risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 shupp and williams (2008), and...

70
Social Design Engineering Series SDES-2019-3 Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both median and random rules Yoshio Kamijo School of Economics and Management, Kochi University of Technology Research Institute for Future Design, Kochi University of Technology Teruyuki Tamura Kyoto College of Economics 12th April, 2019 School of Economics and Management Research Institute for Future Design Kochi University of Technology KUT-SDE working papers are preliminary research documents published by the School of Economics and Management jointly with the Research Center for Social Design Engineering at Kochi University of Technology. To facilitate prompt distribution, they have not been formally reviewed and edited. They are circulated in order to stimulate discussion and critical comment and may be revised. The views and interpretations expressed in these papers are those of the author(s). It is expected that most working papers will be published in some other form.

Upload: others

Post on 12-Aug-2021

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

Social Design Engineering Series SDES-2019-3

Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in bothmedian and random rules

Yoshio KamijoSchool of Economics and Management, Kochi University of TechnologyResearch Institute for Future Design, Kochi University of Technology

Teruyuki TamuraKyoto College of Economics

12th April, 2019

School of Economics and ManagementResearch Institute for Future DesignKochi University of Technology

KUT-SDE working papers are preliminary research documents published by the School of Economics and Management jointly with the ResearchCenter for Social Design Engineering at Kochi University of Technology. To facilitate prompt distribution, they have not been formally reviewedand edited. They are circulated in order to stimulate discussion and critical comment and may be revised. The views and interpretations expressedin these papers are those of the author(s). It is expected that most working papers will be published in some other form.

Page 2: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

1

Risk-averse and Self-interested Shifts in Groups in both Median and Random 1

Rules 2

3

Yoshio Kamijoa and Teruyuki Tamurabc 4

5

6

Abstract 7 This study examines whether attitudes toward risk and altruism are affected by being in a group 8 or being alone. Differing from previous economic studies of group decision-making, we attempt 9 to exclude the effects of group informal discussion, which are thought to be a black box when 10 individuals make decisions in a group. Subjects in our experiment were requested only to show 11 their faces to other members without any further communication. Moreover, we adopted two 12 collective decision rules—namely, the median rule and the random rule—which provide the 13 truth-telling mechanism. In experiments of both anonymous investments and donations, we 14 found that subjects who made decisions in a group offered significantly lower amounts than 15 individuals who made decisions alone, even controlling for individuals’ risk and altruistic 16 preferences. Our results indicate that people are more risk averse and self-interested when they 17 are in a group regardless of which collective decision rules are adopted. 18

19 20

Keywords: Group decision, Individual decision, Altruism, Decision under risk 21 JEL classification: C91, C92, D81 22 23

a School of Economics and Management, Kochi University of Technology, 2-22 Eikokuji-cho,

Kochi-shi, Kochi 780-8515, Japan. Email: [email protected]

b Corresponding Author. Email: [email protected] (T.Tamura) c Department of Management, Kyoto College of Economics, 3-1 Higashinaga-cho, Ooe,

Nishikyo-ku, Kyoto City 610-1195, Japan 24

Page 3: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

2

1. Introduction 1 Although a decision maker is almost always assumed to be an individual in normative models of 2

economics, in real-life situations, many important decisions are made by groups, such as 3

company boards, management teams, governments, and legislators. The importance of studies 4

focusing on group decision-making is growing, and thus, economists have come to pay more 5

attention to this area. 6

There is a long history in social psychology of studying group decision-making. Stoner 7

(1961) reported the first experiment in which decisions made by groups led to riskier positions 8

after the discussion, compared to individuals’ decisions. Moscovici and Zavalloni (1969) noted 9

that decision-making in groups has resulted in both risky and cautious directions, and the 10

authors regarded risky and cautious shifts 1 as a special case of group polarization. A 11

comprehensive survey by Kerr et al. (1996) concluded “there are several demonstrations that 12

group discussion can attenuate, amplify, or simply reproduce the judgment biases of individuals” 13

(p. 693). Furthermore, group interaction and discussion might deliver different results in group 14

decisions.2 15

In previous economic studies of group decision-making, the differentials in preference 16

toward risk and altruism between individuals and groups were examined.3 Baker et al. (2008), 17

Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 18

averse than individuals were in a lottery choice experiment, while Mifune et al. (2016) observed 19

a similar tendency by using a kind of stag-hunt game and comparing individual-on-individual 20

treatment with group-on-individual treatment. However, Rockenbach et al. (2007) and Zhang 21

and Casari (2012) found that group decisions display a risky shift in comparison to individual 22

decisions. Harrison et al. (2012) concluded that there were no significant differences between 23 1 In social psychology, the two main explanations for these shifts are social comparison theory (Levinger and Schneider 1969) and persuasive argument theory (Burnstein et al. 1973; Brown 1974). Social comparison theory states that people are motivated to perceive and present themselves in a socially desirable way. According to persuasive argument theory, the reason that group decisions lead to a particular direction is that once certain novel arguments are shared during group discussions, then these arguments persuade other group members on the issue. 2 In addition, Sunstein (2000, 2002) and Manin (2005) pointed out that groups indeed shifted to more extreme positions but the shifts were not systematic in one direction. 3 Another perspective in economic studies of group decision-making is to explore whether groups are more rational than individuals are (see Bornstein and Yaniv 1998; Cox and Hayne 2006; Kocher and Sutter 2005; Song 2008). Charness and Sutter (2012) concluded that group decision-making was more likely to be close to standard game-theoretic predictions, because groups were more cognitively sophisticated and more productive owing to peer effects, and had more self-interested preferences.

Page 4: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

3

the risk aversion of individuals and groups. With regard to altruistic preference, Cason and Mui 1

(1997) reported that a dictator group was less self-interested than an individual dictator was, 2

whereas Luhan et al. (2009) concluded that a dictator group was more self-interested than an 3

individual dictator was. The method of communication within the dictator group in Cason and 4

Mui (1997) was face-to-face, whereas the method used in Luhan et al. (2009) was online chat. 5

According to Luhan et al. (2009), whether group decision-making is more self-interested than 6

individual decision-making depends on the anonymity within the dictator group. 7

Since all of the experimental economic literature in the previous paragraphs on group 8

decision-making, except for Masclet et al. (2009) and Harrison et al. (2012), features groups that 9

were allowed to communicate with other group members via face-to-face discussions or 10

electronic chats, the observed decisions of groups were due to the mixed effect of the preference 11

changes of individuals by being in a group and the group’s formal or informal discussion 12

process. Consequently, little is known about pure subjects’ preference differentials in terms of 13

how they decide—alone or in a team. This study differs from that of previous literature for the 14

three points as follows. First, we attempt to exclude the effects of group informal discussion, 15

which are thought to be a “black box” when individuals make decisions. Second, the prior 16

literature adopted different “collective decision rules” on group decision-making (e.g., majority 17

rule, unanimity, and dictator rule), and these rules may affect the final results of the experiments. 18

To our best knowledge, this is the first experiments comparing two collective decision rules, the 19

median rule and random rule, in this area. Although these two rules enhance truth-telling 20

mechanism (see Cason et al. 2006), we here attempt to examine whether there is no difference 21

between both rules on group decision-making indeed. Finally, we collect the data about both 22

individuals’ attitudes toward risk and altruism from same subjects, and our results that the 23

existence of other group members have significant influence on both attitudes no matter which 24

collective decision rules are adopted. 25

In order to compare the risk and altruistic attitude of groups and individuals, our 26

experiment was composed of two parts. First, all subjects were asked to conduct an individual 27

task. For risk attitude, we implemented a lottery choice task introduced by Holt and Laury 28

(2002). For altruism attitude, we used a standard public goods game (PGG). These variables are 29

utilized as controls for individuals’ preferences toward risk and altruism in our regression model. 30

Second, we separated the subjects into individual-choice and group-choice tasks, and then, 31

Page 5: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

4

played an anonymous investment game and donation game in each. For a group-choice task, 1

subjects were requested only to show their faces to the other members, and each player made 2

the same decision by the median rule condition and random rule condition, receiving the same 3

payoff for his or her group. We mainly noted that groups exhibit more risk aversion and are 4

more self-interested than individuals are in both collective decision rules, even controlling for 5

individuals’ risk and altruistic preferences in the regression model. Moreover, our results show 6

that the group effects we observed have greater impacts in the random rule than those in the 7

median rule in investment, and more risk-seeking subjects tend to be affected by the group 8

effects to a large extent. 9

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Our experimental design and procedure are 10

introduced in Section 2. Section 3 presents the results of the experiment. Section 4 provides 11

discussion about our results and Section 5 concludes. 12

13 2. Experimental Design 14 All subjects in our experiment were undergraduate students from various disciplines at Kochi 15

University of Technology, Kyoto Sangyo University, and Kansai University, and were recruited 16

via the university website and e-mail solicitation. We conducted 18 sessions between July 2015 17

and December 2017. No subject participated in more than one session. The experiment was 18

programmed and conducted with the software z-Tree developed by Fischbacher (2007). 19

Subjects were seated individually and in front of a computer screen in a lab. 20

Table 1 presents our experimental design consisting of two parts. First, all subjects in a 21

session were asked to carry out an individual task as mentioned later in this section (Tasks 1 and 22

2). Second, for Tasks 3 and 4, in the case of the 24 participating subjects, 12 subjects were 23

assigned randomly to the individual-choice task and 12 subjects to the group-choice task 24

(divided into four groups of three people). For the group-choice task, subjects were assigned to 25

the median rule condition and the random rule condition, both of which provide truth-telling 26

mechanism at the time of group decision-making. 27

28

[Table 1 about here] 29

30

Subjects were told that the members of groups were identical in Tasks 3 and 4. Subjects 31

were not allowed to communicate with each other, because we attempt to exclude the effects of 32

Page 6: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

5

group discussion from the decision-making processes in groups. However, we considered that if 1

there were no interaction between group members before making decisions as a group, the 2

members would not realize that they were indeed assigned to groups. Therefore, to increase 3

credibility in our experiments, we used the same mutual identification4 employed in Bohnet and 4

Frey (1999), in which each member of the group would stand up and show their face to the 5

other member in silence. The instruction sheets for both the individual-choice task and the 6

group-choice task were identical except for the parts related to the individual or group task. 7

These were distributed to subjects at the beginning of each task independently and read aloud. 8

There were few questions about the experimental procedures. All required one-shot anonymous 9

decisions,5 and there was no feedback of any kind until the end of the experiments. 10

Here, we describe our task in detail. In Task 1, the risk preference elicitation experiment 11

introduced by Holt and Laury (2002) was conducted, where subjects choose between a “safe” 12

(Option A) and a “risky” (Option B) option. All 10 decisions appeared simultaneously, as shown 13

in Table 2, and 110 yen equaled approximately 1 US dollar at the time of the experiment. One 14

decision was chosen randomly by the computer for payment at the end of the experiment. We 15

calculated the coefficient of relative risk aversion based on the constant relative risk aversion 16

(CRRA) utility function: 17

𝑢𝑖(𝑌𝑖) =𝑌𝑖1−𝛾𝑖

1 − 𝛾𝑖

18

where 𝛾𝑖 is the coefficient of relative risk aversion and 𝑌𝑖 represents the lottery outcomes for 19

subject i. The coefficient is less than 0 for subjects who are risk seeking, equal to 0 for subjects 20

who are risk neutral, and greater than 0 for subjects who are risk averse. 21

22

[Table 2 about here] 23

24

4 As for the group decision-making without anonymity, Shupp and Williams (2008), Baker et al. (2008) , Rockenbach et al. (2007) and Cason and Mui (1997) used face-to-face discussion with other group members to examine the differentials in preference toward risk or altruism between individuals and groups, as mentioned in the introduction. 5 He and Villeval (2014) reported that, in groups, people made very different choices between first and final choices after they observed other member’s choices in an ultimatum game and a kind of dictator game. While the authors investigated how individual preferences were aggregated in groups, the purpose of this study was to examine pure subjects’ preference differentials to decide whether to be alone or in a group, and thus, we focus on their choices in each one-shot decision.

Page 7: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

6

In Task 2, a standard public goods game was used to measure the individual altruistic 1

preference. Subjects determined how much of the 200-yen endowment to keep or invest into 2

public goods. Payoffs were determined by contributions of each member being doubled and 3

divided evenly between the members of the group. While Masclet et al. (2009) controlled 4

socio-demographic variables, such as salaried and self-employed workers, we used these 5

variables as controls in the regression model (Task 1: risk preference; Task 2: altruistic 6

preference). 7

In Tasks 3 and 4, we used the anonymous investment and donation game. Subjects 8

received a 200-yen endowment and decided how much money to invest or donate, ranging from 9

0 yen to 200 yen (intervals of 10 yen). In Task 3, their investment options were as follows: 50% 10

chance to win 2.5 times of their invested amount and 50% chance to lose their entire investment. 11

In Task 4, they donated money to the Japanese Red Cross Society. For the group-choice task, the 12

group decision was determined based on the median rule or the random rule by group members 13

and each team member received the same payoff in the group decision tasks. For the median 14

rule, the instruction sheets explained that the median value is the middle value in sorted order of 15

values, and the group decision is determined based on the median values. For the random rule, 16

subjects were instructed that the group decision was determined based on the choice of group 17

members, randomly selected with a one-third chance. Thus, in the group choice task, each group 18

member showed his or her choice for selection as the group decision and we consider that this 19

choice appropriately reflects his or her altruistic and risk preference when he or she is in a group 20

and shares a common interest with other members in each task. We observed and analyzed these 21

three values for the amount of investment and donation in each group of three people, 22

respectively, and hence, group choice is defined as “individual choice in a group” for the rest of 23

this paper. Following these tasks, we ran some experiments, and subjects were asked to answer 24

the post-experimental questionnaire individually, including questions related to social value 25

orientation (SVO) that we elaborate in the results section. 26

On average, a session lasted for about 1 hour and 15 minutes, including the 27

post-experimental questionnaire and final payment of subjects. Each participant earned 2,140 28

yen on average. 29

30

3. Results 31

Page 8: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

7

3.1 Median rule and random rule 1

Of the 360 subjects in our experiment, we excluded the 8 subjects who switched backed more 2

than twice and the 4 subjects who chose the safe option (Option A) in decision 10 of the risk 3

attitude task (Task 1).6 As for the rest of our subjects, 320 subjects did not switch back at all 4

and 28 subjects switched backed once. For subjects who switched backed once, we followed the 5

procedure utilized in Lusk and Coble (2005), Harrison et al. (2007), and Anderson and Mellor 6

(2008) to calculate the range of relative risk attitude. Therefore, the sample size we finally used 7

consists of 348 subjects (59.77 % male and 40.23 % female).7 8

Tables 3 and 4 present the descriptive statistics for group-choice sub sample, and for 9

individual-choice sub sample, respectively. Although the sessions of the median rule condition 10

took place at Kochi University of Technology (87 subjects; 64.37% male) and Kyoto Sangyo 11

University (90 subjects; 77.78 % male), and the random rule condition at Kansai University 12

(171 subjects; 47.95 % male), we confirmed there was no significant difference between the 13

subsample of both rules except for the proportion of “Male” (group-choice sub sample; 78.26 % 14

male vs. 47.67 % male; p<0.01, and individual-choice sub sample; 63.53 % male vs. 48.24 % 15

male; p<0.01, using a chi-square test of independence). 16

17

[Table 3 about here] 18

19

[Table 4 about here] 20

21

3.2 Risk attitude 22

In order to extract the effects of being assigned to groups more completely, we ran a regression 23

model, controlling for some other factors. Since our dependent variable is left and right 24

censored variables (takes values from 0 to 200), we ran a Tobit model widely used in economic 25

models. We estimated the investment equation, in which independent variables are individual 26

attitudes measured in Task 1 (about risk), “Group-choice” dummy variables (whether assigned 27

to group-choice tasks or not), an interaction term between “Group-choice” and “Random-rule,” 28

6 Because choosing a safe option in the tenth decision means preferring a certain 200 yen over a certain 380 yen, we interpret this as a sign that the subject did not understand the instructions (see Anderson and Mellor 2008, p. 1265). 7 We determined the lower bound of the range by the first choice of risky option and the upper bound by the last choice of safe option (see Anderson and Mellor 2008, p. 1265).

Page 9: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

8

university dummy variables, and gender dummy variables. Model 2 includes the independent 1

variable of contributions in PGG (Task 2) for robustness checks in the equation. We present the 2

marginal effects on the expected value of the censored outcome estimated after the Tobit model. 3

Table 5 shows the estimation results of regression on investment, in which robust standard 4

errors are utilized. Of primary interest here is the estimated marginal effects of “Group-choice” 5

variable. We confirm that it is negative and significant at the level of 0.05, which indicates that 6

subjects in a group tend to be more risk averse than individuals tend to be. According to the 7

estimated marginal effects, subjects were more likely to decrease the investment by 8

approximately 20.3 yen on average in Model 1, and 19.9 yen in Model 2 (subjects were asked to 9

invest in their options, ranging from 0 yen to 200 yen in Task 3). Note that the estimated 10

coefficients of interaction term between “Group-choice” and “Random rule” are not significant 11

in both Models. These results mean that the effects of being assigned to groups have also same 12

impacts no matter which collective decision rules are adopted in investment. 13

As for other independent variables, the marginal effects of risk attitude assessed by the 14

CRRA is negative and significant at the level of 0.01, which indicates that more risk-averse 15

subjects tend to decrease the amount of investment. With respect to gender effect, males tend to 16

invest more than females tend to by approximately 20 yen on average in both Models 1 and 2 at 17

a significance level of 0.01. Whether Eckel and Grossman (2008) concluded that males are 18

indeed more risk-seeking than females, Filippin and Crosetto (2016), who conducted a 19

meta-analysis of the Holt and Laury risk elicitation method in the experimental literature, 20

reported that gender differences in risk attitudes appear in less than 10% of the available 54 21

replications studies. 22

23

[Table 5 about here] 24

25

3.3 Altruistic preferences 26

Regarding the donation equation in Table 6,8 Model 2 includes variable of individuals’ risk 27

preference (Task 1) for robustness checks. By focusing on the effects of being assigned to 28

groups, subjects in group-choice tasks significantly decrease their donation compared to those in 29

individual-choice tasks, at a significance level of 0.05. For regression results, we conclude that 30 8 For altruism, evidence of gender difference is mixed in previous studies (see Kamas et al. 2008). Our results show there is significant gender difference in the amount of donation (p<0.1).

Page 10: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

9

subjects in a group tend to be more self-interested than individuals tend to be. On average, they 1

tend to decrease the donation by about 23.8 yen in Model 1 and 23.3 yen in Model 2 (the range 2

of the donation choice was 0–200 yen in Task 4). We here also observe that the coefficients of 3

interaction term between “Group-choice” and “Random rule” are not statistically significant in 4

donation equation. These results indicate that the group effects are robust in both collective 5

decision rules, the median and random rule. Comparing estimated marginal effects of 6

“Group-choice” variable and the mean of two dependent variables, investment (mean = 113.89 7

yen) and donation (mean = 48.12 yen),9 it seems that the effects of being assigned to groups on 8

altruism are greater than those on risk attitudes (marginal effects; 20.3 yen on risk attitudes vs. 9

23.8 yen on altruism in Model 1). 10

For other independent variables, the amount of contribution in PGG is positively 11

associated with the amount of donation at a significance level of 0.01. In order to check the 12

robustness of the donation equation, we controlled subjects’ prosocial orientation in both 13

Models, measured by SVO developed by Van Lange et al. (1997, 2007). This SVO variable is 14

widely known to be associated with the results of the dictator game and it assesses the 15

individual altruistic preferences (refer to Cornelissen et al. 2011). The dummy variable of 16

prosocial equals 1 if subjects were defined as prosocial in the SVO method, and are 0 for any 17

other case.10 The coefficients of both the contribution and prosocial variables are positive and 18

statistically significant at the level of 0.01. Hence, we might capture and control the other 19

aspects of altruism by introducing the prosocial dummy variable, as defined in the SVO method. 20

21

[Table 6 about here] 22

23

4. Discussion 24

Based on the above results that the coefficients of interaction term between “Group-choice” and 25

“Random rule” are not significant in both investment and donation equations confirm that group 26

effects we observed are robust and have same impacts in both collective decision rules. 27

However, to examine more precisely whether there is no difference between the median and 28

9 The mean of investment and donation variables, for individual choice are 113.89 yen and 48.12 yen respectively, and for group choice 93.48 yen and 31.52 yen. 10 In our sample, approximately 45.1% of subjects were defined as “prosocial.” This is consistent with Au and Kwong (2004), who reported that by meta-analysis, about 45% were categorized as “prosocial” on average in various studies.

Page 11: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

10

random rule on group decision-making, we extract the group-choice subsample (N = 178) and 1

ran a regression model adding “random rule” dummy variables and “random rule” interaction 2

terms to our model.11 In Table 7, Model 1 reports regression results of investment equation, and 3

Models 2 and 3 of donation equation for the group-choice sub sample (Model 3 controls for 4

individuals’ risk preference instead of contributions in Model 2). According to the results of 5

investment (Model 1), the marginal effect of “Random rule” dummy variable is negative and 6

significant at the level of 0.05. This result indicates that subjects were more likely to decrease 7

the investment by approximately 30.7 yen on average when random rule was adopted. In 8

addition, the coefficients of interaction term between “Random rule” and “Risk preference” are 9

positive and significant at the level of 0.05. With reference to Figure 112 to aid the discussion, 10

this suggests that in the random rule more risk-seeking subjects tend to decrease their 11

investment than more risk-averse subjects do. In seeking a possible explanation for these results, 12

we assumed that whereas the probability (1/3 chance) that his/her choices are selected is 13

obvious in the random rule, the probability of the selection is ambiguous in the median rule. 14

Thus, the group effects (risk-averse shift in groups) have greater impacts in the random rule 15

than those in the median rule, because the subjects realize that his/her choices may be selected 16

indeed for the group decisions. Furthermore, risk-seeking subjects are more affected by group 17

effects than risk-averse subjects are, because the former may understand that their preference is 18

relatively higher than that of other subjects, and thereby decrease the level of investment to a 19

large extent, that is, refrain from risk-taking behavior, by considering the group decisions. 20

21

[Table 7 about here] 22

23

[Figure 1 about here] 24

25

For the altruistic task, although Figure 2 suggests that other-regarding subjects tend to 26

decrease the level of donation more than self-interested subjects do in the random rule, the 27

coefficients of “random rule” dummy variables and “random rule” interaction terms are not 28

11 Since in our experiments the random rule conditions were only performed at Kansai University, so we exclude university dummy variables from the model. 12 We take values of −2 and 2 for choosing the risky option in decision 1 and the safe option in decisions 10, respectively, as the midpoint of the CRRA interval, following Reynaud and Couture (2012).

Page 12: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

11

significant in all models in Table 7. Thus, we conclude that the significant difference between 1

both rules that we captured as above is not observed in donation task. Since in our experiment, 2

the individual-choice task and the group-choice task were conducted in the same session and the 3

instruction sheets subjects received were identical, so we run same regression model for 4

individual-choice sub sample (N = 170) in Table 8. We confirm that announcing the collective 5

decision rule, the median rule or random rule, does not cause significant difference for the 6

individual-choice task in our experiments. 7

8

[Figure 2 about here] 9

10

[Table 8 about here] 11

12

5. Conclusions 13

We attempted to investigate pure subjects’ preference differentials toward risk and altruism to 14

decide whether to be alone or in a group. Our experiment was designed to exclude the effects of 15

informal discussion in a group by forbidding communication with members of the group and 16

adopting the two collective decision rules, the median and random rule, both of which enhance 17

truth-telling mechanism at the time of group decision-making. Our results show that subjects 18

who made decisions in a group tended to decrease their amount of investment and donation on 19

average in both rules. These results are in line with some previous economic literature (see 20

Shupp and Williams 2008; Luhan et al. 2009; Masclet et al. 2009, as cited in the introduction). 21

However, the prior literature discusses communication effects and different “collective decision 22

rules” in order to reach agreement in group decision-making (e.g., majority rule, unanimity, and 23

dictator rule). In this current paper, we conclude that pure subjects’ preferences appear to be 24

more risk averse and self-interested when they are assigned to a group whose members have a 25

common interest in both the median and random rule. In addition, comparing the both rules, we 26

also found that the group effects (risk-averse shift in investment) had greater impacts in the 27

random rule than those in the median rule, and that risk-seeking subjects were more affected by 28

group effects than were risk-averse subjects, that is, they decreased their level of investment 29

more. 30

Page 13: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

12

Our results shed light on the “black box” of group decision-making, as mentioned in the 1

introduction. Ambrus et al. (2015) found that median group members have a significant 2

influence on group decisions via free discussion in the trust game and risk task of Holt and 3

Laury (2002). Luhan et al. (2009) reported that most self-interested group members had the 4

largest impact on the group decision via electronic chat in a dictator game. While median group 5

members in prior works might have caused preference shifts when assigned to a group, these 6

works focused only on how individual preferences were aggregated to a group attitude 7

(preference aggregation). However, preference shifts also might have occurred by the existence 8

of other group members. We suggest that these two effects (preference shifts and aggregation) 9

were mixed up in prior works. 10

11

Page 14: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

13

Acknowledgments 1

This work was supported by the Japan Society for the Promotion of Science Grant-in-Aid 2

for Scientific Research (B) [grant number JP26285047]. 3

4

Page 15: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

14

References 1

2

Ambrus, A., Greiner., B., Pathak, P. A. (2015). How individual preferences are aggregated in 3

groups: An experimental study. Journal of Public Economics, 129, 1–13. 4

5

Anderson, L. R., Mellor, J. M. (2008). Predicting health behaviors with an experimental 6

measure of risk preference. Journal of Health Economics, 27(5), 1260–1274. 7

8

Au, W. T., Kwong, Y. Y. (2004). Measurements and effects of social-value orientation in social 9

dilemmas: A review. In R. Suleiman, D. V. Budescu, I. Fischer, D. M. Messick (Eds.), 10

Contemporary research on social dilemmas (pp. 71–98). New York: Cambridge University 11

Press. 12

13

Baker, R., Laury, S., Williams, A. (2008). Comparing small-group and individual behavior in 14

lottery-choice experiments. Southern Economic Journal, 75(2), 367–382. 15

16

Bohnet, I., Frey, B. (1999). The sound of silence in prisoner's dilemma and dictator games. 17

Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 38(1), 43–57. 18

19

Bornstein, G., Yaniv, I. (1998). Individual and group behavior in the ultimatum game: Are 20 groups more “rational” players? Experimental Economics, 1, 101–108. 21 22 Brown, R. (1974). Further comment on the risky shift. American Psychologist, 29, 468–470. 23 24 Burnstein, E., Vinokur, A., Trope, Y. (1973). Interpersonal comparisons versus persuasive 25 argument: A more direct test of alternative explanations for group-induced shifts in individual 26 choices. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 9, 236–245. 27

28

Cason, T.N., Mui, V. L. (1997). A laboratory study of group polarisation in the team dictator 29

game. Economic Journal, 107, 1465–1483. 30

31

Cason, T. N., Saijo, T., Sjostrom, T., Yamato, T. (2006). Secure implementation experiments: Do 32

strategy-proof mechanisms really work? Games and Economic Behavior, 57(2), 206–235. 33

Page 16: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

15

Charness, G., Sutter, M. (2012). Groups make better self-interested decisions. Journal of 1

Economic Perspectives, 26(3), 157–176. 2

3

Cornelissen, G., Dewitte, S., Warlop, L. (2011). Are social value orientations expressed 4

automatically? Decision making in the dictator game. Personality and Social Psychology 5

Bulletin, 37, 1080–1090. 6

7

Cox, J. C., Hayne, S. C. (2006). Barking up the right tree: Are small groups rational agents? 8

Experimental Economics, 9(3), 209–222. 9

10

Eckel, C., Grossman, P. (2008). Men, women and risk aversion: Experimental evidence. In C. 11 Plott, V. Smith (Eds.), Handbook of Experimental Economics Results. New York: 12 North-Holland (Elsevier). 13 14 Filippin, A., Crosetto, P. (2016). A reconsideration of gender differences in risk attitudes. 15 Management Science, 62(11), 3138–3160. 16 17 Fischbacher, U. (2007). z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments. 18 Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178. 19 20 Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., Rutstrom, E. E. (2007). Estimating risk attitudes in Denmark: A 21 field experiment. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 109(2), 341–368. 22 23 Harrison, G. W., Lau, M. I., Rutstrom, E. E., Tarazona-Gomez, M. (2012). Preferences over 24 social risk. Oxford Economic Papers, 65(1), 25–46. 25

26

He, H., Villeval, M.C. (2014). Are teams less inequality averse than individuals? IZA 27

Discussion Paper No. 8217. 28

29

Holt, C. A., Laury, S. K. (2002). Risk aversion and incentive effects. American Economic 30

Review, 92(5), 1644–1655. 31

32

Page 17: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

16

Kamas, L., Preston, A., Baum, S. (2008). Altruism in individual and joint-giving decisions: 1

What’s gender got to do with it? Feminist Economics, 14, 23–50. 2

3

Kerr, L. N., MacCoun, R. J., Kramer, G. P. (1996). Bias in judgment: Comparing individuals 4

and groups. Psychological Review, 103, 687–719. 5

6

Kocher, M., Sutter, M. (2005). The decision maker matters: Individuals versus group behaviour 7

in experimental beauty-contest games. Economic Journal, 115, 200–223. 8

9

Levinger, G., Schneider, D. J. (1969). Test of the “risk is value” hypothesis. Journal of 10

Personality and Social Psychology, 11, 165–169. 11

12

Luhan, W. J., Kocher, M. G., Sutter, M. (2009). Group polarization in the team dictator game 13

reconsidered. Experimental Economics, 12, 26–41. 14

15

Lusk, J. L., Coble, K. H. (2005). Risk perceptions, risk preference, and acceptance of risky food. 16

American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 87(2), 393–405. 17

18

Manin, B. (2005). Deliberation: Why we should focus on debate rather than discussion. 19

Paper delivered at the Program in Ethics and Public Affairs Seminar. Princeton University 20

(13 October). 21

22

Masclet, D., Loheac, Y., Denant-Boemont, L., Colombier, N. (2009). Group and individual risk 23

preferences: A lottery-choice experiment. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 24

70(3), 470–484. 25

26

Mifune, N., Hizen, Y., Kamijo, Y., Okano, Y. (2016). Preemptive striking in individual and 27

group conflict. PLoS ONE, 11(5), e0154859. 28

29

Moscovici, S., Zavalloni, M. (1969). The group as a polarizer of attitudes. Journal of 30

Personality and Social Psychology, 12, 125–135. 31

Page 18: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

17

Reynaud, A., Couture, S. (2012). Stability of risk preference measures: Results from a field 1

experiment on French farmers. Theory and Decision, 73(2), 203–221. 2

3

Rockenbach, B., Sadrieh, A., Mathauschek, B. (2007). Teams take the better risks, Journal of 4

Economic Behavior & Organization, 63(3), 412-422. 5

6

Shupp, R. S., Williams, A. W. (2008). Risk preference differentials of small groups and 7

individuals. Economic Journal, 118, 258–283. 8

9

Song, F. (2008). Trust and reciprocity behavior and behavioral forecasts: Individuals versus 10

group-representatives. Games and Economic Behavior, 62(2), 675–696. 11

12

Stoner, J. A. F. (1961). A comparison of individuals and group decisions involving risk. 13

Cambridge, MA: Unpublished master’s thesis (MIT). 14

15

Sunstein, C. R. (2000). Deliberative trouble? Why groups go to extremes. Yale Law Journal, 16

110, 71–119. 17

18

Sunstein, C. R. (2002). The law of group polarization. The Journal of Political Philosophy, 10, 19

175–195. 20

21

Van Lange, P. A., Bekkers, R., Shuyt, T. N., Vugt, M. V. (2007). From games to giving: Social 22

value orientation predicts donation to noble causes. Basic and Applied Social Psychology, 29, 23

375–384. 24

25

Van Lange, P. A., De Bruin, E. M. N., Otten, W., Joireman, J. A. (1997). Development of 26

prosocial, individualistic, and competitive orientations: Theory and preliminary evidence. 27

Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 73(4), 733–746. 28

29

Zhang, J., Casari, M. (2012). How groups reach agreement in risky choices: An experiment. 30 Economic Inquiry, 50(2), 502–515. 31

Page 19: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

18

Table 1 Our experimental design 1

2 3

Part 1 Part 2

Individual task (N = 348) Individual-choice task (N = 170)—Task 1 —Task 3—Task 2 —Task 4

Group-choice task (N = 178) Collective decision rules—Task 3 Median rule condition (N = 92)—Task 4 Random rule condition (N = 86)

Page 20: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

19

Table 2. Lottery choice experiment (Holt and Laury, 2002) 1

2 Note: EV(A) and EV(B) represent expected value of Options A and B, respectively. The last column provides the 3

proportions of subjects who chose the risky option (Option B) for the first time in 10 decisions. To calculate the 4 proportions, we here used data from subjects who did not switch back at all in this task. These two columns 5 were not displayed to the subjects. 6

7

Probability Payoff Probability Payoff Probability Payoff Probability Payoff1 10% 200 yen 90% 160 yen 10% 380 yen 90% 10 yen 117 0.62 20% 200 yen 80% 160 yen 20% 380 yen 80% 10 yen 84 0.33 30% 200 yen 70% 160 yen 30% 380 yen 70% 10 yen 51 0.64 40% 200 yen 60% 160 yen 40% 380 yen 60% 10 yen 18 5.25 50% 200 yen 50% 160 yen 50% 380 yen 50% 10 yen -15 13.96 60% 200 yen 40% 160 yen 60% 380 yen 40% 10 yen -48 12.57 70% 200 yen 30% 160 yen 70% 380 yen 30% 10 yen -81 28.48 80% 200 yen 20% 160 yen 80% 380 yen 20% 10 yen -114 27.09 90% 200 yen 10% 160 yen 90% 380 yen 10% 10 yen -147 8.710 100% 200 yen 0% 160 yen 100% 380 yen 0% 10 yen -180 2.9

Propotion of subjects

EV(A)-EV(B)DecisionOption A Option B

Page 21: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

20

Table 3. Descriptive statistics for the group-choice subsample: Median rule (MR) vs. Random rule (RR) 1

Group-choice sub sample Median Rule Random Rule MR - RR

Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev. p-value

Investment 101.74 67.41

84.65 56.50

0.12

Donation 31.20 54.39 31.86 50.61 0.19

Risk preference 0.44 0.41 0.51 0.60 0.30

Contributions 63.91 74.83 47.56 59.98 0.36

Prosocial 0.42 0.50 0.43 0.50 0.93

Male 0.78 0.41

0.48 0.50

0.000 ***

Note: Median rule (N=92), Random rule (N=86). Except for the proportion of “Male,” we confirmed there was no significant difference between median 2 rule and random rule samples regarding the amount of donation and investment, the level of “Risk preference (Task 1)” and “Contributions (Task 2)” 3 (by a non-parametric Mann–Whitney U-test), and also the proportion of subjects who were defined as “Prosocial” in the SVO method (by a 4 chi-square test of independence). Only the proportion of “Male” was significantly different between median rule and random rule samples (78.26 % 5 vs. 47.67 %; p<0.01; chi-square test of independence). 6

7 8 9

Page 22: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

21

Table 4. Descriptive statistics for the individual-choice subsample: Median rule (MR) vs. Random rule (RR) 1 Individual-choice sub sample Median Rule Random Rule MR - RR

Mean Std. Dev. Mean Std. Dev. p-value

Investment 116.24 62.45

111.53 68.11

0.64

Donation 52.59 66.92 43.65 61.81 0.42

Risk preference 0.52 0.53 0.53 0.50 0.89

Contributions 67.29 69.03 58.59 64.87 0.50

Prosocial 0.45 0.50 0.51 0.50 0.44

Male 0.64 0.48

0.48 0.50

0.045 **

Note: Median rule (N=85), Random rule (N=85). Only the proportion of “Male” was significantly different between median rule and random rule samples 2 (63.53 % vs. 48.24 %; p<0.01; chi-square test of independence). 3

Page 23: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

22

Table 5. Estimation results: Investment (Tobit model) 1 Investment Model 1 Marginal Model 2 Marginal Effects Effects

Risk preference -47.36*** -34.29*** -46.51*** -33.66*** (10.92) (7.60) (10.76) (7.49) Group dummy -28.38** -20.32** -27.74** -19.87** (13.15) (9.14) (13.10) (9.12) Interaction term (group × random rule) -12.84 -9.33 -11.74 -8.52 (18.74) (13.61) (18.57) (13.48) Contributions - - 0.157** 0.11** - - (0.078) (0.06) Male 28.36*** 20.82*** 27.70*** 20.32*** (9.25) (6.78) (9.159) (6.71) Kochi University of Technology -5.333 -3.86 -7.093 -5.13 (14.80) (10.68) (14.61) (10.53) Kyoto Sangyo University 7.821 5.68 7.086 5.15 (16.65) (12.14) (16.51) (12.03) Constant 133.9*** - 124.4*** - (12.29) - (12.98) -

Observations 348 348 Log pseudolikelihood -1493.87 -1491.39 Note: Significance levels: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. 2 3

Page 24: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

23

Table 6. Estimation results: Donation (Tobit model) 1 Donation Model 1 Marginal Model 2 Marginal Effects Effects

Contributions 0.317*** 0.15*** 0.320*** 0.15*** (0.10) (0.05) (0.10) (0.05) Group dummy -43.28** -23.78** -42.46** -23.27** (17.68) (10.59) (17.66) (10.55) Interaction term (group × random rule) 34.70 15.82 34.20 15.60 (23.64) (10.07) (23.50) (10.02) Prosocial 45.92*** 19.32*** 45.70*** 19.22*** (12.33) (4.30) (12.38) (4.33) Risk preference - - 8.554 4.14 - - (12.24) (5.92) Male -23.83* -12.54* -22.98* -12.04* (12.16) (6.82) (12.31) (6.87) Kochi University of Technology 23.06 10.77 22.96 10.72 (19.22) (8.68) (19.24) (8.68) Kyoto Sangyo University 13.49 6.38 13.37 6.32 (18.69) (8.62) (18.67) (8.61) Constant -15.98 - -21.20 - (14.65) - (17.13) - Observations 348 348 Log pseudolikelihood -1139.47 -1139.22 Note: Significance levels: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. 2 3

Page 25: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

24

Table 7. Estimation results for the group-choice sample (Tobit Model) 1 Group-choice subsample Model 1 Marginal Model 2 Marginal Model 3 Marginal Investment Effects Donation Effects Donation Effects

Risk preference -88.19*** -66.76*** - - -19.73 -8.96 (21.85) (15.57) - - (27.24) (12.35) Interaction term (random rule × 57.88** 40.50** - - 35.22 14.86

risk preference) (25.10) (15.63) - - (32.24) (12.58) Random rule -40.68** -30.66** 30.19 12.01 -2.670 -1.23 (16.77) (11.94) (22.22) (7.55) (21.49) (9.97) Contributions - - 0.275 0.12 0.150 0.07 - - (0.19) (0.08) (0.127) (0.06) Interaction term (random rule × - - -0.285 -0.13 - -

contributions) - - (0.25) (0.12) - - Prosocial - - 43.14*** 16.56*** 42.33*** 16.35*** - - (15.89) (5.05) (15.76) (5.04) Male 25.04** 18.83** -16.13 -7.90 -15.90 -7.81 (11.21) (8.32) (15.89) (8.35) (15.99) (8.42) Constant 126.6*** - -39.13* - -21.59 - (14.65) - (23.41) - (23.33) -

Observations 178 178 178 Log pseudolikelihood -780.1 -549.2 -549.4 Note : Significance levels: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. 2 3

Page 26: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

25

Table 8. Estimation results for the individual-choice subsample (Tobit model) 1 Individual-choice sub sample Model 1 Marginal Model 2 Marginal Model 3 Marginal Investment Effects Donation Effects Donation Effects

Risk preference -64.18*** -44.37*** - - -1.419 -0.72 (24.16) (16.07) - - (28.52) (14.55) Interaction term (random rule × 41.05 28.18 - - 21.39 10.59

risk preference) (36.61) (24.58) - - (39.29) (18.75) Random rule -22.22 -14.90 -29.55 -16.10 -30.83 -16.83

(24.56) (15.79) (24.23) (13.88) (29.92) (17.21) Contributions - - 0.419** 0.21** 0.493*** 0.25*** - - (0.20) (0.10) (0.161) (0.08) Interaction term (random rule × - - 0.156 0.08 - -

contributions) - - (0.30) (0.15) - - Prosocial - - 47.73** 21.70*** 49.74** 22.42*** - - (19.73) (7.56) (19.85) (7.45) Male 34.57** 24.82** -35.53* -19.74* -34.20* -18.92* (14.61) (10.64) (18.16) (10.63) (18.44) (10.73) Constant 141.2*** - 0.212 - -6.039 - (18.77) - (20.58) - (23.95) -

Observations 170 170 170 Log pseudolikelihood -709.9 -587.4 -587.3 Note : Significance levels: *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1. Robust standard errors in parentheses. 2 3

Page 27: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

26

Fig. 1 Scatter plots with a regression line: Investment (Group-choice sub sample) 1

2

3

¥0

¥20

¥40

¥60

¥80

¥100

¥120

¥140

¥160

¥180

¥200

-2 -1.5 -1 -0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2

Inve

stm

ent

Risk preference

Median rule

Random rule

Page 28: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

27

Fig. 2 Scatter plots with a regression line: Donation (Group-choice sub sample) 1

2 3

¥0

¥50

¥100

¥0 ¥50 ¥100 ¥150 ¥200

Don

atio

n

Contributions

Median rule

Random rule

Page 29: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

28

Appendix A13. Experiment Instructions (in English for the median rule) 1

2

1. Introduction 3

4

Thank you for participating in our experiment. I now explain our experimental procedure. If you 5

have any questions, please simply raise your hand. In addition, please do not communicate in 6

any way with other subjects and turn off your cellphone during the experiment. To start, ensure 7

that the following materials are on your table. 8

9

● Instructions 10

● Experimental agreement form 11

● Receipt 12

● Ballpoint pen 13

14

2. Experimental description 15

16

In this experiment, you will make four different types of decisions privately using the computer 17

in front of you. You will earn different amounts depending on your decisions. At the end of the 18

experiment, you will be paid in cash based on your decisions as well as 1,100 yen for 19

participating in this experiment. Please make decisions with the objective of earning a lot of 20

money. 21

Now, the first experiment will start. In the remainder of these instructions, ‘Player’ 22 indicates subjects who make decisions in the experiment and ‘Experimenter’ indicates 23 non-players, or we who are conducting the experiment. You can stop participating in the 24 experiment at any time. 25 26

13 Appendix A-F are not meant to be published.

Page 30: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

29

3.Experimental tasks 1

3.1 Task 1 2

3

In this task, the Player chooses between Option A and Option B as follows. 4

5

6

7

For example, in Questions 1, both options are as follows: there is a 10% chance of 8

earning 200 yen and a 90% chance of earning 100 yen (Option A); on the contrary, there is a 9

10% chance of earning 380 yen and a 90% chance of earning 10 yen (Option B). After making 10

decisions from Questions 1 to 10, one question will be chosen randomly by the computer for 11

payment at the end of the experiment. In more detail, if the computer were to choose the fifth 12

Page 31: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

30

question, the Player who preferred Option A would have a 50% chance of earning 200 yen and a 1

50% chance of earning 160 yen. Similarly, the Player who preferred Option B would have a 2

50% chance of earning 360 yen and a 50% chance of earning 10 yen. 3

If you have any questions about this task, please simply raise your hand. We now have 1 4

minute to consider Task 1. 5

After this instruction, all 10 questions and options will appear on your computer, such as 6

shown in Figure 1. Please make all your decisions and click the OK button on the bottom right 7

of your screen after inputting your decisions. 8

9

10

Figure 1. Computer screen for Task 111

12 13

Page 32: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

31

3.2 Task 2 1

2

The Player has a 200-yen endowment and this will be assigned randomly to a group of three 3

people. The Player will decide how much of the 200-yen endowment to keep or invest in their 4

group project. The payment will be determined by the contributions of each member being 5

doubled and divided evenly between the members of the group, as follows. 6

7

Your earnings = (All contributions in your group × 2 ÷ 3) + (200 - Your investment) 8

9

For example, if each member were to invest the same amount of 200 yen in the group 10

project, each member would earn 400 yen. For another example, if no members were to invest 11

in the group project at all, each member would earn 200 yen. 12

13

Exercise 1 14

In a certain group, if one member were to invest 120 yen and two members were to invest 60 15

yen in their group project, how much money would each group member earn in Task 2? 16

17

Member investing 120 yen: yen 18

Member investing 60 yen: yen 19

20

Exercise 2 21

In a given group, if two members were to invest 180 yen and one member nothing at all in their 22

group project, how much money would each group member earn in Task 2? 23

24

Member investing 180 yen: yen 25

Member investing nothing at all: yen 26

27

If you have any questions, please simply raise your hand. We now have 1 minute to 28

consider Task 2. 29

After this instruction, the screen will change on your computer, for example, as shown in 30

Figure 2. Please decide how much money to invest in your group project, ranging from 0 yen to 31

Page 33: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

32

200 yen (in intervals of 10 yen). Click the OK button on the bottom right of your screen after 1

inputting your decision. 2

3

Figure 2. Computer screen for Task 24

5

6

Page 34: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

33

1

In Tasks 3 and 4, the subjects will be divided randomly into two groups: individual-choice and 2

group-choice tasks. The subjects who are assigned to the individual-choice task will make 3

decisions alone until the end of the experiment; on the other hand, subjects assigned to the 4

group-choice task will make decisions in a group until the end of the experiment. 5

6

Individual-choice task 7

Subjects assigned to the individual-choice task make decisions by themselves for each task 8

according to their preferences. 9

10

Group-choice task 11

Subjects will be assigned randomly to groups, each comprising three people. The members of 12

groups are identical until the end of the experiment. Subjects in the group-choice task make 13

decisions according to their preferences when they are in a group and share common interests 14

with other members of their group for each task. The group decision will be determined based 15

on the median rule by group members and each team member receives the same payoff in the 16

group-decision tasks. We now introduce the members of each group to each other. Please stand 17

up and show your face to the other members when your number is called. In addition, please do 18

not communicate in any way with other members and other subjects during the experiment. 19 20

21 22 23

Page 35: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

34

3.3 Task 3 1 2

Individual-choice task 3

The Player has a 200-yen endowment and will decide how much of the 200-yen endowment to 4

invest in the Option, as follows: there is a 50% chance of winning 2.5 times your invested 5

amount and a 50% chance of losing your entire investment. 6

7

Your earnings = 200 - Your investment + Profit from the Option 8

9

Group-choice task 10

The Player and other members of the group each have a 200-yen endowment. You will decide 11 how much of the 200-yen endowment to invest in the Option, as mentioned below. The group 12 decision is determined based on the median rule by group members and each group member 13 will receive the same payoff. For example, if the three group members were to decide to invest 14 0 yen, 50 yen, and 100 yen, respectively, then the group investment decision in the Option 15 would be 50 yen. 16 Please make a decision according to your desired level of investment in this Option. 17 18

Your earnings = 200 - The amount of group decision of investment + Profit from the 19

Option 20

21 22 Note: About median value 23 The median value is the middle value in sorted order of values. For example, when the 24 observed number in the sorted order is {0, 30, 80, 100, 200}, then the median value is 80. 25 26 27

If you have any questions, please simply raise your hand. We now have 1 minute to 28

consider Task 3. 29

After this instruction, the screen will change on your computer, such as that shown in 30

Figure 3. Please decide how much money to invest in this Option, ranging from 0 yen to 200 31

yen (in intervals of 10 yen). Click the OK button on the bottom right of your screen after 32

inputting your decision.33

Page 36: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

35

Figure 3. Computer screen for Task 3 1

2

For individual-choice task 3

4

5 For group-choice task 6

7

8

Page 37: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

36

3.4 Task 4 1 2

Individual-choice task 3

The Player has a 200-yen endowment and will decide how much of the 200-yen endowment to 4

donate to the Japanese Red Cross Society. The Experimenter will indeed donate the amount of 5

the contribution that was decided in this task to the Japanese Red Cross Society. 6

7

Your earnings = 200 - Your Donation 8

9

Group-choice task 10

The Player and other members of the group each have a 200-yen endowment. You will decide 11 how much of the 200-yen endowment to donate to the Japanese Red Cross Society. The group 12 decision will be determined based on the median rule by the group members and each group 13 member will receive the same payoff. For example, if the three group members were to decide 14 to denote 0 yen, 50 yen, and 100 yen, respectively, then the group’s donation decision would 15 be 50 yen. Please make a decision according to your desired level of donation to the Japanese 16 Red Cross Society. 17 18

Your earnings = 200 - The amount of group decision of donation 19 20 Note: About the Japanese Red Cross Society (a direct quote from website) 21 Japanese Red Cross Society provides protection and assistance to suffering from conflicts, 22 disasters, and diseases. We would appreciate for your donation, blood donation or volunteering 23 with us. 24 25 26

If you have any questions, please simply raise your hand. We now have 1 minute to 27

consider Task 4. 28

After this instruction, the screen will change on your computer, such as that shown in Figure 4. 29

Please decide how much money to donate to the Japanese Red Cross Society, ranging from 0 30

yen to 200 yen (in intervals of 10 yen). Click the OK button on the bottom right of your screen 31

after inputting your decision.32

Page 38: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

37

Figure 4. Computer screen for Task 4 1

2

For individual-choice task 3

4

5 For group-choice task 6

7

8

Page 39: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

38

Appendix B. Experiment Instructions (in English for the random rule) 1

2

1. Introduction 3

4

Thank you for participating in our experiment. I now explain our experimental procedure. If you 5

have any questions, please simply raise your hand. In addition, please do not communicate in 6

any way with other subjects and turn off your cellphone during the experiment. To start, ensure 7

that the following materials are on your table. 8

9

● Instructions 10

● Experimental agreement form 11

● Receipt 12

● Ballpoint pen 13

14

2. Experimental description 15

16

In this experiment, you will make four different types of decisions privately using the computer 17

in front of you. You will earn different amounts depending on your decisions. At the end of the 18

experiment, you will be paid in cash based on your decisions as well as 1,100 yen for 19

participating in this experiment. Please make decisions with the objective of earning a lot of 20

money. 21

Now, the first experiment will start. In the remainder of these instructions, ‘Player’ 22 indicates subjects who make decisions in the experiment and ‘Experimenter’ indicates 23 non-players, or we who are conducting the experiment. You can stop participating in the 24 experiment at any time. 25 26

Page 40: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

39

3.Experimental tasks 1

3.1 Task 1 2

3

In this task, the Player chooses between Option A and Option B as follows. 4

5

6

7

For example, in Questions 1, both options are as follows: there is a 10% chance of 8

earning 200 yen and a 90% chance of earning 100 yen (Option A); on the contrary, there is a 9

10% chance of earning 380 yen and a 90% chance of earning 10 yen (Option B). After making 10

decisions from Questions 1 to 10, one question will be chosen randomly by the computer for 11

payment at the end of the experiment. In more detail, if the computer were to choose the fifth 12

Page 41: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

40

question, the Player who preferred Option A would have a 50% chance of earning 200 yen and a 1

50% chance of earning 160 yen. Similarly, the Player who preferred Option B would have a 2

50% chance of earning 360 yen and a 50% chance of earning 10 yen. 3

If you have any questions about this task, please simply raise your hand. We now have 1 4

minute to consider Task 1. 5

After this instruction, all 10 questions and options will appear on your computer, such as 6

shown in Figure 1. Please make all your decisions and click the OK button on the bottom right 7

of your screen after inputting your decisions. 8

9

10

Figure 1. Computer screen for Task 111

12 13

Page 42: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

41

3.2 Task 2 1

2

The Player has a 200-yen endowment and this will be assigned randomly to a group of three 3

people. The Player will decide how much of the 200-yen endowment to keep or invest in their 4

group project. The payment will be determined by the contributions of each member being 5

doubled and divided evenly between the members of the group, as follows. 6

7

Your earnings = (All contributions in your group × 2 ÷ 3) + (200 - Your investment) 8

9

For example, if each member were to invest the same amount of 200 yen in the group 10

project, each member would earn 400 yen. For another example, if no members were to invest 11

in the group project at all, each member would earn 200 yen. 12

13

Exercise 1 14

In a certain group, if one member were to invest 120 yen and two members were to invest 60 15

yen in their group project, how much money would each group member earn in Task 2? 16

17

Member investing 120 yen: yen 18

Member investing 60 yen: yen 19

20

Exercise 2 21

In a given group, if two members were to invest 180 yen and one member nothing at all in their 22

group project, how much money would each group member earn in Task 2? 23

24

Member investing 180 yen: yen 25

Member investing nothing at all: yen 26

27

If you have any questions, please simply raise your hand. We now have 1 minute to 28

consider Task 2. 29

After this instruction, the screen will change on your computer, for example, as shown in 30

Figure 2. Please decide how much money to invest in your group project, ranging from 0 yen to 31

Page 43: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

42

200 yen (in intervals of 10 yen). Click the OK button on the bottom right of your screen after 1

inputting your decision. 2

3

Figure 2. Computer screen for Task 24

5

6

Page 44: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

43

1

In Tasks 3 and 4, the subjects will be divided randomly into two groups: individual-choice and 2

group-choice tasks. The subjects who are assigned to the individual-choice task will make 3

decisions alone until the end of the experiment; on the other hand, subjects assigned to the 4

group-choice task will make decisions in a group until the end of the experiment. 5

6

Individual-choice task 7

Subjects assigned to the individual-choice task make decisions by themselves for each task 8

according to their preferences. 9

10

Group-choice task 11

Subjects will be assigned randomly to groups, each comprising three people. The members of 12

groups are identical until the end of the experiment. Subjects in the group-choice task make 13

decisions according to their preferences when they are in a group and share common interests 14

with other members of their group for each task. The group decision will be determined based 15

on the choice of group members, randomly selected with a one-third chance, and each team 16

member receives the same payoff in the group-decision tasks. We now introduce the members 17

of each group to each other. Please stand up and show your face to the other members when 18

your number is called. In addition, please do not communicate in any way with other members 19

and other subjects during the experiment. 20 21

22 23 24

Page 45: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

44

3.3 Task 3 1 2

Individual-choice task 3

The Player has a 200-yen endowment and will decide how much of the 200-yen endowment to 4

invest in the Option, as follows: there is a 50% chance of winning 2.5 times your invested 5

amount and a 50% chance of losing your entire investment. 6

7

Your earnings = 200 - Your investment + Profit from the Option 8

9

Group-choice task 10

The Player and other members of the group each have a 200-yen endowment. You will decide 11 how much of the 200-yen endowment to invest in the Option, as mentioned below. The group 12 decision is determined based on the choice of group members, randomly selected with a 13 one-third chance and each group member will receive the same payoff. Please make a decision 14 according to your desired level of investment in this Option. 15 16

Your earnings = 200 - The amount of group decision of investment + Profit from the 17

Option 18

19

If you have any questions, please simply raise your hand. We now have 1 minute to 20

consider Task 3. 21

After this instruction, the screen will change on your computer, such as that shown in 22

Figure 3. Please decide how much money to invest in this Option, ranging from 0 yen to 200 23

yen (in intervals of 10 yen). Click the OK button on the bottom right of your screen after 24

inputting your decision.25

Page 46: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

45

Figure 3. Computer screen for Task 3 1

2

For individual-choice task 3

4

5 For group-choice task 6

7

8

Page 47: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

46

3.4 Task 4 1 2

Individual-choice task 3

The Player has a 200-yen endowment and will decide how much of the 200-yen endowment to 4

donate to the Japanese Red Cross Society. The Experimenter will indeed donate the amount of 5

the contribution that was decided in this task to the Japanese Red Cross Society. 6

7

Your earnings = 200 - Your Donation 8

9

Group-choice task 10

The Player and other members of the group each have a 200-yen endowment. You will decide 11 how much of the 200-yen endowment to donate to the Japanese Red Cross Society. The group 12 decision is determined based on the choice of group members, randomly selected with a 13 one-third chance and each group member will receive the same payoff. Please make a decision 14 according to your desired level of donation to the Japanese Red Cross Society. 15 16

Your earnings = 200 - The amount of group decision of donation 17 18 Note: About the Japanese Red Cross Society (a direct quote from website) 19 Japanese Red Cross Society provides protection and assistance to suffering from conflicts, 20 disasters, and diseases. We would appreciate for your donation, blood donation or volunteering 21 with us. 22 23 24

If you have any questions, please simply raise your hand. We now have 1 minute to 25

consider Task 4. 26

After this instruction, the screen will change on your computer, such as that shown in Figure 4. 27

Please decide how much money to donate to the Japanese Red Cross Society, ranging from 0 28

yen to 200 yen (in intervals of 10 yen). Click the OK button on the bottom right of your screen 29

after inputting your decision.30

Page 48: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

47

Figure 4. Computer screen for Task 4 1

2

For individual-choice task 3

4

5 For group-choice task 6

7

8

Page 49: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

48

Appendix C. Experiment Instructions (original Japanese version for the median 1

rule) 2

3

実験インストラクション 4

5 1. はじめに 6

この度は、実験にご参加頂き、誠にありがとうございます。これから行う実験につ7 いて説明いたします。ご不明な点がございましたら、手を挙げて質問してください。8 なお、実験が終了するまで私語は慎み、携帯電話の電源は切ってください。最初に、9 以下の配布物が手元にあることを確認してください。 10 11 ●実験インストラクション(本紙) 12 ●実験の同意書 13 ●謝金の領収書 14 ●筆記用具 15 16 17 2. 実験の概要 18 本日、お集まり頂いた方には、これからコンピュータを使用して 4 種類の異なる実19 験に参加して頂きます。各実験の意思決定の結果に応じて、皆さまの実験報酬が決定20 されます。実験終了後、実験報酬に参加報酬 1,100 円を加えた金額を現金にて支払い21 ます。是非、多くの現金を獲得してください。 22 これより、実験 1 を行います。実験インストラクションにおいて、「プレイヤー」と23 は皆さまであり、「実験者」とは実験を実施する私たちを指します。なお、実験の途中24 において、いかなる理由により退席された場合にも、皆さまが不利益を被ることはご25 ざいません。 26 27 28

Page 50: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

49

3.1. 実験 1 1 この実験では、あなた自身にとって、以下の「オプション A」と「オプション B」2

のどちらがより好ましいかを選択して頂きます。 3 4

5 6

例えば、Q1 では、 7 「オプション A:確率 10%で 200 円、確率 90%で 160 円を獲得」と「オプション B:8 確率 10%で 380 円、確率 90%で 10 円を獲得」のどちらのオプションが、あなたにと9 ってより好ましいかを選択してください。実験では、Q1 から Q10 まで、それぞれ「オ10 プション A」または「オプション B」を同様に選択して頂き、最後にコンピュータが11 ランダムにくじ(1 番から 10 番)を引き、皆様が実際に獲得する金額を決定いたしま12

オプションA オプションB

Q1.確率10%(200円)

確率90%(160円)

確率10%(380円)

確率90%(10円)

Q2.確率20%(200円)

確率80%(160円)

確率20%(380円)

確率80%(10円)

Q3.確率30%(200円)

確率70%(160円)

確率30%(380円)

確率70%(10円)

Q4.確率40%(200円)

確率60%(160円)

確率40%(380円)

確率60%(10円)

Q5.確率50%(200円)

確率50%(160円)

確率50%(380円)

確率50%(10円)

Q6.確率60%(200円)

確率40%(160円)

確率60%(380円)

確率40%(10円)

Q7.確率70%(200円)

確率30%(160円)

確率70%(380円)

確率30%(10円)

Q8.確率80%(200円)

確率20%(160円)

確率80%(380円)

確率20%(10円)

Q9.確率90%(200円)

確率10%(160円)

確率90%(380円)

確率10%(10円)

Q10.確率100%(200円)

確率0%(160円)

確率100%(380円)

確率0%(10円)

Page 51: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

50

す。具体的には、コンピュータのくじ引きにおいて「5 番」が出た場合には、Q5 で「オ1 プション A」を選択されている回答者は、「オプション A:確率 50%で 200 円、確率2 50%で 160 円を獲得」が実現します。「オプション B」を選択されている回答者も同様3 に獲得金額が実現します。 4

ここまでの説明で質問などはございますか。それではこれから、意思決定について考え5 て頂くため、1 分間のシンキングタイムを取ります。 6 1 分間経過したので、これから意思決定を行って頂きます。目の前の PC の画面に注目7 してください。以下の画面が表示されましたら、Q1 から Q10 までそれぞれ「オプショ8 ン A」または「オプション B」の選択を入力してください。入力後は、「OK」ボタン9 をクリックし、そのままお待ちください。 10 11 【入力画面(「オプション」の選択)】 12

13 14

Page 52: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

51

3.2. 実験 2 1 プレイヤーは、はじめに 200 円を所持し、それぞれランダムに 3 人から構成された2

グループに所属しています。その 200 円の内のいくらかをグループのプロジェクトに3 貢献する金額を決定して頂きます。プロジェクトへの貢献は 200 円の内のいくらでも4 構いません(0 円から 200 円までの金額)。グループの全メンバー(3 人)からプロジ5 ェクトに貢献された総額の 2 倍の金額が、グループ全員に平等に分配されます。各プ6 レイヤーが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 7

8 獲得金額=(全メンバーの貢献額 ×2 ÷ 3 )+(200 -あなたの貢献額) 9

10 例えば、グループ内の 3 人全員がそれぞれ 200 円を貢献した場合、全メンバーの貢11 献額は 600 円となり、あなたはこの実験より 400 円を獲得します。一方、3 人全員が12 全く貢献をしない場合は、全メンバーの貢献額は 0 円となり、あなたはこの実験にお13 いて 200 円を獲得します。 14 15 16 <練習問題> 17 問 1. ある 1 つのグループで、1 人のメンバーが「120 円」を貢献し、2 人が「60 円」18

を貢献した場合に、ぞれぞれのメンバーの獲得金額はいくらですか。 19 「120 円」を貢献したメンバー: 円 20 「60 円」を貢献したメンバー: 円 21

22 23

問 2. ある 1 つのグループで、2 人のメンバーが「180 円」を貢献し、1 人が全く貢献24 をしなかった場合(= 貢献額「0 円」)、ぞれぞれのメンバーの獲得金額はいくら25 ですか。 26

「180 円」を貢献したメンバー: 円 27 貢献額「0 円」のメンバー: 円 28

29 ここまでの説明で質問などはございますか。それではこれから、意思決定について考え30 て頂くため、1 分間のシンキングタイムを取ります。 31 1 分間経過したので、これから意思決定を行って頂きます。目の前の PC の画面に注目32 してください。以下の画面(次ページ)が表示されましたら、あなた自身の貢献額を入33 力してください(0 円から 200 円までの金額)。貢献額の入力は、10 円単位で行うこ34 とができます。入力後は、「OK」ボタンをクリックし、そのままお待ちください。 35 36

Page 53: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

52

【入力画面(貢献額の決定)】 1

2 3

4

Page 54: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

53

1 実験 2 まで終了いたしました。続いて、実験 3 から実験 4 を順次行います。これ以2 降、各実験では皆様に「1 人の意思決定」または「3 人グループの意思決定」をして頂3 きます。どちらの意思決定を行って頂くかは、コンピュータによりランダムに決定さ4 れます。「1 人の意思決定」の方は、すべての実験終了まで「1 人の意思決定」をして5 頂きます。同様に、「3 人グループの意思決定」に選ばれた方はすべての実験終了まで6 「3 人グループの意思決定」をして頂きます。 7 8 (Ⅰ)1 人の意思決定:皆さまには、ご自身 1 人の場合を考えて、各実験における意9 思決定をして頂きます。あなたにとって、最も望ましい値を入力してください。 10 11 (Ⅱ)3 人グループの意思決定:皆さまは、これからメンバーがランダムに構成され12 た 3 人のグループに所属します。グループのメンバーは、すべての実験終了まで同じ13 です。あなたは、グループの意思決定をどのようにしたら良いか、正直にお答えくだ14 さい。実際のグループにおける選択は、後述の通りグループ内の「中央値(実験 3~4)」15 のルールにより決定します。中央値で決定する場合には、皆さんにとって正直に回答16 することが最適な選択であると知られております。多数決の場合にも、あなた自身の17 お考えを正直に回答してください。 18

同一グループのメンバーは、各実験において上記のルールに従い、同じ行動をし全19 員同額の金額を獲得します。 20

これから、グループのメンバーを紹介します。座席番号を呼ばれた方はご起立をお21 願いします。ただし、すべての実験終了までグループのメンバーと相談をしたり、話22 すことはできません。 23

24 25

Page 55: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

54

3.3. 実験 3 1 2 <1 人の意思決定の方> 3

プレイヤーは、はじめに 200 円を所持しています。その 200 円の内のいくらかを以4 下の「オプション」に投資することができます。投資は 200 円の内のいくらでも構い5 ません(0 円から 200 円までの金額)。 6

7 【オプション:確率 50%で投資額の 2.5 倍の金額を得る、確率 50%で投資額を失う】 8 9

あなたが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 10 11

獲得金額 = 200 -あなたの投資額 + オプションから得た金額 12 13

実際にオプションから得られる金額は、コンピュータのくじ引きにより決定します。 14 15 16 <3 人グループの意思決定の方> 17

あなたとグループの他のメンバーは、それぞれ 200 円を所持しており、その内のい18 くらをグループとして「オプション」に投資するかを、あなた自身のご判断で入力し19 てください。投資は 200 円の内のいくらでも構いません。グループとしての投資額は、20 メンバーの投資額の中央値により決定します。例えば、それぞれのメンバーの投資額21 が「0 円」、「50 円」、「100 円」であれば、中央値の「50 円」がグループの投資額とな22 ります。同一グループのすべてのメンバーは、上記に従い同額を投資し同じ金額を獲23 得します。3 人グループの意思決定の場合も、グループにおいて最も望ましいと思う24 投資額を入力してください。あなたが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 25

26 獲得金額 = 200 -グループの投資額 + オプションから得た金額 27

28 29 ※中央値とは 30 データを大きさの順に並べたときに、ちょうど中央に位置するデータのことである。 31

例えば、(0, 30, 80, 100, 200)における中央値は、「80」である。 32 33 34 ここまでの説明で質問などはございますか。それではこれから、意思決定について考え35

て頂くため、1 分間のシンキングタイムを取ります。 36

Page 56: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

55

1 分間経過したので、これから意思決定を行って頂きます。目の前の PC の画面に注目1 してください。以下の画面が表示されましたら、投資額を入力してください(0 円から2 200 円までの金額)。投資は、10 円単位で行うことができます。入力後は、「OK」ボ3 タンをクリックし、そのままお待ちください。 4 5 【入力画面(「投資額」の決定)】 6

<1 人の意思決定の方> 7

8 <3 人グループの意思決定の方>9

10

Page 57: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

56

3.4 実験 4 1 2 <1 人の意思決定の方> 3

プレイヤーは、はじめに 200 円を所持しています。その 200 円の内のいくらかを「日4 本赤十字社」に寄付することができます。寄付は 200 円の内のいくらでも構いません5 (0 円から 200 円までの金額)。皆さまに入力して頂いた寄付額は、実験者から実際に6 「日本赤十字社」へ寄付いたします。あなたが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 7

8 獲得金額 = 200 -寄付額 9

10 11 <3 人グループの意思決定の方> 12

あなたとグループの他のメンバーは、それぞれ 200 円を所持しており、その内のい13 くらをグループとして「日本赤十字社」に寄付するかを、あなた自身のご判断で入力14 してください。寄付は 200 円の内のいくらでも構いません。グループとしての寄付額15 は、メンバーの寄付額の中央値により決定します。例えば、それぞれのメンバーの寄16 付額が「0 円」、「50 円」、「100 円」であれば、中央値の「50 円」がグループの寄付額17 となります。同一グループのすべてのメンバーは、上記に従い同額を寄付し同じ金額18 を獲得します。3 人グループの意思決定の場合も、グループにおいて最も望ましいと19 思う寄付額を入力してください。あなたが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 20

21 獲得金額 = 200 -グループの寄付額 22

23 24

※日本赤十字社とは 25 日本赤十字社は、紛争・災害・病気などで苦しむ人を救うためあらゆる支援をして26

います。皆様の寄付・献血・ボランティアをお待ちしております(日本赤十字社 HP27 より引用)。 28

29 30 31 ここまでの説明で質問などはございますか。それではこれから、意思決定について考え32

て頂くため、1 分間のシンキングタイムを取ります。 33 1 分間経過したので、これから意思決定を行って頂きます。目の前の PC の画面に注目34 してください。以下の画面(次ページ)が表示されましたら、寄付額を入力してくださ35

Page 58: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

57

い(0 円から 200 円までの金額)。寄付は、10 円単位で行うことができます。入力後1 は、「OK」ボタンをクリックし、そのままお待ちください。 2

3 【入力画面(「寄付額」の決定)】 4 5

<1 人の意思決定の方> 6

7 8

<3 人グループの意思決定の方> 9

10

Page 59: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

58

Appendix D. Experiment Instructions (original Japanese version for the random 1

rule) 2

3

実験インストラクション 4

5 1. はじめに 6

この度は、実験にご参加頂き、誠にありがとうございます。これから行う実験につ7 いて説明いたします。ご不明な点がございましたら、手を挙げて質問してください。8 なお、実験が終了するまで私語は慎み、携帯電話の電源は切ってください。最初に、9 以下の配布物が手元にあることを確認してください。 10 11 ●実験インストラクション(本紙) 12 ●実験の同意書 13 ●謝金の領収書 14 ●筆記用具 15 16 17 2. 実験の概要 18 本日、お集まり頂いた方には、これからコンピュータを使用して 4 種類の異なる実19 験に参加して頂きます。各実験の意思決定の結果に応じて、皆さまの実験報酬が決定20 されます。実験終了後、実験報酬に参加報酬 1,100 円を加えた金額を現金にて支払い21 ます。是非、多くの現金を獲得してください。 22 これより、実験 1 を行います。実験インストラクションにおいて、「プレイヤー」と23 は皆さまであり、「実験者」とは実験を実施する私たちを指します。なお、実験の途中24 において、いかなる理由により退席された場合にも、皆さまが不利益を被ることはご25 ざいません。 26 27 28

Page 60: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

59

3.1. 実験 1 1 この実験では、あなた自身にとって、以下の「オプション A」と「オプション B」2

のどちらがより好ましいかを選択して頂きます。 3 4

5 6

例えば、Q1 では、 7 「オプション A:確率 10%で 200 円、確率 90%で 160 円を獲得」と「オプション B:8 確率 10%で 380 円、確率 90%で 10 円を獲得」のどちらのオプションが、あなたにと9 ってより好ましいかを選択してください。実験では、Q1 から Q10 まで、それぞれ「オ10 プション A」または「オプション B」を同様に選択して頂き、最後にコンピュータが11 ランダムにくじ(1 番から 10 番)を引き、皆様が実際に獲得する金額を決定いたしま12

オプションA オプションB

Q1.確率10%(200円)

確率90%(160円)

確率10%(380円)

確率90%(10円)

Q2.確率20%(200円)

確率80%(160円)

確率20%(380円)

確率80%(10円)

Q3.確率30%(200円)

確率70%(160円)

確率30%(380円)

確率70%(10円)

Q4.確率40%(200円)

確率60%(160円)

確率40%(380円)

確率60%(10円)

Q5.確率50%(200円)

確率50%(160円)

確率50%(380円)

確率50%(10円)

Q6.確率60%(200円)

確率40%(160円)

確率60%(380円)

確率40%(10円)

Q7.確率70%(200円)

確率30%(160円)

確率70%(380円)

確率30%(10円)

Q8.確率80%(200円)

確率20%(160円)

確率80%(380円)

確率20%(10円)

Q9.確率90%(200円)

確率10%(160円)

確率90%(380円)

確率10%(10円)

Q10.確率100%(200円)

確率0%(160円)

確率100%(380円)

確率0%(10円)

Page 61: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

60

す。具体的には、コンピュータのくじ引きにおいて「5 番」が出た場合には、Q5 で「オ1 プション A」を選択されている回答者は、「オプション A:確率 50%で 200 円、確率2 50%で 160 円を獲得」が実現します。「オプション B」を選択されている回答者も同様3 に獲得金額が実現します。 4

ここまでの説明で質問などはございますか。それではこれから、意思決定について考え5 て頂くため、1 分間のシンキングタイムを取ります。 6 1 分間経過したので、これから意思決定を行って頂きます。目の前の PC の画面に注目7 してください。以下の画面が表示されましたら、Q1 から Q10 までそれぞれ「オプショ8 ン A」または「オプション B」の選択を入力してください。入力後は、「OK」ボタン9 をクリックし、そのままお待ちください。 10 11 【入力画面(「オプション」の選択)】 12

13 14

Page 62: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

61

3.2. 実験 2 1 プレイヤーは、はじめに 200 円を所持し、それぞれランダムに 3 人から構成された2

グループに所属しています。その 200 円の内のいくらかをグループのプロジェクトに3 貢献する金額を決定して頂きます。プロジェクトへの貢献は 200 円の内のいくらでも4 構いません(0 円から 200 円までの金額)。グループの全メンバー(3 人)からプロジ5 ェクトに貢献された総額の 2 倍の金額が、グループ全員に平等に分配されます。各プ6 レイヤーが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 7

8 獲得金額=(全メンバーの貢献額 ×2 ÷ 3 )+(200 -あなたの貢献額) 9

10 例えば、グループ内の 3 人全員がそれぞれ 200 円を貢献した場合、全メンバーの貢11 献額は 600 円となり、あなたはこの実験より 400 円を獲得します。一方、3 人全員が12 全く貢献をしない場合は、全メンバーの貢献額は 0 円となり、あなたはこの実験にお13 いて 200 円を獲得します。 14 15 16 <練習問題> 17 問 1. ある 1 つのグループで、1 人のメンバーが「120 円」を貢献し、2 人が「60 円」18

を貢献した場合に、ぞれぞれのメンバーの獲得金額はいくらですか。 19 「120 円」を貢献したメンバー: 円 20 「60 円」を貢献したメンバー: 円 21

22 23

問 2. ある 1 つのグループで、2 人のメンバーが「180 円」を貢献し、1 人が全く貢献24 をしなかった場合(= 貢献額「0 円」)、ぞれぞれのメンバーの獲得金額はいくら25 ですか。 26

「180 円」を貢献したメンバー: 円 27 貢献額「0 円」のメンバー: 円 28

29 ここまでの説明で質問などはございますか。それではこれから、意思決定について考え30 て頂くため、1 分間のシンキングタイムを取ります。 31 1 分間経過したので、これから意思決定を行って頂きます。目の前の PC の画面に注目32 してください。以下の画面(次ページ)が表示されましたら、あなた自身の貢献額を入33 力してください(0 円から 200 円までの金額)。貢献額の入力は、10 円単位で行うこ34 とができます。入力後は、「OK」ボタンをクリックし、そのままお待ちください。 35 36

Page 63: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

62

【入力画面(貢献額の決定)】 1

2 3

4

Page 64: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

63

1 実験 2 まで終了いたしました。続いて、実験 3 から実験 4 を順次行います。これ以2 降、各実験では皆様に「1 人の意思決定」または「3 人グループの意思決定」をして頂3 きます。どちらの意思決定を行って頂くかは、コンピュータによりランダムに決定さ4 れます。「1 人の意思決定」の方は、すべての実験終了まで「1 人の意思決定」をして5 頂きます。同様に、「3 人グループの意思決定」に選ばれた方はすべての実験終了まで6 「3 人グループの意思決定」をして頂きます。 7 8 (Ⅰ)1 人の意思決定:皆さまには、ご自身 1 人の場合を考えて、各実験における意9 思決定をして頂きます。あなたにとって、最も望ましい値を入力してください。 10 11 (Ⅱ)3 人グループの意思決定:皆さまは、これからメンバーがランダムに構成され12 た 3 人のグループに所属します。グループのメンバーは、すべての実験終了まで同じ13 です。あなたは、グループの意思決定をどのようにしたら良いか、正直にお答えくだ14 さい。実際のグループにおける選択は、確率 1/3 でグループ内の誰かの意思決定が選15 択されます。 16

同一グループのメンバーは、各実験において上記のルールに従い、同じ行動をし全17 員同額の金額を獲得します。 18

これから、グループのメンバーを紹介します。座席番号を呼ばれた方はご起立をお19 願いします。ただし、すべての実験終了までグループのメンバーと相談をしたり、話20 すことはできません。 21

22 23

Page 65: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

64

3.3. 実験 3 1 2 <1 人の意思決定の方> 3

プレイヤーは、はじめに 200 円を所持しています。その 200 円の内のいくらかを以4 下の「オプション」に投資することができます。投資は 200 円の内のいくらでも構い5 ません(0 円から 200 円までの金額)。 6

7 【オプション:確率 50%で投資額の 2.5 倍の金額を得る、確率 50%で投資額を失う】 8 9

あなたが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 10 11

獲得金額 = 200 -あなたの投資額 + オプションから得た金額 12 13

実際にオプションから得られる金額は、コンピュータのくじ引きにより決定します。 14 15 16 <3 人グループの意思決定の方> 17

あなたとグループの他のメンバーは、それぞれ 200 円を所持しており、その内のい18 くらをグループとして「オプション」に投資するかを、あなた自身のご判断で入力し19 てください。投資は 200 円の内のいくらでも構いません。グループとしての投資額は、20 確率 1/3 でグループ内の誰かの投資額が選択されます。 21

同一グループのすべてのメンバーは、上記に従い同額を投資し同じ金額を獲得しま22 す。3 人グループの意思決定の場合も、グループにおいて最も望ましいと思う投資額23 を入力してください。あなたが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 24

25 獲得金額 = 200 -グループの投資額 + オプションから得た金額 26

27 28 ここまでの説明で質問などはございますか。それではこれから、意思決定について考え29

て頂くため、1 分間のシンキングタイムを取ります。 30 1 分間経過したので、これから意思決定を行って頂きます。目の前の PC の画面に注目31 してください。以下の画面が表示されましたら、投資額を入力してください(0 円から32 200 円までの金額)。投資は、10 円単位で行うことができます。入力後は、「OK」ボ33 タンをクリックし、そのままお待ちください。 34 35

Page 66: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

65

【入力画面(「投資額」の決定)】 1 <1 人の意思決定の方> 2

3 <3 人グループの意思決定の方> 4

5 6

Page 67: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

66

3.4 実験 4 1 2 <1 人の意思決定の方> 3

プレイヤーは、はじめに 200 円を所持しています。その 200 円の内のいくらかを「日4 本赤十字社」に寄付することができます。寄付は 200 円の内のいくらでも構いません5 (0 円から 200 円までの金額)。皆さまに入力して頂いた寄付額は、実験者から実際に6 「日本赤十字社」へ寄付いたします。あなたが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 7

8 獲得金額 = 200 -寄付額 9

10 11 <3 人グループの意思決定の方> 12

あなたとグループの他のメンバーは、それぞれ 200 円を所持しており、その内のい13 くらをグループとして「日本赤十字社」に寄付するかを、あなた自身のご判断で入力14 してください。寄付は 200 円の内のいくらでも構いません。グループとしての寄付額15 は、確率 1/3 でグループ内の誰かの寄付額が選択されます。 16

同一グループのすべてのメンバーは、上記に従い同額を寄付し同じ金額を獲得しま17 す。3 人グループの意思決定の場合も、グループにおいて最も望ましいと思う寄付額18 を入力してください。あなたが受け取る獲得金額は、以下の通りです。 19

20 獲得金額 = 200 -グループの寄付額 21

22 23

※日本赤十字社とは 24 日本赤十字社は、紛争・災害・病気などで苦しむ人を救うためあらゆる支援をして25

います。皆様の寄付・献血・ボランティアをお待ちしております(日本赤十字社 HP26 より引用)。 27

28 29 30 ここまでの説明で質問などはございますか。それではこれから、意思決定について考え31

て頂くため、1 分間のシンキングタイムを取ります。 32 1 分間経過したので、これから意思決定を行って頂きます。目の前の PC の画面に注目33 してください。以下の画面(次ページ)が表示されましたら、寄付額を入力してくださ34 い(0 円から 200 円までの金額)。寄付は、10 円単位で行うことができます。入力後35

Page 68: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

67

は、「OK」ボタンをクリックし、そのままお待ちください。 1 2

【入力画面(「寄付額」の決定)】 3 4

<1 人の意思決定の方> 5

6 7

<3 人グループの意思決定の方> 8

9 10

Page 69: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

68

Appendix E. Summary of the Experimental Design 1 2 1. Individuals’ risk and altruistic preferences (Tasks 1 and 2) 3

In order to control for individuals’ risk and altruistic preferences, we implemented two 4

experiments: a lottery-choice task developed by Holt and Laury (2002) for risk preference 5

(Task 1), and a standard public goods game for altruism attitude (Task 2). These are used for 6

control variables in our regression model (Tables 3–8). 7

8

2. An anonymous one-shot investment game and a donation game (Tasks 3 and 4) 9

To compare the risk and altruistic attitudes of groups and individuals, we used an anonymous 10

one-shot investment game and a donation game. For the investment task, subjects decided how 11

much money to invest in their options, ranging from 0 yen to 200 yen. The investment options 12

were as follows: a 50% chance of winning 2.5 times of their invested amount and a 50% 13

chance of losing their entire investment. For the donation task, subjects decided how much 14

money to donate to the Japanese Red Cross Society, ranging from 0 yen to 200 yen. 15

16

3. Experimental design 17

In our experiment, we implemented four different types of tasks, as mentioned below. In the 18

current paper, we investigated the differences between individual and group decision making in 19

an anonymous one-shot investment game and a donation game (Tasks 3 and 4). 20

Subjects were divided randomly into two groups: individual-choice and group-choice 21

tasks. For the group-choice task, the subjects were requested only to show their faces to other 22

members without any further communication. The group decision was determined based on the 23

median rule by group members, or the choice of group members, randomly selected with a 24

one-third chance (the random rule). Each team member received the same payoff. Subjects 25

Page 70: Risk-averse and self-interested shifts in groups in both ...18 Shupp and Williams (2008), and Masclet et al. (2009) reported that groups were more risk 19 averse than individuals were

69

were told that the members of groups were identical until the end of the experiment. 1

All subjects in our experiment were undergraduate students at Kochi University of 2

Technology, Kyoto Sangyo University , and Kansai University with the following breakdown: 3

Kochi University of Technology, individual-choice task (N=48) and group-choice task (N=42); 4

Kyoto Sangyo University, individual-choice task (N=48) and group-choice task (N=48; Kansai 5

University, individual-choice task (N=87) and group-choice task (N=87). 6

7

Appendix F. Selection and Eligibility of Subjects 8

9

All subjects in our experiment were undergraduate students from various disciplines at Kochi 10

University of Technology, Kyoto Sangyo University, and Kansai University, and who have 11

native-level Japanese language skills (almost all our subjects were Japanese undergraduate 12

students). They were recruited via the university website and e-mail solicitation, as 13

follows: at Kochi University of Technology (Sona systems, URL: 14

https://kutexp.sona-systems.com/Default.aspx?p_language=JA); at Kyoto Sangyo 15

University (KEEL, URL: https://www.cc.kyoto-su.ac.jp/~aquirax/index.php?KEEL). 16

We conducted 18 sessions between July 2015 and December 2017. No subject participated in 17

more than one session. 18