relation to school boards concerned the “rental”

or “cost recovery” rate. Many CMSM/DSSABs thought that their centres were being charged

exorbitant rates. The rates are prohibitive in many cases and many CMSM/DSSABs pointed out

that this anomaly is undermining the provincial Schools First Policy that they all, in principle,

agree with. But because of the high rates, many operators are finding that it just isn’t viable to

operate in school premises. In some cases, the rates are so high that operators are trying to

relocate the space into the community. Many CMSM/DSSABs have ceased attempting to build

Ontario Early Years Child and Family Centres (now re-branded as EarlyON centres) in school

space because the rental cost is prohibitive. In other instances, CMSM/DSSABs are trying to

negotiate with school boards to acquire land on school board property that can be operated

entirely by the CMSM/DSSAB. The problem of “rent” is a critical problem to address. One

general manager captured the opinions of most of his counterparts by suggesting that:

“The Ministry should fund the school as a whole and not see operators as a

lessee in their building”

Some CMSM/DSSABs did agree that “out-of-pocket” costs were a reasonable expectation but

that child care centres should not become the source of revenue generation for the school

boards. Other CMSM/DSSABs were adamant that the point of the Schools First policy was to

integrate child care seamlessly into the fabric of learning from birth to school-leaving age.

Virtually all municipalities believe that the Ministry should establish a clear policy that permits

child care centres and EarlyON Centres to flourish and that this be followed consistently across

the province. One general manager interviewed coined the view of many other CMSM/DSSAB

colleagues:

“We’re all under the Ministry of Education and supposed to be partners and

yet we’re seen as tenants of the school. The accommodation rates should be

part of the school funding formula and should be covered by the Ministry of

Education rather than charging it back to the families through child care.”

Page 103: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

93

Therefore, they suggested, the costs should be borne by the Ministry in just the same way they

are for school age children, and not put back on the child care centres to pass along to the

parents. Other CMSM/DSSABs could see the rationale for some modest amount of cost

recovery.

The improvement in relationships between the schools and child care sector has made great

strides in recent years. While celebrating these developments, there is still room for

improvements: more direction from Ministry is needed on the importance of relationships in

schools with child care; specific directives to principals, teachers and janitors would help; to

improve the day-to-day experience for child care and EarlyON centres; there is definitely a need

to strengthen the role of the Early Leads to improve communication and efficiency. The

Ministry should consider giving child care the same status in schools as grade school education

has so that child care programs would not have to pay rent or cost recovery.

3.8 EXPANSION PLANS

While recognizing that CMSM/DSSABs now had flexibility in the distribution of their allocations,

the Ministry has asked them to prioritize accessibility and fee subsidy, followed by affordability.

The Ministry staff and CMSMs and DSSABs have worked together to establish targets for the

number of additional children to be supported through this expansion strategy and funding.

CMSM/DSSABs will achieve these targets as follows:

Everywhere, the service system managers’ first priority is to eliminate subsidy waiting

lists; some are also using their funds to eliminate the waiting list for children with

special needs.

Physical expansion is also occurring mainly through capital projects in school space but

some CMSM/DSSABs have been able to organize the expansion or retrofitting of existing

centres. Where possible, CMSM/DSSABs are encouraging centre operators to expand

their enrolment capacity to match the licensed capacity. Many operators are too

nervous to expand and many CMSM/DSSABs thought that incentives would be required.

Almost all system service managers plan to expand Home Child Care if they can succeed

in attracting providers. A few CMSM/DSSABs have started to provide start-up grants to

family Home Child Care providers to encourage them to enroll or to remain as licensed

providers. For example, one CMSM/DSSAB is offering $1,500; another is attempting to

attract providers with iPads and other gadgets; others are helping them with necessary

renovations required to meet the new CCEYA regulations; another is paying (through

the agency) the additional $20 per day to all providers even though providers are

normally expected to have completed a year’s service prior to receiving it.

Page 104: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

94

The Journey Together funding is enabling CMSM/DSSABs to support their Indigenous

partners in the community to create new child care centres and community hubs

including EarlyON centres together with complementary programs for the Indigenous

off-reserve population.

Several CMSM/DSSABs have goals to expand access to hours (especially non-traditional

hours), infants and Home Child Care. To achieve these goals, many of them are

providing incentives to operators to provide these additional programs. Others are

considering such initiatives.

Affordability initiatives have so far been limited. System service managers are attempting to

prevent fee increases by supporting centres with the general operating grant. This is usually

dedicated to increasing wages without increasing parent fees. There are a few CMSM/DSSABs

who have taken bolder steps with regard to affordability. For example, Manitoulin-Sudbury has

worked with their child care operators to agree on a fee to the parent and amount of the grant

from Manitoulin-Sudbury that covers the difference between the fee to the parent and the

actual cost to the operator. The table below shows the age category, the fees in October 2013,

the fee in September 2017, the % decrease and the grant allocated to the centre, based on the

age of the child.

Page 105: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

95

Table 25

Change in Fee Structure in Manitoulin-Sudbury DSSAB -- 2016 to 2017

MANITOULIN-SUDBURY DSSAB

Centre-based Child Care Rates

Oct. 2013 fee Sep 2017 fee % decrease Grant to centre per child

Infant Full Day $45.00 $35.00 22 $8,500

Toddler Full Day $36.00 $30.00 17 $5,500

Preschool Full Day $32.00 $25.00 22 $3,500

School Age Full Day $30.00 $20.00 33 $1,750

Socialization all ages $15.00 $15.00 0 not known

Before School $10.50 $5.00 52

After School $10.50 $10.00 5

Before and After $15.00 $10.00 33 $1,750

With family groupings $5,000

Family Home Child Care

Overnight care 13 hrs+ $58.00 $45.00 21

Extended Day 9-13 hrs $46.00 $35.00 24

Full Day 5-9 hrs $36.00 $25.00 31

Half Day - up to 5 hours $28.00 $15.00 46

Before School $7.00 $5.00 29

After School $10.00 $10.00 0

Before and After $16.00 $10.00 38

Page 106: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

96

In order to offer Home Child Care at the price listed above and to pay providers, Home Child

Care agencies also received base funding from the DSSAB. Two non-profit Home Child Care

Agencies in the Manitoulin-Sudbury Region are eligible for the following grants:

1-3 homes - Up to $17,983/year/home

4-6 homes - Up to $13,487/year/home

7-10 homes - Up to $11,688/year/home

11-15 homes - Up to $9,890/year/home

16-25 homes - Up to $8,092/year/home

CMSM/DSSABs have embraced the challenge posed by the Ministry to work on expansion and

are putting enormous effort into achieving their targets, often with limited staff, short timelines

and absence of planning resources. The priorities to increase accessibility, expand access to fee

subsidy, and work on affordability are being achieved by reducing the subsidy lists, expanding

capacity through capital expansion, Journey Together and collaboration with school boards.

Other initiatives include attempts to expand Home Child Care, access to non-traditional hours,

rural programs and infant programs. Mainly CMSM/DSSABs are assisting affordability by using

general operating grants to prevent fee increases but initiatives such as those of Manitoulin-

Sudbury DSSAB suggest possible future directions.

3.9 CHALLENGES TO EXPANSION

The system service managers are acutely aware that making child care more affordable will

undoubtedly increase demand. They do, however, have many concerns about the stability of

the present system and about the lack of excess capacity to accommodate additional demand –

especially for infants and toddlers.

As indicated in the section on Centre-based Care, leading the list of their concerns are the

workforce issues – attracting and retaining RECEs. This, they believe, will be the number one

barrier to expansion.

There was a general concern about the lack of guaranteed funding. This is causing reticence to

move ahead aggressively on the part of the operators and is also a cause for some wariness on

the part of some of the CMSM/DSSABs and, of course, their councils. They are all worried

about expanding and then having funding cut. CMSM/DSSABs believe that the solution to this

problem is multi-year funding allocations. The CMSM/DSSABs had many suggestions for 3- or

4-year funding guarantees including a suggestion that the Ministry could mirror the 4-year

Housing funding guarantees.

Page 107: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

97

Inadequate capital funding for expansion in the community by CMSM/DSSABs is another

barrier. This is especially true in many areas where the school board space has tapped out. The

CMSM/DSSABs recommended a new capital program providing funding directly to

CMSM/DSSABs to undertake developments in their communities.

But with capital funding, CMSM/DSSABs stressed that the Ministry needs to understand

timelines better: it takes 2-3 years for a child care centre to materialize from notice of funding,

to planning, council approvals, design, construction and licensing. Some smaller communities

are able to complete the process in 1-2 years but they still make the point about the constraints

of the funding guidelines. In addition, many communities are concerned that they have

committed to several capital projects without future guarantees of operating funding.

CMSMs with a high percentage of for-profit operators (York, Peel, and Halton) raised some

concerns about their capacity to expand at the same time as limit the expenditures available to

for-profit operators. They indicate that the only growth is in the for-profit sector and so they

would like to see some “wiggle-room” regarding the thresholds in places where CMSM/DSSABs

are very dependent on for-profit operators. Other CMSM/DSSABs are worried about the

growing influence of chain child care and are supportive of the Ministry’s policy to prioritize

funding to the non-profit and public sectors.

CMSM/DSSABs mentioned that they would need more money for administrative costs to deal

with additional caseworker load and eligibility review. It was also recognized that more support

will be needed for planning and research in an expanded system. Expedited expansion will also

require funding for the development of projects from conception to turnkey.

Some of the CMSM/DSSABs are suggesting that to accommodate rapid expansion, it may be

necessary to rationalize the sector’s development and management systems. This would

involve establishing separate management companies that are able to undertake the

development of new programs, and organize back-end functions such as financial management,

payroll and purchasing.

Most CMSM/DSSABs envelop rural areas in their municipal region. It was stressed that there

needs to be a strategy to deal with rural issues including the lack of transportation. Similarly,

with Northern communities, it was stressed that there needs to be inherent flexibility in the

north because of unique circumstances. For example, they would love to continue supporting

programs in low-population communities where the numbers are uneconomic. They are now

working to establish small centres (15 children) with family groupings to make these programs

possible.

Many CMSM/DSSABs talked about the difficulties of existing operators only being willing to

open the traditional hours (7 a.m. to 6 p.m.) – or less in many places. They also referred to

many operators who will not accept part-time children unless they pay for a full-time space.

Page 108: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

98

Several CMSM/DSSABs are therefore paying the full-time fee for children who are only using

the space for part-time hours. Several CMSM/DSSABs have introduced incentives to operators

to take infants, extend their hours beyond the traditional hours and to allow enrolment of part-

time children.

Most CMSM/DSSABs identified Home Child Care as the best way to address the problems of

evening, overnight and weekend hours as well as rural access but most of them noted that

there were not a large number of providers willing to do this. In fact, most CMSM/DSSABs are

finding great difficulty in recruiting new providers at all.

Most municipal representatives think that there is still not enough public knowledge about the

benefits of quality early learning and child care as well as about the subsidy program. It was

suggested by several CMSM/DSSABs that further provincial public education campaigns would

help the system work better.

The major barrier to expansion in centres is the shortage of RECEs occasioned by low wages and

disinterest in the occupation by potential professionals because of those low wages. Other key

issues are the lack of guaranteed funding, inadequate capital funding for expansion in the

community by CMSM/DSSABs, the need for more realistic funding timelines, management of

the for-profit issue, more funding for administration, development and management of a new

system including the need to examine new, more workable models; the need to develop a

strategy to overcome barriers to rural expansion; the reluctance of some operators to expand

where need exists and the overall need to make the goals and importance of early childhood

education clearer to all through robust public education campaigns.

3.10 SUGGESTED SOLUTIONS TO THE AFFORDABILITY CRISIS

We asked municipal representatives about suggested policy responses to the crisis of

affordability in child care. Here are some of those suggestions:

Fix the child care subsidy system by making the sliding scale more generous and

available. Revamp the income test so that payback thresholds are increased and

payback rates reduced for middle-income families.

Use the GOG to stabilize fees and prevent rate increases along the lines implemented in

Manitoba, PEI and Quebec. This would involve setting fee caps, introducing a salary

scale and providing negotiated grants to the operators to cover the difference between

the fee charged to the parent and the actual cost. Some suggested that wages and fees

should be weighted by region.

Expand Home Child Care as a more affordable alternative;

Page 109: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

99

Make early education and child care universal like schools; As one CMSM interview

participant commented:

We have to make it cheaper for everybody; if there are no problems with

universality for 4- and 5-year-old children, then it should be the same for 0-4’s.

It doesn’t work if we value education but only starting at 3 years, 8 months.

Fix wages and staff recruitment problems before anything;

One CAO suggested evaluating the administration of funding through the tax system

even though he wasn’t personally in favour of it.

Despite the recognition of the problems of capacity, staffing, funding timelines and others,

CMSM/DSSABs without exception believed that they were in the best position to advance the

system because of their knowledge of local needs and resources. Most importantly, they are

universally keen to undertake improvements and expansion.

Page 110: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

100

CHAPTER 4: WHY PUBLIC FUNDING OF CHILD CARE

MAKES SENSE

Chapter Summary

Increased public funding for child care affordability has widespread support in Ontario.

Impacts on Parents

o Affordable child care will help parents balance the demands of work and family

life.

o Affordability of child care is particularly important to mothers; child care

responsibilities are often a barrier to employment and equal treatment for

women.

o Quebec’s child care reforms played a major role in helping mothers increase

their access to employment.

o The net cost of government child care assistance is substantially lower than its

gross cost, because increases in parental employment cause increases in tax

revenue and reductions in social assistance and other benefits. There may also

be increased growth and productivity, multiplying the revenue effects.

Impacts on Children

o The years from birth to age five are crucial ones for children’s development.

o There is substantial and widespread evidence that early childhood education and

care can be positive for children’s cognitive and language development,

completed education levels, and eventual employment and wages, as well as

making them happy in the short run.

o There is also substantial and widespread evidence that the effects of early

childhood education and care are not uniform, but are heterogeneous. Policy

needs to be directed towards making positive effects as strong as possible.

o In particular, children from lower-income backgrounds are likely to have stronger

positive effects, if they are not excluded from access and quality services.

o Multiple dimensions of quality are key factors in child care’s effects on children.

Page 111: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

101

o Child care services need to promote and complement parental interactions with

children rather than substitute for them.

4.1 WHY PUBLIC FUNDING OF CHILD CARE MAKES SENSE.

There is now widespread support for measures that make child care more affordable for

families in Ontario. There are several reasons. Adema, Clarke and Thevenon from the Social

Policy Division of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) put the

case this way:

“Formal Early Childhood Education and Care (ECEC) services can help

address a range of work, family and child issues. Affordable ECEC helps

parents to participate in paid work, increasing family income and reducing the

risk of family and child poverty. High-quality ECEC also has positive effects on

child cognitive and social development, improving school-readiness (OECD,

2010) and, further down the line, social and labour market outcomes (Camilli

et al., 2010; Havnes and Mogstad, 2011a; Ruhm and Waldfogel, 2012). These

effects stretch across most children, but are strongest for those from lower

socio-economic positions where high-quality ECEC can help mitigate many of

the effects of a poor start (see e.g. OECD, 2006; Gormley et al., 2008; Dumas

and Lefranc, 2012; Ruhm and Waldfogel, 2012; Van Huizen and Plantenga,

2015). Formal ECEC has the potential to play a central role in promoting social

mobility and breaking the cycle of disadvantage.” (OECD, 2016, p. 5)

4.1.1 Impacts on Parents and Families

The money and time pressures on young families are quite acute. When children are young,

parents are young. Young parents are involved in trying to establish employment experience,

or get an education, and buy or rent to establish a home for their young children. It is a time of

high expenditures and the high costs of child care can be very difficult to manage for families at

any level of income. Increasing numbers of families are postponing childbirth or foregoing

having children altogether. Making child care considerably more affordable can help young

families balance the demands of family life and work in ways that are better for them and for

society.

The burden of having children does not fall equally on both spouses in most families. Partly

because women’s wages are often lower than men’s and partly because of patriarchal social

norms and early experiences that are hard to overcome, mothers carry most of the burden of

childrearing in many families. Thankfully, this is changing, but still the change is very slow. As a

result, high child care fees are a major barrier to women’s equal participation in the workforce.

Often mothers are the ones who stay at home to care for children, or work part-time or in self-

Page 112: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

102

employment, when children are young. This puts them in a position of disadvantage in

employment and the ability to earn income, often for the rest of their lives.

More than three decades ago, Supreme Court Justice Rosalie Abella (1984) wrote that “child

care is the ramp that provides equal access to the workforce for mothers.” When child care is

more affordable, women can earn income and care for children, reducing the exclusion of

mothers from employment and reducing the gender gap in wages, occupational segregation,

and the threat of poverty when marriages break up and when women are elderly and alone.

There are good reasons for believing that improving the affordability of regulated child care

would encourage increased employment and labour market earnings for mothers, contributing

to both gender equity and improving family incomes for both high- and low-income families

with children.

The Quebec child care reforms beginning in the late 1990s provide evidence about the effects

of a substantial decrease in the price of licensed child care and an increase in its supply.

Lefebvre and Merrigan (2005, 2008) reported that, in 2002, the policy change increased the

participation rate of mothers with at least one child aged 1 to 5 years of age by 8 percentage

points (to a new level of 69% participation). Hours of work per year and weeks worked per year

also increased. The authors’ conclusion was that “the substantial decrease in the price of day

care in the province of Québec caused by a policy of generous subsidization of day care

providers had a substantial positive effect on labour supply and earnings.” (Lefebvre &

Merrigan, 2008, p.545). This was true for mothers with completed education at high school or

less and for mothers with more than high school education

Lefebvre, Merrigan, and Verstraete (2009) looked at the longer-term effects of the Québec

child care reforms. In other words, they examined the issue of whether mothers who were

encouraged to join the labour force by the availability of subsidized child care when their

children were young would stay in the labour force once their children reached school age.

These results were surprisingly positive for mothers with high school education or less. Before

the child care reforms, these mothers with lower levels of completed education and all children

in school had employment rates of only about 50%. Their study found that as the reforms were

phased in, the employment rates of these mothers kept increasing, reaching about 70% by

2002. This is a group for whom attachment to the labour force is traditionally weak. The

implication would appear to be that the child care reforms have had an important effect on

families most at risk of being in poverty by encouraging these mothers to join and stay in the

labour force.

In corroboration of this, Pierre Fortin and his colleagues note that, in Quebec, the labour force

participation rate of single mothers with children of preschool age rose by about 22 percentage

points from 1996-2008 while the number of these families on social assistance was cut in half,

Page 113: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

103

poverty rates fell from 36% to 22%, and their median after-tax income rose by 81% (Fortin,

Godbout and St-Cerny, 2013, p.6).

It is worth noting that the positive effects on mothers’ employment are not just positive for

families. As economists from Ontario, British Columbia, Quebec and the U.S. have shown, there

are substantial fiscal benefits for governments as well (Baker, Gruber and Milligan [2008],

Fortin, Godbout and St-Cerny [2013] and Laurin and Milligan [2017]). For instance, Baker,

Gruber and Milligan estimated that close to 40% of the cost of child care provision in Quebec

was covered by the extra revenues (and lower costs) generated by additional employment

facilitated by the child care reforms.

Kevin Milligan from University of British Columbia and his colleague from the C.D. Howe

Institute estimate the fiscal effects of a revised method of funding parental child care expenses

in this way:

“In the short term, the net cost of the program could be reduced by about

three-quarters after accounting for estimated new tax revenues (and lower

income-tested government benefit payments) at the federal and provincial

levels. In the long term, assuming that at least some of the program’s

beneficial impact on maternal employment persists as children enter their

school-age years, the program might generate more revenue than it costs….”

(Laurin and Milligan [2017], pp.2-3).

Fortin, Godbout and St-Cerny (2013) calculate the revenue implications for governments of the

Quebec child care program. These range from 31% of the total cost to 147% of total costs in

2008 depending on what is included. The low figure ignores the longer-run increases in labour

force participation identified by Lefebvre, Merrigan and Verstraete (2009) and Laurin and

Milligan (2017). It also ignores tax revenues from indirect and payroll taxes and corporate

income taxes related to increased growth and productivity. The higher figure includes all of

these.

Supporting this line of thinking, a recent paper from the International Monetary Fund

(Petersson, Mariscal and Ishi, 2017) uses Canada as an example to show how increases in

women’s labour force participation has positive effects on the productivity of labour and the

rate of growth of GDP.

Not all studies find that child care subsidization dramatically increases labour supply.

Richardson (2012) provides a summary of some of the main issues (Box 3, page 19). Haeck,

Lefebvre and Merrigan (2015) provide a thoughtful review of studies and conclude that child

care reforms that are more comprehensive are likely to have larger impacts on labour supply.

Cascio, Haider and Nielsen (2015) discuss a group of studies showing that the intensity of labour

supply effects depend on a number of factors. In general, if there are shortages of child care

Page 114: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

104

spaces, subsidization cannot increase labour supply. And, if child care subsidies only encourage

parents to substitute formal child care for some type of paid informal care, there will be not

much effect on parents’ labour supply (see also Havnes and Mogstad [2011b] and Andresen

and Havnes [2014] for how there can be different magnitudes of labour supply effects brought

about by subsidization of different age groups within the same country).

4.1.2 The Effects on Children

The years from birth to age five have been identified as the most important developmental

period during childhood (Shonkoff and Phillips, 2000). Brain development in the first years of

life lays the foundation for much that comes after – language development, literacy, cognitive

and emotional development and self-regulation (McCain and Mustard, 1999; Shonkoff and

Phillips, 2000).

There is lots of evidence that experiences in early childhood education and care services can

have positive effects on children’s cognitive and language development, and longer run positive

effects on academic outcomes, completed education levels, employment and wages. These

effects are both short run and long run, for full-day child care from early ages, for preschools

and kindergartens. Ruhm and Waldfogel (2012) is perhaps the best recent summary of the

considerable evidence on long-term effects6.

There is also lots of evidence that the effects of child care on children are not uniform, but are

heterogeneous (Havnes, 2012; Kottelenberg and Lehrer, 2014, 2017). For various reasons, the

positive effects for low-income and immigrant children are likely to be larger, and there is some

evidence that girls are more likely to thrive than boys. Further, these effects of child care are

dependent on the quality of licensed child care – on factors such as staff-child ratios and the

skills and capabilities of early childhood educators. The size of effects also depends on the type

of care a child would otherwise have received, and on the quality of school experiences that

follow on from child care.

Lower Incomes or Disadvantage There have been several waves of research about the effects of child care on children. Many of

the early studies were random assignment studies of children from lower income families to

good quality child care centres. Overwhelmingly, these studies (e.g., the Perry Preschool Study,

the Abecedarian Study, the Chicago Parent-Child Center Program) found that good child care

6 It is difficult to study the effects of child care on children because (a) there are a very large number of factors that affect child

development that need to be statistically controlled, and (b) the type and quality of child care that children receive is selected by parents so that factors affecting this selection process need to be statistically controlled. Ruhm and Waldfogel (2012) discuss these issues and how to recognize “good” studies. See also Duncan and Gibson-Davis (2006), Miller et al.(2016), and Cleveland (2016).

Page 115: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

105

can have very positive effects on children and that these advantages can be long-lasting. In

particular, good child care can compensate, at least partially, for a disadvantaged home life.

A benefit-cost analysis of the Abecedarian Early Childhood Intervention (Masse and Barnett,

2003) has revealed how broad and long-lasting the effects of a well-designed ECEC program can

be on disadvantaged children. The benefits to participants (and the community) included:

Improved measures of intelligence and achievement over the long term, leading

to higher earnings and fringe benefits now and in the future

Lower levels of grade retention and placement in special education classes,

leading to cost savings in elementary and secondary education

Improved employment and earnings of mothers of the children receiving early

childhood education services

Reduced probability of smoking and improved health

Reduced use of social assistance.

Other studies of centre-based programs include various studies of Head Start in the U.S. Head

Start children are a targeted low-income group with heterogeneous programs delivered to

approximately one million children per year.

Currie and Thomas (1995) find long-term (i.e., into the early school years) positive effects on

school achievement for white Head Start attendees, but not for African-American children,

apparently because of the later negative effects of their schooling. In a second paper (1999)

Currie and Thomas found long-term positive effects on school achievement for Hispanics.

Examining the long-term effects of Head Start programs when children were in their early

twenties, Garces, Currie and Thomas (2002) found White children who attended Head Start

were more likely to complete high school, to attend college, and to earn more than other White

children who did not attend Head Start. African-American children were more likely to

complete high school than similar children who did not attend Head Start. Deming (2009) finds

strong positive effects of Head Start on a summary index of young adult outcomes using data

from the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth.

Child Care for All Children Other studies have looked at child care or preschool for much broader groups of children. For

instance, a universal 4-year-old prekindergarten program in Tulsa Oklahoma has demonstrated

the strong positive cognitive and language effects of a well-designed prekindergarten. Strong

effects on measures of pre-reading, pre-math and language were found for both disadvantaged

and middle-class children, and from different racial and ethnic groups (with, in general,

Page 116: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

106

somewhat larger effects for disadvantaged and both Black and Hispanic children, but

substantial positive effects for all children).

The Oklahoma results were partly due to the very high quality of prekindergarten services

provided. Prekindergarten services were provided in the schools by teachers who had both a

teaching certificate and a certificate in early childhood education, and who were paid at public

school rates. Classroom sizes were capped at 20 children, and, with one lesser-trained

assistant, this meant that staff-child ratios were 1:10 (Gormley, Gayer, Phillips and Dawson,

2005).

Recently, Felfe, Nollenberger and Rodriguez-Planas (2015) have studied the introduction of

universal child care for 3-year-olds in Spain and found sizeable improvements in children’s

reading skills at age 15 and evidence of a reduction in grade retention in earlier years.

Dumas and Lefranc (2012) study the effects of a major increase in preschool (i.e., écoles

maternelles) in France in the 1960s and 1970s, assessing the long-run impact of preschool

attendance on later schooling and employment outcomes. The effects were sizeable and long-

lasting, with children who attended preschool having more success in school and obtaining

higher wages once employed, in a study controlling well for selection bias (see Warren et al,

2016, for a summary). These effects are driven by what happens to lower- and middle-class

children, so one effect of preschool is to narrow inequalities amongst children.

Warren and Haisken-DeNew (2014) study the effects of preschool programs in Australia in the

year prior to formal schooling. They look at results for children in Year 3 of school on NAPLAN

(the National Assessment Program – Literacy and Numeracy). They find that children attending

preschool, particularly those with well-qualified teachers, did significantly better on all five

NAPLAN domains. These results controlled statistically for the socioeconomic background of

students, their prior cognitive abilities and the strength of the child’s home learning

environment.

Havnes and Mogstad (2011a) examine the long-term effects of the introduction of universal

access to early childhood education and care for 3-6-year-olds in Norway in the 1970’s. A

difference-in-differences design, based on differential implementation of the program by

municipalities, finds strong positive effects on long-term child outcomes. An increase of 17,500

child care spaces results in about 6,200 additional years of education measured thirty years

later. There are also significant increases in labour market participation for these children

when they grow up, and reduced welfare dependency.

Black, Devereux, Loken and Salvanes (2014) studied the long-term effects of attending nearly

universal child care in Norway in a later period - the early 1990s. The authors use sharp

discontinuities in the price of child care by income in Norway to statistically identify the role of

child care attendance on the later academic achievement of children.

Page 117: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

107

They find that 3-5-year-old children attending good quality Norwegian child care have better

grades in junior high school. They suggest that a major mechanism is the increase in effective

income in families when child care is made less expensive.

In summary, there are very good reasons to believe that some forms of centre-based child

care/preschool/prekindergarten can have important positive effects on children, whether these

children are disadvantaged and low-income and from lone-parent families or whether these

children are from middle-income and two-parent families.

However, the evidence is complex. Not every experience will be positive; the magnitude of

effects will differ, the level of quality will matter, what happens to parenting practices may

matter, the size of the impact will depend on what type and quality of care the early childhood

education and care services replace.

In considering the effects of early childhood education and care, it is important to recognize

that nearly every study finds that the effects on “disadvantaged” children are more strongly

positive than for children who are less disadvantaged. These services do not need to be

targeted interventions; ordinary ECEC programs, and particularly higher quality ECEC programs,

that are widely available to children, have also been found to narrow child outcome gaps

(Cleveland, 2017; Duncan and Sojourner, 2013; Havnes and Mogstad, 2015). In a number of

studies, strong positive effects for immigrant children are also found (Dhuey, 2011; Drange and

Telle, 2010; Spiess et al., 2003)

Quality and type of care matters There are a very large number of factors that can affect a child’s development and behaviour.

The effect sizes measured in research appear to be dependent on two main factors: the quality

and type of child care/ early education they receive, and the quality (support and stimulation)

of the care the children would have alternatively received (often related to the family situation

of the child). The age of the child moderates both of these factors, and the persistence of

improved child outcomes will depend on later classroom experiences (Magnuson, Ruhm, and

Waldfogel, 2007a).

Generally speaking, the quality of early childhood education and care provided is key to the

magnitude of its effects on children’s development. This conclusion comes from a multitude of

studies (see Sylva et al, 2004; Taggart et al., 2015; NICHD-ECCRN and Duncan, 2003; Peisner-

Feinberg et al, 2001; Van Huizen and Plantenga, 2015).

The big short-term effects of the Tulsa, Oklahoma prekindergarten programs (Gormley, Gayer,

Phillips, and Dawson; 2005) appear to be strongly related to the high quality of the services

provided in the schools by teachers who had both a teaching certificate and a certificate in

early childhood education, and who were paid at public school rates. Classroom sizes were

Page 118: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

108

capped at 20 children, and, with one lesser-trained assistant, this meant that staff-child ratios

were 1:10.

The long-lasting character of cognitive effects in Danish centre-based child care (Esping-

Andersen et al., 2012) appears to be related to differences in the average quality of care

relative to the U.S. The results are especially strong for disadvantaged children in Denmark, but

fade out and are not maintained for disadvantaged children in the U.S.

Datta Gupta and Simonsen (2010) find that family day care in Denmark is of worse quality than

centre care in that country. Looking at non-cognitive outcomes, they find that this difference in

quality makes outcomes significantly worse for boys whose mothers have lower levels of

education and who attend family day care.

Effects on parenting can matter a lot

When studies find negative effects of ECEC, these can sometimes be traced to the changed

child-rearing behaviours of parents when child care arrangements change. For instance, Herbst

and Tekin (2014) looking at the effects of child care subsidies available to low-income families

in the U.S. find that in subsidized families there were poorer interactions between parents and

their children when children were in care.

Kottelenberg and Lehrer (2014b) find that the rapid increase in the use of child care in Quebec

had negative effects for some families and some children. In general, they find that boys are

worse off in a variety of behavioral dimensions, ranging from anxiety to hyperactivity and

inattention. The authors trace this back to changes in parental behaviours that were different

for boys than girls

Elizabeth Cascio and Diane Schanzenbach (2013) studied public preschool programs for 4-year-

olds in the U.S. For lower income children, there were positive effects on the amount of time

that mothers spend reading with kids, on mothers’ employment, and on test scores of children

right through 8th grade.

Characteristics of later schooling/care matter

Currie and Thomas (2000) seek to explain why positive effects of Head Start programs on

children’s development appear to fade out more quickly for African-American children than for

White children. After analyzing school quality attended by children after Head Start, they

conclude that the reason is that African-American children typically attend poorer quality

schools once compulsory schooling starts.

Page 119: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

109

Magnuson, Ruhm, and Waldfogel (2007b) analyzed average-quality prekindergartens in the

Early Childhood Longitudinal Study – Kindergarten Cohort (ECLS-K) and found improved reading

and math skills for children attending prekindergarten. These preschool effects did not persist

in small and high instruction classrooms because, in that environment, other children are able

to catch up. However, in large and low instruction classrooms, the preschool advantage

continued to exist, largely due to continuing low performance in that environment of children

cared for exclusively by parents (Magnuson, Ruhm, & Waldfogel, 2007b). The longer-term

effects of early childhood experience partly depend on classroom experiences during at least

the first years of school.

Effects depend on the nature of the alternative care that is replaced

Cascio (2009) finds that the introduction of universal kindergartens into public schools had

long-term positive effects (on high school dropout rates and institutionalization rates) for white

children but not for black children. After investigating alternative possible explanations, she

concludes that kindergarten funding crowded out attendance at Head Start and other early

education programs that may have had similar or even more positive effects for many black

children.

It has often been said that this is one main reason why developmental effects on low-income

children are stronger than for higher-income children. For low-income children, access to

centre-based ECEC of reasonable quality may be replacing care by a relative, neighbour or

parent. These types of care can be positive of course, but in circumstances where licensed child

care is unaffordable, this alternative care may not be done with motivation and enthusiasm,

but because better alternatives are not available or affordable.

Socioemotional/behavioural effects

Intensive early intervention projects such as Perry Preschool, Chicago Child-Parent Centres, and

Abecedarian have had both strongly positive cognitive and language effects on children, but

have also had strongly positive socio-emotional or behavioural effects. In fact, James Heckman

and his colleagues (Heckman, 2007; Heckman et al., 2006; Heckman and Mosso, 2014; Cunha

and Heckman, 2009) have argued that these non-cognitive advances – the ability to

concentrate, the emotional disposition to share and co-operate, reductions in aggressive

behavioural tendencies, abilities to self-regulate – are of key importance to beginning a virtuous

cycle of learning ability.

However, there have been frequent suggestions that child care, particularly when it is of less

than adequate quality, can have negative effects on these non-cognitive traits. For instance,

the NICHD-ECCRN (2006) said that, amongst children using ordinary child care of different kinds

Page 120: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

110

in the U.S., better quality of child care was related to better socioemotional and peer outcomes

at some ages. However, more child care hours over the child’s life predicted more behaviour

problems and conflict, as reported by care providers. And although more time in centre-based

care was related to higher cognitive and language scores, it was also related to more problem

behaviours and fewer prosocial behaviours, as reported by care providers.

Magnuson, Ruhm and Waldfogel (2007a) found attendance at prekindergarten programs in the

U.S. is associated with improved academic skills in kindergarten, but also with higher levels of

behaviour problems. However, program quality moderates behaviour problems;

prekindergartens located in public schools did not have adverse behavioural impacts.

Baker, Gruber and Milligan (2008) found a pattern of negative socio-emotional and behavioural

effects of the Quebec child care reforms in the late 1990’s. The universal child care initiative

dramatically increased the use of regulated child care over time, and had strong positive effects

on maternal labour supply. However, the authors find that on socio-emotional measures such

as aggression and hyperactivitiy/inattention, children in Quebec did worse than similar children

in the rest of Canada over the same period. It has been suggested (Ruhm and Waldfogel, 2012)

that the large expansion of low-quality family day care was partially responsible for these

negative effects.

Kottelenberg and Lehrer (2013a, 2013b, and 2014b) re-examine these results to determine the

origins of negative effects. For instance, Kottelenberg and Lehrer find that negative effects are

concentrated in children who begin the use of child care at young ages (2013b). There are

positive developmental effects found for children above 3 years of age. Second, as described

above, the authors find that negative socio-emotional and behavioural effects are found only

for boys. These negative effects appear to have been fostered by changes in parenting

practices and home environments of parents with boy children. The authors find positive

effects on behaviours for children who are most disadvantaged.

In a companion analysis using different techniques (2013a), Kottelenberg and Lehrer find that

the average effect of child care across Canada including Quebec is positive for motor and social

development and is not significantly negative for any socio-emotional or behavioural indicator.

Kottelenberg and Lehrer’s results make it clear that when it comes to assessing the impacts of

early childhood education and care services on children, the details matter enormously.

Positive effects and negative effects are both possible, depending on quality and type of care,

child and family background, gender, child age, and the impact of new programs on parenting

behaviours.

Lebihan, Haeck and Merrigan (2015) provide a very useful follow-up study of the effects of

Quebec’s child care reforms. They find that negative effects on health, behaviour and motor

and social development found by Baker et al. (2008) disappear over time in two ways. First,

Page 121: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

111

there are not long-lasting negative effects as children get older, into their school years. And

second, negative non-cognitive effects of the child care system on Quebec children 0-4 years of

age declined each year and disappeared by 2008-2009, the last year for which data are

available. In other words, many problems were associated with problems of growth and

transition.

Although governments worry about how much child care promotes cognitive and social

development, parents are often especially concerned that their children are happy and that

they build positive relationships with their peers and their educators. Although the literature

does not concentrate on the happiness of children, it is clear that good child care focusing on

play-based learning and promoting positive social attitudes and behaviours can make children

and parents happier in their daily lives.

4.2 CONCLUSIONS

Improving the affordability of child care is likely to have positive effects on parental

employment and incomes. It will make it easier for families to balance the demands of work

and family life. It will open opportunities and improve conditions for women’s participation in

employment and study.

Increased parental employment will also reduce the net cost of funding new child care

programs, because parental employment increases tax revenues, reduces social assistance and

other benefits payable and may contribute positively to economic growth.

There is substantial and persuasive evidence that early childhood education and care can

promote children’s cognitive and language development, and social and emotional capacities

and can provide them positive everyday experiences that contribute to their well-being. The

effects of early childhood education and care are not homogeneous. Therefore, it is a

continuing goal of policy to ensure that impacts are positive for all children. This has

implications for the quality of care, for the complementarity of parental and non-parental care,

for tailoring experiences to children’s needs, and for the importance of later school

experiences.

Page 122: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

112

CHAPTER 5: THE AFFORDABILITY PROBLEM

Chapter Summary

Child care fees in Ontario range from about $9,000 to over $20,000 per child per year

for children 0-4 years.

There is substantial regional and age variation in fees, but they are high everywhere

relative to incomes, and have been rising faster than inflation.

The Family Income Affordability Measure (FIAM) calculates the net fee parents have to

pay to get licensed child care for their children 0-6 years as a percent of expected family

income after taxes and benefits.

The Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure (CPAM) calculates the average net fee

parents have to pay as a percent of the after-tax income contribution that the main

caregiving parent will make to family income if employed. The main caregiving parent is

the one whose work or study activities are most closely linked to the decision to use

child care.

For families that have at least one child 0-6 years and want to access licensed child care,

we find the average family in Ontario would have to spend 20.8% of after-tax family

income on child care or nearly 60% of the net income contribution of the main

caregiving parent when employed. For families with at least one child 0-4 years, the

average family would have to spend nearly one-quarter (23.5%) of after-tax family

income on child care or just over two-thirds (67%) of the net income contribution of the

main caregiving parent.

For the Family Income Affordability Measure, a net child care expenditure of less than

10% of family income is considered affordable, from 10% to less than 20% is

unaffordable and 20% or more is completely unaffordable.

For the Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure, net child care expenditure of less than

30% of that parent’s income is considered affordable, from 30% to less than 60% is

unaffordable and 60% and above is considered completely unaffordable.

By either measure, fewer than 22% of families find licensed child care to be affordable.

Use of licensed child care and employment of the main caregiving parent is closely

Page 123: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

113

related to these measures of affordability. For families that find child care affordable by

either measure, there is over 63% probability of using licensed child care and over 80%

probability that the main caregiving parent is employed; for families that find child care

unaffordable or completely unaffordable, the corresponding probabilities are much

lower.

With current policies and levels of affordability in Ontario, about 8% of infants use

licensed child care services, about 30% of toddlers and about 37% of children of

preschool age.

Considering only families with employed mothers, over 12% of infants, over 42% of

toddlers and 50% of preschool-aged children currently use licensed child care.

Many families combine parental care of children with employment of all parents in the

household. Parents may arrange their work shifts so that this is possible (off-shifting).

In these cases, the main caregiving parent will often work part-time or be self-employed

in the household. There is evidence that these care decisions are strongly affected by

the unaffordability of paid child care.

The unaffordability of child care affects many aspects of women’s employment, hours,

and pay.

Across the system, parents pay between 50%-63% of the total cost of licensed child care

services in Ontario. Governments pay the rest.

Licensed child care is difficult to afford for many families in Ontario. With one child, the typical

price of child care ranges from about $9,000 per year to over $20,000 per year, depending upon

the child’s age and where you live in the province. At these fee levels, child care is considerably

more expensive than most university programs. With two or more children, the cost of child

care is prohibitive for all but the most affluent families, unless the family is eligible for, and able

to access, child care subsidies directed at lower income families.

5.1 CHILD CARE FEES IN ONTARIO ARE HIGH AND RISING

There are two complementary sources of information about child care fees in Ontario, one

from an annual study by the Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives (CCPA), another from a

survey – a census - conducted by the Ministry of Education in 2015 and 2017. The CCPA survey

(Macdonald and Friendly, 2017) is conducted in cities (and selected rural areas) by telephone.

It includes services provided by both centres and family homes. Our data from the Ministry of

Education survey includes only centres, but includes centres whether in cities, small towns or

rural areas.

Page 124: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

114

Tables 26 and 27 below show median fee levels in cities and rural areas across Ontario, from Macdonald and Friendly (2017). Table 26 shows the median monthly fee and Table 27 provides the same information but on an annual basis; it makes the comparison to family incomes easier.

Table 26

Median Monthly Fee for Care in Child Care Centres and Homes,

Selected Ontario Cities and Rural Areas, 2017

Infants Toddlers Preschoolers

Windsor $988 $879 $781

London $1,217 $1,120 $1,010

Kitchener $1,325 $1,085 $975

Hamilton $1,062 $1,052 $931

Brampton $955 $1,128 $1,050

Mississauga $1,452 $1,200 $1,052

Vaughan $1,415 $1,150 $1,031

Toronto $1,758 $1,354 $1,212

Markham $1,150 $1,120 $1,017

Ottawa $988 $1,109 $1,009

Rural Eastern Ontario

$927 $868 $825

Rural Central Ontario

$1,085 $1,020 $911

Rural South-West Ontario

$939 $846 $781

Rural Northern Ontario

$868 $825 $825

Source: Macdonald and Friendly (2017)

Page 125: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

115

Table 27

Median Annual Fee for Full-time Care in Child Care Centres and Homes,

Selected Ontario Cities and Rural Areas, 2017

Infants Toddlers Preschoolers

Windsor $11,976 $10,548 $9,372

London $14,604 $13,440 $12,120

Kitchener $15,900 $13,020 $11,700

Hamilton $12,744 $12,624 $11,172

Brampton $11,460 $13,536 $12,600

Mississauga $17,424 $14,400 $12,624

Vaughan $16,980 $13,800 $12,372

Toronto $21,096 $16,248 $14,544

Markham $13,800 $13,440 $12,204

Ottawa $11,976 $13,308 $12,108

Rural Eastern Ontario

$11,124 $10,416 $9,900

Rural Central Ontario

$13,020 $12,240 $10,932

Rural South-West Ontario

$11,268 $10,152 $9,372

Rural Northern Ontario

$10,416 $9,900 $9,900

Source: Macdonald and Friendly (2017)

These annual fees are high relative to typical family incomes, and especially in comparison to

the income of the main caregiving parent who may have to sacrifice employment and pay if

child care is unaffordable. Fees in Toronto are particularly high, but are noticeably high in other

parts of the GTA. Even in rural areas of Ontario, where incomes are often lower, fees for

licensed child care are between about $9,000 and $13,000, annually, varying by the child’s age.

Page 126: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

116

According to Macdonald and Friendly (2017), preschool fees have increased by less than the

rate of inflation in only one of Ontario’s surveyed cities – Kitchener. In all other Ontario cities,

the rise in fees from 2014 to 2017 has been higher than inflation, often considerably higher.

Administrative data collected by the Ministry of Education confirm the picture sketched by

Macdonald and Friendly. Table 28 shows median daily and annual child care centre fees for

Infants, Toddlers and Preschoolers from the Child Care Operators’ Survey of 2017. This is a

survey with responses from over 5,300 licensed centres in Ontario. The centres are grouped

into regions and the median full fee for each age category is tabulated across centres.

Table 28

Median Daily and Annual Fees for Full-time Care in a Child Care Centre,

by Age Category and Region of Ontario, 2017

Daily Annual

Infant Toddler Preschool Infant Toddler Preschool

Toronto $85.00 $66.00 $52.00 $22,185 $17,226 $13,572

West Toronto $66.95 $52.55 $46.25 $17,474 $13,716 $12,071

Central $57.50 $48.86 $42.84 $15,008 $12,752 $11,181

Southwest $55.45 $48.40 $42.00 $14,472 $12,632 $10,962

East $61.00 $51.00 $43.34 $15,921 $13,311 $11,312

North $51.00 $42.00 $38.00 $13,311 $10,962 $9,918

Source: Ministry of Education, 2017

Infant care is substantially more expensive than toddler care, which is substantially more

expensive than preschool care. This is largely driven by differences in staffing ratios. Infants

need to have three caregivers in the room for every ten infant children. Toddlers require a

ratio of one caregiver to every five children. Preschool children have a required ratio of one to

eight.

There is strong regional variation as well. Toronto fees are substantially higher than in other

regions, partly, as we will see, because wages are higher in Toronto centres, but also because

real estate charges (occupancy expenses) are typically higher in the Toronto region. Fees are

lower in the Northern region, partly because municipalities in the North allocate a larger share

of their funding to the General Operating Grant which tends to lower fees. Municipalities can

also keep fees low with contributions from their own budgets.

Page 127: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

117

Fee information has been gathered using the Child Care Operators’ Survey in both 2015 and

2017 in Ontario. Table 29 below shows that there have been rises in the median fee level for

each age category in each region over the 2015-2017 period, with the exception of infants in

the North. Otherwise, the rate of rise has been between 2.0% and 10.6% in each fee category.

Over the same period, from March 2015 to March 2017, the all-items Consumer Price Index for

Ontario rose by 3.4%. The typical fee rise for child care is greater than inflation over the period.

Table 29

Percent Change in Median Full-Time Fee in a Child Care Centre,

by Age Category and Region of Ontario, 2015-2017

Infants Toddlers Preschool

Toronto 2.7% 3.2% 8.3%

West Toronto 5.1% 5.1% 2.8%

Central 10.6% 8.6% 7.1%

Southwest 9.8% 7.6% 5.0%

East 8.2% 2.0% 3.7%

North 0.0% 5.0% 2.7%

5.2 CHILD CARE IS UNAFFORDABLE FOR MOST FAMILIES

Child care fees are, of course, not a measure of affordability of child care. The fees need to be

compared to the incomes that families have available.

We have developed two measures of the affordability of licensed child care: the Family Income

Affordability Measure (FIAM) and the Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure (CPAM).

The Family Income Affordability Measure (FIAM) calculates, for each family, the ratio of the net

price of licensed child care to the total expected income of the family after taxes and after any

child and family benefits (such as the Canada Child Benefit). The FIAM is a measure of the

inequality of burden that child care imposes on different families – it is a family-specific

measure. It is measured as a percentage; a high number means that child care is unaffordable

– it takes up a large proportion of the take-home income of the family.

Page 128: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

118

A second measure of affordability is closely related to the decision of families to use licensed

child care or not and of the main caregiving parent to be employed. The Caregiving Parent

Affordability Measure (CPAM) is based on the income that the main caregiving parent7 might be

able to earn. It is her decision to be employed (particularly, full-time employed) that most

often triggers the demand for a regular child care arrangement. The employment decision will

probably involve weighing up the expected net income contribution that this parent makes to

household income vis-a-vis the net cost of child care. The CPAM calculates this ratio - the net

price of licensed care divided by the expected net income contribution if this parent is

employed. When the fee for child care is a very substantial proportion of expected earnings,

this parent is much more likely not to be employed, or to seek informal child care arrangements

(often parent or relative care) that have a low dollar cost. The CPAM is an affordability

measure that is particularly relevant when a policy maker is considering the possibility of how

affordability relates to changes in employment and child care type used.

Both of these measures are based on the cost of care for children 0-6 years of age in a family

(note: not just the children who are 0-4 years of age). In other words, affordability is measured

on a family basis, aggregated over your children younger than compulsory school age. The

details of these two measures are described in more depth in the Technical Report to the City

of Toronto study on affordability of licensed child care (Cleveland, Krashinsky, Colley and Avery-

Nunez, 2016b).

It is not clear where the dividing line between “affordability” and “unaffordability” should be

drawn. Ultimately, that is a question for politicians, policy makers and advocates to answer.

For the purposes of providing snapshots of affordability, we have adopted the following

conventions for the Family Income Affordability Measure. We will consider licensed child care

to be “affordable” if a family can access it for their 0-6-year-old children for less than 10% of

after-tax, after-benefit family income (i.e., less than 10% of family disposable income), for any

number of children. If licensed child care costs 10% to 19.99% of net family income, we will call

it “unaffordable”. If purchasing licensed child care costs 20% or more of total family income

after taxes and benefits, we will say that licensed child care is “completely unaffordable” for

that family. As you will see, employment and child care decisions are closely related to whether

child care is affordable or not.

A different set of conventions applies to the Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure. We will

consider licensed child care to be “affordable” if a family can access it for their 0-6-year-old

7 The main caregiving parent is not necessarily the mother. In the case of a single parent father, he is the main caregiving

parent. In the case of two gay male parents, the one earning the lower income is considered the main caregiving parent.

Because our data sets do not provide information on who the family considers to be the main caregiving parent, we assume the

mother takes this role in heterosexual couples.

Page 129: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

119

children for less than 30% of the after-tax, after-benefit earnings contribution that the

“mother” would make to family income if employed (i.e., less than 30% of her net

contribution). If licensed child care costs 30% to 59.99% of her net contribution, we will call it

“unaffordable”. If purchasing licensed child care costs 60% or more of her earnings

contribution after taxes and benefits, we will say that licensed child care is “completely

unaffordable” for that family. Again, we will see that this measure of the affordability of

licensed child care is closely related to child care and employment behaviours.

Table 30 indicates that fewer than 20% of Ontario families with at least one infant, toddler or

preschool aged child can be said to be able to afford licensed child care. For most families,

using licensed child care would consume 10% or more of their disposable after-tax, after-

benefit income. Another 35% of families would use up between 10% and 20% of their available

household income if they were to purchase licensed child care. And nearly half of all Ontario

families with children younger than kindergarten age (46%) find licensed child care to be

completely unaffordable – using it would consume 20% or more of their total available

household income.

Table 30

Affordability of Licensed Child Care in Ontario in 2017 for Families

with at least One Child Younger than Kindergarten Age (i.e., 0-4 Years)

based on the Family Income Affordability Measure (FIAM)

Note: Does not include families with parents on maternity or parental leave. These calculations are based on family characteristics and spousal income data from the National Household Survey (NHS) of 2011, child care fee levels from the 2017 Child Care Operators’ Survey and income of the main caregiving parent projected using the September 2016 Labour Force Survey. Income and payroll taxes and benefits for each family in the NHS are calculated using CTaCs (Canadian Tax and Credit Simulator; Milligan, 2016). Results are weighted to population totals, using Statistics Canada weights.

Across all Ontario families with children younger than compulsory school age, the average value

of this Family Income Affordability Measure is 20.8%, meaning the average family would

currently have to spend over 20% of their after-tax, after-benefit income to access licensed

child care services, even after taking account of the improvements in affordability brought

about by the child care subsidy system for a substantial number of families.

Degree of Affordability Number of Families Percent of Families

Affordable (< 10% of net family income) 85,495 19.0%

Unaffordable (10%-19.9% of net family income) 156,880 34.9%

Completely Unaffordable (20% or more of net family income)

207,580 46.1%

TOTAL 449,950 100.0%

Page 130: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

120

We find a quite similar pattern of unaffordability using the Caregiving Parent Affordability

Measure. This measure compares the extra income that the main caregiving parent is

projected to be capable of earning (if she is able to obtain child care and enter the workforce).

The after-tax, after-benefit contribution that her employment would bring to the family is

compared to the net price of child care (after benefits such as the Child Care Expense Deduction

that reduce the net price of child care for families). For only about 22% of families is the cost of

child care less than 30% of the contribution from her earnings. For another 33% of families, the

net cost of licensed child care would be between 30% and 60% of the contribution from her

Table 31

Affordability of Licensed Child Care in Ontario in 2017 for Families with at least One Child

Younger than Kindergarten Age (i.e., 0-4 Years) Based on the Caregiving Parent Affordability

Measure (CPAM)

Degree of Affordability Number of Families Percent of Families

Affordable (< 30% of main caregiving parent’s income contribution)

98,285 21.8%

Unaffordable (30%-59.9% of main caregiving parent’s income contribution)

148,465 33.0%

Completely Unaffordable (60% or more of main caregiving parent’s income contribution)

203,205 45.2%

TOTAL 449,950 100%

Note: Does not include families with parents on maternity or parental leave. These calculations are based on family characteristics and spousal income data from the National Household Survey (NHS) of 2011, child care fee levels from the 2017 Child Care Operators’ Survey and income of the main caregiving parent projected using the September 2016 Labour Force Survey. Income and payroll taxes and benefits for each family in the NHS are calculated using CTaCs (Canadian Tax and Credit Simulator; Milligan, 2016). Results are weighted to population totals, using Statistics Canada weights.

earnings. And for fully 45% of families, the net cost of child care would eat up 60% or more of

her net contribution to the family’s well-being.

This second affordability measure is particularly important for looking at whether the price of

licensed child care is a major barrier to having and maintaining employment for caregiving

parents (most often the mother). As Table 31 shows, for many families, the fees they must pay

to access licensed child care dramatically reduce the returns to the family from her

employment, and discourage continued labour force participation.

Across all Ontario families with children younger than compulsory school age, the average value

of this Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure is 58.1%, meaning that for the average family

close to 60% of the net income contribution made by employment of the main caregiving

parent would be eaten up by the net cost of licensed care for their children not yet in Grade 1.

Page 131: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

121

These calculations already take into account the improvements in affordability brought about

by the child care subsidy system for a substantial number of families.

5.3 AFFORDABILITY OF CHILD CARE AFFECTS PARENT

DECISIONS

It is no surprise, then, that our affordability measures and the probability of being employed

full-time are strongly related. Tables 32 and 33 provide projections from our statistical model

about the ways in which affordability is likely to affect the decision to use licensed child care

and full-time employment. The results confirm in most dramatic fashion that affordability

matters.

The more affordable licensed child care is, the higher the probability of using licensed care and

of being employed full-time. Over 60% of families for whom licensed care is affordable on the

family income measure (FIAM) will demand licensed care, and over 80% will be employed full-

time. When licensed child care is unaffordable, the probability of demanding licensed care is

cut in half and the probability of being employed full-time drops below 60%. When licensed

care is completely unaffordable, both the likelihood of using it and the probability of being

employed full-time fall substantially, as shown in Table 32.

The same story emerges from our other affordability measure (CPAM) in Table 33. The more

affordable licensed child care is, the more likely it will be used and the more likely the main

caregiving parent will be employed full-time. In other words, the price of licensed child care is a

major barrier to children gaining access to licensed care and to the full employment of parents.

Page 132: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

122

Table 32

Probability of Using Licensed Child Care and Full-Time Employment by Affordability of

Licensed Child Care (Measured By FIAM)

Degree of Affordability Probability of using licensed care (% of families)

Probability of parent (MCP) being employed full-time (%)

Affordable (< 10% of net family income)

62.9% 80.9%

Unaffordable (10%-19.9% of net family income)

31.9% 59.7%

Completely Unaffordable 20% or more of net family income)

11.1% 32.2%

Average of all families 29.0% 54.6%

Source: Behavioural estimates of demand for licensed child care and employment supply are derived from a statistical model

using the National Household Survey, resident in Statistics Canada’s Research Data Centre at the University of Toronto.

Table 33

Probability of Using Licensed Child Care and Full-Time Employment by Affordability of

Licensed Child Care (Measured By CPAM)

Degree of Affordability Probability of using licensed care (% of

families)

Probability of main caregiving parent being employed full-time

(%)

Affordable (< 30% of main caregiving parent’s income contribution)

65.0% 88.7%

Unaffordable (30%-59.9% of main caregiving parent’s income

contribution)

31.3% 60.3%

Completely Unaffordable (60% or more of main caregiving parent’s

income contribution)

7.7% 20.4%

Average across all families 29.0% 54.6%

Source: Behavioural estimates of demand for licensed child care and employment supply are derived from a statistical model

using the National Household Survey, resident in Statistics Canada’s Research Data Centre at the University of Toronto.

The problem of affordability does not emerge because all families with young children are poor,

not employed, or only employed in temporary or insecure jobs. In many families with young

children, parents are fully employed, sometimes in secure employment, earning reasonable

incomes (for their occupation and job experience) and paying substantial taxes. However, the

Page 133: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

123

period when children are young is also the period of life when young families do not yet have

much employment experience, are low down on the career ladder and are trying to move up.

Frequently, parents are trying to buy a condo or house, renovate it to accommodate children,

accumulate furnishings for the house, and spend a considerable amount on goods and services

for young children. It is a difficult financial time for many families. Balancing the competing

needs of work and family is frequently difficult.

Table 34 below depicts the distribution of family income (before tax) for Ontario families with

children 0-5 years of age, inclusive. The data is recent – from the 2016 Census – and refers to

earnings in the 2015 calendar year. As you can see, there are 513,110 couple families with

children 0-5 and 109,560 lone parent families with children 0-5. The median income for these

couple families is $94,349 annually. The median income for these lone parent families is

$30,117.

Our particular interest is in families with children 0-4 years of age (inclusive), but publicly

available data did not provide incomes broken down in this way. However, population figures

are available from the 2016 Census for 0-4. The count of 0-4 children in Ontario from the

Census is 695,875 children (or about 139,175 on average in every birth year cohort). 582,240 of

these children are in two parent families and another 107,090 are in single parent families

(there are a few in "other" families). So, about 15% of children 0-4 are from lone parent

families.

Of course, affordability of licensed child care is strongly related to family income. Table 35

below estimates the average level of affordability by household income level. Child care is

much less affordable for those with lower levels of expected income. And yet, it is also true

that, on average, the cost of licensed child care will eat up more than 10% of disposable family

income even in families earning $100,000 and more annually.

This latter point is even more true when we look at the average values of the Caregiving Parent

Affordability Measure in Table 35. CPAM reflects the barriers to employment faced by many

mothers. And, while these barriers are lower in more affluent families, the cost of child care

eats up close to half of a mother’s expected net income from employment even in more

affluent households. The issue of child care affordability is not restricted to low-income

families and the solutions to the problems posed by child care (un)affordability need to help

families well beyond this group.

Page 134: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

124

Table 34

Number of Families, by Family Income in Ontario with Children 0-5 Years of Age, 2015

Lone Parent Families

Couple Families Total Families

$0 - $9,999 10,395 8,340 18,735

$10,000 - $19,999 19,350 7,605 26,955

$20,000 - $29,999 24,775 16,745 41,520

$30,000 - $39,999 19,025 28,250 47,275

$40,000 - $49,999 12,545 34,105 46,650

$50,000 - $59,999 7,880 36,405 44,285

$60,000 - $69,999 4,910 36,770 41,680

$70,000 - $79,999 3,060 36,720 39,780

$80,000 - $89,999 2,240 36,325 38,565

$90,000 - $99,999 1,715 34,720 36,435

$100,000 - $124,999 2,145 74,495 76,640

$125,000 - $149,999 710 55,000 55,710

$150,000 - $199,999 470 62,500 62,970

$200,000 and more 335 45,125 45,460

TOTALS 109,555 513,105 622,660

Source: 2016 Census, Statistics Canada

Page 135: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

125

Table 35

Affordability by Expected Family Income Level in Ontario Families with Children Younger than

Compulsory School Age

5.4 THE CURRENT LEVEL OF THE DEMAND FOR CHILD CARE

Affordability and other factors combine to produce current patterns of parental employment,

demand for paid child care and decisions to have children cared for entirely within the family.

We would like to have a clear picture of the child care decisions that families currently make,

but that requires current data. The Ministry of Education collects information from providers

about the total supply of licensed child care of different types. However, surprisingly, there has

been no province-wide data collection about the factors affecting the demand for licensed child

care since 2010-2011.

Although child care services are primarily a provincial responsibility under the Canadian

constitution, the collection of data by Statistics Canada is entirely a federal responsibility. It is

unclear why the federal government no longer considers it a priority to collect information

about children’s development and child care. This was a priority in the 1990s and 2000s and

the data collected then has helped to produce many important studies and to facilitate

governmental decisions about children. It would make sense for municipal and provincial

governments and children’s advocates to pressure the federal government to find a

replacement now for the National Longitudinal Survey of Children and Youth (NLSCY) and

associated studies. Alternatively, as in Quebec, the Ontario government will have to collect its

own survey data on child care demand and children’s development.

Expected Annual Income of the Household

Average of Family Income Affordability Measure

Average Level of Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure

Less than $50,000 30.8% 61.7%

$50,000 - $99,999 21.2% 69.5%

$100,000 and more 12.7% 44.2%

Total 20.8% 58.1%

Page 136: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

126

In the absence of current data, we have analyzed patterns of child care demand in 2010-2011

using the Survey of Young Canadians (a one-time cross-sectional survey based on the NLSCY

questionnaire), applied these results to Ontario data from the National Household Survey of

2011, and then updated these results using Ministry of Education supply data from 2017.

This gives us the patterns of demand for different types of child care and employment

arrangements shown in the table below.

Table 36

Projected Demand for Child Care Arrangements by Age Category, 2017

Source: Statistical model resident in the Research Data Centre, University of Toronto.

Note: Infants being cared for by parents while on maternity/parental leave are not included in the table (this is really a separate

category of care). The percentage of infants in parent or relative care while parents are employed in this table is slightly

overstated because we are not able to account for the increased use of maternity/parental leave between 2011 and 2017.

Considering these four distinct types of care, licensed child care is used for a minority of infants,

but for more toddlers or preschool-aged children than other arrangements. In fact, when we

consider children having employed mothers, fully 50% of preschool-aged children use licensed

child care, and nearly 43% of toddlers use licensed child care in Ontario. Despite affordability

problems, there is considerable evidence of parental desire to give their children a licensed

group experience when they are young.

Percent of All Children Percent of All Children

of Employed Mothers

Type of Care Arrangement

Infants (0-17

months)

Toddlers (18-29

months)

Preschool

(30 months – kindergarten)

Infants (0-17

months)

Toddlers (18-29

months)

Preschool

(30 months – kindergarten)

Licensed Child Care

7.8% 30.0% 37.0% 12.4% 42.6% 50.0%

Unlicensed Paid Child Care

19.0% 16.1% 15.2% 31.3% 22.9% 20.4%

Parent or Relative Care While Parents

Employed

34.0% 24.3% 21.9% 55.8% 34.6% 29.6%

Parent at Home, not Employed

39.1% 29.5% 25.9% n.a. n.a. n.a.

TOTAL 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Page 137: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

127

Informal paid care (unlicensed paid care provided either in the caregiver’s home or the child’s

home) is widely used for infants, but less so for toddlers or preschoolers.

It is a surprise to many that so many children with employed mothers are cared for entirely

within the family, sometimes by relatives, but most frequently by the parents themselves.

Some of these families are “off-shifting” – shifts are arranged so that one parent is always

available to provide care. Frequently, instead, one parent (more frequently the mother) will

work out of the home and provide care for the child at the same time as she works. In both the

case of off-shifting or work at home, it is generally the case that the employed mother will be

working part-time. Cleveland, Krashinsky and Forer (2015) show that care provided by parents

while they are employed is strongly related to lower incomes and lower levels of completed

education. In other words, the prevalence of parental care while parents are employed can be

viewed as a symptom of the affordability problem.

5.5 WHY AFFORDABILITY OF CHILD CARE IS ALSO A

WOMEN’S ISSUE

More affordable regulated child care may be positive for children’s development, and it may

increase GDP through its short and long-term effects on employment. But these “productivity

effects” are not the only reasons why governments care about child care affordability.

Governments also care about the effects on economic inequality among families. If access to

child care narrows developmental disparities between children from different backgrounds and

increases earnings and employment opportunities for parents who are economically

disadvantaged, governments may consider child care spending to be a good investment.

Intertwined with these rationales for government spending on child care, governments are

likely to want to spend money on child care in order to reduce the economic burden of child

rearing for mothers of young children. They might describe this as advancing policies that

contribute to work-family balance. In other words, child care is important because it can

change the economic opportunities available for women (Cleveland, 2017).

Women now far outnumber men among recent college graduates in most industrialized

countries (OECD, 2008). Girls do better in school, both cognitively and behaviourally. Logically,

women should now be earning more than men and taking the preponderance of leadership

roles in the economy. But, women are not. A central reason seems to be that women are

primarily responsible for child rearing.

The motherhood pay gap measures the hourly pay gap between mothers with dependent

children and all other women. Victor Fuchs (1988) was the first to identify a motherhood gap in

wages – a gap of 7%-9% in wages between the earnings of women without children and those

with children, after holding constant observable differences between these two groups of

Page 138: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

128

women. Waldfogel and Pal (2014) have found that, in the U.S., there has been no change in the

overall size of this motherhood gap in pay over the period 1977-2007. Drolet (2002) finds that

women who delay having children earn 6% more than workers who have children early, with all

other factors held constant. Caranci and Gauthier (2010) find that career interruptions play a

big role.

Carole Vincent (2013) summarizes a wide range of evidence helping to explain why women

earn less than men. The gap in average hourly wages between women who are working full-

time and men who are working full-time in Canada in 2011 is 13% - women’s wages are 87% of

men’s wages. The hourly full-time wage gap is much smaller than before (24% in 1988), but it

persists despite enormous changes in women’s employment and education. Vincent identifies

four main hypotheses, not mutually exclusive, to explain this continuing wage gap:

women’s choice of low-paid occupations,

choice of lower paid jobs because of their non-pecuniary characteristics,

women’s choice of jobs with greater work-life balance because of their role as

main caregivers for children and family members, and

gender stereotypes in workplace organizational practices that value men’s

employment patterns.

Every one of these explanations is closely related to women’s caregiving roles and the way that

caregiving responsibilities shape the educational and occupational choices that girls make, the

decisions to work part-time, to take time off for parental leave, to take time off to care for sick

children, to refuse jobs that are time inflexible and the types of average workforce behaviours

that are punished by gender stereotypes (Kleven, Landais and Sogaard, 2018).

Perhaps it is no surprise that the OECD (2012) finds that across the OECD the gender wage gap

for workers without children is relatively small (6.6%), but that the gender wage gap for

workers with children is several times as large. And, despite the enormous changes in mothers’

workforce roles, women still spend more than twice as much time each week as men do

providing primary child care for children (Statistics Canada, 2011)

5.6 THE SIZE OF PARENTS’ SHARE

Another perspective on the child care affordability problem is gained by looking at the share of

child care costs borne by families, in comparison to the share borne by government. This

calculation can only be approximate and indicative, but it is useful nonetheless.

Governments spend substantial amounts on child care – in 2017, the combination of provincial

and municipal expenditures in Ontario amounts to $1.44 billion. Much of this is spent on child

Page 139: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

129

care subsidies directed at low- and middle-income families – close to $800 million under

different spending envelopes. Approximately, another $450 million is spent either through the

General Operating Grant, or to support the very low wages of child care workers in different

ways. This latter $450 million can be viewed as keeping the fees charged to parents lower than

they would otherwise have been (either directly, or indirectly through the support of wages).

We know the median fee levels for child care in different age categories and in different regions

across the province. And we know the number of children in different age categories that are

currently using licensed child care. Most of this child care is full-time for children below

kindergarten age. We can use the full-time fee levels for infants, toddlers and preschoolers,

and the before-and-after school fee levels for children of kindergarten age to make an

approximate calculation of the total expenditure and the parental share for families with

children 0-6 years.

The total amount of child care expenditure at full-fee levels across the province would be just

slightly more than $2.9 billion ($2.917 billion). In fact, since about $450 million has been spent

lowering the average level of fees and supporting wages, we can conclude that the bulked-up

full level of expenditure would be about $3.367 billion. Of course, not all families are paying full

fees. As mentioned above, about $800 million is spent on child care subsidies annually.

Table 37 lays out the main numbers.

Table 37

Calculation of Parental Share of Total Cost of Child Care

amongst Current Users of Licensed Child Care

Costs/expenditures Amount in millions of dollars

Percent of total

Full Cost of Child Care Services at Current Use Levels

$3,367 100.0%

Government Expenditure on Lowering Fees/Supporting Wages

$450 13.4%

Government Expenditure on Child Care Subsidies

$800 23.8%

Expenditure by Parents $2,117 62.9%

In other words, despite substantial spending by governments, parents still pay the bulk of the

costs of child care. Since only about 30% of children who currently use licensed child care have

their fees reduced by the child care subsidy system, the majority of parents (the remaining

Page 140: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

130

70%) are paying an amount which is close to the full cost of providing child care services.

Hence, the province and most of its families have a substantial child care affordability problem.

Of course, this is only a calculation about current users of licensed child care. Families who do

not currently use licensed child care are, we presume, those with the largest affordability

problem.

There are, in addition, funds related to the cost of child care that are paid through the Child

Care Expense Deduction (CCED). The CCED is claimable, typically by the parent with the lower

level of earnings, as a deduction from income before taxes are levied on this parent. In general,

the parent can only get a deduction if there have been legitimate child care expenditures during

the previous year that have assisted that parent in earning income/being employed. The limit

of expenditures that can be claimed is either the total amount of child care costs actually

incurred or $8,000 per child younger than seven years of age, or $5,000 per older child, or

2/3rds of the lower earner’s annual income, whichever of these is less.

Because this deduction is only available if there are child care expenditures, the Child Care

Expense Deduction helps reduce the fee the family would otherwise have to pay for child care.

We calculate that the total amount of the Child Care Expense Deduction (federal and provincial

combined) for children younger than compulsory school age using licensed child care in Ontario

is $412 million annually.

There are two possible interpretations of the role of the Child Care Expense Deduction. One,

which we favour (Cleveland and Krashinsky, 1999), is that the Child Care Expense Deduction

reflects a legitimate and necessary expense of employment for the second earner in a

household (or the primary earner if a lone parent family). This earner should not be taxed on

income that is not really income, but is income that pays for this necessary cost of being

employed.

According to this interpretation, the Child Care Expense Deduction is not a gift to the parent,

but is merely a by-product of taxing her fairly – only on income that is really income. It should

not, therefore, feature in the calculation of the government’s vs. the parents’ share of total

costs.

The second interpretation of the Child Care Expense Deduction is that this is a special benefit

for families with child care costs, and so should be counted as part of the government’s

contribution. According to this interpretation, the value of tax relief due to the Child Care

Expense Deduction should be included in the calculation above. If we did this, the value of the

parents’ contribution would fall to 50.6%.

Page 141: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

131

CHAPTER 6: DIFFERENT CHILD CARE FUNDING

APPROACHES – THE THEORY

Chapter Summary

We seek a funding approach that improves affordability of 0-4-year-old child care for

families, while giving special assistance to lower-income families and maintaining or

improving quality and accessibility.

The market for child care is a mix of public and private, but there is a growing public

interest in keeping fees low and quality high in order to remove barriers to parental

employment and increase children’s access to good services.

Governments who fund child care on the demand side seek to use market mechanisms

to stimulate supply and enhance quality of services.

Supply-side funding recognizes child care as a substantially regulated market, with

private (largely not-for-profit) service providers, but regulated supply, quality, staff

compensation and fees.

There are two major types of sliding scale to subsidize child care. One uses family

income to determine the percent of family income that a family should pay. The second

type of sliding scale uses family income to determine the percent of the full fee that a

particular family has to pay.

Quebec created a network of high-quality not-for-profit services called CPEs (Centres de

la Petite Enfance, or Early Childhood Centres). These have had important positive

effects on children’s development.

However, because of very substantial supply shortages in the early days of Quebec’s

child care reforms, Quebec’s system has developed in negative ways; this provides a

crucial reminder that problems of phase-in and transition are at least as important as

initial funding policy plans.

The Child Care Expense Deduction is a measure originally designed to provide fairer

taxation of employed mothers; it shelters from taxation the part of income that pays for

a legitimate work expense. Taxation of mothers would be unfair without it.

Page 142: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

132

6.1 WHAT ARE THE GOALS OF CHILD CARE FUNDING?

“You’ve got to be very careful if you don’t know where you are going, because you might not

get there.” Quote from Yogi Berra, baseball philosopher.

The best child care funding approach depends on what our objectives are. Affordability of child

care is a very important objective, but it is not the only objective. Accessibility (which includes

the actual availability of needed services, together with flexible hours and service

characteristics that meet the diverse needs of different families), and high quality are very

important as well. Another way of putting this same point: affordability is not so much a goal,

as it is a means to reaching a set of goals related to children’s development and happiness, and

to parental employment and other activities. Affordability, accessibility and quality of services

are needed to reach these goals.

If employment of parents were the only goal, then any way of making child care more

affordable might be acceptable. Even then, finding the right hours of service in the right

location for the appropriate age of child would be important to parents, and that would mean

that accessibility matters too.

Parental employment is not the only, nor even the most important, goal of child care policy.

The effects of early childhood education on children, on children’s happiness, on children’s

emotional, social and language development matter as well. In fact, without child care services

that are positive for children, the affordability of child care is not worth achieving. The quality

of ECEC provided to children is always a central issue, because we believe that the quality of

care is directly and substantially related to the effects on children’s multi-faceted development

in the early years (Lamb, 1998; Shonkoff and Phillips, 2000; Sylva et al., 2011).

Quality is not easy to describe or measure, but it can be seen in staff-child ratios, in curriculum

frameworks to support early childhood education and care, in group sizes, training levels of

early childhood educators, in the quality of the leadership and mentorship provided by senior

staff and in the interactions between parents and educators. Quality is reflected in the

resources available to educators, in the way that children from different backgrounds and with

different abilities are integrated into the group, in the low rate of turnover of qualified staff.

The other key dimension of government’s funding objectives is to make sure that lower-income

families are particularly enabled to access quality child care services. This is important to

mention for two reasons. One is that the benefits to both children and parents in lower-income

families can be especially large; this is found in the majority of studies (Burger, 2010; Duncan

and Sojourner, 2013; Elango et al., 2015). The second reason is that lower-income families are

sometimes less likely than other families to be first in line when enhanced child care funding

arrangements become available. Often accessing licensed child care is part of a set of life

changes in low-income families; these changes may take time. As a result, when there is not

Page 143: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

133

enough child care capacity for all families or when there are variations in child care quality,

these families can end up with poorer quality services or on a waiting list. This can be true of

children in indigenous or immigrant families as well.

This is not to say that children from higher-income families should not receive their fair share of

financial assistance to access good quality child care. Families at all income levels have

difficulty affording child care. Pierre Fortin (2017b) makes a persuasive case, discussing

criticisms of child care funding in Quebec:

It is good practice to ensure that middle- to high-income households

sometimes receive government services at low cost in exchange for the

mountains of taxes they will pay throughout their adult lives. Low-fee

universal childcare is one of the very few public services that college- and

university-educated middle- and high-income families can hope to get in the

first 15 years of their adult lives in return for the taxes they pay. They do not

get healthcare because they are young and healthy. They do not get

employment insurance or social assistance because they hold college and

university degrees. They do not use free public schools yet because their first

child is not going to reach school age before they are 33. Viewed in this light,

the access of richer young households to low-fee childcare is not a “boon” to

them, but a well-earned return for their contribution to maintaining and

developing good public services…. Furthermore, the presence of middle- and

high-income parents in a low-fee childcare system helps establish and

maintain good-quality childcare and prevents the stigma that is too often

associated with “programs for the poor”. (pp. 18-19)

So, our objective is to find a funding approach that can dramatically improve the affordability of

0-4-year-old child care for families, while giving special assistance to lower-income, indigenous

and immigrant families and maintaining or improving quality and accessibility. The multiplicity

of objectives is what makes child care policy complex.

6.2 HOW DOES THE CHILD CARE MARKET WORK?

How does the market for child care work? Is the market for child care services like the market

for cabbages, or is it more like the market for health care, or the market for education?

If it is like the market for cabbages, then we will be very happy as a society to let this market

run itself, without government interference. In the market for cabbages, consumers earn

incomes and decide how much to allocate towards the purchase of cabbage, what type of

cabbage, and whether to buy cabbages in a deep-discount supermarket or in a high-end

purveyor of expensive but very fresh vegetables. Or, consumers will decide to grow the

Page 144: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

134

cabbages themselves, allocating time to cabbage-growing that might otherwise have been

allocated to employment, training, or leisure.

Government policy in relation to the cabbage market can mostly be summarized as “hands-off”.

In other words, we as a society (reflected in the attitude of our governments) believe that

demanders of cabbages will behave in ways that ensure that the suppliers of cabbage try hard

to meet their demands and also that the competition from a large number of potential

suppliers of cabbages will ensure that cabbage producers will have constant pressure on them

to charge reasonable prices in relation to their costs, but also to ensure quality. This only works

well if consumers can easily acquire information about the quality of cabbages they might

purchase. And even with cabbages, there may be some role for government to ensure food

safety if some growers cut too many corners on costs. And, there may be other “public

interest” issues in relation to climate change and land use that compel governments to

intervene in this market. But, for the most part, we agree that minimizing government’s role

will allow consumers to benefit the most from the cabbage market.

However, the health and education markets are different. A very substantial proportion of

health services are provided free-of-charge to Canadians. Doctors are paid by governments for

services delivered, according to a negotiated fee schedule. In most cases, doctors are not free

to sell their services privately if someone is willing to pay more than the government will.

Suppliers to this market are not free to enter at their will and their behaviour and rules of

payment are determined by government regulations.

Primary and secondary education are also provided free-of-charge. Suppliers of free education

are not private enterprises but are schools established and regulated by government at

different levels. There are multiple arguments for the highly regulated nature of these markets,

but much of the argument focuses on promoting and preserving the quality of services. It is

believed that consumer sovereignty, expressed with consumer buying power, would not ensure

that health care and education would be high quality services.

University education is not free in Canada, but it is heavily subsidized, so that fees to students

are well below total per-unit costs. The provision of university education is restricted to certain

not-for-profit enterprises that are believed to share the social mission of government in

providing the best possible quality of education to students, within the limits of resources

available. For-profit universities have not generally been allowed or wanted in Canada. Partly

this is an issue of trust and quality – does the need to make a profit divert for-profit enterprises

from the social mission we want educational institutions to have? And partly this is an issue of

ethics – since government is providing the majority of the funding of post-secondary education,

is it ethically appropriate to enrich individuals who own enterprises that provide this service?

Page 145: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

135

So, I return to my original question: “Is the market for child care services like the market for

cabbages, or is it more like the market for health care, or the market for education?”

Right now, the child care market is mixed. In Ontario, at least 75% of services are provided by

not-for-profit enterprises and there is a government preference for future development to

occur in the not-for-profit sector. But, child care is a purchased service, purchased by parents

in markets from producers competing with each other. As discussed in the chapter on

affordability, there is a large amount of parental expenditure on child care. In licensed child

care, perhaps about 40%-50% of the total cost is paid by governments, so 50%-60% or more is

paid by parents. There is additional parent expenditure on informal paid child care.

However, there is a substantial public interest in the results produced by the child care market.

Unlike with cabbages, it is not only the direct consumers and producers that benefit (Cleveland

and Krashinsky, 1998, 2003, 2004a; Cleveland, 2012). Further, there is a substantial public

interest in simultaneously keeping child care fees low and child care quality high. This will

increase women’s access to the labour market and increase children’s access to good quality

services.

Historically, there are two main forms that government intervention in the child care market

has taken. First, is the subsidization of fees for low-income families accessing the labour

market or training for future employment. Second, is the regulation of supply characteristics

believed to promote child care quality (e.g., staff-child ratios, group sizes, education/skills of

educators and other staff, restriction of the provision of services by for-profit operators)?

In the last 30 years, governments have also taken on a funding role designed to promote the

quality of services through providing supplementary funding for child care sector wages. This

wage funding has had the intent of creating pay equity for child care staff who are

overwhelmingly female, and allowing licensed child care facilities to attract better qualified

staff without raising parent fees too much.

As governments in Canada come to recognize the public interest in improving child care

affordability, accessibility and quality, this mixed market is becoming, and should become,

more like education and health care, and less like cabbages. This is the background to this

chapter’s discussion of preferred funding mechanisms.

6.3 FUNDING TOOLS

There are a number of funding/policy tools that can be used to help parents access care for

their children when they are young (Cleveland and Krashinsky, 2004a):

Page 146: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

136

Child-related leaves and associated benefits – including maternity, parental, paternity

and child-rearing leaves, with or without paid benefits, with or without full job

protection;

Publicly-provided ECEC services – including pre-primary education and ECEC services

provided by public sector bodies or non-profit agencies (even with user fees so long as

these fees are small for all users);

Supply subsidies to ECEC services – operating grants, quality-enhancement grants,

wage-enhancement grants, capital equipment grants, tax benefits and tax reductions

given to ECEC services otherwise normally subject to taxation;

Demand-side subsidies for the use of ECEC – subsidies to low-income families for the

use of ECEC services, tax deductions of ECEC expenses or tax credits based on ECEC

expenditure, vouchers for the purchase of approved types of ECEC services.

We will not consider child-related leaves and benefits here. There are important discussions to

be had about future changes to parental leave that will affect parental decisions about infant

care, but it is not part of our mandate to engage in this discussion now.

6.4 SUPPLY-SIDE VS. DEMAND-SIDE FUNDING

The most important discussion is whether funding should occur on the supply-side or on the

demand-side. Should assistance go directly to parents (demand-side), or should governments

finance services, reducing the cost to parents (supply-side)? Should governments play an

important role in enhancing the quality of services, or should governments rely on consumer

choice to deal with issues of service quality?

Some observers believe it is important to direct funding through families; these will allow

parents to make decisions on what kinds of licensed or unlicensed child care are best suited to

their children. These demand-side subsidies can flow through the tax system as tax credits.

Alternatively, they can be provided directly through vouchers, redeemable for any type of paid

child care. Because parents know their own children best, it is argued that consumer choice in

the marketplace is the ideal mechanism to use to ensure that parents and children get good

quality, accessible and affordable child care. It is argued that, because producers will be

competing for the consumer dollar (enhanced by vouchers), fees will be kept as low as possible.

These observers do not deny that there is a public interest in promoting child care, but they

argue that this public interest can be fully implemented by improving affordability with a

voucher. After that, parents as consumers take over to ensure their children get what they

need.

Page 147: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

137

Of course, with supply-side subsidization, there is also considerable scope for parental choice

about types of care, hours of care and individual providers. However, supply and quality

decisions are substantially monitored and regulated by governments, unlike in a pure demand-

side approach. Fee caps are also a typical feature of supply-side funding.

The biggest problem with demand-side subsidies is that they provide inadequate mechanisms

to ensure that parents purchase high quality care that will support children’s optimal

development (Cleveland & Krashinsky, 2004a). Since quality is, perhaps, the key determinant of

child care’s effects on children, this is a central problem.

Markets only work well if purchasers can effectively monitor the output they are purchasing,

and reward firms that produce the highest quality for the lowest price, and if firms will respond

to those market signals. But the market for child care is decentralised and somewhat chaotic.

Further, each parent chooses from only a small number of providers that are geographically

convenient, so each producer only competes effectively with a few other providers. Many

parents have never purchased child care before, and by the time they learn what they need to

know, their children are old enough so that the parents may never purchase child care again.

Working parents have little time to seek out and evaluate child care, even if they knew entirely

what they were looking for. Furthermore, the direct consumer of the care - the child him or

herself - cannot easily communicate with the parent about what kind of care is being delivered.

And the effect of good or bad child care is seldom immediately apparent. For these reasons,

studies have found that parents often over-estimate the quality of the care that they purchase

relative to the assessments of objective measures of quality (Helburn, 1995; Mocan, 2007;

Walker, 1991).

If it is difficult for parents to determine quality accurately, then the presumed advantages of

the marketplace disappear. Informal and unregulated child care may appear to be as good for

their children as licensed care. For-profit firms may have an incentive to provide child care that

seems of high quality but is not. Because parents can be fooled into buying low quality care,

low-quality providers will be able to underprice higher-quality producers and drive them out of

business. For example, suppose that a high-quality producer sells child care services for

$14,000 per year. If a low-quality producer can produce child care services for $10,000, but can

dress that care up in a way that makes it seem to be of equal quality as the higher cost care,

then the low-quality producer could sell the care for $12,000 and make a profit while

simultaneously winning over the customers of the higher-quality producer. As a result, the

market will fail, and the higher-quality producer will be driven out of business even though the

public might prefer that kind of care if they had full information about it (Walker, 1991).

Further, vouchers can lead to segregated forms of education (Krashinsky, 1986; MacLeod and

Urquiola, 2009), and to limits on the ECEC choices of children perceived to have “problems”. If

subsidies to all children are the same, profit-oriented ECEC centres will not seek to serve the

Page 148: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

138

more problematic children, since they may consume resources that might otherwise go to the

entrepreneurs running the centres. This leads to a problem familiar in the education field and

known as “cream-skimming”. The costs of administering a market-based child care system to

avoid this form of segregation can be considerable.

Supply-side subsidies can be provided in a variety of ways. ECEC services can be provided

directly through the public sector by various levels of government (e.g., directly-operated

municipal centres) or child care services can be provided by not-for-profit or for-profit

providers who are rigorously monitored to encourage the maintenance of quality standards and

financial reporting standards. With supply-side funding, governments regulate the supply and

location of services, rather than letting independent operators make unfettered supply

decisions. With demand-side subsidization, frequently there will be too much supply in some

places (densely populated urban areas) and too little supply in others (rural areas and small

towns). This can lead to high per-child costs in over-supplied areas and inadequate services

elsewhere.

When services are provided by not-for-profit operators, the provision of supply-side funding for

services acts to stabilize the financial position of the small organizations that are frequently the

typical providers. In some jurisdictions, for-profit operators are allowed to join not-for-profit

providers in the delivery of low-cost services (and the corresponding receipt of supply-side

subsidies)8.

There is a further philosophical issue about supply-side vs. demand-side funding. In 1987, the

Peterson government in Ontario published a major policy document about the reform of child

care funding, called New Directions for Child Care. The document promised “a comprehensive

policy that recognizes child care as a basic public service, not a welfare service.” When child

care funding becomes large – when governments are providing more than half of the total cost

of child care services9 – one could argue that child care has become a public service. The

government has the right and the obligation to ensure that child care services are positive for

children and parents. The argument that market forces will compel good behaviour by

suppliers is much less powerful when governments are the dominant funder. In this

circumstance, simply providing funding to parents (demand-side funding) without ensuring the

quality and characteristics of services provided would be unacceptable to many.

8 See Cleveland and Krashinsky (2009) for a discussion of why not-for-profit child care is likely to provide systematically better

child care quality especially in larger urban areas. 9 In the chapter analyzing child care affordability in Ontario, we concluded that government subsidizes about 40%-50% of the

full costs of child care services already. All political parties appear to agree there will be substantial additional investments in

child care in the near future. It appears to be reasonable to conclude that, soon, child care in Ontario will be predominantly

government funded.

Page 149: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

139

The evidence on the benefits and costs of early childhood education and care does not suggest

that all and any expenditure of public money on ECEC, even if provided on the supply-side, will

generate benefits greater than costs. The precise design of ECEC financing programs matters.

In particular, the ratio of benefits to costs is clearly affected by the quality of ECEC services

available; benefits to children rise with quality level, not just up to some point, but apparently

without obvious limit (Lamb, 1998). However, costs also rise, in general, as the quality level of

ECEC services rises.

The ratio of benefits to costs can also be affected by the degree of employment support for

parents that child care programs provide. Programs that provide appropriate hours of support

to make parental employment more convenient are more beneficial to parents and therefore

increase governmental tax revenues which offset operating costs (Peterssen, Mariscal and Ishi,

2017).

6.5 TYPES OF SLIDING SCALE

Supply-side funding always provides a considerable amount of base funding to child care

suppliers. However, parental contribution schemes can vary. At one end of the continuum,

services can be free to parents. So, for instance, in France, the Écoles Maternelles are free for

children from 3 years of age and up (and, if space is available, from 2 years). In New Zealand,

children at 3 and 4 years of age are eligible to have 20 hours of free child care in a child care

centre or other service. Above 20 hours, parents pay for care at a flat hourly rate, unless they

have low income. In England, 30 hours of free child care is available for employed parents of

children 3 or 4 years of age.

Many jurisdictions have some sort of sliding scale for parents and base funding for suppliers.

For instance, in Sweden, parents pay 3% of family income for the first child in child care (up to a

maximum), so the amount of payment varies as income varies. A second child costs another 2%

of family income, and so on.

There are two major types of sliding scale.

1. One uses family income to determine the percent of family income that a family should

pay. The Swedish funding scheme is this kind of sliding scale. So is our current subsidy

system in Ontario. The amount of family income determines how much a subsidized

family has to contribute; the amount of contribution by parents is not affected by the

amount of the full-fee for that type of care. Of course, our current subsidy system is not

available as a right, which makes it different from most sliding scales used elsewhere for

child care.

Page 150: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

140

2. The second type of sliding scale uses family income to determine the percent of the full

fee that a particular family has to pay. At low levels of family income, a family will pay a

very small percentage of the total fee. At higher levels of income, the percentage paid

will be higher, but often these sliding scale schemes provide some level of assistance to

all families.

6.6 FUNDING LESSONS FROM THE QUEBEC EXPERIENCE

With apologies to colleagues in Quebec, there are many negative lessons to learn from

Quebec’s experience in child care funding reform from 1997 through till today.

The major thing that Quebec did get right was making licensed child care very affordable for

Quebec families, both at preschool and school ages.

Another thing that Quebec did get right was increased generosity and accessibility of

maternity/parental benefits. The basic plan in Quebec involves 18 weeks of maternity benefit

paying 70% of previous average weekly income and 32 weeks of parental leave (which may be

shared between parents). The first 7 weeks of parental leave are compensated at 70% of

previous average weekly income and the next 25 weeks at 55%, up to a maximum. The special

plan in Quebec involves 15 weeks of maternity benefit paying 75% of previous average weekly

income and 25 weeks of parental leave (which may be shared between parents) also

compensated at 75% of previous average weekly income, up to a maximum. There is no two-

week waiting period before benefits start in Quebec. There are also paternity benefits available

in a basic plan or special plan and available exclusively to the biological father. The basic plan

has 5 weeks of paternity benefits, available on a use-it-or-lose-it basis, compensated at 70% of

previous average weekly income. The special plan has 3 weeks of paternity benefits, again

available on a use-it-or-lose-it basis, compensated at 75% of previous average weekly income.

Self-employed income is considered eligible under these Quebec plans. Adoptive parents are

eligible for parental benefits in Quebec. For those of you familiar with maternity/parental leave

arrangements in the rest of Canada, you will recognize that those in Quebec are more

generous, flexible and more encouraging of fathers’ participation.

A third thing that Quebec got right was the creation of a network of high-quality not-for-profit

services called CPEs (Centres de la Petite Enfance, or Early Childhood Centres). These have

been found to have important positive effects on children’s development (Fortin, 2018).

However, the roll out of child care services and funding had real problems in Quebec. There’s

an ancient Greek proverb, whose current English expression is “there’s many a slip ‘twixt the

cup and the lip”. Quebec’s child care reform experience gives a good sense that developing

excellent theoretical models of child care funding does not guarantee that the plans will not go

awry.

Page 151: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

141

Quebec’s original model was to have supply-side base funding for not-for-profit Early Childhood

Centres (CPEs) which would also become local hubs for accessing home child care as an

option10. Parents would pay a flat fee of only $5.00 per day for child care. At school age, child

care would be available through the school system for before-and-after school child care.

The school system was able to build out capacity very quickly, but not so the not-for-profit

centres which were to be the foundation and major providers of care for the Quebec reforms.

There was not enough capacity for the huge flood of demand for child care that resulted from

making it much more affordable.

As a result, four things happened (Fortin, 2017b).

1. Middle to higher income families were disproportionately likely to access the (better

quality) CPE spaces (Haeck et al., 2015). Lower income families ended up

disproportionately in lower quality forms of care, or on a waiting list (Japel et al., 2009).

When major new early childhood education and care programs are rolled out, it is

important to ensure that they are of benefit to families that are more disadvantaged. A

policy that focuses on lowering current child care prices will initially benefit families

currently using regulated child care, especially those that are in the middle and upper

ranges of the income distribution, so this is difficult to achieve and requires specific

policy attention. Without special measures, those who need assistance most are least

likely to receive it.

2. Family home day care came to have a much bigger role in the emerging child care

system than was originally intended. Now, approximately one-third of all children 0-4

are in home child care. Home child care can be especially important in small cities,

towns and rural areas and for parents working non-traditional hours or on weekends.

However, the amount of early childhood training and knowledge of family day care

providers in Quebec is minimal; most studies of quality in subsidized family day care find

that it is not of the educational quality that the Quebec system anticipates (see Chart 1).

3. The system came to rely on for-profit centre care providers11. Right from the beginning

there were not enough not-for-profit CPE spaces so the government developed a plan to

10 Studies suggest that the CPEs are generally of much higher quality than other forms of child care in Quebec (Drouin et al.,

2004; Cleveland and Bigras, 2013; Institut de la Statistique du Quebec, 2015) and have positive effects on children’s

development (I. Laurin et al., 2015; J. Laurin et al., 2015; Geoffroy et al. 2010; Herba et al. 2013)

11 Recent experience in the U.K., Australia and the Netherlands suggests that expansion of demand-side funding typically leads

to rapid increases in the proportion of for-profit providers, including large chain operators providing child care (Penn and Lloyd,

2013; Cooke and Henehan, 2012; Elliott, 2006).

Page 152: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

142

“temporarily” rent spaces from for-profit operators. These for-profit operators were

not required to have the same proportion of trained staff as CPEs. Non-profit subsidized

early childhood centres (CPEs) are typically of good quality in Quebec, but there are not

enough spaces in them to meet demand. The quality of for-profit centres is substantially

lower (Cleveland & Bigras, 2013; see also Chart 1). However, now about one-third of all

children 0-4 are in for-profit centres. As explained above, lower-income families are

more likely to have their children in these lower-quality for-profit centres.

4. The Quebec government, in 2009, expanded an existing tax credit for child care

expenses into a major new funding mechanism for child care in the province. This tax

credit covers expenses for unlicensed care as well as licensed care providers who are

not directly funded under the low-fee scheme (the low-fee scheme was originally $5 per

day, but is now on a sliding scale of payments). The tax credit provided an alternative

form of sliding scale, but abandoned a central government role in promoting and

ensuring quality of services. Under the tax credit scheme, the amount of for-profit child

care in Quebec has increased very rapidly – for-profit full-fee child care multiplied by 12

times in 10 years (Fortin, 2017a).

Chart 1

Percent of Quebec children 18-66 months attending care of either inadequate or

good/excellent quality, in three types of care

Page 153: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

143

The moral of the Quebec story is that issues of transition matter enormously.12

Making licensed child care affordable today in Ontario would create a huge gap between supply

and demand. Phasing-in affordability may not be popular; all families want help now.

However, phasing-in can permit governments and the child care sector to increase the capacity

of good quality services, and to recruit trained staff to provide these services. Building a good

quality, well-regulated and monitored child care system takes time, but it is key to the positive

experiences of Ontario children and parents.

6.7 THE CHILD CARE EXPENSE DEDUCTION

The Child Care Expense Deduction (CCED) is a frequently neglected and much misunderstood

element of the child care affordability puzzle. The CCED is a deduction in the tax system

available to reduce the effect of child care expenses as a barrier to labour force entry. This

deduction reduces the income on which tax is payable for employed single parents and the

lower earner in a two-parent family when both parents are employed.

There are two ways to think about the Child Care Expense Deduction. Either it is a way of

providing assistance to families to make child care more affordable. If this perspective is true,

the CCED is a poorly-designed demand-side subsidy that gives more money to the rich than the

poor, and provides no incentives to use better-quality care. If this perspective is accurate, it

should be abolished or, rather, replaced.

The other way to think of the Child Care Expense Deduction (Cleveland and Krashinsky, 1999) is

as a measure for fair taxation. The CCED is not properly thought of as a way of financing child

care; instead it is a measure to treat individuals (mostly women) equitably in the tax system. If

there were no CCED, mothers wishing to enter the labour force would have to pay for their

child care expenses out of income that had already been taxed (making those child care

expenses much more expensive).

Since, for these mothers, child care expenses are a legitimate work expense, the dollars that

pay for child care should not be taxed. Expenses on child care can be deducted up to a

maximum whether they are for licensed or unlicensed care. The maximum amounts of child

care expenses claimable are $8,000 per child for children 0-6 and $5,000 per child for children

7-16 years. However, actual levels of child care expenses are often much higher than this in

Ontario.

12 Haeck, Lefebvre and Merrigan (2015, p. 151) explain that because of the rush to provide spaces the government recruited

daycare workers with no specific training in ECEC, did not enforce the curriculum, and did not enforce required ratios relating to

qualified educators.

Page 154: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

144

If this perspective is accepted (and we think it should be, even though many child care

advocates think otherwise) then, because the Child Care Expense Deduction is a measure built

into the federal tax system (it also affects provincial income taxes collected), it would make

sense for the Ontario government to pressure the federal government to make the expenditure

limits more reasonable…closer to actual costs of child care in Ontario.

The federal government has made important, but as yet only minor, financial commitments to

funding child care in Canada. Naturally, the Ontario Government would be interested in

maximizing federal financial contributions. It is worth noting then, that there is an interaction

between Ontario child care funding and the federal Child Care Expense Deduction.

It works this way. If the Ontario government decides to provide much more generous funding

to improve affordability of licensed child care and lowers the fees parents have to pay for child

care, this will save the federal government a considerable amount of money on the CCED

(parents will claim less tax relief on the CCED). The provincial government should, therefore,

negotiate with the federal government to get its fair share of the money saved as it makes

licensed child care more affordable. This issue is discussed with respect to Quebec child care by

none other than Jean-Yves Duclos (now Minister of Families, Children and Social Development

in the federal government) in Clavet and Duclos (2012).

6.8 CONCLUSIONS ABOUT ALTERNATIVE FUNDING

APPROACHES

Demand-side funding has some positives. It does give parents full control over how to spend

any assistance provided by governments (within the limits imposed by the voucher or tax credit

system). Particularly for parents whose needs are atypical (shift work, long hours, children

needing atypical care), demand-side funding may increase their power in negotiating what they

need.

However, demand-side funding often leads to rapid price increases and cost increases (often

due to higher vacancy rates). Competition in child care markets, being strongly geographically-

based (i.e., only those services that are close to each other are in direct competition for parent

dollars), appears to be insufficient to keep prices from rising substantially. Demand-side

funding is typically associated with a rapid expansion of for-profit providers, frequently big-box

chains, and a decline in quality. Once for-profit provision is established as the majority of

provision, governments become less powerful in their ability to monitor and enforce quality

improvements, and make regulatory changes that might impact the bottom line.

Supply-side funding has many more advantages. A fundamental advantage of supply-side

funding is that governments have a direct relationship with providers; governments are the

direct funders of the providers. This means that governments have considerable leverage with

Page 155: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

145

providers (even if a portion of them are for-profit providers) to insist upon and monitor

constant quality improvements. This direct relationship gives government greater ability to

control the supply and location of new child care facilities, to ensure that adequate good-

quality facilities are available in rural and low-income areas, that services with longer hours are

available, that facilities are not segregated by social class. By controlling supply, governments

can also reduce excessive vacancy rates that are a problem in demand-side systems and that

drive up per-unit costs of child care provision.

The disadvantage of supply-side funding is the flip side of these advantages – governments will

take a large role and responsibility for quality, supply and various characteristics of child care

supply. If governments do a poor job, supply-side funding will have poorer results. In many

countries with successful supply-side funding, municipal governments play a major role in these

supply and quality decisions and implementation. Usually, there is also an important role for

parents and providers in collective management of the system’s evolution. Ontario is fortunate

in having a well-developed municipal role already.

In order to ensure that low-income families can afford and have good access to child care

services, services should either be provided free of charge or with fees adjusted by a sliding

scale based on family income. In addition, if there are service shortages as funding is phased

in, local governments should develop means of ensuring that children from all income groups

and backgrounds have a fair process of gaining access.

The Quebec experience of child care reforms suggests that managing the expansion of the

system is very important if new services are going to be accessible, affordable and of high

quality. It is not possible to make child care affordable immediately for all families because

there is insufficient supply. As with full-day kindergarten, there must be a phase-in period over

which affordability gradually increases and access to scarce services is fairly managed.

The current Child Care Expense Deduction, a part of the tax system, is best viewed as a way of

improving tax fairness for the lower-earning parent in a family (often the mother). Without the

Child Care Expense Deduction (CCED), this parent’s wage has to cover both (a) the cost of child

care and (b) the income tax on top of the part of income used to pay for that child care. The

Child Care Expense Deduction (if large enough) eliminates the income tax on top of child care

expenses, but still leaves the child care expenses. Since the cost of child care can be viewed as

a necessary cost of employment, it is unfair and punitive to tax this part of income. It provides

a big disincentive to employment.

In recent years, as the cost of child care has soared, the CCED covers only a portion of total

child care costs for many families. The federal government should be encouraged to raise the

value of this tax deduction to reflect actual costs.

Page 156: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

146

CHAPTER 7: WHAT OTHER JURISDICTIONS DO

Chapter Summary

Different child care funding and management approaches are often discussed discretely

as either/or arrangements. In fact, most jurisdictions choose a combination of tools

which have been tailored to deliver the type of child care system they want. We can

learn how tools are combined to produce results in other jurisdictions.

Many jurisdictions use a sliding scale of payments, where parents pay for child care

according to their income. Our current subsidy system is one particular form of this, but

there are many variations.

Many jurisdictions provide substantial operating grants (sometimes known as base

funding) to services. These operating grants serve twin purposes of supporting higher

wage levels for child care staff and lower fees for parents.

A third funding approach is to make available free child care services for some age group

of children or for some number of hours per week.

A fourth, quite different, funding approach is to provide a tax credit or voucher for

parents in order to purchase child care. This is typically known as demand-side funding.

This funding could be made available only for use with licensed/regulated services (as in

Australia) or for whatever type of care the parent wishes to use (as in Quebec with the

Tax Credit for Child Care Expenses).

This chapter looks at the use of these tools in various countries and Canadian provinces.

England

o England’s early childhood services are systematically divided into education, on

the one hand, and care, on the other. Education services for children younger

than compulsory school age are largely in the public sector and often in schools.

They mostly serve children three to five years of age. Care services are largely in

the private sector, with the lion’s share being for-profit services and a smaller

share being not-for-profit. Child care services are viewed as being a support for

parental employment, not as education, and are typically quite expensive.

o The central government provides funding to local authorities (i.e., municipalities)

to ensure that every three and four-year-old has access to a part-time nursery

education. This supply-side funding is paid to providers, public and private, to

Page 157: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

147

cover the costs of a nursery place for each child for up to 15 hours per week, 38

weeks per year.

o As of September 2017, working parents of three and four-year-olds living in

England are entitled to the new 30 hours free childcare offer, worth around

£5,000 per child (Can$8,600). That’s an extra 15 hours of education/care for

parents who each work and earn at least a little over £6,000 per year

(Can$10,300). This is not available if you or your partner earn more than

£100,000 per year (Can$172,000). The 30 hours of free child care can be

redeemed at participating nursery schools and nursery classes, childminders,

Sure Start Children’s Centres, playgroups and preschools.

Australia

o There are four major types of regulated child care (known as approved child

care) in Australia – long day care (centre care for children 0-6), family day care,

Out of School Hours Care (known as OSHC – before and after school centre care

for children 6-12) and occasional care. About 45% of children 2-3 years of age

use long day care and over 40% of children 4-5 years of age are enrolled in a full-

day preschool program provided in a long day care centre. Many other 4-year-

old children are in state-funded preschools (sometimes called kindergartens) at

nominal fees.

o Australia has a new sliding scale of child care fees where families earning less

than about AU$65,000 get 85% of costs covered, falling to 50% at about

AU$170,000. Beyond AU$350,000 there is no child care fee assistance;

assistance for fees is capped at AU$11.55 per hour, higher than most current

fees. (The Australian dollar (AU$) and Canadian dollar (Can$) are of almost equal

value, so we do not convert these currency figures into Canadian dollars).

o There are activity requirements to be eligible for this fee assistance. Low-income

families who do not meet the activity requirements are eligible for 12 hours per

week of child care for each child.

o Median fees in Australia for 0-5-year-olds are about AU$20,000 annually;

increased generosity of funding over the years has lowered the fees that parents

have to pay, but only temporarily – the general trend is up.

New Zealand

o There are a number of different types of ECEC services in New Zealand. The

predominant type of teacher-led service is centre-based ECEC, which children

Page 158: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

148

can attend either part-time or full-time and which caters for children from birth

to school age. In New Zealand, children can choose to start school any time after

their fifth birthday and must start school by the time of their sixth birthday.

o Another paid centre-based, teacher-led option is kindergarten; New Zealand

kindergartens are generally community-based (i.e., not-for-profit) and focused

on children from three to five years of age. Historically, kindergartens operated

on a part-day basis, but now most operate for the full school day. There are also

home-based services, typically in the caregiver’s home but sometimes in a child’s

home. In all licensed services, there are required standards for curriculum,

facilities, health and safety, governance and management.

o Most child care funding in New Zealand is provided on the supply side in order to

keep parent fees low.

o There is also 20 hours of “free” ECEC provided to all 3- and 4-year-old children.

o All supply-side funding is provided to child care services through the Ministry of

Education according to formulas based on cost-drivers.

o the Ministry of Social Development provides some additional subsidies to low-

income families; there are income and activity requirements.

Denmark

o Most child care funding in Denmark is supply-side funding, provided by

municipalities to child care providers. Local authorities are required to ensure

that there is a child care place for every child over 26 weeks of age whose

parents want one (within 4 weeks of turning 26 weeks of age). The central

government provides block grants to local municipalities and local governments

raise tax money as well to fulfill these obligations.

o Parents can choose centre care or a home care child minder and the same

subsidy will follow the child, based on the parents’ choice. Public childminders

are contracted by the municipality to provide the service. They are selected,

trained, paid and supervised by the municipality.

o Most child care funding in Denmark is designed to keep parent fees relatively

low. Parent fees are set annually by municipalities, and municipalities are

required to fund child care providers so that parents pay no more than 25% of

the actual cost of the service. There are also discounts for siblings.

o Parents on low incomes in Denmark receive an additional subsidy (an ‘aided

Page 159: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

149

place subsidy’) from the local authority, according to a nationally-set sliding

scale.

Norway

o There are three types of child care (known as kindergartens) in Norway. Ordinary

kindergartens (barnehager) can be public or private. They offer half-day or full-

day service all year round for children between zero and five years of age. Family

kindergartens (familiebarnehager) are based in private homes, where an

assistant works with a maximum of five children, supervised and mentored by a

qualified kindergarten teacher on a weekly basis. Open kindergartens (åpne

barnehager) are part-time drop-in centres with programmes for parents and

children to participate in together, led by a qualified kindergarten teacher.

o Obtaining a place in kindergarten is a statutory right for every child, but

participation in ECEC is voluntary.

o About 50% of the centres in Norway are municipally owned and operated; the

other 50% are run by private operators, most of them not-for-profit.

o Most child care funding in Norway is supply-side operating funding. The

government imposes a statutory fee cap on the parental fee for centre-based or

family child care (NOK 2,655 per month in 2016 or about Can$418 per month or

Can$4,600 per 11-month year). This means that parents cover about 15% of the

cost of ECEC through parent fees. The bulk of the operating costs of ECEC are

covered by government funding, that is about 85% of operating costs. About

90% of children 1-5 years of age attend child care.

o A new plan provides 20 hours of free child care per week to 3-, 4- and 5-year-old

children from families earning less than about Can$66,000 annually. Parents

have to engage in some activity (e.g., Norwegian language courses) in order to

be eligible.

Sweden

o Sweden has an integrated and largely universal child care system for children

younger than school age, considered as a part of the education system (but

voluntary). It is designed to support employment and study activities as well as

providing play-based education for children at low or zero cost to parents.

o The main type of child care in Sweden is centre-based preschool or förskola.

Preschool is also available provided as home child care. Preschool serves

Page 160: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

150

children 1-5 years of age (children younger than one year of age are nearly all

cared for by their parents receiving relatively generous parental payments).

Preschool is intended to be safe, fun and instructive; it promotes a philosophy of

the equality of all individuals and particularly of girls and boys. Municipalities

are responsible for ensuring that children who want to attend are provided a

place in preschool – within four months of the request. Most of the preschools

(81%) are municipally owned and operated. About 19% of centres are

independently operated – run by parents, staff or as a business.

o The central government defines goals and objectives of child care, such as the

national curriculum. Municipalities play the main role in implementing policy,

planning and delivering ECEC services. Municipalities also determine working

conditions and pay of child care staff locally. Municipalities receive annual

quality reports and pedagogical documentation from child care services

o In Sweden, the parent fee depends on parental income in a scheme known as

Maxtaxa. Under this scheme, parents are charged no more than 3% of

household income for one child in preschool/child care up to a maximum

monthly household income. The maximum a family could have to pay per month

for one child in preschool is approximately Can$209 per month.

o For the second child, the maximum charge is another 2% of household income,

and another 1% for the third.

Quebec

o Quebec has a network of Early Childhood Centres and family homes that were

the original heart of their system of reduced-fee child care services. The base

rate for this child care is now (2017) $7.75 per day for families earning less than

about $50,000. For other families, there is a sliding scale of payments rising to

$21.20 per day at about $160,000 and above.

o For families not using reduced-fee child care in Quebec, there is a tax credit for

child care expenses – a different sliding scale of payments. Families earning less

than about $35,000 will be reimbursed through the tax system for 75% of the full

fee; families earning more will be reimbursed less; families earning above about

$155,000 will be reimbursed 26% of the full fee.

Prince Edward Island

o Recently, Prince Edward Island has reorganized existing licensed child care

programs into a publicly-managed network of Early Years Centres and Infant

Page 161: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

151

Homes; fees are regulated, wages are based on a common salary scale, there is

sector planning, professional development and management support.

o PEI requires two-thirds of staff to be qualified at two-year ECE diploma or above.

Manitoba

o Manitoba has pioneered many innovations in management of a child care

system. Manitoba provides base funding to services willing to become a funded

facility. Funded facilities are not-for-profit centres and family homes that are

willing to cap fees; two-thirds of staff are required to have an ECE diploma,

however, there are important problems recruiting sufficient staff.

This chapter reviews child care funding policies and effects in a number of countries and

provincial jurisdictions in Canada. The countries include England, Australia, New Zealand,

Denmark, Norway, and Sweden13. The provinces include Quebec, Prince Edward Island, and

Manitoba.

7.1 GENERAL FUNDING APPROACHES

Many jurisdictions use a sliding scale of payments, where parents pay for child care according

to their income. Our current subsidy system is one particular form of this, but there are many

variations. In particular, there are variations that are more generous and that provide some

guarantee that child care spaces are available to eligible families.

Many jurisdictions provide substantial operating grants (sometimes known as base funding) to

services. These operating grants serve twin purposes of supporting higher wage levels for child

care staff, and lower fees for parents. The grants could be designed to leave parents with a flat

fee (e.g., $25.00 per day), or they could be combined with a sliding scale of fees (covering the

service costs not covered by parental contributions).

A third funding approach is to make available free child care services for some age group of

children or for some number of hours per week. Of course, this would need to be supported by

the provision of 100% operating funding to child care services by government for that age

group and those hours.

13 These are chosen as countries from whom we often borrow social policy innovations, or ones that have made a priority of

improving child care affordability. We considered including the United States, but many of their early childhood policies are

state-based and the diversity makes these policies difficult to summarize.

Page 162: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

152

A fourth, quite different, funding approach is to provide a tax credit or voucher for parents in

order to purchase child care. This is typically known as demand-side funding. This funding

could be made available only for use with licensed/regulated services (as in Australia) or for

whatever type of care the parent wishes to use (as in Quebec with the Tax Credit for Child Care

Expenses).

There are many complementary policies which can be used in conjunction with these funding

approaches. Obviously maternity/parental leave and benefits is a policy that can dramatically

alter child care use for very young children. In addition, the Child Care Expense Deduction

changes the net price of child care for parents; we discuss this elsewhere. Further,

complementary policies to enhance compensation and qualifications of staff and develop salary

scales and career ladders can be very important to the quality of services provided and the

ability to recruit and retain qualified staff.

Another complementary tool can be putting a cap on fees, either through restrictions on what

fee levels will be covered by a sliding scale, or with more direct controls. And finally, there are

related issues around the role of not-for-profit, for-profit and public providers in the provision

of services; many jurisdictions place restrictions on the role of for-profit providers. In Ontario,

the role of the municipalities in administering and possibly amending the funding system is also

of critical importance to consider.

These policies are complicated. Each broad approach has multiple possible variations. And the

ways in which different funding approaches are combined within one funding system both

enrich and complicate the picture. One way of deepening a discussion of best funding

approaches is to look in some depth at what other countries and provinces have done.

Nearly every jurisdiction, both in Canada and in other countries adjusts child care fees so that

lower income families pay less than other families. We will use the term “sliding scale” to refer

to these systems of fee adjustment, although that description seems to fit some examples

better than others. The predominant rationale for these sliding scales is one of equity: lower

income families cannot afford the same level of fees as higher-income families. At full fee

levels, child care is truly unaffordable for many families and especially lower-income families.

However, there is a strong “efficiency” argument, too. The effects of access to child care are

found to be very positive in changing the lives of both children and parents in low-income

families, as long as that child care is of reasonably good quality. The large majority of studies of

child care’s effects on children’s development find that the positive effects are larger for

children from lower-income families. And access to child care is likely to have substantial

positive effects on family incomes because it helps to overcome an important barrier to

parental employment.

Page 163: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

153

Hence, differential fee levels according to parental incomes are found in nearly all jurisdictions.

This similarity masks very important differences, however, as to the mechanisms used to adjust

fees, the generosity of the fee relief and the centrality of these fee adjustments in the funding

system of each jurisdiction.

7.2 ENGLAND

England’s early childhood services are systematically divided into education, on the one hand,

and care, on the other. Education services for children younger than compulsory school age are

largely in the public sector and often in schools. They mostly serve children three to five years

of age. Care services are largely in the private sector, with the lion’s share being for-profit

services and a smaller share being not-for-profit (typically called the voluntary sector in

England). Child care services are viewed as being a support for parental employment, not as

education, and are typically quite expensive.

The central government provides funding to local authorities (i.e., municipalities) to ensure that

every three- and four-year old has access to a part-time nursery education. This supply-side

funding is paid to providers, public and private, to cover the costs of a nursery place for each

child for up to 15 hours per week, 38 weeks per year. This funding is known as the Early Years

Entitlement (or EYE). Over 60% of the EYE goes to the state education sector, but there is a

considerable amount that goes through the private sector as well. You can also get this 15

hours of free nursery education if your child is age 2 and you are on income support or

otherwise have a very low income.

As of September 2017, working parents of three and four-year-olds living in England are

entitled to the new 30 hours free childcare offer, worth around £5,000 per child (Can$8,600).

That’s an extra 15 hours of education/care for parents who each work and earn at least a little

over £6,000 per year (Can$10,300). This is not available if you or your partner earn more than

£100,000 per year (Can$172,000). The 30 hours of free child care can be redeemed at

participating nursery schools and nursery classes, childminders, Sure Start Children’s Centres,

playgroups and preschools.

Tax-Free Childcare is only available to working parents, including the self-employed. For every

£8 (Can$13.80) parents put in this savings account, the government will supplement this with

an extra £2(Can$3.45), up to £2,000 per year (Can$3,450). Despite its name, the scheme has

little to do with the tax system. The basic rate of tax in England is 20%, so when the

government contributes £2,000 (Can$3,450) out of your child care costs of £10,000

(Can$17,200), it is as if you did not have to pay the basic rate of tax on the income you used to

pay for child care. You are not eligible for Tax-Free Childcare if you or your partner earns

£100,000 per year or more. The government contribution is bumped up to £4,000 per year

(Can$6,900) for a disabled child under 17 years of age.

Page 164: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

154

Universal Credit is a monthly payment to help with your living costs, designed to “incentivize

work”. You may be able to get it if you’re working on a low income or out of work. Universal

Credit is being phased in over the next few years. It will replace a number of existing benefits,

including the Child Tax Credit and the Working Tax Credit (see White and Friendly, 2012, for

description of these earlier tax credits). If you, and any partner, are working, or you’re due to

start work, and you’re claiming Universal Credit, you can claim back up to 85% of your eligible

child care costs for children under 16. You could get up to £646 a month (Can$1,100) for one

child, or £1,108 (Can$1,900) for two or more. You can use it to help pay: registered

childminders, nurseries, and nannies; registered after-school clubs and play schemes;

registered schools; home care workers working for a registered home care agency.

7.3 AUSTRALIA

There are four major types of regulated child care (known as approved child care) in Australia –

long day care (centre care for children 0-6), family day care, Out of School Hours Care (known

as OSHC – before and after school centre care for children 6-12) and occasional care. About

45% of children 2-3 years of age use long day care and over 40% of children 4-5 years of age are

enrolled in a full-day preschool program provided in a long day care centre. Many other 4-year-

old children are in state-funded preschools (sometimes called kindergartens) at nominal fees.

Australia has a new sliding scale child care funding scheme, called the Child Care Subsidy, which

has passed through Parliament and will be implemented in July 2018. It replaces two other

funding streams, one of which was a sliding scale and one of which was not. Under the new

Child Care Subsidy, families will be able to claim subsidy for a number of types of approved

child care (essentially similar to licensed child care in Canada). Families earning up to

AU$65,710 will pay 15% of the cost of the child care services they use, up to a cap; in other

words, these families will have 85% of the costs subsidized. The cap is set at AU$11.55 per hour

(or AU$115.50 per 10-hour day). Any amount beyond this price per hour remains to be paid by

the family. Note that the Australian dollar (AU$) and Canadian dollar (Can$) are of almost

equal value, so we do not convert these currency figures into Canadian dollars.

Beyond AU$65,710 annually, families will have their subsidy coverage reduced by 1 percentage

point for each additional AU$3,000 of family income. So, for instance, at AU$68,710 income,

the family would have 84% of its costs subsidized, rather than 85%. And, at AU$95,710, the

family would have 75% of its costs subsidized. This continues up to AU$170,710 of income, at

which point a family will have 50% of its child care costs subsidized. From AU$170,710 of

income out to AU$250,000, the sliding scale takes a pause and families at all these income

levels get 50% subsidy. The rationale for this design was to avoid disadvantaging too many

families relative to previously existing schemes – the Child Care Rebate used to cover 50% of

parents’ out-of-pocket child care costs.

Page 165: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

155

Beyond AU$250,000, the subsidy again declines at a rate of 1 percentage point for every

additional AU$3,000 of family income out to AU$340,000; at this income level, families have

20% of their child care costs subsidized. The 20% coverage continues to AU$350,000; beyond

this income level, there is no subsidy available.

There are a couple of other conditions on this Child Care Subsidy. First, families earning over

AU$185,000 per year will only be covered for up to AU$10,000 of child care expenses per year.

Second, there is an activity requirement for this sliding scale. Approved activities include

employment, self-employment, business, education and even some kinds of volunteering. All

parents in a family need to be engaged in approved activities for at least four hours per week in

order to qualify for 18 hours per week of subsidy. If all parents are “active” for more than eight

hours per week, but less than 24, they will qualify for 36 hours of subsidy per week. If parents

are active for 24 or more hours per week, they will qualify for up to 50 hours of subsidy.

Table 38

Fee subsidy as a % of Family Income

Combined Family Income Subsidy as % of actual fee charged up to hourly fee cap

Up to AU$65,710 85 percent

AU$65,711 – AU$170,709 Tapering to 50 percent – falling 1 percentage point for each AU$3,000 of income

AU$170,710 – AU$249,999 50 percent

AU$250,000 – AU$339,999 Tapering to 20 percent – falling 1 percentage point for each AU$3,000 of income

$AU340,000 – AU$349,000 20 percent

$AU350,000 and above 0 percent

The median daily child care fee for children younger than school age in Australia is now AU$77

(or AU$385 per week, or about AU$20,000 for a full year). Since 2005, child care prices have

been rising more rapidly than inflation. This is predicted to continue.

The chart below (Productivity Commission, 2014, p.475) records the out-of-pocket child care

costs that parents have paid over the years in Australia as compared to the trend of general

prices. Each time there has been an increase in child care funding, designed to increase

affordability, it has had that immediate effect. However, shortly after that, fees have risen

sufficiently to wipe out much of the affordability improvement. In a free-market child care

system, it is hard to avoid this.

Page 166: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

156

Chart 2 Growth in Out-of-Pocket Child Care Costs as Compared to Rise in General Price Level

As a result of recommendations from the Productivity Commission, Australia has now put a cap

on the child care prices it will subsidize. This cap is now set at AU$11.55 per hour of child care.

This cap is intended to put a lid on price rises, but it is substantially higher than current fees, so

it is unlikely to be immediately effective.

In Australia, families who earn less than AU$65,710 per year are eligible for 85% subsidy on

child care even if they do not meet the activity requirement. However, their children are only

entitled to 12 hours per week of child care in this case.

7.4 NEW ZEALAND

There are a number of different types of ECEC service in New Zealand. Amongst licenced

services, there is a division between teacher-led and parent- or whanau-led services (whānau is

Page 167: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

157

a Māori word referring to an extended family group in that community). Teacher-led services

are led by professional trained teachers.

The predominant type of teacher-led service is centre-based ECEC, which children can attend

either part-time or full-time and which caters for children from birth to school age. In New

Zealand, children can choose to start school any time after their fifth birthday and must start

school by the time of their sixth birthday. Many children start school at 5 years of age.

Another paid centre-based, teacher-led option is kindergarten; New Zealand kindergartens are

generally community-based (i.e., not-for-profit) and focused on children from three to five

years of age. Historically, kindergartens operated on a part-day basis, but now most operate

for the full school day. There are also home-based services, typically in the caregiver’s home

but sometimes in a child’s home. In all licensed services, there are required standards for

curriculum, facilities, health and safety, governance and management.

There are two main types of parent/ whānau-led services that are licensed: playcentres and te

kohanga reo. Kohanga reo are centres in which children are totally immersed in the Māori

language and culture.

Most of New Zealand’s child care funding is directed at reducing fees for all children through

payments to providers. On top of that there are 20 hours of free ECEC that children of 3 and 4

years of age are eligible for.

In addition to supply-side funding, the Ministry of Social Development provides child care

subsidies that are income-tested. These subsidies are for children 0-6 years of age. Families

with low incomes can access between 3 and 9 hours of ECEC per week even if parents do not

meet activity requirements.

However, if parents are looking for subsidies to cover between 9 and 50 hours per week of child

care, they have to meet both income and activity requirements to qualify. New Zealand’s

income test is different from some other income tests in a couple of ways. First, the payment is

not a percentage of the total cost of care. Rather, it is a fixed dollar amount of subsidy.

Second, the income at which subsidy is triggered varies with family size. This may be fairer; a

larger family with the same income as a smaller one is effectively less well off.

Families with one child receive maximum subsidy when their incomes are below NZ$800

(Can$725) per week (NZ$41,600 for a full year [Can$37,700]). The threshold is higher with two

children - NZ$920 (Can$835) per week (or NZ$47,840 for a full year [Can$43,420]) – and higher

still with three or more children - NZ$1,030 (Can$935) per week (or NZ$53,560 for a full year

[Can$48,620]). That maximum subsidy is a fixed dollar amount - NZ$5.06 per hour (Can$4.60).

As incomes for each of these family sizes rise, the eligibility for subsidy assistance falls. Subsidy

eligibility disappears for these three family sizes at NZ$1,400, NZ$1,600 and NZ$1,800 per week

Page 168: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

158

(or NZ$72,800, NZ$83,200 and NZ$93,600 for a full year). In Canadian dollars, subsidy eligibility

for these three family sizes disappears at Can$1,270, Can$1,450, and Can$1,630 per week, or

Can$66,040, Can$75,400, and Can$84,760 per year.

Notice that the eligibility for subsidy jumps down as income increases, providing somewhat

perverse incentives not to earn too much money. For instance, a family with one child earning

NZ$799 per week (Can$724) is eligible for $5.06 per hour of subsidy (Can$4.60). Yet the same

family earning NZ$800 per week (Can$725) is only eligible for NZ$4.04 per hour (Can$3.65). On

a full year basis, for 50 hours per week, this family’s subsidy would fall from NZ$13,156

(Can$11,960) to NZ$10,504 (Can$9,490) due to earning an extra NZ$1.00 per week! A number

of other subsidy systems are similarly designed.

7.5 DENMARK

Most child care funding in Denmark is supply-side funding, provided by municipalities to child

care providers. Local authorities are required to ensure that there is a child care place for every

child over 26 weeks of age whose parents want one (within 4 weeks of the child turning 26

weeks of age. The central government provides block grants to local municipalities and local

governments raise tax money as well to fulfill these obligations. Parents can choose centre care

or a home care child minder and the same subsidy will follow the child, based on the parents’

choice. Public childminders are contracted by the municipality to provide the service. They are

selected, trained, paid and supervised by the municipality.

Most child care funding in Denmark is designed to keep parent fees relatively low. Parent fees

are set annually by municipalities, and municipalities are required to fund child care providers

so that parents pay no more than 25% of the actual cost of the service. There are also

discounts for siblings. As an example, parent fees in Rudersdal Commune on the outskirts of

Copenhagen ranged from about Can$4,000 to nearly Can$9,000 in 2017 (varying by age of child

and type of care). Danes spend between 7% and 10% of their after-tax income on child care.

Parents on low incomes receive an additional subsidy (an ‘aided place subsidy’) from the local

authority, according to a nationally-set sliding scale. In 2012, parents with an annual household

income of DKK 485,500 (about Can$97,000) or above pay the set full fee. Families with incomes

below this level pay varying amounts based on income. For instance, parents with earnings

between DKK 312,226 – 315,690 (about Can$63,000) pay 50% of the fee and parents with

earning of DKK 156,301 (about Can$31,200) or lower are exempt from ECEC fees. There is an

additional subsidy for single parents.

Page 169: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

159

7.6 NORWAY

There are three types of child care (known as kindergartens) in Norway. Ordinary kindergartens

(barnehager) can be public or private. They offer half-day or full-day service all year round for

children between zero and five years of age. Family kindergartens (familiebarnehager) are

based in private homes, where an assistant works with a maximum of five children, supervised

and mentored by a qualified kindergarten teacher on a weekly basis. Open kindergartens (åpne

barnehager) are part-time drop-in centres with programmes for parents and children to

participate in together, led by a qualified kindergarten teacher.

Obtaining a place in kindergarten is a statutory right for every child, but participation in ECEC is

voluntary. About 50% of the centres in Norway are municipally owned and operated; the other

50% are run by private operators, most of them not-for-profit.

Most child care funding in Norway is operating funding provided in order to keep parent fees

relatively low. The government imposes a statutory fee cap on the parental fee for centre-

based or family child care (NOK 2,655 per month in 2016 or about Can$418 per month or

Can$4,600 per 11-month year14). This means that parents cover about 15% of the cost of ECEC

through parent fees. The bulk of the operating costs of ECEC are covered by government

funding, that is about 85% of operating costs. About 90% of children 1-5 years of age attend

child care.

In addition, there are special funding provisions for lower-income families. Norwegian

municipalities have the central operational, administrative and funding role in child care and

municipalities have also been responsible for developing subsidy schemes for lower-income

families who are not able to afford parental fees. However, since the design of these subsidy

schemes has not been mandated, there has been large variation in these plans, with some

municipalities only giving very small reductions in child care fees to low-income families. In

2015, the national government has mandated that families earning less than about Can$25,000

may not pay more than 6% of their family income for the first child in child care. The second

child would cost 70% of this fee and the third and subsequent children would cost 50%. The

median income in 2015 of couples with children 0-6 years of age in Norway is about

Can$117,000 annually.

A new plan provides 20 hours of free child care per week to 4- and 5-year-old children from

families earning less than about Can$66,000 annually (for 2016-17). Parents have to engage in

14 Norwegian kindergartens are typically open 11 months a year, with the last month (usually July) regarded as a summer

holiday. Annual intake is in August.

Page 170: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

160

some activity (e.g., Norwegian language courses) in order to be eligible. From 2016, this has

been extended to 3-year-old children.

7.7 SWEDEN

Sweden has an integrated and largely universal child care system for children younger than

school age, considered as a part of the education system (but voluntary). It is designed to

support employment and study activities as well as providing play-based education for children

at low or zero cost to parents.

The main type of child care in Sweden is centre-based preschool or förskola. Preschool is also

available provided as home child care. Preschool serves children 1-5 years of age (children

younger than one year of age are nearly all cared for by parents receiving relatively generous

parental payments). Preschool is intended to be safe, fun and instructive; it promotes a

philosophy of the equality of all individuals and particularly of girls and boys. Municipalities are

responsible for ensuring that children who want to attend are provided a place in preschool –

within four months of the request. Most of the preschools (81%) are municipally owned and

operated. About 19% of centres are independently operated – run by parents, staff or as a

business.

Central government defines goals and objectives of child care, such as the national curriculum.

Municipalities play the main role in implementing policy, planning and delivering ECEC services.

Municipalities also determine working conditions and pay of child care staff locally.

Municipalities receive annual quality reports and pedagogical documentation from child care

services Local municipalities are responsible for funding of ECEC services in Sweden, with grants

from the central government, and for fulfilling the legal obligation to provide an ECEC place

from age one to every child who applies for it. Full-day, full-year preschool is not free-of-charge

to working and studying parents, but the maximum parent contribution is controlled. The

charge to the parents depends on parental income in a scheme known as Maxtaxa. Under this

scheme, parents are charged no more than 3% of household income for one child in preschool

up to a maximum monthly household income of 45,390 SEK (January 2017 – about Can$6,950).

That means that the maximum a family could have to pay per month for one child in preschool

is 3% of 45,390 SEK or 1,362 SEK per month. At current exchange rates, that is approximately

Can$209 per month, or Can$2,500 per year. That is the maximum charge for one child, for

families with an income of about Can$83,400 per year or more. Families with lower incomes

would pay less using the 3% rule.

Families with more than one child in preschool will pay more than this. For the second child,

the maximum charge is another 2% of household income (or at maximum about Can$140 per

month). For a third child, the maximum charge is 1% of household income up to about Can$70

Page 171: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

161

per month. In total, parents pay approximately 10% of the total cost of providing child

care/preschool in Sweden

7.8 JURISDICTIONS IN CANADA

The most significant development in terms of establishing affordable early learning and child

care across Canada in recent years has been the expansion of kindergarten and pre-

kindergarten programs. Newfoundland and Labrador, PEI, Nova Scotia, New Brunswick,

Quebec, Ontario, British Columbia and Yukon Territory now offer full school day kindergarten

for five-year-olds. Ontario and NWT also offer full school day kindergarten for four-year-olds.

Quebec, Manitoba, Saskatchewan, Alberta and the Yukon Territory offer varying amounts of

kindergarten for four-year-olds usually targeted to vulnerable populations. This has certainly

reduced the pressure on the length of time that parents are required to pay for full-day child

care services, but the price still limits the choices for most parents for their children under 4 or

5. For children 0-4, fees for licensed child care continue to be out of reach for the majority of

middle-income parents.

A 2017 study of licensed child care fees in Canada found the following average monthly fees in

selected cities:

Table 39

Average Monthly Fees in Selected Cities, 2017

Toronto Montreal Charlottetown Winnipeg Vancouver

Infants $1,758 $168 $738 $ 651 $1,360

Toddlers $1,354 $168 $608 $451 $1,292

Preschool $1,212 $168 $586 $451 $950

Source: Macdonald and Friendly (2017)

There has been expansion and improvements in access in all provinces and territories in

Canada. But, there are three provinces that have done the most to address the affordability

issue. Prince Edward Island, Quebec and Manitoba.

7.8.1 Quebec

There has already been significant discussion about Quebec’s child care policies and effects in

Chapter 6, under the heading “Funding Lessons from the Quebec Experience.”

Page 172: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

162

Quebec is the province that has done the most to make child care affordable. There have been

correspondingly dramatic increases in the use of licensed child care in Quebec as well as a

significant increase in the labour force participation of mothers.

Quebec has two different sliding scales15. One applies to families using reduced-fee child care

(what was originally known as $5 per day child care). Regulated home child care, not-for-profit

CPEs (Centres de la Petite Enfance, or Early Childhood Centres), and some for-profit child care is

known as reduced-fee child care. It is no longer available at $5 per day. As of January, 2017,

the basic rate became $7.75 per day. If your family income after deductions (line 275 of the

Quebec income tax form – equivalent to line 236 on the Ontario income tax form) amounts to

$50,920 or less, you have no more to pay.

Above $50,920, you must pay $8.45 per day, unless your family income is at least $76,380.

From this income level up, the parental fee contribution rises gradually ($0.15 per day for every

$1,000 of family income) until it reaches $21.20 per day at an income level of $161,380. The

maximum daily rate is $21.20.

To put this in annual terms (assuming a full year of 261 days of child care), the basic rate for this

reduced-fee child care is $7.75 per day or annually, $2,022.75. At $76,380 of family income,

you would pay $2,205.45 annually. At the maximum fee, you would pay $5,533.20 per year.

The second child in a family incurs a fee that is half of the fee for the first child, and a third and

subsequent child will receive reduced-fee child care for no additional charge.

The basic rate of $7.75 per day is paid directly to the child care centre or home provider from

whom you receive child care services. Any extra amount is calculated at the end of the year

when your taxes are filed. Of course, it is possible to get your employer to increase deductions

earlier in the year to cover these extra child care costs which might otherwise be a surprise at

tax time.

I said above that Quebec has two different sliding scales. Families who do not use reduced-fee

child care in a centre or home can instead claim a tax credit for child care expenses that is very

generous, and is geared to the level of family income. The tax credit can be used to cover part

of the cost of nearly any paid type of child care, other than reduced-fee child care or care by

parents. The only requirements are that at least one of the parents is in an approved activity

(such as employment, business, education, research funded by a grant or maternity/parental

leave), and that there be proof of the child care expenses.

15 See the calculator at http://www.budget.finances.gouv.qc.ca/budget/outils/garde-net-en.asp, in order to compare these

two alternatives from the point of view of the parent.

Page 173: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

163

The table below shows the different levels of the sliding scale. As you can see, families with

income below $35,060 will have 75% of their child care expenditures refunded, and so on.

Table 40

Child Care Fee Subsidy Relief as a % of Family Income

Family Income Percent of child care expenditures refunded

$0 - $35,060 75%

$35,061 - $41,545 70%

$41,546 - $48,050 65%

$48,051 - $96,085 60%

$96,086 - $137,940 57%

$137,941 - $141,860 50%

$141,861 - $145,780 44%

$145,781 - $149,695 38%

$149,696 - $153,635 32%

$153,636 or over 26%

It seems as if the tax credit for child care expenses will be more expensive for the parent than

the reduced-fee child care However, because reduced-fee child care triggers smaller amounts

of tax reduction under the federal Child Care Expense Deduction, the two alternatives leave

most parents in very similar positions.

One potential objection to this kind of tax credit is that families will not receive assistance until

long after the child care expenditures take place. In fact, it is relatively simple to arrange for

monthly payments of reimbursement to be made in advance of the reconciliation of accounts

at tax time.

7.8.2 Prince Edward Island

Significant changes to both Prince Edward Island’s kindergarten and regulated child care system

were introduced in 2010. Full-day kindergarten in the schools was also announced at this time,

starting in 2011. This had a large impact on the existing regulated child care programs.

Page 174: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

164

Prince Edward Island introduced a new policy framework, Securing the Future for Our Children:

Preschool Excellence Initiative transforming the regulated child care system. It reorganized

existing licensed child care programs into a publicly-managed network of Early Years Centres

and Infant Homes. This reorganization resulted in the regulation of parent fees, wage

enhancements based on a common salary scale, training and a career ladder for staff as well as

sector planning, professional development and management support to programs. Centres

transitioning to Early Years Centres were required to cap fee increases, meet the criteria of

being an Early Years Centre and provide financial information to allow the Department to

assess their need for base funding.

Existing centres were given the option to apply to become an Early Years Centre (EYC), remain a

regulated private non-EYC centre or retire their license (with compensation). The Sector

Adjustment Measures Program offered existing operators an option to sell their license and

also worked on converting available space in schools for Early Years Centres. Bridge funding

was provided during the transition. There are currently 47 Early Years Centres and one family

home child care provider (directly licensed by the province).

The Early Years Centres and Infant Homes are required to implement the Early (0-4) Learning

Framework Curriculum. New professional classifications were introduced to improve quality

and offer a career ladder for educators. All staff working in Early Years Centres and Infant

Homes have to have at least a 90-hour entry level certificate or a one-year ECE Diploma. There

are now four staff classifications in the Early Years Centres:

Director - post-diploma or Degree;

Certified Level 2 - 2-year diploma program

Certified Level 1 - 1 year certificate program

Certified Entry - 90-hour entry level certificate.

Only PEI and Manitoba require a post-diploma or degree credential for Directors of Early

Learning and Child Care Centres. PEI also requires two-thirds of its staff to be certified at Level

2 or above.

PEI has adopted a wage grid in the Early Years Centres for each of these classifications. The

province used this wage grid to calculate the amount of base funding. Providers offering family

home child care are also required to complete a 30-hour training program as well as having

letters of reference and a first-aid certificate.

The daily parent fees set by the province are currently:

Page 175: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

165

Infants: $32

Toddlers: $26

Preschool $25

Fees in Charlottetown are now the third least expensive among Canada’s main cities.

The Early Years Centres receive quarterly base funding (unit funding) based on a formula that

provides operating funding to meet the centres’ expenses together with parent fees or a fee

subsidy for eligible families. Quality Enhancement Grants and Special Needs Grants are also

available.

This initiative was aimed at achieving four of the key elements in the delivery of early learning

and child care services:

Public management of regulated programs: to address quality, accountability for

funding

Capped parent fees: to address parent affordability

Curriculum and professional qualifications: to address quality improvement

Fixed salary grid: to stabilize wages, attract and retain professionals to the profession.

No other province has yet introduced a wage grid or taken over leadership and direction of its

early learning and child care programs to this extent. Alberta has recently introduced a pilot

project involving capped fees at $25 a day with the government paying operating grants to

ensure operational viability but there are only 22 centres participating and the pilot is expected

to last three years followed by a rigorous evaluation. Attempts to ensure high quality, flexible

hours and inclusion of children with special needs are significant aspects of this pilot.

7.8.3 Manitoba

Manitoba has had a number of the same elements in its child care system as does Prince

Edward Island, and Manitoba pioneered many of these reforms. Manitoba has had maximum

parent fees in place for all those non-profit centres that opt in. Base funding is provided to the

child care centres to make up the difference between the parent fee/subsidized fee and the

actual cost of the service.

Daily parent fees are capped at the following amounts and are the second lowest in Canada.

4-10 Hours Over 10 Hours

Page 176: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

166

Infants: $28.00 $42.00

Preschool: $18.80 $28.20

Both regulated child care centres and (directly-licensed) family home providers receive

provincial operating grants (base funding) to make up the difference between the parent

fee/fee subsidy and the actual cost of operations.

Although Manitoba represents the second most publicly-managed system in Canada, it still

experiences substantial staff shortages mainly because of low wages. Even though Manitoba

requires that two-thirds of its staff hold at least Level 2 qualifications, the shortage of staff has

led to a sharp erosion of this requirement in order to keep centres functioning.

The Manitoba Child Care Association has developed a suggested salary grid and benefit package

for use by Manitoba’s child care centres but use of this grid is not mandatory and at present the

actual salaries are still below the recommended amounts.

Manitoba has, however, introduced several creative initiatives to attract, recruit and retain

early childhood educators in the system. These initiatives include:

Introduction of a classification system to provide a career ladder for early childhood

educators:

o Director: Like PEI, Manitoba requires directors to hold a post-diploma or

degree credential.

o ECE 3: Two-year ECE diploma plus post-diploma study

o ECE 2: Two-year ECE diploma

o Child Care Assistant: 40 hours of Early Childhood Education training.

Requirement that two thirds of staff must have an ECE credential. All provinces

except Ontario and the Territories require at least a minimal amount of training

(ranging from 45 to 120 hours) to work with children in a centre. In Ontario, there

are no training requirements for child care assistants and no training requirements

for family home child care providers.

Recruitment and Retention Strategies:

o Manitoba Workplace Training Model is an accelerated apprenticeship

program available to child care assistants who have been in the field for 2

years. They can then apply to enrol in early childhood education courses at

the post-secondary level. The student goes to school 2 days a week and

Page 177: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

167

continues to work in the child care centre for three days a week. The student

does their practicum in their place of employment. The Manitoba

government funds the centre for replacement staff while the student is in

class. It is an extremely popular program and has resulted in a very high

retention rate at the post-secondary level. In addition, staff are certified

through the Competency-Based Assessment (CBA) process.

o Manitoba also actively attempts to recruit ECEs back to the profession by

giving them a bonus of up to $3,000 in 2017.

The Manitoba experience demonstrates that without increases in staff wages (plus the

provision of benefits) the capping of fees together with the provision of operating funding is

insufficient to stabilize the sector, ensure sufficient qualified staff in the sector and guarantee

quality.

7.9 SUMMARY

Different child care funding and management approaches are often discussed discretely as

either/or arrangements. In fact, most jurisdictions choose a combination of tools which have

been tailored to deliver the type of child care system they want. We can learn from how tools

are combined to produce results in other jurisdictions.

England has a strong separation between education services for children 3-5 years and child

care for younger children. There is substantial public funding (with activity requirements) for

the provision of free services for children 3-5. There is a relatively stingy tax credit for younger

children, where child care fees are high.

Australia has a relatively generous sliding scale for the use of approved child care services by

children of families who meet activity requirements. Fees are high; Australia has imposed a fee

cap for sliding scale assistance, but the fee cap is not binding.

New Zealand lowers child care fees with relatively generous supply-side funding. Its child care

has an international reputation for quality, diversity and curriculum. Children 3 or 4 years of

age are eligible for 20 hours per week of (nearly) free child care. For those who cannot afford

the lowered fees, the Ministry of Social Development provides subsidies to low-income families

with income and activity requirements.

Young children have a right to access to child care services in Denmark. Municipalities play a

major role in policy and funding services. Supply-side funding keeps fees below 25% of the cost

of the service, and there are additional subsidies available for low-income families.

Page 178: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

168

Access to kindergartens (child care) in Norway is a statutory right from age one. Many centres

are municipally operated and municipalities play a major role in implementing policy. Most

funding is supply-side funding and the central government imposes a statutory fee cap on

services. Parents pay about 15% of costs. About 90% of children 1-5 years-of-age attend child

care.

Sweden has an integrated and largely universal child care system for children younger than

school age, considered as a part of the education system. It is designed to support employment

and study activities as well as providing play-based education for children at low or zero cost to

parents. In Sweden, as in other Scandinavian countries, municipalities play a major role in

determining and implementing policy and in funding and provision of services. Municipalities

are responsible for ensuring that every child who wants services actually receives them. Parent

fees are limited to no more than 3% of family income for the first child, another 2% for the

second, and another 1% for the third.

Quebec has two funding schemes. Some families have access to reduced-fee services, either in

a CPE, or family child care, or in a for-profit centre that is part of the reduced-fee services

scheme. These families pay fees (2017) according to a sliding scale from $7.75 per day to

$21.20 per day, based on family income. Other families attend services – licensed or unlicensed

– that are not part of the reduced-fee scheme. They can receive financial assistance from a tax

credit for child care expenses, where families earning less than $35,000 receive 75%

reimbursement and other families receive less reimbursement according to family income.

Prince Edward Island has established a publicly-managed network of Early Years Centres and

Infant Homes, where fees, staff wages, professional development and other aspects of services

are regulated. Two-thirds of staff have to have a two-year ECE qualification or better.

Manitoba provides base funding to not-for-profit centres and family homes in order to lower

fees to a legislated fee cap. Two-thirds of staff are required to have an ECE diploma.

Page 179: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

169

CHAPTER 8: DIFFERENT FUNDING APPROACHES – THE

EVIDENCE

Chapter Summary

There are several alternative funding approaches – subsidy systems, universal sliding

scales, free child care, flat parental fees, and tax credits for child care expenses; we

combine these to form four discrete options: a $40K-$240K sliding scale, free preschool

child care plus a $50K-$150K sliding scale, a flat fee of $20 per day per child plus a fully-

funded amended subsidy system, and a tax credit for child care expenses.

We use an Excel spreadsheet-based model to calculate the returns from employment

under the four funding options as compared to the existing funding system; charts show

the amount of additional spendable income available after child care fees as a percent

of pre-tax earnings. In other words, the charts measure how much better off a family is

as a result of the main caregiving parent’s employment; we call this the Ontario Child

Care Employment Returns Model (OCCER Model).

Lone Parent Families

The existing Ontario subsidy system is important in lowering the barriers to employment

for those lone parent families able to access subsidies; however, this financial assistance

disappears above about $85,000. In general, if there were no child care costs,

incentives to employment would be much stronger – child care is an important barrier

to employment.

For lone parent families, either of the sliding scales we are considering provides much

stronger employment incentives than the existing subsidy system; additional spendable

income after child care costs is higher at nearly all levels of income.

The tax credit for child care expenses is negative for low-income lone parent families –

they do much worse than with the subsidy system; above about $50,000, the tax credit

improves employment returns, but not generally by as much as the sliding scale options.

The $20 per day per child flat fee combined with a fully-funded subsidy system improves

employment returns for many families compared to the current situation. However,

between about $20,000 and $90,000, it does not boost employment returns by as much

as the sliding scale funding models.

Page 180: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

170

Two-Parent Families

We model the returns to employment in a two-parent family with two children, where

the potential cost of child care is $30,000 annually. We look at the increase in

spendable income generated for a family when the main caregiving parent becomes

employed (at different possible levels of earnings). In today’s world, the main caregiving

parent is still most often the mother in the family, so we will use the terms “she” and

“her” to refer to the main caregiving parent.

When this parent enters the labour force she gains employment income. But as her

earned income rises, her family will be eligible for less Canada Child Benefit, less Ontario

Child Benefit and she will have to pay income taxes, Canada Pension Plan payments and

Employment Insurance payments. Her spouse will lose the value of the Spousal Credit,

as a credit against his taxes. And, of course, she will face substantial fees for licensed

child care. All of this reduces the percentage of her gross earnings that contributes to

an increase in spendable income for the family, and affects the employment returns

from taking a paid job.

The returns to employment, if this family faces the full child care cost, are

extraordinarily negative. If she cannot earn at least $60,000 per year, there is little

financial reason to be employed.

Subsidy improves these returns dramatically, but for a low earning main caregiving

parent, she will only increase the family’s spendable income by 20%-30% of her gross

earnings. The Ontario child care subsidy system is less helpful to this two-parent family

than to a lone-parent family, largely because this family is only eligible for partial

subsidy.

The tax credit performs poorly for this two-parent family – it is worse than the existing

subsidy system for our two-parent family with two children unless the main caregiving

parent earns $35,000 or more. And it provides lower employment incentives than other

funding policies for other levels of her gross earnings.

The $20 per day per child policy, combined with a well-funded subsidy system, improves

employment returns for a two-parent family better than other policies if her gross

earnings are over $55,000. However, for earnings below about $40,000, this policy fares

much worse, only a modest improvement over the existing subsidy system.

Both the $40K-$240K sliding scale, and the provision of free child care for children of

preschool age combined with a $50K-$150K sliding scale for children of other ages, do

quite well in increasing employment incentives (reducing barriers to employment) for

the main caregiving parent in a two-parent family. The latter policy combination – free

Page 181: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

171

for preschool ages plus a sliding scale for other ages – is noticeably better than the

$40K-$240K sliding scale when the main caregiving parent’s income is quite low.

Child Care Demand and Employment Simulations

Our Ontario Child Care Demand and Employment Simulation Model (OCCDES) provides

statistical estimates of the effects of these alternative funding policies on child care

demand, parental employment, family incomes, measured affordability of child care,

net child care costs, and the overall costs and revenues to government;

Simulations confirm that licensed child care is distinctly unaffordable right now for many

families. Families with young children (0-4) now have to spend over 23% of their after-

tax family income to access licensed child care services. That amounts to 2/3rds of the

income contribution of the average main caregiving parent.

The $40K-$240K sliding scale would transform the child care system into one that is

affordable to virtually all families. Demand for all age categories of licensed child care

increases dramatically in this simulation, more than doubling overall and rising to nearly

six times its current level for infants. The average percent of family income that a family

with children 0-4 would spend on licensed child care would now be 2.7%, and the

average percent of the main caregiving parent’s income contribution would be 9.5%.

Making child care services free of charge for children from 2½-4 years of age would also

have dramatic effects. This is combined with a $50K-$150K sliding scale for infants,

toddlers and kindergarten children. Affordability is very substantially improved for

families in all income categories, particularly lower-income families. On average,

families with children 0-4 would now pay 2.7% of after-tax family income to access

licensed child care services. There are substantial increases in the demand for infant and

toddler child care, and an especially large increase in the demand for preschool care in

this simulation. Overall demand would more than double.

Lowering the full fee to $20 per day per child for infants, toddlers, preschoolers and

kindergarten children is combined with the maintenance and expansion of the subsidy

system to provide extra assistance to low-income families. This simulation substantially

improves affordability – to 3.7% of after-tax family income on average for families with

children 0-4. There are substantial increases in the demand for infant and toddler care

and overall demand for licensed care more than doubles.

The final simulation would adopt a new provincial tax credit for child care expenses. The

existing Child Care Expense Deduction (federal and provincial) continues. We model this

with a continuation of the existing subsidy system; without this the tax credit would

have very negative effects for low-income families. Even so, this tax credit has effects on

Page 182: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

172

affordability that are notably less effective than for alternative funding policies. With

this tax credit, families with children 0-4 would pay, on average, 7.8% of their after-tax

family income to access licensed child care. Families with incomes below $50,000 would

pay 8.0% of net incomes, families between $50,000 and $100,000 would pay 7.3% of

income and families at $100,000 and above would pay out 6.0% of net family income.

This pattern, in relation to family income, is opposite to those of alternative policies.

Only two of these simulations are ones that we think should be considered seriously for

implementation. Both the $40K-$240K sliding scale (Simulation C) and free child care

for preschool children plus a $50K-$150K sliding scale (Simulation D) have very positive

effects on affordability and desirable distributional effects in terms of income groups

and lone parent/two parent affordability.

There are, however, important problems of phase-in. There are not yet enough licensed

spaces to meet all the demand that would be created. In the chapter on transitions, we

discuss how these issues of transition affect our recommendation about the best new

funding approach.

8.1 DIFFERENT FUNDING APPROACHES

We have discussed different child care funding tools in the chapter on the theory of different

funding approaches, and in the chapter on child care policies in other jurisdictions. There are

four funding tools that are widely used:

- sliding scales of fees, where the amount that families pay for child care depends on their

income.

- provision of free child care services.

- flat fees – a fixed fee for everyone, independent of parental income.

- funding schemes in the form of a tax credit or tax deduction.

These funding tools can be used on their own or in combination. In this chapter, we evaluate

the effects of four different combinations of policy reforms to improve affordability of child

care in Ontario

A. Ontario could adopt a generous sliding scale of child care fees, where all families with

earnings less than $40,000 pay nothing, all families with incomes above $240,000 pay

80% of the full cost of the child care they use, and in between, families pay an increasing

percentage of the full fee as their income is higher.

Page 183: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

173

B. Ontario, recognizing the popularity and developmental value of licensed child care for

children of preschool age - between 2½ years of age and junior kindergarten – could

provide child care free of charge to these children. We model a couple of alternative

complementary schemes to improve affordability for children of other ages. One is what

we call a $50K-$150K sliding scale, meaning that families with income below $50,000

pay nothing and families with income above $150,000 pay 80% of the full fee. Between

these income levels, the percentage of the full fee payable increases gradually.

C. Ontario could cap licensed child care fees at a flat fee of $20 per day per child for

infants, toddlers, preschoolers and kindergarten children. An expanded subsidy system

(a form of sliding scale) would provide financial assistance to families that cannot afford

$20 per day and families with children of other ages.

D. Kevin Milligan has recently recommended replacing the Child Care Expense Deduction

with a tax credit for child care expenses similar to one currently available in Quebec.

Ontario could adopt a version of his federally-oriented plan, with a demand-side sliding

scale in the form of an Ontario child care expenses credit. Families would be reimbursed

with 75% of the child care fees paid by families with low incomes, tapering off to 26% at

high incomes.

In this chapter, we use numerical and statistical methods to determine what the effects of

these different policy reforms would be. We are interested in comparing how different families

would be affected by each of these different policy directions. We are interested in the effects

on parental incomes, the change in net child care fees for families, the changes in measured

affordability, the effects on family decisions to use licensed child care, and the effects on labour

force participation of parents. And, of course, we are interested in what the net cost to the

Ontario government of each policy alternative would be.

This chapter will present and summarize evidence from our investigation into the effects of

these alternative child care funding reforms.

We have used two different approaches to assessing these funding alternatives.

1. Using an Excel-type spreadsheet-based model, we have modelled the tax and benefit

system facing Ontario families at different possible income levels.16 To this, we have

added the child care funding system proposed by each of these funding alternatives.

16 Appendix D summarizes the tax and benefit rules that apply to families with young children in Ontario.

Page 184: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

174

This allows us to produce mappings – charts – which show how taxes, benefits and child

care expenses combine to affect the percent of gross income that ends up being

available to each family as spendable income (after child care fees). Different child care

funding policies will leave families with different amounts of spendable income. In

other words, these charts will show us how the different policies we are considering will

affect the returns parents get from employment. Child care is a barrier to employment

when it dramatically reduces the returns from paid work. An affordability policy is good

when it substantially improves the returns from employment. We call this model the

Ontario Child Care Employment Returns Model (OCCER model). It is in the spirit of work

done by Immervoll and Barber (2005) and Richardson (2012).

This first approach does not require detailed information about Ontario families (e.g.,

how many are rich or poor, how many and what ages of children, etc.). The calculations

are based on the situations faced by hypothetical families at different income levels.

2. We have also built a second model – a child care policy simulation model - which relies

on very detailed data about Ontario families, their income, educational, immigrant,

marital and child characteristics. This model, resident in the Research Data Centre at

the University of Toronto, uses data on Ontario families with children 0-6 years of age

from the National Household Survey of 201117. At its heart, this model uses statistical

analysis to forecast the child care and employment decisions of parents. These

decisions are affected by a wide range of family characteristics as well as by policies that

affect either parent incomes or the net fee that families must pay for licensed child care.

We will discuss some details of this simulation model in the second section of this

chapter. We call this the Ontario Child Care Demand and Employment Simulation

Model (OCCDES Model).

8.2 MODEL #1 (SPREADSHEET MODEL) – RETURNS TO

EMPLOYMENT

8.2.1 Lone Parent Families

Parents have little incentive to work or use child care if most of their earnings disappear in

taxes and child care costs. This section quantifies the income gain parents will get from

participation in employment when employment requires the payment of substantial child care

fees. We assess the effects of child care costs on family resources by looking at the percentage

17 This model could be updated when 2016 Census data is available.

Page 185: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

175

of income parents have available after a transition into employment. These incomes are

disposable or take-home incomes (we call it “spendable” income) measured after child care

costs and after all income taxes, after the payment to the family of all child benefits, and after

payroll taxes such as Employment Insurance contributions and Canada Pension Plan

contributions are deducted from gross earnings.

Charts 3 through 6 describe the situation faced by a lone parent family living in Ontario. This

family has one child aged 2 (a toddler) and full child care fees are assumed to be $17,000 per

year. When the lone parent enters the labour force, she gains employment income. But as her

earned income rises, she will be eligible for less Canada Child Benefit, less Ontario Child Benefit

and will have to pay income taxes, Canada Pension Plan payments and Employment Insurance

payments.18 And, of course, she may face substantial fees for licensed child care. The chart

calculates her increase in spendable income when she goes out to work in paid employment.

This increase in spendable income is shown as a percentage of her gross earnings (her annual

pay before taxes), and we can interpret it as her returns from employment – the percent of her

extra income she has available to spend after taxes and child care costs.

Have a look at the chart labelled “Returns from Employment After Child Care: With and

Without Child Care Costs, With and Without Subsidy - Lone Parents.” It has three lines on it.

Each reflects the situation of a single parent family with a child aged 2. For two of the lines, she

has annual child care fees of $17,000. For comparison, the other line shows her situation with

no child care costs. Each of these lines measures the contribution made to her spendable

income from being employed; the amount of additional income she would have to spend is

expressed as a percentage of her gross earnings (i.e., her earnings before taxes and child care

costs). The higher the percentage she gets to keep, the lower are the effective barriers to

employment for lone parents. The lower the percentage, the higher these barriers are.

Start with the top line – the blue line with round-shaped markers; this shows the impact of the

tax and benefit systems on take-home income of a single parent family when there are no child

care costs. In other words, this line gets rid of child care costs and shows us how much her

earnings are affected by taxes and benefits without considering child care costs.

The tax and benefit system is designed to provide strong employment incentives, especially at

lower levels of earnings. As you can see, when employment earnings are very low, a single

parent’s job will increase disposable income by more than 100% of gross employment earnings

(up to about $15,000 of earnings). Up to $45,000, the combination of taxes and benefits still

18 Low-income lone parents could also be eligible for social assistance (Ontario Works) payments and might lose some or all of

these at higher levels of income. Ontario Works has special arrangements for child care assistance. We do not consider the

effects of social assistance.

Page 186: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

176

leaves this lone parent family with over 80% of her gross employment earnings. A large

percentage of lone parent families have incomes below this level. Even beyond $45,000, lone

parent families get to keep over 70% of gross employment earnings up to about $110,000. In

other words, if there are no child care costs, the tax and benefit systems are designed to

minimize barriers to labour force participation for single parents.

The lowest line on the chart, the purple-coloured line with triangle markers, indicates by how

much spendable income (i.e., after child care expenses) rises as a lone parent family enters the

labour force if she had $17,000 of child care costs but could not access the current child care

subsidy system. This chart measures the net income contribution of employment as a percent

of the gross employment earnings of the lone parent. At low levels of earnings, the net

contribution from employment is negative, or only a small percentage of gross earnings. Out to

$65,000 of gross earnings, she gets to keep less than 50% of her income; there is little incentive

to be employed if this lone parent has to pay full child care costs.

The middle line, the red one with the square markers, is the “subsidy” line. It shows the

percent of gross earnings from which this family would benefit if in receipt of child care subsidy

at different levels of annual gross employment earnings. The existing child care subsidy system

goes a long way to restore the employment incentives built into the tax and benefit system for

low-income lone parents (if they are able to access subsidies). The existing subsidy system

reduces child care expenses to zero for families earning $20,000 or less. Up to this point, the

line with squares lies directly on top of the one with round markers. Up to $40,000, annual

child care expenses remain modest (below $2,000), so, at these income levels, a lone parent

family’s spendable income is still at or close to 80% of gross employment earnings. Beyond

$40,000, child care subsidy coverage diminishes rapidly, so that at $70,000 of gross

employment earnings, the lone parent’s spendable income is only about 60% of gross

employment earnings. Beyond $90,000 of employment earnings, there is no assistance

provided by the subsidy system (for this particular family situation).

What can we learn from this chart? Mostly, that the subsidy system matters. Without

subsidies, lone parents have very little incentive to be employed. With subsidy, low-earning

single parents get to keep the large majority of their earnings, while receiving lower-cost child

care. Because of financial constraints and space shortages, subsidies have not always been

available to those families eligible to receive them; this chart shows the effect of subsidies on

those able to access them.

In sum, the tax and benefit system is designed to provide strong employment incentives for

lone parents (to reduce barriers to workforce entry), but child care costs can dramatically

reduce the potential returns from employment. In fact, without a subsidy system, there would

Page 187: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

177

be either negative or very modest incentives for lone parents to seek employment19. The chart

gives us a strong visual representation of the importance of the child care subsidy system for

lower-earning lone parents (those able to earn up to about $40,000 annually). For lone parent

families in this income range, the subsidy system largely restores employment incentives

(income returns from work). For those families who receive a child care subsidy, employment

incentives diminish substantially and rapidly above $40,000 of annual earnings. However, out

to about $85,000 of gross earnings, the subsidy system provides much stronger employment

incentives than if this lone parent had to pay the unsubsidized cost of child care.

19 In this discussion, we ignore the employment disincentives created by social assistance. These employment disincentives are

well known. We focus instead on employment barriers that are created by child care costs. It is possible to use the OCCER

model to look at social assistance and child care issues together.

Page 188: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

178

Chart 3

Returns from Employment After Child Care: With and Without Child Care Costs, With and Without Subsidy - Lone Parents

-60%

-50%

-40%

-30%

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

70%

80%

90%

100%

$10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 $60,000 $70,000 $80,000 $90,000 $100,000 $110,000 $120,000 $130,000 $140,000 $150,000

Spen

dab

le In

com

e as

% o

f G

ross

Ear

nin

gs

Pre-tax Employment Earnings of Lone Parent

No child care costs Child care costs with no subsidy Child care costs as reduced by subsidy system

Page 189: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

179

8.3 ALTERNATIVE FUNDING MODELS

On the following pages, we present three charts that describe the effects of the alternative

funding proposals described at the beginning of this chapter. Putting all of the lines on one

chart makes the results difficult to read, so we show the results in three charts (and draw

conclusions in the accompanying text).

The first of these charts looks at two alternative sliding scales that deliver more favourable

results than the current subsidy system. Each would affect the employment returns

(spendable income after child care costs) for single parents. Our benchmark is the existing

subsidy system (for those able to access a subsidy). This subsidy reference line is the red line

shown with squares on it. This shows the impact of the current subsidy system on net earnings

- the percentage of gross earnings by which this single parent is better off than she would be

without employment. This line repeats the child care subsidy line from the previous chart.

There are two other lines on this chart. The first is a sliding scale where families earning less

than $40,000 pay nothing and the percentage of the full-fee paid increases gradually until

$240,000 of income (a $40K-$240K sliding scale). At $240,000 of income or above, a family

would pay 80% of the full-fee, shown by the orange or rust-coloured line with triangle markers.

An alternative sliding scale (one that could be combined with free child care for preschool

children) can be described as $50K-$150K. Families earning less than $50,000 would pay

nothing, families earning over $150,000 would pay 80% of the full fee. Between these two

income levels, the percent payable would rise smoothly from 0% to 80%. This is shown as a

black line with square markers.

Either of these sliding scales leaves more spendable income in the hands of a lone parent

family; barriers to labour force participation are reduced compared to the current situation

with child care subsidy. Either of the sliding scales is positive for any lone parents earning

above $20,000 and has identical coverage for those earning less than $20,000. Above about

$70,000 of income for a lone parent, the $40K-$240K sliding scale is somewhat more generous

than the $50K-$150K sliding scale.

The second chart in this group shows the subsidy line again, for reference, along with two new

lines. The subsidy line is red with square markers. The yellow line with round markers

represents the combination of a fixed fee of $20 per day per child along with keeping the

existing subsidy system for lower-income families. As you can see, out to about $50,000, this

funding plan treats lone parents in the same way as the current subsidy system – they are

neither better nor worse off. Beyond $50,000 of gross income, the lone parent gets to keep

about 67% of gross earnings, falling to about 62% as income rises towards $150,000. This is

considerably more rewarding than the current subsidy system.

Page 190: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

180

The green line, with diamond-shaped markers, represents the effects on lone parents of the tax

credit for child care expenses described at the beginning of this chapter. As you can see, out to

about $50,000 of income, this funding proposal would be worse than the current subsidy

system at providing employment incentives for lone parents. Beyond this income level, the tax

credit leaves more spendable income in lone parent hands than the current subsidy system,

and parallels the effects of the $20 per day alternative. Beyond $135,000 of income, the

income support from this tax credit diminishes.

Even though it makes for a potentially confusing chart, it is useful to put all of these lines on a

single chart so they can all be compared. That is what the next chart does. The red line with

square markers represents the effects on spendable income of the current subsidy system for a

lone parent with $17,000 of child care costs. The black line with square markers represents the

effects on spendable income of the $50K-$150K sliding scale. The rust-coloured line with

triangle markers represents the effects of the $40K-$240K sliding scale. The yellow line, with

round markers, represents the effects on spendable income of the $20 per day fixed fee

combined with additional assistance for low-income families. The green line, with diamond-

shaped markers reflects the percent of gross income left in lone parent hands with a tax credit

for child care expenses (replacing the existing subsidy system).

Summarizing what we see on the chart, the tax credit creates significantly higher employment

barriers for lower-earning single parent families than does the existing subsidy system. If the

single parent earns gross income below $50,000, she would have more income left to her by

the subsidy system than by the tax credit.

Beyond $50,000 or $55,000, both the $20 per day and tax credit approach provide more of a

boost in spendable income than the current subsidy system. However, out to $90,000, either

one of the sliding scales is considerably more generous than either $20 per day or the tax

credit. It is worth recalling that according to the 2016 Census, about 85% of lone parent families

with children 0-5 in Ontario had gross incomes below $60,000.

Either one of the sliding scales provides stronger employment incentives for lone parents than

the current subsidy scheme. This is true at low levels of income compared to the existing

subsidy system and relative to competing policies out to about $100,000 of gross earnings.

With this type of sliding scale of payments, the large majority of lone parents would have

spendable income (i.e., after taxes and child care costs) equal to more than 65% or more of

their gross employment earnings. Relative to the existing subsidy system, either one of the

sliding scales would substantially reduce employment barriers for lone parents able to earn

$20,000 or more (and would reduce employment barriers equally for those earning less than

$20,000).

Page 191: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

181

Chart 4

Returns from Employment After Child Care with Alternative Sliding Scales - Lone Parents

50%

55%

60%

65%

70%

75%

80%

85%

90%

95%

100%

$10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 $60,000 $70,000 $80,000 $90,000 $100,000 $110,000 $120,000 $130,000 $140,000 $150,000

Spen

dab

le In

com

e as

% o

f G

ross

Ear

nin

gs

Pre-tax Employment Earnings of Lone Parent

Existing subsidy system $40K-$240K sliding scale $50K-$150K sliding scale

Page 192: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

182

Page 193: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

183

Chart 5

Returns from Employment with $20 Per Day and Tax Credit Policies- Lone Parents

50%

55%

60%

65%

70%

75%

80%

85%

90%

95%

100%

$10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 $60,000 $70,000 $80,000 $90,000 $100,000 $110,000 $120,000 $130,000 $140,000 $150,000

Spen

dab

le In

com

e as

% o

f G

ross

Ear

nin

gs

Pre-tax Employment Earnings of Lone Parent

Existing subsidy system $20 per day plus subsidy Quebec-style tax credit

Page 194: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

184

Chart 6

Returns from Employment After Child Care With Alternative Possible Child Care Policies - Lone Parents

50%

55%

60%

65%

70%

75%

80%

85%

90%

95%

100%

$10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 $60,000 $70,000 $80,000 $90,000 $100,000 $110,000 $120,000 $130,000 $140,000 $150,000

Spen

dab

le In

com

e as

% o

f G

ross

Ear

nin

gs

Pre-tax Employment Earnings of Lone Parent

Existing subsidy system $40K-$240K sliding scale $50K-$150K sliding scale

$20 per day plus subsidy Quebec-style tax credit

Page 195: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

185

What do we conclude from these charts? First that the existing subsidy system is very

important at reducing barriers to employment for those lone-parent families that are able to

access it and who earn less than about $40,000. Above that income, either the $40K-$240K

sliding scale of fees or the $50K-$150K sliding scale provide strong employment incentives and

strongly reduced net costs of child care. The credit for child care expenses is inadequate in

providing employment incentives for lower-income lone parents. The $20 per day funding

policy (combined with well-funded subsidies) matches the effects of the existing subsidy system

out to about $50,000 of lone-parent earnings, but is less generous than the sliding scale policies

above this, until income reaches levels that are quite high.

8.3.1 Two Parent Families

We have also produced a set of charts – Charts 7 through 10 - detailing the situation of a

hypothetical two-parent family. One parent is employed earning a gross annual wage of

$40,000 per year. The family has two children – one two years of age and one three years of

age – a toddler and a preschooler. If the other parent – the main caregiving parent - is

employed, the family will use licensed child care costing $30,000 for the two children. In

today’s world, the main caregiving parent is still most often the mother in the family, so we will

use the terms “she” and “her” to refer to the main caregiving parent (Kleven, Landais and

Sogaard, 2018). The charts below show the family situation at different levels of her gross

earnings – pre-tax earnings. She might earn anything between $10,000 and $150,000 to add to

her partner’s income.

She would like to know how much of her gross earnings she will have available to spend after

deciding to take up paid employment – her returns from employment. The returns from

employment is a measure of her incentive to be employed, or, looked at another way, the

amount she does not get to keep is a measure of the barriers to entering the labour force. The

higher the percentage of income she gets to keep, the more worthwhile employment is. The

more income goes to taxes and child care, the bigger the barriers to employment.

The chart measures, at each possible level of her gross earnings, how much additional

spendable income her family will have, compared to the situation when she is not employed.

Spendable income is what she has left after taxes, benefits and the net cost of child care have

been taken into account. Her family’s additional spendable income when she is employed is

expressed as a percentage of her gross earnings, so it measures the percentage of her gross

income that is left to her family as additional spendable income.

When this parent enters the labour force she gains employment income. But as her earned

income rises, her family will be eligible for less Canada Child Benefit, less Ontario Child Benefit

and she will have to pay income taxes, Canada Pension Plan payments and Employment

Insurance payments. Her spouse will lose the value of the Spousal Credit, as a credit against his

Page 196: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

186

taxes. And, of course, she will face substantial fees for licensed child care. All of this reduces

the percentage of her gross earnings that contributes to an increase in spendable income for

the family, and affects the employment returns from taking a paid job.

Chart 7 replicates the situation modelled in Chart 3, except now for a two-parent family.

Amongst other things, it shows the situation if the family somehow has no child care costs (the

blue line with round markers). Taxes and benefits reduce the increase in the family’s spendable

income, so the increase in spendable income is between 50%-60% of her gross earnings.

The red line, with square markers, shows the family’s situation if she is able to get an Ontario

child care subsidy. Her children do not receive a full subsidy, even when her earnings are low,

because her husband already earns $40,000. So, child care subsidy is helpful, but the family still

has a significant child care cost burden, reducing spendable income. At low levels of her

earnings, the increase in spendable income is just over 20% of gross earnings. From $25,000

on, spendable income increases by between 30%-40% of her gross annual earnings. Even with

a child care subsidy, there is not a substantial employment incentive.

The situation of this family if there are $30,000 of child care costs, but no child care subsidy is

available, is, of course, much worse. This is shown by the purple line with triangle markers.

When the potential earnings of the mother are low, it makes little sense to seek employment.

Below about $45,00020 of earnings, her decision to work would reduce family spendable

income instead of increasing it; the child care costs are greater than her after-tax contribution

to household income. On the chart, her employment returns peak at 39% at $150,000 of

income – a relatively modest increase for what appears to be a substantial level of earnings.

Chart 8 shows how alternative funding policies could affect this family’s returns from

employment of the main caregiving parent. The effects of the existing subsidy system are

again shown as the red line with square markers. As mentioned for Chart 7, the subsidy system

leaves employment returns low for this two-parent family. However, the other two funding

policies modelled boost employment returns up to just about 50% or above – a very substantial

improvement compared to the existing subsidy system. The black line with square markers

shows the impact on this family of making preschool-aged child care free and a $50K-$150K

sliding scale for other ages of children. Across income levels, the net return from employment

is pretty constant at about 50% of gross earnings, certainly much better than the returns if

there is no child care subsidy, and much better than the coverage given by the current subsidy

20 This result depends on the cost of child care, but the pattern is the same at other levels of child care costs. If total child care

costs for two children were, somehow, only $15,000 per year, then if her earnings were less than $20,000, her decision to work

would be reducing family spendable income. And her employment return would not get above 40% of her gross earnings until

she was earning about $70,000 per year.

Page 197: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

187

system. The rust-coloured line on Chart 8 shows the effect of the $40K-$240K sliding scale.

This policy reduces employment barriers compared to the existing subsidy system, but not

quite as much, compared to free preschool plus the $50K-$150K sliding scale, for two-parent

families with the main caregiving parent earning less than about $30,000.

Chart 9 shows two different funding policies compared to the effects of the current subsidy

system. The yellow line, with round markers, shows the policy of capping fees at $20 per day

per child, combined with the existing subsidy system. As with lone parents, this policy is not as

good at reducing employment barriers for lower-income families. When the main caregiving

parent in the two-parent family earns less than about $50,000, the $20 a day policy generates

employment returns that are between 20% - 50%, which is lower than the sliding scale policies

modelled on the previous chart. Beyond $50,000 of earnings, the $20 per day policy enhances

employment returns to about 55%.

Page 198: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

188

Chart 7

Returns from Employment After Child Care: With and Without Child Care Costs, With and Without Subsidy - Two Parent, Two

Child Family

-200%

-180%

-160%

-140%

-120%

-100%

-80%

-60%

-40%

-20%

0%

20%

40%

60%

$10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 $60,000 $70,000 $80,000 $90,000 $100,000 $110,000 $120,000 $130,000 $140,000 $150,000

Spen

dab

le In

com

e as

% o

f M

ain

Car

egiv

ing

Pare

nt'

s G

ross

Ear

nin

gs

Pre-tax Employment Earnings of Main Caregiving Parent in Two-Parent Family

No subsidy No child care costs With subsidy

Page 199: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

189

Chart 8

Returns from Employment After Child Care: Sliding Scales and Free Child Care Options - Two Parent, Two Child Family

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

$10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 $60,000 $70,000 $80,000 $90,000 $100,000 $110,000 $120,000 $130,000 $140,000 $150,000Spen

dab

le In

com

e as

% o

f G

ross

Ear

nin

gs

Pre-tax Employment Earnings of Main Caregiving Parent in Two-Parent Family

With subsidy $40K-$240K sliding scale Free preschool CC + $50K-$150K sliding scale

Page 200: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

190

Chart 9

Returns from Employment After Child Care: $20 per day and Tax Credit Policies - Two Parent, Two Child Family

-40%

-30%

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

$10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 $60,000 $70,000 $80,000 $90,000 $100,000 $110,000 $120,000 $130,000 $140,000 $150,000

Spen

dab

le In

com

e as

% o

f G

ross

Ear

nin

gs

Pre-tax Employment Earnings of Main Caregiving Parent in Two-Parent Family

With subsidy $20 per day + subsidy Tax Credit, no subsidy

Page 201: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

191

Chart 10

-40%

-30%

-20%

-10%

0%

10%

20%

30%

40%

50%

60%

$10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 $50,000 $60,000 $70,000 $80,000 $90,000 $100,000 $110,000 $120,000 $130,000 $140,000 $150,000

Spen

dab

le In

com

e as

% o

f G

ross

Ear

nin

gs

Pre-tax Employment Earnings of Main Caregiving Parent in Two-Parent Family

With subsidy $40K-$240K sliding scale

Free preschool CC + $50K-$150K sliding scale $20 per day + subsidy

Tax Credit, no subsidy

Page 202: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

192

Returns from Employment After Child Care With Alternative Possible Child Care Policies - Two Parent, Two Child Family

Page 203: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

193

The other line on chart 9 – the green one with diamond-shaped markers – represents the

effects of a tax credit which replaces the existing subsidy system as a demand-side sliding scale.

Up to about $35,000 of earnings for the main caregiving parent, this policy generates worse

employment returns than even the existing subsidy system – below about 30% of her gross

earnings. Under these circumstances, the incentives to be employed with two children are very

small. Beyond $35,000, the tax credit delivers employment returns better than the current

subsidy system, but only reaches 50% at about $90,000 of her earnings (i.e., $130,000 of family

gross income, because we have assumed her partner earns $40,000). Beyond about $135,000

of family income, this tax credit has a region of poor employment incentives because child care

assistance drops dramatically over a $20,000 income range (from about $135,000 to $155,000).

Chart 10 is difficult to read, but very useful because it compares all four of our funding policy

alternatives to the effects of the current subsidy system. What we can see is that the current

child care subsidy system (the red line with square markers) does not shelter this two-parent

family very well from the negative effects of child care fees on the spendable income generated

by employment. By working, this parent only increases the family’s spendable income by

between 20% - 40% of her gross earnings. So, for instance, if she decided to return to work for

a $60,000 salary, the family’s spendable income (after taxes, benefits and child care costs)

would be less than $20,000 higher than when she stayed at home. That’s not much incentive

to return to work – a significant barrier to employment.

Which of the four alternative funding policies does the best job of enhancing these

employment incentives? The clear loser in this competition is the tax credit. It reduces

employment incentives relative to the existing subsidy system for parental earnings less than

about $35,000 and it is not better at restoring employment returns at any other level of

income. The $20 per day plus subsidy plan is better than other funding reforms at enhancing

employment returns above about $55,000 (i.e., family gross income of about $95,000).

However, it does a poor job for the many main caregiving parents whose earnings are low.

Either one of the funding policies with a sliding scale does a good job across the income range

at enhancing employment returns. However, at quite low levels of earnings, the policy that

provides free child care for children of preschool age and a $50K-$150K sliding scale is

noticeably better.

Page 204: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

194

8.4 MODEL #2 (BEHAVIOURAL MODEL) – DEMAND FOR CHILD

CARE, EMPLOYMENT, AND OTHER IMPACTS

Our Ontario Child Care Demand and Employment Simulation Model (OCCDES) models the

employment decision made by the main caregiving parent in the family. This is the parent

whose employment decision will trigger the demand for child care arrangements. The main

caregiving parent21 is presumed to make linked decisions about the amount of employment she

will seek (full-time, part-time or not currently employed) and simultaneously about the type of

child care she will use for her children who are younger than compulsory school age (typically 0-

6 years). Because it models the changes in child care and employment decisions that will be

made as funding of child care changes, it is called a “behavioural model”.

The types of child care available are grouped into three categories: licensed care, unlicensed or

unregulated care by a non-relative, and care by parents or relatives of the child. If the main

caregiving parent is not currently employed, it is assumed that she provides primary child care

for the child. As a result, our model seeks to estimate the factors that lead the main caregiving

parent to choose from seven possible combinations of employment and child care:

1. full-time employed and using licensed child care,

2. full-time employed and using unregulated paid care by a non-relative,

3. full-time employed and care provided by parents or relatives,

4. part-time employed and using licensed child care,

5. part-time employed and using unregulated paid care by a non-relative,

6. part-time employed and using care provided by parents or relatives, and finally,

7. the main caregiving parent is not currently employed and provides the primary care for

the child.

Each of these alternatives represents a quite different strategy for managing life with young

children (Stalker and Ornstein, 2013). Some strategies use more money, but then that money

needs to be earned. Some strategies use substantial amounts of parent or relative time to

provide child care, but this is combined with the earning of income (and the dramatic reduction

of any other uses of parental time). Some strategies use parental time, and forego earned

21 The main caregiving parent is most frequently the mother, but may be a sole parent father or one member of a gay male two-

parent family.

Page 205: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

195

income. Because these alternatives represent different strategies of caring for young children,

decisions about using these alternatives are differentially affected by different factors.

8.4.1 Main Determinants of Child Care Demand and Employment

The key factors that are incorporated in the simulation model are:

1. The net (after-tax, after-benefit) price the family has to pay for all children younger than

compulsory school age in the family,

2. The net (after-tax, after-benefit) expected employment earnings of the main caregiving

parent,

3. The net (after-tax, after-benefit) other income in the family (principally the spouse’s

income but also including a number of government benefits for either sole parent or

two parent families),

4. The presence in the family of infants, of toddlers, of preschool-aged children,

5. The number of siblings 0-9 years of age in the family,

6. Whether the principal caregiving parent has a post-secondary education or not,

7. Whether the principal caregiving parent is a sole parent or not,

8. Whether the main caregiving parent is Canadian-born or a recent immigrant (and how

recent).

Each of these factors is expected to affect differentially the decisions families make about child

care and employment strategies. For instance, families with larger numbers of children are

more likely to decide to not be employed (unless subsidy is available). Families who have very

recently immigrated to Canada are less likely to be employed than families who immigrated a

while ago, or families in which the caregiving parent is Canadian-born. Families in which the

main caregiving parent has a post-secondary education are more likely to use licensed child

care and be employed. And so on.

Many of these variables have more than one path of influence on the child care and

employment decisions of families. For instance, having an infant child will increase the price

that families would have to pay to use licensed care, but many parents also have strong feelings

about what types of care are most appropriate for very young children. The variable listed

above “presence of infants” will pick up the second of these effects; the price of child care will

pick up the first.

Page 206: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

196

The model includes statistical estimates of the responsiveness of child care and employment

decisions to each of these factors.22 For modelling policy, responsiveness to the price of

licensed child care is often particularly important. Our statistical estimates find that child care

and employment behaviour is quite sensitive to price changes. This is an important driver in

the simulations discussed below.

Elasticity is a concept that measures the percentage change in one thing for a one unit change

in another thing. We find that the elasticity of licensed child care demand to the price of

licensed child care is -1.30 – in other words, we expect that when child care price falls by 10%,

child care demand will rise by 13.0%.

As for employment, we find that a 10% rise in licensed care prices would be associated with

approximately a 5.2% fall in full-time employment of main caregiving parents. Or, that a 10%

cut to licensed child care fees, would be associated with a 5.2% rise in full time employment.

This refers to full-time employment. Some of this movement into full-time employment comes

from parents entering the labour force. But some is based on a movement from part-time

employment. As a result, total employment is predicted to rise by about 2.3% when child care

fees are cut by 10%.

8.4.2 Results from Simulations

The tables below – an entire group of tables – shows the results of simulations on the different

funding approaches outlined at the beginning of this chapter. We also model the current

funding situation, known as the Base Case. And, we model the potential effects of the existing

subsidy system if all funding and space limitations and stigma were removed.

The first simulation (Simulation A) is the Base Case. Information on the current child care

and subsidy situations has been used to make this simulation represent current reality of child

care demand and employment decisions in Ontario. It is most appropriate to interpret other

simulations as an alternative to or a change from this Base Case. The Base Case reflects the

current child care subsidy system as it is. The current subsidy system is quite restrictive in

certain ways. Families may be eligible for subsidy but not able to access payments because of

government financial limitations. Alternatively, money may be available, but child care centres

in the local area do not have spaces available for the age and number of children needed.

The second simulation (Simulation B) maintains existing subsidy eligibility rules but

assumes there are no financial or space limitations on the access to child care subsidies. In

22 The technical details of this type of model are described in Cleveland, Krashinsky, Colley and Avery-Nunez, 2016b.

Page 207: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

197

other words, any family earning less than $20,000 who wishes to be employed and use licensed

child care will pay nothing for child care. Above that, and up to $40,000, a family would pay

10% of the extra income. Above that a family will pay 30% of additional income earned until

they earn a high enough income that they are no longer subsidized. That means a family would

pay $0 at $20,000 of family income, $2,000 at $40,000 of family income, up to $8,000 at

$60,000 of income, up to $14,000 at $80,000 of income and up to $20,000 at $100,000 of

income. So, if a family was using infant care that cost more than $20,000 or if the sum of the

full-fees for an infant and toddler was more than $20,000, the family could still get a modest

amount of financial assistance at $100,000 of income. But most families getting any substantial

amount of financial assistance would have incomes below about $80,000.

The third simulation (Simulation C) models a sliding scale, but one that is different both in

generosity and in design from the existing subsidy system (which is also a form of sliding scale).

We call this new sliding scale the $40K-$240K sliding scale. With the subsidy system, the

amount of your income determines directly the total child care fee you have to pay. With this

alternative type of sliding scale, your income determines what fraction of the full child care fee

charged by the child care service you have to pay. All families with earnings less than $40,000

pay nothing, all families above $240,000 pay 80% of the full cost of the child care they use, and

in between, families pay an increasing percentage of the full fee as their income is higher. So,

for instance, a family earning $60,000 would pay 16% of the full fee; a family earning $100,000

would pay 32% of the full fee; a family earning $140,000 would pay 48% of the full fee and so

on. The amount a family pays depends both on what their family income is, and on the number

and ages of their children. Their income determines the percent and the number and ages of

children determine how much the full fee is.

The fourth simulation (Simulation D) models making licensed child care free of charge for

all children between 2½ years of age and kindergarten – free child care for preschoolers. This is

combined with a sliding scale for other children in the family. This sliding scale can be called a

$50K-$150K sliding scale. Similar to the sliding scale described above, the amount of family

income determines the percentage of the full child care fee that has to be paid for each child.

Families earning less than $50,000 would pay nothing, families earning more than $150,000

would pay 80%, and there would be a sliding scale of payments between. This sliding scale

would be available for infants and toddlers but also children of kindergarten age (and

presumably school age children, but our model only covers the effects related to children

younger than compulsory school age).

The fifth simulation (Simulation E) provides prospective users of child care with a flat fee of

$20 per child per day ($5,220 on an annual basis) for infants, toddlers, preschoolers and

children of kindergarten age. The government would have to provide sufficient base funding

for child care services so that they could lower the fee for child care for all ages to $20 per day

per child. The existing subsidy system is not abolished, but it is amended in a way similar to

Page 208: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

198

that described for Simulation B. In particular, all financial and space restrictions on subsidy are

assumed to be eliminated, so all eligible families that our model predicts will want to use

licensed child care can access it. And, there is a relatively small change to income-eligibility

requirements to make this more generous. Instead of child care being free of charge for

families at incomes below $20,000, child care services would now be free for families with

incomes below $40,000. Above that, the subsidy rules would resume, so families between

$40,000 and $60,000 would pay 10% of their incremental income for child care, and families

above that would pay another 30% of the incremental income.

The sixth simulation (Simulation F) models a tax credit for child care expenses similar to one

available currently in Quebec (Laurin and Milligan, 2017). As suggested by Kevin Milligan, the

tax credit would reimburse 75% of child care expenses at low incomes and falls to 26%

coverage at higher levels of income. In other words, families at low incomes have to pay 25% of

the full-fee and high-income earners pay 74% of the full-fee. We have seen in the charts above

that this policy is negative for low-income families compared to the current situation. To

reduce this effect, we assume that the current subsidy system continues to exist along with this

new tax credit.23 This is problematic in terms of policy design – there would now be two co-

existing sliding scales, one for the subsidy system and one for the tax credit, overlaid on each

other.

23 Laurin and Milligan’s (2017) policy recommendations were for the federal government and they recommended that this new

child care expenses tax credit should replace the federal Child Care Expense Deduction. This is not really within the control of

the Ontario government, so for this simulation, we assume the Child Care Expense Deduction continues.

Page 209: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

199

Table 41 Child Care Demand and Employment in Six Simulations

A. Base Case – Current Funding

B. Fully-funded subsidy system (sliding scale)

C. Sliding Scale - $40K - $240K

D. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus

$50K-$150K sliding scale

E. Operating Grant to $20 per day, plus fully-funded

subsidy system with turning point at $40K

F. Tax Credit for Child Care

Expenses, add on top of existing subsidy system

Description of Funding Reform

No change. Current subsidy

system, plus existing wage and operating

grants.

Keep current income limits in subsidy system

but provide assistance to all eligible with no stigma, flexible

rules, and adequate supply of funding and

services.

Replace existing subsidy system with new sliding

scale of payments for 0-6 years. Families earning less than $40K free. Above that

income, families pay additional 4% of full fee for every extra $10K of income

to $240K after which everyone pays 80% of full

fee.

Use base funding to reduce fee for preschool-

aged children to zero. Replace existing subsidy system with sliding scale. Families earning less than $50K free. Percent of fee

paid as income rises to $150K, max at 80% of full

fee.

Reduce full-fee for infants, toddlers, preschoolers and

kindergarten children to $20 per day per child. Replace subsidy system with fully-

funded, flexible-rules subsidy system with families earning

less than $40K free.

Tax credit for child care expenses,

provides a sliding scale of fee

payments, but the sliding scale of the

existing subsidy system is also maintained.

Demand for Licensed Child Care – Number of Children

Infant Demand 12,155 37,695 69,000 63,260 67,465 46,055

Toddler Demand 40,690 60,450 94,040 88,385 90,915 80,250

Preschool Demand 93,830 125,805 181,620 190,500 175,055 158,325

Kindergarten (B/A) Demand

91,725 118,975 181,502 172,710 171,750 156,595

Employment (or Not Employment) of Main Caregiving Parents with Children 0-6 Years of Age

FT employment (# of main caregiving

parents) 331,045 381,920 458,435 452,945 448,470 427,340

PT employment 116,940 93,590 60,050 62,825 63,715 69,320

Not employed 158,515 130,990 88,015 90,730 94,315 109,840

Page 210: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

200

Table 42 Affordability Measures in Six Simulations

A. Base Case – Current Funding

B. Fully-funded, flexible-rules

subsidy system (sliding scale)

C. Sliding Scale - $40K - $240K

D. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus $50K-$150K sliding scale

E. Operating Grant to $20 per day, plus fully-funded,

subsidy system with turning point at $40K

F. Tax Credit for Child Care Expenses.

Maintain existing subsidy system.

Number of Families with Children 0-4 Years of Age in Each Category of Affordability

Affordable – measured by FIAM (families with children 0-4)

85,495 210,220 444,755 428,890 442,130 336,775

Unaffordable – measured by FIAM (0-4) 156,880 214,560 4,940 20,400 7,595 104,180

Completely Unaffordable – measured by FIAM (0-4) 207,580 24,955 35 440 0 8,990

Overall Average Level of Family and Caregiving Parent Affordability Measures for Families with Children 0-4 Years

Average Value of Family Income Affordability Measure for families with children 0-4

23.5% 10.3% 2.7% 2.7% 3.7% 7.8%

Average Value of Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure for families with children 0-4

67.3% 33.7% 9.5% 9.7% 12.6% 23.5%

Average Level of Family Income Affordability Measure for Lone Parent and Two-Parent Families with Children 0-6

Average Value of FIAM for lone parent families with children 0-6

25.1% 2.7% 0.2% 0.2% 0.5% 6.1%

Average Value of FIAM for couple families with children 0-6

19.9% 11.2% 2.9% 3.2% 4.2% 7.2%

Average Level of FIAM by Expected Level of Family Income for Families with Children 0-6 Years

Average Value of FIAM – families with < $50K family income

30.8% 2.7% 0.1% 0.0% 0.2% 8.0%

Average Value of FIAM – families with $50K-$100K of family income

21.2% 12.7% 2.4% 2.4% 5.1% 7.3%

Average Value of FIAM – families with$100K or more of family income

12.7% 12.2% 4.3% 5.0% 4.6% 6.0%

Page 211: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

201

Table 43 Net Child Care Costs in Six Simulations

A. Base Case – Current Funding

B. Fully-funded, flexible-rules

subsidy system (sliding scale)

C. Sliding Scale - $40K - $240K

D. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus $50K-$150K sliding scale

E. Operating Grant to $20 per day,

plus fully-funded subsidy system

with turning point at $40K

F. Tax Credit for Child Care Expenses.

Maintain existing subsidy system.

Page 212: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

202

A. Base Case – Current Funding

B. Fully-funded, flexible-rules

subsidy system (sliding scale)

C. Sliding Scale - $40K - $240K

D. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus $50K-$150K sliding scale

E. Operating Grant to $20 per day,

plus fully-funded subsidy system

with turning point at $40K

F. Tax Credit for Child Care Expenses.

Maintain existing subsidy system.

Overall Average Net Child Care Cost and Average for Lone-Parent and Two-Parent Families – Children 0-6

Average Net Annual Cost of Child Care to Parents after CCED

$13,395 $8,250 $2,505 $2,710 $3,110 $5,100

Average Net Cost – Lone Parents $9,100 $1,450 $150 $135 $325 $2,280

Average Net Cost - Couples $14,325 $9,725 $3,020 $3,270 $3,710 $5,715

Average Net Child Care Cost by Level of Family Income – Children 0-6 Years

Average Net Cost – Family income < $50K $11,975 $1,185 $45 $0 $95 $3,145

Average Net Cost – Family income $50K - $100K

$13,935 $8,540 $1,650 $1,715 $3,500 $4,815

Average Net Cost – Family Income $100K and over

$13,960 $13,415 $5,245 $5,775 $5,050 $6,895

Average Net Child Care Cost by Age of Youngest Child – Children 0-6 Years

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child Infant $20,175 $9,490 $3,100 $4,045 $3,225 $7,160

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child Toddler $14,550 $9,340 $2,865 $3,825 $3,460 $5,590

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child Preschool

$11,160 $7,975 $2,370 $790 $3,150 $4,460

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child JK $8,470 $6,400 $1,785 $2,705 $2,625 $3,420

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child SK $8,630 $6,670 $1,860 $2,815 $2,730 $3,545

Page 213: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

203

Table 44 Costs and Revenues in Six Simulations

A. Base Case – Current Funding

B. Fully-funded, flexible-rules

subsidy system (sliding scale)

C. Sliding Scale - $40K - $240K

D. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus

$50K-$150K sliding scale

E. Operating Grant to $20 per day, plus fully-funded subsidy system with turning point at

$40K

F. Tax Credit for Child Care Expenses.

Maintain existing subsidy system.

Additional Gross Funding Cost to Government

$0 $1,295m $4,465m $4,435m $3,925m $3,245m

Total Tax Revenue, Net of Benefits

$6,021m $6,330m $7,350m $7,340m $7,160m $6,850m

Federal Tax Revenue, Net of Benefits

$4,258m $4,515m $5,315m $5,300m $5,165m $4,925m

Ontario Tax Revenue, Net of Benefits

$1,763m $1,815m $2,035m $2,040m $1,995m $1,925m

Parents’ Contribution to Cost of Licensed Child Care

$2,053m $2,170m $1,300m $1,165m $1,620m $2,060m

Page 214: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

204

There are four tables that show the results from these six simulations. The first (Table 41)

shows the amounts of child care demand and employment of the main caregiving parent that

results from the policy situation described in each simulation. Remember that our model of

child care demand and employment only covers children 0-6 years of age (not children already

in Grade 1 and above).

Table 42 tabulates our measures of affordability – the Family Income Affordability Measure

(FIAM) and the Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure (CPAM) – for each of the six policy

simulations. Affordability measures are shown for different groups of families. The FIAM

reflects the family’s net child care cost as a percent of after-tax after-benefit family income.

CPAM reflects the net child care cost as a percent of the expected income contribution of the

main caregiving parent after taxes and benefits.

Table 43 tabulates the net family child care cost for its children 0-6 in the six simulations. These

average costs vary by family income level, by the age of child and so on; average costs are

shown broken down by these characteristics. Naturally, the different funding reforms lead to

different net child care costs for different types of families.

Table 44 tabulates the cost and revenue implications for each of the six funding policy

simulations.

8.5 CHILD CARE DEMAND AND EMPLOYMENT

The Base Case represents the current situation (2017). There is demand for infant care across

the province amounting to 12,155 children, nearly 41,000 toddlers, 94,000 children of

preschool age and 92,000 kindergarten children in before and after school care. Given current

incomes and costs of child care for different families, our model projects employment of nearly

448,000 main caregiving parents, over 70% of them full-time. Nearly 160,000 main caregiving

parents with children 0-6 are not employed. Note that main caregiving parents on

maternity/parental leave are excluded from the model.

It may come as a surprise that part-time employment is higher in the base case than in other

simulations. As we learn by looking through the simulations, part-time employment, rather

than full-time, is one important way that families adapt when child care is unaffordable. In

many cases, parents combine part-time employment with parental off-shifting to care for

children, or with part-time care for children by relatives. When child care is affordable, part-

time employment goes down, because full-time employment is now compatible with having

children.

Page 215: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

205

Of course, part-time employment is not the only adaptation that families can make when child

care is unaffordable. As you can see on the row labelled “Not employed 0-6” many parents stay

out of the labour force (and provide their own child care all day long) when licensed child care

is unaffordable, as it is in the base case.

All five of the alternative policy simulations have substantial effects on child care demand and

employment; all five simulations change child care costs for families and family behavior is

sensitive to child care costs.

Simulation B suggests that even the existing subsidy system has the capability of providing

assistance to many more families than at present; this simulation assumes the continuation of

the subsidy system but there are no longer any funding or space shortages or stigma effects for

families. In this case, the demand for all age categories of licensed child care rises substantially

– by about 100,000 children 0-6 years of age. Parental employment also is projected to rise, by

about 27,500, but there is also a substantial shift from part-time to full-time employment as

child care is more affordable for some families.

Simulations C, D and E are projected to have fairly similar effects on child care demand and

employment. Simulation C provides a $40K-$240K sliding scale of fees that replaces the

existing subsidy system. Both low- and high-income families have reduced child care fees.

Total demand for child care for children 0-6 is dramatically higher than in the base case, over

525,000 children would want to use licensed child care compared to about 240,000 in the base

case. The increase in demand for infant care, previously very expensive, is particularly large –

over 5 times as many children would demand infant care. Employment would grow

substantially as well (presuming there were enough spaces to meet the extra demand) – by

over 70,000 compared to the base case.

The changes in child care demand and employment for simulations D and E are a bit more

modest, but of the same order of magnitude. There would be dramatic increases in both child

care demand and employment (presuming no shortage of spaces to meet demand). Simulation

D is the one providing free child care for preschool-aged children (so there is a particularly large

increase in demand at this age) as well as a $50K-$150K sliding scale of payments for other age

categories. Simulation E provides child care for infants, toddlers and preschoolers at $20 per

day as well as releasing funding constraints on an amended subsidy system.

Simulation F would keep the existing subsidy system and provide a sliding-scale tax credit for

child care expenses, similar to one of the ways used to fund child care in Quebec. The tax credit

would apply to expenses for both licensed and unlicensed child care. The effects on demand

and employment would be a bit smaller than for simulations C, D, and E. Compared to the base

case, licensed child care demand would increase by about 200,000 spaces and parental

employment would increase by a bit less than 50,000.

Page 216: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

206

8.6 AFFORDABILITY MEASURES

Table 42 shows the impact of the six simulations on our measures of the affordability of

licensed child care. The top three rows show how many families in Ontario with children 0-4

are calculated to find licensed child care affordable, unaffordable or completely unaffordable.

This is the Family Income Affordability Measure, so the thresholds are less than 10% of family

income (affordable), from 10% to 19.99% (unaffordable) and 20% or above (completely

unaffordable). Currently, only somewhat over 85,000 families find licensed child care

affordable but that rises to well above 400,000 families in simulations C, D or E and about

340,000 families with the tax credit for child care expenses in simulation F. Any of the

simulations dramatically reduce the number of families who find child care to be “completely

unaffordable”.

Distributions of affordability by number of parents and by family income are particularly

interesting. In the base case, measured by the Family Income Affordability Measure for families

with children 0-6, child care eats up more of family income on average for lone parent than for

two parent families – 25.1% vs. 19.9%. The subsidy system does dramatically reduce the

effective price of child care for many lone parent families, but there are many others eligible

but not receiving subsidy.

This is reflected in the distribution of affordability by family income as well. Families projected

to earn less than $50,000 will, on average, have to spend over 30% of after-tax income if they

want to access licensed child care. This falls to 21.2% for those earning $50,000 to $100,000

and 12.7% for families earning $100,000 and above. Licensed child care is not really affordable

on average for any of these groups of families.

All five other simulations have strong impacts on affordability. Making subsidized child care

spaces available to all families eligible under the current income rules (i.e., simulation B) would

itself dramatically improve affordability, particularly for lower-income and lone parent families.

Simulations C, D and E have similar distributional impacts on affordability, lowering it

substantially for both lone parent and two parent families. The $20 per day simulation is

somewhat less beneficial for middle-income families than either the $40K-$240K sliding scale or

free care for preschool-aged children combined with a $50K-$150K sliding scale. Simulation F,

the tax credit for child care expenses, has a much smaller (but still large relative to the base

case) impact on improving affordability for both lone parent and two parent families. However,

even when paired with the current subsidy system, it leaves low-income families with child care

that is less affordable than for middle-income or high-income families.

Page 217: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

207

8.7 NET CHILD CARE COSTS

Table 43 makes the issue of affordability more concrete, calculating the average net cost of

licensed child care for different types of families with children 0-6 years. The average net cost

subtracts the value of the Child Care Expense Deduction that each family would be eligible for

(given the income of the lower earner and the projected amount of child care expenses) from

the full fee that parents would have to pay.24 Of course, it also subtracts any financial

assistance or child care subsidy for which a family would be eligible in that particular

simulation.

In the base case, the average net child care cost that Ontario families face for their children 0-6

is $13,395. For lone parents, subsidy reduces the average to just over $9,000. For couple

families, the average net child care cost is over $14,000. All income groups face high average

child care costs. For families earning under $50,000, the average cost is just about $12,000,

while for middle- and higher-income families, the average cost is nearly $14,000.

Costs are strongly related to child’s age. Families with at least one infant child face an average

child care cost over $20,000, even accounting for the CCED and subsidies. Families in which the

youngest child is a toddler have average costs of about $14,500, and with a preschool child, the

average cost is over $11,000. Families in which the youngest child is in kindergarten face

average child care costs close to $8,500.

While making subsidies available to all eligible families (Simulation B) would lower net child

care costs, they would still average over $8,000 and be unaffected for higher-income families

(still over $13,000 on average).

As with other tables in this group, Simulations B, C, and D would all have dramatic effects on

affordability – the average net cost of child care would fall to between $2,500 and $3,100,

approximately. All these simulations are very positive for lone parents and two parent families.

All are particularly strong in reducing net child care costs for low-income families and have

substantial, but lesser, effects in reducing costs for middle- and higher-income families.

The tax credit for child care expenses has a substantial, but smaller, effect on the average net

cost of licensed child care. The average net cost of child care would be just over $5,000 per

family, lower for lone parents than for two parent families. And, lower for low-income than for

middle- or higher-income parents. The average child care cost for families with an infant

24 As we have noted elsewhere in this report, there is controversy over whether to think of the CCED as child care assistance or

as a necessary component of horizontal equity in taxation of employed parents. Here we treat it as a form of child care

assistance.

Page 218: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

208

would now be just over $7,000 annually and between about $3,500 and $5,500 for families

with other ages of children.

8.8 COSTS AND REVENUES

Table 44 focuses on overall totals of costs and revenue effects due to different child care

policies. The top row shows the additional cost to government due to each simulation.

Naturally, the additional cost in the base case is zero – this represents the current situation.

Parents of young children pay a considerable amount in taxes, even after deducting what they

receive in child benefits. In the current situation (i.e., the base case), total government

revenues from these families (as calculated by the Canadian Tax and Credit Simulator; Milligan,

2016) amount to just over $6 billion, with about $4.3 billion going to the federal government

and about $1.7 Billion going to the provincial government.

We have also used the model to calculate the total amount of the costs of licensed child care

that are paid by parents (not including the CCED). In the current situation, parents contribute

just over $2 billion.

If child care subsidies were funded and spaces available for all eligible families, in Simulation B,

the additional subsidies would cost government about $1.3 billion per year. The net cost is less,

though, because, as parental employment rises, tax revenues will rise even in the short run.25

Tax revenues rise by about $300 million relative to the base case, but the majority of this

accrues to the federal government.

The parental contribution to the costs of child care rises in this simulation. Of course, individual

families are paying less, but more of them are using licensed care, giving us this result.

The additional cost to government of the $40K-$240K sliding scale would be nearly $4.5 billion.

However, tax returns rise, even in the short run, by over $1.3 billion. So, the net cost of this

comprehensive approach to improving affordability is only about $3.2 billion annually.

However, the lion’s share of additional tax revenues go to the federal government; it is an

important policy task for the provincial government to retrieve some of these additional funds

from the federal government to fund child care programs.

25 A number of studies have found that child care causes government revenues to rise by greater amounts in the medium-term

because parents stay in the labour force in greater numbers after their children are in school (Lefebvre, Merrigan and

Verstaete, 2009; Laurin and Milligan, 2017). For the longer run, other studies have found increases in productivity and growth

that would increase these revenue gains by even more (Fortin, Godbout and St-Cerny, 2013; Peterssen, Marischal and Ishi,

2017).

Page 219: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

209

Simulation D would make licensed child care free of charge for children of preschool age

(largely 3-year-olds); at the same time, fees for other age categories of children would be paid

based on income according to a sliding scale ($50K-$150K sliding scale). The overall additional

cost to government would be nearly $4.5 billion. As with simulation C, there would be over

$1.3 billion of additional tax revenues for governments in the short term, much of it going to

the federal government. The net cost to governments would therefore be about $3.2 billion.

Simulation E would cap child care fees for infants, toddlers and preschoolers at $20 per day

(just over $5,000 per full year). This would be combined with full funding of a subsidy system

with slightly more generous income rules than the current one. The additional cost of this

program would be nearly $4 billion. Additional revenues of over $1.1 billion would come to

governments, most of it to the federal government.

Finally, simulation F would maintain the existing subsidy system (without expanded funding)

and provide a tax credit for child care expenses. The gross cost of this program would be over

$3.2 billion. Additional taxes of over $800 million would be generated by increased

employment and incomes. The net cost of this program would therefore be about $2.4 billion.

8.9 SUMMARY OF EVIDENCE FROM SIMULATIONS

These simulations show us several things. First, they confirm that licensed child care is

unaffordable for many families now. Families with young children (0-4) now have to spend, on

average, over 23% of their after-tax family income to access licensed child care services, taking

into account the subsidy system and other benefits that reduce the price of child care to

families. That is fully 2/3rds of the income contribution from employment that a main

caregiving parent can make to the family, on average. It’s no wonder that many families say

that child care is unaffordable.

The second simulation (Simulation B) – transforming the subsidy system into an accessible and

fully-funded sliding scale, where parents have guaranteed access to financial assistance – has

strong impacts on affordability and child care use. Even though the income requirements for

financial assistance are unchanged from the existing subsidy system, having access to financial

assistance as a right is obviously very different from the current restrictive constrained child

care subsidy system. These income requirements are targeted at low to medium income

families; affordability improves dramatically for low-income families and for many middle-

income families, but not for families earning $100,000 and above.

The third simulation (Simulation C) – a generous sliding scale where the amount of family

income determines the fraction of the full fee that parents must pay – transforms the child care

system into one that is affordable to virtually all families. In this simulation, families earning

$40,000 or less get child care for free. Families earning $240,000 and above pay 80% of the full

Page 220: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

210

cost of child care used by their family. Between those two income limits, the fraction of the full

fee that parents pay rises steadily with pre-tax family income. For every additional $2,500

earned above $40,000, a family pays an extra 1% of the full fee. At an income of $145,000, a

family would pay 50% of the cost and be subsidized for the other 50%. Demand for all age

categories of licensed child care increases dramatically in this simulation, more than doubling

overall and, for instance, rising to nearly six times its current level for infants. There would be

important problems of phasing-in access with this rapid expansion, discussed in the chapter on

transitions. Affordability is dramatically improved. The average percent of family income that a

family would spend on licensed child care would now be 2.7%, and the average percent of the

main caregiving parent’s income contribution would be 9.5%. Affordability is dramatically

improved for all income groups, relative to the base case, and particularly for low-income

families. This, along with simulation D, are the most costly simulations in terms of total

government expenditure (nearly $4.5 billion), but there are large effects on families and there

are tax revenues of an additional $1.3 billion that come with increase employment in the short

run. There may be additional employment effects and tax revenues in the longer term.

Further, the model does not calculate savings in social assistance payments related to increased

employment and incomes.

The fourth simulation (Simulation D) would make child care services for children from 2½-4 into

a public service – free of charge to all children in the period before kindergarten. It combines

this with a $50K-$150K sliding scale for infants, toddlers and kindergarten children.

Affordability is very substantially improved for lone-parent and two-parent families, and for

families in all income categories, particularly lower-income families. On average, families with

children 0-4 would now pay 2.7% of after-tax family income to access licensed child care

services. Compared to the base case, over 340,000 additional families with children 0-4 would

now find licensed child care to be affordable, using our conventional thresholds for

affordability. There are substantial increases in the demand for infant and toddler child care,

and an especially large increase in the demand for preschool care in this simulation.

The fifth simulation (Simulation E) targets operating grants at infant, toddler and preschool

children, lowering the full fee to $20 per day per child for each of these age categories, but not

for children of kindergarten age. The expanded fully-funded subsidy system provides financial

assistance to kindergarten children (before-and-after school care) and to families that cannot

afford $20 per day. This simulation substantially improves affordability – to 3.7% of after-tax

family income on average for families with children 0-4. There are substantial increases in the

demand for infant and toddler care particularly and important increases for other ages as well.

The final simulation (Simulation F) considers adopting a tax credit for child care expenses

similar to one that is part of the funding system in Quebec. The existing Child Care Expense

Deduction (federal and provincial) continues along with this new tax credit. The income

thresholds for this refundable tax credit mimic those in Quebec – 75% refund to families

Page 221: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

211

earning below about $35,000, 70% from $35,000 to about $41,500 and so on. The final income

threshold is at about $150,000; above this income level, families are compensated for 26% of

their child care expenses. The existing subsidy system (not fully funded) is continued along with

the tax credit.

This tax credit has effects on affordability that are notably less effective than for simulations C,

D and E simulation. With this tax credit, families with children 0-4 would pay, on average, 7.8%

of their after-tax family income to access licensed child care. In affordability terms, this option

delivers less to low-income families. Families with incomes below $50,000 would pay 8.0% of

net incomes, families between $50,000 and $100,000 would pay 7.3% of income and families at

$100,000 and above would pay out 6.0% of net family income. This pattern, in relation to

family income, is opposite to those of other alternative policies.

8.10 CONCLUSIONS

Only two of these simulations are ones that we think should be considered seriously for

implementation. Both the generous sliding scale (Simulation C) and free child care for

preschool children plus a $50K-$150K sliding scale (Simulation D) have very positive effects on

affordability and desirable distributional effects in terms of income groups and lone parent/two

parent affordability.

The tax credit has a number of problems, even ignoring discussion of demand-side vs. supply-

side approaches. As we saw in the charts in the first part of this chapter, the tax credit for child

care expenses is quite negative for low-income families if it is seen as a replacement for the

existing subsidy system. Lone parent families earning less than about $50,000 (i.e., most lone

parents) would be worse off than with the existing subsidy system. Even if the existing subsidy

system is combined with the tax credit (as in Tables 41 through 44), this option does not do as

good a job as other alternatives for low- and middle-income families.

Further, the tax credit for child care expenses, if combined with the existing subsidy system,

produces an unusual animal. The existing subsidy system is a sliding scale; the tax credit is also

a sliding scale. It is not clear how these two sliding scales should interact, producing a funding

system that is not transparent for parents who will have difficulty understanding its effects. On

top of this, there would now be three forms of tax relief for child care expenses – the existing

federal Child Care Expense Deduction, the existing provincial Child Care Expense Deduction, and

the new provincial tax credit for child care expenses. Combined with the maintenance of the

existing subsidy system, this looks like a patchwork of conflicting and overlapping funding

systems, rather than a coherent and understandable way to improve child care affordability.

The $20 per day per child funding model is less problematic, but on balance not the most

desirable option. The $20 per day approach would get high marks on transparency and ease of

Page 222: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

212

understanding. If it was not combined with special arrangements for low-income families, it

would make child care less affordable for them. However, combined with a fully funded child

care subsidy system for low-income families, this option would very substantially improve

affordability.

This option is a little bit cheaper in terms of overall cost, but factoring in tax revenues, the net

cost of the program is similar to the $40K-$240K sliding scale and the free preschool plus $50K-

$150K. And, particularly for lone parents in the income range from $20,000 to $90,000, either

one of the sliding scale approaches does more to reduce employment barriers and to provide

income incentives to being in the labour force.

Either of the new funding policies reflected in simulations C ($40K-$240K sliding scale) and D

(free for preschool plus $50K-$150K sliding scale) would have dramatic effects in improving the

affordability of child care for all families. There are, however, very important problems of

phase-in or transition to consider. There are not nearly enough licensed spaces to meet all the

demand that would be created if the government were to implement either of these options

immediately. In the upcoming chapter on transitions, we will discuss how these issues of

transition affect our recommendation about the best new funding approach.

Page 223: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

213

CHAPTER 9: WORKFORCE ISSUES, COMPENSATION AND

COSTS

Chapter Summary

It is not possible to solve child care affordability problems without considering

workforce compensation; wage and benefit payments are by far the largest component

of child care costs and, for many reasons, compensation of child care staff will rise.

The government needs a strategic plan to address workforce issues in order to manage

rapid expansion of the sector.

This would include establishing target levels of education and training, the design of a

salary ladder, target compensation packages, and recruitment issues.

Taking all workers in child care centres together, the median wage level in Ontario

(before minimum wage rises) is between $15 and $20 per hour. In most parts of the

province, unqualified staff receive (in March 2017) a wage which is very low ($11.40-$15

per hour at the median). Qualified staff receive between $15 and $20 per hour. Even

supervisors’ wages are not particularly high across most of the province at $20-$26.68

per hour at the median. Toronto is an exception, with hourly wages for unqualified and

qualified program staff and supervisors being higher, at the median, than in the rest of

the province; Ottawa is a partial exception, too.

If we compare hourly wages in other occupations to those in child care, we get a sense

of the difficulties of recruiting additional qualified workers at current wages. Current

child care wages appear to be competitive with other occupations when workers are 15-

24 years of age. However, child care wages are distinctly uncompetitive with hourly

wages paid to female workers who are 25-54 years of age in many occupations across

the province.

Compensation levels need to rise in child care if expansion is going to be possible. In

particular, compensation levels need to rise so that the staff that are recruited will be

capable, well-qualified staff who will decide to stay in the sector.

We have developed a spreadsheet-based costs model for child care centres in Ontario;

this suggests that staffing costs are often over 80% of infant costs, are generally less

than 80% of toddler costs, and are often less than 70% of costs for children of preschool

age.

Page 224: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

214

We use the costs model to calculate the impact of a 10% increase in wages, a 5

percentage-point increase in benefits, and the impact of reaching a desirable target

level of compensation for all child care workers; we also model the effect of having all

contact staff as qualified RECEs.

This type of costs modelling has an important role to play in controlling costs,

determining appropriate fees, and capping fees.

Manitoba, PEI, and Saskatchewan have created policy models with some useful lessons

– about salary grids, benefit packages, professional development, and caps on fees.

9.1 WORKFORCE ISSUES, COMPENSATION AND COSTS

Why should we discuss workforce compensation issues and costs in a study of child care

affordability? There are several reasons:

As child care is made more affordable, demand for it will rise, meaning more demand

for trained staff. There are already shortages of qualified staff in child care centres, and

shortages of providers willing to be recruited to provide home child care. This means

that compensation will have to rise to recruit more early childhood educators and home

child care providers. This could impact affordability unless addressed.

Shortages of staff pose a threat to the maintenance of quality as the child care system

expands. Finding ways to avoid staff shortages and stimulate the supply of educators

will reduce threats to quality.

The recent rise in Ontario’s minimum wage has affected many child care workers,

because many previously received a base rate (before Wage Enhancement Grant) that

was at or close to the previous level of the minimum wage. The rise to $14 per hour

(and to $15 on January 2019) is positive for those workers, but temporarily negative for

the sector. Wages for trained staff are now, relatively speaking, too low, and this will

have to be addressed in order to recruit large numbers of early childhood educators.

There will be pressures for all costs to rise as the child care sector expands. Some of

these cost rises will be legitimate and will contribute to building the type of licensed

child care system Ontario needs. Others will not. It is not easy to tell one from the

other, so provincial and municipal officials need to be prepared for an expanded role in

assessing (sometimes called benchmarking) child care costs to determine how much

compensation providers should receive for services.

All of these mean that it is not really possible to discuss increased affordability and reform of

the child care system without discussing issues of workforce compensation in particular, and

Page 225: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

215

the cost of providing child care services in general. It is certainly not possible to develop policy

recommendations for dramatically improving affordability without considering both the likely

and the desired impacts of new funding on workforce compensation. Wage and benefit

payments are the largest element by far in the costs of child care centres who are the main

providers of licensed services. When wages rise, costs rise and the full fee charged by

operators must rise, unless the government is willing to increase funding to cover higher

compensation for child care educators and other staff.

In fact, the Ministry of Education needs a workforce strategy to accompany its affordability

strategy. In other words, the Ministry needs a plan – a strategic direction – to address the

compensation issues that will come up as the sector expands rapidly. A strategy is a planned

response to a series of interconnected issues that cannot effectively be addressed separately.

This strategy needs to address issues such as:

The target level of education/training of child care educators in the long run. Are we

aiming for university-level education for some staff? Do we want all program staff to be

qualified? Will that make child care too expensive?

Where will the new early childhood educators come from as the system expands? What

occupations do we have to compete with to get a larger share of new college

graduates? What are the typical compensation packages in those occupations that the

child care system needs to match or better?

The need for a salary ladder in child care – a progressive set of occupational descriptions

in the field, with associated expected salary levels, that creates the possibility and vision

of rising through the ranks. What would that look like in Ontario – what would the new

occupational levels and requirements be? How much wage differentiation does there

need to be between different levels in order to provide encouragement to stay in the

field and have incentives to upgrade skills?

How sensitive is the supply of new workers likely to be to increasing compensation

levels? Are these new workers going to have the characteristics we need for an

expanded system of high quality? What does that mean about how much of an increase

in compensation will be needed?

If we have a crisis of inadequate supply of program staff in the next few years, what

compromises are we willing to make to find staff quickly? What do we think about

wholesale recognition of prior learning and experience, which Quebec did early in its

expansion? Does this create problems?

Page 226: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

216

What about expanding immigration to recruit new early childhood educators? Are

there any problems with this approach?

How big is the effect on costs of changes in wages, benefits and working conditions?

How much of a feedback effect on costs and fees do we expect from rising wages and

compensation?

No doubt there are other related issues as well.

A workforce strategy is necessary because the government has twin and conflicting interests. It

does not want compensation of child care educators to be so high that child care is completely

unaffordable and high cost. But, child care educators are the ones that produce the quality of

experiences that children have every day. So, the government needs to ensure that staff

compensation (wages, working conditions and benefits) is sufficient to attract and retain the

workers who will build a high quality child care system.

Right now, the compensation of child care workers is, with some exceptions, notoriously

low…so low that it is hard to recruit and retain staff, so low that becoming a child care educator

is something you can only afford to do when you’re young, so low that it is impossible to

contemplate a dramatic expansion of the sector while maintaining and enhancing the quality of

services. So, government also has a very strong interest in ensuring that staff compensation is

fully adequate and structured to provide strong incentives for constant self-improvement.

9.2 HOW MUCH DO CHILD CARE WORKERS EARN IN

ONTARIO?

Let’s look at some evidence about wages of child care workers in Ontario. The tables below

summarize data from the 2017 Child Care Operators’ Survey. The reported data does include

the effect on wages of the $2 per hour Wage Enhancement Grant for many child care workers –

therefore, for most workers, the lowest wage category is actually $13.40 to $15.00, rather than

$11.40 to $15.00. Since the data is from 2017, it does not include the effect of the increase in

the minimum wage from $11.60 to $14.00 on January 1st, 2018.

This data is provided by child care centres in Ontario in response to a Ministry of Education

survey. Centres were asked how many staff of different types (e.g., qualified full-time, qualified

part-time, unqualified full-time, unqualified part-time, Supervisory full-time, Supervisory part-

time, etc.) were in different hourly wage categories. The data is from March 31, 2017 and

Page 227: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

217

nearly 4,800 out of 5,351 centres responded26 to this part of the survey. The wage data is

reported including the effects of the Wage Enhancement Grant ($2 per hour for eligible staff).

The first table summarizes some key results about median wage levels, while other tables

provide details about the dispersion of wage levels across centres and individual workers.

The bottom row provides a quick summary. Across all staff, the median wage in centres in

every region and on First Nations reserves is $15-$20 per hour. In other rows, we find that

unqualified staff generally receive lower wages than this, supervisors generally receive more. In

Toronto, median wage levels are higher for some occupational categories.

26 The numbers of staff recorded in the tables below are lower than the actual number of staff for several reasons, including

non-response. The data set suggests that there is a total of 48,637 staff across the province but the Ministry of Education

calculates the correct number to be about 65,100.

Page 228: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

218

Table 45

Summary Table: Median Wage Levels in Ontario Child Care Centres

by Occupational Category, by Region, 2017

Source: Ministry of Education

Occupation Toronto West Toronto Central Southwest East North First Nations Whole Province

Median Level of Wages by Occupational Category in Child Care Centres

Qualified Program Staff

$20-$26.68 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20

Unqualified Program Staff

$15-$20 $11.40-$15 $11.40-$15 $11.40-$15 $15-$20 $11.40-$15 $11.40-$15 $11.40-$15

Supervisors $30-$35 $20-$26.68 $20-$26.68 $20-$26.68 $20-$26.68 $20-$26.68 $20-$26.68 $20-$26.68

Non-Program Staff $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20

All Staff in Centres $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20 $15-$20

Page 229: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

219

Table 46

Number and Percent of All Child Care Workers Paid in

Each Hourly Wage Category, by Region, 2017

All Staff

Hourly Wage Toronto West Toronto

Central Southwest East North First Nations

TOTAL

Number of all staff in each region at each wage level (incl. Supervisors)

$11.40-$15 2,337 2416 3,998 2,442 1,392 770 210 13,565

$15-$20 3,601 2,865 4,311 4,467 2,302 1081 253 18,880

$20-$26.68 3,401 1,850 1,782 2,040 1,698 525 143 11,439

$26.68-$30 811 260 234 229 287 115 11 1,947

$30-$35 838 155 143 189 257 42 6 1,630

$35-$40 296 59 57 69 81 24 9 595

$40 plus 306 46 138 40 35 15 1 581

TOTAL 11,590 7,651 10,663 9,476 6,052 2,572 633 48,637

Percent of all staff in each region at each wage level (incl. Supervisors)

$11.40-$15 20.2% 31.6% 37.5% 25.8% 23.0% 29.9% 33.2% 27.9%

$15-$20 31.1% 37.4% 40.4% 47.1% 38.0% 42.0% 40.0% 38.8%

$20-$26.68 29.3% 24.2% 16.7% 21.5% 28.1% 20.4% 22.6% 23.5%

$26.68-$30 7.0% 3.4% 2.2% 2.4% 4.7% 4.5% 1.7% 4.0%

$30-$35 7.2% 2.0% 1.3% 2.0% 4.2% 1.6% 0.9% 3.4%

$35-$40 2.6% 0.8% 0.5% 0.7% 1.3% 0.9% 1.4% 1.2%

$40 plus 2.6% 0.6% 1.3% 0.4% 0.6% 0.6% 0.2% 1.2%

TOTAL 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Source: Ministry of Education

This table groups all staff together by wage level, with numbers tabulated for each region

separately. Toronto, in particular, has more staff and higher wage levels, so it is useful to break

this data down by region. The top part of the table shows the number of staff at each wage

level. The bottom part shows the percent of staff in each region at each wage level. Full-time

and part-time staff are grouped together. When looked at separately, it appears the hourly

Page 230: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

220

wages of full-time and part-time staff are similar (there will be differences in benefits between

full-time and part-time staff but these are not recorded in the data set).

The data on percent of staff at each wage level are useful for calculating the median wage in

each region because the median is the 50th percentile. Looking at the bottom part of the table,

we can see that the median in each region is in the $15-$20 range.

The previous table grouped together all staff, but it is more useful to break staff down into

qualified program staff, unqualified program staff, non-program staff and supervisors. The next

four tables do precisely that. The form of each table is similar to the one above, with the

numbers of staff in the top half of the table and the percent of staff in the bottom half. In each

case, full-time and part-time staff are both included.

Page 231: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

221

Table 47

Number and Percent of Qualified Program Staff in

Each Hourly Wage Category, by Region, 2017

Hourly Wage Toronto West Toronto

Central Southwest East North First Nations

TOTAL

Number of full and part time qualified contact staff at each wage level in each region

$11.40-$15 387 841 901 934 380 177 43 3,663

$15-$20 1,851 1,569 2,539 2,905 1,166 628 163 10,821

$20-$26.68 2,466 1,206 1,135 1,440 1,193 279 91 7,810

$26.68-$30 546 168 57 82 126 55 2 1,036

$30-$35 609 43 41 52 103 13 0 861

$35-$40 131 19 14 47 16 0 4 231

$40 plus 43 5 62 2 6 0 0 118

TOTAL 6,033 3,851 4,749 5,462 2,990 1,152 303 24,540

Percent of full and part time qualified contact staff at each wage level in each region

$11.40-$15 6.4% 21.8% 19.0% 17.1% 12.7% 15.4% 14.2% 14.9%

$15-$20 30.7% 40.7% 53.5% 53.2% 39.0% 54.5% 53.8% 44.1%

$20-$26.68 40.9% 31.3% 23.9% 26.4% 39.9% 24.2% 30.0% 31.8%

$26.68-$30 9.1% 4.4% 1.2% 1.5% 4.2% 4.8% 0.7% 4.2%

$30-$35 10.1% 1.1% 0.9% 1.0% 3.4% 1.1% 0.0% 3.5%

$35-$40 2.2% 0.5% 0.3% 0.9% 0.5% 0.0% 1.3% 0.9%

$40 plus 0.7% 0.1% 1.3% 0.0% 0.2% 0.0% 0.0% 0.5%

TOTAL 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Source: Ministry of Education, 2017

The median wage level for qualified staff is $20-$26.68 in Toronto, but it is $15-$20 in all other

regions. There are more municipal centres and unionized centres in Toronto than in other

regions. Staff in these centres tend to be more highly paid.

Page 232: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

222

Table 48

Number and Percent of Unqualified Program Staff in

Each Hourly Wage Category, by Region, 2017

Hourly Wage Toronto West Toronto

Central Southwest East North First Nations

TOTAL

Number of full and part time unqualified contact staff at each wage level in each region

$11.40-$15 1,660 1284 2,621 1,086 794 478 101 8,024

$15-$20 1,405 907 1,201 907 722 268 29 5,439

$20-$26.68 553 304 131 58 174 59 2 1,281

$26.68-$30 57 11 15 8 7 3 0 101

$30-$35 17 0 14 7 5 0 1 44

$35-$40 8 0 6 0 2 0 2 18

$40 plus 14 2 2 0 4 0 0 22

TOTAL 3,714 2,508 3,990 2,066 1,708 808 135 14,929

Percent of full and part time unqualified contact staff at each wage level in each region

$11.40-$15 44.7% 51.2% 65.7% 52.6% 46.5% 59.2% 74.8% 53.7%

$15-$20 37.8% 36.2% 30.1% 43.9% 42.3% 33.2% 21.5% 36.4%

$20-$26.68 14.9% 12.1% 3.3% 2.8% 10.2% 7.3% 1.5% 8.6%

$26.68-$30 1.5% 0.4% 0.4% 0.4% 0.4% 0.4% 0.0% 0.7%

$30-$35 0.5% 0.0% 0.4% 0.3% 0.3% 0.0% 0.7% 0.3%

$35-$40 0.2% 0.0% 0.2% 0.0% 0.1% 0.0% 1.5% 0.1%

$40 plus 0.4% 0.1% 0.1% 0.0% 0.2% 0.0% 0.0% 0.1%

TOTAL 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Source: Ministry of Education, 2017

Unqualified program staff are teaching staff (i.e., contact staff) who do not have an RECE

designation or equivalent. In fact, there are no specific qualifications necessary. If there are

three teaching staff in a group, two of them can be unqualified staff and one a qualified RECE or

equivalent (one of every two in a group must be qualified for preschool age). In some cases,

there are only two teaching staff managing a group, in which case one of them can be

unqualified and one qualified.

Page 233: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

223

As you can see in the table above, the median hourly wage for unqualified staff is $15-$20 in

Toronto and in the Eastern Region (with Ottawa pulling the median up). In all other regions,

over 50% of unqualified staff are in the lowest wage category $11.40-$15.00 per hour, so the

median wage is in this category.

Table 49

Number and Percent of Child Care Supervisors in

Each Hourly Wage Category, by Region, 2017

Source: Ministry of Education, 2017

Hourly Wage Toronto West Toronto

Central Southwest East North First Nations TOTAL

Number of full and part time supervisory staff at each wage level in each region

$11.40-$15 17 28 38 42 52 6 3 186

$15-$20 65 137 277 276 119 59 8 941

$20-$26.68 247 297 447 368 180 129 34 1,702

$26.68-$30 170 68 145 122 119 40 9 673

$30-$35 176 41 78 123 89 26 5 538

$35-$40 130 19 22 22 34 23 3 253

$40 plus 202 21 29 25 18 14 1 310

TOTAL 1,007 611 1,036 978 611 297 63 4,603

Percent of full and part time supervisory staff at each wage level in each region

$11.40-$15 1.7% 4.6% 3.7% 4.3% 8.5% 2.0% 4.8% 4.0%

$15-$20 6.5% 22.4% 26.7% 28.2% 19.5% 19.9% 12.7% 20.4%

$20-$26.68 24.5% 48.6% 43.1% 37.6% 29.5% 43.4% 54.0% 37.0%

$26.68-$30 16.9% 11.1% 14.0% 12.5% 19.5% 13.5% 14.3% 14.6%

$30-$35 17.5% 6.7% 7.5% 12.6% 14.6% 8.8% 7.9% 11.7%

$35-$40 12.9% 3.1% 2.1% 2.2% 5.6% 7.7% 4.8% 5.5%

$40 plus 20.1% 3.4% 2.8% 2.6% 2.9% 4.7% 1.6% 6.7%

TOTAL 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Page 234: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

224

Supervisors, as one would expect, receive a higher hourly wage than other staff. In Toronto,

this typical wage is considerably higher - the median Supervisor’s wage is $30-$35 per hour. In

all other regions, it is $20-$26.88 per hour.

Table 50

Number and Percent of Non-Program Staff in

Each Hourly Wage Category, by Region, 2017

Hourly Wage Toronto West Toronto

Central Southwest East North First Nations TOTAL

Number of full and part time non-program staff at each wage level in each region

$11.40-$15 273 263 438 360 166 109 63 1,672

$15-$20 280 252 294 379 295 126 53 1,679

$20-$26.68 135 43 69 174 151 58 16 646

$26.68-$30 38 13 17 17 35 17 0 137

$30-$35 36 71 10 7 60 3 0 187

$35-$40 27 21 15 0 29 1 0 93

$40 plus 47 18 45 13 7 1 0 131

TOTAL 836 681 888 950 743 315 132 4,545

Percent of full and part time non-program staff at each wage level in each region

$11.40-$15 32.7% 38.6% 49.3% 37.9% 22.3% 34.6% 47.7% 36.8%

$15-$20 33.5% 37.0% 33.1% 39.9% 39.7% 40.0% 40.2% 36.9%

$20-$26.68 16.1% 6.3% 7.8% 18.3% 20.3% 18.4% 12.1% 14.2%

$26.68-$30 4.5% 1.9% 1.9% 1.8% 4.7% 5.4% 0.0% 3.0%

$30-$35 4.3% 10.4% 1.1% 0.7% 8.1% 1.0% 0.0% 4.1%

$35-$40 3.2% 3.1% 1.7% 0.0% 3.9% 0.3% 0.0% 2.0%

$40 plus 5.6% 2.6% 5.1% 1.4% 0.9% 0.3% 0.0% 2.9%

TOTAL 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0% 100.0%

Source: Ministry of Education, 2017

There are a relatively small number of non-program staff in Ontario child care centres. In every

region, the median wage for these staff is in the $15-$20 range.

Page 235: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

225

After looking at this group of tables, the general picture of wage levels in licensed child care

centres is pretty clear. In most parts of the province, unqualified staff receive a wage which is

very low ($11.40-$15 per hour at the median) even with the $2 per hour Wage Enhancement

Grant added in. In Toronto and Ottawa, the median wage for unqualified staff is $15-$20 at the

median.

Qualified staff in most parts of the province receive between $15 and $20 per hour. However,

even then, in most regions, at least 15% of staff with RECE qualifications receive between

$11.40 and $15.00 an hour with the Wage Enhancement Grant included. Toronto’s qualified

staff earn $20-$26.68 at the median. And, between 24% and 40% of qualified staff in other

regions earn $20-$26.68 per hour.

Even supervisors’ wages are not particularly high across most of the province at $20-$26.68 per

hour at the median. In Toronto, the median supervisor gets $30-$35 per hour but there is a

wide dispersion of wage rates for supervisors.

9.3 HOW HIGH ARE HOURLY WAGES IN COMPETING

INDUSTRIES?

If licensed child care is to grow, it needs to attract young people who would normally end up in

other occupations. It also needs to be able to attract workers who already have an ECE

diploma, but have gone into other occupations and industries.

It is worth comparing current wage levels in child care (which we have just seen) to those in

other occupations across the province. This can help us to think about the problem of trying to

recruit staff into child care, especially qualified staff. Recruitment of qualified staff will be a

major problem if the licensed child care sector is to be made much more affordable and to

expand dramatically.

The table below shows data on hourly wages of female workers in Ontario from the Labour

Force Survey in 2016 in some occupations that the child care sector might wish to recruit from.

This table provides average hourly wages for different occupations and for age groupings 15-24

years of age and 25-54 years of age.

Let’s consider the broad picture that emerges from comparing these hourly wages to those

currently paid in child care centres. Child care centres pay hourly wages which are, in many

cases, competitive with the hourly wages that 15-24-year-old female workers (generally female

workers with little experience and modest or recent qualifications) receive in a range of

occupations, including some health and education occupations. In other words, child care pays

$15-$20 per hour as do these occupations when the worker is young and inexperienced (15-24

years of age).

Page 236: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

226

However, child care wages are distinctly uncompetitive with hourly wages paid to workers who

are 25-54 years of age in most occupations. Those workers earn, on average, between $20 and

$30 for the most part. The exception here is a range of retail sales and service occupations,

most of which do not require college qualifications. Hourly wages paid to qualified RECE staff

are reasonably competitive with most of these occupations (generally less than $20 per hour on

average).

In brief, it will be very difficult to recruit and keep staff who can do better in a wide range of

occupations outside child care. Compensation levels will need to increase in child care if

expansion is going to be possible. In particular, compensation levels need to rise so that the

staff that are recruited will be capable, well-qualified staff who will decide to stay in the sector.

Page 237: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

227

Table 51

Average Hourly Wage of Female Workers in Selected Occupations,

by Age Category of Workers, Ontario 2016

National Occupational Classification (NOC) 2016 Average Hourly Wage

for Workers 15-24 years of age

2016 Average Hourly Wage for Workers 25-54

years of age

Finance, insurance and related business administrative occupations [13] $17.71 $25.13

Office support occupations [14] $14.98 $21.15

Distribution, tracking and scheduling co-ordination occupations [15] $13.86 $20.58

Professional occupations in nursing [30] $30.33 $34.88

Technical occupations in health [32] $18.80 $27.66

Assisting occupations in support of health services [34] $17.29 $20.53

Professional occupations in education services [40] $22.21 $37.35

Professional occupations in law and social, community and government services [41]

$21.20 $36.08

Paraprofessional occupations in legal, social, community and education services [42]

$14.80 $22.27

Care providers and educational, legal and public protection support occupations [44]

$17.57 $20.91

Professional occupations in art and culture [51] $15.31 $27.16

Technical occupations in art, culture, recreation and sport [52] $14.19 $24.22

Retail sales supervisors and specialized sales occupations [62] $12.94 $20.14

Service supervisors and specialized service occupations [63] $12.09 $16.32

Sales representatives and salespersons - wholesale and retail trade [64] $11.75 $17.56

Service representatives and other customer and personal services occupations [65]

$12.14 $17.00

Sales support occupations [66] $11.25 $13.96

Service support and other service occupations, n.e.c. [67] $11.42 $15.54

Source: Cansim Table 282-0152 Labour force survey estimates (LFS), wages of employees by type of work, National

Occupational Classification (NOC), sex, and age group, annual (current dollars)

Note: This table provides a comparison with hourly wages of female workers. In so doing, it leaves to the side the issue of

equity of pay between male and females. We do not intend to suggest this is an unimportant problem.

Page 238: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

228

The higher levels of wages for 25-54-year-olds in virtually all of these competing occupations

suggest that an occupational ladder, built into a salary scale, may be very important in child

care in order to retain workers over time. Unless higher levels of qualifications and related

experience are compensated in child care, it is likely that workers will not stay in the sector.

We do not have data on employee benefits, but that is an important element of compensation

as well.

9.4 COSTS AND FEES IN ONTARIO CHILD CARE CENTRES

We know, then, that compensation will rise in the child care sector as it expands, and further

that wage and benefit levels need to rise if the sector is to attract and retain trained and

capable staff.27 But that means that the cost of providing child care services, and the fees that

child care operators need to charge, will rise too. This will be a challenge for attempts to

improve affordability – a challenge that needs to be managed.

How big is this challenge? By how much will rising compensation levels affect the cost of

producing child care services?

We have developed an Excel-type spreadsheet-based model of costs in Ontario child care

centres for the purpose of looking at the impact of wages on costs for different age groups of

children. The model and results are described in detail in an appendix to this report. We call

the model the Ontario Child Care Centre Costs model (OCCCC model). In the paragraphs below,

we summarize results from simulations using this model; details on these simulations are

available in the appendix.

A costs model is a tool for thinking in an organized way about how changes in one type of cost

is likely to affect the overall per-child cost of providing child care to children. The model does a

good job of explaining regional and age variations in costs and fees across the province, except

that infant fees are generally lower than per-child costs would predict (perhaps because of

cross-subsidization) and fees in the North are typically lower than predicted (perhaps because

of municipal priorities for expenditure in the North).

What Percent of Costs is made up of Staff Compensation?

27 Some economists argue that service sectors where there are few opportunities for productivity improvements are, even

without the pressures of expansion, particularly likely to have wages rise relative to other industries – this is commonly called

Baumol’s Cost Disease (Baumol and Bowen, 1966).

Page 239: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

229

It is common to say that staffing costs are 80% of all costs, but that is not exactly true. The

OCCCC model suggests that the staff costs percentage varies by age category of children. For

infants (when we look at the low end of the median wage range), staff costs are 79%-83%

across the regions. For toddlers, staff costs are about 70%-76%. For preschoolers, staff costs

are about 62%-69% across the regions.

Of course, if we take the high end of the median wage range the picture is somewhat different,

but still similar. For infants (when we look at the high end of the median wage range), staff

costs are 82%-87% across the regions. For toddlers, staff costs are 75%-81%. For preschoolers,

staff costs are about 69%-75% across the regions.

In other words, staff compensation has less impact on the parental fee for children of preschool

age than for infants or toddlers.

What Would Be the Effect of a 10% Rise in Wages?

We can use the costs model to explore some issues about costs. For instance, we can conclude

that a 10% rise in wages causes a rise of between 8.0% and 8.6% in the daily costs of infant care

(with the higher percentage coming where costs were highest before). For toddler care, the

rise of 10% in wages causes a rise of between 7.2% and 8.0% in daily costs. For preschool care,

the rise of 10% in wages causes a rise of between 6.3% and 7.4% in daily costs.

What Would Be the Effect of a Rise in Benefits?

A rise in benefits from the assumed 20% of wages to 25% of wages for all staff would raise the

cost of infant care by 3.2%-3.6%. Daily costs for toddlers would rise by 2.8%-3.4% relative to

current levels. Daily costs for preschool child care would rise by 2.5%-2.9% relative to current

levels.

How Expensive Will Child Care Be When Compensation Reaches Its Target Level?

One useful thought-experiment is to imagine what would happen to child care costs when

wages and benefits reach some kind of “target” level. Although it is unclear what this level is,

we could imagine that, over time, wages for qualified staff will rise to $26.68 per hour with

benefits at 25% of the wage package. For unqualified staff, wages could rise to $20 per hour

with benefits at 25%. And supervisors’ wages could rise to $35 per hour, with benefits at 25%.

I assume here that the WEG continues at $2 per hour for all staff, even for those who have

reached $26.68 per hour. Wages, benefits and all other costs are assumed to be the same in all

regions.

Page 240: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

230

In this case, the annual cost of infant care would be $29,497 or $113.02 per day. The cost of

toddler care would be $21,284 annually or $81.55 per day. The cost of preschool care would be

$15,381 or $58.93 per day. These totals are based on assumed occupancy costs (i.e., rent or

mortgage carrying costs) of $1,000 per child.

What Would Happen to Costs If All Staff Were Qualified?

Currently, a substantial number of child care staff are unqualified. If all staff were qualified, so

that all educators in every room received current wage levels received by qualified staff, we

calculate that there would be an increase of between 16.2% and 17.7% in the daily costs of

infant care. For toddlers, there would be an increase of between 10.7% and 12.2% in daily

costs. For preschoolers, there would be an increase of 8.7% to 10.2%.

A more practical and immediate use of this kind of model is as part of controlling fees in child

care services in different municipalities. Most municipalities already have some means of

determining whether fees charged to municipalities for subsidized children are reasonable or

not. Some, like the City of Toronto and Ottawa, are developing sophisticated spreadsheet

models (cousins to the one we have developed) to help operators determine more appropriate

fee levels given costs. If municipalities are to play a major role in the capping of fee rises in the

future, many will want to develop cost models appropriate to their own situations.

9.5 SOLVING THE STAFF SHORTAGES PROBLEM

The set of questions at the beginning of this chapter asked about compensation packages

needed to attract staff, how to create a career ladder – including a salary ladder and how to

ensure high quality staff to the field.

The mandate of this project does not extend to a detailed analysis of these issues. A Task Force

could be established to review the options and decide on a comprehensive compensation

package.

But, because the issue is so central to the success of the project, we thought it would be useful

to explore some of the examples from other Canadian jurisdictions to begin that discussion.

In terms of comparative compensation packages to attract staff to the sector, there are

certainly past analyses of job descriptions for the purposes of pay equity comparisons that

might be a worthwhile starting point. But even within the sector itself, there are examples.

Both the municipalities that run public child care programs and the school boards that fund

junior and senior kindergarten programs have considerably more attractive compensation

packages than most small non-profit centres. The first goal would be to compete with these

organizations, or come closer to being able to do that to stop the outflow and high turnover of

Page 241: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

231

staff that destabilizes the sector, demoralizes existing staff and has a negative impact on

providing a quality program. As we noted above, the higher-paid municipal and college

programs are not losing staff to the school boards.

A career path and a salary scale are intrinsically linked. Other Canadian provinces including,

PEI, Manitoba and Saskatchewan have adjusted their job titles and descriptions and adopted

different qualification levels for these different positions so that staff have opportunities for

advancement within the organization. In those provinces, they have introduced the following

classifications:

There are three levels in Manitoba:

Child Care Assistant (CCA); Requires no previous ECE qualifications but required to

undertake a 40-hour course of study

Early Childhood Educator (ECE II). Requires a minimum of two-year ECE diploma or

equivalent

Early Childhood Educator III. Requires two-year ECE diploma or equivalent plus an

advanced diploma/certificate or degree.

In Saskatchewan:

ECE I: Requires 120-hour orientation course or equivalent

ECE II: Requires a one-year ECE certificate or equivalent

ECE III: Requires a two-year ECE diploma or equivalent

In PEI:

Certified Entry: 90 hours of training (three entry-level courses)

ECE – Certified Level I: 1 year education at college

ECE II – Certified Level II: 2 year post-secondary education to earn a diploma in early

learning and child care

Director: Post-diploma or degree

Currently Ontario has no requirements for training for unqualified staff and only has one job

classification for early childhood educators: the Registered Early Childhood Educator: it requires

a two-year early childhood diploma from a recognized community college or equivalent.

Supervisors and directors are not required to have additional educational qualifications.

Unqualified staff (child care assistants) are not required to have training nor to undertake

training as a condition of service.

Page 242: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

232

It is easy to see how a salary scale based on three or four job classifications would permit staff

to experience an actual career ladder. Further, the additional requirements for qualifications

would improve quality in the programs. So far, Prince Edward Island is the only province that

has a mandated salary scale.

This salary grid in PEI provides expectations of gradually rising wage levels. Table 52 provides an

example of that salary grid (without suggesting that these rates are appropriate for Ontario).

New Brunswick is expected to be announcing a similar development in the coming months.

Table 52

Prince Edward Island Wage Grid

PRINCE EDWARD ISLAND

Five-year Wage Grid for Early Years Centres

Position Average hourly pay

pre-September 2010

New scale Year 1 New scale Year 5

Director (level 3) - post diploma $15.00 $21.00 $23.64

Certified (level 2) – 2-year program $12.00 $15.00 $16.88

Certified (level 1) – 1-year certificate $10.00 $13.50 $15.17

Certified Entry - (new) $10.00 $12.00 $13.50

Special needs assistant $ 10.21 $ 11.71 TBD

Manitoba has fee caps and encourages operators to adopt the salary scale established by the

Manitoba Child Care Association but it is not yet mandatory28.

Another necessary component of any compensation package should include access to benefits

beyond the compulsory minimums. Currently, the Ontario Coalition for Better Child Care offers

a benefit package, taken up by approximately 250 centres, as well as the larger governmental,

college and unionized organization. In general, benefit packages beyond minimums are rare for

Ontario’s child care staff.

28 Details of Manitoba’s Salary Scale are published by the Manitoba Child Care Association. Retrieved from

http://mccahouse.org/wp-content/uploads/2016/12/Child-Care-MSCGS-2016-2017-.pdf

Page 243: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

233

Many child care centres in Manitoba also opt in to the Association’s benefit package. The

Manitoba Child Care Association program for their members is designed for early childhood

educators, child care assistants, and licensed family child care providers and provides the most

comprehensive plan that includes individual or family coverage and allows members to choose

the appropriate level of protection whether they are single, have a family, or are integrating

coverage with their partner’s plan. Child care centres can choose from 3 different plan design

options and can have a 3- or 6-month waiting period for new employees to enroll. There is a 6-

month waiting period for licensed family child care providers. It also includes a retiree plan for

members that have been enrolled for two previous years and are leaving the child care

workforce due to retirement.29

Another issue to consider is requiring a minimal level of training requirements for Home Child

Care providers such as those that exist in other jurisdictions.

Required professional development is another feature of many provinces in Canada.

Newfoundland and Labrador, Prince Edward Island, and Nova Scotia require a minimum of 30

hours professional development over three years; B.C. requires that early childhood educators

undergo a minimum of 40 hours every five years. In Ontario, credit has to go first to the

Ministry of Education for funding professional development opportunities (not yet required)

and secondly, to the CMSMs and DSSABs for their emphasis on improving quality by offering

professional development opportunities, regular mentoring and other intensive quality

assurance measures across the province. Required number of hours, like other provinces and

other professions, would be a welcome addition to the ongoing professionalization of the

sector.

In view of the numbers of unqualified staff in the system, another question is posed about how

to provide additional avenues to train unqualified staff. The Ministry’s Upgrade Program

whereby educators can apply for a grant towards upgrading through education grants, travel

grants and a training allowance, is a good start in addressing the scarcity of RECEs working in

child care centres. But more is needed for staff who do not have the capacity to study at the

same time as working. Other possible avenues to consider include:

Introducing an apprenticeship program so unqualified staff do not need to go off site

(and not get paid) to do placements; George Brown and Conestoga Colleges are

29 Manitoba Child Care Association. Salary Grid. Retrieved from: http://mccahouse.org/membership-information/group-

benefits

Page 244: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

234

examples of colleges offering a one year certificate program and an apprenticeship

program for unqualified staff.

Providing incentives to colleges to offer more on-line courses and courses with flexible

hours that would be accessible to staff in their non-working hours so that it becomes

possible for staff to keep their jobs and study at the same time.

Providing a staff replacement (substitute) grant so that operators may hire supply staff

to cover for unqualified staff while attending a recognized college training program in

early childhood education. Although this is difficult because of the current lack of supply

staff, raising rates for supply staff could be funded and implemented so that supply staff

would be attracted to child care centres rather than school boards.

Directly paying for training of current staff out of general operating grants.

Providing enhanced funding to francophone and indigenous programs for salaries,

benefits and training options. There are at least two francophone child care centres in

the province that were newly built but unable to open in September 2017, due to lack of

staff.

Resolving the problem of “split shifts” in before and after programs could resolve the

problem of finding staff for these programs.

Implement an incentive grant of up to $5,000 for ECEs with approved ECE diplomas or

degrees who return to work in a non-profit centre after having been away from the

sector for at least two consecutive years.

Any such initiatives will require the support of the College of Early Childhood Educators for

registering early childhood educators with different qualification levels. Also, the cooperation

of the community colleges and the Association of Early Childhood Educators Ontario (AECEO)

across the province would be essential to success.

9.6 CONCLUSIONS

The government needs a strategic plan to address workforce issues in order to manage rapid

expansion of the sector. This would include establishing target levels of education and training,

establishing a ladder of occupations and occupational requirements, creating a salary ladder (or

regionally-based salary ladders), determining target compensation packages, and determining

what policies will best facilitate recruitment and retention.

Current wage levels are low, even with the addition of a $2 per hour Wage Enhancement Grant.

Taking all workers in child care centres together, the median wage level in Ontario (before

Page 245: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

235

minimum wage rises) is between $15 and $20 per hour. Unqualified staff generally receive less.

Even supervisors’ wages are not particularly high across most of the province at $20-$26.68 per

hour at the median. Toronto is an exception, with hourly wages for unqualified and qualified

program staff and supervisors being higher, at the median, than in the rest of the province.

Current child care wages appear to be competitive with other occupations (outside the child

care sector) when workers are 15-24 years of age. However, child care wages are distinctly

uncompetitive with hourly wages paid to female workers who are 25-54 years of age in many

occupations across the province. Compensation levels need to rise in child care if expansion is

going to be possible. In particular, compensation levels need to rise so that the staff that are

recruited will be capable, well-qualified staff who will decide to stay in the sector.

Page 246: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

236

CHAPTER 10: TRANSITIONS - HOW TO MANAGE

GROWTH IN THE CHILD CARE SYSTEM

Chapter Summary

This chapter concludes that implementing free child care for preschool-aged children is

the immediate priority to improve affordability of licensed child care in Ontario. As

physical and staffing capacity are ramped up, increased affordability for other ages

should be phased in.

Ontario is in a good position to take the next steps in expanding the licensed child care

system and in making it much more affordable. However, expansion will not be easy; it

will bring some very large challenges.

Any one of the funding reform proposals considered in Chapter 8 would have major

impacts on the demand for licensed child care services. With full implementation of

either one of the sliding scales modelled, the increase in the number of children 0-4

years of age using licensed care would be nearly 200,000 and for children 0-6 (not yet in

school), demand would increase by 275,000 children. Immediately after the

announcement of a new funding policy, there is likely to be a substantial shortage of

capacity relative to demand, unless the government is able to find a way to phase-in

affordability over time.

There are (at least) five distinct problems of transition (or phase-in) that are important

to consider:

o Physical capacity in licensed centres and homes;

o Development and management of the expanded system;

o Shortages of trained qualified staff and even of unqualified staff;

o How to ration scarce spaces and/or phase-in demand;

o Maintaining and improving quality during the transition, including the role of for-

profit child care providers in the transition and after;

Even if capacity can be rolled out very quickly, there will be some capacity constraints

(i.e., shortages or excess demand) over the next 5 years.

We are assuming that the CMSM/DSSABs, with their knowledge, enthusiasm and

Page 247: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

237

expertise, are the natural developers of the new system. For this, they will need funding

for dedicated staff to conduct the necessary planning, capacity search, design of

premises for programs (both retrofitted and newly-built) navigating through local

council policies, overseeing construction, finishing, equipping and contracting new turn-

key operations. They will also need clear targets and timelines with both capital and

guaranteed operating funding to anchor these projects.

The management capacity in the sector is in some cases weak. The majority of child

care centres in Ontario are managed by small- to medium-sized non-profit boards of

directors, usually composed of parents. Many directors of programs have little

management expertise or management qualifications.

We recommend that existing centres and home agencies be required to apply to be

designated child care services (centres and home networks) to provide free preschool

child care services and receive substantial public funding from government. Existing

centres and home child care agencies would sign contracts agreeing on provision of

services, conditions of service, rights to inspect etc. in exchange for base-funding from

municipalities for services provided.

As demand expands, operators will struggle to find enough qualified staff, or indeed

enough staff at all. Compensation will have to rise in order to attract sufficient new

staff. The province (and municipalities) have a strong interest in structuring higher

compensation to provide incentives for continuous upgrading, apprenticeships, basic

training for unqualified staff, and incentives for qualified staff to make licensed child

care into a career choice.

There are a number of ways of rationing spaces when there is excess demand (by

geography, by age of child, by income group, etc.) but rationing (i.e., allocating services

in a managed way) will be easier if access to dramatically improved affordability can be

phased-in. Careful management of the timing of funding reforms could help with excess

demand issues.

In earlier chapters, we have concluded that the two sliding scale policy alternatives – a

$40K-$240K sliding scale, or free child care for preschool children plus a $50K-$150K

sliding scale – are better at reducing barriers to employment and improving affordability

than either the flat fee ($20 per day) or tax credit approach. The free child care for

preschool children policy has a distinct advantage – it would be easier to phase in. The

Government of Ontario could decide, as an immediate priority, to make preschool-aged

child care free for Ontario families. Preschool-aged child care is already very popular;

most families seek out good quality group experiences for their children in the year or

so before kindergarten. Making child care free would help all families with child care

Page 248: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

238

affordability in the time immediately before kindergarten.

Starting with children of preschool age makes sense in other ways. There is already a

large licensed capacity of child care available to serve children of this age, so shortages

would be less acute than for other age groups. Because the required staff: child ratio

for preschoolers is 1:8, expansion of services requires fewer new staff than if, for

instance, expansion was concentrated among children of toddler age, where the staff:

child ratio is 1:5. It will take time and effort to ramp up both physical capacity and staff

capacity; the efforts will bear more fruit more quickly for children of preschool age.

During the phase-in period for free preschool child care, the existing child care subsidy

system would continue for children younger or older than preschool. As licensed

capacity and staffing capacity increase, the Government should increase funding

available for subsidy, and loosen some of the restrictive regulations on activity

requirements so that more funding is available to improve affordability, particularly for

infants and toddlers.

Making preschool child care free will require that licensed capacity for preschool-aged

children be expanded rapidly. The development and licensing of this expansion needs

to be carefully managed by municipalities, so that new capacity for infants, toddlers and

other ages is incorporated into newly built or renovated centres. As infant and toddler

capacity is expanded, the Ministry of Education can increase funding and loosen rules on

subsidy so that more families are able to afford this child care. When there is sufficient

physical and staff capacity, the Government can amend legislation to provide a $50K-

$150K sliding scale of funding as a right to parents.

It is highly problematic to rely on the for-profit sector as a major provider of services if

you are seeking to build a quality service, and what is essentially a public service. The

Ministry of Education has made it clear that coming expansion will be focused in the

not-for-profit and public sectors. This is appropriate, but may be difficult.

This chapter considers problems of the transition from the current system of child care services

to one that is much more affordable. We conclude that implementing free child care for

preschool-aged children is the immediate priority to improve affordability of licensed child care

in Ontario. As physical and staffing capacity are ramped up, increased affordability for other

ages should be phased in.

Ontario already has a large and generally well-managed system of child care services and it

provides substantial amounts of funding, through municipalities, to families who are able to

access the subsidy system. Ontario also provides funds directly for wage enhancement and

funding, through municipalities, for operating grants, special needs resourcing and a variety of

other purposes.

Page 249: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

239

Since moving into the Ministry of Education and before, Ontario has developed many aspects of

its ability to manage the child care system. There is a new Child Care and Early Years Act,

clarifying roles, responsibilities and regulation. There are clear objectives for the development

of child care in the province. There is a professional college of Early Childhood Educators.

There is a 5-year plan and financing for expansion of capacity for children 0-4. Data on services,

subsidies, capacity and enrollment (amongst others) is now regularly collected and its fitness

for purpose is improving (a dramatic change from the last 30 years). On top of that, across

Ontario, there is a large group of skilled and knowledgeable administrators and planners, many

of them at the municipal level, who know the issues of child care very well and are dedicated to

improving services and funding for families.

All these are very important strengths. Ontario is in a good position to take the next steps in

expanding the licensed child care system and in making it much more affordable. However,

expansion will not be easy and it will bring some very large challenges. In our opinion, as

discussed in Chapter 6, Quebec provides a roadmap of the challenges ahead. However,

Ontario will want to plan its trip much more carefully than did Quebec if it wants the eventual

outcome to be an affordable system of good quality child care.

Chapter 8 on the effects of different funding models presented five funding approaches to

improve child care affordability, in addition to the Base Case. As shown in the table below,

most of these efforts to make child care affordable imply substantial increases in licensed

capacity. Even in the most modest of these, in which subsidy income limits are not changed but

funding becomes available as a right, the amount of new capacity needed for children 0-4 is

77,275 spaces and for children 0-6 is just over 100,000 spaces. In the most dramatic of the

options simulated, the increase in the number of children 0-4 years of age using licensed care

would be nearly 200,000 and for children 0-6 (not yet in school), demand would increase by

over 285,000 children.

That means that immediately after the announcement of a new funding policy, there is likely to

be a dramatic shortage of capacity relative to demand, unless the government is able to find a

way to phase-in affordability over time.

Page 250: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

240

Table 53

Number of Additional Child Care Spaces Needed for Full Implementation of Alternative Child Care Funding Policies

A. Base Case –

Current Funding

B. Fully-funded subsidy system (sliding scale)

C. Sliding Scale - $40K - $240K

D. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus

$50K-$150K sliding scale

E. Operating Grant to $20 per day, plus fully-

funded subsidy system with turning point at

$40K

F. Tax Credit for Child Care Expenses, add on top of existing subsidy

system

Description of Funding Reform

No change. Current subsidy system,

plus existing

wage and operating

grants.

Keep current income limits in

subsidy system but provide assistance to all eligible with no stigma, flexible

rules, and adequate supply of funding

and services.

Replace existing subsidy system with new sliding

scale of payments for 0-6 years. Families earning

less than $40K free. Above that income,

families pay additional 4% of full fee for every extra $10K of income to $240K

after which everyone pays 80% of full fee.

Use base funding to reduce fee for

preschool-aged children to zero. Replace existing

subsidy system with sliding scale. Families

earning less than $50K free. Percent of fee

paid as income rises to $150K, max at 80% of

full fee.

Reduce full-fee for infants, toddlers, preschoolers and

kindergarten children to $20 per day per child.

Replace subsidy system with fully-funded,

flexible-rules subsidy system with families

earning less than $40K free.

Tax credit for child care expenses, provides a

sliding scale of fee payments, but the sliding scale of the

existing subsidy system is also maintained.

Additional Capacity Needed for

Children 0-4 Years

n.a. 77,275 197,985 195,470 186,760 137,955

Additional Capacity Needed for

Children 0-6 Years n.a. 104,525 287,762 276,455 266,785 202,825

Page 251: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

241

In fact, there are (at least) five distinct problems of transition (or phase-in) that are important

to consider:

Physical capacity in licensed centres and homes;

Development and management of the expanded system;

Shortages of trained qualified staff and even of unqualified staff;

How to ration scarce spaces and/or phase-in demand;

Maintaining and improving quality during the transition, including the role of for-profit

child care providers in the transition and after.

10.1 PHYSICAL CAPACITY

The good news is that the Province, with the usually enthusiastic support of the municipalities,

has already begun a capital expansion plan focused on services for children 0-4. The plan is to

serve 100,000 more children within the next 5 years. However, this capital expansion plan has

moved slowly so far, partly because it is difficult to spend the money within the currently

allocated timelines, partly because of difficulties finding sufficient space in schools. And, as you

can see in the table above, nearly all of the simulated policy changes would require more than

100,000 new spaces for children 0-4, and most would require more than 200,000 spaces for

children 0-6. So even if capacity can be rolled out very quickly, there will be capacity

constraints (i.e., shortages or excess demand) over the next 5 years. We have extensive

discussion of capacity expansion issues in the chapter on municipalities, and a number of

recommendations in the chapter dedicated to recommendations.

10.2 DEVELOPMENT AND MANAGEMENT OF THE EXPANDED

SYSTEM

Service expansion requires a number of aspects of service delivery to grow at the same time.

We assume that the CMSM/DSSABs, with their knowledge, enthusiasm and expertise, are the

natural developers of an expanded system at the local level. For this, they will need funding for

dedicated staff to conduct the necessary planning, capacity search, design of premises for

programs (both retrofitted and newly built) and for navigating through local council policies,

overseeing construction, finishing, equipping and contracting new turn-key operations.

Municipalities will also need clear targets and timelines with both capital and guaranteed

operating funding to anchor these projects.

Page 252: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

242

The management capacity in the sector is in some cases weak. The majority of child care

centres in Ontario are managed by small- to medium-sized non-profit boards of directors,

usually composed of parents. Many directors of programs have little management expertise or

management qualifications and this may leave an expanded system with ability gaps. It may be

necessary to find new models for the management and governance of child care programs. The

CMSM/DSSABs should be given support to choose the best models possible. They may decide

to develop and expand municipally-operated services or municipal management supports.

They may decide to create an independent management company to handle or support some

functions such as financial administration, payroll, human resources, and purchasing; or they

may simply continue working with the existing non-profit boards.

Both Quebec and Prince Edward Island have enabled the creation of new institutions to deliver

services that are more heavily subsidized and more publicly managed than in the past. These

were called Early Childhood Centres in Quebec and Early Years Centres in P.E.I. Prince Edward

Island’s initiative was described this way in Chapter 7:

It reorganized existing licensed child care programs into a publicly-managed

network of Early Years Centres and Infant Homes. This reorganization resulted

in the regulation of parent fees, wage enhancements based on a common

salary scale, training and a career ladder for staff as well as sector planning,

professional development and management support to programs. Centres

transitioning to Early Years Centres were required to cap fee increases, meet

the criteria of being an Early Years Centre and provide financial information to

allow the Department to assess their need for base funding.

Existing centres were given the option to apply to become an Early Years

Centre (EYC), remain a regulated private non-EYC centre or retire their license

(with compensation).

Many centres that have applied to meet the Early Years Centre criteria in P.E.I. have not yet

met all of the quality, staffing and other criteria. Centres are transitioning over time, as is

appropriate. What this new status enforces, however, is a recognition that, in exchange for

very substantial or complete base-funding to child care centres and homes, existing child care

services must “up their game”. Quality must be enhanced, staffing must be stabilized and

reasonably compensated, fees and costs must be controlled. Services must operate in ways

that are financially transparent and open to regular quality evaluation. It is a recognition that

child care is a public service, even though delivered by institutions that are not necessarily

public.

We recommend that existing centres and home agencies that wish to be funded to provide free

preschool child care should be required to apply to be designated child care services (centres

Page 253: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

243

and home networks) to provide these reduced-fee services and receive substantial public

funding from government. Existing centres and home child care agencies would sign contracts

agreeing on provision of services, conditions of service, rights to inspect, and so on, in exchange

for payments from municipalities for services provided.

10.3 STAFF SHORTAGES

Staff shortages mirror shortages of physical capacity. As demand expands, child care service

operators will struggle to find enough qualified staff, or indeed enough staff at all. As argued in

Chapter 9 on workforce and cost issues, compensation will have to rise in order to attract

sufficient new staff. However, unconditional equal percentage increases for all qualification

levels may not be the best way to do this. The province (and municipalities) have a strong

interest in structuring higher compensation to provide incentives for continuous upgrading,

apprenticeships, basic training for unqualified staff, and incentives for qualified staff to make

licensed child care a career choice.

When infant capacity expands, it demands substantially more staff (per child served) than care

for older children. Increasing funding for preschool age children, as a first priority, could make

it easier to phase-in increased staffing and new staffing policies.

Issues of compensation are discussed in Chapter 9 on workforce issues, as well as in Chapter 3

on the municipal role in managing the child care system. There are a series of related

recommendations in Chapter 11 on Recommendations.

10.4 RATIONING AND PHASING-IN

It’s not easy to phase-in demand. If the government is going to make licensed child care more

affordable (lower the effective fee levels for families), a logical first step would seem to be to

apply those lower fees (whether through a sliding scale, the provision of free services, or a $20

flat fee, for instance) to all those children currently in licensed services. However, that would

instantly mean line-ups to get into existing services, long waiting lists and lots of pressure on

Supervisors for each child to be given the next available space. Most of the families currently in

child care who don’t get subsidy are middle to high-income families. They would, therefore, be

the first to receive financial assistance. Most of the families that move very quickly to get on

centre waiting lists are likely to be middle class families. Certainly, that is what happened in

Quebec. Lower-income families are likely to be disadvantaged in this contest, if there is no

deliberate rationing through a managed waiting list system, of the potential demand for child

care. Management of the waiting list should ensure that all income and social groups get access

to new and existing services as spaces become available.

Page 254: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

244

There are a number of ways of rationing (by geography, by age of child, by income group, etc.)

but rationing (i.e., allocating services in a managed way) will be easier if access to dramatically

improved affordability can be phased-in. The tables below suggest that careful management of

the timing of funding reforms could help with excess demand issues.

10.4.1 Phasing-In Free Preschool Child Care

We concluded in Chapter 8 that the two sliding scale policy alternatives – a $40K-$240K sliding

scale, or free child care for preschool children plus a $50K-$150K sliding scale – are better at

reducing barriers to employment and have better results in improving affordability than either

the flat fee ($20 per day) or tax credit approach. The policy of free child care for preschool

children plus a sliding scale is preferable at very low levels of income to the $40K-$240K sliding

scale. However, the free child care for preschool children policy has another advantage – it

would be easier to phase-in. The Government of Ontario could decide, as an immediate

priority, to make preschool-aged child care free for Ontario families. Preschool-aged child care

is already very popular; most families seek out good quality group experiences for their children

in the year or so before kindergarten. Making child care free would help all families with child

care affordability in the time immediately before kindergarten.

Starting with preschool age makes sense in other ways. There is already a large licensed

capacity of child care available to serve children of this age, so shortages would be less acute

than for other age groups. Because the required staff: child ratio for preschoolers is 1:8,

expansion of services requires fewer new staff than if, for instance, expansion was

concentrated among children of toddler age, where the staff: child ratio is 1:5. It will take time

and effort to ramp up both physical capacity and staff capacity; the efforts will bear more fruit

more quickly for children of preschool age.

Affordability for all families would be improved, because all children are of preschool age at

some point. However, affordability problems are acute at infant and toddler ages. During the

phase-in period for free preschool child care, the existing child care subsidy system would

continue for children younger or older than preschool. The Government should gradually

increase funding available for subsidy, and loosen some of the restrictive regulations on activity

requirements so that more funding is available, particularly for infants and toddlers.

As physical capacity for children of preschool age is expanded, the province and municipalities

should collaborate to ensure that newly built or renovated centres include increased licensed

capacity for infants and toddlers. The province and municipalities have licensing, funding and

regulatory powers that will allow them to achieve this aim. As licensed capacity for infants and

toddlers grows, the province should increase funding available for the subsidy system so that

these spaces become more affordable for families.

Page 255: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

245

At some point, there will be sufficient physical and staff capacity that the Government could

change legislation to provide funding to families through a $50K-$150K sliding scale as a right.

The tables below look at the effects of phasing-in this policy piece-by-piece. The tables have a

similar form to those provided in the second part of the chapter on evidence about alternative

funding models; they are based on policy simulations performed with the Ontario Child Care

Demand and Employment Simulation Model. As before, the tables show projected values of

child care demand, parental employment, measures of affordability, net child care costs and

governmental costs and revenues.

Simulation D2 in the tables below looks at combining free child care for children of preschool

age with renovation of the existing subsidy system to give full-funding of subsidies to all eligible

families so that these subsidies are available as a right. Full-funding for subsidies is an interim

alternative to a $50K-$150K sliding scale. Simulation D3 models free child care for children of

preschool age combined with a simple continuation of the existing Ontario subsidy system for

families with children of other ages.

These alternatives are not offered because they are ultimately preferable to free preschool

child care plus a $50K-$150K sliding scale. They are offered as potential ways of phasing-in that

option. In other words, these may be waystations along the road to fully affordable child care,

recognizing the difficulties caused by moving immediately to a completely new and more

generous funding system.

The results in Table 58 (in comparison with those in Table 53) give a sense of what we mean.

The additional demand for spaces for children 0-4 would be nearly 200,000 with a policy of free

child care for preschool children combined with a $50K-$150K sliding scale (simulation D).

However, with simulation D2, this additional 0-4 demand would be about 133,000. With

simulation D3, this extra demand would be about 83,000. So, if this were the chosen direction

for improving affordability, the Ontario government could delay implementation of the $50K-

$150K sliding scale until sufficient physical capacity for infants and toddlers and sufficient

trained staff were available.

The Ministry of Education should implement free child care for children of preschool age on a

very short time schedule (as was true with full-day kindergarten). The transition to a $50K-

$150K sliding scale would be more gradual. In the near term, the existing Ontario subsidy

system would be retained. As more capacity for preschool children is built over the next few

years, these services will also be required to expand capacity for infants and toddlers. As

physical and staffing capacity expand, the existing subsidy system can be funded more

generously to improve affordability of infant and toddler care. At a certain point, the expansion

of capacity and staff would be sufficient to get rid of the subsidy system and replace it with an

“as-of-right” sliding scale of payments. Simulations D3 and D2 on Tables 53-57 in comparison

to simulation D on Tables 41-44 measure the implications of this kind of phase-in.

Page 256: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

246

Table 54

Demand and Employment – Effects of Phasing-In Free Preschool Child Care

A. Base Case – Current Funding D2. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus fully-funded, flexible-rules

subsidy system

D3. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, maintain subsidy system

Description of Funding Reform No change. Current subsidy system, plus existing wage and operating

grants.

Use base funding to reduce fee for preschool-aged children to zero. Keep

current income limits in subsidy system but provide assistance to all eligible with

no stigma, and more flexible rules.

Use base funding to reduce fee for preschool-aged children to zero.

Keep current subsidy system.

Demand for Licensed Child Care – Number of Children

Infant Demand

12,155 40,795 17,850

Toddler Demand 40,690 64,685 48,185

Preschool Demand 93,830 174,705 163,470

Kindergarten (B/A) Demand 91,725 130,725 109,150

Number of Main Caregiving Parents Employed or Not – Families with Children 0-6 Years of Age

Full-time employment (# of main caregiving parents)

331,045 407,045 371,895

Part-time employment 116,940 82,420 97,390

Not employed 158,515 115,535 137,215

Page 257: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

247

Table 55

Affordability Measures - Effects of Phasing-In Free Preschool Child Care

A. Base Case – Current Funding

D2. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus fully-

funded, flexible-rules subsidy system

D3. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, maintain

subsidy system

Number of Families with Children 0-4 Years of Age in Each Category of Affordability

Affordable – measured by FIAM (families with children 0-4) 85,495 296,795 208,650

Unaffordable – measured by FIAM (0-4) 156,880 140,165 112,735

Completely Unaffordable – measured by FIAM (0-4) 207,580 12,770 128,560

Overall Average Level of Family and Caregiving Parent Affordability Measures for Families with Children 0-4 Years

Average Value of Family Income Affordability Measure for families with children 0-4

23.5% 6.9% 15.3%

Average Value of Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure for families with children 0-4

67.3% 23.2% 44.3%

Average Level of Family Income Affordability Measure for Lone Parent and Two-Parent Families with Children 0-6 Years

Average Value of FIAM for lone parent families with children 0-6 25.1% 2.0% 15.1%

Average Value of FIAM for couple families with children 0-6 19.9% 8.3% 14.1%

Average Level of FIAM by Family Income for Families with Children 0-6 Years

Average Value of FIAM – families with < $50K family income 30.8% 2.1% 20.5%

Average Value of FIAM – families with $50K-$100K of family income 21.2% 9.8% 15.1%

Average Value of FIAM – families with$100K or more of family income 12.7% 8.5% 8.8%

Page 258: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

248

Page 259: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

249

Table 56

Net Child Care Costs – Effects of Phasing-In Free Preschool Child Care

A. Base Case – Current

Funding D2. No charge for 2½-4-year-old

children, plus fully-funded, flexible-rules subsidy system

D3. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, maintain subsidy

system

Average Net Annual Cost of Child Care - All Parents

$13,395 $6,005 $9,255

Average Net Child Care Cost for Lone-Parent and Two-Parent Families – with Children 0-6 Years

Average Net Cost – Lone Parents $9,100 $1,050 $5,640

Average Net Cost - Couples $14,325 $7,080 $10,040

Average Net Child Care Cost by Level of Family Income – Children 0-6 Years

Average Net Cost – Family income < $50K $11,975 $920 $8,100

Average Net Cost – Family income $50K - $100K $13,935 $6,590 $9,840

Average Net Cost – Family Income $100K and over

$13,960 $9,350 $9,570

Average Net Child Care Cost by Age of Youngest Child – Families with Children 0-6 Years

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child Infant $20,175 $8,625 $17,150

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child Toddler $14,550 $8,465 $11,830

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child Preschool $11,160 $1,685 $2,020

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child JK $8,470 $6,400 $7,910

Average Net Cost – Youngest Child SK $8,630 $6,670 $7,980

Page 260: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

250

Page 261: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

251

Table 57

Costs and Revenues – Effects of Phasing-In Free Preschool Child Care

A. Base Case – Current Funding

D2. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus fully-funded, flexible-rules subsidy system

D3. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, maintain subsidy

system

Additional Gross Funding Cost to Government

$0 $2,600m $1,610m

Total Tax Revenue, Net of Benefits

$6,012m $6,730m $6,520m

Federal Tax Revenue, Net of Benefits

$4,258m $4,820m $4,645m

Ontario Tax Revenue, Net of Benefits

$1,763m $1,910m $1,875m

Parents’ Contribution to Cost of Licensed Child Care

$2,053m $1,665m $1,640m

Page 262: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

252

Table 58

Number of Additional Child Care Spaces Needed as New Funding Policies Are Phased-In

A. Base Case – Current Funding D2. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, plus fully-funded, flexible-rules subsidy

system

D3. No charge for 2½-4-year-old children, maintain subsidy system

Description of Funding Reform

No change. Current subsidy system, plus existing wage and

operating grants.

Use base funding to reduce fee for preschool-aged children to zero. Keep

current income limits in subsidy system but provide assistance to all eligible with

no stigma, and more flexible rules.

Use base funding to reduce fee for preschool-aged children to zero. Keep

current subsidy system.

Additional Capacity Needed for Children 0-4

Years of Age n.a. 133,510 82,830

Additional Capacity Needed for Children 0-6

Years of Age n.a. 172,510 100,255

Page 263: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

There can, of course, be problems with this kind of phased-in funding approach. Some families

will not immediately receive the financial assistance they need. It is useful to remember that,

since all children are of preschool age at some point in their lives, moving right away to make

preschool-aged child care free of charge will address affordability for every family, even though

it will leave some other child care affordability problems to be handled over time. Further, if

the supply of licensed child care spaces is expanded reasonably quickly and funding is adjusted

in tandem, phasing-in funding reforms would be much preferable to the chaos of immediate

full funding reform.

10.5 MAINTAINING QUALITY AND THE ROLE OF THE FOR-

PROFIT SECTOR

The lessons from Quebec discussed in Chapter 6 appear to confirm what much other research

has already argued. It is highly problematic to rely on the for-profit sector as a major provider

of services if you are seeking to build a quality service, and what is essentially a public service.

The Ministry of Education has made it clear that coming expansion will be focused in the not-

for-profit and public sectors (Ontario Ministry of Education, 2017). Under the most recent

Management and Funding Guideline for CMSM/DSSABs, in a discussion of enhanced

accountability measures, the Ministry makes clear the prioritization of not-for-profit services:

“The ministry is taking steps to further prioritize provincial funding to the non-

profit child care sector, and support the effective use of ministry funding, by

working closely with CMSMs and DSSABs to maintain funding allocated to for-

profit child care at current levels. Beginning in 2017, a For Profit Maximum

Percentage Threshold has been added to the Budget Schedule of the service

agreement to support CMSM and DSSABs with maintaining existing maximum

expenditure levels to for-profit entities. The threshold was determined based

on past expenditures that each CMSM and DSSAB directed towards for-profit

programs in the most recently reviewed financial statements submission. This

overall threshold applies to base funding, the child care expansion plan and

ELCC funding. The government recognizes and values the important role of

both non-profit and profit licensees in providing accessible quality child care

services for children and families in Ontario. We also recognize that a number

of communities in Ontario are served by for-profit licensees which support

access to licensed child care; therefore 2017 will be a transition year. The

ministry will work with those CMSMs and DSSABs that do not maintain or

reduce their thresholds in 2017 and will consider financial penalties for

exceeding for-profit thresholds in the future.” (Ontario Ministry of Education,

2017)

Page 264: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

254

This is causing difficulty for some municipalities, but it has been embraced enthusiastically by

the large majority. Many municipalities already have passed council resolutions mandating all

or nearly all of any new child care development to occur in the not-for-profit and public sectors.

There are good reasons for this directive. The fundamental objective of for-profit institutions is

to make profit for owners and shareholders. In a situation, where it is difficult to perceive and

measure quality, it is difficult for consumers to hold producers to account using market

mechanisms. There is overwhelming evidence from many countries that market mechanisms

are completely inadequate to foster and promote good quality early learning and child care

services.

What is needed are producers of child care whose primary objective is the provision of quality

experiences for children, producers who are willing to make constant quality improvement

their watchword. These producers need to be financially transparent and open (because

government will need to monitor costs). These producers need to have as a key objective

making early learning and child care into a public service at good quality and affordable for all.

Although there will be a few small for-profit providers willing to accept the necessary

conditions, most will not. In particular, large shareholder-run corporations anxious to cut staff

compensation and cut corners on quality cannot be a growing component of Ontario’s

expanding system of early learning and child care services.

However, this can create problems for transition to a much larger and more affordable child

care system in Ontario. For-profit operators, and especially corporate chains of child care

services, will be vocal in their desire and willingness to build new services quickly if the

government announces an affordability plan with substantial base funding of child care

services. Yet, if the Government relies on for-profit expansion, it will largely lose control over

the evolution of and quality of the early learning and child care system.

There will be substantial downward pressures on quality as the child care sector expands

rapidly, even if it is dominated by not-for-profit and public providers. There will be many new

staff with little experience, there will be shortages of trained staff, and there will be inadequate

numbers of experienced educators to properly mentor new staff. In this circumstance, to rely

on providers whose fundamental objectives do not align well with quality promotion would be

a serious mistake.

10.6 CONCLUSIONS

Ontario has an excellent basis for the development and expansion of its child care system. The

Ontario Government has dramatically updated legislation and regulations, has expanded

funding and capacity, and has created the College of Early Childhood Educators. The well-

developed role and talents of municipalities is a big advantage. There are a large number of

Page 265: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

255

dedicated staff and operators across the province, most of them in the not-for-profit and public

sectors.

Despite these advantages, dramatically increasing affordability will not be easy. When

affordability of child care increases, our models and common knowledge tell us that the

demand will increase dramatically. Any policy that fully implements affordable child care

immediately will cause a flood of excess demand for licensed services.

For all four of the main alternative policies simulated to improve affordability, demand for

licensed child care for children 0-6 would nearly double or more than double – increasing by

more than 200,000 children. Demand for services for children 0-4 would double or more.

Capacity – both physical and staffing capacity – could not instantly expand by these amounts to

meet this demand.

Experiences in Quebec can educate us about the likely effects of this excess demand, if it is not

managed properly:

Middle- and higher-income families getting disproportionate access to spaces and

better-quality spaces;

Excessive reliance on family home child care because it is easier to expand;

Excessive reliance on lower-quality for-profit child care services;

Public funding of informal child care through a tax credit scheme.

Even if capacity can be rolled out very quickly, there will be some capacity constraints over the

next five years. This implies that the Government needs to address a number of challenges

during this phase-in period. These challenges include how to develop new physical capacity,

management capacity, and how to recruit and retain large numbers of well-qualified staff. We

suggest that municipalities will have a large role in developing new capacity. We suggest trying

out new approaches to improving management and administration of child care services. We

suggest that compensation will have to rise to attract and retain staff. In fact, an entire

workforce strategy is necessary to deal with issues of an occupational ladder, salary scale, and

other workforce issues. It is important that compensation packages encourage continuous

upgrading of child care staff abilities and making licensed child care into a career choice.

We recommend that existing centres and home agencies be required to apply to be designated

child care services (centres and home networks) to provide free preschool child care and

receive substantial public funding from government. Existing centres and home child care

agencies would sign contracts agreeing on provision of services, conditions of service, rights to

inspect etc. in exchange for payments from municipalities for services provided.

Page 266: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

256

Based on the evidence presented in other chapters as well as this one, we favour funding free

child care for preschool-aged children combined with a sliding scale to improved affordability at

other ages. Given the importance of managing the challenges posed by excess demand for

services, we recommend moving immediately on affordability for children of preschool age, and

later on the sliding scale for other ages. This will reduce the pressures on physical and staff

capacity and allow for both of these challenges to be solved over time. Since all children are of

preschool age at some point, this will address affordability for every family, even though it will

leave some child care affordability problems to be handled over time.

Page 267: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

257

CHAPTER 11: RECOMMENDATIONS

The following recommendations derive from economic and statistical analysis and economic

modelling, from interviews with municipal representatives and from knowledge of the workings

and issues in Ontario’s child care sector. Some of these recommendations are for immediate or

near-term implication. Some cannot be implemented immediately because of capacity and

staff shortages relative to anticipated increased demand.

MAIN RECOMMENDATIONS

1. We recommend that the Government of Ontario announce a series of funding reforms

over the next 5 years to dramatically improve the affordability of licensed child care in

the province.

Free Centre and Home Child Care for Children of Preschool Age

2. Our primary recommendation is that the Government of Ontario should begin within

the next number of months the implementation of free child care in centres and homes

for children of preschool age (2½ years of age to kindergarten age). Making child care

free for preschool children will allow children from families of all backgrounds to have

positive and enjoyable experiences in quality licensed services in the period immediately

before kindergarten. Further, this will significantly reduce barriers to employment and

other activities for parents.

There is already a substantial capacity for preschool-aged child care, but investment in

additional capacity should be a top priority. There are shortages of qualified staff, so

measures will need to be quickly adopted that increase the supply of early childhood

educators.

Expanded Child Care Subsidies and then a $50K-$150K Sliding Scale of Fees

3. In the near-term, for children of other ages, the Government of Ontario should

continue, and fund more generously, the existing child care subsidy system.

Municipalities should be encouraged to advertise the availability of subsidy assistance to

middle-income families. The province should change legislation and regulations as

necessary to loosen activity requirements associated with child care subsidy to allow

children continuous access to services even when parental employment is intermittent.

Page 268: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

258

4. When additional licensed child care capacity is available and qualified staff shortages

have been reduced or eliminated, the child care subsidy system should be replaced with

a sliding scale of payments (such as the $50K-$150K sliding scale described in the body

of the report) to make licensed child care affordable for children of other ages. Family

income would determine the percent of full fee a family would have to pay. For children

other than preschool age, families with earnings less than $50,000 would pay nothing;

families earning over $150,000 will pay 80% of the full fee. In between, families pay an

increasing percentage as family income rises. We call this a $50K-$150K sliding scale.

Implementation of Funding Reforms

5. Sliding scales of payment are based on family income, a matter which many families

wish to keep private and confidential from the child care service which their children

attend. When the sliding scale of payments is implemented, there should be a province-

wide internet portal that allows families to determine how much fee they would have to

pay, and to request/reserve a child care spot and to find out much information about

the choice of services available. Actual billing and payment collection (e.g., direct debits)

could occur at either the provincial or municipal (CMSM/DSSAB) level.

6. We recommend that the new sliding scale of payments should be interpreted so that

there is additional fee relief for families with multiple children. Various countries

reduce fees by one-third to one-half for second children, and more for additional

children.

7. We recommend that there should not, eventually, be an activity requirement (e.g., paid

work, looking for paid work, training, education) for attending child care services or for

receiving the benefits of public funding for child care. As the new system of funding is

being phased-in, there may be supply shortages. If there are shortages, it is legitimate

that “activity” be one of the criteria by which a waiting list is managed. Even when

there are shortages, we would recommend that families earning less than $40,000

annually should not have an activity requirement imposed as a condition of their

children’s access to child care.

8. Licensed child care services that are authorized to and have signed a contract to deliver

free preschool child care or to provide services at reduced-fees on a sliding scale will

have all legitimate costs of provision for child care services provided paid directly (and in

advance) by the municipality in which they are located. The child care service will be

accountable for providing records of services provided to each child. The province will

compensate municipalities (largely in advance) for these supply-side payments.

Page 269: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

259

9. We recommend that municipal governments develop and adopt methods of

determining the legitimate costs of services to calculate the amount of base funding

necessary to pay child care services for the services delivered to families. A number of

municipalities already have developed “benchmarking tools” used to facilitate the

assessment of the legitimate costs of providing services. Typically, these are currently

used to determine the amount charged for services to subsidized families. The

provincial government should mandate the use of these assessment tools and help

municipalities to develop a unified approach to determining legitimate costs.

10. We recommend that the province develop and maintain expertise in studying the costs

of service provision (e.g., compensation, utilities, occupancy costs, food and nutrition,

supplies, administration, etc.), the factors affecting the cost of service provision, and the

factors affecting the costs of each key element affecting costs. Initially, this would focus

on the costs of preschool-aged care, but would broaden to all ages as funding expands.

There will be a natural tendency for costs to rise as a new system of funding is

introduced and implemented. Government will want to determine whether that

upward pressure on costs is legitimate, and identify and implement methods of

reducing relevant supply constraints.

11. We recommend that the province work with municipalities and sector representatives

to establish reasonable levels of fee caps for services, as a new system of sliding-scale

payments is introduced. These fee caps may be regional to reflect the local nature of

some costs and the rationale for these fee caps should be clearly documented. Fee caps

should be revised from time to time.

12. Management abilities are weak in some child care services. We recommend that

municipalities should consider facilitating the establishment of separate local

management companies that are able to undertake both the development of new

programs, and/or organize back-end functions such as financial management, human

resources management, payroll and purchasing. These companies would provide

services to individual child care programs for a fee. Municipalities should oversee the

work of these management companies.

New Contracts and New Institutions

13. This new funding system requires a new contract with child care services that will be

providing reduced-fee or free services. Government will be providing the lion’s share of

the funds and needs to ensure that services will be of high quality, will be responsive to

parental needs, and will welcome children from diverse backgrounds in their

community. Services will have to be willing to be completely financially transparent,

Page 270: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

260

open to regular evaluations of quality, and will have substantial and meaningful parent

control or influence.

We recommend that existing centres and home agencies be required to apply to have

the right to provide these free or reduced-fee services and receive substantial public

funding from government. Existing centres and home child care agencies would sign

contracts agreeing on provision of services, conditions of service, rights to inspect etc. in

exchange for payments from municipalities for services provided. In a similar situation

in PEI, centres with such contracts were designated as Early Years Centres as a mark of

recognition of this new status. Ontario would have to develop a similar designation, as

a signal of quality and regulation to parents.

These contracts would itemize conditions to which centres and home agencies would

agree in exchange for regular and substantial base funding. These contracts would

cover issues of financial viability, transparency about costs and finances, and

participation in regular evaluations and upgrades of quality. These contracts would

itemize agreements to work towards compensating staff according to agreed wage and

benefit scales, and establishing governance mechanisms that ensure very substantial

parental participation or control. The contracts would ensure that services were in

concert with identified municipally-determined needs for service development, and

these centres and home agencies would otherwise act to promote public and parental

interests in provision of child care services for children.

14. We recommend that services that do not wish to become designated Child Care Centres

or Home Agencies be permitted to continue to operate under current rules, regulations

and conditions. All existing services with purchase-of-service agreements will be

encouraged to sign these contracts and transform themselves into designated Child

Care Centres or Home Agencies.

15. The Ministry of Education, through its delegated authority, should offer the following

options to the existing commercial child care programs in Ontario:

to remain a commercial child care centre charging parent fees to full-fee parents

and with government support through existing purchase-of-service agreements

to take fee-assisted children;

to apply to become a designated Child Care Centre. This means that the centres

must agree to accountability measures, agree to ensure all staff have minimum

qualifications, participate in mandatory professional development, pay salaries

according to the salary scale and cap the fees according to the service system

manager’s specifications. In exchange, they would receive base funding

payments from the local municipality covering the legitimate costs of operation.

Page 271: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

261

to sell their business to an operator willing to purchase the assets, with approval

of the Ministry of Education and the local municipality. Local municipalities

might become purchasers of assets as part of their development role.

Capital Expansion

16. We recommend that the Ministry of Education make plans for a faster pace of capital

expansion than foreseen in the current Capital Expansion Program.

17. Capital expansion will have to be rapid in order to accommodate additional demand.

Most centres and operators involved in child care provision do not have expertise in

many of the tasks associated with capital expansion: hiring architects and builders,

designing child care facilities, negotiating with municipal planning authorities, organizing

and obtaining financing, and so on. We recommend that the Ministry encourage

CMSM/DSSABs to become much more active in the development process, in some cases

becoming effective development agencies for the stabilization and expansion of the

early learning and child care system. This would include finding locations and

constructing new facilities and tendering to choose operators for newly constructed

child care centres. It would also include various different ways of assisting existing

service providers with renovations and expansions. Municipalities will need an assured

funding stream to take on this role.

18. We recommend that the Ministry of Education provide funding to municipalities and,

through municipalities, to not-for-profit child care operators for capital expansion and

renovation. This would involve funding for capital, retrofit, renovation, maintenance,

and staff recruitment. The Ministry of Education should provide funding for this

development and receive regular reports on these activities.

The Government of Ontario should recognize that capital projects take considerable

time and provide funding with sufficient time for completion of the projects, bearing in

mind a realistic appreciation of the stages and approvals necessary. It typically takes 2-3

years for a new-build child care centre to materialize from notice of funding, to

planning, council approvals, design, construction and licensing. Some smaller

communities are able to complete the process in 1-2 years. Retrofitting can be

accomplished in less time depending on the scope of work. Both capital and operating

funding need to be allocated to municipalities on a multi-year cycle (Housing apparently

has a 4-year cycle) and guaranteed in order to permit municipalities to make long term

plans and enter into contracts for development and construction.

19. Other recommendations with respect to capital development:

Page 272: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

262

o Continue funding the Schools First program; provide direction to the school

boards to collaborate closely with the CMSM/DSSABs to ensure that local

planning guidelines are taken into account in capital decisions.

o Ensure that all new capital construction include spaces for infants and toddlers,

so as to build up this capacity.

o Initiate a Capital Construction Program for community construction outside the

schools where necessary. Priority should still be given to building space in or

around schools, but the CMSM/DSSABs also have a considerable amount of

knowledge about the feasibility of construction elsewhere. The funding should

be available for this.

o Initiate a Retrofit Program (for both schools and community) to be led by the

CMSM/DSSABs according to the needs of expansion priorities.

o Provide allocations for CMSM/DSSABs to be used to assist child care centres and

family home child care agencies and providers to undertake minor renovations

and upgrades to facilitate expansion.

Relationships in Schools

20. There is universal support among service system managers for the Ministry’s Schools

First policy. We recommend that the Ministry of Education should:

o require regular liaison and consultation between school boards and

CMSM/DSSABs;

o Ensure that the school boards’ Early Years Leads are mandated to provide

support to child care in the schools on a full-time basis.

o Provide support to school boards to educate schools regarding the role and

importance of early learning and child care as part of the entire school system.

o Either eliminate payments or mandate a formula for low payments from early

learning and child care programs required by school boards for rent or cost

recovery. Early learning and child care is now an intrinsic part of the whole

education system from 0-18.

Page 273: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

263

Home Child Care

21. We recommend that the Ministry of Education should support the Home Child Care

Association of Canada’s position to introduce:

“Core funding provided directly to the home child care agency that covers all

fixed administrative costs as demonstrated initially by a budget submission

and confirmed through the submission of audited financial statements.30 “

Grants to cover the costs of that administration would then be paid quarterly to the

home care agency.

The underlying assumption is that the agency will be responsible for the entire premises

providing home child care and not just the numbers of children who are receiving fee-

assistance. This base funding would cover the operating costs of supporting and

improving the provision to the entire premises of high quality licensed home child care,

including: recruiting providers, screening and training providers, engaging in a quality

assurance process to include coaching and supporting providers, assist with home set-

up, regularly monitor the homes and cover the program and administration costs of the

agency. The providers would then receive their full per diem rate based on the number

of children the provider is caring for.

Base funding should be determined by CMSM/DSSABs based on actual costs in

accordance with financial and operating information provided to the CMSM/DSSABs in

the same manner as costs are approved at child care centres. Base funding should be

worked out to take into account flexible and part-time hours offered by home care

providers.

30 Home Child Care Association of Ontario. Expanding and Strengthening the Licensed Home Child Care System in

Ontario: A New Funding Model, 2017.

Page 274: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

264

Workforce Issues and Staffing

22. We recommend that the Ministry of Education should, as a matter of urgency, appoint a

Task Force, headed by a well-respected community representative, to review and make

recommendations for a new system of classification of early learning and child care staff

positions with appropriate qualifications and requirements for mandatory training for

new staff, including:

o Minimal level of training requirements at entry level. Several provinces already

require this. PEI has the minimum requirement of 90 hours training to be obtained

within a specific timeframe.

o Minimal level of training requirements for Home Child Care providers.

o Introduce new classifications for the positions of Child Care Assistant, Early

Childhood Educator and Supervisor/Director. Reclassify positions to provide a more

meaningful career path for the profession.

o Make recommendations on requirements for mandatory professional development.

o Consult with Community Colleges to plan training to appropriate to the revised

classifications.

23. We recommend that the Ministry of Education should, after substantial consultation,

develop a province-wide (or region-specific) salary scale for all classifications based on

the revised occupational classifications. The salary scale should provide

encouragements for upgrading qualifications and capabilities. The salary scale should

include provision for supply staff. The salary scale should aspire to make early

childhood education and care into an attractive and desirable career choice with

compensation comparable to other such occupations. A timeline and path should be

established whereby compensation can rise towards these desired levels.

24. The Ministry of Education should also set up a working group to identify appropriate

insurance providers and to develop model benefit packages for consideration by

operators. The Ministry should consider the Manitoba Child Care Association program

for their members. It is designed for early childhood educators, child care assistants,

and licensed family child care providers and provides a comprehensive plan that

includes individual or family coverage and allows members to choose the appropriate

level of protection whether they are single, have a family, or are integrating coverage

with their partner’s plan. Child care centres can choose from 3 different plan design

options and can have a 3 or 6 month waiting period for new employees to enroll. There

is a 6-month waiting period for licensed family child care providers. It also includes a

Page 275: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

265

retiree plan for members that have been enrolled for two previous years and are leaving

the child care workforce due to retirement.31

25. We recommend that the Government of Ontario should address as a matter of urgency

the issue of Director’s Approvals by adopting the recommendations proposed by the

College of Early Childhood Educators of Ontario:

At a minimum, the College recommends that any individual working in the

place of an RECE (e.g., individual working under Director Approval in a

licensed child care setting or a Letter of Permission for DECE positions in

school boards, etc.) be regulated by the College and subject to the same

requirements and accountabilities to practice in accordance with the Code of

Ethics and Standards of Practice as RECEs.

Doing so would ensure that expectations for practice are consistent and would

help to eliminate confusion. Importantly, children and families would be

afforded the same protections and access to the same recourse mechanisms

through the College for practice, safety and conduct concerns and other

issues.32

The College, along with other organizations, recommends that the Ministry should

review its requirements for evidence that an RECE is not available in the centre requiring

“Director’s Approval”, and should determine whether they are sufficiently strict. There

should be a maximum duration imposed for the maintenance of a Director’s Approval.

26. The Ministry should offer an incentive grant of up to $5,000 for ECEs with approved ECE diplomas or degrees who return to work in a non-profit centre after having been away from the sector for at least two consecutive years.

27. The Ministry of Education should offer additional avenues to train unqualified staff. It was recognized that The Ministry’s Upgrade Program whereby educators can apply for a grant towards upgrading through Education grants, travel grants and a training allowance, is a good start to addressing the scarcity of RECEs working in child care centres. But more is needed for staff who are do not have the capacity to study at the

31 Manitoba Child Care Association. Salary Grid. Retrieved from: http://mccahouse.org/membership-information/group-

benefits

32 The College previously shared these concerns with the Ministry in its submission to the Ministry’s consultation in April 2016

regarding the Child Care and Early Years Act and the Education Act. A copy of the College’s submission is posted on its website

at https://www.college-ece.ca/en/Documents/cceya_regulation_phase_2.pdf.

Page 276: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

266

same time as working. We have heard various other suggestions to enhance the staff experience; these included:

o Introducing an apprenticeship program so unqualified staff do not need to go off

site (and not get paid) to do placements; George Brown College and Conestoga

Colleges are examples of colleges offering a one year certificate program and an

apprenticeship program for unqualified staff.

o Providing incentives to colleges to offer more on-line courses and courses with

flexible hours that would be accessible to staff in their non-working hours so that

it becomes possible for staff to keep their jobs and study at the same time.

o Directly pay for training of current staff out of the General Operating Grant.

Waterloo is one of the CMSMs and DSSABs already paying for staff to go to

college in the daytime.

o Provide a staff replacement (substitute) grant so that operators may hire supply

staff to cover for unqualified staff while attending a recognized college training

program in early childhood education. The lack of supply staff everywhere was a

common refrain. The school boards are paying $14 an hour for supply staff, in

many cases more than staff in early learning and child care centres earn and

consequently staff are opting to supply for school boards before community

child care centres. Raising rates for supply staff, as well as overall wages, is the

obvious solution to this problem.

o Mandate and fund minimum requirements for annual professional development

and training for centres and homes.

o Provide enhanced funding to francophone and Indigenous programs for salaries,

benefits and training options. There are at least two francophone child care

centres in the province that were newly built but unable to open in September,

2017 due to lack of staff. Attracting staff to the B/A school programs is also a

serious problem because of the wages and the split shifts.

Page 277: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

267

Rural and Remote Communities

28. Most CMSMs and DSSABs envelop rural areas in their municipal region. It was stressed

that there needs to be a strategy to deal with rural issues including the lack of

transportation. A few CMSMs and DSSABs suggested that funding for transportation

should be available for families in rural areas.

The issues are somewhat similar with Northern communities. It was stressed that there

needs to be inherent flexibility in the north because of the unique nature of the

circumstances. For example, the CMSMs and DSSABs would love to continue supporting

programs in low-population communities where the numbers are uneconomic, but

recognize the cost pressures. They are now working to establish small centres (15

children) with family groupings to make these programs possible.

We recommend that the Ministry of Education should consult widely and examine the

issues of service delivery in rural and remote areas. This investigation should include

the examination of transportation options. This investigation would result in

development of a strategy for effective delivery and use of child care services in rural

and remote communities.

Flexible Hours Child Care

29. We recommend that municipalities, with the aid of the Ministry of Education, should

investigate the need for child care services beyond traditional hours. In each

municipality, provision of necessary services for extended hours, unusual hours and

part-time hours, whether in home child care or child care centres should be explicitly

included in Service System Manager plans. These plans should incorporate the

development of appropriate rates for flexible hours and part-time hours care. In

consultation with the Ministry, this would be incorporated into the schedule of grants

provided to centres and for Home Child Care.

The Federal Government Should Contribute More

30. The Government of Ontario should put substantial pressure on the Government of

Canada to play its required role in relation to supporting and funding the provision of

child care in the provinces. We have seen that any substantial funding program to

improve the affordability of child care in Ontario will bring increased revenues (at

minimum, hundreds of millions of dollars annually) to the federal government, because

of increased employment and incomes and reduced payment of child benefits. The

Page 278: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

268

federal government should be refunding at least that amount of money to the province

in addition to current funding.

31. There is another reason the federal government should be contributing more financially

for Ontario funding of licensed child care. The Government of Canada is responsible for

income tax rules in nine provinces, including Ontario. For a long time, the Child Care

Expense Deduction has been too low in comparison to the price of licensed child care in

Ontario’s larger cities. Currently, the maximum deduction from income for families with

one child 0-6 years is $8,000 annually. However, the actual fee can be over $20,000 for

infants and over $15,000 for toddlers. Even fees for preschool child care can be well

over $8,000. As a result of the low level of the Child Care Expense Deduction, the lower

earner in many families (often the mother) is overtaxed and parental returns from

employment are considerably lower than they should be. This has been true for many

years. When the Government of Ontario lowers or eliminates child care fees, it will be

reducing the effects of this over-taxation, but this is really the job of the federal

government. This provides another reason why the federal government should be

contributing financially to support the Government of Ontario in its expenditures on

licensed child care. We recommend that the Ontario Government negotiate for an

increased federal financial contribution.

32. Statistics Canada is Canada’s statistical agency, and it has a very good reputation for

collecting reliable data. However, it has been many years since it collected data on early

learning and child care. The National Longitudinal Survey of Children and Youth (NLSCY)

collected detailed data on children and their well-being, together with child care use

data from 1994-5 to 2008-9. There was some further data collection in 2010-11. Since

then, there has been nothing. Without reasonable data on families, children and child

care use, both policy analysis and research are very significantly impaired. The Ontario

government should seek a firm commitment from the Government of Canada to initiate

a new program of research on child care, children and families, as a matter of urgency.

Page 279: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

269

REFERENCES

Abella, R. (1984) Equality in Employment: A Royal Commission Report. Royal Commission on

Equality in Employment. Ottawa: Minister of Supply and Services, Canada.

Akbari, E. and K. McCuaig. (2014) Early Childhood Education Report 2014. Toronto: Ontario

Institute for Studies in Education.

Alexander, C., K. Beckman, A. Macdonald, C. Renner, and M. Stewart. (2017) Ready for Life: A

Socio-Economic Analysis of Early Childhood Education and Care Ottawa: The Conference

Board of Canada.

Andresen, M., and T. Havnes. (2014) Women and Children First? Labor Market Effects of

Universal Child Care for Toddlers accessed at

https://www.nhh.no/Files/Filer/institutter/fin/wp/Eckhoff%20Andresen%20WomChiFir

st_20141027.pdf

Association of Early Childhood Educators Ontario. (2015) Regional Wage Scales for RECEs

Working in Regulated Childcare in Ontario: A Discussion Paper.

Baker, M., J. Gruber and K. Milligan. (2008) “Universal Childcare, Maternal Labor Supply and

Family Well-Being.” Journal of Political Economy 79(4): 709-745.

Baumol, W., and W. Bowen (1966) Performing Arts, The Economic Dilemma: A Study of

Problems Common to Theater, Opera, Music, and Dance. New York: Twentieth Century

Fund.

Black, S., P. Devereux, K. Loken, and K. Salvanes (2014) “Care or Cash? The Effect of Child Care

Subsidies on Student Performance.” The Review of Economics and Statistics 96(5): 824-

837.

Bradley, R. and D. Vandell. (2007) “Child Care and the Well-Being of Children.” Archives of

Pediatrics and Adolescent Medicine. 161(7):669-676. doi:10.1001/archpedi.161.7.669

Brooks-Gunn, J. (2003). Do You Believe in Magic? What We Can Expect from Early Childhood

Intervention Programs. Social Policy Report, Society for Research in Child Development

17(1), 3-14.

Budig, M., and M. Hodges (2010) “Differences in Disadvantage: Variation in the Motherhood

Penalty across White Women’s Earnings Distribution.” American Sociological Review

75(5): 705-728.

Page 280: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

270

Burchinal, M., C. Howes, R. Pianta, D. Bryant, D. Early, R. Clifford, and O. Barbarin (2008)

“Predicting Child Outcomes at the End of Kindergarten from the Quality of Pre-

Kindergarten Teacher-Child Interactions and Instruction.” Applied Developmental

Science. 12(3): 140-153.

Burger, K. (2010) “How Does Early Childhood Care and Education Affect Cognitive

Development? An International Review of the Effects of Early Interventions for Children

from Different Backgrounds.” Early Childhood Research Quarterly 25: 140-165.

Burton, P. and S. Phipps (2011) “Families, Time and Well-Being in Canada.” Canadian Public

Policy, 37, 3, pp. 395-423.

Camilli, G., S. Vargas, S. Ryan, and W. Barnett (2010) “Meta-Analysis of the Effects of Early

Education Interventions on Cognitive and Social Development.” Teachers College Record

112(3): 579-620.

Caranci, B., and P. Gauthier. (2010) “Career Interrupted: The Economic Impact of Motherhood.”

TD Economics, October 2010, accessed at:

https://www.td.com/document/PDF/economics/special/td-economics-special-bc1010-

career-interrupted.pdf

Cascio E. (2009) Maternal Labor Supply and the Introduction of Kindergartens into American

Public Schools Journal of Human Resources 44: 140-170.

Cascio, E., S. Haider, and H. Nielsen. (2015) “The Effectiveness of Policies That Promote Labor

Force Participation of Women with Children: A Collection of National Studies.” Labour

Economics 36: 64-71.

Cascio, E., and D. Schanzenbach. (2013) “The Impacts of Expanding Access to High-Quality

Preschool Education.” Working Paper 19735. New York: National Bureau of Economic

Research.

Clavet, J-V and J-Y Duclos. (2012) Le Financement des Services de Garde des Enfants: Effets Sur

Le Travail, Le Revenue des Familles, et Les Finances Publiques. CIRANO working paper.

Cleveland, G. (2012) “The Economics of Early Childhood Rducation and Care in Canada.” In

Recent Perspectives on Early Childhood Education in Canada, N. Howe and L. Prochner

(eds.) Toronto: University of Toronto Press, Scholarly Publishing Division. Chapter 3, pp.

80-108.

Cleveland, G. (2016) “Econometrics and the Study of Early Childhood: A Guide for Consumers.”

Chapter 19, pp. 305-323, Sage Handbook of Early Childhood Research. A. Farrell, S.

Kagan, and K. Tisdall (Eds.) Los Angeles, CA: Sage Reference.

Page 281: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

271

Cleveland, G. (2017) “The Role of Early Childhood Education and Care in an Equality Agenda.”

Chapter 6: 75-98 in R. Brym, Inequality and the Future of Canadian Society. Proceedings

of the First S.D. Clark Symposium on the Future of Canadian Society. Oakville, Ontario:

Rock’s Mills Press.

Cleveland, G., and N. Bigras. (2013) “The Determinants of Child Care Quality in Quebec: How

Specification Matters.” Working Paper. University of Toronto Scarborough.

Cleveland, G. and B. Forer. (2010) “Child Care Use and Child Development in Immigrant, Lone

Mother, Rural and Official Language Minority Families in Canada.” Working Paper.

Accessed at http://www.childcarepolicy.net/publications/ on January 30, 2016.

Cleveland, G., B. Forer, D. Hyatt, C. Japel and M. Krashinsky. (2008) “New Evidence About Child

Care in Canada: Use Patterns, Affordability and Quality.” IRPP Choices, 14, 12, pp. 2-42.

Cleveland, G., and M. Krashinsky. (1998). The benefits and costs of good childcare: The

economic rationale for public investment in young children. Childcare Resource and

Research Unit, Centre for Urban and Community Studies, University of Toronto,

Monograph Number 1.

Cleveland, G., and M. Krashinsky. (1999) “Tax Fairness for One-Earner and Two-Earner Families:

An Examination of the Issues.” CPRN Discussion Paper No. F/07. Ottawa, Ont.: Canadian

Policy Research N.etworks, Inc.

Cleveland, G., and M. Krashinsky (2003) Fact and Fantasy: Eight Myths about Early Childhood

Education and Care. Toronto: Childcare Resource and Research Unit: ISBN-1-896051-25-

1.

Cleveland G., and M. Krashinsky. (2004a) Financing ECEC Services in OECD Countries. OECD

Directorate for Education. Paris: OECD.

Cleveland, G., and M. Krashinsky. (2004b) Financing Early Learning and Child Care in Canada.

Discussion paper prepared for the Canadian Council on Social Development’s National

Conference on Child Care in Canada, Winnipeg, Nov. 12-14, 2004. Ottawa, ON: Canadian

Council on Social Development.

Cleveland, G., and M. Krashinsky. (2009). The Nonprofit Advantage: Producing Quality in Thick

and Thin Child Care Markets. Journal of Policy Analysis and Management, 28, 440-62.

Cleveland, G., M. Krashinsky, S. Colley, and C. Avery-Nunez. (2016a) City of Toronto Licensed

Child Care Demand and Affordability Study, accessed at

https://www1.toronto.ca/City%20Of%20Toronto/Children's%20Services/Files/pdf/T/Tor

onto%20Demand%20&%20Affordability%20Study%202016.pdf

Page 282: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

272

Cleveland, G., M. Krashinsky, S. Colley, and C. Avery-Nunez. (2016b) Technical Report: City of

Toronto Licensed Child Care Demand and Affordability Study, accessed at

https://www1.toronto.ca/City%20Of%20Toronto/Children's%20Services/Files/pdf/T/Tor

onto%20Demand%20&%20Affordability%20Study%20-

%20technical%20report%202016.pdf

Cleveland, G., M. Krashinsky, and B. Forer. (2015) “Assessing the Affordability of Regulated

Child Care in Canada.” Working Paper. University of Toronto Scarborough.

Commission for Childcare Reform (2015) Meeting Scotland’s Challenge: The Report of the

Commission for Childcare Reform.

Conti, G. and J. J. Heckman. (2012) “The Economics of Child Well-Being.” NBER Working Paper

No. 18466, New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Cooke, G., and K. Henehan. (2012) Double Dutch: The Case Against Deregulation and Demand-

Led Funding in Childcare. London: Institute for Public Policy Research.

Cunha, F. and J. J. Heckman. (2009) “The Economics and Psychology of Inequality and Human

Development.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 7, 2, pp. 320-64.

Currie J. and D. Thomas (1995) “Does Head Start Make a Difference?” American Economic

Review 85: 341-64.

Currie J. and D. Thomas. (1999) “Does Head Start Help Hispanic Children?” Journal of Public

Economics 74:235-62.

Currie, J. and D. Thomas. (2000) “School Quality and the Longer-Term Effects of Head Start.”

Journal of Human Resources, 35, 4, pp. 755-74.

Datta Gupta, N. and M. Simonsen. (2010) “Non-Cognitive Child Outcomes and Universal High-

Quality Child Care.” Journal of Public Economics 941-2: 30-43.

Datta Gupta, N. and M. Simonsen (2016) “Academic Performance and Type of Early Childhood

Care.” Economics of Education Review 53: 217-229.

Dhuey, E. (2011) “Who Benefits from Kindergarten? Evidence from The Introduction of State

Subsidization.” Education Evaluation and Policy Analysis, 33(1): 3-22.

Deming, D. (2009) “Early Childhood Intervention and Life-Cycle Skill Development: Evidence

from Head Start”. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics 1(3), 111-134.

Page 283: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

273

Dumas, C., and A. Lefranc (2012) “Early Schooling and Later Outcomes.” Chapter 7, 164-189, in

J. Ermisch, M. Jantti, and T. Smeeding (eds). Inequality from Childhood to Adulthood: A

Cross-National Perspective on the Transmission of Advantage. New York: Russell Sage

Foundation.

Drange, N. and K. Telle (2010) “The Effect of Preschool on The School Performance of Children

from Immigrant Families: Results from An Introduction of Free Preschool In Two

Districts in Oslo” Discussion Papers 631, Statistics Norway, Oslo, Accessed at:

http://www.ssb.no/publikasjoner/DP/pdf/dp631.pdf.

Drouin, C, Bigras, N., Fournier, C, Desrosiers, H., and Bernard, S. (2004) Grandir En Qualité 2003:

Enquête Québécoise sur la Qualité des Services de Garde Éducatifs. Québec: Institut De

La Statistique Du Québec.

Duncan, G., and C. Gibson-Davis (2006) “Connecting Child Care Quality to Child Outcomes:

Drawing Policy Lessons from Non-Experimental Data.” Evaluation Review30(5): 611-630.

Duncan, G., and A. Sojourner. (2013) “Can Intensive Early Childhood Intervention Programs

Eliminate Income-Based Cognitive and Achievement Gaps?” Journal of Human

Resources, 48(4), 945-968.

Dynarski, S., Hyman, J. and D.W. Schanzenbach. (2013) “Experimental Evidence on the Effects of

Childhood Investments on Post-Secondary Attainment and Degree Completion”. Journal

of Policy Analysis and Management 32(4): 692–717.

Elango, S., J. Garcia, J. Heckman, and A. Hojman. (2015) “Early Childhood Education.” National

Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 21766. Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of

Economic Research.

Elliott, A. (2006) Early Childhood Education: Pathways to Quality and Equity for All Children.

Australian Education Review Series. Camberwell, Victoria: Australian Council for

Educational Research.

Esping-Andersen, G., I. Garfinkel, W-J. Han, K. Magnuson, S. Wagner and J. Waldfogel. (2012)

“Child Care and School Performance in Denmark and the United States.” Children and

Youth Services Review, 34, pp. 576-89.

Felfe, C., N. Nollenberger, and N. Rodriguez-Planas. (2012) “Can’t Buy Mommy’s Love?

Universal Childcare and Children’s Long-Term Cognitive Development.” IZA Discussion

Paper No. 7053. Bonn, Germany: Institute for the Study of Labor.

Fortin, P. (2017a) “Quebec Daycare: A Success that Must Now Focus on Equity.” Globe and Mail

April 27, 2017.

Page 284: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

274

Fortin, P. (2017b) “Twelve Flawed Statements of the Fraser Institute on Quebec’s Childcare

Program.” Working Paper. School of Management. Université du Quebec a Montréal.

Fortin, P. (2018) “Quebec’s Childcare Program at 20: How Has It Done, and What the Rest of

Canada Can Learn.” Inroads: Canadian Journal of Opinion 42, accessed at

http://inroadsjournal.ca/quebecs-childcare-program-20-2/

Fortin, P., L. Godbout, and S. St-Cerny. (2013) “L’impact des Services de Garde à Contribution

Réduite du Québec sur le Taux d’activité Féminin, le Revenu Intérieur et les Budgets

Gouvernementaux.” Revue Interventions Économiques/Papers in Political Economy 47:

1-28.

Friendly, M., B. Grady, L. Macdonald and B. Forer. (2015) Early Childhood Education and Care in

Canada 2014. Toronto: Childcare Resource and Research Unit.

Friendly, M., S. Halfon, J. Beach and B. Forer. (2013) Early Childhood Education and Care in

Canada 2012. Toronto: Childcare Resource and Research Unit.

Fuchs, V. (1988) Women's Quest for Economic Equality. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.

Gambaro, L. and K. Stewart and J. Waldfogel. (2015) A Question of Quality: Do Children from

Disadvantaged Backgrounds Receive Lower Quality Early Childhood Education and

Care? British Educational Research Journal, 41 (4). pp. 553-574. ISSN 1469-3518

Garces E., D. Thomas and J. Currie. (2002) “Longer Term Effects of Head Start”. American

Economic Review 92: 999-1012.

Geoffroy, Marie-Claude, Sylvana Côté, Charles-Édouard Giguère, Ginette Dionne, Philip Zelazo,

Richard Tremblay, Michel Boivin and Jean Séguin. (2010) “Closing the Gap in Academic

Readiness and Achievement: The Role of Early Childcare.” Journal of Child Psychology

and Psychiatry, vol. 51, no. 12, December 1359-1367.

Gormley W. Jr., T. Gayer, D. Phillips and B. Dawson. (2005) “The Effects of Universal Pre-K on

Cognitive Development”. Developmental Psychology 41: 872-84.

Gormley, W., D. Phillips, and T. Gayer (2008) “Preschool Programs Can Boost School Readiness.”

Science 320: 1723-1724.

Grimshaw, D. and J. Rubery. (2015) The Motherhood Pay Gap: A Review of the Issues, Theory

and International Evidence. Geneva: International Labour Office.

Page 285: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

275

Haeck, Catherine, Pierre Lefebvre and Philip Merrigan. (2015) “Canadian Evidence on Ten Years

Of Universal Preschool Policies: The Good And The Bad.” Labour Economics, vol. 36,

October, 137-157.

Havnes, T. (2012) “Comment on Ruhm and Waldfogel: Long-Term Effects of Early Childhood

Care and Education.” Nordic Economic Policy Review 1: 53-60.

Havnes T. and M. Mogstad. (2011a) “No Child Left Behind: Universal Childcare and Children’s

Long-Run Outcomes.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 3, 97-129.

Havnes, T., and M. Mogstad. (2011b) “Money for Nothing? Universal Child Care and Maternal

Employment” Journal of Public Economics 95: 1455–1465.

Havnes, T. and M. Mogstad. (2015) Is Universal Child Care Leveling the Playing Field? Journal of

Public Economics 127:100-114.

Heckman, J. (2007) “The Economics, Technology and Neuroscience Of Human Capability

Formation.” Working Paper No. 13195. New York: National Bureau of Economic

Research.

Heckman, J., S. Moon, R. Pinto, P. Savelyev and A. Yavitz. (2010) A New Cost-Benefit and Rate of

Return Analysis for the Perry Preschool Program: A summary. Working Paper 16180,

Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Heckman, J. and S. Mosso. 2014. “The Economics of Human Development and Social Mobility.”

Working Paper No. 19925. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.

Heckman, J., J. Stixrud and S. Urzua. 2006. “The Effects of Cognitive and Noncognitive Abilities

on Labor Market Outcomes and Social Behavior.” Journal of Labor Economics, 24, 411–

82.

Helburn, S. (Ed.) (1995) Cost, Quality and Child Outcomes in Child Care Centers: Technical

Report. Denver, Department of Economics, Center for Research in Economic and Social

Policy, University of Colorado at Denver.

Herba, Catherine, Richard Tremblay, Michel Boivin, Xuecheng Liu, Chantal Mongeau, Jean

Séguin and Sylvana Côté. (2013) “Maternal Depressive Symptoms and Children’s

Emotional Problems: Can Early Child Care Help Children of Depressed Mothers?” Journal

of the American Medical Association. Psychiatry, vol. 70, no. 8, August, 830-838.

Herbst, C. and E. Tekin. (2014) “Child Care Subsidies, Maternal Health, and Child-Parent

Interactions: Evidence from Three Nationally Representative Datasets.” Health

Economics, 23, pp. 894-916.

Page 286: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

276

Immervoll, H. and D. Barber (2005) Can Parents Afford to Work? Childcare Costs, Tax-Benefit

Policies and Work Incentives. OECD Social, Employment and Migration Working Papers,

no. 31. OECD, Paris.

Institut de la statistique du Québec. (2004) Grandir en qualité 2003: Enquête québécoise sur la

qualité des services de garde éducatifs. Quebec City.

Institut de la statistique du Québec. (2015) Grandir en qualité 2014: Enquête québécoise sur la

qualité des services de garde éducatifs. Quebec City.

Japel, C., R. Tremblay, and S. Côté. (2005) “Quality Counts!: Assessing the Quality of Daycare

Services Based on the Quebec Longitudinal Study of Child Development.”. IRPP Choices

Choices. 11 (5) (December. Accessed at http://www.irpp.org).

Japel, C. and C. Welp. (2009) “Lessons to be Learned from Québec's Child Care System.” Our

Schools, Our Selves 18(3): 57-65. Toronto

Kleven, H., C. Landais, and J. Sogaard (2018) “Children and Gender Inequality: Evidence from

Denmark.” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 24219. Cambridge,

MA: NBER.

Kottelenberg, M. and S. Lehrer. (2013a) “New evidence on the impacts of access to and

attending universal child-care in Canada.” Canadian Public Policy, 39, 2, pp. 263–85.

Kottelenberg, M. and S. Lehrer. (2013b) “The Gender Effects of Universal Child Care in Canada:

Much Ado About Boys?” Working Paper. Queen’s University.

Kottelenberg, M. and S. Lehrer. (2014a) “Do the Perils of Universal Child Care Depend on The

Child’s Age?” CESifo Economic Studies 60(2): 338-365.

Kottelenberg, M. and S. Lehrer. (2014b) “Re-investigating Who Benefits and Who Loses from

Universal Child Care in Canada.” Working Paper. Queen’s University.

Kottelenberg, M., and S. Lehrer. (2016) “Targeted or Universal Coverage? Assessing

Heterogeneity in The Effects of Universal Childcare.” Journal of Labor Economics 35(3):

609-

Kottelenberg, M., and S. Lehrer. (2017) “Does Quebec’s Childcare Policy Give Boys and Girls an

Equal Start?” Working Paper 23259. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge,

MA.

Krashinsky, M. (1986) “Why Educational Vouchers May Be Bad Economics.” Teachers College

Record 88(2): 139-151.

Page 287: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

277

Lamb, M. (1998) “Non-Parental Child Care: Context, Quality, Correlates and Consequences.” In

Child Psychology in Practice I. Sigel, and K. Renninger (vol. eds.) in W. Damon (series ed.)

Handbook of Child Psychology: Volume 4. 5th Edition: 73-133. New York: John Wiley and

Sons, Inc.

Laurin, A., and K. Milligan. (2017) “Tax Options for Childcare that Encourage Work, Flexibility,

Choice, Fairness and Quality”. Commentary No.481, Fiscal and Tax Policy, C.D. Howe

Institute. Toronto: C.D. Howe Institute.

Laurin, I., D. Guay, N. Bigras, et M. Fournier. (2015) Quel Est L’effet de la Fréquentation d’un

Service Éducatif sur le Développement de l’Enfant à la Maternelle Selon Le Statut

Socioéconomique? Résultats de l’Enquête Montréalaise sur l’expérience Préscolaire des

Enfants de Maternelle (EMEP, 2012). Agence de la Santé et des Services Sociaux de

Montréal, accessed at http://www.dsp.santemontreal.qc.ca/EMEP.

Laurin, J., M-C. Geoffroy, M. Boivin, C. Japel, M-F. Raynault, R. Tremblay and S. Côté. (2015)

“Childcare Services, Socioeconomic Inequalities, and Academic Performance.”

Pediatrics, vol. 136, no. 6, December, 1112-1124.

Lebihan, L., C. Haeck and P. Merrigan. (2015) “Universal Childcare and Long-Term Effects on

Child Well-Being: Evidence from Canada.” Working Paper No. 15-02. Groupe de

recherche sur le capital humain, Université du Québec à Montréal.

Lefebvre, P. and P. Merrigan. (2005) “Low-Fee ($5/Day/Child) Regulated Childcare Policy and

the Labor Supply of Mothers with Young Children: A Natural Experiment from Canada.”

Working Paper 05-08. Inter-university Centre on Risk, Economic Policies and

Employment (CIRPÉE).

Lefebvre P. and P. Merrigan. (2008) “Child-Care Policy and The Labor Supply of Mothers with

Young Children: A Natural Experiment from Canada.” Journal of Labor Economics 26:

519–548.

Lefebvre P., P. Merrigan and M. Verstraete. (2009) “Dynamic Labour Supply Effects of Childcare

Subsidies: Evidence from a Canadian Natural Experiment on Low-Fee Universal Child

Care.” Labour Economics, 16, pp. 490-502.

Lloyd, E., and H. Penn. (2014) “Childcare Markets in an Age of Austerity”. Early Childhood

Education Research Journal. 22(2), 386–396.

Macdonald, D., and M. Friendly (2014) Parent Trap: Child Care Fees in Canada’s Big Cities.

Ottawa: Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives.

Page 288: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

278

Macdonald, D., and M. Friendly. (2016) A Growing Concern: 2016 Child Care Fees in Canada’s

Big Cities. Ottawa: Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives.

Macdonald, D., and M. Friendly. (2017) Time Out: Child Care Fees in Canada 2017. Ottawa:

Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives.

Macdonald, D., and T. Klinger. (2015) They Go Up So Fast: 2015 Child Care Fees in Canadian

Cities. Ottawa: Canadian Centre for Policy Alternatives.

MacLeod, B., and M. Urquiola (2009) “Anti-Lemons: School Reputation and Education Quality”

National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 15112.

Magnuson K, C. Ruhm, and J. Waldfogel. (2007a) “The Persistence of Preschool Effects: Do

Subsequent Classroom Experiences Matter?” Early Childhood Research Quarterly 22: 18-

38.

Magnuson K. C. Ruhm, and J. Waldfogel. (2007b) “Does Pre-kindergarten Improve School

Preparation and Performance?” Economics of Education Review 26: 33–51.

Masse L and Barnett WS (2003) A Benefit-Cost Analysis of the Abecedarian Program. New

Brunswick, NJ: National Institute for Early Education Research. Accessed at:

http://nieer.org/resources/research/AbecedarianStudy.pdf.

McCain, M., and J.F. Mustard. (1999) Early Years Study. Toronto: Publications Ontario.

Miller, P., D. Henry, and E. Votruba-Drzal. (2016) “Strengthening Causal Inference in

Developmental Research.” Child Development Perspectives 10(4): 275-280.

Milligan, K. (2016) Canadian Tax and Credit Simulator: User Guide. Version 2016-2. Vancouver,

B.C.: University of British Columbia.

Mocan, N. (2007) “Can Consumers Detect Lemons? An Empirical Analysis of Information

Asymmetry in the Market for Child Care.” Journal of Population Economics. 20(4): 743-

780.

NICHD-ECCRN and G. Duncan. (2003) “Modeling the Impacts of Child Care Quality on Children’s

Preschool Cognitive Development.” Child Development 74: 1454-75.

NICHD-ECCRN -- National Institute of Child Health and Human Development Early Child Care

Research Network. (2006) “Child-Care Effect Sizes for the NICHD Study of Early Child

Care and Youth Development.” American Psychologist, 61, 2, pp. 99-116.

Page 289: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

279

Ontario Federation of Indigenous Friendship Centres [OFIFCs]. (2017) Response to the

Development of an Indigenous Early Learning and Child Care Framework. Toronto: OFIFC

Ontario Ministry of Community and Social Services. (1987) New Directions for Child Care

Toronto: Ministry of Community and Social Services. ISBN: 0772946647 (1989 reprint)

Ontario Ministry of Education. (2017) Ontario Child Care and Child and Family Program Service

Management and Funding Guideline 2017: For Consolidated Municipal Service

Managers and District Social Services Administration Boards. On-line. Toronto: Queen’s

Printer for Ontario.

Ontario Ministry of Finance. (2016) Ontario Population Projections Update 2015-2041: Ontario

and Its 49 Census Divisions. Toronto: Queen’s Printer for Ontario.

OECD (2006) Starting Strong II: Early Childhood Education and Care. Paris: OECD Publishing.

OECD (2007) Babies and Bosses: Reconciling Work and Family Life: A Synthesis of Findings for

OECD Countries. Paris: OECD Publishing.

OECD (2010) PISA 2009 Results: Overcoming Social Background: Equity in Learning

Opportunities and Outcomes (Volume II). Paris: OECD Publishing.

OECD (2012) Closing the Gender Gap: Act Now. Paris: OECD Publishing.

OECD (2016) “Who Uses Childcare?” Background Brief on Inequalities in the Use of Formal Early

Childhood Education and Care (ECEC) Among Very Young Children. Social Policy Division,

OECD, Paris. Accessed at https://www.oecd.org/els/family/Who_uses_childcare

Backgrounder_inequalities_formal_ECEC.pdf on January 2, 2018. Authored by W.

Adema, C. Clarke, and O. Thevenon.

Peisner-Feinberg, E. S., M. Burchinal, R. Clifford, M. Culkin, C. Howes, S. Kagan, and N. Yazejian.

(2001). “The Relation of Preschool Child-Care Quality to Children's Cognitive and Social

Developmental Trajectories through Second Grade”. Child Development, 72(5), 1534-

1553. doi: 10.1111/1467-8624.00364

Penn, H., and E. Lloyd (2013) The Costs of Childcare. London: Childhood Wellbeing Research

Centre.

Petersson, B., Mariscal, R., and K. Ishi. (2017) “Women Are Key for Future Growth: Evidence

from Canada.” IMF Working Paper WP/17/166. International Monetary Fund.

Page 290: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

280

Phipps, S., P. Burton and L. Lethbridge. (2001) “In and Out of the Labour Market: Long-Term

Income Consequences of Child-Related Interruptions to Women’s Paid Work.” Canadian

Journal of Economics, 34(2): 411-429.

Plantenga, J., and Remery, C. (2009) The Provision of Childcare Services: A Comparative Review

of 30 European Countries. Brussels: European Commission.

Productivity Commission (2014) Childcare and Early Childhood Learning, Volume 2, Inquiry

Report No. 73, Canberra, AU: Australian Government Productivity Commission.

Richardson, L. (2012) “Can Parents Afford to Work? An Update.” Paper presented at the

European Population Conference, 13-16 June, 2012. Accessed at

http://epc2012.princeton.edu/papers/120718 on January 2, 2018.

Ruhm, C., and J. Waldfogel. (2012) “Long-Term Effects of Early Childhood Care and Education.

“Nordic Economic Policy Review 1: 23-51.

Shonkoff, J. and D. Phillips. (2000) From Neurons to Neighborhoods: The Science of Early

Childhood Development. Washington, DC: National Academy Press.

Spiess, K., F. Buchel, and G. Wagner (2003) “Children’s School Placement in Germany: Does

Kindergarten Attendance Matter?” Early Childhood Research Quarterly 18: 255-270.

Stalker, G., and M. Ornstein. (2013) “Quebec, Childcare, and the Household Strategies of

Couples with Young Children.” Canadian Public Policy / Analyse de Politiques, vol. 39, no.

2, 241–262.

Statistics Canada. (2011) “Women in Canada: A Gender-Based Statistical Report.” Statistics

Canada Catalogue no. 99-012-XIE2011001.

Sylva, K., E. Melhuish, P. Sammons, I. Siraj-Blatchford, and B. Taggart. (2004) The Effective

Provision of Pre-School Education(EPPE) Project: Final Report. London, England:

University of London.

Sylva, K., E. Melhuish, P. Sammons, I. Siraj-Blatchford, and B. Taggart. (2011) “Pre-School

Quality and Educational Outcomes at Age 11: Low Quality Has Little Benefit.” Journal of

Early Childhood Research 9(2): 109-124.

Taggart, B., K. Sylva, E. Melhuish, P. Sammons, and I. Siraj. (2015) Effective Pre-School, Primary

and Secondary Education Project (EPPSE 3-16+). London: Department of Education.

Page 291: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

281

TD Economics. (2007) “Market forces advance prospects for women in the workforce: TD

Economics” Accessed at: http://www.td.com/document/PDF/economics/special/td-

economics-special-bc0907-woman-pr.pdf

Thevenon, O. (2013) “Drivers of Female Labour Force Participation in the OECD.” Social

Employment and Migration Working Papers #145. Paris: OECD.

Tweddle, A., K. Battle, and S. Torjman. (2017) Canada Social Report: Welfare in Canada, 2016.

Ottawa, ON: Caledon Institute of Social Policy.

Van Huizen, T., and J. Plantenga. (2015) “Universal Child Care and Children’s Outcomes: A Meta-

Analysis of Evidence from Natural Experiments.” Discussion Paper Series/Tjalling C.

Koopmans Research Institute, No. 15(13), Utrecht University School of Economics.

Vincent, C. (2013) “Why Do Women Earn Less Than Men? A Synthesis of Findings from

Canadian Microdata.” CRDCN Synthesis Series, Canadian Research Data Centre Network.

Waldfogel, J. (1998) “Understanding The ‘Family Gap’ In Pay for Women with Children.” Journal

of Economic Perspectives. 12, 1, pp. 137-56.

Waldfogel, J. and I. Pal. 2014. “Re-Visiting the Family Gap in Pay in The United States.” Working

Paper, Columbia University.

Walker, J. (1991) "Public Policy and the Supply of Childcare Services." in D. Blau, The Economics

of Childcare pp. 51-77.

Warner, M., and R. Gradus. (2011) “The Consequences of Implementing a Child Care Voucher

Scheme: Evidence from Australia, the Netherlands and the USA.” Social Policy and

Administration 45(5): 569-592.

Warren, D. and J. Haisken-DeNew. (2014) Early Bird Catches the Worm: The Causal Impact of

Pre-school Participation and Teacher Qualifications on Year 3 National NAPLAN

Cognitive Tests. Working Paper, Melbourne Institute, University of Melbourne.

Warren, D., M. O’Connor, D. Smart, and B. Edwards. (2016) A Critical Review of the Early

Childhood Literature: Technical Report. Melbourne: Australian Institute of Family

Studies. ISBN 978-1-76051-114-2. DOI:10.13140/RG.2.2.13014.75843.

White, L., and M. Friendly. (2012) “Public Funding, Private Delivery: States, Markets, and Early

Childhood Education and Care in Liberal Welfare States – A Comparison of Australia, the

UK, Quebec, and New Zealand.” Journal of Comparative Policy Analysis 14(4): 292-310.

Page 292: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

282

Zachrisson, H., E. Dearing, R. Lekhal, and C. Toppelberg. (2013) “Little Evidence that Time in

Child Care Causes Externalizing Problems During Early Childhood in Norway.” Child

Development 84(4): 1152-1170.

Zhang, X. (2008) “The Post-Childbirth Employment of Canadian Mothers and the Earnings

Trajectories of their Continuously Employed Counterparts, 1983 To 2004.” Analytical

Studies Branch Research Paper Series, Statistics Canada catalogue no. 11F00119M.

Page 293: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

283

APPENDIX A: GLOSSARY

AFNI Adjusted Family Net Income

AQI Assessment Quality Instrument

B/A Before/After School

CCB Canada Child Benefit

ELCC Canada-Ontario Early Learning and Child Care Agreement

CPAM Caregiving Parent Affordability Measure

CCEYA Child Care and Early Years Act

CMSM Consolidated Municipal Service Manager

DSSAB District Social Services Administration Board

ECEC Early Childhood Education and Care

ECERS Early Childhood Environment Rating Scale

EDI Early Development Instrument

EOs EarlyOn Centres (formerly Ontario Early Years Child and Family Centres)

FHCC/HCC Family Home Child Care/Home Child Care

FIAM Family Income Affordability Measure

FF Funding Formula

GOG General Operating Grant

HCC Home Child Care

HDLH How Does Learning Happen

IWA Indian Welfare Agreement

ITERS Infant/Toddler Environment Rating Scale

JT Journey Together

MCYS Ministry of Children and Youth Services

MCSS Ministry of Community and Social Services

EDU Ministry of Education

MOHLTC Ministry of Health and Long-Term Care

NOA Notice of Assessment

OCCDES Ontario Child Care Demand and Employment Simulation Model

OCCER Ontario Child Care Employment Returns Model

OEYCFC Ontario Early Years Child and Family Centre

OMSSA Ontario Municipal Social Services Association

OW Ontario Works

PT Part-time

R&R Recruitment and Retention

Page 294: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

284

RECE Registered Early Childhood Educator

SB School Board

SACERS School-age Care Environment Rating Scale

SNR Special Needs Resourcing

WEG Wage Enhancement Grant

Page 295: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

285

APPENDIX B: WHAT FACTORS AFFECT COSTS IN

ONTARIO CHILD CARE CENTRES?

What Is a Child Care Costs Model?33

A child care costs model is a model of the typical types and amounts of costs in a child care

centre. This model includes wage and benefit costs and the costs of occupancy, administration,

supplies and so on.

It is a model of operating costs, not of capital costs. The costs of purchasing land and building a

centre are not included (although occupancy costs partly reflect capital costs; occupancy costs

(e.g., rent) will be higher in areas where initial land purchase and construction costs were

higher).

It is not a model that sums costs across the entire child care system. This costs model does not

calculate the total cost of producing child care services across Ontario, or across any region.

Instead, it looks at cost situations that are believed to be typical for a centre in different

regions.

A costs model is a tool for thinking in an organized way about the ways in which change in one

type of cost is likely to affect the cost of providing child care to children. More specifically,

there are several reasons for developing a model of the cost of providing licensed child care for

children.

- The first is to be able to predict what the effects of higher wages will be on the full cost per child of providing child care

- The second is to be able to forecast what is likely to happen to the total cost per child of producing child care if particular types of mandated changes in quality occur (e.g., increasing the proportion of staff with RECE-level training, changing group sizes, changing staff-child ratios, etc.)

- The third is to help us to think about what the implications of dramatically increasing the size of the child care system could be for the costs per child of providing services.

This type of costs model would also be useful in trying to determine whether current fees

charged by centres are reasonable or not. In that sense, this kind of model is a cousin to

33 Thanks to Petr Varmuza, OISE – University of Toronto, and Nicole Warner at Children’s Services at City of Toronto for many

suggestions about modelling costs. They are, of course, not responsible for my use of their suggestions.

Page 296: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

286

models that have been developed by municipalities (e.g., Toronto, Ottawa) to help centres

determine what fees they should be charging to the municipality for subsidized children.

Ideally, we would have a whole set of cost models representing different sizes of centre and

different age combinations in a centre. Given the time and data available, a model of the costs

in a “typical” child care centre is a good start.

We are interested particularly in children younger than kindergarten age. Let’s model costs for

a centre for children 0-4 years, with 10 infants, 15 toddlers and 48 children of preschool age34.

We can this the Ontario Child Care Centre Costs Model (or OCCC model)

Staffing

Let us imagine this centre obeys all the rules and regulations to the letter. The maximum group

size for infants is 10, so there is one infant group. The maximum group size for toddlers is 15,

so there is one toddler group. The maximum group size for preschoolers is 24, so our centre

would have two preschool groups. There are 10 infants – at current ratios that means 3 staff in

the infant room at any time the 10 infants are present. There are 15 toddlers; at current ratios,

that means 3 staff in this room at times other than close to starting time or closing time. There

are 48 preschoolers (i.e., from 30 months of age to Junior Kindergarten); that means 6 staff in

this room except at the beginning and end of the day. In addition, a full-time supervisor is

needed for the centre as a whole.

The regulations now state that for the toddlers and preschoolers (but not the infants), the

required staff complement is a minimum of 2/3rds of the normal requirement for the first 90

minutes and last 60 minutes of each day (arrival and departure periods). This means that staff

requirements for toddlers fall to 2 staff and requirements for preschoolers fall to 4 staff in the

first 90 minutes of the program and the last 60 minutes.

We assume, therefore, that there are 73 children enrolled in the child care centre, when it is

full (at its licensed capacity). At the height of the day, there would be 12 staff working, 3 in the

infant room, 3 in the toddler room, and 6 in the preschool room(s), plus the supervisor.

However, at the beginning and end of the day there could be fewer staff; for two and one-half

hours, there could be 2 staff in the toddler room and 4 staff working with preschoolers. In the

infant room, there is no allowance of reduced-staffing for beginning and end of the day for

34 Given group size regulations, this means that there is one infant group, one toddler group and one preschool group. Staff-

child ratios and requirements for qualified staff need to be respected for each group.

Page 297: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

287

safety reasons. Assuming that the child care centre stays open for 11 hours per day, that

means 8½ hours of 12 program staff and 2½ hours of 9 program staff. Therefore, a total of

124.5 hours of program staff time are needed to cover an 11-hour day for these 73 children.

Plus the supervisor.

It is a requirement that a minimum of 1/3rd of staff in each infant and toddler group need to be

qualified RECE’s whereas the remainder can be unqualified staff (not RECE’s). For preschool-

aged children, the regulations require two-thirds of staff to be qualified. For the infant room,

given the 1/3rd ratio of qualified to unqualified staff, we can calculate that 11 of the 33 daily

hours would have to be provided by qualified staff.

The calculation is trickier for toddlers and preschoolers. For toddlers, 1 out of 3 staff would be

qualified for the main part of the day (8½ hours) and 1 out of 2 staff would be qualified for the

remainder of the day. For preschoolers, 4 out of 6 staff would be qualified for the main part of

the day, and 3 out of 4 staff for the remainder of the day (assuming groups would be merged

with smaller numbers). For toddlers, that means 11 hours provided by qualified staff, and 19.5

hours provided by unqualified staff. For preschool children, 41.5 hours would be provided by

qualified staff and 19.5 hours by unqualified staff.

Some of these hours might be provided by full-time staff and some by part-time staff. I am

going to ignore any wage differences between full-time and part-time staff, and just do

calculations based on the number of hours required using data on typical wage rates for

qualified and unqualified staff. The evidence from the 2017 Child Care Operators’ Survey

confirms that hourly wages for full-time and part-time staff at the same level of qualifications

are similar. Benefits may be different between full-time and part-time staff, but we will ignore

this for lack of information.

Fringe benefits can cost between about 15% and 25% of the wage bill. The lower figure would

cover only mandatory benefits and statutory holidays. The higher figure (25%) is a desirable

target. I will set benefits as 20% of the wage for all types of staff and use this as a toggle switch

to see the effect on overall costs of increasing this to 25%.

When program staff and supervisors are away on vacation or sick time, they need to be

replaced. Toronto currently adds 10% to staff expenses to account for this. Let’s allow 10% for

staff replacement costs.

Other Expenses

I include $400 per child per year for program expenses. For this centre with 73 children, that

would be $29,200. I include $4 per child per day for food and food preparation; that would be

$76,212. Administrative staff costs are expected to be $1,200 per child per year ($87,600).

Other administrative costs include office supplies and machine rental ($10,000 per year),

Page 298: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

288

insurance ($4,000 annually), accounting and other professional fees ($6,000 annually).

Professional training and development during the year might cost $3,000 per year. These

charges would vary widely from centre to centre and across the province depending on

circumstances. The total of the expenses above would be $216,012 for a centre with 73

children.

CCEYA regulations require 2.8 square metres (just about 30 square feet) of indoor space for

each child who is an infant, toddler or preschooler. That would be 2,190 square feet. There is

also a substantial requirement for outdoor space. Although it is possible to get quotations on

the cost per square foot of child care centre space, this varies enormously across cities and

regions in Ontario. I will leave this open, assuming that the rental (or equivalent) cost of space

(and cleaning etc.) will vary from about $1,000 per child per year to about $3,000 per child per

year. For the calculations below, I will presume a standard amount of $1,000 per child,

although in Toronto and other cities, it may be considerably more, unless the space is provided

at reduced rates on a charitable or public service basis.

Calculating Costs

Wage costs vary across the province and by qualification level of staff. In the 2017 Child Care

Operators’ Survey, most child care centres in the province provided information about the

wages earned by different categories of staff. The data reports wages in categories, not as an

actual dollar figure. So, for instance, we know how many qualified program staff (RECE’s,

typically) in a centre received an hourly wage of $11.40-$15.00 per hour, and how many

received between $15.00 and $20.00 per hour, and so on. This allow us to determine what is

the median category of wages for a particular type of worker in each region (so, for instance,

we can say that the median qualified program staff in Toronto receives an hourly wage

between $20.00 and $26.68 per hour, but we don’t know where in that range the wage of the

median worker falls). In our calculations below, we look at both the low wage and high wage of

the range for the median worker of each type in each region (so, in the example above, we

would do calculations of costs if the median qualified program staff in Toronto earned $20.00

per hour and calculations of costs if she earned $26.68 per hour).

Table B-1 below shows the wage category for the median worker of each type in each region,

from the 2017 Child Care Operators’ Survey.

Page 299: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

289

Table B-1

Hourly Wage Ranges of Median Workers by Region for Different Categories of Staff

in Child Care Centres, Ontario 2017

Qualified Program Staff

Program Staff Without

Qualifications

Supervisor

Toronto $20-$26.68 $15-$20 $30-$35

West Toronto $15-$20 $11.40-$15 $20-$26.68

Central $15-$20 $11.40-$15 $20-$26.68

Southwest $15-$20 $11.40-$15 $20-$26.68

East $15-$20 $15-$20 $26.68-$30

North $15-$20 $11.40-$15 $20-$26.68

Source: Child Care Operators’ Survey 2017

These hourly wages are reported including the influence of the Wage Enhancement Grant. For

all program staff (including supervisors) earning less than $26.68 per hour, the province

contributes $2.00 per hour in a Wage Enhancement Grant, or the amount necessary to bring

them up to $26.68 per hour, whichever is less. There are other grants that contribute towards

the costs of wages (pay equity grants and others). These vary across centres and I do not have

an average figure either in Toronto or across the province.

Let us take Toronto as an example and look at total costs and cost per child. The wage cost of

typical staff (i.e., at the median) who are qualified (i.e., who are certified with the College of

Early Childhood Educators as Registered Early Childhood Educators) is between $20 and $26.68

per hour and the wage cost for untrained staff is between $15 and $20 per hour. Given the

Wage Enhancement Grant, the amount the centre has to pay would be between $18 per hour

and $24.68 per hour for qualified staff and between $13 and $18 for unqualified staff.

For the care of infants, the total annual wage and benefit bill for program staff (not including

the Supervisor) would be between $166,746 and $229,958, using the low and high point of the

wage range for median staff in the Toronto region. Using the same methods, for toddlers, the

wage and benefit bill would be between $155,551 and $214,457. For preschoolers, the wage

and benefit bill would again be between $344,692 and $473,791. Across all age categories in

this 73-space centre, the total for program staff wages and benefits (not including the

Supervisor) would be between $666,989 and $918,208.

Assume the Supervisor works an 8-hour day for all 261 operating days per year at the average

wage of between $30 and $35 per hour (not eligible for the Wage Enhancement Grant). Her

Page 300: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

290

annual wage and benefit bill would be between $82,685 and $96,466. The total wage and

benefit packet for program staff plus supervisor in this centre would then be between $749,674

and $1,014,672.

The other expenses, as itemized above are $216,012, not including occupancy costs. There is

considerable variation in occupancy costs; we are presuming $1,000 per child annually, but this

will be low in many cases. In this centre, if occupancy costs are $73,000, total centre costs

would be between $1,038,686 and $1,303,684. Since there are 73 children being cared for, the

average cost in this hypothetical Toronto centre is between $14,229 and $17,857 per child.

Allocating Costs By Children’s Age Category

To get at the “true” costs of care for infants, toddlers and preschoolers separately, I will assume

that the program staff costs stay with the children in the room but that other costs are divided

according to the total number of children in the centre.

The joint costs are made up of the program expenses, food, office expenses, administrative

staff and administrative costs, insurance, professional development, rent plus the salary and

benefits of the Supervisor. These will be shared equally amongst the children. From our

calculations, including the low and high median Supervisor’s wage in Toronto, that total is

between $371,697 and $385,478. Dividing this equally amongst the children, these joint costs

contribute between $5,092 and $5,281 to each child’s costs in Toronto.

The salary and benefit cost for program staff for infant care, including occasional staff

replacement costs, are between $166,746 and $229,958. Divided amongst 10 children, this is

between $16,675 and $22,996 each. That would make the cost per infant (including the joint

costs) between $21,766 and $28,276. Stated on a daily basis, this would be between $83.40

and $108.34 per day for infant care in this Toronto centre.

The salary and benefit cost for program staff for toddlers, including occasional staff

replacement costs, are between $155,551 and $214,457. Divided amongst 15 toddlers, this is

between $10,370 and $14,297 each. That would make the cost per toddler (including the joint

costs) between $15,462 and $19,578. Stated on a daily basis, this would be between $59.24

and $75.01 per day for toddler care in Toronto.

The salary and benefit cost for program staff for children of preschool age, including staff

replacement costs, are between $344,692 and $473,791. Divided amongst 48 preschoolers,

this is between $7,181 and $9,871 each. That would make the cost per preschooler (including

the joint costs) between $12,273 and $15,151. Stated on a daily basis, this would be between

$47.02 and $58.05 per day for preschool care in Toronto.

Page 301: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

291

Using the median wage ranges provided in Table B-1, we can do the same type of calculations

for other regions of the province. Table B-2 shows the results of these calculations for all

regions as full-year costs for infants, toddlers and preschoolers. Table B-3 shows the same

information in the form of daily costs of child care.

Table B-2

Calculated Annual Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child Care Centres,

by Region, Ontario 2017

Annual Costs per Infant Annual Costs per Toddler Annual Costs per Preschooler

Toronto $21,766-$28,276 $15,462-$19,578 $12,273-$15,151

West Toronto $18,206-$21,641 $13,029-$15,336 $10,106-$12,147

Central $18,206-$21,641 $13,029-$15,336 $10,106-$12,147

Southwest $18,206-$21,641 $13,029-$15,336 $10,106-$12,147

East $19,746-$25,556 $14,073-$17,701 $10,658-$12,973

North $18,206-$21,641 $13,029-$15,336 $10,106-$12,147

Source: Ontario Child Care Centre Costs Model, developed by authors. Assumptions described in text of this appendix.

Page 302: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

292

Table B-3

Calculated Daily Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child Care Centres,

by Region, Ontario 2017

Infant Costs per day Toddler Costs per day Preschool Costs per day

Toronto $83.40-$108.34 $59.24-$75.01 $47.02-$58.05

West Toronto $69.75-$82.92 $49.92-$58.76 $38.72-$46.54

Central $69.75-$82.92 $49.92-$58.76 $38.72-$46.54

Southwest $69.75-$82.92 $49.92-$58.76 $38.72-$46.54

East $75.66-$97.92 $53.92-$67.82 $40.84-$49.70

North $69.75-$82.92 $49.92-$58.76 $38.72-$46.54

Source: Ontario Child Care Centre Costs Model, developed by authors. Assumptions described in text of this

appendix.

These costs can be compared to the full fees shown in Table B-4. Although there are

differences (infant full fees charged to parents are sometimes lower than median calculated

costs per infant; fees in the North appear to be lower than estimated costs), the broad pattern

of similarity suggests that, as you would expect, the cost of services and the fees charged for

services are closely related.

Page 303: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

293

Table B-4

Median Full Fees Charged for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child Care Centres,

by Region, Ontario 2017

Median Infant Full Fee per day

Median Toddler Full Fee per day

Median Preschool Full Fee per day

Toronto $85.00 $66.00 $52.00

West Toronto $66.95 $52.55 $46.25

Central $57.50 $48.86 $42.84

Southwest $55.45 $48.40 $42.00

East $61.00 $51.00 $43.34

North $51.00 $42.00 $38.00

Source: Ontario Child Care Operators’ Survey 2017. Data provided by Ministry of Education. Calculations by authors.

Other Important Considerations

There are three other considerations that would affect the calculations above:

1. occupancy costs;

2. General Operating expenditures that could reduce wage expenditures/reduce fees

charged;

3. the cost of vacancies.

Each of these could have an important impact on calculated costs.

Occupancy costs, as stated before, can vary enormously within a region and across regions. We

did the calculations above based on the low assumed occupancy cost of $1,000 per child per

year. If the occupancy cost was, for instance, $3,000 per child per year, it would add $2,000 per

child per year to each of those per-child costs calculated above. Each $1,000 per child per year

on occupancy costs translates into nearly $4.00 per day of extra costs.

In 2015, across the province, municipalities spent nearly $266 million on General Operating

expenditures. The precise direction of these expenditures is under municipal discretion and

varies widely across municipalities, but much of it is directed to supporting wages of educators

and staff and reducing fees or at least not letting them rise. Variations between calculated

costs and full fees (as shown in the comparison of Tables 3 and 4) may be partly explained by

the effect of General Operating expenditures on fees charged.

Page 304: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

294

Finally, but not least important, there is the issue of vacancies. Every vacancy represents lost

revenue, and that lost revenue can be thought of as a cost, because it often means that the

costs have to be spread over a smaller number of children. That would not be true if every time

there was a vacancy, staffing and other costs went down by the same proportion. However,

costs in child care are lumpy and inflexible, due to regulations on staff-child ratios etc., so costs

do not go down much when a centre is not full.

The issue of vacancies can be a big problem because of the way that children “graduate” from

preschool-aged child care. Preschool-aged children are those between 30 months of age (2½

years) and kindergarten age. However, children enter kindergarten at only one point during the

year – the beginning of September. Essentially, in September (and the couple of months

preceding September), children who are eligible to enter kindergarten in September change

their child care arrangements. Some will move into a before and after school child care class

within the same centre. Some will drop out of child care because kindergarten hours are

sufficient for the family’s needs. Whatever, the reason, child care centres lose one full calendar

year of preschool children all on one day (or at least at one time of year close to September).

All of the preschool children in the centre who are between three years eight months of age at

the beginning of September and four years seven months of age at the beginning of September

become eligible to enter kindergarten on the same day.

This creates two vacancy-related problems for child care centres. First, there are likely to be a

large number of preschool vacancies in each centre in each September and the months

following until the centre builds up its clientele to full complement. However, there is a second

dynamic at play. Because toddlers “graduate” from toddler rooms all throughout the year as

they reach 30 months of age, but preschoolers “graduate” all at one time, there can be

insufficient room during the year to allow toddlers to move up into a preschool room. Some

centres like to leave some vacancy in the preschool room during the year to allow them to

accommodate “graduating” toddlers.

These pressures (added to the pressures caused by lack of affordability) mean that many

centres will have some vacancies at different periods during the year. However, vacancies are a

real cost. Since costs are not very flexible, vacancies mostly mean that the full costs need to be

divided amongst a smaller number of children. Vacancies can clearly add to cost pressures in

child care.

Staff Costs as a Percent of Total Costs

It is common to say that staff costs make up 80% or more of all costs in child care. That’s not

bad as a very round approximation, but it’s not very exact. In fact, if we take the low end of the

median wage range for each type of staff and in each region, staff costs (including qualified and

non-qualified program staff wages and benefits, supervisor wages and benefits and an

Page 305: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

295

allowance for replacement for sick days and holidays) are only over 80% of all costs for infants

in Toronto and the Eastern Region.

The staff costs percentage varies by age category of children. For infants (when we look at the

low end of the median wage range), staff costs are 79%-83% across the regions. For toddlers,

staff costs are about 70%-76%. For preschoolers, staff costs are about 62%-69% across the

regions. Of course, if we take the high end of the median wage range the picture is somewhat

different, but still similar. For infants (when we look at the high end of the median wage range),

staff costs are 82%-87% across the regions. For toddlers, staff costs are 75%-81%. For

preschoolers, staff costs are about 69%-75% across the regions.

Therefore changes in staff compensation will have a bigger effect on the cost of and fee for

infant care than it will on the cost of and fee for preschool care.

What Can We Learn From this Costs Model?

We can use a model like this to answer several interesting questions about costs. For instance:

What effect will a 10% rise in wages have on costs of providing child care?

What effect would a rise in benefits have on the costs of providing child care?

What effect would a move to “recommended” levels of compensation have on the costs of providing child care?

What effect would requiring all program staff to be RECE-qualified have on the costs of providing child care?

Page 306: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

296

The Effect of a 10% Rise in Wages

If the low and high ends of the median wage range rise by 10% for all types of staff (qualified

and unqualified program staff, as well as supervisors), the results are as shown in Table B-5.

This can be compared to Table B-3 to see the amount of the rise in daily costs in different

regions. In summary, we can say that a 10% rise in wages causes a rise of between 8.0% and

8.6% in the daily costs of infant care (with the higher percentage coming where costs were

highest before). For toddler care, the rise of 10% in wages causes a rise of between 7.2% and

8.0% in daily costs. For preschool care, the rise of 10% in wages causes a rise of between 6.3%

and 7.4% in daily costs. In each case, the higher of these percentages comes where costs were

previously highest.

Note that, since benefits are calculated as 20% of wage costs, the 10% rise in wages has an

effect on the total cost of benefits, as well as affecting pure wage costs.

Table B-5

Calculated Daily Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child Care Centres with

a 10% rise in Wages above Current Levels,

by Region, Ontario 2017

Infant Costs per day Toddler Costs per day Preschool Costs per day

Toronto $90.22-$117.66 $63.65-$80.99 $50.21-$62.34

West Toronto $75.53-$89.69 $53.71-$63.12 $41.40-$49.68

Central $75.53-$89.69 $53.71-$63.12 $41.40-$49.68

Southwest $75.53-$89.69 $53.71-$63.12 $41.40-$49.68

East $81.70-$106.19 $57.80-$73.09 $43.40-$53.16

North $75.53-$89.69 $53.71-$63.12 $41.40-$49.68

Page 307: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

297

The Effect of a Rise in Benefits to 25%

We have modelled employee benefits as 20% of wage costs for all staff levels. In many

occupations, benefit packages cost more like 25% of wages. Table B-6 below shows what

would happen to daily costs if employee benefits were to rise to 25%.

In sum, the daily costs of providing child care would rise by 3.2%-3.6% for infants. Daily costs

for toddlers would rise by 2.8%-3.4% relative to current levels. Daily costs for preschool child

care would rise by 2.5%-2.9% relative to current levels.

Table B-6

Calculated Daily Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child Care Centres with

a Rise in Employee Benefits to 25% of Wages, by Region, Ontario 2017

Infant Costs per day Toddler Costs per day Preschool Costs per day

Toronto $86.24-$112.22 $61.08-$77.50 $48.35-$59.84

West Toronto $72.03-$85.74 $51.37-$60.58 $39.70-$47.85

Central $72.03-$85.74 $51.37-$60.58 $39.70-$47.85

Southwest $72.03-$85.74 $51.37-$60.58 $39.70-$47.85

East $78.18-$101.36 $55.53-$70.01 $41.91-$51.14

North $72.03-$85.74 $51.37-$60.58 $39.70-$47.85

The Effect of a Rise in Wages and Benefits to “Recommended” Levels

In order to recruit more staff and more qualified staff as the child care sector expands, wages

and benefits will have to rise; it Is unclear by how much.

One useful thought-experiment is to imagine costs when wages and benefits reach some kind

of “target” level. Although it is unclear what this level is, we could imagine that, over time,

wages for qualified staff will rise to $26.68 per hour with benefits at 25% of the wage package.

For unqualified staff, wages could rise to $20 per hour with benefits at 25%. And supervisors’

wages could rise to $35 per hour, with benefits at 25%. I assume here that the WEG continues

at $2 per hour for all staff, even those who have reached $26.68 per hour. Wages, benefits and

all other costs are assumed to be the same in all regions.

Page 308: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

298

In this case, the annual cost of infant care would be $29,497 or $113.02 per day. The cost of

toddler care would be $21,284 annually or $81.55 per day. The cost of preschool care would be

$15,381 or $58.93 per day. Of course, occupancy costs could be higher than the assumed

annual amount of $1,000 per child, pushing the annual and daily totals up by corresponding

amounts.

The Effect of Having All Program Staff Qualified

Another possible use of this type of costs model is to simulate the effect on costs of changes in

legislation or regulations. So, for instance, one could simulate the impact of different changes

in staff-child ratios. Or, as in this example, one could simulate the effect of requiring all

program staff to have RECE qualifications.

We do this by assuming that the wage levels for qualified staff apply to all program staff (not

including supervisors). This is only a very partial way of looking at this issue. We would imagine

that if all program staff had to be qualified, there would be a large increase in the demand for

qualified staff. Shortages would probably lead to a rise in wage levels above current levels. We

ignore this important factor and only look at the immediate cost impact of requiring all program

staff to be qualified.

Table B-7 shows the daily costs that result from hiring only qualified program staff. Note that it

is assumed that both wages and benefits (and all other costs) remain the same as currently.

The only change is that all program staff on the floor (apart from supervisory staff) receive the

same wage rates as qualified staff do now.

The effect on costs of having all program positions filled by qualified staff varies across regions

and age groups as shown in Table B-7. Infants and toddlers generally have a larger percentage

of unqualified staff, so changing to all qualified staff has a bigger impact than for preschoolers.

But the effect also depends on how big the differences in wages between qualified and

unqualified staff before this change. At the largest, this causes an increase in nearly 18% in per-

child costs. Sometimes, the effect on costs is much smaller. The details matter in this case.

Page 309: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

299

TableB-7

Calculated Daily Costs for Infant, Toddler and Preschool Child Care in Child Care Centres with

All Program Staff Having Qualifications,

by Region, Ontario 2017

Infant Costs per day Toddler Costs per day Preschool Costs per day

Toronto $97.92-$127.74 $67.82-$86.47 $49.70-$61.63

West Toronto $74.40-$97.44 $52.66-$67.34 $39.58-$49.22

Central $74.40-$97.44 $52.66-$67.34 $39.58-$49.22

Southwest $74.40-$97.44 $52.66-$67.34 $39.58-$49.22

East $75.66-$97.92 $53.92-$67.82 $40.84-$49.70

North $74.40-$97.44 $52.66-$67.34 $39.58-$49.22

Conclusions from the Costs Model

This appendix presents a costs model to help to determine what the per child cost of care is in

different regions and for different age categories of children. The model is one attempt to

determine what the key costs are in centres and how they vary. As the licensed child care

system expands with improved affordability, it will likely be necessary to have some controls

over rising costs and fees. The Ministry of Education will want to work with municipalities to

determine the most appropriate way to model reasonable costs of service provision.

The calculated costs of child care provision are based on the data on wages from the Child Care

Operators’ Survey from March 2017. It does not include the effect on wages of the increase in

the minimum wage of January 2018. Modelling costs is made more difficult by the fact that

wage data is only available in ranges (e.g., $11.40-$15.00, $15.00-$20.00, etc.). More precise

data on wages actually paid would make this kind of model more useful.

We can draw some conclusions from the calculated per child costs of child care for infants,

toddlers and preschoolers in different regions. It seems as if in most or all regions, there is

some cross-subsidization of infant care. In other words, the median fee charged for infant care

in each region is below the range of calculated costs of infant care. Further, in the North

region, fees for all types of care are below calculated costs. This suggests that the General

Operating Grant is used actively in the North to lower child care fees and improve affordability.

Page 310: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

300

The conventional wisdom is that wages and benefit costs make up 80% or more of the cost of

child care. However, it is useful and important to see that staff costs are a bigger fraction of

infant care costs, than of toddler or preschool costs. When we look at the low end of the wage

ranges that are considered in each region, it is a good generalization that the percent of staff

costs is in the 80’s for infants, the 70s for toddlers and the high 60s for preschoolers. The

percentages are somewhat higher if overall wage levels are higher, but the principle remains.

In other words, staff costs (wages and benefits of program staff and supervisor) are a

considerably lower percentage of the cost of preschool child care than they are of infant child

care.

This implies that when wages or benefits rise, they will have less effect on the costs of

preschool child care than on the costs of infant child care. We see that in the simulation of a

10% rise in staff wages. This pushes up infant care costs by 8.0%-8.6%. It pushes up toddler

care costs by 7.2%-8.0%. It pushes up preschool child care costs by 6.3%-7.4%.

Benefits in our costs model are assumed to be 20% of wage costs for all staff. If benefits rise to

25% of wage costs, the result in an overall rise in costs per child of between 2.5% and 3.6%.

The percentage rise is higher for infants than for toddlers and for preschoolers.

Raising wages and benefits to target levels would have important effects on costs and fees. If

wages were $26.68 for all qualified workers and $20 for all unqualified workers, if supervisors

received $35 per hour and benefits for all staff were 25% of wage costs, the annual cost of

infant care would be $29,497 across the province. The annual cost of toddler care would be

$21,284, and the annual cost of preschool care would be $15,381. If occupancy costs were

higher than the assumed amount of $1,000 per child, these figures would be correspondingly

higher.

This is not intended as an argument against rising wages and benefits in child care. It is obvious

that wages and benefits will rise and should rise. It is important though that rising wages and

benefits are designed appropriately to meet their objectives of recruiting and retaining a highly

skilled workforce. There should be compensation for higher qualifications and perhaps for

experience, and there should be a sufficient occupational ladder and set of qualifications to aim

for that there is incentive for continual upgrading of skills and abilities. If compensation rises in

a way that does not meet these goals, then child care will be expensive but of inadequate

quality.

We also model the effect on costs of having all staff qualified (i.e., all staff are paid the wages

and benefits currently received by qualified staff). This can have a large effect on per-child

costs – nearly 18% rise for infant care in Toronto and nearly 15% for toddler care in Toronto.

However, the effect of this reform is highly dependent on both the age category of child and

what the prior differences in wages between qualified and unqualified were.

Page 311: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

301

If child care in Ontario is going to move from its current market model to one in which child

care is seen as a public service delivered by not-for-profit operators, there will be much more

discussion and concern about what level of costs is reasonable. Wages, benefits and fees are

likely to be managed rather than determined entirely by markets, so costs modelling may be an

important management tool. This appendix is a contribution to that project.

Page 312: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

302

APPENDIX C: THE EVOLUTION OF CHILD CARE AND

CHILD CARE POLICY IN ONTARIO

The Evolution of Child Care and Child Care Policy in Ontario

Essentially, the story of child care in Ontario begins in World War Two. In order to permit

women with young children to fill vital wartime production jobs, under the Dominion-Provincial

War Time Agreement, federal and provincial governments established and funded day care

facilities on a 50/50 cost-shared basis. The Day Nurseries Branch was established in the Ontario

Government to administer funding. In Toronto, most of the forty-one newly-established

programs were operated by the local government. When the war ended and the government

wanted to shut down these facilities, there was organized resistance and 19 of the facilities

were kept open.

The Day Nurseries Act was established in 1946 to provide a legislative and regulatory

framework for these facilities and others. However, federal government funding disappeared,

responsibility for day care was moved into the welfare department, administrative

responsibility rested with municipalities and funding assistance was now “means-tested”. As

the Daycare Reform Action Alliance put it “Daycare was no longer a right…but for those in

‘special need’.” (p.3, 1975)

The Canada Assistance Plan and Child Care Subsidies

The modern history of child care in Ontario begins in 1966 when the federal government

passed the Canada Assistance Plan. This was a response to the pervasive concern about

poverty and the effects of poverty in Canada. The Canada Assistance Plan established a major

federal role in funding welfare and social services – generally on a 50/50 basis with the

provinces. Because women with young children, and particularly single women with young

children, were an important component of family poverty, the Canada Assistance Plan also

provided some funding for child care. This was a major innovation; for the first time since

World War Two, the federal government was a major funding participant in child care.

Under the Canada Assistance Plan, families could be provided financial assistance with child

care services in two possible ways: the welfare incomes route and the welfare services route. A

province would have to choose which method to use. Under the welfare incomes route, a

family could be provided financial assistance with child care if they were determined to be “in

need”. To determine need, a family had to undergo a needs test – a comparison of their

Page 313: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

303

legitimate expenditures to their available income (including assets that could readily be

liquidated). If the needs test could show that a family did not have enough income available to

be able to afford licensed child care, they would be given a subsidy (in Ontario, cost-shared

50/30/20 among the federal, provincial and municipal governments). The amount of subsidy

they were given would depend on whether the needs test showed that they had some income

(after deducting expenditures) that they could contribute.

The welfare services route was simpler. Families had to undergo an income test (but did not

have to provide evidence about their expenditures). The income test was said to be a

judgement of whether the family was “in need or likely to be in need” (i.e., likely to be in need

if the family did not receive assistance obtaining child care). If the family income was below a

certain point (the turning point, which varied according to the number of parents and the

number of children), the family would get a full subsidy. If the family income was higher than

this, a formula determined how much subsidy the family would receive towards their child care

costs. Subsidies were cost-shared 50/50 between the province and the federal government.

All provinces except Ontario went with the simpler welfare services route (income test).

Ontario went with the welfare incomes route (needs test). Part of the rationale of the Ontario

government was that the welfare services route required that all eligible service providers had

to be not-for-profit, rather than commercial. Only with the welfare incomes route was it

permissible for subsidies to be used in for-profit child care services.

However, as a result of this decision by the government, Ontario’s subsidy system has had a

long history of being strongly twinned with social assistance, with very intrusive testing of

potentially subsidizable families, and with bureaucratic administration of access to the subsidy

system. This was compounded in Ontario with municipal responsibility for administration of

subsidy. The administration of the needs test and rules around what subsidy would cover

(minimum fees, maximum amounts the municipality would cover, etc.) varied from one

municipality to another, making the funding of child care opaque and forbidding to many

potential users. Further, the cost-sharing in Ontario was 50/30/20 instead of 50/50, because

municipalities were expected to pick up a 20% share. As a result, municipalities had incentives

to spend less on child care and change eligibility and payment rules to reduce their potential

expenditures.

With either the welfare services route or the welfare incomes route, there was also an activity

test for subsidy eligibility. In other words, parents were expected to either be employed, in

training for employment, or studying (as well as qualifying according to the needs test in

Ontario or income test in other provinces) to be eligible for a child care subsidy. There were

exceptions to this rule, of course; special circumstances for either children or parents might

satisfy the activity test.

Page 314: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

304

The Mainstreaming of Child Care – the 1970s, 1980s and 1990s

Day care was an important public issue throughout the 1970’s and 1980’s, paralleling the

increase in women’s participation in labour markets. The Royal Commission on the Status of

Women reporting in 1971 wrote:

“We recommend that the federal government immediately take steps to enter

into agreement with the provinces leading to the adoption of a national Day-

Care Act under which federal funds would be made available on a cost-sharing

basis for the building and running of day-care centres meeting specified

minimum standards, the federal government to (a) pay half the operating

costs; (b) during an initial seven-year period, pay 70 per cent of capital costs;

and (c) make similar arrangements for the Yukon and Northwest Territories”

In June of 1974 in Ontario, Minister Margaret Birch tabled proposals in the legislature

that became known as the Birch Proposals. The initiative was driven by a desire to reduce costs

and fees. There were proposed reductions in required staff-child ratios; decreased standards in

staff qualifications and training; elimination of the requirement that daycares have kitchens and

altering the requirements for physical standards. The proposals were criticized by both non-

profit and for-profit day care associations for different reasons. Opposition to these proposals

birthed the child care advocacy movement in the province. The government eventually shelved

the recommendations.

At the federal level, there were two major reports on child care funding – the Katie Cooke

report (or Task Force on Child Care) in 1986 and the Special Parliamentary Committee on Child

Care which reported in 1987. The mandate of the Task Force, set up by the Trudeau

government, was to “examine and assess the need for child care and parental leave in Canada,

as well as the adequacy of current systems, and make recommendations on the federal

government’s role in the development of a national system of quality child care.” The Task

Force recommended a publicly funded universal child care system as a long term objective.

This would be gradually developed and eventually cost $11.3 billion per year.

The Special Parliamentary Committee on Child Care, established by the incoming Mulroney

government called for reform of the Child Care Expense Deduction and more money to be

spent on subsidies, operating grants and capital grants. This would have established a federal

role in child care spending with total federal spending of nearly $1 million annually.

In Ontario, in 1987, the government under David Peterson published a major policy document

entitled New Directions for Child Care. The document promised “a comprehensive policy that

recognizes child care as a basic public service, not a welfare service.” This ushered in payment

of direct operating grants to licensed child care services – the first major example of supply-side

Page 315: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

305

funding in child care in Ontario. In addition, the government mandated the inclusion of day

care centres in all newly-built schools, beginning a twinning of child care and schools that

continues today.

Introduced in 1988, the Direct Operating Grant (DOG) program increased salaries and wages of

staff and care providers in both licensed centres and private home day care agencies. The

average wage increase for child care centre staff was 18% in non-profit centres and 12% in

commercial centres. An evaluation of the first year of the DOG was completed in July, 1990,

indicating that 85% of the approximately $46.5 million was used to augment salaries and

benefits, and 15% was used for non-salary purposes. (p. 4)

In 1994, the Report of Ontario’s Royal Commission on Learning recommended free early

childhood education programs for all three, four and five year olds as part of the education

system in Ontario.

In 1995, Minister Janet Ecker published Improving Ontario’s Child Care System: Ontario’s Child

Care Review.

The federal Canada Assistance Plan, which was the foundation of child care subsidy systems

across the country, was terminated in 1996. This was the end of 50/50 federal/provincial cost-

sharing of most child care expenditures (50/30/20 in Ontario). The Canada Assistance Plan was

replaced by the Canada Social Transfer to fund social services and post-secondary education,

but this is a block grant, so there is no accounting for whether federal funds are spent on child

care or not. Following the demise of the Canada Assistance Plan, provinces and territories

began to plan, fund, develop and operate in increasingly different ways.

The most significant developments were the major changes to family and child care policies in

Quebec from 1997 onwards.

In April 1999, the Report of the Early Years Study, by Dr. Fraser Mustard and Hon Margaret

McCain, was released. The report made the case that development in a child’s first six years

sets the foundation for lifelong learning, behaviour and health. The report recommended that

Early Childhood Development and Parenting Centres should be accessible and affordable for all

children and families in Ontario prior to school entry.

In 2001/2 103 Ontario Early Years Centres were established in every riding in Ontario.

In the early 2000s, the federal government developed a Children’s Agenda. Under this, there

was a Multilateral Framework Agreement for spending on early learning and child care

developed in 2003. This provided additional funding for provinces, and led towards the

bilateral agreements designed to provide funding for a National Child Care Plan. These bilateral

agreements were cancelled under the incoming Harper Government in 2006.

Page 316: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

306

Recent Child Care Policy Developments in Ontario

A new Ontario government in 2003 had a platform for young children called Best Start. It was a

long-term plan to promote healthy development and early learning and child care for Ontario

children so they would arrive at school ready to learn. The goal was to create a universal

regulated child care system as a “seamless extension of our public education system”. A

Ministry of Children’s Services was established (later changed to the Ministry of Children and

Youth Services). It took the responsibility for children’s services previously held by the Ministry

of Community and Social Services.

In November 2004, the government announced its Best Start strategy. This involved a major

expansion of child care for children of junior and senior kindergarten age, moving towards

integrated seamless services. Three pilot projects were established to develop part-day

preschool (at no cost to parents) Temiskaming, Hamilton, Chatham-Kent-Lambton) as well as

construction of new centres in schools and the beginning of forging new relationships between

school boards, schools, municipalities and child care operators. Also, a plan to revamp the

subsidy system, develop an early learning framework and establish a College of Early Childhood

Educators.

Federal-provincial bilateral agreements providing funding for child care were cancelled in

March 2006, but some funds still flowed as a result of these agreements.

Ontario revised its subsidy system to introduce income testing effective January 1, 2007. The

system was more generous than the previous needs test. Family incomes below $20,000 of

adjusted family income would qualify for full subsidy. Up to $40,000 families would have to

contribute 10% of the extra income earned above $20,000. Above $40,000, families would

have to contribute 30% of the income earned above $40,000. This meant that for a family with,

for instance, $20,000 of annual child care fees to pay, the availability of partial subsidy would

disappear at a family income level of $100,000.

In 2007, a new curriculum framework for the early years, known as ELECT, was adopted, and

the College of Early Childhood Educators was established. In the election campaign of 2007,

the incumbent governmental party promised to bring in a universal full-day early learning

program for all four and five year-old children in Ontario.

Charles Pascal was appointed as Early Learning Advisor to Premier Dalton McGuinty in

November 2007 to recommend a model for implementing full-day early learning for all four and

five year-olds. His report, With Our Best Future in Mind, came out in June 2009. It

recommended that child care become the responsibility of the Ministry of Education and that

full-day learning for 4 and 5 year olds become universally available with a team teaching model

(university-qualified teacher and community-college trained early childhood educator as well as

Page 317: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

307

offering a seamless experience for children from early morning until evening. Best Start

Centres, typically in schools, would become the main location for 0-4 year-old child care.

Full day early learning (i.e., full-day kindergarten for 4 and 5 year olds with a team-teaching

model) was phased in across the province over the period 2010-2014.

In 2011, the province began consultations on a plan to modernize the child care system.

Developments under this plan include:

Revised governing legislation and regulations - the Child Care and Early Years Act, 2014;

More specific curriculum guidelines - How Does Learning Happen? Ontario’s Pedagogy for the Early Years;

Expanding before and after school programming for children 6-12 years in schools – co-ordinated by the school system and in collaboration with CMSMs/DSSABs.

Expanding spaces through capital investments focused in new and expanding schools.

Integrating Ontario’s child and family programs – Ontario Early Years Child and Family Centres to be managed by local municipalities (instead of being separate and independently funded) beginning in 2018. They were transferred from Ministry of Children and Youth Services in 2014.

$2 per hour wage enhancement grants provided directly by the province to all staff earning less than $26.26 per hour.

There is also a plan to develop a French language resource document to promote French language and Francophone culture in Ontario.

In 2017, Ontario published “Ontario’s Renewed Early Years and Child Care Policy Framework”.

Renewed because it updates and changes an Early Years and Child Care Framework published in

2011. As the document says, it sets out the government’s “plan to transform Ontario’s early

years and child care system.” (p. 5). The document outlines 7 areas of action. They are:

1. Increasing access to early years and child care programs and services

2. Ensuring a more affordable early years and child care system

3. Establishing an early years workforce strategy

4. Determining a provincial definition of quality in the early years

5. Developing an approach to promoting inclusion in early years and child care settings

6. Creating an outcomes and measurement strategy

7. Increasing public awareness of Ontario’s early years and child care system

Recent developments include:

Page 318: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

308

In 2017, the Ministry provides $1.44 billion to 47 municipalities (including wage enhancement,

child care expansion plan funding, ELCC funding, operating funding, fee subsidies, special needs

resource funding and administration). There are 406,395 licensed child care spaces in 2016-17,

up 117% since 2003-2004.

The $1.44 billion includes funding under the federal/provincial Canada-Ontario Early Learning

and Child Care Agreement. This agreement provides for $435million of spending over three

years.

There is $120 million over 2016-2019 to create 4,000 new child care spaces in schools – a new

Child Care Expansion Plan. There is $269 million over 3 years for wage enhancement.

Early years initiative under The Journey Together: Ontario’s Commitment to Reconciliation with

Indigenous Peoples. This initiative is intended to enhance access to culturally relevant,

Indigenous-led early years programs and services off-reserve, including child care and child and

family programs.

On September 12, 2016, Ontario made a commitment to provide access for 100,000 more

children aged 0 to 4 years.

First Nations Child Care

The Child Care and Early Years Act, 2014 (CCEYA) authorizes a First Nation or group of First

Nations to establish, administer, operate and fund child care and early years programs and

services. Some fee subsidies for licensed on-reserve child care programs are cost shared on an

80% provincial / 20% First Nations basis. First Nations manage the fee subsidy system in their

respective communities. The province covers 100% of other child care costs under the Ministry

of Community Services Act.

Currently, 57 out of 133 First Nations have provincially-funded licensed child care in their

communities, with a total capacity of 3,175 licensed child care spaces. There are also two

licensed home-based child care agencies on reserve supporting a total of 31 homes (Licensing

data as of March 31, 2017). These are in Akwesasne and Six Nations.

Ontario has increased child care funding to the 57 First Nations with existing child care

programs from $17.7M in 2011-12 to $27.7M in 2017-18 ($30.8M with wage enhancement

funding).

There is funding to support formal and informal child care costs for individuals participating in

the full Ontario Works (OW) Program. EDU provided $964,237 in 2016-17 to 17 First Nations

without licensed child care on reserve, and 30 of the 57 First Nations with licensed child care on

reserve.

Page 319: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

309

The Ministry of Education currently provides approximately $712,000 to five First Nations

currently delivering child and family programs on reserve.

Since 2011-12 the government has increased First Nations child care funding from $17.7 million

to $30.8 million in 2017-18, including $2.9M in wage enhancements.

Page 320: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

310

The Evolution of Child Care in Ontario – in Numbers

Table C-1

Licensed Child Care Spaces Available in Ontario 1992-2015

Year Ontario: Number of licensed child care spaces

(0-12)

Ontario: Number of licensed child care centre

spaces (0-5) (est.)

1992 145,545 105,150

1995 147,853 n.a.

1998 167,090 108,150

2001 173,135 118,160

2004 206,743 123,970

2006 229,875 138,920

2007 242,488

2008 256,748 159,150

2010 276,410 163,120

2012 292,997 175,880

2014 334,010 199,328

2015 350,801 215,578

2017 406,395 253,121

Source: Most of these figures are from the Childcare Resource and Research Unit, ECEC in Canada 2014. The 0-5 spaces are

calculated from % of 0-5 children who have spaces available. 2015 and 2017 figures are calculated from Ministry of Education

data and do not include regulated home care. The Ontario Child Care Providers’ Survey of 2017 tabulates that there were

12,641 children younger than compulsory school age using home child care in March 2017, and 15,923 including all ages.

Page 321: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

311

Table C-2

Provincial/Municipal Expenditure on Licensed Child Care, Ontario

Year Provincial/Municipal Expenditure on Licensed Child Care ($ millions)

1995 541.8

1998 470.5

2001 451.5

2003/4 497.4

2005/6 830.1

2007/8 780.4

2009/10 801.8

2011/12 865.1

2013/14 960.1

2015/16 1,307.5

2016/17 1.440.0

Source: Most of these figures are from CRRU, ECEC in Canada 2014. 2015 and 2016 figures are provided by the Ministry of

Education and may not be perfectly comparable.

Page 322: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

312

APPENDIX D: TAXES AND BENEFITS FOR ONTARIO

FAMILIES

Ontario parents who have incomes will generally have to pay income taxes on that income, and

will also have Canada Pension Plan payments and Employment Insurance payments. In

addition, they will be eligible for benefits, some of which work through the tax system (reducing

taxes payable) and some of which are separate from the tax system (e.g., Canada Child Benefit).

These taxes and benefits are important for families and important for society. Even though

many of us when asked how much income we make, will think of our gross (i.e., pre-tax)

income, it is the after-tax after-benefit (i.e., net) income that is most important for our well-

being and the well-being of our children. Even though taxes and benefits are difficult to

calculate precisely, economists believe that parents’ economic decisions are affected by net

income rather than gross income. Of course, child care costs also influence parent decisions,

but our concern in this appendix is to describe the taxes and benefits that affect the amount of

income parents have available to spend, before considering child care costs.

Our objective is to describe the details of these benefits and taxes.

1. Canada Child Benefit (CCB) is calculated from July of one year to June of the next, based on

adjusted family net income from the previous year, the number and ages of children.

To calculate the adjusted net income of one parent take that parent’s income from all sources

plus registered disability savings plan (RDSP) benefits received and plus any social assistance

payments received. Then subtract any pension contributions, any union dues, and the Child

Care Expense Deduction. The Child Care Expense Deduction is generally only claimable by the

lower earning spouse in the family.

Add together the adjusted net income of both parents, if there are two, to get Adjusted family

net income (AFNI).

We can calculate the Canada Child Benefit (CCB) as follows.

$6,400 per year ($533.33 per month) for each eligible child under the age of six; and $5,400 per year ($450.00 per month) for each eligible child aged 6 to 17.

These amounts start being reduced when the adjusted family net income (AFNI) is over

$30,000. The reduction is calculated as follows:

For families with one eligible child, the reduction is 7% of the amount of AFNI between $30,000 and $65,000, plus 3.2% of the amount of AFNI over $65,000.

Page 323: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

313

For families with two eligible children, the reduction is 13.5% of the amount of AFNI between $30,000 and $65,000, plus 5.7% of the amount of AFNI over $65,000.

For families with three eligible children, the reduction is 19% of the amount of AFNI between $30,000 and $65,000, plus 8% of the amount of AFNI over $65,000.

For families with four or more eligible children, the reduction is 23% of the amount of AFNI between $30,000 and $65,000, plus 9.5% of the amount of AFNI over $65,000.

What all of this means is that for a family with one child under age 6, the CCB declines from

$6,400 to $3,950 as ANFI rises from $30,000 to $65,000, and then declines more slowly as ANFI

rises from $65,000 up to $188,437 (at which point the CCB has fallen to zero). For a family with

two children under age 6, the CCB declines from $12,800 to $8,075 as ANFI rises from $30,000

to $65,000, and then declines more slowly as ANFI rises from $65,000 up to $206,667 (at which

point the CCB has fallen to zero).

In addition, there is an Ontario Child Benefit (OCB) which comes from the Province and, in

effect, “tops up” the CCB. The Ontario Child Benefit provides direct financial support to low to

moderate income families – whether they are working or not. It helps parents with the cost of

raising their children.

The Ontario Child Benefit supports about one million children in over 500,000 families. It

provides a maximum payment of $1,356 per child per year ($113 per child per month), and is

provided as an additional part of the CCB, paid by Revenue Canada. The OCB declines by 8% of

any family net income above $20,706. That means that for a family with one child under age 6,

the OCB disappears when family net income rises above $37,656, while for a family with two

children under age 6, the OCB disappears when family net income rises above $54,606.

The CCB is more generous, especially to middle and upper middle class families.

2. Payroll Taxes

a) Employment Insurance

In 2017, the employee contribution is 1.63% of earnings up to $51,300, for a maximum

employee payment of $836.19. The rate is applied from the first dollar earned. The premium

generates a non-refundable tax credit, reducing its cost by 21.05% in Ontario once the

individual begins paying income taxes (but not before).

b) Canada Pension Plan

In 2017,the employee contribution is 4.95% of earnings up to $55,300, with an exemption for

the first $3,500 earned, for a maximum employee payment of $2,564.10. The rate is thus

Page 324: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

314

applied on all dollars above $3,500. The premium generates a non-refundable tax credit,

reducing its cost by 21.05% in Ontario once the individual begins paying income taxes.

3. Working Income Tax Benefit (WITB): a relatively small income tax credit for low income

individuals. Only one person in the family can claim it. It is not a “tax credit” as defined on

Schedule 1, but rather is a straight credit against taxes owed, so it can be more important than

it looks if income is very low.

The WITB is calculated a little differently than the description below if the recipient is disabled.

Calculate in the following way:

“Working Income” = employment or self-employment income + taxable scholarship

income.

“Adjusted Family Income” = Net Income from line 236 on the personal income tax form

(that is all income, minus deductions such as pension contributions and union dues and

the child care expense deduction).

For person with dependant or spouse

Take (Working Income −3000)x0.25

Take this amount or $1,868, whichever is less

Subtract from this 0.15[Adjusted Family Income – 16,122]

As before, the $1868 number clicks in at relatively low incomes. The WITB disappears when

Adjusted Family Income goes over $28,575.33. This tax credit is not a big player if the spouse’s

net income is above $20,000 (which itself is below what someone working full time at the

minimum wage would earn). But this credit could come into play if the mother was , and so

strangely enough (“strangely”, because the purpose of the WITB is to encourage labour force

participation), serves as a mild work disincentive for mothers with low income spouses.

4. Social Assistance (from Tweddle, Battle and Torjman, 2017). This document calculates basic

support levels for two relevant types of families– single parents with one child and two-parent

families with two children. In Ontario, social assistance is known as Ontario Works. Once the

family is eligible for social assistance, net income reduces the payment received by 50% of net

earnings above $2,400 per year. These earnings do not include the Canada Child Benefit,

Ontario Child Benefit, and the HST credit. Social assistance is paid on top of the child benefits,

and the HST and provincial tax credits.

The maximum amount for a single-parent family with one child is $19,940 (so social assistance

disappears as soon as Net Income exceeds $42,280) and the maximum amount for a couple

with two children is $27,774 (so social assistance disappears as soon as Net Income exceeds

Page 325: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

315

$57,948. Being on OW qualifies you for a full child care subsidy. Social Assistance payments

are not taxable.

5. Subsidized Housing is available to some but not all poor families. Generally there are long

waiting lists for subsidized housing. The program requires families to pay 30% of income for

housing, so there is a large “tax-back’ rate on families when the mother goes out to work.

Typically, the calculation of the 30% contribution is on available income. Subsidized housing is

available to only a small number of families.

6. HST Credit is paid automatically by Revenue Canada to eligible families using the previous

year’s net income. Currently (based on the 2016 tax year), a single parent family with one child

receives a maximum payment of $707 as long as net income is under approximately $36,429.

When income is over this amount, the benefit is reduced by 5% of the excess of net income

over $36,429. In contrast, a two-parent family with two children receives a maximum payment

of $854 as long as family net income is under $36,429. When income is over this amount, the

benefit is reduced by 5% of the excess of family net income over approximately $36,429. For

married couples, the credit is paid to the individual whose tax return is assessed first. The child

tax benefit is not included in family net income for this calculation.

7. Federal Taxes are calculated from the 2016 Federal form. Single parents with one child do

not start paying taxes until taxable income exceeds $22,948 (the personal amount of $11,474

plus the same amount for the dependent child), plus $1,161 (the employment amount) plus

whatever the total of CPP and EI contributions are. Two-parent families must be calculated

twice, once for each adult. When one spouse is not earning income, the other spouse gets

credits for the personal amount of $11,474 plus the same amount for the dependent spouse)

plus $1,161 (the employment amount) plus whatever the total of CPP and EI contributions are.

When the main caregiving parent goes out to paid work, the other parent loses her as a credit

as her net income rises. The main caregiving parent will take the CCED until her income rises

above the other parent’s, in which case he takes it.

8. Ontario Taxes are calculated from the 2016 Ontario form, and is somewhat more

complicated than the federal calculation for lower income taxpayers, both because of the

Ontario Tax Reduction and because of the separate structure of the Ontario Health Premium.

Not counting the tax reduction (see below), single parents with one child do not start paying

taxes until adjusted net income exceeds $18,511 (the personal amount of $10,011 plus $8,500

for the dependent child) plus whatever the total of CPP and EI contributions are. This means

that no taxes are generated until adjusted net income exceeds $19,629.36.

There is a tax reduction for individuals who owe very small amount of Ontario tax, but the

reduction is calculated for the parent with the higher taxable income (for a single parent with

one child, any tax owed below $658 is cancelled, and the tax reduction applies, but at a lesser

Page 326: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

316

amount, as long as taxes are less than $1,316; for a single parent with two children, any tax

owed below $1,085 is cancelled, and the tax reduction applies, but at a lesser amount, as long

as taxes are less than $2,170). For the single parent with one child, taxes are eliminated as long

as taxable income is below about $34,000, and there is a partial Ontario tax reduction until

taxable income gets above just below $45,000.

Notwithstanding the calculations above, individuals with taxable income above $20,000 will

have to pay an Ontario Health Premium (which is calculated after the tax reduction is applied).

The Health Premium is 6% of (Net Income − $20,000) for Net Income between $20,000 and

$25,000, $300 if Net Income is between $25,000 and $36,000, $300 + .06(Net Income −

$20,000) for Net Income between $36,000 and $38,500, $450 if Net Income is between $38,500

and $48,000, $450 + .25(Net Income − $48,000) for Net Income between $48,000 and $48,600,

$600 if Net Income is between $48,600 and $72,000, $600 + .25(Net Income − $72,000) for Net

Income between $72,000 and $72,600, $750 if Net Income is between $72,600 and $200,000,

$750 + .25(Net Income − $200,000) for Net Income between $200,000 and $200,600, and $900

if Net Income is over $200,600.

Two-parent families must be calculated twice, once for each adult. When one spouse is at

home, the other spouse gets credits for the personal amount of $10,011 plus $8,500 for the

dependent spouse) plus whatever the total of CPP and EI contributions are. When the main

caregiving parent goes out to paid work, the other spouse loses her as a credit as her net

income rises. The main caregiving parent takes the CCED until her income rises above the other

spouse’s, in which case he takes it.

Charts are Easier to Read Than Numbers

It is, of course, virtually impossible to read about these taxes and benefits and get a clear

picture of their implications. In Chapter 8, entitled “Different Funding Approaches – The

Evidence”, we use this information about taxes and benefits to calculate the implications for

two different family types with different numbers and ages of children. One is a lone parent

family with one child of toddler age (e.g., 24 months), facing child care fees of $17,000 annually.

The other is a two-parent family with one toddler and one preschooler (e.g., 24 months and 36

months). Assumed child care fees for these two children are $30,000 annually. The main

caregiving parent is considering whether it is worth taking paid employment. In the two-parent

family, the other spouse is assumed to be already employed and earning a gross income of

$40,000 per year. The charts in Chapter 8 are based on calculations of after-tax, after-benefit

income. Further, the net child care costs are subtracted from the main caregiving parent’s

spendable income when she enters paid employment. The charts show what percentage of her

gross income is actually made up of an increase in spendable income available to the family.

Page 327: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

317

APPENDIX E: PEOPLE WHO HELPED US

Toronto Elaine Baxter-Trahair, General Manager, Children’s Services, City of Toronto and Past-President, Ontario Municipal Social Services Association

Karen Gray, Director, Service System Planning and Policy Development, Children’s Services, City of Toronto

Nicole Warner, R.E.C.E., Program Manager, Funding Project Team, Children’s Services, City of Toronto

Shanley McNamee, Director, Strategic Business and Financial Services, Children's Services, City of Toronto

Dena Warman, Project Officer, Growth Strategy, Children’s Services, City of Toronto

West Toronto Keith Palmer, Director, Community Services, County of Dufferin

Lori-Jane del Medico, Manager, Children’s Services, County of Dufferin

Alex Sarchuk, Commissioner, Social & Community Services, Halton Region

Sandy Palinski, Director, Children’s Services, Social and Community Services Department, Region of Halton

Stephanie Houghton, Supervisor, Child Care, Children’s Services, Social and Community Services Department, Region of Halton

Suzanne Finn, Acting Director of our Early Years and Child Care Services, Region of Peel

Olivia Nunes, Manager of System Planning Early Years & Child Care Services Division, Region of Peel

Priya Rana, Project Manager, Early Years & Child Care Services Division, Region of Peel

Luisa Artuso, Director of Children’s Early Years Division, Social Services, County of Wellington and President, Ontario Municipal Social Services Association

Central Christine MacDonald, Director, Social Services and Housing, County of Bruce

Roxanne Lambert, Director of Children’s Services, Region of Durham

Barbara Arbuckle, Children's Services Manager, Grey County

Tara Cockerill, Children's Services Program Supervisor, Children’s Services, Grey County

Page 328: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

318

Janine Mitchell, Manager Social Services, Human Services, City of Kawartha Lakes.

Anne Kuipers, Program Supervisor, Children’s Services, City of Kawartha Lakes

Rick Williams, Commissioner, Community Services, District of Muskoka

Tina Kilbourne, Manager, Children’s Programs, District of Muskoka

Lesley Patterson BHEc, R.E.C.E., Manager Early Years Services, Community & Social Services, County of Northumberland

Sandra Robinson, Program Manager, Children’s Services, City of Peterborough

Greg Bishop, General Manager, County of Simcoe

Jan Janssen, Director, Children and Community Services, County of Simcoe

Dan Beale, Interim Director, Integrated Children’s Services, Social Services Branch, Community and Health Services Department, The Regional Municipality of York

Naomi Weinroth, Manager Child Care Services and Children’s Community Programs, Regional Municipality of York

Southwest Michelle O’Connor, Manager of Children’s Services and Early Years Programs, Health and Human Services, City of Brantford

Melanie Mears, Program Supervisor, Children’s Services, City of Brantford.

Kelly Emery, Director of Child Care and Early Years Division, Municipality of Chatham Kent

Chris Myers, Early Years Supervisor-Finance, Municipality of Chatham Kent

Grace Mater, Director, Children’s and Home Management Services, Community and Emergency Services Department, City of Hamilton

Dawn Meitz – Manager, Business Support, Children’s & Home Management Services Division, Community and Emergency Services Department, City of Hamilton

Chris Borst, Program Analyst (Early Years Data Analysis Coordinator), City of Hamilton

Colin McMullan – Manager, Performance, Planning & Evaluation, Children’s & Home Management Services Division, Community and Emergency Services Department, City of Hamilton

Michelle Gaynor, Social Services Manager, Huron County Social and Property Services

Diane Millian, RECE, Children's Services Supervisor, Huron County Social and Property Services

Doug Ball, Manager, Social Planning and Children's Services, County of Lambton

Lynne Livingston, Managing Director, Neighbourhood, Children and Fire Services, City of London

Page 329: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

319

Paul D’Hollander, Manager, Neighbourhood Operations, City of London

Cheryl Killip, Manager, Children’s Services Neighbourhood, Children and Fire Services

City of London

Darlene Edgar, Director, Niagara Region Children’s Services

Lori Bell, Manager, Children's Services, Community Services, Regional Municipality of Niagara

Michelle Balint, Children's Services Supervisor, County of Norfolk

Jeff Wilson, Programs and Operations Coordinator, St. Thomas Elgin Social Services - Children's Services

Barb Hobson, Manager of Children’s Services, City of Stratford

Douglas Bartholomew-Sanders, Commissioner, Community Services, Regional Municipality of Waterloo

Barb Cardow, Director, Children's Services, Regional Municipality of Waterloo

Sheri Phillips, Manager, Child Care Subsidy, Regional Municipality of Waterloo

Jelena Payne, Community Development and Health Commissioner, City of Windsor

Dawn Bosco, Manager, Children's Services, City of Windsor

Linda Higgins, Manager of Finance, Children’s Services, City of Windsor

East Kristine Greaves, RECE, Division Supervisor, Child Care Services, City of Cornwall

Christine Leoux, Child Care Program Officer, City of Cornwall

Erin Rivers, Director, Community and Human Services, Hastings County

Cathy Utman, Child Care Manager, Hastings County

Sheldon Laidman, Director, Housing and Social Services Department, City of Kingston

Laura Austin, Supervisor, Childcare & Homemaking Programs, Housing and Social Services, City of Kingston

Mary Lou White, Children’s Services Manager, County of Lanark

Pam Kent, RECE, Supervisor, Children’s Services, Prince Edward - Lennox & Addington Social Services

Jason Sabourin, Acting Manager, Children’s Services, Community and Protective Services, City of Ottawa

Page 330: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

320

Anne Comtois Lalonde, Director of Social Services, United Counties of Prescott and Russell

Judy Mulvihil, Manager, Children’s Services, County of Renfrew

Angela Picard, Intake Coordinator, Children’s Services, County of Renfrew

Amanda Kutchkoskie, Eligibility Coordinator, Licensed Home Visitor, Children’s Services, County of Renfrew

Diane Kennedy, Eligibility Coordinator, Children’s Services, County of Renfrew

North Beth Nowak, Director of Children’s Services, District of Cochrane Social Services Administration Board

Luisa Valle, Director of Children & Citizen Services, City of Greater Sudbury

Monique Poirier, Manager of Children Services, City of Greater Sudbury

Henry Wall, Chief Administrative Officer, Kenora District Services Board

Sarah Stevens, Director of Integrated Social Services, Kenora District Services Board

Fern Dominelli, Chief Administrative Officer, Manitoulin-Sudbury District Social Services Board

Joseph Bradbury, Chief Administrative Officer, Nipissing District Social Services Board

Lynn Démoré-Pitre, RECE, Director of Children’s Services, District of Nipissing Social Services Administration Board (DNSSAB)

Janet Patterson, Chief Administrative Officer, Parry Sound District Social Services Board

Cec Barks, R.E.C.E., District Program Manager, Children’s Services, Parry Sound District Social Services Board

Dan McCormick, Chief Administrative Officer, Rainy River District Social Services Board

Tanis Fretter, Integrated Services Manager, (Child Care Lead), Rainy River District Social Services Administration Board

Shelley Shute, Director of Integrated Services, Rainy River District Social Services Administration Board

Mike Nadeau, Chief Administrative Officer-Social Services, District of Sault Ste. Marie

Carla Fairbrother M.A. RECE, Manager of Early Years Services, Early Years Services Division-Social Services, District of Sault Ste. Marie

Susan Parr, Quality Assurance Coordinator - Early Years, District of Sault Ste. Marie

Don Studholme, Chief Administrative Officer, District of Temiskaming

Page 331: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

321

Dani Grenier-Ducharme, Children’s Services Manager, District of Temiskaming

William Bradica, Chief Administrative Officer, District of Thunder Bay Social Services Board

Louise Piercey, Manager, Child Care and Early Learning, District of Thunder Bay Social Services Board

Ministry of Education Shannon Fuller, Assistant Deputy Minister, Early Years Division. Ministry of Education

Maxx-Phillippe Hollott, A/Director, Financial Accountability and Data Analysis Branch, Early Years and Child Care Division, Ministry of Education

Jeff Butler, Director, Early Years and Child Care Policy, Ministry of Education

Judy Cerny, Senior Statistical/Research Analyst Early Years Outcomes and Assessments Unit, Ministry of Education

Yang Cathy Luo, Senior Statistical/Research Analyst, Financial Accountability and Data Analysis Branch, Early Years and Child Care Division, Ministry of Education

Josie Verrilli, Chief of Staff to Minister Responsible for Early Years and Child Care

James McLean, Senior Policy Advisor to Minister Responsible for Early Years and Child Care

Monica Lysack, Special Advisor to Minister Responsible for Early Years and Child Care and Professor of Early Childhood Education, Sheridan College

Kerry Smuk, Senior Policy Advisor to Minister Responsible for Early Years and Child Care

Sue Ewen, Manager, Licensing and Compliance, Child Care Quality Assurance and Licensing, Early Learning Division, Ministry of Education, West Region

Natalie Kent, Senior Program Advisor, Licensing and Compliance, Child Care Quality Assurance and Licensing, Early Years and Child Care Division, East Region

Pam Brown, Manager, Licensing and Compliance, North Region,

Abigail Dwosh, CPA, CA, Manager, Planning and Program Transformation Unit, Early Years and Child Care Programs and Service Integration Branch, Early Years and Child Care Division

Helen Kandiuk, Senior Policy and Financial Analyst, Early Years and Child Care Division,

Other Early Learning and Child Care Organizations Elisa McFarlane, Executive Director, Ontario Municipal Social Services Association

Darryl Wok, Policy Analyst, Ontario Municipal Social Services Association

Chantille Davis, Policy and Operations Coordinator, Ontario Municipal Social Services Association

Page 332: AFFORDABLE FOR ALL - Childcarepolicy.netchildcarepolicy.net/wp-content/uploads/2018/03/AFFORDABLE-FOR-A… · AFFORDABLE FOR ALL: MAKING LICENSED CHILD CARE AFFORDABLE IN ONTARIO

322

Beth Deazeley, Registrar & CEO, College of Early Childhood Educators

Cynthia Abel, RECE, Director of Registration, College of Early Childhood Educators

Melanie Dixon, RECE, Director of Professional Practice, College of Early Childhood Educators

Brandy Fong, Early Childhood Development Program Coordinator, Nipissing First Nation Health Service.

Marni Flaherty, Past Board Chair, Home Child Care Association of Ontario and Chief Executive Officer, Today's Family Early Learning and Child Care

Kim Hiscott, RECE, Board Chair, Home Child Care Association of Ontario and Executive Director, Andrew Fleck Children’s Services, Ottawa

Lyndsay Macdonald, RECE, Coordinator, Association of Early Childhood Educators of Ontario

Martha Friendly, Executive Director, Child Care Resource and Research Unit

Kerry McCuaig, Fellow in Early Childhood Policy, Atkinson Centre, Ontario Institute for Studies in Education, University of Toronto.

Jane Bertrand, Program Director for the Margaret and Wallace McCain Family Foundation and member of the Directing Committee of the Centre for Excellence for Early Childhood Development.

Laurel Rothman, Interim Coordinator, Public Policy and Government Relations, Ontario Coalition for Better Child Care

Patricia Chorney-Rubin, Director of Early Childhood Education, George Brown College

Linda Lowther, The Lowther Group, PEI

Pat Wege, Executive Director, Manitoba Child Care Association

Petr Varmuza, PhD Candidate, Dept. of Applied Psychology and Human Development, Early Learning Cohort, OISE, University of Toronto.