supply and demand of physician services econ 737.01

40
Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

Upload: felicia-rynard

Post on 30-Mar-2015

223 views

Category:

Documents


6 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

Supply and Demand of Physician Services

Econ 737.01

Page 2: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

Supply and Demand of Physician Services: Outline

• A. General Models• B. Forms of Compensation• C. Physician-Induced Demand

Page 3: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

General Models: Outline

• I. Supply of Physicians• II. Supply of Physician Services– a. Model with Complete Information– b. Incomplete Information– c. Objectives Besides Income

Page 4: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

I. Supply of Physicians

• Summary Statistics (U.S.; 1994)– 126 medical schools– 16,000 graduates per year– 550,000 practicing physicians– 254 physicians per 100,000 residents– Average net income : $182,400– Average work hours: 55/week– Physicians work a lot and make a lot• Market forces or shortage?

Page 5: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

I. Supply of Physicians

• Market distortions– Barriers to entry• Educational and licensing requirements• AMA controls these; incentive to restrict supply too

much?• This would reduce supply below socially optimal level

– Medical school subsidies• Could raise supply above socially optimal level

Page 6: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

I. Supply of Physicians• Empirical Evidence– Difficult to measure physician shortages or excess

returns on investments in medical education– 1900-1950

• Supply side: new medical school graduates constant• Demand side: average age, real per capita GDP, and insurance

coverage all increased dramatically• Consistent with excessively restricted entry

– More recently• Output of medical schools has expanded dramatically in last

10-20 years• Weeks et al. (1994): returns to education for physicians,

lawyers, dentists, and MBAs all similar

Page 7: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Supply of Physician Servicesa. Model with Complete Information

• Monopolistic Competition– Many sellers– Differentiated products (physicians are imperfect substitutes)– Some market power

• Demand exogenous from physician’s perspective• Perfect information on both sides• Physicians maximize profit• Nonretradable goods

Page 8: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Supply of Physician Servicesa. Model with Complete Information

• Physician makes “all or nothing” offer to patient, who would prefer to consume less care at the given price

• Physician can price discriminate• If price set by demand side (i.e. insurance

companies/Medicare), physician responds by increasing quantity

• Quality of service is another dimension to consider

Page 9: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Supply of Physician Servicesb. Incomplete Information

• Punch line from part a: Even with perfect information, the differentiated and nonretradable nature of medical goods can keep medical expenditures above competitive levels.

• Relaxing the assumption of perfect information further enhances our understanding of why medical expenditures are so high.

Page 10: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Supply of Physician Servicesb. Incomplete Information

• 1) Irreducible uncertainty– Doctors and patients have imperfect information

about the underlying condition and effectiveness of treatments

– Most doctors and patients are risk averse– => increased test frequency and treatment

intensity

Page 11: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Supply of Physician Servicesb. Incomplete Information

• 2) Principal-agent problem– Principal: patient– Agent: doctor– Doctors know more than patients about

appropriate level of care (asymmetric information)– Outcomes are often difficult for patient to observe– Often gray areas about appropriate treatment– => Could lead to excessive provision of care– “Induced demand”

Page 12: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Supply of Physician Servicesb. Incomplete Information

• 3) Unobservable physician quality– Large fixed cost with trying a new physician– Information asymmetry makes it hard to observe

physician quality– => Prices may not fully adjust to an increase in

competition

Page 13: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Supply of Physician Servicesc. Objectives Besides Income

• Parts a and b assume that physicians act to maximize income. Other considerations:– 1) Medical ethics: legal and moral constraints– 2) Patient’s best interest (patient’s utility enters

into doctor’s utility function)• Patient’s utility, not society’s utility. Why is this an

important distinction?

– 3) Target income

Page 14: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Supply of Physician Servicesc. Objectives Besides Income

• 3) Target income– Motivation: explain positive association between

physicians per capita and prices of services, negative association between fees paid and quantity supplied

– Physicians aim to maintain a “target income”– If increased competition lowers their income, they

take advantage of their market power by raising prices or inducing demand to keep income relatively stable

– What does this say about physician behavior before the increase in competition?

Page 15: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Supply of Physician Servicesc. Objectives Besides Income

• 3) Target income– Taken seriously for a long time– Generally rejected now, though still subject of

debate in literature– If target income hypothesis is true, there should be

large income effects on supply (identified using non-labor income), and this doesn’t seem to be the case

• Can you think of other explanations for the apparent paradoxes?

Page 16: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

Forms of Compensation

• I. Fee-for-service• II. Capitation• III. Salary• IV. Pay-for-performance

Page 17: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

I. Fee-for-service

• Physicians are paid an additional amount of money for each service they provide

• Would expect this to increase the amount of care provided

• Open question how much these additional services would improve health

• Schuster et al. (1998) estimate up to 30% of services are not medically necessary

• Often supplemented with incentives to economize

Page 18: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

I. Fee-for-service

• Who sets the fees?– Used to be physicians– In response to incentive problems, insurance plans

began negotiating fees and Medicare began setting fees

– These groups can do this because they are large enough that they have market power (monopsony)

– How does this tie into the “public option” debate?

Page 19: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Capitation• Physicians receive fixed amount of money for providing services

to a patient for a particular period of time• Incentive to keep long patient roster but give them each as little

attention as possible• Could lead to higher referral rates

– Various schemes to makes physicians share in financial risk• Still need to provide enough care to attract and retain patients• Incentive to select healthy patients (cream skimming; cherry

picking)– Fee for a patient is “risk adjusted” based on expected utilization– This adjustment only accounts for 10% of variation

• Often supplemented with incentives to ensure sufficient quality of care

• Could be combined with ffs in a “mixed” system

Page 20: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Capitation

• Quantity– Capitation seems to be effective in reducing

quantity and expenditures (is this good?)– Stearns et al. (1992)• Group of WI employees enrolled in IPA• Change from ffs to capitation system where physicians

shared in financial risk of hospitatlization and specialty costs• Increased primary care visits by 18%• Decreased specialist visits by 45%, hospital visits by 16%,

and length of stay by 12%

Page 21: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Capitation

• Quantity– Ogden et al. (1990)• Group of IL employees enrolled in IPA• Switched from ffs to capitation with shared financial

risk• Specialist costs increased 2% compared to 12% the

previous year• Hospital outpatient costs dropped 7% compared to

increasing 12% the previous year• Little change in inpatient hospital utilization

Page 22: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Capitation

• Quantity– Mooney (1994)• GPs in Copenhagen, Denmark switched from capitation

to mixed capitation-ffs• Provision of services that provided extra fees increased

dramatically• Decrease in referrals to specialists and hospitals

Page 23: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Capitation

• Quality– Sorbero et al. (2003): patients 36% more likely to

switch physicians under capitation than ffs– Shen et al. (2004): survey with hypothetical

treatment decisions; physicians more “bothered” by their decisions under capitation than ffs

Page 24: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Capitation

• Referral rate– Capitation does seem to lead to more referrals on

the margin, both theoretically and empirically, if the GP does not share in the financial risk• Theoretical: Barros and Martinez-Giralt (2003); Iverson

and Luras (2000b)• Empirical: Forrest et al. (2003); Carlsen and Norheim

(2003)

Page 25: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

III. Salary

• Provides fixed income to physician over a particular time period

• Ex. in US: Staff HMOs• Incentive to do as little as possible to keep job• Often supplemented with incentives to ensure

reasonable quantity and quality of care• Less common than others, but do see it in

national health systems like UK and staff HMOs in US

Page 26: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

IV. Pay-for-performance

• Ties part of physician or hospital reimbursement to meeting performance thresholds (clinical outcomes, patient satisfaction, etc.)

• New and largely untested• >20 million in US covered (Rosenthal et al., 2004)• Difficult to measure “performance”• What incentive problems might result from paying

on the basis of outcomes?

Page 27: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

Physician-Induced Demand

• I. Theory• II. Evidence from Increased Competition• III. Evidence from Decreased Fees• IV. Summary

Page 28: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

I. Theory

• Physician-induced demand (PIP): “when the physician influences a patient’s demand for care against the physician’s interpretation of the best interest of the patient” (Handbook, p. 504)

• Physician exploits role as agent to alter the patient’s demand curve

• Distinctions that make PID challenging to identify empirically (not enough to just look at quantity)– Useful agency v. inducement– Demand shifting v. quantity setting

Page 29: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

I. Theory• Model

• Where Y=income, I=inducement, N=number of patients, m=margin, x=quantity, i=inducement

• Solving yields

0'',0',0,0,0,0

)(

))()((

),(

21

222111

xxUUUU

iiNI

ixmixmNY

IYUUMax

IIIYYY

YI UUxmxm /'' 2211

Page 30: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

I. Theory

• Testable prediction 1– N down => Y down and I down => UI less negative

and UY up => -UI/UY down => x1’ and x2’ down => i1 and i2 up.

– So, increased competition for patients should increase the per-patient quantity of services• Supply side: more physicians in market• Demand side: less need for services

– Depends on changing tradeoff between I and Y as income changes (income effect)

Page 31: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

I. Theory

• Testable prediction 2– m1 down => UY up => -UI/UY down => i1 and i2 up• Income effect

– m1 down => lower return to inducement in sector 1 => i1 down and i2 up• Substitution effect

– Net effect on i1 ambiguous; net effect on i2 down– So, a drop in fees from one payer should increase

quantity among patients with another payer

Page 32: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Evidence from Increased Competition

• Effect of increase in per capita number of physicians on quantity

• Problems– Really tests joint hypothesis of induced demand

and income effects– Endogeneity of number of physicians (likely a

response to demand)

Page 33: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Evidence from Increased Competition

• Fuchs (1978)– Effect of supply of surgeons on surgeries– 22 metropolitan areas, pooled cross sections from 1963 and 1970– IVs: metro area, hotel receipts, percent white– 10% increase in surgeons => 3% increase in surgeries

• Cromwell and Mitchell (1986)– More years, more areas, better controls– Same identification strategy– Same sign, smaller effect

• Birch (1988) and Grytten el at. (1990)– More dentists per capita => more dental visits

Page 34: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Evidence from Increased Competition

• Rossiter and Wilensky (1983, 1984); Scott and Shell (1997)– Small effects of physician density on quantity for some

procedures• Dranove and Wehner (1994)– Falsification test: estimated “effect” of number of

obstetricians on volume of births– Similar IV methodology to Fuchs and Cromwell and

Mitchell– Found positive effect; suggests methodology is suspect

Page 35: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Evidence from Increased Competition

• Gruber and Owings (1996)– 13.5% fall in fertility from 1970-1982 represents

exogenous shock to incomes of OB/GYNs– Exploited between-state over-time variation in

fertility rates to identify effect on Caesarian section deliveries (more lucrative)

– 10% drop in fertility => 0.6% increase in P(C-section)

Page 36: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

II. Evidence from Increased Competition

• Pauly (1980)– Used large individual-level dataset– Least informed patients should be the most

susceptible to demand inducement – Poor patients in big cities should be the least

informed– Found (small) effect of number of physicians on

quantity of ambulatory care for this group

Page 37: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

III. Evidence from Decreased Fees

• Hadley and Lee (1978); Mitchell et al (1989)– Medicare price freezes during 1970s and 1980s led to

increased utilization• Hurley et al. (1990); Hurley and Labelle (1995); Escarce

(1993b)– No clear evidence of effect of own-fee changes on utilization– Not surprising; theoretical prediction ambiguous

• Rochaix (1993)– GPs in Quebec changed mix of services in response to

lowering of fees

Page 38: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

III. Evidence from Decreased Fees

• Rice (1983)– 1977: Medicare began setting fees in Colorado

based on state-wide averages– Reduced fees in Denver-Boulder area; increased

them in other areas– Physicians facing declining rates increased

provision of surgery, medical services, and tests

Page 39: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

III. Evidence from Decreased Fees

• Nguyen and Derrick (1997)– Impact of Medicare fee reductions for “overpriced

procedures”– For 20% of physicians who experienced the largest

price reductions, 1% reduction in price => 0.4% increase in volume.

• Yip (1998)– Reductions in Medicare fees for thoracic surgeons

led to large increases in volume– Surgeons recouped 70% of lost income

Page 40: Supply and Demand of Physician Services Econ 737.01

IV. Summary

• There is no perfect test for demand inducement, but theory generates predictions that lead to tests that are suggestive.

• “It appears that, in response to economic considerations … physicians can induce demand for their services, they sometimes do induce demand, but that such responses are nether automatic nor unrestrained” (Elgar p. 265, citing Hurley and Lebelle, 1995).