welfare states, family policies, and fertility in europe...

33
Stockholm University Linnaeus Center on Social Policy and Family Dynamics in Europe, SPaDE Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe Gerda Neyer Working Paper 2012: 10

Upload: others

Post on 23-Mar-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

Stockholm University Linnaeus Center on

Social Policy and Family Dynamics in Europe, SPaDE

Welfare States, Family Policies,

and Fertility in Europe

Gerda Neyer

Working Paper 2012: 10

Page 2: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

2

Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe*

Gerda Neyer

Stockholm University Demography Unit, Dept. of Sociology

[email protected]

Abstract: This contribution discusses the potentials of welfare-state approaches for fertility

research in Europe. Demographers mostly concentrate on family policies and their effects on

fertility. They usually find no fertility-elevating effects of individual family policies or only

small effects on the aggregate level. This has led them to turn their attention instead to welfare

states and to national configurations of social and family policies. In this contribution, I argue

that welfare-state and single-policy approaches complement each other and that both are

needed for a better understanding of fertility developments. I outline the main concepts of the

welfare state and their usefulness for fertility research, underlining two aspects in particular:

First, the relative persistence of the orientation of a welfare state provides a framework to

assess the effects of policies and policy changes across countries and over time. Second,

different welfare states are associated with different labor-market and educational systems,

which allows us to view fertility behavior within a framework of interrelated complementary

institutions.

*This paper is also available as a Stockholm Research Report in Demography

Page 3: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

3

1 Fertility developments in Europe

Over the last forty years of the twentieth century, period fertility developments in Europe

were characterized by two specific trends, namely the decline of fertility to below the

replacement level (i.e. to a Total Fertility Rate below 2.1) and the movement from

intraregional diversity to intraregional homogeneity (Neyer 2003). The decline of the TFR

affected all of Europe. In many countries, the TFR dropped to very low levels (below 1.5) or

even to lowest-low levels (below 1.3). Some countries experienced the decline in the late

1970s and early 1980s, others encountered a drop only in the 1990s. At the end of the 20th

century, all European countries had a TFR below the replacement level, and in roughly two-

thirds of the countries the TFR was below 1.5. Overall, about three-quarters of the European

population lived in societies with such a low fertility (Frejka and Sobotka 2008, 17).

During the first decade of the 21st century, the TFR rose again in almost all major European

regions. By 2008, no European country had a lowest-low fertility level and only eight

countries had a TFR below 1.4. Another eight countries even reached highest-low fertility

levels (TFR 1.85 or above; Eurostat 2010, Figure 1). The increase proved not to be the same

across Europe. Contrary to developments in most of Western Europe, the TFRs of the

German-speaking countries (Germany and Austria) as well as of neighboring Switzerland

failed to increase from their very low levels, while in some high-fertility countries (France,

Sweden, the UK) the increase was larger in absolute terms than what many other countries

experienced (Goldstein et al. 2009, 671). In Central and Eastern Europe, the onset and the

range of the increase varied greatly (Goldstein et al. 2009, 669). With the subsequent

economic crisis, many affected countries lost their gains in the TFR (Sobotka et al. 2011).

Page 4: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

4

Figure 1: Period total fertility in major regions of Europe and in the United States, 1950-2006

1.0

1.5

2.0

2.5

3.0

3.5

1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

Pe

rio

d T

FR

EuropeNorthern EuropeSouthern Europe Central-Eastern Europe German-speakingWestern Europe Eastern EuropeUnited States

Lowest-low fertility

Replacement

threshold

Source: Frejka and Sobotka 2008, 21.

Notes: Data are weighted by the population size of given countries and regions. Countries are grouped into

regions as follows:

Western Europe: Belgium, France, Ireland, Luxembourg, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom;

German-speaking countries: Austria, Germany, and Switzerland;

Northern Europe: Denmark, Finland, Iceland, Norway, and Sweden;

Southern Europe: Cyprus, Greece, Italy, Malta, Portugal, and Spain;

Central-Eastern Europe: Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, Lithuania, Poland, Slovakia,

Slovenia, Bosnia-Herzegovina, Bulgaria, Macedonia, Montenegro, Romania, and Serbia & Kosovo;

Eastern Europe: Belarus, Moldova, Russia, and Ukraine.

The general fertility decline of the last four decades of the 20th

century was accompanied by a

process of regional convergence. In the 1960s, Europe‟s fertility pattern was rather dispersed

and showed marked differences in fertility levels even between countries in the same region.

By the beginning of the 21st century, fertility levels had moved towards greater homogeneity

within regions. At the same time fertility differences between regions had not diminished;

they had remained stable or had even increased slightly (Neyer 2003). Due to the uneven

increase in the TFR at the beginning of the 21st century the differences in fertility levels

among European regions have not diminished. The regional disparity between the high-

fertility regions (the Nordic countries, France, the Netherlands, Ireland and the UK) and the

low-fertility regions (the German-speaking countries, Southern, Central and Eastern Europe)

Page 5: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

5

has rather persisted or has even become more pronounced (Frejka and Sobotka 2008;

Goldstein et al. 2009).

Low fertility and distinct regional differences are not a new phenomenon in Europe. During

the first decades of the 20th

century, fertility in Western and Eastern Europe also declined to

below replacement levels. By the mid-1920s, more than half of the European population lived

in countries with sub-replacement fertility (Frejka and Ross 2001, 214f.), and by the mid-

1930s only a minority of European countries had fertility rates above replacement (van Bavel

2010, 2). The fertility increase to and beyond replacement level that followed in the late 1940s

and during the “baby boom” of the 1950s and 1960s marks a temporary phase in the

otherwise low-fertility history of 20th

century Europe.

Despite the long history of low-fertility patterns in Europe, comparisons and subsequent

conclusions about sub-replacement fertility have usually been drawn with the high-fertility

decades of the mid-20th

century as a reference point. Just like in the 1920s and 1930s, the

currently low fertility in Europe has generated several doomsday scenarios that predict the

demise of the continent. Europe has been pictured as graying and even as vanishing

demographically. Some authors have seen it as sliding into a global disadvantage due to its

lack of young people and have portrayed it as falling behind in technological advancement,

and as losing out in productivity, economic performance, and political power. Many authors

fear that low fertility and the shortage of young people will have adverse effects on Europe‟s

labor markets and on European social-security and welfare-state systems. Immigration,

proposed by some as a remedy against the consequences of low fertility, is rejected by others

who warn that further immigration will jeopardize Europe‟s social and cultural cohesion, its

ethnic homogeneity, and the survival of “Europeanness”. (For a summary of these arguments,

see Neyer 2011; for the perception of low fertility in the 1920s and 1930s, see van Bavel

2010.)

Such concerns about the consequences of low fertility have spurred much public and political

interest in policies that could raise fertility levels. The increase in the TFR during the first

decade of the 21st century has not silenced the voices that call for such policies. Quite on the

contrary, the number of countries which state that they endorse policies to elevate fertility has

continued to rise since the turn of the century. In 2001 about a third of the European countries

reported that they had implemented policies to raise fertility. By 2009, half of the countries

Page 6: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

6

claimed to have such policies in place (United Nations 2002; 2010). The European Union has

also come to view low fertility as a challenge. It has started a number of initiatives to monitor

the demographic trends of Europe and to guide countries in taking policy measures which are

assumed to increase fertility and to promote “demographic renewal” (Policies 2006).

To an observer, the national and supra-national initiatives to tackle low fertility levels raise

the question whether policies do in fact influence fertility developments and bring about or at

least contribute to higher fertility. Many studies which compare the fertility-related policies

and the TFR of selected countries attribute differences in fertility levels to differences in

policies supporting families (Sleebos 2003; Bonoli 2008; Castles 2003; Gauthier 2007).

Unfortunately, the results stated depend on the methods used (Hoem 2008), on the selection

of countries, and on the time frame in which the TFR and the policies are compared. Some

European countries with comparatively high levels of fertility have very meager policies (e.g.,

Ireland or the UK); other countries with extensive family support programs have experienced

continued or temporary low fertility levels (e.g., the German-speaking countries; Sweden in

the first half of the 1990s). This challenges the unconditional assumption that fertility-related

policies boost fertility levels.1 Even the recent increase in the TFR in many low-fertility

countries in Europe cannot unanimously be attributed to fertility-related policy initiatives

enacted to increase fertility. According to Goldstein et al. (2009), in some countries the rise in

the TFR was probably related to the implementation of such policies, in others there is no

discernible link between family policy initiatives and fertility developments, and in yet

another group of countries the fertility turn-around happened despite the absence of any major

fertility-related policy intervention. In general, researchers conclude that the effects of

policies on general fertility levels are weak, inconclusive, or contradictory (Neyer 2003;

Sleebos 2003; Gauthier 2007; Thévenon and Gauthier 2011; Spiess 2012; see also the country

chapters in Frejka et al. 2008).

This has led some researchers to take a broader perspective on policies. They propose that one

should pursue an institutional approach (McNicoll 1994) and consider the configurations and

interactions of policies, explore the impact of policy packages, and take the welfare-state

system into account (McNicoll 2001; Neyer 2003; 2005; Neyer and Andersson 2008;

McDonald in this book). Others argue that such a broadening of the angle complicates the

1 The same applies to policies which aim at lowering fertility (Bledsoe et al. 1998).

Page 7: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

7

assessment of policy effects on fertility because it is hardly possible to observe and measure

the impact of policy conglomerations or of the welfare state on human lives (Mayer and

Schoepflin 1989; Rindfuss and Brauner-Otto 2008). I maintain in this chapter that the broader

policy- or welfare-state approach on the one hand and the single-policy approach on the other

hand complement each other. Concentrating on the welfare state, I outline the potential of an

integrative approach for fertility research and present empirical examples to demonstrate its

analytical range. The main conclusion of this exercise is that both approaches are necessary in

order to explain fertility developments in Europe from a policy perspective. Together, they

provide a more integrative framework which allows us to link policies and fertility both

theoretically and empirically.

2 Welfare state and fertility

Several researchers have pointed out the importance of the state for fertility developments

(McNicoll 1994; 2001; Mayer and Schoepflin 1989; Mayer 2009; McDonald 2006). They

stress that the capacity of the state to shape fertility derives from its legal, administrative, and

bureaucratic power to regulate vital relationships within society (McNicoll 1994) and to

structure the individual‟s life course (Mayer 2009). European countries are unique in that the

welfare state has become an essential institution – some maintain even the essential institution

– which shapes human behavior and social and economic relationships. Although many

proclaim that the “golden age of the welfare state” (i.e., from the 1950s to the mid-1970s) has

passed and that economic and demographic challenges will lead to the dismantling of the

welfare state, current research does not corroborate this claim (Pierson 1996, Pierson 2001,

Boeri et al. 2001). The welfare-state reforms in European countries during the most recent

three decades have rather been what Pierson (2001) calls recalibrations of the welfare state.

Many of the adjustments have involved the modification of existing and the introduction of

new welfare policies (Pierson 2001, 16). They signal a shift in the focus of the welfare state

towards greater responsiveness to “new social risks” (Esping-Andersen 1999; Bonoli 2005;

Palier 2010). These “new social risks” are largely related to the transformation of gender

relationships and to the decline of the “male-breadwinner family” (Esping-Andersen 1999;

2002; Bonoli 2005; Taylor-Gooby 2004). They involve primarily woman-centered life-course

risks which have been covered insufficiently by the “old” welfare state with its focus on the

Page 8: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

8

income retention of the male breadwinner, viz, the reconciliation of work and family life, care

needs, and lone parenthood (Bonoli 2005, 431). These “new social risks” are closely related to

childbearing. The same consideration applies to other “new social risks” to which welfare

states have become more responsive, namely, low education, low income, long-term

unemployment, and insufficient social-security coverage (Bonoli 2005; Esping-Andersen

1999). This implies that the welfare state has become potentially more important for

childbearing decisions and fertility developments. It makes the question of how and to what

extent we can assess the impact of the welfare state on fertility even more pressing.

2.1. Quantifying the welfare state

Researchers have pursued several strategies to measure the importance of the welfare state for

human life. One approach is to classify welfare states according to how extensive or generous

they are. Most often generosity or extensiveness are measured in monetary or other

quantifiable terms. Examples are the share of the general domestic product attributed to social

policies, expenditure on family-relevant social policies (e.g., health), the length of maternity

leave and of parental leave after childbirth, the wage compensation granted to mothers (and

fathers) during such leaves, the benefits granted to single mothers or to each child in a family,

public subsidies for childcare, housing, and education, and so forth. The attraction for

demographers of these and similar indicators is that they are often available for a large

number of countries and that many of these indicators have been standardized for comparative

purposes. Examples of such databases are: the OECD Social Expenditure Database, the

OECD Family Database, the European System of Integrated Social Protection Statistics

(ESSPROS), the Comparative Family Policy Database, and the GGP Contextual Database.

During the last two decades, more fine-grained indicators have become available, as have

previously missing ones that are associated with the welfare coverage of “new social risks”, of

gender, and of family issues. This means that demographers have an increasing number of and

more refined indicators at hand. Such indicators are well suited to rank welfare states or to

determine clusters of welfare states along demography-relevant aspects (see, for example,

Thévenon 2008). A weakness of such indicators is that many of them represent only the

quantitative dimensions of a welfare state and its policies: Merely quantifying welfare-state

measures have proved to be of limited potential in capturing essential characteristics of the

welfare state and in explaining current or long-term cross-national differences in fertility

Page 9: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

9

outcomes. Even if measures of specific policies are selected, relying on the purely quantitative

aspects of such policies may not be sufficient to show possible linkages between policies and

fertility. The reason for this is that extensiveness or generosity does not necessarily indicate

how supportive a policy or a welfare state is. For example, social expenditure may be high

because of high unemployment, which in turn leads to greater expenditure on unemployment

benefits, even if these are low. Likewise, a long parental leave appears quantitatively as

generous, while in fact long leaves are known to inhibit mothers‟ return to the labor market

and women‟s employment careers (Rønsen and Sundström 2002). A merely quantitative

approach does not uncover such features, because it neither discloses the principles on which

a welfare state is based nor its aims. Both of these latter dimensions are essential, however, in

that they shape the content and the direction of a welfare state and its social policies (for an

example of an approach which recognizes these dimensions, see Kalwij 2010). They are

therefore crucial elements needed to capture the essence of the welfare state and to assess its

potential impact on fertility.

2.2 The welfare state from the perspective of its principles and aims

Several researchers have developed welfare-state concepts that recognize explicitly the

principles and the aims of a welfare state (Wilensky 1975; Flora and Heidenheimer 1982;

Esping-Andersen 1990). Such notions have become dominant in welfare-state research. This

approach differs significantly from the purely quantifying approach. The latter regards a

welfare state primarily as the “sum of its policies” (measured, as we mentioned above, in

terms of extensiveness or generosity). An approach which considers the principles and aims

of a welfare state focuses on the structuring functions of the welfare state and on the

ideological premises on which its social policies are based (Wilensky 1975). It regards the

welfare state as an institution which provides social order for human behavior through its

social policies. As an institution, it creates a “stable equilibrium” (McNicoll 2009, 790) for

individual action and for society, and it gives guidance and meaning to behavior.

Page 10: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

10

2.2.1 Welfare regimes: The principles of equality and of security

The principles and aims acknowledged as essential for welfare states are commonly related to

equality and to security. Equality is usually conceived as equality across class lines. Some

distinguish between equality of opportunities and equality of result (Flora and Heidenheimer

1982). Security relates primarily to protection against economic and demographic risks

(unemployment, old age) through social-security systems (Flora and Heidenheimer 1982).

Based on the way in which these principles and aims are transposed into welfare-state

policies, distinct welfare regimes can be identified. In his seminal and widely applied

typology of welfare regimes, Esping-Andersen (1990) classifies Western welfare states

according to three dimensions which govern core social policies, related to unemployment,

health/invalidity, and old-age pensions:

(1) “De-commodification”, which is “the degree to which individuals, or families, can uphold

a socially acceptable standard of living independently of market participation” (Esping-

Andersen 1990, 37). In essence, this refers to the social security granted to a person in case of

unemployment, sickness, old age, or any other life-course issue which makes her/him unable

to participate in the labor market (e.g., childbearing, childrearing).

(2) “Social citizenship”, which is whether access to welfare-state benefits are granted on the

basis of individual rights (social citizenship), on the basis of needs (Esping-Andersen 1990,

21-23), or on the basis of specific family constellations. Benefits based on needs often rest on

the principle of subsidiarity, in that the family is regarded as the primary source of welfare

and the state only as a back-up. Benefits are only granted if individual and family resources

are exhausted or if the family is unable to provide welfare. Entitlements based on specific

family forms (marriage) acknowledge the principle of mutual support in family relationships

and grant access to social security to the partner/children of the main provider. In both cases,

an individual‟s welfare is made dependent on family relationships and/or family resources

(Fraser and Gordon 1994).

(3) “Stratification”, which is whether welfare-state policies reinforce, sustain, or reduce social

cleavages and status differences between various social and economic groups. This includes

whether access to and levels of benefits are granted on equal terms to everyone or whether

they vary by occupational status (blue-collar/white-collar/public workers) or by family status

(married/non-married).

Page 11: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

11

These dimensions generate three specific types of Western welfare regimes: (1) the

universalistic or social-democratic welfare regime of the Nordic countries, characterized by a

high degree of de-commodification, social-citizenship based rights to welfare benefits, and

policies which are directed towards social equality; (2) the conservative-corporatist welfare

regime of continental Western Europe, with stratifying and subsidiary welfare systems based

on employment- and occupation-related social insurance schemes; and (3) the liberal welfare

regime of the English-speaking countries with its reliance on the market and on private

provision of social security and with minimal (means-tested) public support.

There have been several suggestions to modify Esping-Andersen‟s typology (see, Arts and

Gelissen 2002 for an overview). Most of them are based on claims that specific countries

deviate from the ideal types of welfare regimes. Following Ferrera (1996), many researchers,

including demographers, acknowledge Southern European countries as a separate welfare

regime (the “Latin rim” or “Mediterranean” model), because of the highly fragmented system

of social protection, the close reliance on the family as provider of welfare, the distinct

clientalism in these countries, and the pronounced labor-market insider-outsider divide.2 Post-

communist countries in Eastern and Central European have been added as an additional,

although diverse and volatile, welfare regime, which combines Bismarckian (conservative)

and liberal (market-based) welfare aspects (Cerami and Vanhuysse 2009). All of these

modifications of the three worlds of welfare maintain the primary focus on the core social-

security systems in Western Europe (unemployment, health/invalidity, old-age pension) and

on their logics regarding social rights, protection against labor-market risks, and class

structures.

2.2.2 Welfare regimes, gender, and the family

Feminist and gender researchers have broadened this framework further by emphasizing the

notions of gender ingrained in welfare policies. They emphasize how views of gender shape

welfare-state policies and how welfare states in turn shape gender relationships in the family,

in the economic sphere, and in society. They thus include the family in a more subtle way in

their classification and analysis of welfare states. They de-compose “the family” and

2 The allocation of the Netherlands and of Switzerland to the conservative welfare regime has also been

contested; both are seen as hybrid cases (Arts and Gelissen 2002).

Page 12: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

12

distinguish between partnership and parenthood as two different forms of relationships which

are shaped by welfare-state policies. They introduce care, that is, care giving and care

receiving, as essential dimensions of welfare policies (Knijn and Kremer 1997). They bring in

family policies as part of social policies. Finally, they modify the welfare-state principles by

turning the attention to risks, rights, and stratifications related to or resulting from gender

(being female or male), sexual orientation (heterosexual, same-sex, transsexual), partnership

forms (cohabitation, marriage, divorce, widowhood), or parenthood status (single mothers;

other forms of parental status). (For an overview over these aspects, see Neyer 2003).

Taken together these features expand the range and content of social policies substantially.

Just like the labor market or class structure, the family, gender, and sexual relationships are

regarded as targets of the welfare state. Linking gender, the labor market, the family, and the

welfare state, feminist and gender welfare-state researchers have highlighted three additional

fertility-relevant welfare-state principles:

(1) “Commodification”, which is the way in which welfare states support the

labor-force participation of women and mothers, and maintain or alter the “male-

breadwinner” family (Orloff 1993; Lewis 1992; Gornick et al. 1997). In a broader sense,

commodification includes maintaining and supporting the employability of individuals,

especially of those who have difficulties entering and remaining in the labor market (e.g.,

mothers, youth, immigrants, the less educated, the long-term unemployed). It also extends to

the way in which policies promote or hamper gender equality in the labor market, that is, in

types of employment, at the workplace, in income, in career options and so forth, as an

essential aspect of commodification over the life-course.

(2) “Familialism”/“de-familialisation”, which depicts the way in which a

welfare state deals with “care”. ”Familialism” refers to the extent to which welfare states

regard the family and thus directly or indirectly women as the primary providers of care. It

describes the degree to which welfare states support familial care, encourage mothers‟ retreat

from the labor market after childbearing, and strengthen their caring functions (Leitner 2003).

This includes the preferential treatment of marriage (and of a married female carer) over other

family forms. “De-familialisation” refers to the aim of a welfare state to reduce family care

responsibilities and (female) dependencies by providing institutional care (Anttonen and

Sipilä 1996; Esping-Andersen 1999; Saraceno and Keck 2010; Saraceno 2011).

Page 13: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

13

(3) “De-gendering of employment and care”, which is the extent to which

welfare states seek to alter gender relationships by supporting the employment of mothers and

by promoting the engagement of fathers in childcare and family work (Sainsbury 1999; Korpi

2000). This refers primarily to policy aims to change the male-breadwinner/female-carer

family model towards the more gender-equal dual-earner/dual-carer family form (Sainsbury

1999).

If the dimensions of commodification, familialism, and de-gendering of employment and care

are added in the classification of welfare states, the welfare-regime pattern becomes more

diverse. The continental European welfare states do not constitute a common regime any

longer. With their high degree of de-familialisation, France and Belgium are closer to the

Nordic welfare states. Among the other continental welfare states, there exist different

patterns of support for women‟s employment, of familialism and de-familialisation: Southern

Europe is less de-familialising than other conservative Western European countries; Eastern

Europe, once a region in which states ideologically supported female employment and

encouraged childbearing through various degrees of familialism, has undergone a process of

re-familialisation and moved towards different, albeit frequently changing patterns of

familialism (Lewis 1992; Anttonnen and Sipilä 1996; Gornick et al. 1997; Sainsbury 1999;

Leitner 2003; Neyer 2005; Szelewa and Polakowski 2008; Szikra and Tomka 2009).

2.2.3 Family-policy change and regime continuity

The family-policy based pattern of welfare regimes has become more diverse during the past

decade. The reforms of the European welfare states in order to tackle new social risks – in

particular policy initiatives related to (female) labor-force participation, parental leave, and

childcare – have not been uniform across countries nor have they all gone in the same

direction. For example, Finland, Norway, and recently also Sweden introduced some “re-

familialisation” policies by giving parents a choice between using public childcare or taking

care of children at home for a longer period of time. These countries seem to partly move

away from their gender-equality principles, so that the Nordic welfare regime appears less

homogenous with respect to de-familialisation. Germany, by contrast, replaced its

conservative parental-leave system by regulations modeled after the Nordic countries. Judged

on the basis of its current parental leave system, it emerges as a de-familialising country,

Page 14: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

14

deviating from the rest of the group of countries with conservative parental-leave patterns.

Austria took a position in-between by diversifying its parental leave regulations so that

parents can now choose among five different modes of leave. Some authors find that such

policy changes, which diverge from the general welfare orientation of a country, have made it

more difficult to allocate countries to specific welfare regimes and to locate stable patterns.

Some countries even tend to shift between different regimes, depending on which policy is

included in the analysis. (See, e.g., the classification of care regimes in Saraceno and Keck

2010 and of family policies in Thévenon 2011). This may also make it more difficult to assess

linkages between welfare-state configurations and fertility.

However, such fuzziness and instability arise primarily if the classification is based on only

one single policy at a time. Radical, paradigmatic changes in policy directions are rare (Hall

1993). Even if such changes do occur, they usually apply to only one policy or to a very

limited set of policy features. The change usually does not affect the direction of the welfare

state (although it can mark the beginning of a gradual transformation). If we consider the

main principles and orientations of welfare- and family policies as a whole, the regime

patterns have remained remarkably persistent over time (Castles and Obinger 2008). Despite

the changes mentioned above, Germany and Austria, for example, continue to be conservative

welfare states, and the Nordic countries still constitute a distinct, highly gender-equality

oriented welfare regime. Fundamental changes of the welfare state as such have happened

only in post-communist countries. They were not brought about by a replacement of one set

of welfare policies through another, but by the breakdown of the political and economic

system, the concurrent disruption of the organizational and administrative basis of much of

the (non-family) welfare production, and the rise of capitalism. These developments

“dislodged” previous welfare policies and welfare functioning. However, some basic

principles, such as familialism, have continued to prevail and have governed post-communist

welfare adjustments in a way that some authors see more path-dependency and path-

continuation than path-departure and path-cessation, despite the transformation of the welfare

systems (Cerami and Vanhuysee 2009).3

3 Authors who stress path-dependency see the post-communist welfare institutions as partly reaching back to pre-

communist times (Cerami and Vanhuysse 2009).

Page 15: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

15

2.2.4 Welfare regimes and fertility research

For several reasons, the lines of welfare-state research described above provide a useful

approach for policy-oriented fertility research. First, this approach links welfare-state policies

more closely to human behavior than purely expenditure-based approaches do. By focusing

on the notions of gender, equality, security, class, social rights, and family incorporated in

welfare-state policies, this research emphasizes that welfare states are not neutral towards all

groups of society and towards all forms of social behavior. Welfare states support specific

types of behavior and discriminate against others. They give privilege to specific forms of

life-course organizations by making work and family behavior which is compatible with

welfare-state policies more meaningful, “rational” or advantageous than other forms of

behavior. Welfare states thus create a realm of “agency inequality” (Korpi 2000) along

gender, class, age and other social lines.

Second, focusing on the principles and aims governing welfare policies offers a common basis

to characterize the main orientation of a welfare state, to reduce the heterogeneity of its social

policies to essential features, and to cluster welfare states into broader groups of welfare

regimes. This facilitates comparative research on the linkage between social policies and

fertility. It is usually impossible to include all social policies in comparative research. Even if

we only consider a selection of policies, the breadth of variation in policy manifestations

across countries may result in findings that cannot be interpreted in a meaningful way.

Welfare-state regimes represent the basic characteristics of the social-policy environment in

which women and men make their fertility decisions. They can thus serve as an indicator of

this environment in fertility analyses.

Third, by considering the welfare-state regime, we avoid over- or underestimating the effects

of single policies. Policies may have different effects depending on whether they are in line

with or go against other welfare-state policies and thus line up with or counteract the general

orientation of a welfare state (Neyer and Andersson 2008). Singling out one policy as an

explanatory factor for fertility change or for the persistence of fertility patterns may lead to

wrong conclusions as to the magnitude or even the direction of a policy effect (Neyer and

Andersson 2008). Situating the policy within its broader welfare-state context, that is, in

relation to the main principles and aims of the welfare state, mitigates this problem.

Page 16: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

16

Fourth, the gender and feminist welfare-state approach connects well with two major

demographic theories of fertility development and fertility differentials in advanced societies,

namely McDonald‟s theory of gender equity and Goldscheider‟s theory of a two-step gender

revolution. Both theories link low fertility in highly-advanced capitalist countries to the

discrepancy between high female labor-force participation and low gender equity in family

care work, that is, to the increasing “commodification” of women on the one hand and the

persistence of a high degree of familialism and a low degree of de-gendering of care on the

other hand (McDonald 2000; Goldscheider 2000). Both theories hold that the decline from

high to low fertility levels in Western countries has been associated with an increase in

women‟s presence in the labor market and in other public institutions and with a concomitant

persistence of women‟s sole responsibility for family work and care, while a subsequent

increase from low to higher fertility levels necessitates a stronger involvement of men in

family work and care. Welfare states play a mediating role in shaping these movements via

their support or non-support of gender equality in employment and care (Neyer 2006). More

generally speaking, the theories predict higher fertility if the orientation of a welfare state

towards women and men complies with prevailing societal gender norms and the behavior of

women and men, and the theories expect fertility to decline and remain low if there is a

divergence between the gender logic of a welfare state on the one hand and the societal

development regarding gender norms and gender behavior on the other hand. The same may

apply to the childbearing developments among specific groups in society, since some social

groups hold attitudes and are in a position to lead a life course which complies with the

existing social policies while other social groups are not (see also Bourdieu 1996).

So far, the theoretical assumptions about the relationship between welfare-state logics and

fertility developments have primarily focused on women; this is why the gender and feminist

approach has proved to be especially useful for fertility research. However, if we want to link

men‟s fertility behavior and male fertility developments to welfare-state configurations, the

gender and feminist notions may apply only partially. For men, fertility decisions still seem to

depend largely on employment and on the economic security to maintain of a family rather

than on care options or on the possibility to combine employment and care (Neyer et al.

2011). As a consequence, typologies of welfare states centered on employment and social-

security, such as those by Esping-Andersen and his successors, may be more suitable to assess

the linkage between welfare states and male fertility. Similar considerations may apply if, for

Page 17: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

17

example, we look at connections between welfare-state systems and immigrants‟ fertility

behavior or at the interrelationship between economic developments, welfare-state

configurations and fertility behavior. Briefly, to assess the relationship between welfare-state

systems and fertility, it is necessary to consider which welfare-state dimensions are relevant

for the persons or groups and for the event studied.

Fifth and partly resulting from the arguments set out above, because of the enduring nature of

welfare-state principles, the regime concept offers a useful policy framework for comparative

analysis of fertility developments over time. The difficulties one encounters in a cross-

sectional comparative analysis intended to include all fertility-relevant social policies are

aggravated if one attempts to incorporate the development of these policies across many

countries and over time. As we have mentioned, welfare-state typologies offer a way to

reduce the range and variety of social policies to a few shared characteristics and to explicitly

acknowledge the social-policy system either in the analysis or in the interpretation. A welfare-

state approach is particularly appropriate if policy explanations are sought for trends in

aggregate (cohort or period) fertility measures.4 These can rarely be related to the

introduction, existence or elimination of a single policy, such as parental leave, family

benefits, or childcare institutions. Instead, aggregate fertility measures tend to reflect the

broader circumstances under which childbearing decisions are made, that is their context.

Regime concepts offer to provide a structure to this context by representing essential welfare-

state features which guide behavior over the life course.

To summarize, the welfare-regime approach reaches beyond purely measurable aspects of

social policies and aims to capture the essence of structuring elements of welfare systems.

This has its advantages, as outlined above, but it also has some disadvantages for fertility

research. Some may regard it as a drawback that some welfare-state classifications are based

on researchers‟ judgments about policy directions. This introduces a qualitative element into

the analysis. A challenge is also posed by welfare states which deviate from the ideal-type

welfare regimes, that is, welfare states whose policies follow rather heterogeneous principles,

such as Switzerland or the former Eastern-Bloc countries. Their allocation to a specific

4 Aggregate fertility measures have received much criticism because they do not reflect fertility-relevant

behavioral aspects (e.g., Hoem 2008; Hoem and Mureşan 2011). Some authors therefore consider them

inappropriate for the assessment of the relationship between policies and fertility. Nevertheless, they are still the

dominant indicators of fertility development and are commonly used as reference categories in policy

discussions.

Page 18: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

18

welfare regime or – in the case of the former communist countries – their clustering into one

or two welfare regimes must be considered carefully. Some authors argue furthermore that

changes in the labor market, such as the increase in new types of work which are less well

covered by welfare regulations, have decreased the power of the welfare state to shape

individual lives, even though welfare-state policies to cover “new social risks” have been

expanded (Scharpf and Schmidt 2000). Despite these issues, the concept of welfare regimes

constitutes a valuable contribution to an institutional approach in fertility research by linking

individual behavior with the structured macro-level environment in which a person lives.

2.3 Welfare states and institutional complementarities

The institutional approach of welfare-state research stresses that welfare states do not only

affect employment and family behavior, but that they also structure the labor market and other

institutions. Demographers have mostly turned their attention to the relationship between

welfare-state policies and family behavior. Less attention has been paid to the fact that

different welfare regimes are associated with differently organized labor markets, as is

indicated by Esping-Andersen‟s concept of welfare regimes based on class- and labor-

relations. The organization and structure of the labor market per se can affect family behavior,

including fertility developments (Rindfuss and Brauner-Otto 2008). For example, women

working in a labor market with a high share of women and with welfare-state policies which

support women‟s employment probably encounter different childbearing conditions than

women working in a labor market with a low share of female employees and with welfare-

state policies which promote exit from the labor-market when a woman enters motherhood.

Beyond the mere employment structure of the labor market, scholars highlight the fact that

different welfare regimes offer different schemes and levels of protection to wage earners

(Esping-Andersen 1990; Hall and Soskice 2001). In conservative welfare states, the various

groups of employees (such as public employees, blue-collar workers, white-collar workers,

workers in new types of employment such as call centers, the new self-employed, and so

forth) are usually covered by distinctly different labor-protection schemes. In social-

democratic welfare regimes, the protection is more universal; in liberal welfare states labor

protection is largely absent. This creates labor markets of different characters, with different

conditions of entry and exit, of internal mobility, of inclusion and exclusion, and of economic

Page 19: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

19

and social security. In a manner similar to varieties of welfare regimes, researchers therefore

speak of “varieties of capitalism” (Hall and Soskice 2001).

The approach based on varieties of capitalism distinguishes between the “coordinated market

economies” of Western continental and social-democratic welfare states on the one hand and

the “liberal market economies” of the liberal welfare states on the other hand (Hall and

Soskice 2001).5 In contrast to the situation in liberal market economies, labor-market entry is

more institutionalized in coordinated market economies. In the latter, the labor markets show

a high degree of occupational and gender segregation; they offer less opportunity for upward

mobility for women, and the comparatively strong social protection of workers leads to less

movement into and out of the labor market (Mandel and Semyonov 2006).

Scholars using varieties of capitalism stress that the institutional complementarities are not

limited to linkages between welfare-state regimes and labor-market regimes; they also extend

to other societal institutions, such as to educational systems. Estévez-Abe et al. (2001) show

that different market economies have different systems of skill formation. In coordinated

market economies with their high protection of workers against dismissal, educational

systems provide high-level and often highly standardized industry-, firm-, or occupation-

specific skills through vocational schools and apprenticeships. In liberal market economies

with their low protection and high mobility of workers, the educational systems provide

general, transportable skills (Estévez-Abe et al. 2001, Estévez-Abe 2005; 2009; Hall and

Soskice 2001; Soskice 2005).

The varieties-of-capitalism approach has been criticized for lumping together the

universalistic welfare states of the Nordic countries and the corporatist-conservative welfare

states of continental Europe (McCall and Orloff 2005, Mandel and Shalev 2009; Rubery

2009; Thelen 2012). Recent modifications of the coordinated market economies suggest that

we should distinguish between “sector-coordinated” market economies with industry-based

systems of protection (corresponding largely to the corporatist-conservative welfare states)

and “national-coordinated” market economies with greater egalitarian aims (“egalitarian

5 There is a substantial difference between the welfare-state approach and the approach based on “varieties of

capitalism”. The former stresses the role of the state, the latter stresses the role of firms and employers in the

development of social policies and in structuring economic relationships. My application of the varieties-of-

capitalism approach selects only a specific aspect of this research line, a line which to me seems useful for

fertility research.

Page 20: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

20

capitalism”, comprising the Scandinavian welfare states) (Thelen 2012)6. These distinctions

offer a more suitable framework to capture varieties in female labor-force participation,

gender (in)equality in employment, transitions into/out of the labor market, and differences in

systems of skill acquisitions.

With these extensions, the varieties-of-capitalism approach offers intriguing new aspects for

demographic research. It stresses the interdependency and the complementarity between

different institutions, in particular between the labor market, the educational system, and

welfare-state policies. If different configurations of the welfare state are associated with

different systems of skill acquisition, with different circumstances in the labor market, and

with different constraints regarding mobility in and out of employment and across

occupations, we cannot only focus on family policies as the essential institutional force

determining childbearing behavior. We also need to consider the constraints imposed by these

other complementary institutions. Combining welfare-regime approaches with a varieties-of-

capitalism approach leads to a more comprehensive concept of institutional setting, namely

one which puts the emphasis on the linkages between the various fertility-relevant institutions.

If we use a conceptual framework for fertility research which considers institutional

complementarities rather than focusing on one institution only, we are better able to assess to

what extent changes in one institution (e.g., the labor market or the gender system) affect the

potential impact of other institutions (e.g., the welfare state, family policies) on fertility. Such

a dynamic model of institutional complementarities expands the institutional framework for

explaining differentials in childbearing behavior and fertility outcome which cannot be

explained sufficiently well otherwise.

2.3.1 Welfare state, institutional complementarities, and fertility: An example

To summarize the arguments and to illustrate the usefulness of such notions for fertility

research, let us consider findings of studies on ultimate childlessness by educational field and

educational level among Swedish and Austrian women born in 1955 to 1959. (For details, see

6 The terms “sector-coordinated” and “national-coordinated” economies refer to the way in which labor

negotiations between employers‟ associations and unions (e.g., collective bargaining) are carried out. The sector-

coordinated economies lead to more occupation-/sector-specific welfare and labor-market systems, national-

coordinated economies to more egalitarian systems (Thelen 2012).

Page 21: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

21

Hoem et al. 2006; Neyer and Hoem 2008). In Sweden as well as in Austria, the overall level

of childless among women of this cohort is the same (15,7%). In both countries, women

educated for teaching or health professions remain childless less often than women in most

other educational fields, at each level of education (Figure 2 and Figure 3). However, Sweden

and Austria differ markedly with regard to childlessness by educational level. Austrian

women with an upper-secondary or tertiary education have much higher childlessness than

women with a lower education, while there exist no such differences by educational level

among Swedish women7 (Figure 3).

Figure 2: Percent childless by educational field and educational level. Austrian women born

1955-1959

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

40

1 2 3 4 5 6

pe

r c

en

t c

hild

les

s

educational level

General

Teaching, Health, Social Work

Art, Humanities, Religion

Econ., Busin., Adm., Law, Social Sc.

Industry, Craft, Engin., Nat. Sc.

Agriculture

Personal Services

primary apprenticeship vocationalmiddle

highschoolgeneral &vocational

vocationalcollege

university

textile worker

on

food proc.

book seller

sales

banking,

r

midwife

med-tech.ass.

pre-school teachernurse

hairdresser

beautician

high schooltourism

tourism

primary-school teacher

vocational-school teacher

med.-therap.

.

social worker

engineer

agricult.

pharmacist

physician.

high school teacher

social scient.

journalist

veterin.

artist, theolog., humanist

law

nat.scient.econ.

hotel/restaurant

social worker technician

agricult.

technician architect

psychol.

dental ass

agricult.agricult.

Source: Neyer and Hoem 2008

7 There is an exception for the most highly qualified women in Sweden, that is, women with a PhD. The Austrian

data do not distinguish between the different levels of university-based tertiary education, so that no comparison

is possible for this most highly educated group of women.

Page 22: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

22

Figure 3: Percent childless by educational field and educational level. Swedish women born

1955-59

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

2 3 4 5 6 7

Pe

r c

en

t c

hild

les

s

e

General ed

Personal service etc.

Esthetic, humanist, religious

Adm., econ., social sci.

Industry,crafts,engin.,nat. sci.

Teaching and health

waitress

post office official

beautician

midwife

primary-school teacher

policewoman

nurse

deaconess

humanist

theologian

lawyer

social scientist

artist

librarian

natural scientist

high-school teacher

MDsocial worker

special education teacherdentist

childcare worker

dental nurse

medical secretary

primary school

long secondary school

PhD (Med)

PhD (SH)

PhD (NT)

pre-school teacher

pharmacist

engineer

music/arts teacher

after-school

primary two year secondary three year secondary vocational & lower tertiary university PhD

Source: Hoem, Neyer and Andersson 2006

Page 23: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

23

Figure 4: Childlessness by educational level at age 40+. Women born in 1955 to 1959:

Austria and Sweden

Source: Neyer and Hoem 2008

Notes:

Sweden primary up to age16

lower secondary&apprenticeship 2-year secondary

upper secondary 3-year secondary

lower tertiary 2-3 years

tertiary 4 year & PhD

Austria primary up to age 10 or 14

lower secondary&apprenticeship apprenticeships& voc. middle

upper secondary vocational & general highschool

lower tertiary teachers' & voc. Colleges

tertiary university through PhD

The differences and similarities in levels of childlessness between and among Austrian and

Swedish women cannot be explained by a single factor only, such as by differences in family

policies. We need a broader and more comprehensive framework, because ultimate

childlessness is measured at the end of a woman‟s reproductive life (at age 41+). We thus

observe the final outcome of a series of decisions and behaviors that stretch over more than 25

Page 24: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

24

years. We argue that the patterns are produced by the distinct institutional settings of the two

countries during the period in question, namely the structure and the flexibility of the

educational system, the differences in labor-market and employment conditions for different

educational groups, the gendered patterns in education and in the labor market, the welfare-

state orientation and the gender and family policies, as well as the way in which education,

labor market, and family and gender policies are intertwined. To support the argument, we

consider some of the institutional commonalities and differences, concentrating on the aspects

discussed above. (For more detailed descriptions, see Hoem et al. 2006; Neyer and Hoem

2008).8 Austria and Sweden share a sufficient number of features to make a comparison of the

selected cohort of women interesting. Both countries revised their educational systems in the

early 1970s to facilitate access to higher education for all social groups. Both introduced

parental-leave schemes and individual taxation in the first half of the 1970s to increase female

labor-force participation. Both countries are classified as “coordinated market economies”

with a high degree of institutionalization of labor- and social-policy issues; both countries

have educational systems with a large share of vocational training; and both countries are

“strong” welfare states with a long-established system of family policies (Estévez-Abe et al.

2001; Culpepper 2007; Pontussen 2000; Soskice 2005). However, Austria and Sweden have

taken markedly different paths regarding these institutions. Since the 1960s, Swedish policies

for the labor market, social relations, education, the family have been directed towards

reducing inequality and towards promoting social and gender equality. The educational

system is set up to promote higher educational attainment, to allow for flexible moves

between educational fields, and to encourage recurrent and life-long education and training.

Comprehensive primary education (up to age 16) avoids early separation of pupils into

different educational tracks. Vocational training is offered at the (upper-)secondary and at the

tertiary level. Contrary to many other coordinated market economies with vocational training

systems, Sweden offers a high share of its vocational training at the tertiary level (29.9%;

Culpepper 2007, 621), and it is therefore ranked as a country with a more general educational-

skill profile and high labor market mobility (Culpepper 2007, 620f.; Estévez-Abe et al. 2001;

Benner and Vad 2000).

8 The description focuses on the period from 1970 to 2000; this covers roughly the main reproductive years of

women of the cohort 1955-59.

Page 25: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

25

By contrast, the Austrian school system is highly segregated and changes between educational

tracks are difficult. Separating pupils into different educational tracks starts as early as after

four years of schooling (at age 10) and continues afterwards through diversification of the

school system into different types of schools or different lines of education with partially

different curricula. Vocational training is offered mostly at the secondary level, either in

vocational schools or as apprenticeships. (Only 3.9% are provided at the tertiary level;

Culpepper 2007, 621). Unlike in Sweden, the Austrian system of apprenticeships is

segregated from the general school system. It offers much less general education and much

less portable skills than the Swedish vocational system does (Culpepper 2007). There are few

opportunities to interrupt and subsequently re-enter the educational system; below university

level it is almost impossible. Access to post-secondary and tertiary education is restricted to

those who have passed a final comprehensive high-school (upper-secondary school) exam.

This leads to a class divide between those who have passed this exam and those who have not.

Adult education and training is provided through specific institutions and is often costly.

Contrary to Sweden, the Austrian system is not organized to support gender and social

equality in education. Austria has largely adhered to gender-specific lines and programs (at

least at the time when our cohorts went to school); it has not succeeded in diminishing social

and class differences in educational participation and educational attainment to the extent that

Sweden has.

The different educational strategies of Sweden and Austria are associated with very different

patterns of educational attainment among the women of the cohorts 1955-59. Only 13% of

these Austrian women have attained tertiary education, compared to 33% of the Swedish

women. The vast majority (80%) of the Austrian women have only completed compulsory

school, vocational “middle” school, or an apprenticeship as their highest educational

attainment. This compares with 53% of the Swedish women who have equivalent degrees.

Austrian women with a high-school (upper-secondary school) or higher degree constitute a

clear minority (20%), while almost half of the Swedish women hold such a degree. One can

expect that these differences in educational distribution have repercussions on the labor

market structure, on women‟s employment, and on their childbearing behavior.

The Swedish approach to the labor-market has focused on “commodification”, labor-market

mobility and gender equality (Benner and Vad 2000). Since the 1960s it has been directed

towards increasing female labor-force participation, towards integrating every adult person

Page 26: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

26

into the labor market, and towards reducing gender and social inequality in pay and other

work-related aspects. Welfare-state and family policies, both based on social-citizenship

rights, have been geared towards this goal, as well. Since the middle of the 1970s, family

policies aim to support the dual-earner/dual-carer family (Sainbury 1999), in which both

women and men pursue employment and share childrearing. Parental-leave regulations have

been gender neutral since then, and parental-leave benefits replace a high share of a woman‟s

or man‟s previous income. Since 1995, Sweden also has reserved one month of parental leave

for each parent (the “daddy month”).9 Public childcare has been extended to grant every child

access to high-quality and affordable childcare. As a consequence of these policy strategies,

female labor-force participation rates ranged from 60% to 83% during 1970 to 2000, which is

far above the corresponding rates in Austria (45% to 62%).

As a conservative welfare state with a sector-/branch-coordinated welfare- and labor-policy

system, Austria has put much less emphasis on integrating women into the labor market and

on promoting equality in employment and care. For a long time and through most of the

reproductive years of our cohort, the social-security system backed the male-breadwinner

family model by granting free coverage to married (later also to non-marital registered) non-

employed partners. Labor-market policies and work agreements distinguished between

women and men. Direct discriminatory treatment was only gradually abolished, but indirect

gender-unequal regulations have continued to exist (e.g., the seniority principle in the public

sector, which has been the main employer of highly educated women). Moreover, the

protection of a person‟s occupational and educational status in case of unemployment

hampers transitions between occupations with different qualification requirements. Welfare

and family policies have been directed towards facilitating mothers‟ work interruption after

childbirth. Until 1990, parental leave, inflexible and lowly paid, was only available for

mothers; the introduction of a (subsidiary) father‟s leave in 1990 was accompanied by a

doubling of the parental-leave period to two years, which has lengthened the labor-market

absence of mothers. Childcare for children below age three has hardly been available, and

although the overall coverage for children at three to six years has been relatively high, there

has been great regional variation regarding childcare coverage and full-time offers. In general,

while Sweden has aimed at increasing female education and labor-force participation and at

9 This was extended to two months in 2002, but (a) most of the women of our cohort (1955 to 1959) had finished

their childbearing by then, and (b) our data did not include the year 2002.

Page 27: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

27

easing mothers‟ care work, Austria has maintained much of its class-oriented, gender-

differentiating work/family policies, despite the fact that education has been increasing among

women.

If we interpret the results of the study of Swedish and Austrian women‟s ultimate

childlessness in light of the differences in the educational system, the labor market, the family

policies, and the gender orientation of the welfare state, it is difficult to single out one factor

which could explain the striking difference in the levels of childlessness between women with

less education and women with higher education in the two countries. The clear class divide

in Austria indicates a discrepancy between the work aspirations of highly educated women on

the one hand and the obstacles of combining work and motherhood on the other hand; the

latter is brought about by the general conservative orientation of the welfare state, and the

resulting conditions of education, of family-policy support, and of labor-market circumstances

for women.

3 Conclusion

In this paper, I have outlined some of the central concepts of the welfare state and have

highlighted their usefulness for fertility research. The main conclusion is that studies on the

impact of family policies on fertility should consider the welfare-state context in which they

are embedded. Such an approach will lead to a more nuanced assessment of policy influences

and provide a more rooted understanding of estimation results. In addition, it allows scholars

to judge the potential fertility effects that policies might have if the social or economic

environment changes or if the policies are transferred to other welfare regimes. The broader

range of interpretations that the welfare-state approach offers is particularly appropriate in

evaluations of the current changes of family policies in contemporary Europe and their

influence on fertility.

During the past two decades family policies have become a highly dynamic policy area as

many European welfare states have amended their family policies to tackle “new social risks”

and to meet EU targets of raising women‟s labor-force participation, increasing childcare

availability, facilitating work-life balance, and achieving greater gender balance in work and

care. Governments also seek “best practices” in family policies, that is, options that have had

the desired effect in other countries, including the effect of raising fertility. These features

Page 28: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

28

have greatly increased research opportunities for demographers. The changes in parental-

leave and other fertility-related policies and in childcare provisions in many countries allow

us to study (a) the fertility effects of similar policies in similar welfare states, (b) the effects of

different policies in similar welfare states, (c) the effects of similar policies in different

welfare states, and (d) the effects of different policies in different welfare states. This can be

extended to explorations of the interplay between welfare regimes and economic and social

developments as well as family policies, and of their influence on fertility. Such “most-

similar” and “most different” research designs can produce more robust results as to the

impact of policies on fertility across welfare regimes and across different economic and social

environments. They allow us to better assess the influence that welfare-state and other

institutional configurations as well as family policies can have on the short- and long-term

development of fertility.

Acknowledgement: I thank Tomáš Sobotka and Tomas Frejka for Figure 1 and the

permission to reproduce it in this paper, as well as Jan Hoem and Gunnar Andersson for

editorial advice.

References

Anttonen, A. and Sipilä, J. (1996). European social care services: Is it possible to identify

models?. Journal of European Social Policy 6(2): 87-100.

Arts, W. and Gelissen, J. (2002). Three worlds of welfare capitalism or more? A state-of-the-

art report. Journal of European Social Policy 12(2): 137-158.

Benner, M. and Vad, T.B. (2000). Sweden and Denmark: Defending the welfare state. In:

Scharpf, F.W. and Schmidt, V.A. (eds.). Welfare and Work in the Open Economy. Volume

II: Diverse Responses to Common Challenges in Twelve Countries. Oxford: Oxford

University Press: 399-466.

Bledsoe, C., Banja, R. and Hill, A.G. (1998). Reproductive mishaps and Western

contraception: An African challenge to fertility theory. Population and Development

Review 24(1): 15-57.

Boeri, T., Börsch-Supan, A. and Tabellini, G. (2001). Would you like to shrink the welfare

state. A survey of European citizens. Economic Policy 16(32): 9-50.

Bonoli, G. (2005). The politics of the new social policies: Providing coverage against new

social risks in mature welfare states. Policy & Politics 33(3): 431-449.

Page 29: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

29

Bourdieu, P. (1996). On the family as a realized category. Theory, Culture & Society

13(3):19-26.

Castles, F.G. (2003). The world turned upside down: Below replacement fertility, changing

preferences and family-friendly public policy in 21 OECD countries. Journal of European

Social Policy 13(3): 209-227.

Castles, F.G. and Obinger, H. (2008). Worlds, families, regimes: Country clusters in

European and OECD area public policy. West European Politics 31(1-2): 321-344.

Cerami, A. and Vanhuysse, P. (eds.) (2009): Post-Communist Welfare Pathways. Theorizing

Social Policy Transformations in Central and Eastern Europe. New York: Palgrave

MacMillan.

Culpepper, P.D. (2007). Small states and skill specificity. Austria, Switzerland, and

interemployer cleavages in coordinated capitalism. Comparative Political Studies 40: 611-

637.

Esping-Andersen, G. (1990). The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton: Princeton

University Press.

Esping-Andersen, G. (1999). Social Foundations of Postindustrial Economies. Oxford:

Oxford University Press.

Esping-Andersen, G. with Gallie, D., Hemerijk, A. and Myers, J. (2002). Why We Need a New

Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Estévez-Abe, M. (2005). Gender bias in skills and social policies: The varieties of capitalism

perspective on sex segregation. Social Politics 12(2): 180-215.

Estévez-Abe, M. (2009). Gender, inequality and capitalism: The “varieties of capitalism” and

women. Social Politics 16(2): 182-191.

Estévez-Abe, M., Iversen, T., and Soskice, D. (2001). Social protection and the formation of

skills. A reinterpretation of welfare state. In: Hall, P. and Soskice, D. (eds.). Varieties of

Capitalism. The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford

University Press: 145-183.

Ferrera, M. (1996). The ‚Southern Model„ of welfare in social Europe. Journal of European

Social Policy 6(1): 17-37.

Flora, P. and Heidenheimer, A. (1982). The historical core and changing boundaries of the

welfare state. In: Flora, P. and Heidenheimer, A. (eds.). The Development of Welfare States

in Europe and America. New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers: 17-34.

Fraser, N. and Gordon, L. (1994). A geneology of dependence: Tracing a keyword of the U.S.

welfare state. Signs 9(2): 309-336.

Frejka, T. and Ross, J. (2001). Paths to subreplacement fertility: The empirical evidence. In:

Bulatao, R.A. and Casterline, J.B. (eds.): The Global Fertility Transition. Supplement to

Population and Development Review 27: 213-254.

Page 30: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

30

Frejka, T. and Sobotka, T. (2008). Overview chapter 1: Fertility in Europe: Diverse, delayed

and below replacement. In: Frejka, T., Sobotka, T., Hoem, J.M. and Toulemon, L. (eds.).

Childbearing trends and policies in Europe. Demographic Research 19(3): 15-36.

Frejka, T., Sobotka, T., Hoem, J.M. and Toulemon, L. (Eds.). Childbearing trends and

policies in Europe. Volume 1-3. Demographic Research 19.

Gauthier, A.H. (2007). The impact of family policies on fertility in industrialized countries: A

review of the literature. Population and Policy Review 26: 323-346.

Goldscheider, F.K. (2000). Men, children and the future of the family in the third millennium.

Futures 32: 525-538.

Goldstein, J., Sobotka, T. and Jasilioniene, A. (2009). The end of „lowest-low“ fertility?

Population and Development Review 35(4): 663-699.

Gornick, J.C., Meyers, M.K. and Ross, K.E. (1997). Supporting the employment of mothers:

Policy variation across fourteen welfare states. Journal of European Social Policy 7(1): 45-

70.

Hall, P.A. (1993). Policy paradigms, social learning, and the state: The case of economic

policymaking in Britain. Comparative Politics 25(3): 275-296.

Hall, P.A. and Soskice, D. (2001). An introduction to varieties of capitalism. In: Hall, P.A.

and Soskice, D. (eds.). Varieties of Capitalism. The Institutional Foundations of

Comparative Advantage. Oxford: Oxford University Press: 1-70.

Hoem, J.M. (2008). The impact of public policies on European fertility. In: Frejka, T.,

Sobotka, T., Hoem, J.M. and Toulemon, L. (eds.). Childbearing trends and policies in

Europe. Demographic Research 19(10): 249-259.

Hoem, J.M. and Mureşan, C. (2011). An extension of the conventional TFR. European

Journal of Population 27(4): 389-402.

Hoem, J.M., Neyer, G. and Andersson, G. (2006). Education and childlessness. The

relationship between educational field, educational level, and childlessness among Swedish

women born in 1955-59. Demographic Research 14(15):331-380.

Kalwij, A. (2010). The impact of family policy expenditure on fertility in Western Europe.

Demography 47(2): 503-519.

Korpi, W. (2000). Faces of inequality: Gender, class, and patterns of inequalities in different

types of welfare states. Social Politics 7(2): 127-189.

Knijn, T. and Kremer, M. (1997). Gender and the caring dimension of welfare states: Towards

inclusive citizenship. Social Politics 4(3): 328-361.

Leitner, S. (2003). Varieties of familialism. The caring function of the family in comparative

perspective. European Societies 5(4): 353-375.

Lewis, J. (1992). Gender and the development of welfare regimes. Journal of European

Social Policy 2(3): 159-173.

Page 31: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

31

Mahoney, J. and Thelen, K. (2010). A theory of gradual institutional change. In: Mahoney, J.

and Thelen, K. (eds.). Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power.

Cambridge: Cambridge University Press: 1-37

Mandel, H. and Semyonov, M. (2006). A welfare state paradox: State interventions and

women‟s employment opportunities in 22 countries. American Journal of Sociology 111(6):

1910-1949.

Mandel, H. and Shalev, M. (2009). Gender, class, and varieties of capitalism. Social Politics

16(2): 161-181.

Mayer, K.U. and Schoepflin, U. (1989). The state and the life course. Annual Review of

Sociology 15: 187-209.

Mayer, K.U. (2009). New directions in life course research. Annual Review of Sociology 35:

413-433.

McCall, L. and Orloff, A.S. (2005). Introduction to special issue of Social Politics: “Gender,

class, and capitalism”. Social Politics 12(2): 159-169.

McDonald, P. (2000). Gender equity theory in fertility transition. Population and

Development Review 26(3): 427-439.

McDonald, P. (2006). Low fertility and the state: The efficacy of policy. Population and

Development Review 32(3): 485-510.

McNicoll, G. (1994). Institutional analysis of fertility. Population Council Research Division

Working Paper 72.

McNicoll, G. (2001). Government and fertility in transitional and post-transitional societies.

In: Bulatao, R.A. and Casterline, J.B. (eds.): The Global Fertility Transition. Supplement to

Population and Development Review 27, Supplement: 129-159

McNicoll, G. (2009). Legacy, policy, and circumstance in fertility transition. Population and

Development Review 35(4): 777-794.

Neyer, G. (2003). Family policies and low fertility in Western Europe. Supplement to Volume

1, Journal of Population and Social Security: 46-93.

Neyer, G. (2005). Family policies in Western Europe. Fertility policies at the intersection of

gender, employment and care policies. Österreichische Zeitschrift für Politikwissenschaft:

91-102.

Neyer, G. (2011). Should governments in Europe be more aggressive in pushing for gender

equality to raise fertility? The second “No”. Demographic Research 24(10): 225-250.

Neyer, G. and Andersson, G. (2008). Consequences of family policies on childbearing:

Effects or artifacts? Population and Development Review 34(4): 699-724.

Neyer, G., Lappegård, T. and Vignoli, D. (2011). Gender equality and fertility: Which

equality matters? Stockholm Research Report on Demography SRRD_2011:9.

Page 32: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

32

Neyer, G. and Hoem, J.M. (2008). Education and permanent childlessness: Austria vs.

Sweden. A research note. In: Surkyn, J., Deboorsere, P. and Van Bavel, J. (eds.).

Demographic Challenges for the 21st Century. A State of the Art in Demography. Brussels:

VUP Press: 91-112.

Orloff, A.S. (1993). Gender and the social rights of citizenship: The comparative analysis of

gender relations and welfare states. American Sociological Review 58(3): 303-328.

Palier, B. (ed.). (2010). A Long Goodbye to Bismarck? The Politics of Welfare Reform in

Continental Europe. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press.

Pierson, P. (1996). The new politics of the welfare state. World Politics 48(2): 143-179.

Pierson, P. (2001). Coping with permanent austerity. Welfare state restructuring in affluent

democracies. In: Pierson, P. (ed.). The New Politics of the Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford

University Press: 410-456.

Policies to reconcile labor force participation and childbearing in the European Union (2006).

Population and Development Review 32(2): 389-393.

Pontusson, J. (2000). Labor market institutions and wage distribution. In: Iversen, T.,

Pontussen, J. and Soskice, D. (eds.). Employment and Central Banks. Macroeconomic

Coordination and Institutional Change in Social Market Economies. Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press: 292-330.

Rindfuss, R. and Brauner-Otto, S. (2008). Institutions at the transition to adulthood:

Implications for fertility tempo in low fertility settings. Vienna Yearbook of Population

Research: 57-87.

Rønsen, M. and Sundström, M. (2002). Family policy and after birth employment among new

mothers: A comparison of Finland, Norway and Sweden. European Journal of Population

18(2): 121-152.

Rubery, J. (2009). How gendering the varieties of capitalism requires a wider lens. Social

Politics 16(2): 192-203.

Sainsbury, D. (ed.) (1999). Gender and Welfare State Regimes. Oxford: Oxford University

Press.

Saraceno, C. (2011). Childcare needs and childcare policies: A multidimensional issue.

Current Sociology 59(1): 78-96.

Saraceno, C. and Keck, W. (2010). Can we identify intergenerational policy regimes in

Europe? European Societies 12(5): 675-696.

Scharpf, F.W. and Schmidt, V.A. (eds.) (2000). Welfare and Work in the Open Economy.

Volume I: From Vulnerability to Competitiveness in Comparative Perspective. Oxford:

Oxford University Press.

Sleebos, J. (2003). Low fertility rates in OECD countries: Facts and policy responses. OECD

Labour Market and Social Policy Occasional Papers 15.

Page 33: Welfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe .../menu/standard/file/WP_2012_10.pdfWelfare States, Family Policies, and Fertility in Europe* Gerda Neyer Stockholm University

33

Sobotka, T., Skirbekk, V. and Philipov, D. (2011). Economic recession and fertility in the

developed world. Population and Development Review 37(2): 267-306.

Soskice, D. (2005). Varieties of capitalism and cross-national gender differences. Social

Politics 12(2): 170-179.

Szelewa, D.K. and Polakowski, M.P. (2008). Who cares? Changing patterns of childcare in

Central and Eastern Europe. Journal of European Social Policy 18(2): 115-131.

Szikra, D. and Tomka, B. (2009). Social policy in East Central Europe: Major trends in the

twentieth century. In: Cerami, A. and Vanhuysse, P. (eds.): Post-Communist Welfare

Pathways. Theorizing Social Policy Transformations in Central and Eastern Europe. New

York: Palgrave MacMillan: 17-34.

Spiess, C.K. (2012). Zeit, Geld, Infrastruktur und Fertilität: Befunde empirischer

Mikrostudien und was wir daraus lernen können. In: Bertram, H. and Bujard, M. (eds.).

Zeit, Geld, Infrastruktur – zur Zukunft der Familienpolitik. Soziale Welt, Sonderband 19:

321-336.

Taylor-Gooby, P. (ed.) (2004). New Risk, New Welfare. The Transformation of the European

Welfare State. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Thelen, K. (2012). Varieties of capitalism: Trajectories of liberalization and the new politics

of social solidarity. Annual Review of Political Science 15: 137-159. First published online

as a review in advance 2011.

Thévenon, O. (2008). Family policies in Europe: Available databases and initial comparisons.

Vienna Yearbook of Population Research 2008: 165-177.

Thévenon, O. (2011). Family policies in OECD countries: A comparative analysis.

Population and Development Review 37(1): 57-87.

Thévenon, O. and Gauthier, A.H. (2011). Family policies in developed countries: A „fertility

booster‟ with side effects. Community, Work & Family 14(2): 197-216.

Wilensky, H. (1975). The Welfare State and Equality. Structural and Ideological Roots of

Public Expenditure. Berkeley: University of California Press.

United Nations (2001). National Population Policies 2001. New York: United Nations

Publications.

United Nations (2010). World Population Policies 2009. New York: United Nations

Publications.

Van Bavel, J. (2010). Subreplacement fertility in the West before the baby boom: Past and

current perspectives. Population Studies 64(1): 1-18.