tax base elasticities: a multi-state analysis of long-run and short-run dynamics

28
Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics Donald Bruce,* William F. Fox,{ and M. H. Tuttle{ We examine the relative dynamic responses of state personal tax revenues and sales tax bases to changes in state personal income. Our econometric analysis, which includes separate analyses of long-run and short-run dynamics for each state, permits the estimation of asymmetric short-run responses depending upon the relationship between current and expected tax base growth. Results indicate that the average long-run elasticity for income taxes is more than double that for sales taxes. Most states have asymmetric short-run income elasticities, which are again greater for income taxes than for sales taxes. However, a joint analysis of long- and short-run dynamics reveals that neither tax is universally more volatile. After calculating state-specific income elasticities for both taxes, we employ cross-section regression techniques to explain the variation in elasticities across states. Several policy factors are found to be important, including elements of tax bases and rate structures. JEL Codes: H2, H7 1. Introduction Generating ; sufficient revenue to finance government service delivery is arguably the most important characteristic of state tax systems because revenue collection is the primary purpose for most taxation. Despite this obvious point, collections often remain in the back seat of any economic analysis, with efficiency and equity frequently receiving the most analytical attention. Revenue is frequently introduced either as a constraint in maximization problems or by assumption, while other aspects of the tax system are analyzed. Further, the analyses are often static, meaning government revenue is only considered in a single year, with no consideration given to the dynamics of revenue performance. The poor fiscal performance of most states from 2001 through 2003 has at least temporarily brought revenue issues to the forefront. States have had difficulty in financ- ing legislated budgets—or in some cases, even maintaining past spending levels. 1 Un- fortunately, the emphasis of many political discussions has been on meeting current revenue Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:33 1 Cust # 240184 * Center for Business and Economic Research, 105 Temple Court, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996- 4334, USA; E-mail [email protected]; corresponding author. { Center for Business and Economic Research, 101 Temple Court, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996- 4334, USA; E-mail [email protected]. { Department of Economics and International Business, 237A Smith-Hutson Building, Sam Houston State University, Huntsville, TX 77341, USA; E-mail [email protected]. The authors thank Mohammed Mohsin, Robert Ebel, Robert Strauss, John Mikesell, and three anonymous referees for very helpful comments and John Deskins for very valuable research assistance. Received September 2004; accepted February 2006. 1 See Jenny (2002) for an example of the problems that states have confronted. Southern Economic Journal 2006, 73(2), 000–000 0

Upload: others

Post on 01-Mar-2022

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysisof Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Donald Bruce,* William F. Fox,{ and M. H. Tuttle{

We examine the relative dynamic responses of state personal tax revenues and sales tax bases tochanges in state personal income. Our econometric analysis, which includes separate analyses oflong-run and short-run dynamics for each state, permits the estimation of asymmetric short-runresponses depending upon the relationship between current and expected tax base growth.Results indicate that the average long-run elasticity for income taxes is more than double thatfor sales taxes. Most states have asymmetric short-run income elasticities, which are againgreater for income taxes than for sales taxes. However, a joint analysis of long- and short-rundynamics reveals that neither tax is universally more volatile. After calculating state-specificincome elasticities for both taxes, we employ cross-section regression techniques to explain thevariation in elasticities across states. Several policy factors are found to be important, includingelements of tax bases and rate structures.

JEL Codes: H2, H7

1. Introduction

Generating ;sufficient revenue to finance government service delivery is arguably the most

important characteristic of state tax systems because revenue collection is the primary purpose

for most taxation. Despite this obvious point, collections often remain in the back seat of any

economic analysis, with efficiency and equity frequently receiving the most analytical attention.

Revenue is frequently introduced either as a constraint in maximization problems or by

assumption, while other aspects of the tax system are analyzed. Further, the analyses are often

static, meaning government revenue is only considered in a single year, with no consideration

given to the dynamics of revenue performance.

The poor fiscal performance of most states from 2001 through 2003 has at least

temporarily brought revenue issues to the forefront. States have had difficulty in financ-

ing legislated budgets—or in some cases, even maintaining past spending levels.1 Un-

fortunately, the emphasis of many political discussions has been on meeting current revenue

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:33 1 Cust # 240184

* Center for Business and Economic Research, 105 Temple Court, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996-

4334, USA; E-mail [email protected]; corresponding author.

{ Center for Business and Economic Research, 101 Temple Court, University of Tennessee, Knoxville, TN 37996-

4334, USA; E-mail [email protected].

{ Department of Economics and International Business, 237A Smith-Hutson Building, Sam Houston State

University, Huntsville, TX 77341, USA; E-mail [email protected].

The authors thank Mohammed Mohsin, Robert Ebel, Robert Strauss, John Mikesell, and three anonymous

referees for very helpful comments and John Deskins for very valuable research assistance.

Received September 2004; accepted February 2006.1 See Jenny (2002) for an example of the problems that states have confronted.

Southern Economic Journal 2006, 73(2), 000–000

0

Page 2: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

goals without considering whether the revenue system is structured to collect sufficient

revenue over the long term.2 Much debate can be expected during the next several years on

the design of tax structures that can best prevent recurrence of similar fiscal crises. A clear

understanding of the dynamic properties of revenue structures is necessary so that tax

structures can be adapted to ensure they generate appropriate revenue growth in the future.3

This paper fills this gap by analyzing the factors that determine the dynamic performance

of revenue systems. This is achieved by estimating long-run and short-run income elasti-

cities for personal income taxes and general sales taxes for every state. Then, the factors that

explain the elasticity differences across states are examined to discern the implications for tax

policy.

The primary focus in this paper is on the income elasticities of the two major tax sources

relied upon by state governments, the sales and the personal income taxes. Combined, these

taxes generated 66.7% of all state tax revenue in 2004.4 Reliance on these tax instruments varies

both over time and across states. In 2004, state sales taxes raised between 14.5% of tax revenue

in Vermont and 61.3% in Tennessee.5 In 2004, state personal income taxes raised between

17.4% of revenue in North Dakota and 70.0% in Oregon. Across all states, the income tax has

grown dramatically as a share of state tax revenue, rising from 17.3% in 1967 to 33.1% in 2004.

The sales tax has also risen, although at a less robust rate, growing from 28.6% of state tax

revenue in 1967 to 33.6% in 2004.

State tax structures can be envisioned much like personal portfolios. Revenue growth and

volatility are parallels to the risk-reward framework for the portfolio, but we have little

information on the way in which growth occurs. Current experience illustrates the parallel,

since many states have seen that an adequate long-term growth rate is not necessarily sufficient

to ensure that service delivery will be properly financed on an annual basis. Further, depending

upon the particular economic environment, tax revenue growth may slow (or accelerate) more

radically than would appear consistent with long-run relationships between personal income

and revenue growth. Again, the rapidity with which revenue growth slowed for the states

during 2001 appeared to be radically different from the slow pace with which revenue growth

recovered in the 2003 to 2005 time period. Tax and financing structures must be able to pro-

vide adequate revenues during the wide array of different economic environments that may

arise. Thus, this paper not only investigates long-run elasticities but also estimates short-run

elasticities for every state and seeks to determine the differences between the short- and long-

run elasticities. Further, the econometric specifications are designed to consider whether short-

run elasticities are asymmetric, since revenues may be more responsive in certain economic

environments. Based on this information, states can not only enhance the design of their tax

structures, but they can also use careful resource planning, such as rainy day funds, to smooth

expenditures during downturns.

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:36 2 Cust # 240184

2 One example is the strong tendency for states to partially correct their revenue shortfalls with increases in specific taxes

on tobacco products. Forty states have raised their cigarette tax rates a total of 63 times since 2000. See http://

www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/cig_inc02.html.3 There is no intent in this study to identify the appropriate size of government. Revenue growth is deemed appropriate if

it is sufficient to fund the publicly desired level of expenditures as determined through the political process.4 U.S. Bureau of the Census, State Tax Collections, 2004. See also http://www.census.gov/govs/www/statetax.html.5 All percentages in this paragraph refer to states that impose the tax being discussed. State tax shares are taken from

information provided by the Federation of Tax Administrators at http://www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/04taxdis.html.

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 3: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

2. Literature Review

The literature on income elasticities and stability of state and local taxes has a long history,

though it is relatively sparse. In the seminal paper in this literature, Groves and Kahn (1952)

estimate state and local revenue elasticities and recognize that elasticities need not be constant

over time. Fox and Campbell (1984) estimate the sales tax elasticity for ten disaggregated

taxable sales categories and find the elasticities vary by sales category, average 0.59 over the

long term, and are widely variable on an annual basis. Variation occurs as the income elasticity

for taxable durable goods categories declines in recessions and rises in expansions and moves

in the opposition direction for nondurable goods. Otsuka and Braun (1999) use a random

coefficient model and generally confirm the Fox and Campbell results.

Dye and McGuire (1991) examine the elasticity and stability of both the individual in-

come and sales taxes. They conclude that the components of both the income (by income class)

and sales (by type of consumption) tax structures vary significantly and that both flat and pro-

gressive income taxes are likely to grow faster than either a broad or a narrow-based sales tax.

Sobel and Holcombe (1996) build on the Dye and McGuire analysis through the use of

time series techniques and by examining more tax instruments. A key limitation of both Dye

and McGuire and Sobel and Holcombe, however, is that their analyses rely on stylized rather

than actual tax structures. For example, Sobel and Holcombe proxy the sales tax base with

national total retail sales and nonfood retail sales. However, retail sales differ dramatically

from the sales tax bases imposed by states. Several states exempt some retail purchases be-

sides food (such as gasoline and clothing), tax a varying number of services and tax many

business purchases.6 Also, state income tax bases have very different exemption and deduction

structures and often exclude certain forms of income. For example, pension income is exempt in

many states. Differences between the actual tax base used in a state and the stylized tax bases

seen by economists occur for many reasons, including political, economic development, and

administrative factors.

The rate structures also differ from those implicit in the analyses of the earlier studies.

Many states impose multiple sales tax rates and complicated progressive income tax regimes.

Thus, earlier research is useful as exploratory steps, but fails to investigate how actual tax

structures respond to economic growth, how specific tax structure characteristics alter the

underlying elasticities, and how these relationships change over time.

This paper extends the literature on state revenue elasticities in three important ways.

First, tax elasticities are estimated for each state using actual tax base data. Thus, the estimated

relationships between bases and personal income result from the response of legislated tax bases

and rates to changing income, and the resulting wide differences across states illustrate how

important policy decisions are to the final outcome. These estimates are much more useful for

understanding the underlying determinants of tax base growth. Second, both short-run and

long-run elasticities are measured, and the short-run elasticities are allowed to be asymmetric

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:37 3 Cust # 240184

6 The actual tax structures differ widely by state from the very broad base used by Hawaii, representing 108.2% of state

personal income, to the narrow base imposed in states such as Massachusetts and New Jersey, representing about 30%

of personal income. Values are drawn from calculations prepared by the authors using data from State Government

Finances, U.S. Bureau of the Census and tax rates obtained from various sources. See Ring (1999) for state estimates of

the extent to which business purchases are included in the base. An overview of state taxation of services as well as

exemptions for certain categories of tangible goods is provided by the Federation of Tax Administrators at http://

www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/tax_stru.html. We return to these issues below.

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 4: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

based on the direction of underlying disequilibrium. Third, the study directly examines the

determinants of the variation in elasticities across states. This allows states to better understand

what policy decisions affect revenue responses and what state characteristics cause revenues to

grow differently across states.

3. Econometric Specification

Several steps are required to estimate the long-run elasticities, short-run elasticities, and

any asymmetries that may exist in the short run. This section describes the econometric

methods used to estimate the tax elasticities. First, we estimate long-run elasticities using

a single-equation cointegration technique, namely Dynamic Ordinary Least Squares (DOLS)

(Stock and Watson 1993).7 These estimated elasticities measure the long-run, stable

relationships between state tax bases and state personal income. Next, we estimate short-run

elasticities and speed of adjustment parameters for each tax instrument via an error correction

model, which restricts the tax base to adjust toward the estimated long-term relationship. This

method follows that employed by Sobel and Holcombe (1996). We further contribute to the

current literature by introducing a model that allows and tests for asymmetric responses in both

the short-run tax base elasticity and long-run speed of adjustment for each state. Finally, we

estimate cross-sectional regressions to examine the possible determinants of these elasticities.

Long-Run Income Elasticities

Over long time periods, sales and personal income tax bases in each state depend upon the

level of state personal income as follows:

Bit ~ f i I i

t

� �ð1Þ

In Equation 1, for state i in year t, B denotes the natural log of the current period tax

measure and I denotes the natural log of personal income. Caution must be observed when

using time-series data to estimate relationships such as this, since the use of non-stationary

time-series observations may produce spurious results.8 Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) tests

(Dickey and Fuller 1981) suggest that the natural logs of sales tax bases, personal income tax

revenues, and personal income in each state contain a unit root, or are non-stationary.9

However, the risk of spurious regression is eliminated if the variables in question tend to move

together over a long period of time (i.e., if they are cointegrated). Although the presence of

cointegration removes the problem of spurious regression, several other problems can arise in

the context of time series regression via OLS. These problems include serial correlation, non-

normally distributed residuals, and endogeneity.10 Personal income shares a theoretical long-

run relationship with both the sales tax base and the personal income tax base, mitigating the

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:38 4 Cust # 240184

7 See Ludvigson and Steindel (1999) for an example of the use of this technique.8 See Granger and Newbold (1974).9 From the ADF tests, all series appear to be integrated of order one and first-difference stationary. All ADF results are

available from the authors upon request.10 While the lack of a suitable instrumental variable precludes thorough testing for endogeneity, we provide evidence of

serial correlation in the analysis that follows.

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 5: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

possibility of spurious regression. We further correct for the deficiencies of OLS by using

DOLS to estimate the long-run elasticity of each tax base with respect to personal income. The

DOLS specification, which provides a correction for bias and serial correlation, is as follows:

Bit ~ bi

0 z bi1I i

t zXj

g~{j

cigDI i

tzg z Qit ð2Þ

Equation 2 is estimated separately for each tax base, and the long-run elasticity of the specific

tax base with respect to personal income in state i is given by b1.11 The j leads and lags of the

change in personal income represent the DOLS correction to adjust for possible endogeneity

and autocorrelation.12 We use standard delta notation to denote first differences of our key

variables.

Symmetric Short-Run Elasticities

Changes in long-run equilibrium tax bases caused by changes in personal income may not

be fully realized until after an adjustment period. More importantly, stability between tax bases

and personal income need not hold in the short run; any differences between short and long-run

income elasticities create deviations between the long-run equilibrium base and the current

period base. Therefore, actual bases from either tax for state i (denoted by Bt) may be above or

below the long-run equilibrium value (denoted by Bt*) in any period. In Equation 3, the current

period value of e measures the deviations of the respective actual tax base in period t from its

long-run equilibrium value. These short-run deviations occur when the immediate effect of

a change in personal income is different from the long-run effect.

Bit ~ Bi�

t ~ eit ~ Bi

t { bi0 { bi

1I it ð3Þ

Thus, two short-run effects can exist in any time period: tax bases can respond to changes

in personal income and tax bases can adjust according to the disequilibrium (e) that exists at the

beginning of the period. The selected econometric approach must capture both of these short-

run effects, and this is achieved with an error-correction model (ECM):

Bit { Bi

t{1 ~ ai0 z ai

1 I it { I i

t{1

� �z ai

2 eit{1 z mi

t ð4Þ

The ECM involves separate regressors to measure each of these effects. The a1 parameter in

Equation 4 captures the immediate, intra-period effects of a change in personal income; it is

a measure of the short-run income elasticity.

One point of interest is how the short-run tax base elasticities differ from the long-run

elasticities. The econometric specification used here allows for direct comparison between the

two. The short-run tax base response to personal income changes is smaller or greater than the

long-run response according to whether a1 is less than or greater than b1. Another interesting

question is how fast tax bases move toward a new long-run equilibrium brought about by

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:39 5 Cust # 240184

11 In Equations 2–5, B denotes the natural log of the current period tax measure and I denotes the natural log of

personal income.12 The appropriate number of leads and lags varies between states and is determined using the Schwarz Bayesian

Criterion (1978). Standard errors in this paper are calculated using the method of Newey and West (1987).

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 6: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

changes in personal income. The a2 parameter in Equation 4 measures the size of adjustment of

the tax base to its long-run equilibrium value, and gives the percentage of disequilibrium that

is removed in every period.13 Therefore, the larger the absolute value of this adjustment

parameter, the faster the tax base moves toward its long-run value.

Asymmetric Short-Run Income Elasticities

The short-run elasticity in Equation 4 is the same regardless of whether the respective tax

base measure is below (et less than zero) or above (et greater than zero) its long-run equilibrium

value. However, it is reasonable to expect that either tax base could exhibit an asymmetric

response as a result of state structural considerations, differences in household behavior, or

other factors.

The ECM can be modified to allow for the presence of any asymmetry, as shown in

Equation 5:

DBit ~ ai

0 z ai1DI i

t z hi1 DBi

t � DI it

� �z ai

2 eit{1 z hi

2 DBit{1 � ei

t{1

� �z ni

t ð5Þ

A dummy variable (DBt) is inserted to identify the tax measure’s position relative to its

equilibrium value.14 This dummy equals zero if the respective tax measure is below its long-run

equilibrium value and one if it is above equilibrium.15 The model specification given by

Equation 5 allows for separate measurement of an asymmetric short-run elasticity and

adjustment parameter.

The revised econometric method provides the ability to estimate differences between short-

run and long-run elasticities and determine whether the short-run elasticities vary according to

the projected future growth in taxes. For example, the respective tax base measure will adjust

upward in the future if it is below long-run equilibrium (et less than zero). Examining whether

h1 is statistically different from zero allows a test of whether this upward adjustment is different

relative to the downward future adjustment when bases are above equilibrium. Asymmetry in

the long-run adjustment of either tax base is determined by the statistical significance of h2.

4. Data Issues

We use annual time series data for 1967 through 2000 to estimate all long-run and short-

run elasticities and adjustment parameters separately for the sales and income tax for each

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:39 6 Cust # 240184

13 The total disequilibrium removed after t periods is given by 1 2 (1 + a2)t.14 Here, a modified version of the method developed by Granger and Lee (1989) is employed. Granger and Lee separate

the error-correction term into its positive and negative elements. Here, a dummy is added to signify the positive and

negative elements of the error-correction term to measure any asymmetries in the short-run adjustment and to allow

for the measurement of any asymmetries in the short-run elasticity. See Cook, Holly, and Turner (1999) for another

application. For an additional method, see Enders and Siklos (2001).15 Specifically, DBt takes the value of zero when et is less than zero and one when it is above zero. While this strategy

identifies asymmetry on the basis of base/revenue growth relative to personal income growth, a potentially more easily

interpretable approach would define asymmetry on the basis of income fluctuations in isolation. Experimentation with

such approaches (e.g., where DBttakes the value of one in times of recession or relatively slow income growth) left us

unable to identify any asymmetry at all. This is likely because there were not enough recession or slow growth years

with which to identify asymmetric responses.

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 7: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

state. Selection of the dependent variables for the sales and income taxes is a key decision in the

analysis. As we have noted, much previous work has relied upon national proxies for state tax

bases. There are two main reasons why we choose to use actual state data rather than national

proxies. First, our approach allows us to develop state-specific elasticity estimates and to

investigate the causes of the wide differences in estimated elasticities across the states. It seems

very likely that elasticities would vary with state-specific tax base characteristics, such as

progressive income tax rates or the extent to which services are taxed by the sales tax. Long-run

elasticities may also be affected by the causes of economic growth, which might be influenced

by the state economic structure. State-specific tax estimates are necessary to study issues such as

how the elasticity is affected by the interplay between the differing state economies and tax

performance. This would not be possible with national proxies.

Second, and more importantly, extensive differences exist between any possible proxies

and the actual bases observed in each state. As a result, state-specific data are necessary to

measure elasticities in the context of the actual tax institutions used across the United States.

State structures also differ so greatly that it is necessary to estimate each state’s elas-

ticity independently. The most significant difference is that approximately 40% of the sales

tax is paid on intermediate purchases (Ring 1999), and this portion of the base will not be

reflected in national consumption proxies used by other analysts. Various components of

retail sales or consumption (from national income accounts) do not include these inter-

mediate purchases, which are large shares of the sales tax base in every state.16 This is not to say

that taxation of intermediate purchases is good tax policy, but it is a large part of actual tax

bases, and it is not possible to examine actual sales tax elasticities with this part of the base

excluded.

State treatment of consumer purchases also differs widely from measures of consumption

in the economic data. For example, 30 states exempt food for consumption at home, seven

exempt some clothing, all but one exempt prescription drugs, 10 exempt nonprescription drugs,

and states tax between 14 (Colorado) and 160 (Hawaii) of the 168 categories of services

enumerated by the Federation of Tax Administrators (FTA).17 The problem is exacerbated

by the radical differences in state definitions of taxable food, clothing, services, and other

transactions.

Figure 1 illustrates the importance of the sales tax base choice.18 Personal consumption

has risen during the time series, from about 62% to 70% of GDP. Retail sales have been slightly

volatile but are nearly the same share of GDP at the beginning and end of the panel. The simple

average of all statss’ actual sales tax bases, on the other hand, is consistently much larger than

retail sales (because the taxation of business inputs and services exceeds exemption of goods)

but has declined from 53.2% of GDP in 1979 to 40.1% in 2003. Observation of these data series

evidences the definitional differences between actual sales tax bases and economic data and

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:41 7 Cust # 240184

16 As a general rule, states exempt goods purchased for resale and goods that become component parts of other goods.

This means that states frequently tax a range of intermediate purchases including computers, software, cash registers,

services, packaging and many other items.17 See the wealth of state tax rule information provided by the FTA at http://www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/tax_stru.html.18 Data in Figure 1 are taken from: retail sales, U.S. Department of Commerce, Advanced Monthly Sales for Retail and

Food Services; consumption, National Income Accounts, Bureau of Economic Analysis; and state sales tax bases are

drawn from calculations prepared by the authors using data from State Government Finances, U.S. Bureau of the

Census and tax rates obtained from various sources.

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 8: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

how these series are diverging over time.19 Differences in state definitions of the actual tax base

are even broader than the divergence from economic data. Hawaii’s tax base was 92.6% of

GSP in 2000, while Rhode Island’s base was only 27.5% of GSP in the same year. Proxies

cannot reasonably be used to account for the differences arising from state-specific policy

choices.

Similar cross-state differences exist for the income tax. Twenty-seven states start

calculation of the personal income tax with federal adjusted gross income, leaving the state

free to set deductions and exemptions, if any are used at all, according to state preferences. Ten

states start with federal taxable income, meaning federal exemptions and deductions are

accepted. Four states do not explicitly start with a federal definition of income.20 In every case,

states make adjustments to income after the starting point. For example, all but three states

allow some personal exemption, but the amounts vary significantly. Some states exempt all or

part of pension income. States do not allow deduction of state income taxes, but eight states

allow deduction of federal income tax paid. Tax structures in 14 states are at least partially

indexed for inflation. National proxies, such as personal income or GSP, cannot allow for

these cross-state differences, and at best can be seen as some type of average income across

states that does not capture actual tax institutions. Further, these measures often do not include

capital gains and some other forms of non-labor income that have been an important part of

taxable income. National tax measures, such as adjusted gross income or taxable income, are

closer to state tax measures. However, these proxies cannot account for the differences in state

practice.

State data on the income and sales tax bases, the preferred dependent variables, are

unfortunately not directly available. Actual state sales tax bases are measured here as state sales

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:41 8 Cust # 240184

19 Likely causes of the decline in state sales tax bases over time include policy decisions to narrow the base (such as new

exemptions of food for consumption at home), different growth rates of taxable and nontaxable transactions, and

inability of states to collect the tax on rapidly growing remote sales.

Figure 1. Personal Consumption, General Sales, and Retail Sales as a Percentage of GDP

20 Again, see the FTA resources at http://www.taxadmin.org/fta/rate/inc_stp.html.

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 9: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

tax revenue divided by the general state sales tax rate.21 While many states impose rates that

differ from the general rate on a narrow set of transactions, the resulting difference between the

estimated and actual bases will be very small. In fact, the only variation from the actual tax

base could arise because tax credits could alter the timing of sales tax receipts between fiscal

years. The income tax is measured here using actual revenues rather than the base because 35

states impose progressive rates and the quotient obtained by dividing income tax revenue by

the maximum rate will differ significantly from the actual income tax base.22 Based on the

significant limitations of alternative tax base proxies, we believe that our resulting elasticity

estimates are much better measures of actual state relationships than would be obtained using

non-tax proxies for tax bases.

State tax revenue data are drawn from the U.S. Census,23 with each tax base measure

adjusted for inflation using the GDP deflator. Specifically, we estimate the relationships

between inflation-adjusted tax bases and inflation-adjusted personal income. Factors besides

personal income that can influence the pattern of tax bases, such as legislated base changes, are

taken into account in our cross-section analysis.24

5. Empirical Results

Long-Run Income Elasticities

We estimate Equations 2 and 5 separately for each state and provide average parameter

estimates across the states for the sales tax in Table 1 and the income tax in Table 2. State-

specific estimates are shown in Figures 2 and 3 and Tables 3 and 4. The average parameter

estimates appear very reasonable, but there are significant differences across the states, as

expected. The average long-run income tax elasticity is 1.832, which is more than twice the

average sales tax elasticity. The difference between the average long-run sales tax and income

tax elasticities is statistically significant at the 99% level of confidence. Both are significantly

different from one, with income tax revenues growing significantly faster than personal income

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:50 9 Cust # 240184

21 This approach has been used in a number of other papers. See Mikesell (2004) for an example.22 The resulting coefficient estimates from these types of regressions are often termed buoyancy measures rather than

elasticities because the relationship between the dependent variable—revenues—and personal income includes

influences from rate and base changes. However, in our cross-section analysis we separate out the effects of base and

rate changes on the elasticity estimates and simulate the elasticities for each state net of rate changes.23 Tax revenue data used in this paper are taken from U.S. Bureau of the Census, State Government Finances, annual.

See also http://www.census.gov/govs/www/state.html.24 Another important issue that we are not able to explore in this framework is the possible spatial relationships between

state tax base elasticities, or the notion that one state’s elasticities are related to those in similar or surrounding states.

Such an analysis would be a worthwhile addition to the literature but is left for future research.

Table 1. Average State Sales Tax Elasticities

Mean Variance

Long-run sales tax elasticity 0.811 0.048Short-run sales tax elasticity above equilibrium 1.804 7.179Short-run sales tax elasticity below equilibrium 0.149 0.880Sales tax adjustment parameter above equilibrium 20.332 0.054Sales tax adjustment parameter below equilibrium 20.513 0.150

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 10: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

and sales tax bases growing slower than personal income. The long-run income tax elasticity

estimate is greater than the long-run sales tax elasticity estimate in every state that employs

both taxes (see Tables 3 and 4).25,26 The relative sizes of the long-run elasticities are consistent

with the change in the share of revenues raised by these two taxes.

The highest sales tax elasticity, at 1.365, occurs in Massachusetts, and the lowest, at 0.339,

occurs in North Dakota (see Table 3 and Figure 2). Only nine states have sales tax elasticities

above 1.0, and in four cases the difference from 1.0 is statistically significant. Individual state

income tax elasticities vary widely (see Table 4 and Figure 3). The estimate for the income tax

elasticity is only below 1.0 in two states, North Dakota and Vermont, and is only significantly

below 1.0 in North Dakota.27 Thirteen states have income tax elasticities above two, and in five

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:46:51 10 Cust # 240184

27 The North Dakota elasticity is not significantly different from zero.

Table 2. Average State Income Tax Elasticities

Mean Variance

Long-run personal income tax elasticity 1.832 0.427Short-run personal income tax elasticity above equilibrium 2.663 5.014Short-run personal income tax elasticity below equilibrium 0.217 2.180Personal income tax adjustment parameter above equilibrium 20.618 0.192Personal income tax adjustment parameter below equilibrium 20.411 0.090

Figure 2. Long-Run Sales Tax Elasticities

25 No sales tax elasticity is calculated for Indiana because personal income and sales tax revenues are not cointegrated.

No income tax elasticity is calculated for Connecticut because the tax was only introduced in 1991, leaving only a short

time series of revenue data.26 This result continues to hold for all states except Massachusetts when we adjust the income tax elasticities for rate

changes using the cross-section results. Adjusted elasticities are provided in Appendix 2.

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 11: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

cases the elasticity is significantly above two. As shown in Figure 4, the distribution of income

tax elasticities is much wider than for the sales tax.

It is difficult to compare our results with earlier research because those studies used

different econometric methods and generally relied on national proxies rather than state-level

analysis. A comparison with Dye and McGuire (1991) is particularly difficult because they

estimate growth rates for various tax alternatives and components of the base rather than

elasticities. Our income tax elasticity estimates for the average state are higher than Sobel and

Holcombe (1996) find for the national proxies, and 34 of 40 states have a higher long-run

elasticity than their national estimate. This is expected given our use of relatively more variable

state-specific data. Our average sales tax estimate, on the other hand, is in the middle of those

presented by Sobel and Holcombe. With that said, we find essentially no state to have sales tax

elasticity as high as their high-end estimate.

Short-Run Elasticities and Adjustment Parameters

Short-run estimates are generated using the error correction model that allows for

asymmetric income elasticities and rates of adjustment when the above and below equilibrium

estimates are significantly different (Equation 5). Otherwise, the coefficients are from the

symmetric model (Equation 4). The primary focus from a policy perspective is on the collection

of revenues within a fiscal year rather than on the more narrowly defined relationship between

bases and income. As previously described, the change in bases during any year is the net of two

effects: (1) the change in bases in response to any change in personal income and (2) the

adjustment to eliminate any existing disequilibrium. Thus, it is important to evaluate both

effects and how they interact. As the results are discussed, each effect is considered separately

and then the net impact is evaluated.

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:00 11 Cust # 240184

Figure 3. Long-Run Personal Income Tax Elasticities

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 12: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:10 12 Cust # 240184

Table 3. Sales Tax Elasticities

Long-Run

Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticities Speed of Adjustment

When Current

Revenue Value is

below Long-Run

Equilibrium

When Current

Revenue Value is

above Long-Run

Equilibrium

When Current

Revenue Value is

below Long-Run

Equilibrium

When Current

Revenue Value is

above Long-Run

Equilibrium

Alabama 0.712** 0.050 1.120** 20.152 20.152Arizona 0.744** 21.232** 1.452** 20.742** 20.742**Arkansas 0.835** 0.323 1.398** 20.915** 20.113California 0.833** 21.408** 1.146** 21.874** 20.193Colorado 0.781** 1.869** 1.869** 20.183* 20.183*Connecticut 1.242** 1.152** 2.781** 20.168* 20.168*Florida 0.926** 20.049 1.445** 20.528** 20.528**Georgia 0.708** 0.171 1.209** 20.263** 20.263**Hawaii 1.110** 0.629** 1.285** 20.476** 20.476**Idaho 0.847** 0.665** 1.456** 20.246** 20.246**Illinois 0.871** 0.028 0.028 20.226 20.226Indiana — 0.723* 0.723* — —Iowa 0.374** 20.056 0.853** 20.850** 20.850**Kentucky 0.654** 0.826** 0.826** 20.255** 20.255**Kansas 0.630** 0.466* 0.466* 20.119 20.119Louisiana 0.514** 20.347 1.531** 20.182* 20.182*Maine 0.904** 20.857 1.047 20.380** 20.380**Maryland 0.767** 1.162** 1.162** 20.154 20.154Massachusetts 1.365** 0.354 2.375** 20.320** 20.320**Michigan 0.772** 20.017 1.713** 20.511** 20.511**Minnesota 0.876** 20.226 0.903** 21.082** 20.409*Mississippi 0.486** 20.188 1.340** 20.262* 20.262*Missouri 0.639** 22.192** 0.907* 20.612** 20.612**Nebraska 0.431* 0.191 18.779** 20.905** 20.905**Nevada 0.781** 20.500 1.600** 20.506** 20.506**New Jersey 1.049** 20.297 1.552** 20.601** 20.601**New Mexico 0.924** 20.628 3.070** 21.188** 20.399*New York 0.750** 0.128 1.571** 20.438** 20.438**North Carolina 0.874** 0.501 1.820** 21.045** 20.124North Dakota 0.339 0.256 20.506* 20.483** 0.260Ohio 1.033** 1.802** 1.802** 20.357** 20.357**Oklahoma 0.695** 1.890** 1.890** 20.124* 20.124*Pennsylvania 1.069** 1.504** 1.504** 20.216** 20.216**Rhode Island 0.531** 0.515 1.848** 20.124 20.124South Carolina 0.773** 21.150 1.143** 20.510** 20.510**South Dakota 1.145** 0.471** 0.471** 20.562** 20.562**Tennessee 0.716** 0.308 1.271** 20.240* 20.240*Texas 0.997** 1.580** 1.580** 20.749** 20.749**Utah 0.873** 21.544 1.780** 20.234** 20.234**Virginia 0.800** 20.645 0.826** 20.293** 20.293**Vermont 0.735** 0.779 2.289** 20.840** 20.061Washington 0.740** 0.045 1.722** 21.404** 20.546**West Virginia 1.013** 21.146 3.295** 20.829** 20.106Wisconsin 1.113** 20.623 1.373 20.289** 20.289**Wyoming 0.720** 1.443** 1.443** 20.134 20.134

Bold, italicized, and underlined type indicate statistically significant differences from one, two, and three, respectively,

at the 5% level. Bold type for speed of adjustment results indicates that the coefficient is not statistically different from 21.0.

* Statistically significant differences from zero at the 10% level.

** Statistically significant differences from zero at the 5% level.

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 13: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:12 13 Cust # 240184

Table 4. Personal Income Tax Elasticities

Long-Run

Elasticity

Short-Run Elasticities Speed of Adjustment

When Current

Revenue Value is

Below Long-Run

Equilibrium

When Current

Revenue Value is

Above Long-Run

Equilibrium

When Current

Revenue Value is

Below Long-Run

Equilibrium

When Current

Revenue Value is

Above Long-Run

Equilibrium

Alabama 1.823** 1.393** 3.009** 20.221 21.216**Arizona 1.140** 0.768** 0.768** 20.271** 20.271**Arkansas 2.102** 0.833 0.833 20.508** 20.508**California 1.749** 21.536 3.223** 20.718** 20.718**Colorado 1.256** 21.040 0.962* 20.181* 20.181*Delaware 1.018** 20.885 1.088* 20.174* 20.174*Georgia 1.690** 0.130 1.199** 20.172** 20.172**Hawaii 1.320** 20.786 2.013** 20.667** 20.667**Idaho 1.565** 20.001 2.382** 20.683** 20.683**Illinois 1.565** 0.298 2.882** 21.017** 21.017**Indiana 2.435** 20.783 1.702** 0.445 20.611**Iowa 2.349** 1.176** 22.679 20.256** 20.256**Kentucky 2.600** 0.465 0.465 0.015 0.015Kansas 2.260** 0.461 6.223** 20.609** 20.609**Louisiana 2.272** 1.123 8.938** 20.292* 21.176**Maine 2.873** 0.403 2.639** 20.051 21.638**Maryland 1.183** 0.510* 1.986** 20.814** 20.814**Massachusetts 1.415** 0.538 1.660** 20.248** 21.548**Michigan 1.879** 0.570 3.210** 20.366** 20.366**Minnesota 1.320** 20.128 2.300** 20.262 20.930**Mississippi 1.910** 2.400** 2.400** 20.563** 20.563**Missouri 2.292** 0.046 6.242** 20.370** 21.784**Montana 1.604** 20.486 2.313** 20.392** 20.392**Nebraska 2.491** 1.170* 1.170* 20.811** 20.811**New Jersey 2.016** 20.195 2.031** 20.470** 20.470**New Mexico 3.024** 26.223 8.370* 20.207** 20.207**New York 1.295** 21.169* 2.160** 20.309** 20.309**North Carolina 1.545** 0.767** 2.505** 20.265** 21.181**North Dakota 0.809 0.197 0.197 20.298** 20.298**Ohio 3.983** 22.479 2.529* 20.956** 20.136Oklahoma 2.613** 1.731** 4.250** 20.434** 20.434**Oregon 1.440** 0.100 4.333** 20.991** 20.991**Pennsylvania 1.431** 2.042** 5.736** 20.312** 0.064Rhode Island 1.756** 2.344** 2.344** 20.841** 20.311*South Carolina 1.564** 1.536** 1.536** 20.550** 20.550**Utah 1.477** 1.379** 1.379** 20.827** 20.827**Virginia 1.474** 0.140 1.775** 20.655** 20.655**Vermont 0.974** 0.218 0.218 20.549** 20.549**West Virginia 2.569** 1.681* 4.770** 20.296** 20.296**Wisconsin 1.215** 0.186 2.534** 20.485** 20.485**

Bold, italicized, and underlined type indicate statistically significant differences from one, two, and three,

respectively, at the 5% level. Bold type for speed of adjustment results indicates that the coefficient is not statistically

different from 21.0.

* Statistically significant differences from zero at the 10% level.

** Statistically significant differences from zero at the 5% level.

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 14: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Sales Tax Results

Consider sales tax effects arising from a change in personal income (elasticity response).

As shown in Table 1, the mean short-run sales tax elasticity is much greater when the base is

above equilibrium (1.80) than when it is below equilibrium (0.15). Estimates for individual

states differ widely, and in most states, an asymmetric base elasticity is found. Only 11 states

have symmetric short-run sales tax elasticities, with the other 33 states having different short-

run elasticities depending on the direction of disequilibrium (see Table 3).28 The short-run

above-equilibrium elasticity is only below the long-run elasticity in three states: Illinois, Kansas,

and South Dakota. Tax bases respond slowly to an increase in personal income when they are

below the long-run level. The base (and tax revenues) is most likely to be below equilibrium

during a recession or sluggish economic growth period, so the low elasticity suggests that the

revenue rebound will not be affected very much by whether personal income growth during the

recovery is rapid or slow. Yet, the high above-equilibrium short-run elasticities provide

evidence that the base is more responsive to a change in personal income when it is adjusting

downward toward its long-run value.

Second, consider the adjustment to the long-run equilibrium. The speed of adjustment

coefficient is negative on average both when the base is above and below expectations

(Table 1), but the effect is to reduce the base when it is above expectations and raise it when it is

below expectations (see Equation 3).29 Of course, the effect of adjustment on the actual base is

greater when the base is farther from equilibrium (since the effect is the coefficient times the

disequilibrium). The average below-equilibrium adjustment parameter is greater in absolute

value than the average above-equilibrium adjustment parameter suggesting a greater response

to disequilibrium below expectations, but the two parameters are only significantly different in

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:14 14 Cust # 240184

Figure 4. Long-Run Elasticities

28 The revenue elasticity for the sales tax in North Dakota is excluded here.29 Positive adjustment parameters are estimated for several states for both the income and sales taxes but the parameters

are never statistically different from zero.

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 15: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

nine states. Thus, the amount of disequilibrium eliminated in each year is generally the same

whether revenues are above or below equilibrium.

The below-equilibrium and above-equilibrium adjustment parameters are not significantly

different from 21.0 for twelve and four states, respectively, indicating that the disequilibrium is

entirely eliminated for these states in the following year. It takes more than one year to

eliminate disequilibrium in all other states. A relationship appears to exist between the size of

the short-run elasticity and the rate of adjustment. The adjustment parameter and short-run

elasticity are positively correlated (0.362) when the base is below expectations and are

negatively correlated (20.370) when the base is above expectations, and both of these

correlation coefficients are statistically significantly different from zero at the 95% level.

The dynamic base change in any year is the combination of the elasticity response and the

adjustment to disequilibrium. Figure 5 illustrates the dynamic sales tax response in two states.30

Panels A and B show the simulated below-equilibrium response when the base begins 1% below

equilibrium and when real personal income grows by 1%. The long-run equilibrium base index

rises by 0.712 in Alabama and by 0.833 in Arkansas because of the one-percent income growth.

Yet, the actual base grows slowly in Alabama because the short-run elasticity is very small

(0.05) and the adjustment coefficient is very low (20.152), meaning little of the preexisting

disequilibrium is eliminated in each year and much of the disequilibrium remains after ten

years. Conversely, Arkansas has a somewhat larger short-run elasticity (0.323) and adjusts to

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:21 15 Cust # 240184

Figure 5. Dynamic Sales Tax Responses—A Comparison between Alabama and Arkansas

30 These simulations examine the effect of a one-time increase in personal income.

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 16: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

disequilibrium more rapidly (20.915). The entire disequilibrium is nearly eliminated after two

years. In the case of a similar income increase when both states are above equilibrium (see

Panels C and D), both states overshoot the expected base increase, and neither fully eliminates

the disequilibrium after ten years.

Several conclusions can be made about the dynamics of sales tax base responses. First,

states are affected very differently by cyclical and trend growth conditions, since the parameter

estimates differ widely by state. Second, tax bases grow less than would be expected from the

short-run elasticity when above equilibrium and faster than would be expected when below

equilibrium because of the adjustment to any preexisting disequilibrium. Results for the short-

run below-equilibrium elasticities and the adjustment parameters are consistent with the res-

ponse of durable goods purchases and business input purchases in the early stages of economic

recovery, depending more on the degree to which expenditure levels have fallen below long-run

equilibrium than on the speed with which income recovers. Another conclusion is that the

relative size of the two effects can vary, depending on how fast personal income changes and

how far tax bases are from their long-run equilibrium. This means the simple relationship

between income and base growth could take any sign. For example, the base could decline as

income rises (when above equilibrium) if the extent of disequilibrium is large relative to the in-

come growth or if the adjustment parameter is large relative to the short-run elasticity. Further,

the statistical estimates indicate that the adjustment parameter is much greater relative to the

short-run elasticity when the base is below expectations than when it is above expectations.

Thus, revenues are much more likely to rise noticeably above expectations (at least for a short

time) than to fall below them. This general logic applies to the income tax results that follow.

Income Tax Results

The pattern of income tax responses is similar to the sales tax (see Tables 2 and 4). Thirty

states have statistically different short-run elasticities depending on whether the base is above

or below equilibrium, while the remaining ten states have symmetric elasticities. The mean

above-equilibrium short-run elasticity (2.66) is much greater than either the long-run elasticity

(1.83) or the below-equilibrium short-run elasticity (0.22). The short-run above-equilibrium

elasticity is below the long-run elasticity in 12 states.

The average short-run sales and income tax elasticities are very similar and not

significantly different when the bases are below their respective long-run equilibrium values.31

As noted above, both taxes have short-run elasticities that are very small when the base is below

equilibrium. Further, while the average short-run elasticities differ by nearly 0.9 when the base

is above expectations, the standard deviations are relatively large, so this difference is not

statistically significant. One distinction between the income and sales tax results is that the

speed of adjustment is greater above equilibrium for the income tax (i.e., the absolute value of

the adjustment coefficient is greater above equilibrium than below equilibrium).

Nonetheless, the adjustment parameters for the income tax are the same for most states,

with only 11 states having a different adjustment parameter when above and below equilibrium.

The above-equilibrium adjustment parameter is not statistically different from 21.0 for 12

states and the below-equilibrium adjustment parameter is not statistically different from 21.0

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:27 16 Cust # 240184

31 The associated p-value is 0.79.

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 17: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

for nine states, suggesting that the entire disequilibrium is eliminated in one year for these

states.

Very different income tax responses are found across the states. For example, Louisiana

has a very high response to personal income growth when the base is above equilibrium, but the

entire disequilibrium is eliminated in the following year.32 On the other hand, New Mexico has

very high elasticity without the rapid adjustment to equilibrium.

6. Which Tax Is More Volatile?

Overall, the estimates do not provide a firm conclusion as to whether the sales or the

income tax is more volatile, with the conclusion depending upon the definition of volatility. The

income tax has a higher long-run elasticity, but that simply means that revenues grow faster

over long periods of time—it tells little about whether the growth path is volatile. Nonetheless,

discussions of volatility have often focused on the long-run elasticity. Volatility is inherently

a short-run issue and is best considered in the context of how an actual tax base (or revenue)

performs relative to its long-run equilibrium value and how much it fluctuates around the

equilibrium during short time periods or different segments of the business cycle.

Conditions when tax bases (and revenues) will be above or below expectations can be

parallel to specific economic environments, though not precisely. Both sales tax bases and

income tax revenues are likely to be above long-run equilibrium during strong growth periods,

such as the late 1990s. The base and revenues are likely to be below long-run equilibrium during

the latter stages of a recession or economic slowdown, as during the early years of the 2000s.

Thus, both taxes will respond gradually as income begins to grow more rapidly at the end of the

economic slowdown, but the total rise in the tax measure will be larger in cases when the extent

of disequilibrium has gotten to be relatively large (because of the adjustment parameter).

Figure 6 illustrates dynamic responses of both the income and sales tax bases for periods

above and below equilibrium using average state parameter estimates and similar assumptions

to Figure 5. The long-run income tax response to a one-percent income increase is twice as

large as for the sales tax, as determined by the long-run elasticities. Given that the short-run

below-equilibrium elasticities are approximately the same, the income tax response will be

much further below equilibrium than the sales tax response (Panels A and B of Figure 6). In

this sense, the income tax is more volatile. However, adjustment to the new equilibrium takes

approximately the same time for both taxes (the income tax takes slightly longer), leaving the

question of relative volatility unanswered.

Differences between the two taxes are also evident in the above-equilibrium scenarios in

Panels C and D of Figure 6. First, it should be noted that the relative extent of disequilibrium

will be greater for the sales tax than for the income tax because the difference between the

short-run above-equilibrium elasticity and the long-run elasticity is greater for the sales tax

(1.804 vs. 0.811) than for the income tax (2.663 vs. 1.832). However, the adjustment para-

meter is larger for the income tax (20.618 vs. 20.332), so the reaction to any amount of

disequilibrium will be greater for the income tax. As shown in Figure 6, the sales tax has the

greater increase relative to the new equilibrium, suggesting that the sales tax can be the more

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:28 17 Cust # 240184

32 The point estimate for the adjustment parameter is not significantly different from 21.0.

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 18: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

volatile tax in above-equilibrium scenarios. The sales tax base adjusts to the new equilibrium

more slowly than the income tax. In sum, the answer to the question of relative volatility

depends upon the particular economic situation at hand.

7. Causes of State Variation in Base Elasticities

While the preceding analysis sheds important light on the differences in tax base elasticities

both across states and over time, the chosen econometric methodology is not designed to

explain the resulting cross-state differences. Toward that end, we now turn to estimates of

cross-section OLS regressions to determine whether the estimated cross-state differences in tax

base elasticities can be explained by observable factors. We estimate separate cross-section

regressions for each vector of estimated parameters (i.e., long-run elasticities, short-run

elasticities, and adjustment parameters for each of the two taxes), but only provide detailed

models of the long-run elasticity models here.

Equation Structure

The regression structure is not drawn from a formal theoretical framework, but is a policy

experiment to provide greater relevance to the findings by identifying features that are

associated with cross-state differences in the elasticities. Quite simply, we are seeking to identify

what factors are related to elasticity differences using four categories of regressors: tax structure

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:28 18 Cust # 240184

Figure 6. Dynamic Tax Responses—Analysis of Sample Means

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 19: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

characteristics, demographic factors, political characteristics, and measures of state economic

structures.33 The variables are listed with summary statistics in Appendix 1.

An important issue is what values to use as regressors, since the elasticities were estimated

using 33 years of data. In order to make these results as useful as possible in a policy context,

our baseline analysis uses regressors defined mostly as of the most recent year (1999) of our

data. Our motivation for doing this is that states are better able to make use of results drawn

from recent data (most closely related to the current environment) than if we were to explain

cross-sectional variation in elasticities using data from an earlier period. Recognizing that this

is temporally misaligned with the underlying elasticities, we also provide results where most

variables are entered as changes between 1970 and 1999.

We include six characteristics of state income tax structures in our income tax regressions:

the income threshold at which the highest marginal tax rate is imposed, a dummy variable for

whether a state-level earned-income tax credit exists, the share of the tax base represented by

capital gains, a series of four dummy variables to measure the taxation of pensions, a measure

of the overall progressivity of the income tax rate schedule, and the average annual change in

the highest marginal income tax rate between 1970 and 1999. More specifically, our pension

taxability dummies control for the total or partial exemption of government or private

pensions. Our progressivity measure is calculated as the change in the effective tax rate over an

income range from $10,000 below to $10,000 above the state’s median income level. Our

inclusion of the average change over time in the highest marginal tax rate is necessitated by our

use of tax revenue rather than tax base as the dependent variable in the income tax elasticity

estimates, and the coefficient is expected to have a positive sign. Including this variable will

allow us to essentially adjust our elasticity estimates for tax rate changes during our period of

analysis. We expect the income threshold to be negatively associated and progressivity to be

positively related with the elasticity because these variables account for how rapidly taxpayer

liabilities grow as their incomes rise. The influence of an earned income credit is less

straightforward to predict, however, as the relationship between income and tax liability varies

depending on shares of taxpayers in the phase-in and phase-out ranges of the credit. Inclusions

of pension income will be positively related to the elasticity if pension income is growing faster

than other forms of income, and negatively related otherwise.

We include two separate tax variables in our regressions of sales tax parameters. The first is

the sales tax base as a percent of personal income. The sign is expected to be positive because

a broader tax base, as given by a larger value of this variable, is an indicator that a state relies

more heavily on taxation of services. The second is a measure of the extent to which the sales tax is

levied on consumers, drawn from the estimates developed by Ring (1999). We do not have an

a priori expectation on this coefficient. We do not include the change in the sales tax rate over time

because we use tax base rather than tax revenue in our calculation of the sales tax elasticities.

These estimated elasticities are, therefore, immune to the effects of rate changes (i.e., the elasticity

of our tax base measure with respect to the tax rate is, by construction of our base measure, zero).

Our list of demographic variables in all regressions includes median income, the per-

centage of the population under 18 years of age, and the percentage of the population over

65 years of age. We control for political factors using a series of dummy variables for the

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:34 19 Cust # 240184

33 Note that we have not included controls for spatial correlation in these regressions, although we suspect that a state’s

elasticity estimates might be related to the economic and policy environments in other states. Such an analysis, while

interesting, relevant, and fruitful, is again left for future research.

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 20: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Governor’s political party, as well as the majority party in the state’s legislature. State economic

conditions enter the regressions via measures of the share of Gross State Product (GSP) in

mining, in services, in agriculture, and in manufacturing; average annual employment growth

over the study period; and the standard deviation of employment growth. It is generally diffi-

cult to impose a priori expectations on many of these variables, so we use empirical techniques

to determine whether any relationships exist between these variables and the elasticities.

Long-Run Income Tax Estimates

As shown in the first column of results in Table 5, many of the variables are statistically

significant at the 90% level in our baseline long-run income tax elasticity model, revealing that

the wide differences in income tax elasticities can often be explained by variation in the included

regressors. For example, the long-run income elasticity is higher in states where the maximum

tax bracket occurs at lower income levels (the coefficient is negative). Of course, like any

regression coefficient, this result holds the degree of progressivity around median income (and

all other variables in the model) constant. Given a level of progressivity, our finding that states

with lower top-bracket thresholds have higher long-run income elasticities is perhaps un-

surprising, since an increase in income would lead to a relatively larger increase in taxes paid in

those states. This result is seen only with the 1999 specification, and not with the 1970–1999

changes specification.

Failure to tax pensions generally lowers the elasticity, suggesting that pension income is rising

faster than other forms of income. The one exception in both models is partial exemption of private

pension income. Some states have chosen to exclude pension income during the study period, so the

coefficient may be capturing both the fall in elasticity as the base was narrowed and the effects that

failure to tax pensions has on the elasticity. The result cannot be interpreted to mean that the

elasticity going forward will be lower for states that have already excluded pensions.

The change in tax rates is positively related to the long-run elasticity in both models,

providing the anticipated finding that revenues grow faster when rates are increased and slower

when rates are decreased. Of the states that imposed an income tax throughout the entire study

period, 16 raised their maximum income tax rate and 14 decreased their rate, with the average

annual change being an increase of 0.3%. Thus, the average income tax elasticity was increased

by 0.09 as a result of rate changes, leaving the average income tax elasticity adjusted for rate

changes still about twice as large as the average sales tax elasticity.34

In terms of state demographic characteristics, our 1999 specification reveals that long-run

income tax elasticities are higher in states with a larger share of their population either under

age 18 or over age 65. Also, for the 1999 model, higher median incomes translate into lower

long-run income elasticities for the personal income tax. Moving to state economic factors, we

find that long-run income tax elasticities tend to be lower in states with significant resource-

based economies, whether agriculture or mining, but the coefficients are only of marginal

significance. A large agricultural sector results in a large reduction in the elasticity, providing

evidence that tax systems respond slowly to economic expansion of this sector. This finding is

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:35 20 Cust # 240184

34 The effect of rate changes can be very important to some states and the adjusted elasticities for each state are presented

in Appendix 2. This calculation uses the coefficient on the tax rate change variable in Table 5 with the change in tax

rates for each state to estimate the income tax base elasticity holding all else constant. The general finding is that

elasticities moved closer to the mean, but they are still statistically different from the mean long-run sales tax elasticity.

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 21: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

consistent with the propensity of states to allow specialized treatment and low effective rates on

income generated in the agriculture sector.35 It may also reveal that credits and loss carry-

forwards from slow economic periods allow taxable income in the agriculture sector to respond

slowly as the economy improves. In any event, if all else is equal, the resource-intensive states

have less revenue-elastic tax systems than other states. More volatile employment growth, on

the other hand, tends to result in higher income tax elasticity in both models.

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:36 21 Cust # 240184

Table 5. Cross-Sectional Analysis of Long-Run Elasticities

Variable

1999 Values

Income Sales

Lowest income in highest PITbracket ($ thousand)a

20.003** (0.001)

EITC dummy 20.273 (0.173)Capital gains/personal income 17.253 (11.523)Progressivity at median income 87.567 (56.813)Partial exemption for

government pensions20.920** (0.392)

Total exemption forgovernment pensions

20.656* (0.314)

Partial exemption for private pensions 0.792** (0.294)Total exemption for private pensions 20.768* (0.398)Average change in top PIT

rate (1970–1999)25.723* (12.132)

ST base/personal income 0.952** (0.451)Consumer share of ST 0.012* (0.006)Percentage of population

under 18 years of agea33.490** (7.856) 0.477 (2.913)

Percentage of populationover 65 years of ageb

27.771** (8.233) 1.854 (3.030)

Median income ($ thousands)a 20.052** (0.021) 0.017** (0.007)Republican legislature 0.660* (0.353) 0.119 (0.128)Democratic legislature 20.284 (0.262) 0.180 (0.121)Republican governor 20.329 (0.300) 0.026 (0.078)Mining share of GSPb 29.560 (7.270) 3.677 (2.398)Average annual employment

growth (1970–1999)24.808 (9.670) 0.471 (2.010)

Standard deviation of employmentgrowth (1970–1999)

23.860** (10.624) 0.548 (4.486)

Manufacturing share of GSPb 21.065 (2.689) 1.768 (1.347)Services share of GSPb 218.081 (17.737) 5.585 (3.966)Agriculture share of GSPb 235.335 (21.218) 4.669 (6.815)Constant 24.657 (4.140) 23.220 (1.903)N 35 43R2 0.601 0.060

Entries are ordinary least-squares regression coefficients with White (1980) standard errors in parentheses.a Variable enters 1970–1999 Changes specifications as the change from 1970 to 1999.b Vanable enters 1979–1999 Changes specifications as the average change from 1970 to 1999.

* Statistically significant at 10% and above.

** Statistically significant at 5% and above.

35 The authors thank John Mikesell for making this observation.

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 22: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Long-Run Sales Tax Elasticities

Unlike the analysis of the long-run personal income tax elasticities, most variables are not

statistically significant in the sales tax elasticity regressions, as shown in the second and fourth

columns of Table 5. One likely explanation is that the range of sales tax elasticities is much

smaller than for the income tax, meaning there is less variation to be explained (see Figure 4).

Also, it is more difficult to summarize important sales tax base differences quantitatively.

Despite this general lack of statistical significance, we find in our 1999 specification that

a broader sales tax base results in higher sales tax elasticity. Given the rapid growth in the

service sector as a share of personal income during the study period, and the fact that greater

taxation of services is responsible for much of the state variation in base breadth, this find-

ing suggests that taxation of more services results in a higher elasticity.36 Quite simply,

consumption of services has been more elastic than consumption of goods over the past several

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:36 22 Cust # 240184

Table 5. Extended

1970–1999 Changes

Income Sales

1.935 (359.289)

20.395 (0.275)2739.067** (289.629)

433.921 (1916.552)21.039** (0.447)

20.306 (0.374)

0.576 (0.350)20.557 (0.420)30.602** (12.405)

21.967** (0.836)20.006 (0.005)

22.785 (3.787) 0.386 (1.103)

20.334 (0.983) 20.070 (0.304)

215.467 (12.968) 1.730 (4.460)0.515* (0.254) 20.047 (0.108)

20.136 (0.289) 0.021 (0.125)0.011 (0.333) 0.007 (0.086)

25.313 (3.592) 0.738 (1.360)28.002 (8.158) 0.972 (2.234)

26.263* (12.747) 22.250 (6.265)

38.594 (105.490) 224.319 (31.092)245.028* (23.391) 24.984 (5.645)

0.738 (22.500) 1.806 (4.705)5.343** (1.869) 1.288** (0.618)

35 430.517 0.047

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 23: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

decades. Alternatively, our 1970–1999 changes model reveals that states in which the change in

sales tax base breadth has been most extensive between 1970 and 1999 tend to have lower

elasticities. The sales tax base in every state declined relative to personal income during our

study period, meaning that states with the greatest base decline tend to have a more elastic sales

tax.37 Decisions by many states during our study period to exempt food for consumption at

home are probably the largest policy-driven narrowing of the bases. Thus, the finding can be

interpreted to mean that exemption of relatively slow-growing food from the base is likely to

increase the sales tax elasticity.

States where a higher share of the sales tax is incident on consumers tend to have higher

elasticities in the 1999 model. One possible explanation for this is that states have high

consumer shares because they have exempted a significant amount of business transactions

during the study period.38 The only other statistically significant result from our regressions of

long-run sales tax elasticities is that median income is found to have a significant and positive

influence on the long-run sales tax elasticity, again only in the 1999 model.

We also estimate similar regressions of all short-run parameters, with the only difference

being our inclusion of the corresponding long-run elasticity as a regressor. To summarize the

many findings of this exercise, we are largely unable to identify many policy variables that are

associated with short-run elasticities and adjustment parameters.

8. Conclusions

As states continue to experience financial hardship due to the flagging revenue

performance of major state taxes, many are tempted to adjust their revenue structure in order

to stave off future instability. In such a policy environment, it is important to understand the

comparative dynamics of various taxes. States’ failure to consider such dynamics in the mid-

1990s helped create their subsequent problems, as a number of states reduced their tax rates or

bases during the robust revenue growth years of the late 1990s, apparently believing that the

existing short-run revenue conditions reflected the underlying long-run revenue environment.

Our research expands upon the earlier literature by estimating long-run income elasticities

of the two major state taxes (personal income and sales), by separately identifying short-run

elasticities, and by allowing variation in the dynamic adjustment of the tax base in response to

personal income changes. Further, we examine the various determinants of the cross-state

variation in all estimated parameters. These results allow for a more in-depth understanding of

state revenue performance and much better insight into the relationship between short-run and

long-run revenue fluctuations.

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:37 23 Cust # 240184

38 One reviewer observed that a higher consumer share might translate into lesser taxation of business, which could

stimulate economic growth.

37 The difference in these results highlights the policy applicability of the 1999 model. While the sales tax base breadth

variable (along with other variables entered as changes over the 30-year span) serves as more of a control variable in

the 1970–1999 changes model, it functions as a policy variable in the 1999 model in that states can broaden their sales

tax bases in order to increase the elasticity of the tax.

36 This result was confirmed in a separate regression where we measured base breadth via the number of taxable services

in each state.

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 24: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

To summarize the many results of this empirical exercise, we first find that the average

long-run income elasticity of state personal income tax bases is more than double that for sales

taxes. Short-run elasticities are found to exhibit asymmetry in most states. Specifically, they are

higher than long-run elasticities when the current tax base is above the long-run equilibrium,

and lower when the current tax base is below equilibrium. Estimated adjustment parameters

indicate that any short-run disequilibrium is quickly alleviated for both taxes in many states.

Contrary to conventional wisdom, neither the personal income tax nor the sales tax

emerges as the universally more volatile tax. While income elasticities are generally larger for

the income tax in both the long run and the short run, a careful assessment of relative volatility

must consider the interaction of long-run elasticities, short-run elasticities, the extent of

preexisting disequilibrium, and the relative speed of adjustment toward the new equilibrium.

The sales tax can actually be the more volatile tax in certain scenarios.

After controlling for state demographic and economic characteristics, we find that

a number of state-specific policy elements are important factors of state variation in estimated

elasticities. Over the long run, personal income taxes are more income-elastic in states where the

maximum tax bracket occurs at lower income levels, pensions are taxed, the rate structure is

more progressive around the median income level, and the top rate has increased by a larger

percentage. In terms of the sales tax, states with broader bases and with larger shares being paid

by consumers have higher income elasticities.

Consequently, these results indicate that states have a number of options for increasing the

overall income elasticity of their tax structures. They can simply shift away from lower-

elasticity taxes (e.g., the sales tax) toward higher-elasticity taxes (e.g., the personal income tax),

or they can work within their existing tax portfolio by adjusting these policy elements.

However, increasing a revenue system’s elasticity does not necessarily increase its volatility.

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:38 24 Cust # 240184

Appendix 1Summary Statistics and Source Notes for Cross-Sectional Regression Variables

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Minimum Maximum

ST base/personal income 0.463 0.153 0.252 1.108Consumer share of ST 59.422 8.892 28.000 89.000Lowest income in highest PIT bracket 59,344 78,977 0 300,000EITC dummy 0.220 0.418 0 1Capital gains/personal income 0.060 0.020 0.026 0.123Progressivity at median income 0.003 0.002 0 0.008Partial exemption for government pensions 0.463 0.505 0 1Total exemption for government pensions 0.268 0.449 0 1Partial exemption for private pensions 0.488 0.506 0 1Total exemption for private pensions 0.073 0.264 0 1Percentage of population under 18 years of age 0.257 0.017 0.223 0.322Percentage of population over 65 years of age 0.125 0.019 0.057 0.176Median income 58,500 7,701 44,947 75,505Republican legislature 0.400 0.495 0 1Democratic legislature 0.380 0.490 0 1Republican governor 0.620 0.490 0 1Mining share of GSP 0.017 0.034 0 0.161Average annual employment growth (1970–1999) 0.035 0.023 0.006 0.129Standard deviation of employment growth

(1970–1999)0.026 0.011 0.015 0.061

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 25: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:38 25 Cust # 240184

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Minimum Maximum

Manufacturing share of GSP 0.162 0.064 0.030 0.316Services share of GSP 0.160 0.027 0.085 0.240Agriculture share of GSP 0.015 0.011 0.003 0.055Average change in top PIT rate (1970–1999) 0.003 0.012 20.025 0.032

Variable Source

ST base/personal income U.S. Bureau of Economic AnalysisConsumer share of ST Ring (1999)Lowest income in highest PIT bracket State Tax Handbook, Commerce ClearinghouseEITC dummy Center for Budget and Policy PrioritiesCapital gains/personal income Internal Revenue Service and Bureau of Economic

AnalysisProgressivity at median income Authors’ calculations based on median income and

tax ratesPartial exemption for government

pensionsFederation of Tax Administrators at http://

assets.aarp.org/rgcenter/econ/ib55_sstax.pdfTotal exemption for government pensions Federation of Tax Administrators at http://

assets.aarp.org/rgcenter/econ/ib55_sstax.pdfPartial exemption for private pensions Federation of Tax Administrators at http://

assets.aarp.org/rgcenter/econ/ib55_sstax.pdfTotal exemption for private pensions Federation of Tax Administrators at http://

assets.aarp.org/rgcenter/econ/ib55_sstax.pdfPercentage of population under 18 years

of ageU.S. Bureau of the Census

Percentage of population over 65 yearsof age

U.S. Bureau of the Census

Median income Statistical Abstract of the United States, U.S.Bureau of the Census

Republican legislature Statistical Abstract of the United States, U.S.Bureau of the Census

Democratic legislature Statistical Abstract of the United States, U.S.Bureau of the Census

Republican governor Statistical Abstract of the United States, U.S.Bureau of the Census

Mining share of GSP Authors’ calculations based on Regional AccountsData, Bureau of Economic Analysis

Average annual employment growth(1970–1999)

Bureau of Labor Statistics

Standard deviation of employmentgrowth (1970–1999)

Bureau of Labor Statistics

Manufacturing share of GSP Authors’ calculations based on Regional AccountsData, Bureau of Economic Analysis

Services share of GSP Authors’ calculations based on Regional AccountsData, Bureau of Economic Analysis

Agriculture share of GSP Authors’ calculations based on Regional AccountsData, Bureau of Economic Analysis

Average change in top PIT rate(1970–1999)

Authors’ calculations based on data from StateTax Handbook, Commerce Clearinghouse

Appendix 1. Continued

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 26: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

References

Cook, Steven, Sean Holly, and Paul Turner. 1999. DSHY revisited: The role of asymmetries. Applied Economics

31:775–8.

Dickey, David A., and Wayne A. Fuller. 1981. Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root.

Econometrica 49:1057–72.

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:39 26 Cust # 240184

Appendix 2Long-Run PIT Elasticities Adjusted for Rate Changes

Unadjusted Adjusted

Alabama 1.82 1.82Arizona 1.14 1.55Arkansas 2.10 1.79California 1.75 1.82Colorado 1.26 1.17Georgia 1.69 1.69Hawaii 1.32 1.41Idaho 1.57 1.65Illinois 1.57 1.40Indiana 2.44 1.95Iowa 2.35 1.86Kansas 2.26 2.27Kentucky 2.60 2.60Louisiana 2.27 2.27Maine 2.87 2.55Maryland 1.18 1.21Massachusetts 1.42 1.05Michigan 1.88 1.40Minnesota 1.32 1.64Mississippi 1.91 1.71Missouri 2.29 1.92Montana 1.60 1.60Nebraska 2.49 3.10New Jersey 2.02 1.16New Mexico 3.02 3.11New York 1.30 1.95North Carolina 1.55 1.45North Dakota 0.81 0.59Ohio 3.98 3.38Oklahoma 2.61 2.47Oregon 1.44 1.54Pennsylvania 1.43 1.25Rhode Island 1.76 1.22South Carolina 1.56 1.56Utah 1.48 1.41Vermont 0.97 0.97Virginia 1.47 1.35West Virginia 2.57 2.42Wisconsin 1.22 1.57Average 1.85 1.76Std. Dev. 0.648 0.611

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle

Page 27: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Dye, Richard F., and Therese J. McGuire. 1991. Growth and variability of state individual income and general sales

taxes. National Tax Journal 44:55–66.

Enders, Walter, and Pierre L. Siklos. 2001. Cointegration and threshold adjustment. Journal of Business and Economic

Statistics 19:166–76.

Fox, William F., and Charles Campbell. 1984. Stability of the state sales tax income elasticity. National Tax Journal

37:201–12.

Granger, Clive W. J., and Paul Newbold. 1974. Spurious regression in econometrics. Journal of Econometrics 2:111–20.

Granger, Clive W. J., and Tae-Hwy Lee. 1989. Investigation of production, sales, and inventory relationships using

multicointegration and non-symmetric error correction models. Journal of Applied Econometrics 4:S145–S159.

Groves, Harold M., and C. Harry Kahn. 1952. The stability of state and local tax yields. American Economic Review

42:87–102.

Jenny, Nicholas W. 2002. State tax revenue decline accelerates. State Tax Notes 26:169.

Ludvigson, Sydney, and Charles Steindel. 1999. How important is the stock market effect on consumption? Federal

Reserve Bank of New York Economic Policy Review 5:29–51.

Mikesell, John L. 2004. State retail sales tax burdens, reliance, and breadth in fiscal 2003. State Tax Notes 33:125.

Newey, Whitney K., and Kenneth D. West. 1987. A simple, positive semi-definite, heteroskedasticity and

autocorrelation consistent covariance matrix. Econometrica 55, 1987:703–08.

Otsuka, Yasuji, and Bradley M. Braun. 1999. The random coefficient approach for estimating tax revenue stability and

growth. Public Finance Review 27:665–76.

Ring, Raymond J., Jr. 1999. Consumer’s share and producer’s share of the general sales tax. National Tax Journal

52:79–90.

Schwarz, Gideon. 1978. Estimating the dimension of a model. The Annals of Statistics 6:461–4.

Sobel, Russell S., and Randall G. Holcombe. 1996. Measuring the growth and variability of tax bases over the business

cycle. National Tax Journal 49:535–52.

Stock, James H., and Mark W. Watson. 1993. A simple estimator of cointegrating vectors in higher order integrated

systems. Econometrica 61:783–820.

U.S. Bureau of the Census. State Tax Collections. Various years.

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:39 27 Cust # 240184

Tax Base Elasticities 0

Page 28: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-Run Dynamics

Authors Queries

Journal: Southern Economic Journal

Paper: soec-73-02-12

Title: Tax Base Elasticities: A Multi-State Analysis of Long-Run and Short-

Run Dynamics

Dear Author

During the preparation of your manuscript for publication, the questions listed below have

arisen. Please attend to these matters and return this form with your proof. Many thanks for

your assistance

Query

Reference

Query Remarks

1 Author: This article hasbeen lightly edited forgrammar, style, and us-age. Please compare itwith your original docu-ment and make changeson these pages. Pleaselimit your corrections tosubstantive changes thataffect meaning. If nochange is required in re-sponse to a question,please write ‘‘OK as set’’in the margin. Copy editor

Southern Economic Journal soec-73-02-12.3d 31/7/06 13:47:39 28 Cust # 240184

0 Bruce, Fox, and Tuttle