working-time policies in switzerland

Upload: bluefish80

Post on 03-Jun-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    1/30

    Discussion Paper No. 69

    Research Institute for Labour Economics and Labour Law

    Working-Time Policies in Switzerland: An Analysis of Desired Working

    Time, Overtime, and Hours Constraints of Swiss Salaried Employees

    Alfonso Sousa-Poza

    Department of Economics and Research Institute for Labour Economics and Labour Law at

    the University of St. Gallen, Switzerland

    Fred Henneberger

    Department of Economics and Research Institute for Labour Economics and Labour Law atthe University of St. Gallen, Switzerland,

    Department of Administrative Science, University of Konstanz, Germany

    Abstract: In this paper, desired working time, overtime, and hours constraints of Swiss salariedemployees are analysed with data from the 1998 Swiss Labour Force Survey and with data from the1997 International Social Survey Programme. It is shown that (i) most Swiss workers do not facehours constraints, when we compare the desired working time with the contractual working time; (ii)the largest portion of constrained workers would like to work less and earn less (17% of all male and22% of all female salaried employees); (iii) there is a deficit of part-time jobs for both men andwomen, especially for high-qualified individuals; (iv) men and women work on average 3.15 and 1.69hours overtime per week, respectively; the most common form of compensation for this overtime isholidays, followed by no compensation and money; (v) a comparison between actual and desiredworking time reveals that a significant amount of workers are constrained in the sense that they wouldprefer shorter actual working hours; (vi) an international comparison of desired working time showsthat workers in Switzerland are quite satisfied with their current workload/pay combination;Switzerland does, however, have the highest portion of workers wanting to work and earn less. Somepolicy implications of these findings are also discussed.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    2/30

    1

    1. Introduction

    The debate over the length of the workweek has re-entered the public sphere in most

    industrialised countries. There are two main reasons for this renewed concern: first, the

    persistent unemployment in many of these countries has led to an increased interest in "work-sharing" policies in order to distribute the available work more equitably. It is commonly

    argued that a reduction of the working time will increase the number of available jobs in an

    economy and that, thereby, unemployment can be reduced or prevented.1A second reason is

    the willingness of families to divide paid and unpaid employment more equally among family

    members. By reducing the working time, men can devote more of their time to the running of

    the household and women can participate in the labour market. In this century, working time

    has declined substantially in all industrialised countries, and, currently, the most commonly-reported workweek in OECD countries is 40 hours (see OECD, 1998a, p. 153). Nevertheless,

    this decline has slowed significantly in recent decades in almost all OECD countries (the

    exceptions being Germany, Japan, and the Netherlands). In a few countries, this decline

    appears to have stopped, while, in others, there has even been an increase in hours (most

    notably the United States). A further characteristic of the current workweek is that there has

    been a growing diversity in the hours worked by employees, with the proportion of employees

    working 40 hours having fallen considerably.

    The debate over the length of the workweek has also entered the public sphere in

    recent years in Switzerland. The largest labour union umbrella organisation, the Swiss

    Federation of Trade Unions (Schweizerische Gewerkschaftsbund, SGB) has recently launched

    a popular referendum ("Volksinitiative") for a nation-wide introduction of an upper limit of

    1872 work hours per year, which corresponds to a 36-hour workweek (see SGB, 1999,

    especially p. 27). Furthermore, this de facto reduction of the workweek would take place

    without significant changes in earnings.2At this point in time, it is difficult to judge whether

    1 The most ubiquitous examples being France and Italy, in which the normal workweek fell from 39 hours to35 hours by legislation. See also OECD (1998a), p. 174. Whether new jobs have been created or not is yetunclear. See Freeman (1998), p. 29, OECD (1998a), p. 182, and, for Germany, Henneberger (2001).Recently, the media has also reported industrial action by French truckers in protest to a reducedworkweek.

    2 According to the referendum text, all employees who earn less than 1.5 times the average wage should notface a reduction in earnings (proposed article 24, paragraph 2 of the constitution). Due to the relativeunequal distribution of income in Switzerland, this covers the largest portion of all Swiss employees.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    3/30

    2

    the voters will accept the proposals in this referendum.3The Swiss employers associations

    generally oppose such measures (see, for example, Schweizerischer Arbeitgeberverband

    (AGV), 1998; Clemmer, 1997). The Swiss Federal Railways (Schweizerische Bundesbahn,

    SBB) have also recently introduced a 39-hour workweek (as in the SGB referendum, based on

    a yearly upper limit of the working time), which meant a reduction of two hours per week for

    approximately 30,000 employees.4The Swiss Post offers a further example of how working

    time reductions are trying to be introduced in Switzerland. In a pilot project in four cantons,

    the Swiss Post is employing unemployed individuals as part of a job-sharing scheme. For

    groups of three currently employed individuals, an unemployed person is given a job, and the

    workload is divided among the four. The working time is thereby reduced by approximately

    25%.5Finally, the Swiss telecommunications company (Swisscom) has recently, as part of a

    pilot project in three cantons, introduced a four-day workweek, which corresponds to a 36-

    hour workweek.6

    There are two main reasons for this resurgent interest in working time reductions in

    Switzerland (see also Henneberger, Graf and Sousa-Poza, 1999). First, in the 1990s,

    Switzerland faced its highest levels of unemployment since the 1930s, and, therefore, "job

    sharing" policies and working time reductions have become popular again. A second reason is

    that Switzerland has one of the highest weekly and annual working times in the industrialised

    world and also one of the highest standards of living. Thus, one could argue that the marginal

    value of leisure is relatively high. In Switzerland, the most commonly reported (contractual)

    workweek is currently 42 hours followed by 40 hours per week, and these figures cover over

    70% of all employed individuals. Compared to its neighbouring countries, Switzerland

    therefore has a very long workweek.7

    3 The SGB did, however, have problems in collecting the required signatures for a referendum (see NeueZrcher Zeitung, 7th of January 1999). In fact, there even appears to be recent evidence that the SGB itselfis giving this topic less importance (seeNeue Zrcher Zeitung, 14th of January 2000).

    4 See also Neue Zrcher Zeitung, 22nd of April 1999. It is also interesting to note that the FederalGovernment has no intention of reducing the working time for its employees (see EidgenssischesPersonalamt (EPA), 1999). The Federal Government does, however, offer individual working-timereductions (see Habltzel and Rebecchi, 1998).

    5 See Graf, Henneberger and Schmid (2000), p. 45f.

    6 See also St. Galler Tagblatt, 31st of January 2000.

    7 In Italy, the most frequently reported workweek is 40 hours (covering 51% of the active labour force), in

    Austria, also 40 hours (covering 55% of the active labour force), in Germany, 38 hours (covering 32% ofthe active labour force), and, in France, 39 hours (covering 55% of the active labour force). See OECD(1998a), p. 157.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    4/30

    3

    What has received surprisingly little attention in this debate on working-time

    reductions is the preferences that workers themselves have with regard to the length of the

    workweek. This is especially the case in Switzerland.8In our opinion, however, understanding

    workers willingness to change their working time and the extent to which workers are

    constrained (i.e., for which desired working time deviates from actual working time) is a

    prerequisite in any discussion of working-time policies. In fact, since a large portion of Swiss

    voters are employed, knowing the extent to which these workers desire shorter working hours

    could give us a rough indication of how the SGB referendum will fare.9

    The general aim of this paper is to analyse Swiss employees working-time (and thus,

    earnings) preferences.10 In section 2, we first take a brief look at the characteristics of the

    Swiss labour market. In this paper, we use data from two interesting data sets: the 1998 Swiss

    Labour Force Survey (SLFS) and the 1997 International Social Survey Programme (ISSP).

    These data sets are discussed in section 3. In section 4, we take a look at contractual and

    desired working time. More specifically, we analyse the extent to which desired working time

    corresponds to the contractual working time. In section 5, we extend our analysis by

    comparing desired with actual working time where actual working time is defined as

    contractual working time plus usual overtime. In this section, we also analyse the

    determinants of overtime and the determinants of the form of compensation for overtime. In

    section 6, a cross-national comparison of hours constraints is undertaken with the ISSP data

    set. Section 7 concludes with a few policy implications of our findings.

    8 A number of studies exist that analyse desired working time in other countries (see, for example, Kahn and

    Lang, 1992 for the United States; Kahn and Lang, 1996 for Canada; Bell and Freeman, 1995 for the UnitedStates and Germany; Bundesmann-Jansen et al. 2000, Bauer et al. 1994 and 1996, Klauder, 1998 andDathe, 1998 for Germany; Sousa-Poza and Henneberger, 2000, 2001 for several countries).

    9 Although one must take into consideration that our subsequent analysis is based on reported desiredworking-time data, which assumes that changes in working time are associated with correspondingchanges in earnings. As pointed out above, the SBG referendum, however, does not, in general, foreseesuch a change.

    10 In this paper, we do not analyse the reasons for the existence of hours constraints. This is in itself animportant topic since the existence of hours constraints is often not easy to explain, and, in traditionaleconomics, they are often assumed not to exist. The interested reader is referred to Lang and Kahn (2000).

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    5/30

    4

    2. The Swiss Labour Market: An Overview

    Switzerland has recently experienced its most severe economic recession since the 1930s.

    This was most notably felt by the high level of unemployment, which reached its maximum in

    1997 with an unemployment rate of approximately 5.2%. As was mentioned above, onepotential reason for this increased interest in working-time policies could have been caused by

    this surge in unemployment (the unemployment rate in 1990 was below 1%). In table 1, a few

    summary statistics for the Swiss labour market are presented (see also Birchmeier, 2001).

    Table 1: some descriptive statistics of the Swiss labour market

    males females total

    participation ratea 87.2 71.8 79.7

    full-time employmentb(in %) 92.3 53.5

    part-time employment (in %) 7.7 46.5

    average contractual weekly working time (hours)c 40.3 29.5 35.1

    median contractual weekly working time (hours)c 42.0 34.0 41.0

    unemployment rated 2.4 3.3 2.7

    median income (SFr. per year; gross)e 71,500 54,600 66,000

    a1999; as a percentage of individuals between the age of 15 and 64bdefined as at least 30 hours working time per week (1999)cbased on the 1998 SLFS (own calculations); only employees who work at least one hour per week and are at

    least 15 years old.d1999e1998Sources: 1998 SLFS, Bundesamt fr Statistik (1999a), OECD (2000), Staatssekretariat fr Wirtschaft (2001)

    The Swiss labour market also has, compared to other industrialised countries, a few unique

    characteristics:

    It has the highest participation rate in Europe. In 1999, for example, about 80% ofindividuals between the age of 15 and 64 were employed. In the European Union (EU),

    the corresponding figure was approximately 63% (see OECD, 2000).

    The female participation rate (defined as a percentage of all females between the age of 15and 64) is also remarkably high with a rate in 1999 of about 72%. The corresponding EUaverage was only 53% (see OECD, 2000).

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    6/30

    5

    As was mentioned above, Switzerland has one of the longest workweeks in Europe andalso the highest annual working time, i.e., if one includes vacations and public holidays

    (see IW, 1999, p. 153).

    Another interesting characteristic is that the Swiss labour force has a very high portion ofpart-time jobs. In Europe, only Holland has a higher portion (see Schaufelberger, 1997,

    OECD, 2000).

    Switzerland also has very few labour disputes and, in an international setting, very fewlost days due to strikes (see IW, 1999, p. 154).

    According to the OECD, Switzerland has the third highest disposable GDP per capitaamong 29 industrialised countries (see OECD, 1998b).

    3. Data

    In order to analyse employeesworking-time preferences in Switzerland, we use data from the

    Swiss Labour Force Survey (SLFS). The SLFS is a nation-wide, representative survey

    conducted annually by the Swiss Federal Statistical Office (Bundesamt fr Statistik, BFS).

    During telephone interviews lasting approximately 20 minutes, individuals (including

    foreigners) are questioned on a number of labour-market related topics. The first SLFS surveywas conducted in 1991, and the sample size is approximately 16,000 individuals (see BFS,

    1996). One of the advantages of the SLFS, in the context of this study, is that it has very

    precise information on desired working time. The wording of the relevant question, posed to

    all currently employedindividuals11, is as follows: "How many hours per week would you like

    to work assuming that your wage is adjusted proportionally?" One drawback of this data,

    however, is that not all workers were posed this question. More specifically, the following

    workers were not set this precise question: (i) employees who work full-time and would not

    prefer to work part-time; (ii) certain part-time workers who would like to work full-time. In

    the former case, it was assumed that these full-time workers are not constrained, i.e., their

    actual working time corresponds to their desired working time, and, in the latter case, these

    part-time employees were assumed to want to work 42 hours per week. Naturally, assuming

    that these full-time workers are not constrained need not always apply, since they may, for

    11 An analysis of hours constraints faced by non-employed individuals would also merit investigation. Thiswould especially be interesting for women since it is often claimed that (frequently well-qualified) women

    remain non-employed due to the fact that there is a deficiency of part-time jobs in the economy.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    7/30

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    8/30

    7

    Data on desired working time do have some problematic characteristics. The main

    problem with such data is that they are based on hypothetical questions. As with most such

    subjective data, one could question its reliability and validity. It should, however, be noted

    that there is ample evidence that such data is not purely "noise", i.e., it correlates with

    observable actions such as job mobility and labour supply (see, for example, Ham, 1982;

    Altonji and Paxson, 1986; Euwals, 1999). In section 5, we do discuss some problematic

    aspects of the SLFS data on desired working time.

    4. Desired vs. Contractual Working Time in 1998

    Table 2 depicts the portion of salaried employees in 1998 that would like to change theircontractual working time, and also the extent of the desired change. As can be seen, however,

    the large majority of workers do not face hours constraints (81.4% and 64.3% of males and

    females, respectively). Of those workers that are constrained, the majority would like to work

    less and earn less. This is especially the case in the male sample.

    Table 2: portion of workers wanting to change their contractual working time in 1998 and to what extent

    > 10 hrs less

    per week

    6-10 hrs less

    per week

    1-5 hrs less

    per week

    not

    constrained

    1-5 hrs more

    per week

    6-10 hrs more

    per week

    > 10 hrs more

    per week

    no. obs.

    males 3.9% 9.0% 3.6% 81.4% 0.7% 0.6% 0.7% 4095

    females 5.0% 9.3% 7.8% 64.3% 6.0% 3.6% 3.9% 3727

    total 4.4% 9.2% 5.6% 73.3% 3.2% 2.1% 2.2% 7822

    The relationship between desired and contractual working time is shown in figures 1 to 3. In

    figures 1 and 2, distributions of desired and contractual working time are plotted for females

    and males, respectively. These figures clearly show that women are more constrained than

    men, and the most predominant difference is the "excess demand" of jobs ranging from 15 to

    38 hours per week.15This is most notably the case for women working between 20 and 38

    hours per week. In figure 2, one notes that mens desired working time mirrors their

    contractual working time remarkably well. There is, however, a notable difference between

    15 It is interesting to note that, despite the fact that women are less satisfied with thier working-time/wagecombination, they often have higher job-satisfaction levels than men. This is also the case for Switzerland

    (see Sousa-Poza and Sousa-Poza, 2000).

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    9/30

    8

    desired and contractual working time in the male sample at around 30 to 38 hours per week.

    More specifically, the desire to work 30 to 38 hours per week is more common than the

    number of contracts offered in this range.

    Figure 1: distribution of contractual and desired working time for women

    contractual/desired working time (hrs./week)

    5651464136312621161161

    percent

    20

    10

    0

    contractual working

    desired working time

    The fact that, in both the male and female samples, there is an apparent deficiency of part-

    time jobs does speak in favour of the often-proposed introduction of flexible part-time work

    with a work rate varying between 70% and 90% of a full-time job (and with an appropriate

    adjustment of the hourly wage rate). In a survey conducted by the State Secretariat for

    Economic Affairs (Staatssekretariat fr Wirtschaft, seco), about 57% of all Swiss firms have a

    good opinion of such flexible part-time contracts (see Blum and Zaugg, 1998, p. 180).

    Although there still appears to be a deficiency of part-time jobs, there has, in the past years,

    been a gradual increase in the number of offered part-time jobs. In 1999, approximately

    41,000 new part-time jobs were created, approximately 60% of which are occupied by women

    (see BFS, 1999b, p. 40 and BFS, 1998, p. 38).16As was mentioned above, Switzerland has, in

    an international comparison, one of the largest portions of part-time jobs (see Schaufelberger,

    1997).

    16 The fact that about 40% of the new part-time jobs were filled by men is an interesting observation.Between 1997 and 1998 the corresponding figure was only 20%.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    10/30

    9

    Figure 2: distribution of contractual and desired working time for men

    contractual/desired working time (hrs./week)

    5651464136312621161161

    percent

    40

    30

    20

    10

    0

    contractual working

    desired working time

    In figure 3, the difference between desired and contractual working time is plotted. In the

    female sample, we observe that the desire to work more than is foreseen in the contract is

    most pronounced at weekly working hours below 26 hours, whereas the desire to work less is

    most favoured by women who work between 36 and 46 hours per week. It also appears to be

    the case that women who work less than about 10 hours per week are the most likely to want

    to work more. The same applies to women who have an actual working time between 17 and

    25 hours per week. In the male sample, the difference between the contractual and desired

    working time more or less fluctuates around zero. Only males working more than 38 hours

    per week seem to prefer being employed a few hours less.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    11/30

    10

    Figure 3: differences between contractual and desired working time for men and women

    contractual working time (hrs./week)

    4946434037343128252219161310741

    desired-contractualworkingtime(hrs./week)

    8

    6

    4

    2

    0

    -2

    -4

    -6

    -8

    males

    females

    In order to analyse the determinants of hours constraints in a multivariate way, we estimate

    regressions for males and females. In table 3, the results of an ordered probit model are

    presented, for which the dependent variable can take on seven possible values corresponding

    to the categorisation in table 2, i.e., 0for workers wanting to work more than 10 hours less

    per week, up to 6for workers wanting to work more than 10 hours more per week. Thus, this

    variable captures the magnitude and direction of hours constraints among employees. Several

    independent variables are included in the regressions: six demographic variables, five

    working-time characteristics, three other work-related characteristics, and twelve dummy

    variables characterising different sectors.17

    17 Since, in Switzerland (as in many other industrialised countries), working conditions are negotiated on a

    sectoral level, the inclusion of the twelve dummy variables captures sector-specific differences. For thesake of clarity, however, the estimated coefficients for these variables have been omitted in the subsequent

    tables.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    12/30

    11

    Table 3: determinants of hours constraints - estimated coefficients and marginal effects of the ordered probitmodel

    males females

    coef. MEb

    coef. MEb

    constant 3.135** 1.541**

    demographic variables

    marrieda

    0.042 0.008 0.023 0.002

    childrena 0.067 0.013 0.268** 0.023high educationa -0.232** -0.047 -0.153** -0.013

    low educationa

    0.262** 0.052 0.107* 0.009

    age10-1 -0.680** -0.136 -0.027 -0.002

    age210-3 0.769** 0.200 0.156 0.122

    working-time characteristics

    works on weekenda

    0.081 0.016 0.013 0.001

    works at nighta 0.014 0.028 0.081 0.007

    works block timesa

    -0.076 -0.015 -0.090 -0.008

    flexible working timesa

    0.034 0.007 0.286** 0.024

    works shifts

    a

    -0.038 -0.008 -0.097 -0.008other work-related characteristics

    tenure 0.009 0.002 -0.021** -0.002

    tenure210-3 -0.068 -0.123 0.255** 0.212

    is in managementa -0.049 -0.010 -0.189** -0.016

    small firm (< 100 employees)a -0.013 -0.003 -0.064 -0.005

    number of observations 4037 3670

    log likelihood -2784 -4428

    pseudo-R2

    0.026c

    0.034c

    Note: The dependent variable can have seven possible values ranging from "work more than 10 hours lessper

    week" to "work more than 10 hours moreper week" (see also table 2). Furthermore, the regressions included

    twelve dummy variables for different sectors, which, for the sake of clarity, are not presented here. The reference

    industry is the banking and insurance sector.adummy variables

    bME = marginal effect calculated at a score equal to 3cthe pseudo-R2measure is that of McFadden (1973)

    */** significant at the 5%/1% level, respectively

    Besides presenting the estimated coefficients, we also show the marginal effects calculated at

    a score equal to 3.18 These marginal effects therefore show the effect that an explanatory

    variable has on the probability of being unconstrained. In the male sample, one notes that, in

    general, middle-aged men with a high education19would most likely want to work less than

    they are contractually required to. The relationship between the dependent variable and age is

    18 The marginal effects (calculated at the sample means) are defined as follows:[ ]

    ( ) =

    x

    x

    xyE, and

    where is the standard normal probability density function.

    19 Degrees from the following institutions were considered to be "high education": university, technical

    college ("hhere Fachschule", "Technikon"), and high school ("Matura", "Diplommittelschule"). Thefollowing categories were considered to be "low education": no degree (i.e., still in compulsory schooling),

    only compulsory schooling, and lower apprenticeship schemes ("Anlehre", "Haushaltslehrjahr"). The

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    13/30

    12

    a parabolic one, with its minimum at around 44 years. Thus, as age increases to 44 years, the

    probability that individuals report wanting to work less than they are contractually required to

    increases; thereafter the probability declines again.20Stated somewhat differently, men in this

    age group are, ceteris paribus, the most willing to reduce their working time. Men with a low

    education are generally more likely to report wanting to work more, and the marginal effect

    shows that these individuals are less constrained than workers with a medium education

    (reference group). Women with a high education, women with higher tenure21, and women in

    management positions22have a tendency to prefer to work less. Women with children, women

    with a low education, and women with flexible working times prefer to work more than

    stipulated in their contract.23A look at the marginal effects also reveals that these women

    have a lower probability of being constrained. It is, therefore, interesting to note that women

    with flexible working times are less constrained than women who do not have the freedom to

    regulate their working times. This is a result that one could expect. The level of education has

    the same effects as in the male sample; the magnitude of these effects is, however, much

    smaller in the female sample. The coefficients of the education variables thus imply that there

    is a deficiency of part-time jobs for high-qualified individuals, especially among males.24 It

    should finally be noted that the explanatory power of these models is quite small, implying

    that a large degree of variation remains unexplained. This is a standard result in these kinds of

    models.

    reference category was primarily made up of apprenticeships ("Berufslehre") and similar qualifications

    ("Vollzeitberufsschule", "hhere Berufsausbildung").

    20 The marginal effects show, on the other hand, that the probability of not being constrained is at itsminimum at around 34 years of age, i.e., men in this age group are most likely to be contrained.

    21 The underlying question for the tenure variable is as follows: "How many years have you been working foryour current employer?"

    22 The management-position variable is defined rather broadly. The exact wording is: "Do you have amanagement position?". About 20% of the female sample has such a position.

    23 The survey question associated with the variable "flexible working times" is worded as follows: "How areyour working times regulated in your main job?" The respondents then had three options: (i) fixed working

    times; (ii) block working times ("gleitende Arbeitszeit"); (iii) fully flexible working times. Totally flexible

    working times imply that the employee can plan his or her own working day. Running working times

    imply that the worker has to be in his or her office at certain times of the day (e.g., between 8 and 10 in the

    morning). Fixed working times are the most common and imply that the worker cannot, in any way, choose

    his or her daily working time.

    24 In a study on women's working-time preferences in Germany it is shown that there also exists a deficiency

    of part-time jobs for high-qualified individuals. See Beckmann and Kempf (1996).

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    14/30

    13

    We can therefore conclude this section by stating that: (i) the overwhelming majority

    of both male and female workers appears to be satisfied with their contractual working time;

    (ii) there seems to be a deficit of part-time jobs for women, especially for jobs with around 20

    hours per week; (iii) there is a deficiency of part-time jobs for high-qualified individuals and

    part-time jobs in the range between 30 and 38 hours per week; (iv) women with very low

    contractual working times (especially less than 10 hours per week) would like to work more;

    (v) a few socio-economic and demographic variables have an influence on hours constraints,

    most notably the level of education: especially middle-aged men with a high education as well

    as highly qualified women prefer working less than they are contractually obliged to. The

    contrary seems to apply to individuals, most notably women, at lower working-time levels,

    which, in turn, are associated with lower income levels.

    5. Desired vs. Actual Working Time in 1998: The Role of Overtime

    In the above discussion, we analysed the relationship between contractual and desired

    working time. Our daily experience tells us, however, that actual working time may deviate

    from contractual working time since most employees work non-trivial amounts of overtime.

    In table 4, overtime statistics for Swiss salaried employees in 1998 are presented.25

    Table 4: overtime in 1998 - summary statistics (hours per week)

    no. obs.a

    mean standard deviation Total hours per

    week

    males 3782 3.15 4.60 4365994

    females 3416 1.69 3.27 1802365

    total 7198 2.47 4.10 6168359

    abased on the whole sample, i.e., including employees that do no overtime

    As can be seen, men work, on average, more overtime hours than women (3.15 compared to

    1.69 hours per week).26Taken over the whole population, men (women) work approximately

    25 The wording of the relevant question is as follows: "Taken over the past 12 months, how many hours perweek did you work in excess of the number of hours stipulated in your contract?" Thus, this variable

    measures the overtime usually worked in a week (and not necessarily the actual overtime worked in, say,

    the previous week).

    26 A total of 56% of all salaried employees do overtime work on a regular basis (males 65% and females47%). These results show that, on average, the demand of the SGB referendum to limit the number of

    overtime hours to 100 per year is, currently, clearly not being met. According to a recent representative

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    15/30

    14

    4.4 (1.8) million hours overtime per week. Thus, in total, over 300 million hours overtime are

    performed each year (based on 1998 data). It therefore comes as no surprise that overtime

    plays an important role in any discussion on working time policies.

    Overtime, however, can take on many different forms. In general, one can distinguish

    between "transitional" overtime, which is compensated with additional free time, and

    "permanent" overtime which is paid out or not compensated in any way. In table 5, we show

    the form of compensation for overtime. A total of 59.8% (57.9%) of all males (females) that

    usually do overtime get compensation in the form of additional holidays. Only 10.6% (16.8%)

    of males (females) receive payment for their overtime. Finally, 29.6% (25.3%) of males

    (females) received no compensation. It is interesting to note that forms of compensation differ

    between genders: males are more likely than females to receive no compensation or

    compensation in the form of free time, whereas females are more likely than males to receive

    payment for their overtime.27 These differences between genders are, needless to say,

    primarily a result of segregated labour markets.

    Table 5: forms of compensation for overtime in 1998 - summary statistics

    no.

    obs.a

    percentage hours per week

    none money holidays none money holidays

    males 2454 29.6% 10.6% 59.8% 6.50 5.70 3.82

    females 1610 25.3% 16.8% 57.9% 4.44 3.96 3.06

    total 4064 27.9% 13.1% 59.0% 5.76 4.81 3.52

    abased on a sample of salaried employees that reported their form of compensation and usually do overtime

    In table 5, we also depict the average number of hours overtime according to the different

    forms of compensation. We note that, in both the male and the female samples, employees

    that do not get compensation for their overtime also work more overtime than workers who

    get some form of compensation. Another interesting result is that, although women are morelikely to receive paid compensation, they, on average, work less overtime than the

    corresponding group of men (3.96 as opposed to 5.70 hours per week). Figure 4 depicts the

    distribution of overtime according to gender. Compared to men, a larger portion of women do

    study for Germany, a strikingly similar result was obtained, i.e., 56% of all employees are confronted with

    regular overtime (see Gro/Munz, 1999).

    27 Below we show that primarily white collar workers do unpaid overtime. Thus, it comes as no surprise thatfemales are more likely to receive payment for their overtime. Note, however, that, on average, women

    work less paid overtime than men. This can easily be deduced from the results in tables 4 and 5.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    16/30

    15

    shorter overtime hours per week. Men, on the other hand, are more likely to spend longer

    hours per week on overtime.

    Figure 4: distribution of overtime for men and women

    overtime (hrs./week)

    423020151050

    percent

    60

    50

    40

    30

    20

    10

    0

    males

    females

    In table 6, we present the results of probit and tobit regressions. In the case of the probit

    model, a dichotomous dependent variable is used with a value equal to 0if the respondent

    does not usually work overtime and equal to 1otherwise. Thus, these regressions reflect the

    determinantsof doing overtime. In the case of the tobitmodel, the dependent variable has a

    value equal to 0 if the respondent does no overtime and equal to the number of overtime

    hours usually done per week otherwise. These regressions show how the numberof overtime

    hours is affected by the explanatory variables. We have used the same explanatory variables

    as in the regressions of the previous section.28Furthermore, and for the sake of clarity, we

    only present the marginal effects (calculated at sample means) here.

    28 As in the above analysis, these regressions also included twelve dummy variables for different sectors.

    Although we do not present the results here, one interesting observation is that workers in the banking and

    insurance sector have a relatively high probability of working long overtime hours and also have a high

    probability of wanting to work less than contractually required to (relative to other industries). One

    possible explanation is that firms in these sectors often try to recruit very productive workers, and they doso by offering relatively high wages together with long required working times (especially overtime). This

    topic is analysed in Sousa-Poza and Ziegler (2001).

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    17/30

    16

    Taking a look at the probit results first we note that men with a high education, men

    that have block or flexible working times, and men in management positions are likely to do

    overtime. Men with a low education have a higher probability of not doing overtime. The age-

    overtime function for men is a parabolic one with its maximum at around 31 years. Thus,

    younger employees are primarily affected by overtime. The determinants of overtime in the

    female sample are very similar to those in the male sample with the exception that marriage

    and the presence of children reduce the probability of doing overtime. This result reflects the

    much-cited observation that women are primarily responsible for household tasks and child-

    care (see, for Switzerland, Sousa-Poza et al., 2001).

    Table 6: the determinants of overtime - marginal effects of the probit and tobit models

    probit tobit

    males females males females

    demographic variables

    marrieda 0.009 -0.059** 0.088 -0.247**

    childrena -0.011 -0.116** -0.014 -0.605**

    high educationa

    0.056** 0.025** 0.874** 0.208*

    low educationa

    -0.225** -0.149** -1.547** -0.676**

    age10-1 0.144** 0.193** 0.120** 0.112**

    age210-3 -0.227** -0.283** -1.160** -1.152**

    working-time characteristics

    works on weekenda

    -0.009 0.027 0.429* 0.183

    works at nighta -0.014 -0.023 0.309 0.005

    works block timesa 0.179** 0.168** 0.964** 0.520**

    flexible working times

    a

    0.086** 0.009 1.325** 0.222works shiftsa

    0.060 0.026 0.225 -0.138

    other work-related characteristics

    tenure 0.001 0.003 0.002 -0.001

    tenure210-3 0.044 -0.008 0.249 0.363is in managementa 0.220** 0.225** 1.852** 1.061**

    small firm (< 100 employees)a

    0.021 0.003 0.044 -0.059

    sigma 4.883** 4.515**

    number of observations 3775 3412 3775 3412

    log likelihood -2150 -2102 -8312 -5738

    pseudo-R2

    0.122b

    0.109b

    0.211c

    0.171c

    Note: The dependent variable in the probit model has a value equal to 0if the respondent does not usually workovertime and equal to 1otherwise. In the case of the tobit model, the dependent variable has a value equal to 0if the respondent does no overtime and equal to the number of overtime hours usually done per week

    otherwise.The regressions include a constant and twelve dummy variables for different sectors. Only the

    marginal effects are depicted here.adummy variablesbthe pseudo-R

    2measure is that of McFadden (1973)

    c the pseudo-R2measure is that of McKelvey and Zavoina (1975)

    */** significant at the 5%/1% level, respectively

    The results of the tobit model show how the independent variables affect the length of

    overtime work. We note that men with a high education work about 52 minutes more

    overtime per week than workers in the reference group, whereas men with a low education

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    18/30

    17

    work about one and a half hours less overtime per week. A further interesting result is that

    men with flexible working times work approximately one hour and 20 minutes more overtime

    per week than individuals that have fixed working times. As one would expect, the effect of

    having a management position is very strong: managers work nearly two hours more overtime

    per week than workers without a management position. The results are similar in the female

    sample with the exception of the marriage and child coefficients.

    As was shown above, there are different forms of compensation for overtime work. In

    order to establish the determinants of the form of compensation for overtime, we estimate

    multinomial logit functions for both males and females. The dependent variable can have

    three possible values, depending on the form of compensation. The summarised results are

    presented in table 7. The marginal effects of these multinomial logits are presented in table A

    in the appendix. In order to keep things simple, we only select some of the most interesting

    variables for the exposition in table 7.

    Table 7: determinants of the form of compensation for overtime (results of the multinomial logit model)

    none holidays money

    males - high education

    - works on weekend- does not have block

    times

    - flexible working times

    - does not work shifts

    - in management

    - does not have a high

    education- does not work on

    weekend

    - does not work at night

    - works block times

    - does not have flexible

    working times

    - works shifts

    - not in management

    - low education

    - not middle aged

    a

    - works on weekend

    - works at night

    - flexible working times

    - not in management

    females - high education

    - elder workers

    - works at night

    - does not have block

    times- does not work shifts

    - in management

    - does not have a high

    education

    - younger workersb

    - single

    - no children- does not work at night

    - works block times

    - works shifts

    - have high tenure

    - in management

    - low education

    - older workers

    - married

    - children

    - works at night- does not have block

    times

    - flexible working times

    - does not have high

    tenurec

    - not in management

    Note: Some stylised results which are based on the estimates of the multinomial logits presented in table A in the

    appendix.ais a parabolic function with its minimum at around 42 years of agebis a parabolic function with its maximum at around 26 years of age

    cis a parabolic function with its minimum at around 43 years of age

    As can be seen in table 7, several factors influence the form of compensation. In fact, the

    picture presented here is that the determinants of the form of compensation are complex, and

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    19/30

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    20/30

    19

    primarily affect blue-collar workers. A similar argument may apply for men who work on

    weekends. On the one hand, such men could be white-collar workers (and thus tend to receive

    no compensation for overtime) who have a fair amount of autonomy with regard to the

    planing of their workweek or, on the other hand, these are primarily blue-collar workers that

    have to work on weekend (and thus tend to receive compensation for their overtime). The

    same reasoning applies to women who work at night. Thus, once again, the picture presented

    here is a complex one with a certain degree of heterogeniety in groups of individuals

    receiving a specific form of compensation. Perhaps the only stylised fact which can be made

    is that white collar workers are the most likely to receive no compensation for overtime and

    blue collar workers are more likely to get compensation in the form of money or holidays.

    As we pointed out in the comparison above between desired and contractual working

    time, most workers are satisfied with their contractual working time (see section 4). It

    therefore comes as no surprise that the number of constrained workers increases substantially

    when we analyse actual working time, actual working time being defined as contractual

    working time plus overtime. Figures 5 and 6compare actual with desired working time. As

    can be seen in both the male and the female samples, the distribution of the actual working

    time curve has become flatter with a larger tail in the upper end, i.e., a large portion of the

    distribution has shifted toward the higher hours. Thus, these figures reveal that actual working

    time is, in general, too long. More specifically, the predominant desire to work approximately

    40 to 42 hours per week is not being fulfilled, i.e., a substantial portion of employees work

    more than 42 hours per week. Taken at face value, these results would imply that hours

    constraints can be reduced by decreasing the number of overtime hours worked. This, in fact,

    is often demanded by unions (see SGB, 1999, p. 27).

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    21/30

    20

    Figure 5: distribution of actual and desired working time for women

    actual/desired working time (hrs./week)

    5651464136312621161161

    percent

    20

    10

    0

    desired working time

    actual working time

    Figure 6: distribution of actual and desired working time for men

    actual/desired working time

    5651464136312621161161

    percent

    40

    30

    20

    10

    0

    desired working time

    actual working time

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    22/30

    21

    At this stage, however, a word of caution needs to be included. Based on the available data, it

    is not clear to what extent the reported desired working time refers to the contractual or the

    actual working time. Although the wording of the question would make us assume that the

    respondents mean desired actual and not desired contractual working time, this need not

    always be the case. It is conceivable that respondents did not explicitly take overtime into

    consideration when reporting their desired (actual) working time. Stated somewhat

    differently: if some respondents reported desired contractualworking time instead of desired

    actual working time and if these two responses are different in the sense that the former

    explicitly excludes overtime, then one does face a problem.32In such a case,figures 5 and 6

    are potentially flawed since they would be comparing desired contractual with actual working

    time. Unfortunately, the only way to solve this problem would be by stating a more precise

    question in the survey. In any case, the analysis in this section does show that the nature of

    overtime plays a very important role in the design of working time policies. Furthermore, it

    does not change our conclusion from section 3, namely that there does not appear to be much

    leeway for a collective reduction of the workweek below 40 hours.33

    Thus, we can conclude this section by stating that: (i) a fair amount of overtime is

    performed each week and that the most common form of compensation for overtime is

    holidays; (ii) a substantial amount of overtime work is not compensated in any form and only

    a small portion is actually paid out; (iii) women are more likely to receive payment for

    overtime than men; (iv) no compensation for overtime is most probable among white collar

    workers, whereas blue-collar workers have a higher probability of obtaining paid

    compensation; (v) if one compares actual working time with desired working time, then one

    notes that a large discrepancy between the most common desired weekly working time of

    between 40 and 42 hours and actual working time exists. Thus, overtime would appear to

    increase the number of constrained workers, in the sense that these workers would like to

    work less.

    32 Desired actual and desired contractual working times are only equivalent if a respondent does not want towork overtime.

    33 A further possible problem with a comparison of desired with actual working time is that, as pointed outabove, a substantial portion of overtime is compensated by free time. It is difficult to judge the extent to

    which this additional free time is taken into consideration when reporting desired working time. Thus, therelationship between contractual working time, desired working time, overtime, and the form of

    compensation for overtime is quite complex and cannot be clearly interpreted with the available data.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    23/30

    22

    6. An International Comparison of Desired Working Time

    As was pointed out in section 2, with regard to the weekly working time, Switzerland is

    somewhat of an exception since it has one of the longest workweeks in Western Europe and

    one of the highest in the industrialised world (see, OECD, 1998a). It is therefore interesting to

    see how hours constraints in Switzerland differ from those in other countries. In order to do

    this we analyse the latest Work Orientations data from the 1997 ISSP (see section 3 above).

    We analyse a sample of workers in 14 industrialised countries. In figure 7, the portion of

    workers wanting to work less and earn less, work the same and earn the same, and work more

    and earn more are depicted. A first interesting result is that the extent of hours constraints is

    relatively small. Furthermore, in most countries, the portion of workers wanting to work more

    and earn more is larger than the portion of workers wanting to work less and earn less. Onlyin three countries is this not the case: Denmark, Norway, and Switzerland. Of all the

    countries considered here, Switzerland has the largest portion of workers wanting to work less

    and earn less. This could be a result of the relatively high income in Switzerland and long

    working hours which could give rise to a higher marginal value of leisure. 34 In figure 8, a

    ranking of the degree of hours constraints is shown. As can be seen, Switzerland is ranked

    fourth out of the 14 countries analysed here. Approximately 70% of all Swiss employees

    reported no hours constraints. Thus, in an international comparison, Swiss workers appear to

    be quite satisfied with their current workload/pay combination. This is an interesting result if

    one considers that Swiss employees work relatively long working hours. Furthermore, this

    outcome confirms the results obtained with data from the SLFS (see section 4).35

    34 This in itself, however, does not explain why these employees should be constrained. Sousa-Poza and

    Ziegler (2001) provide a possible explanation as to why employees may work inefficient long hours in the

    sense that they work more than they would like to.

    35 The results are, in fact, strikingly similar. Since both surveys use somewhat different questions, thissimilarity does provide some support for the reliability of the results presented above. Another similar

    result was obtained by a survey conducted in October 1998 by the GfS-Research Institute. In this survey, a

    total of 641 Swiss workers were asked whether they would like to work more, work less, or work the sameamount (no reference was made to earnings). 65% said that they were satisfied and 23% reported

    overemployment. See GfS (1998).

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    24/30

    23

    Figure 7: hours constraints by country

    0%

    20%

    40%

    60%

    80%

    100%

    Denmark

    France

    Germany

    GreatBritain

    Italy

    Japan

    Netherlands

    NewZealand

    Norway

    Portugal

    Spain

    Sweden

    Switzerland

    UnitedStates

    work less and earn less work the same and earn the same work more and earn more

    Source: Based on Sousa-Poza and Henneberger (2001)

    Figure 8: ranking by country according to the percent of unconstrained workers

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    70%

    80%

    Denmark

    Norway

    GreatBritain

    Switzerland

    Netherlands

    Germany

    Sweden

    France

    NewZealand

    Spain

    Japan

    Italy

    UnitedStates

    Portugal

    Source: Based on Sousa-Poza and Henneberger (2001)

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    25/30

    24

    7. Conclusions

    Workers desired working time, workers hours constraints, overtime, and the form of

    compensation of this overtime are fundamental aspects in the development of working-time

    policies. Yet, these issues have received surprisingly little attention in the current working-

    time debate in Switzerland. The aim of this paper is to present a number of empirical results

    on these topics. With data from the 1998 Swiss Labour Force Survey and with data from the

    1997 International Social Survey Programme we show that:

    Most Swiss workers (81% and 64% of all salaried males and females, respectively) do notface hours constraints when we compare the desired working time with the contractual

    working time. The largest portion of constrained workers would like to work less and earn

    less (17% of males and 22% of females). There does appear to be a deficit of part-time jobs for both men and women. This deficit is

    most pronounced for women who would like to work around 20 hours per week, and also

    for men and women with a high education (i.e., there is a deficit of high-qualification part-

    time jobs).

    Women with very short contractual working hours (less than about 10 hours per week)generally would prefer working more and earning more.

    Men and women with a high education are more likely to want to work less and earn less,whereas the opposite applies to workers with a low education. Women who have flexible

    working times are less likely to be constrained.

    Men and women work on average 3.15 and 1.69 hours overtime per week, respectively.The most common form of compensation for this overtime is holidays, followed by no

    compensation and money. Women are much more likely to receive paid compensation

    than men.

    Men and women with a high education and who have a management position arepredominantly affected by overtime. Furthermore, it is primarily such workers who

    receive no compensation for their overtime.

    Young, single women with no children are likely to get compensation in the form ofholidays, whereas elder, married women, with children have a higher probability of

    getting paid compensation for overtime.

    A comparison between actual and desired working time, where actual working time isdefined as contractual working time plus overtime, reveals that a significant amount of

    workers are constrained in the sense that they would prefer shorter actual working hours.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    26/30

    25

    An international comparison of desired working time reveals that workers in Switzerlandare quite satisfied with their current workload/pay combination (Switzerland ranks fourth

    out of the 14 industrialised countries analysed here). Switzerland does, however, have the

    highest portion of workers wanting to work (and earn) less out of all the 14 countries.

    In the light of the current working-time debate in Switzerland, most notably the

    referendum launched by the SGB, which foresees the introduction of a de factoworkweek of

    36 hours and a mandatory upper limit of 100 hours overtime per year, our analysis could

    suggest the following:

    Our results show quite clearly that the 42 and 40-hour workweek is preferred by anoverwhelming majority of employees. Thus, one could at least question the optimality of a

    nation-wide reduction of the workweek by, on average, four to six hours per week.

    Naturally, the extent to which earnings change plays an important role in such a

    conclusion. If a reduction of the workweek leaves earnings unaffected (something which

    is questionable), then this conclusion obviously needs to be put into perspective.

    If working-time policies at least partially aim at reducing the number of constrainedindividuals, then an increase in part-time jobs and a reduction of overtime is

    recommendable. Our results show that there is a deficiency of part-time jobs for high-

    qualified individuals and also part-time jobs in the range between 30 and 38 hours per

    week. The fact that Switzerland has the largest portion of workers wanting to work less

    and earn less out of the 14 industrialised countries analysed in this paper reinforces this

    conclusion.

    The determinants of hours constraints, overtime, and the form of compensation ofovertime are quite complex. This is primarily due to the high and, to a large extent,

    unobservable heterogeneity of working time preferences between and within different

    groups of employees. As a result, individual (as opposed to collective) working-time

    regulations would seem to be more appropriate. The fact that the goodness-of-fit of the

    above regressions is relatively low implies that a high degree of variability exists, i.e.,

    hours constraints appear to be quite randomly distributed among the underlying

    population, and, thus, the variability of hours constraints cannot be well explained by the

    numerous regressors implemented here. Hours constraints therefore are largely affected

    by unobservable factors such as personality, motivation, etc. Collective working-time

    regulations, by nature, cannot adequately capture this heterogeneity. Therefore, individual

    agreements - perhaps on the basis of a shorter averageworkweek - seem better suited to

    reduce workershours constraints and generally improve their well-being at work.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    27/30

    26

    References

    Altonji, J.G./Paxson, C.H. (1986), "Job characteristics and Hours of Work", in: Ehrenberger,

    R. (ed.), "Research in Labor Economics", Vol. 8, Greenwich, Westview Press, 1-55.

    Bauer, F./Gro, H./Schilling, G. (1994), "Arbeitszeit '93. Arbeitszeiten, Arbeitszeitwnsche,Zeitbewirtschaftung und Arbeitszeitgestaltungschancen von abhngig Beschftigten",Resultate einer aktuellen Reprsentativbefragung bei abhngig Beschftigten inWestdeutschland durch das Institut zur Erforschung sozialer Chancen, Kln, im Auftragdes Ministeriums fr Arbeit, Gesundheit und Soziales des Landes Nordrhein-Westfalen,Bruns, Minden.

    Bauer, F./Gro, H./Schilling, G. (1996), "Arbeitszeit '95. Arbeitszeitstrukturen, Arbeitszeit-wnsche und Zeitverwendung der abhngig Beschftigten in West- und Ostdeutsch-land", Resultate einer aktuellen Reprsentativbefragung bei abhngig Beschftigten inWest- und Ostdeutschland durch das Institut zur Erforschung sozialer Chancen, Kln,im Auftrag des Ministeriums fr Arbeit, Gesundheit und Soziales des Landes Nord-

    rhein-Westfalen, Neusser, Neuss.Beckmann, P./Kempf, B. (1996), "Arbeitszeit und Arbeitszeitwnsche von Frauen in West-und Ostdeutschland",Mitteilungen aus der Arbeitsmarkt- und Berufsforschung, 29:388-

    408.

    Bell, D./Hart, R.A. (1999), "Unpaid Work",Economica, 66:271-290.

    Bell, L./Freeman, R. (1995), "Why do Americans and Germans Work Different Hours?", in:

    Buttler, F./Franz, W./Schettkat, R./Soskice.D. (eds.), "Institutional Frameworks and

    Labor Market Performance: Comparative Views on the U.S. and German Economies",

    Routledge, New York, 101-131.

    Birchmeier, U. (2001), "Ausgewhlte Arbeitsmarkt- und Bildungsindikatoren im Lichte derStatistik. Ein Vergleich der Schweiz mit der EU, den USA und Japan", Die Volkswirt-

    schaft, 74(1):54-59.Blum, A./Zaugg, R.J. (1998), "Beschftigung durch innovative Arbeitszeitmodelle. Schluss-

    bericht", Bundesamt fr Wirtschaft und Arbeit (BWA), BWA Schriftenreihe, Beitrgezur Arbeitsmarktpolitik No. 12, Bern.

    Bundesamt fr Statistik (BFS) (1996), "Die Schweizerische Arbeitskrfteerhebung (SAKE):Konzepte, methodische Grundlagen, praktische Ausfhrung", Bern.

    Bundesamt fr Statistik (BFS) (1998), "Die Schweizerische Arbeitskrfteerhebung (SAKE):Kommentierte Ergebnisse und Tabellen", Bern.

    Bundesamt fr Statistik (BFS) (1999a), "Statistisches Jahrbuch der Schweiz 2000", Bern.Bundesamt fr Statistik (BFS) (1999b), "Die Schweizerische Arbeitskrfteerhebung (SAKE):

    Kommentierte Ergebnisse und Tabellen", Bern.

    Bundesmann-Jansen, J./Gro, H./Muntz, E. (2000), "Arbeitszeit '99. Arbeitszeitstrukturen,Arbeitszeitwnsche und Zeitverwendung der abhngig Beschftigten in West- und Ost-deutschland", Resultate einer aktuellen Reprsentativbefragung bei abhngig Beschf-tigten in West- und Ostdeutschland durch das Institut zur Erforschung sozialer Chancen,

    Kln, im Auftrag des Ministeriums fr Arbeit, Gesundheit und Soziales des LandesNordrhein-Westfalen, Neusser, Neuss.

    Clemmer, P. (1997), "Arbeitszeitreduktion vermag sie Arbeitspltze zu schaffen", in:Arbeitgeberverband der Schweizer Maschinenindustrie (ASM), "Jahresbericht 1997",

    Zrich.Dathe, D. (1998), "Wechselwirkungen zwischen Arbeitszeitpolitik und Arbeitsangebotsver-

    halten Eine Untersuchung zur Bedeutung von Arbeitszeitprferenzen fr eine Politikder Arbeitsumverteilung", WZB, discussion paper FS I 98-201, Berlin.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    28/30

    27

    Eidgenssisches Personalamt (EPA) (1999), "Verbesserte Sozialpartnerschaft beim Bund",Pressemitteilung vom 21.6.1999, Bern.

    Euwals, R. (1999), "Hours constraints within and between jobs", Paper presented at the 11th

    Annual Conference of the European Association of Labour Economists (EALE) in

    Regensburg, Germany.

    Euwals, R./van Soest, A. (1999), "Desired and Actual Labour Supply of Unmarried Men andWomen in the Netherlands",Labour Economics, 6:95-118.

    Freeman, R.B. (1998), "Wages, Employment and Unemployment: An Overview. Can the EU

    pass the jobs test?", in: European Commission: EC/DG V OECD/DEELSA Seminar:Wages and Employment, Luxembourg, 21-31.

    GfS-Research Institute (GfS) (1998), "Der Wunsch nach individuell gestaltbaren Arbeits-

    zeiten", Spezialstudie des GfS-Forschungsinstituts im Rahmen des "Sorgenbarometer"

    fr das "Bulletin" der Credit-Suisse, Bern.Graf, S./Henneberger, F./Schmid, H. (2000), "Flexibilisierung der Arbeit. Erfahrungen aus

    erfolgreichen schweizerischen Unternehmen", Bern.

    Gro, H./Munz, E. (1999), "Erste Ergebnisse einer 1999 durchgefhrten reprsentativen Be-

    schftigtenbefragung zu Arbeitszeitformen und -wnschen", Kln.Habltzel, P./Rebecchi, R. (1998), "Staat und Verwaltung im Wandel", Die Volkswirtschaft,

    71(12):40-44.

    Ham, J.C. (1982), "Estimation of a Labor Supply Model with Censoring Due to Unemploy-

    ment and Underemployment",Review of Economic Studies, 49:335-354.

    Henneberger, F. (2001), "Arbeitszeitpolitik als Beschftigungspolitik? Zur Diskussion der Be-schftigungseffekte von Wochenarbeitszeitverkrzungen in Privatwirtschaft und ffent-lichem Dienst", in: Becker, U. (ed.), "Weniger Arbeit Arbeit fr alle?", Marburg, 17-50.

    Henneberger, F./Graf, S./Sousa-Poza, A. (1999), "Arbeitszeitverkrzung, Arbeitszeitflexibi-lisierung und Arbeitszeitwnsche von Arbeitnehmern", VSAM-Revue, 80(9):18-22.

    Ilmakunnas, S./Pudney, S. (1990), "A Model of Female Labour Supply in the Presence of

    Hours Restrictions",Journal of Public Economics, 41:183-210.

    Institut der deutschen Wirtschaft Kln (IW) (Hrsg.) (1999), "Zahlen zur wirtschaftlichen Ent-wicklung der Bundesrepublik Deutschland. Ausgabe 1999", Kln.

    Kahn, S./Lang, K. (1992), "Constraints on the Choice of Work Hours: Agency vs. Specific-

    Capital",Journal of Human Resources, 27:661-678.

    Kahn, S./Lang, K. (1996), "Hours Contraints and the Wage/Hour Locus", Canadian Journal

    of Economics, 29:71-75.

    Klauder, W. (1998), "Arbeitszeitpolitik im Lichte gesamtwirtschaftlicher Zusammenhngeund des Strukturwandels der Arbeitswelt", Sozialer Fortschritt, 47:48-49.

    Lang, K./Kahn, S. (2000), "Hours Constraints: Theory, Evidence and Policy Implications", in:Houseman, S./Wong, G. (eds.), "Changes in Working Time in Canada and the United

    States", Kalamazoo (MI) (forthcoming).

    McFadden, D. (1973), "Conditional Logit Analysis of Qualitative Choice Behavior", in:

    Zarembka, P. (ed.), "Frontiers in Econometrics", New York, 105-142.

    McKelvey, R./Zavoina, W. (1975), "A Statistical Model for the Analysis of Ordinal Level

    Dependent Variables",Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 4:103-120.

    OECD (1998a), "Employment Outlook", OECD, Paris.

    OECD (1998b), "Main Economic Indicators", OECD, Paris.

    OECD (2000), "Main Economic Indicators", OECD, Paris.

    Ramirez, J.V. (1998), "Unemployment Rate and Working-Hour Constraints: Empirical Evi-

    dence from the Swiss Labour Force",International Journal of Manpower, 19:449-460.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    29/30

    28

    Schaufelberger, C. (1997), "Wegkommen vom Standardmodell 8 Stunden, 5 Tage", Schwei-zer Arbeitgeber, 92:240-244.

    Schweizerischer Arbeitgeberverband (AGV) (1998), "Kontraproduktive 36-Wochenstunden-

    Initiative", http://www.arbeitgeber.ch/arbeitsmarkt/980327.htm.

    Schweizerischer Gewerkschaftsbund (SGB) (ed.) (1999), "Kurz und knapp: Die drei Ziele der

    Initiative fr eine krzere Arbeitszeit", SGB-Dokument No. 62, Bern.Sousa-Poza, A./Henneberger, F. (2000), "Work Attitudes, Work Conditions, and Hours Con-

    straints: An Explorative, Cross-National Analysis", Labour. Review of Labour Econ-

    omics and Industrial Relations, 14(3):351-372.

    Sousa-Poza, A./Henneberger, F. (2001), "An Empirical Analysis of Working-Hours Con-

    straints in 21 Countries", Research Paper, University of St. Gallen.

    Sousa-Poza, A./Schmid, H./Widmer, R. (2001), "The Allocation and Value of Time Assigned

    to Housework and Child-Care: An Analysis for Switzerland", Journal of Population

    Economics(forthcoming).

    Sousa-Poza, A./Sousa-Poza, A.A. (2000), "Taking Another Look at the Gender/Job-Satis-

    faction Paradox", Kyklos, 53:135-152.

    Sousa-Poza, A./Ziegler, A. (2001), "Asymmetric Information on Workers' Productivity as aCause for Inefficient Long Working Hours", Research Paper, University of St. Gallen.

    Staatssekretariat fr Wirtschaft (seco) (2001), "Die Lage auf dem Arbeitsmarkt Januar 2001",Pressedokumentation vom 19. Februar 2001, Bern.

    Stewart, M.B./Swaffield, J.K. (1997), "Constraints on the Desired Hours of Work of British

    Men",Economic Journal, 107:520-535.

  • 8/12/2019 Working-Time Policies in Switzerland

    30/30

    29

    Appendix

    Table A: determinants of the form of overtime compensation - estimated marginal effects of the multinomial

    logit model

    males females

    none holidays money none holidays moneydemographic variables

    marrieda 0.030 -0.031 0.001 0.018 -0.121** 0.103**

    childrena

    0.016 -0.026 0.010 0.031 -0.150** 0.119**

    high educationa 0.123** -0.128** 0.005 0.169** -0.074* -0.095**

    low educationa

    -0.100* 0.059 0.042* -0.294 -0.013 0.043*

    age10-1 0.006 0.005 -0.111** -0.009 0.141* -0.005

    age210-3 0.011 -0.140 0.130** 0.152* -0.272** 0.120*

    working-time characteristics

    works on weekenda

    0.085** -0.151** 0.066** 0.018 -0.021 0.003

    works at nighta 0.042 -0.101** 0.059** 0.080* -0.176** 0.096**

    works block timesa -0.052* 0.064** -0.012 -0.105** 0.225** -0.120**

    flexible working timesa

    0.100** -0.147** 0.046** -0.011 -0.043 0.054**

    works shiftsa -0.156** 0.141** 0.015 -0.288** 0.285** 0.003other work-related characteristics

    tenure -0.243 0.004 -0.002 -0.001 0.008** -0.007**

    tenure210-3 0.028 -0.047 0.020 0.026 -0.107 0.081*

    is in managementa

    0.086** -0.040* -0.046** 0.044** 0.068** -0.112**

    small firm (< 100 employees)a -0.003 0.011 -0.007 0.031 -0.045 0.015

    number of observations 3132 2394

    log likelihood -2505 -1936

    pseudo-R2 0.125b 0.199b

    Note: The dependent variable can have three possible values depending on the form of overtime compensation.

    The regressions include a constant and twelve dummy variables for different sectors. Only the marginal effects

    are presented here. The sample includes all employees that answered to the question dealing with the form ofcompensation for overtime. It should also be noted that over 20% of employees that do not usually work

    overtime also reported their overtime form of compensation. These individuals have alsobeen included in theseregressions (and therefore the sample size here does not correspond to the sample size in table 5).adummy variablesbthe pseudo-R

    2measure is that of McFadden (1973)

    */** significant at the 5%/1% level, respectively