regulating for legitimacy: consumer credit access in ... files/11-047.pdf · regulating for...

38
Copyright © 2010 by Gunnar Trumbull Working papers are in draft form. This working paper is distributed for purposes of comment and discussion only. It may not be reproduced without permission of the copyright holder. Copies of working papers are available from the author. Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull Working Paper 11-047

Upload: others

Post on 15-Oct-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

Copyright © 2010 by Gunnar Trumbull

Working papers are in draft form. This working paper is distributed for purposes of comment and discussion only. It may not be reproduced without permission of the copyright holder. Copies of working papers are available from the author.

Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull

Working Paper

11-047

Page 2: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

1  

Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America

Gunnar Trumbull

November 2010

Abstract

Theories of legitimate regulation have emphasized the role of governments either in fixing market failures to promote greater efficiency, or in restricting the efficient functioning of markets in order to pursue public welfare goals. In either case, features of markets serve to justify regulatory intervention. I argue that this causal logic must sometimes be reversed. For certain areas of regulation, its function must be understood as making markets legitimate. Based on a comparative historical analysis of consumer lending in the United States and France, I argue that national differences in the regulation of consumer credit had their roots in the historical conditions by which the small loan sector came to be legitimized. Americans have supported a liberal regulation of credit because they have been taught that access to credit is welfare promoting. This perception emerged from an historical coalition between commercial banks and NGOs that promoted credit as the solution to a range of social ills. The French regulate credit tightly because they came to see credit as both economically risky and a source of reduced purchasing power. This attitude has its roots in the early postwar lending environment, in which loans were seen to be beneficial only if they were accompanied by strong government protections. These cases suggest that national differences in regulation may trace to historically contingent conditions under which markets are constructed as legitimate.

Page 3: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

2  

Introduction

Why do we regulate markets? Theories of regulation in the public interest have

emphasized the role of governments either in fixing market failures to promote greater

efficiency, or in restricting the efficient functioning of markets in order to pursue public welfare

goals.1 In either case, features of markets serve to justify regulatory intervention. I argue that this

causal logic must sometimes be reversed; that, for certain areas of regulation, its function must

be understood as making markets legitimate.2 Based on a comparative historical study of

consumer credit markets in the United States and France, I examine the sources of national

regulatory divergence. In France, usury and data privacy laws restricted lenders’ ability to offer

credit to riskier borrowers. In the United States, a different set of regulations—including

centralized credit rating, liberal pricing policies, and liberal bankruptcy provisions—promoted

                                                            

1 Because I am interested in regulation in the public interest, I set aside theories of regulation based on regulatory capture by narrow economic interests in order to limit or control market access by competitors, as well as cases of “reverse capture” in which regulatory agencies attempt to dominate a sector. Giandomenico Majone, “From the Positive to the Regulatory State: Causes and Consequences of Changes in the Mode of Governance,” Journal of Public Policy 17/2 (2008), p 162; Steven K. Vogel, Freer Markets, More Rules: Regulatory Reform in Advanced Industrial Countries (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1996), p 15; Daniel Carpenter, Reputation and Power: Organizational Image and Pharmaceutical Regulation at the FDA (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010), pp 38-39.

2 Daniel Carpenter, “Confidence Games: How Does Regulation Constitute Markets,” in Edward J. Balleisen and David Moss, eds., Government and Markets: Toward a New Theory of Regulation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010).

Page 4: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

3  

broad access to credit for the American public. What is important about these regulatory

responses was the role they played in legitimizing what had historically been at best a marginal

economic activity. Although the regulatory outcomes were different, in each country, a series of

regulatory interventions by the state transformed a formerly disreputable small lending sector

into a legitimate economic activity.

Among the advanced industrialized countries, France and the United States represent

nearly opposite poles in consumer credit use. Americans have been heavy users of consumer

credit since the interwar period; the French have relied relatively little on consumer credit. In

1955, non-mortgage consumer debt averaged 15% of household disposable income in the United

States, compared to 0.3% in France. Fifty years later, in 2005, US non-mortgage household debt

had risen to 33% of disposable income.3 French household debt at the time was still below 15%

of disposable income. (See figure 1.) This difference is puzzling in part because of the technical

skill and economic success of French lenders. The consumer finance companies that emerged in

postwar France were quick in assimilating new lending techniques developed in the United

States. From the late 1980s, when consumer use of credit grew more common across Europe, the

French company Cetelem emerged as the dominant player.4 Consumer lending rates were also

roughly the same in both countries. Given comparable know-how in originating consumer loans,

and similar lending rates, why were American and French consumer credit markets so different?

Figure 1. Non-mortgage household debt in France and United States (share of disposable

income), 1945-2005                                                             

3 From the late 1990s, households began rolling over consumer credit into home equity loans. The 33% figure includes 25% credit card and installment debt, plus an additional 8% of extracted equity used to pay off existing debt or make new consumer purchases. Alan Greenspan and James Kennedy, “Sources and Uses of Equity Extracted from Homes,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 24/1 (2008), pp 120-144.

4 In 2008, Cetelem was renamed BNP Paribas Personal Finance.

Page 5: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

4  

 

Sources: United States Federal Reserve Bank; Banque de France; Alan Greenspan and James Kennedy, “Sources and Uses of Equity Extracted from Homes,” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 24/1 (2008), pp 120-144. Note: Home equity extraction contribution to consumer spending and debt reduction estimated at 80% of total home equity extraction, assuming that 20% of extracted equity was shifted to other assets. France experienced no significant home equity extraction.

Using records from lenders and regulators, I argue that differences in credit practice

derive from the ways in which consumer credit markets came to be legitimated in the two

countries. In the United States, a coalition of non-governmental organizations (NGOs) and

commercial lenders helped to construct the market for consumer credit as a legitimate response

to an evolving set of societal problems. Over the course of nearly a century, politicians on the

left and right supported policies that promoted credit access as a form of social welfare. In

France, NGOs were less active and commercial banks stayed away from consumer lending.

Lending instead came to be dominated by dedicated consumer finance companies that were

required to operate under close regulatory scrutiny. If American policies emphasized the value of

0.00%

5.00%

10.00%

15.00%

20.00%

25.00%

30.00%

35.00%

1945 1950 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005

US (with extracted equity)

US 

France

Page 6: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

5  

consumer access, the French response emphasized the value of consumer protection. In both

cases, the point of government regulation was to construct credit markets as socially and

politically legitimate. Once established, these different approaches to consumer credit became

locked in over time. Hence, when France briefly experimented with deregulated consumer credit

markets in the mid-1980s, social activists on the left and right demanded that the government

step back in to re-regulate the market. In the United States, rising personal bankruptcy rates tied

to consumer over-indebtedness in the 1990s and 2000s failed to elicit a regulatory response from

policymakers on the left or right despite the clear social costs. The financial crisis of 2008 traces

its roots in part to the resulting regulatory void.

This process of legitimation by regulation is not unique to consumer credit. Other market

sectors, including life insurance and genetic technologies, have relied on regulatory interventions

in order to shed prior public opprobrium.5 If this legitimating function of regulation is pervasive,

it suggests that the study of regulation might benefit from a strong dose of historical

institutionalism.6 Rather than focus on the functional logic of market failure or the welfare

politics of market externalities, we might better explain existing national differences by studying

the specific historical contexts in which new market sectors come to be perceived as legitimate in

society. To the extent that different strategies of legitimation become locked in over time,

historical institutions may play a critical role in explaining variation in contemporary regulatory

outcomes.                                                             

5 Viviana A. Rotman Zelizer, Morals and Markets: The Development of Life Insurance in the United States (New York: Columbia University Press, 1979); Julia Black, “Regulation as Facilitation: Negotiating the Genetic Revolution,” The Modern Law Review 61/5 (1998): 621-660.

6 See, for example: Daniel Carpenter, Reputation and Power: Organizational Image and Pharmaceutical Regulation at the FDA (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010); David Moss, When All Else Fails: Government as the Ultimate Risk Manager (Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2004).

Page 7: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

6  

The article is organized as follows. The first section introduces the two cases that are to

be compared. It presents two sets of theories that are commonly evoked to account for regulatory

differences, then proposes an alternative theory based on the role of regulation in legitimating

markets. The second section applies this alternative framework to explain patterns of consumer

lending in the two countries. The third addresses sources of national differences in consumer

credit rating. The final section traces the historical evolution of the link between credit and

welfare in the two countries.

Existing Theories of Credit Regulation

The rise in consumer credit use across the advanced industrialized countries, together

with a growing interest in institutions that promote credit access in developing countries, has

focused academic attention on the sources of cross-national differences in credit use. Two kinds

of explanations have dominated the debate. One sees credit markets as beset by problems of

adverse selection that lead to an under-serving of risky borrowers.7 This strain of research has

emphasized the importance of information sharing among lenders to limit non-payment losses.8

Credit research has accordingly focused on credit rating agencies as a driver of credit extension,

and on the use of credit data to select borrowers and set interest rates. 9 In micro-finance and

other social lending institutions, social ties have been seen as an alternative means to overcome

                                                            

7 Faced with a combination of honest-but-risky borrowers and dishonest borrowers who did not intend to repay, the latter group would be less price sensitive and thus over-represented among applicants. Joseph E. Stiglitz and Andrew Weiss, “Credit Rationing in Markets with Imperfect Information,” American Economic Review 71/3 (1981): 393-410;

8 Tullio Jappelli and Marco Pagano, “Information Sharing, Lending and Defaults: Cross-Country Evidence,” CSEF Working Paper, no. 22, 1999; Tullio Jappelli and Marco Pagano, “Information Sharing in Credit Markets,” Journal of Finance 48/5 (1993).

9 Akos Ronas-Tas, “Consumer Credit in Transition Economies,” in Victor Perez-Dias, ed., The European Experience in Comparative Perspective (London: Berghahn Books, 2009).

Page 8: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

7  

the problem of adverse selection.10 Yet the perceived riskiness of consumer borrowers was,

historically, largely a myth. During the Great Depression, consumer loans showed higher

repayment rates than any other class of borrowing.11 In France during World War I, lenders in

the industrial northeast that closed their doors during German occupation were able to collect on

most of the debts after the war ended. And when the United States enacted a liberal consumer

bankruptcy policy in 1978, including a provision for automatic discharge of debts, lenders appear

not to have worried about its impact on non-payment rates, and raised no objections. Observers

frequently but mistakenly attribute the high cost of consumer credit to the risk associated with

unsecured personal loans, but the reality is more mundane. Consumer loans were expensive

(25%-40% was typical in the early postwar period) primarily because of the unusually high

administrative costs associated with writing, tracking, and collecting small loans.12

The second kind of explanation focuses on the potential social costs associated with

liberal credit access. The general proposal is that governments intervene in markets to manage an

inherent trade-off between market efficiency and social equity.13 In a range of markets, including

labor, capital and product markets, governments regulate in order to curb the socially

unacceptable externalities that unfettered markets would generate.14 How much different states

                                                            

10 Asif Dowla, “In credit we trust: Building social capital by Grameen Bank in Bangladesh,“ Journal of Socio-Economics 35/1 (2006), 102-122.

11 Michel Schlosser and Gérard Tardy, Les cartes de crédit (Paris: Dunod, 1971). 12 Archives of the National Consumer Council of the Banque de France (BdF CNC),

1427200301, box 283, Comité national du Crédit, Comité du crédit a court terme, December 1953-June 1961, Meeting of the Comité du crédit à court terme, June 19, 1961, p 21.

13 Joseph E. Stiglitz, “Government Failure vs. Market Failure: Principles of Regulation,” in Edward J. Balleisen and David Moss, eds., Government and Markets: Toward a New Theory of Regulation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010), p 22.

14 Jonas Pontusson, Inequality and Prosperity: Social Europe versus Liberal America (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2005); André Sapir, “Globalization and the Reform of European Social Models,” Journal of Common Market Studies 44/2 (2006), pp 369-390; Guandomenico Majone, “From the Positive to the Regulatory State: Causes and Consequences

Page 9: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

8  

are willing to compromise efficiency in order to promote equality depends in turn on institutional

and political features that are distinctive to their political and historical context.15 In consumer

credit markets, the problem was that credit access appeared to be regressive in its consequences.

In general, the interest paid on outstanding credit reduces borrowers’ purchasing power over

time. But, because the administrative costs of making loans was high and fixed, smaller loans

faced higher interest charges. To the extent that the working class and poor borrowed smaller

amounts, they tended to reduce their purchasing power more. This effect implied that countries

focused on the welfare of the poor and working classes should have an interest in regulation that

limited credit access. Such regulation could take a variety of forms: usury ceilings, restrictions

on downpayment and repayment periods, direct quantitative limits on extended credit, restriction

on advertising and collections practices, limitations on data sharing and collections practices, and

liberal bankruptcy provisions that weakened the contractual claims of lenders. Each of these

regulations has been interpreted as limiting the supply of credit in order to limit the social costs

of free credit markets.16

The problem with this efficiency-versus-equity argument as it relates to consumer credit

markets is that neither American nor French policymakers believed that such a trade-off existed.

In the United States, policymakers on the left and right came increasingly to see consumer credit

as supporting, rather than undermining, social welfare. In their view, more efficient consumer

credit markets were welfare enhancing. In France, early postwar regulators restricted credit not                                                                                                                                                                                                 

of Changes in the Mode of Governance,” Journal of Public Policy 17/2 (2008), p 162; Gosta Esping-Andersen, Three worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1990).

15 André Sapir, “Globalization and the Reform of European Social Models,” Journal of Common Market Studies 44/2 (2006): 369-390; Jonas Pontusson, Inequality and Prosperity: Social Europe versus Liberal America (Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 2005).

16 Theresa A. Sullivan, Elizabeth Warren, and Jay Lawrence Westbroook, As We Forgive our Debtors (Washington, DC: Beard Books, 1999).

Page 10: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

9  

primarily out of concerns about its distributional effects, but because they felt that consumer

credit was an inefficient allocation of capital. France’s restrictive policy with respect to

consumer credit was grounded in the understanding that free markets offered neither welfare

benefits nor efficiency. It is this cross-national difference in perception of the social and

economic implications of consumer borrowing that needs to be explained.

The Puzzle: Explaining Demand for Credit

The adverse selection theory and the equity-versus-efficiency theory share a common

focus on the supply side. Both assume a large, unmet demand for consumer credit, then focus on

explaining differences in the degree to which that demand is being met. Yet a core puzzle of

consumer credit is that demand for it exists at all. After all, consumer credit works over time to

reduce household purchasing power. While borrowing allows a household to move its

consumption forward in time, it also reduces its total consumption by the amount of the interest

payments on the loan. Unlike business borrowing, in which debt creates a corresponding new

stream of income out of which it can be repaid, household borrowing is a pure liability.17 Interest

payments must come out of the budget for future consumption. The effect is to reduce household

purchasing power. Given this, why have households borrowed to finance consumption, and why

has that borrowing increased over time?

Researchers have offered three explanations for this seemingly irrational behavior. The

earliest explanation, formalized in the life-cycle savings model introduced by Franco Modigliani,

suggested that credit could be used to could smooth consumption so as to increase overall

                                                            

17 An estimated 30% of consumer credit actually finances business investment. Some small businesses rely on consumer loans to finance inventory and investments. They may devote household savings to business investments while financing consumption through credit. Educational borrowing is typically also understood as an investment. I am interested in household borrowing that finances pure consumption.

Page 11: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

10  

household utility.18 Assuming a diminishing marginal utility of consumption, households

expecting a higher future income might borrow in order to move some of their consumption

forward. The problem with the life-cycle theory is the very high cost of consumer borrowing.

Households would have to expect extraordinary wage growth in order for a typical 15%-20%

real interest rate to increase their household utility. Moreover, real wage growth had declined or

even stagnated by the early 1980s, at the time when borrowing began to escalate. This pattern of

wage growth and credit use is difficult to explain in terms of life-cycle consumption smoothing.

A second explanation has focused on the role of credit contracts in imposing discipline on

households.19 By contracting for a loan, households received a regular bill that bound their hands

and forced them to pursue “systematic savings.”20 A third and related explanation focuses on the

use of credit as a form of insurance. In this view, households faced with shocks to income and

expenses used credit in order to maintain a minimum level of savings that they would need to

carry themselves through hard times. The problem with both the discipline and the insurance

arguments is that they no longer made sense once revolving credit had become the dominant

form of unsecured consumer borrowing. Revolving accounts, which had by the 1960s become a

dominant form of lending in the United States, gave consumers unusual flexibility in making

repayments. This flexibility was attractive for lenders, who discovered that it allowed them to

reduce non-payment rates, but it also eliminated the discipline of repayment for consumers.

Further, because revolving accounts offered households a line of credit up to a predetermined

                                                            

18 Franco Modigliani and Robert Brumberg, “Utility analysis and the consumption function: An interpretation of cross-section data,” in Kurihara, ed., Post-Keynesian Economics (New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 1954).

19 Lendol Calder, Financing the American Dream: A Cultural History of Consumer Credit (Princton: Princeton University Press, 1999).

20 Robert L. D. Morse (RLDM) Archives, Kansas State University, Box 148, folder 16, JC Penney Company, “100% Down and Nothing a Month for the Rest of your Life,” c 1968.

Page 12: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

11  

credit ceiling, customers had access to liquidity without actually borrowing. Had consumers been

using credit as insurance, we would expect them to establish revolving credit accounts, and then

hold them unused in preparation for future need. This was not the pattern that banks observed.

Without better explanations, economists have embraced the idea that borrowers behave

irrationally. Studies of economic decision-making reveal that consumers possess a steep near-

term discount rate that leads them to prioritize current consumption.21 This emphasis on near-

term consumption makes households accepting of even very high interest rates for short-term

loans. Yet the insight that consumers are short-sighted does not explain differences in policy that

we observe across countries. Consumers also exhibit high demand for gambling, alcohol and

drugs. How countries have responded to regulate their access to these markets has depended on

the historical context in which they came to be regulated.22 Even if consumers share an irrational

short-term bias, the status of the market that serves that demand is set through the regulatory

processes that need to be explained. By focusing on the role that national regulation plays in

legitimating markets, I argue that we can begin to explain both the supply and demand for

consumer credit.

An Alternative View: Regulating for Legitimacy

Historically, consumer borrowing was viewed with deep skepticism in both France and

the United States. At the turn of the 20th Century, social critics saw it as exploitative of the

working classes, an unproductive use of capital, and in contravention of religious dictates against

charging interest. In both countries, activists from the religious right and the labor left spoke out

                                                            

21 David Laibson, “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 112/2 (1997), pp 443-477.

22 Paulette Kurzer, Markets and Moral Regulation (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2001).

Page 13: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

12  

strongly against the problem of usury. In the United States, high interest rate lenders seemed to

pray on the working classes. Loans secured against salaries drove unlucky workers into a cycle

of poverty and unemployment that eventually left them destitute. In France, early itinerant

lenders were seen as promoting profligacy, undermining morality, and taking advantage of

housewives while their husbands were away at work. Yet, by the 1960s, societal attitudes toward

credit had changed. Although interest rates had not fallen significantly in either country,

consumer loans had been reconceived as a legitimate tool for household financial planning.

Formerly marginal economic activities had gained political and social legitimacy. How this

transformation occurred, and the role of government regulation in the process, is central to

understanding persistent national differences in credit practice.

In the United States, an evolving coalition of progressive social groups and business

interests united around credit as socially advantageous. In the interwar period, legitimate

consumer loans were promoted as an alternative to the scourge of high-rate salary lenders. In the

early postwar period, both industrialists and organized labor supported credit as a means to drive

scale in production, raising productivity, profits and wages. By the late 1960s, a new coalition

had emerged that saw credit as a tool for extending economic citizenship to formerly excluded

groups, including women and urban blacks. These ideas would influence the ‘third-way’ politics

that promoted credit access during the 1980s and 1990s. Whether or not they were right,

American interest groups on the left and right came together around the idea that credit access

was a tool for social and economic equality. In France, this coalition of social progressives and

business leaders never emerged. Labor unions argued that the interest paid on loans lowered

worker purchasing power; economic planners warned that credit would drive inflation and hurt

exports; commercial banks saw consumer lending as undignified and unprofitable. The

Page 14: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

13  

legitimacy of consumer credit in France had its origin instead in a close collaboration between

lenders and government regulators. The resulting policies emphasized a strong regulatory

framework of borrower protections rather than the idea of credit access as a right. These different

logics of market legitimacy—access in the United States and protection in France—in turn drove

the regulatory divergence that continued to dominate the sectors through the turn of the century.

Lenders played a role in forging this regulatory divide, but so did government policymakers and

social activists. Through processes that were in part historically contingent, French and

American policymakers and their constituencies came to fundamentally different conclusions

about the credit interests of consumers, about the nature of market failures, and about the very

social and economic purpose of regulation.

The process of defining a legitimate role for consumer credit was shaped by two specific

institutional differences between the two countries. First, the role of banks was critical. American

banks moved quickly to offer consumer credit, while French banks delayed. The participation of

commercial banks in consumer lending in the United States gave the activity legitimacy. It also

created the conditions under which revolving credit and electronic payments would be combined

in the same instrument: the modern credit card. In France, banks did not enter consumer lending

in force until the mid-1980s. Without the legitimacy lent by the participation of commercial

banks, consumer lenders in the early postwar period enjoyed legitimacy through close regulatory

oversight by the French state. By the time banks did begin making consumer loans, France’s

carte bleue debit card system had already established electronic payment and consumer credit as

fundamentally different products. Second, the role of non-governmental organizations (NGOs)

was critical. In France, the interest of certain family associations in increasing access to credit

was offset by objections from both religious groups on the right and organized labor on the left.

Page 15: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

14  

In the United States, by contrast, a range of NGOs across the political spectrum organized to

advocate for credit extension as a tool for economic self-reliance and social inclusion.

The case of consumer credit evokes the importance of interactions between different

societal actors in generating legitimacy for new market activities. In the United States and

France, different legitimacy coalitions emerged to support consumer lending. In the United

States, NGOs and commercial banks formed a legitimacy coalition that supported credit

extension. In France, commercial banks did not engage in consumer lending, and few NGOs

supported credit extension. The legitimacy of consumer lending found a different basis: in a

close interaction between national regulators and consumer lenders that defined consumer credit

as an area of active consumer protection. If consumer credit in the United States was desirable as

a form of social policy, consumer credit in France was acceptable because the state worked

closely with lenders to mitigate its potentially negative societal impact. These different

approaches to credit would in turn affect consumer perceptions of the value of credit. American

consumers were taught that consumer credit would improve their economic status, and their high

level of borrowing reflected that belief. French consumers were taught a different lesson. For

them, consumer credit was acceptable but risky—more akin to gambling than to an investment in

future prosperity. French consumers borrowed, but they also supported government policies that

placed careful restrictions on the scope and extent of lending practice.

Explaining Lender Behavior: Seeking and Finding Legitimacy

The central fact of early postwar consumer credit was that it was largely unprofitable.

The problem had little to do with the riskiness of individual borrowers, as later theories of

adverse selection would suggest. In fact, most early consumer credit was working class credit,

and the regular wage of workers made them reliable repayers. Small lenders did take pains to

Page 16: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

15  

reduce non-payment rates. In the United States, consumer lenders found ways to control non-

payment risk even before local credit bureaus became common in the 1940s and 1950s. Early

Morris Plan banks that pioneered unsecured small lending in the 1910s and 1920s required that

each borrower be joined by two co-makers.23 French postwar retail lenders employed either

door-to-door collections, or relied on the judgment of retailers who were familiar with their

customers. In most cases, non-payment rates remained below 1%.

The high cost of consumer credit derived mainly from the small size of each loan. For

any lending transaction, the basic administrative cost—including loan application, credit check,

bill mailings and reminders, and the associated bookkeeping—were largely invariant. This meant

that small loans were relatively costly to administer, in proportion to the size of the loan. A study

by France’s National Credit Council in 1961 estimated that while the cost of an average

commercial loan came 75% from interest and 25% from administration, the cost of an average

consumer loan came 45% from interest and 55% from administration.24 To earn a profit on small

loans, banks had to charge high interest rates. In the United States in the 1910s, the Russell Sage

Foundation estimated that lenders could not make loans “on a business-like basis” unless they

were allowed to charge up to 42% annually (3.5% per month). By the 1960s, large lenders

estimated that consumer loans below 18% could not be made profitably. The problem for banks

was that they relied heavily on their reputations, and loans at such high rates were generally

considered to be ethically questionable. The high interest rates that would be needed to make

consumer lending profitable could damage their profitable lines of business with commercial

                                                            

23 The Morris Plan of Industrial Loans and Investments (New York: Industrial Finance Corporation, 1915), p 19.

24 BdF CNC, 1427200301, box 283, Comité national du Credit, Comité du crédit a court terme, December 1953-June 1961, Meeting of the Comité du crédit à court terme, June 19, 1961, p 21.

Page 17: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

16  

clients. Non-bank lenders who focused exclusively on consumer borrowing did not have these

reputational concerns.

In France, this moral economy of consumer lending led banks to steer clear. In fact, the

French government periodically encouraged banks to enter the consumer lending field, in the

hope that added competition would reduce consumer borrowing rates. In 1962, and again in

1972, banks dabbled with making personal loans, but quickly withdrew. Alongside concerns

about reputation, France’s commercial banks also discovered that they were unable to make

small loans efficiently. Dedicated consumer finance companies in France had since the 1950s

been investing in automation that allowed them to process small loans at relatively low cost. At

Cetelem, a consumer lender formed in 1954, the staff-to-loans ratio had by the late 1970s

reached 1:1,000, higher even than its American counterparts at the time.25 Commercial banks, by

contrast, were accustomed to making loans on the basis of personal relations with clients. These

personal relationships imposed higher administrative costs, and yielded less reliable repayment.

Critically, French banks at the time were making strong returns on industrial lending in the

context of indicative planning by the French government. By comparison, consumer lending was

a risky, low-margin activity that threatened to eat away at a bank’s credibility. Revolutions in

computerization, telecommunications and deregulation from the early 1980s would eventually

change the economics of consumer lending. During the same period, a decline in economic

planning and the rise of capital markets as an alternative source of industrial finance began to eat

away at the traditional profit center for France’s commercial banks. By the mid-1980s, French

banks were moving aggressively into the consumer lending segment. By that time, many

American banks already had thirty or more years of experience with consumer lending.

                                                            

25 Forum International, July 10, 1979.

Page 18: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

17  

The relatively late move by French banks into consumer lending had a lasting impact on

both public policy and on public attitudes toward consumer credit. Because banks did not

participate in consumer lending, they were at best indifferent to government policies that

restricted consumer credit access. In the United States, banks argued vehemently for the

abolition of Regulation W, a restriction adopted during the Korean War that limited the

downpayment and repayment terms for consumer loans; in France, similar qualitative and

quantitative restrictions on consumer lending went unopposed by commercial banks. Had banks

been actively involved in consumer lending, it is likely that the regulatory treatment of the sector

would have been less restrictive. More generally, consumer lending never gained the early

legitimacy that bank participation in the sector might have conferred.

The absence of banks in the consumer lending sector in France during the mid-1960s also

influenced the way French consumers would learn to think about the relationship between credit

and payment. In 1965, dedicated consumer finance companies in France began offering credit

cards that combined electronic payment with a revolving credit facility. The first of these, called

Crédit en poche (pocket credit), was provided by Cetelem; other finance companies quickly

followed.26 For banks, which were not engaged in consumer lending at the time, these cards

seemed to threaten the traditional role of banks in managing the private payment system. In

1967, with support from the French government, a coalition of French banks countered the threat

by creating their own electronic payment network, called Carte bleue. Like modern debit cards,

Carte bleue offered an efficient electronic payment system that drew directly from one’s savings

account. Critically, there was no link to a credit facility.27 Heavily subsidized by France’s main

                                                            

26 Cetelem’s competitor Sofinco followed with a similar revolving credit card called Carte d’argent. Le Figaro, June 14, 1968.

27 Quoted in Schlosser and Tardy (1971), p 55.

Page 19: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

18  

banks, Carte bleue had by the early 1980s become the universal card-based payment system in

France. Only in 1986, with the launch of Cetelem’s Carte aurore, would French consumers

would begin to associate electronic card payment with access to credit.

The factor that distinguished the American consumer lending sector from its French

counterpart, and from the lending sector in virtually every other advanced industrialized

economy, was the early move by US banks into consumer lending. The first US bank to have a

large consumer lending branch was National City Bank, in 1924. American banks in the

Northeast issued their first credit cards in mid-1950s. Bank of America created the first inter-

bank payment network in 1968. By 1972, 2,000 different banks were offering credit cards

affiliated with one of the two major credit networks. The central role of banks in consumer

lending would profoundly shape attitudes toward credit. In general, banks brought deep

legitimacy to consumer borrowing. If banks were willing to make consumer loans, then

consumers could assume that they were useful. More specifically, the early move by banks into

lending meant that credit access and electronic card-based payment became inextricably

connected. Debit cards that separated payment from credit would not become common in the

United States until the 1990s.28

Why did American banks enter consumer lending when their French counterparts did

not? The willingness of American banks to offer consumer credit had two sources. First, many

banks had learned how to make small consumer loans during the interwar period. In 1934, the

Title I program created under the new Federal Housing Act provided federal insurance for

consumer loans intended for home improvement. By removing uncertainty associated with

repayment, and by setting a federally-mandated interest rate on consumer loans (set at 10%), the                                                             

28 Travel and leisure cards like Carte Blanche, Diners Card and American Express were the exception, but they were used primarily by business people.

Page 20: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

19  

Title I program induced many banks to experiment with consumer lending. What they learned

was that consumers were reliable borrowers.29 One industry observer noted in 1937: “Banks

realize today that even in the absence of a government guarantee they can finance loans…with

safety and at a good profit.”30 By 1950, many American banks had developed the specialized

skills—including standardized risk assessment, automated filing and billing, work specialization,

and prompt collections—needed to make consumer loans efficiently. And, for reasons described

below, banks were spared the reputational costs that otherwise might have kept them from

moving into consumer loans.

Still, American banks could not escape the basic economic reality that small loans were

essentially unprofitable. A survey of consumer lenders in 1972 found that most banks that had

launched credit cards in the 1950s and 1960s had lost money on them.31 Banks nonetheless

flooded the consumer market with credit. The reason had to do with the fragmentation of the

postwar banking sector. In 1950, the United States had 14,000 banks. Most were unit banks that

were restricted by state regulations from having branches. They were also bound by Regulation

Q under the Federal Reserve Act, which banned interest on demand deposits (checking accounts)

and capped interest on time deposits (savings accounts). What banks discovered in the 1950s and

1960s was that consumer credit, and especially the new revolving credit card accounts, was a

powerful lure for attracting new depositors. Drawn by the prospect of a loan, borrowers would

open savings accounts and provide a source of new capital for lending. The credit card business                                                             

29 Carter McFarland, “An Economic Evaluation of FHA’s Property Improvement Program,” The Journal of Land and Public Utility Economics 23/4 (November 1947), p 399.

30 Morris Bernhard, “Personal Loan Departments in Banks,” Bankers’ Magazine 134/4 (April 1937), p 320.

31 JC Penney Corporate Collection (JCPCC), Southern Methodist University, Credit Matters, July 1971, “The Role and Functioning of Consumer Credit,” A Report by the Sub-council on Credit and Related Terms of Sale of the National Business Council for Consumer Affairs, March 13, 1972, p 37.

Page 21: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

20  

also attracted new commercial customers, since retailers who agreed to accept early credit cards

also typically moved their banking operations to the same bank. More than the free toasters that

banks occasionally offered as an inducement, credit was the inducement that banks used to

attract new depositors.

The final ingredient that boosted both the supply and the reputation of credit in the

United States was the role of retailers. Up until the 1950s, virtually every product and process

innovation in consumer credit—including installment lending, the credit card itself, and the

revolving credit account, plus automated equipment for making and collecting loans—had its

roots in the retail sector. In the period of postwar prosperity, large retail chains like Sears, JC

Penney and Montgomery Ward offered credit in order to increase sales. Initially, their credit

activities were purely a tool for promoting merchandising.32 The interest rates they charged,

typically 1% per month, almost never covered the actual cost of credit, which had to be

subsidized out of general revenue. It was only in the late 1970s that JC Penney and Montgomery

Ward began to make a profit on their credit services. Because the goal of early retail credit was

to increase sales, retailers almost never pursued aggressive collections. Until the 1980s, JC

Penney had a policy of writing off consumer debts more than six months past due.33 It was in

part the leniency of retail creditors that taught Americans to see consumer credit as economically

benign. Retail credit was not accessible to everyone, but for customers whose applications were

approved, they learned to see credit as convenient and non-threatening.

                                                            

32 JCPCC, Oral History Interview with William Batten, Session 1, Document #1071L, July 16, 1987, Interviews 1-2, p 2-7.

33JCPCC, Updates on Credit – WM Batten Speeches, 1962-1964, Remarks of William M. Batten, President, J.C. Penney Company, at the Annual Shareholders’ Meeting, May 15, 1962, pp 3-4.

Page 22: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

21  

Historical Roots of Regulatory Divergence: Credit Rating and Data Privacy

The different roles of commercial banks in the United States and France had one final

effect that, though unintended, would have a lasting impact on the institutional context of

consumer lending. Much attention has been paid to the role of credit rating agencies in

promoting access to consumer credit, and the French and American cases appear to affirm this

link.34 The United States had history of consumer credit bureaus dating to the interwar period,

and the broad availability of credit in American has been attributed in part to the ability for

lenders to use credit rating data to distinguish reliable from unreliable credit risk.35 Conversely,

the lack of centralized credit rating data in France has been described as one reason for the

relatively low credit extension in the 1990s and 2000s.36 French lenders shared only “black” non-

payment data, not positive “white” information about credit-relevant factors including assets,

outstanding liabilities, income, and credit and employment history. Foreign lenders like Egg and

Capital One reported staying out of the French market in the 1990s specifically because of the

lack of useful credit rating data.37

In the United States, where tens of thousands of small lenders were offering credit,

retailers and banks had long relied on chambers of commerce and other for-profit credit

                                                            

34 Tullio Jappelli and Marco Pagano, “Information Sharing, Lending and Defaults: Cross-country Evidence,” Journal of Banking and Finance 26 (2002), pp 2017-2045; Tullio Jappelli and Marco Pagano, “Role and Effects of Information Sharing in Credit Markets,” in Bertola Guieppe, Richard Disney and Charles Grant, eds., The Economics of Consumer Credit (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2006), 347-371; Margaret Miller, ed., Credit Reporting Systems and the International Economy (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 2003).

35 Alya Guseva and Akos Ronas-Tas, “Uncertainty, Risk, and Trust: Russian and American Credit Card Markets Compared,” American Sociological Review 66 (2001), pp 623-646

36 Libération, December 7, 1988. 37 Catherine Maussion, ‘Crédit: tout le monde dans le même fichier?’ Libération, October

5, 2002.

Page 23: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

22  

information services to track creditworthiness. Given the high mobility of the US population,

these agencies frequently contacted each other in order to access the past credit records of new

arrivals. Many sponsored Welcome Wagons as a way to assess the credit needs and

creditworthiness of new arrivals.38 In 1950, the United States had 1,500 independent rating

agencies. By the early 1970s, these had consolidated into four main for-profit groups: TRW

(Experian), Retail Credit Company (Equifax), Associated Credit Bureaus (Innovis), and

TransUnion. As lenders began making revolving loans, they contracted with credit bureaus to

track their clients’ creditworthiness over time. Once consumer lending began to become

profitable, in the late 1970s, consumer lenders began incorporating aggregate credit scores into

their own credit risk models, and using these models to guide direct marketing campaigns to

attract new customers.

Why did France not develop a similar system of centralized credit reference data

collection? The problem was not a lack of know-how. In 1900, the Parisian retailer and lender

Georges Dufayel had already accumulated a credit database of over 3.5 million French citizens—

probably the largest rating database of its kind in the world at that time.39 Yet early postwar

lenders never created a centralized credit rating bureau. There were two reasons for this. First,

consumer lenders were relatively few in number. In 1955, France had 70 registered consumer

lenders, and many of these were regionally focused. This meant that lender activities did not

heavily overlap, and the advantages of sharing data were not great. More importantly, the way in

which they assessed credit was different. In the French system, lenders made loans indirectly,

through retailers, and those retailers took responsibility for assessing credit-worthiness of                                                             

38 Louis Hyman, Debtor Nation (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2010). 39 Jacques-Bernard Voirin, “Les Aspects Financiers et Economiques du credit a la

consummation: etude comparative et evolutive,” Doctoral Thesis in Economics, University of Paris, March 1959, p 40.

Page 24: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

23  

borrowers. When borrowers did not pay, retailers shared in the loss. If non-payment rates rose

too high for a particular retailer, it was dropped from the lender’s portfolio. The system was

highly effective, and non-payment rates were regularly below 1%. But it meant that consumer

lenders focused on repayment by retailers rather than by individual consumers. In 1974, the four

largest consumer lenders in France did begin sharing non-payment data, but they never moved to

share the sort of positive data that was used to assess borrower riskiness in the United States.40

In the 1980s, consumer lending in France shifted from indirect sales credit to direct-to-

consumer lending. This shift in practice drove demand for a new credit data service. In 1988, the

Banque de France advocated adopting a centralized “white" credit data depository to which all

French lenders would contribute. Coming at a time when household debt and nonpayment rates

were both rising, policymakers, as well as many consumer lenders, hoped that better data on

household debt levels would help target loans to more reliable borrowers.41 The project would

almost certainly have passed, had it not been for objections from France’s powerful data privacy

agency, the National Commission in Information and Freedom (CNIL). CNIL argued that any

centralized collection of private consumer credit data would unduly infringe on the consumers’

right to privacy, and was therefore illegal under France’s data privacy law.42 Thus, France’s lack

of centralized credit rating would appear to reflect different national approaches to personal

privacy.

In reality, the historical roots of data privacy policy the United States and France trace

their roots to early postwar consumer lending practice. In 1968, authorities in both the United                                                             

40 Gérard de Chaunac-Lanzac, La vie m’a fait crédit (Paris, 2001), 237. 41 Pierre-Laurent Chatain and Frédéric Ferrière, Surendettement des particuliers (Paris:

Editions dalloz, 2000), p 188. 42 Bertrand Bissuel and Anne Michel, “Les établissements de crédit accusés de favoriser

le surendettement, Le Monde, 28 April 2005; Sylvie Ramadier, “La bataille du crédit à la consummation,” Les Echos, 21-22 January 2005, p 8.

Page 25: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

24  

States and France were drafting legislation to introduce the principle of data privacy. The trigger

in each case was an initiative to unify all government-held data into a single electronic database

that could be used to optimize public policy. Consumer and labor advocates in both countries

pushed for lawmakers to limit the collection and sharing of private data. The focus of the

legislation was on the activities of the government, but each country also had to decide how to

regulate data collection and sharing by companies. In the United States, data privacy legislation

became the focus of intensive lobbying by the big-three credit rating agencies, which were in the

midst of digitizing their collections. Coming at a time in which policymakers were pushing

lenders to offer loans to traditionally marginalized borrowers, the credit rating agencies easily

convinced policymakers that the collection and sharing of private credit data promoted fair credit

access. US privacy legislation was therefore limited to government-held data. In France, there

was no credit rating sector to push back against a comprehensive conception of data privacy that

applied the same restrictions to private companies as to the government. Without opposition

from the private sector, France’s privacy legislation gave CNIL a broad mandate to regulate the

exchange of private data among corporations.43 In this way, the early structure of postwar

lending in France set a legal trajectory that continued to shape the sector forty year later.

Explaining Demand for Credit: The Rise of Socially Acceptable Credit

Supply conditions alone cannot explain the different patterns of consumer credit use we

observe in the United States and France; we also need to understand differences in demand. Both

countries harbored deep traditional concerns about the impact of consumer credit on society. In

                                                            

43 Gunnar Trumbull, “Between Global and Local: The Invention of Data Privacy in the United States and France,” in Kirsten Bruchweh, ed., The Voice of the Citizen Consumer (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2010).

Page 26: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

25  

France, the Catholic prohibition against usury, combined with a history of exploitative door-to-

door textile traders that offered sales on credit, had given consumer lending a bad reputation.

This kind of apprehension was if anything stronger in the United States. The roots were partly

religious, as in France, but also economic and social in emphasis. Almost every US state had

strict usury laws on their books limiting interest rates to between 6% and 8% per year. Most were

enacted in the wake of financial crises in the 18th and 19th centuries that had been attributed at

least in part to credit-financed speculation. More generally, policymakers worried that consumer

credit amplified the natural economic cycle, with liberal lending during periods of growth and

scarcity during down cycles. By the turn of the 19th century, social progressives and worker

advocates had also become concerned about sales credit. Door-to-door sellers, discount retail

chains (dubbed “Borax houses”) and company stores all had the reputation of offering credit to

induce their customers to purchase shoddy products.44 Consumer lending was frequently

exploitative. Small salary lenders, the forebears of 21st century check traders, regularly charged

20% to 40% per month, secured against a worker’s future paycheck. Yet, from this common state

of popular apprehension, different attitudes toward consumer credit emerged in United States

and France. This transformation occurred through a regulatory process in which this formerly

disreputable activity came be seen as economically and socially legitimate.

In France, consumer lending became publicly acceptable through a close interaction with

and supervision by regulators. From 1953 until 1984, France’s National Credit Council (CNC),

in consultation with the Banque de France and the French finance ministry, set the terms and

volumes of credit that could be offered by consumer lenders.45 In order to grow, consumer

                                                            

44 Calder, Financing the American Dream, p 56. 45 Albert O. Hirschman and Robert V. Rosa, “Postwar Credit Controls in France,”

Federal Reserve Bulletin 35/4 (1949), p 349.

Page 27: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

26  

lenders had to behave in ways that gave the CNC reason to support them. From 1966, the CNC

also set usury caps that limited the price lenders could charge. Unlike in the United States, where

lenders resorted to a range of creative pricing schemes to evade the highly restrictive state usury

caps, the French caps were genuinely enforced. In one sense, this sort of skepticism about

markets is familiar to the French political economy. The surprise is the silence from consumer,

labor and minority groups that would become strong advocates of liberal access to credit in the

United States. When France did finally experiment with a liberal credit regime, between 1984

and 1989, rising debt and non-payment rates drove a backlash that placed the lending sector

under new forms of government control. The result has been an approach that takes consumer

credit as a legitimate economic activity so long as it is closely managed by the state.

In United States, the legitimation of consumer credit followed a different path. Although

the sector remained tightly regulated at the state level until the late 1970s, a loose and evolving

coalition of lenders and progressive non-governmental organizations (NGOs) had from the very

beginning of the 20th century begun to push for greater access to consumer credit as a response to

social ills. Those NGOs included welfare societies and charitable foundations in the 1910s and

1920, labor unions in the 1950s, and women and civil rights movements of the late 1960s and

1970s. Each argued for greater access to credit on less restrictive terms in order to improve the

welfare of marginalized groups. At the same time, industrialists and employers saw consumer

credit as a private-sector response to social stresses that could take the place of government-

managed welfare policies. It is from this coalition of interests, supported by the lending practices

of banks and retailers, that an American ideal of credit as a means to economic prosperity took

root.

Page 28: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

27  

The US Case: Harnessing Credit for Social Policy

The idea that credit might become a form of self-help for the poor and working classes

emerged at the turn of the nineteenth century. At that time, a set of religion-based social

reformers in Boston and New York began exploring the idea of a rigorous approach to welfare,

what they called “scientific philanthropy,” that would avoid the problems caused by direct

welfare support. As Lewis Edwin Theiss, one of the movement’s early founders, explained:

“Relief, given in love, begets a degenerate craving for more.”46 Scientific philanthropy

advocated modern prison reform, the policy of “friendly visiting” that became the inspiration of

modern social work, as well as the idea of inexpensive credit for workers. Their model was a

French institution, the mont-de-piété, or charitable pawn shop (see below). The first of these,

founded by welfare reformers in New York in 1894, was the Provident Loan Society. By 1915,

there were 40 similar institutions across the country.47 They made loans at 1% per month, and

raised capital by issuing bonds whose return was capped at 6% per year. The idea was to offer

workers and the poor a low-cost alternative to loan sharks, and many of the country’s charitable

foundations invested in their bonds. For the many philanthropic industrialists who helped finance

the effort, charitable pawn looked like a market-based alternative to the sort of expansive welfare

states that were emerging in Europe.

The problem with charitable pawn was not that it didn’t work—most were highly

successful—but that it was not enough. Especially in the wake of the financial crisis of 1906-7,

demand for credit was so high that charitable pawn could not keep pace.48 If enough credit was

                                                            

46 Ibid., p 318. 47 Shelly Tenenbaum, A Credit to Their Community: Jewish Loan Societies in the United

States, 1880-1945 (Detroit: Wayne State University Press, 1993), p 97. 48 Morris R. Neifeld and Stuart Bruchev, Cooperative Consumer Credit (Manchester,

N.H.: Ayter Publishing, 1979), pp 2-3.

Page 29: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

28  

going to be made available, it would have to come from the private sector. The problem was that

the high cost of making small loans meant that lenders were forced to deceive borrowers about

their interest rates in order to operate below low state usury caps. In 1910, two institutions were

created that would propose two very different solutions to this conundrum: the Morris Bank, and

the Russell Sage Foundation. Together, they would set the trajectory of American policy toward

consumer credit.

In 1909, Arthur Morris, a lawyer from Virginia, began making small unsecured loans at

rates that were “reasonable to the borrower and yet fairly remunerative to capital.”49 His bank,

and the network of Morris Plan banks that was founded around the country, was based on two

innovations. First, all loans required two co-signers, who were legally liable if the borrower did

not repay. This system, what Morris called “character as the basis of credit,” resulted in default

rates averaging 0.25% over the duration of the Morris Plan, from 1910 to 1952.50 The second

innovation was based on some legal sleight of hand. For every $100 loan, Morris deducted $6 for

interest and $2 as a processing fee. Although relatively cheap for lending at the time, this was

still far above state usury laws, since the loan was repaid in weekly installments, and interest on

the declining balance was closer to 13%. Morris’s solution was to channel installment payments

to the purchase of investment securities that were then used to repay the loan at the end of the

term. Since the loan was not technically being repaid until the end, interest on the loan was 6%,

and therefore below state usury caps. Morris justified the system as a tool for encouraging thrift.

Morris Plan borrowers learned to save, “in the first instance as a condition of a loan advanced by

                                                            

49 Industrial Finance Corporation, Articles of Incorporation, 1914. 50 AJM, Box 17, Scrap Book 1952, San Francisco News, March 27, 1952.

Page 30: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

29  

us, and afterwards and permanently, for investment.”51 Even more important, Morris repeatedly

made the case that his system would reduce class tensions, giving workers a dignified means to

help themselves.52 By 1930, there were over 140 Morris Plan banks around the country.

The other solution to the problem, proposed by the Department of Consumer Credit

Studies of the Russell Sage Foundation, was to legalize higher interest rates. From 1914 to 1928,

Russell Sage fought state-by-state legislative battles to enact special laws covering small loans.

Under these small loan laws, lenders who registered with state regulators and disclosed the full

cost of their loans as an annual interest rate (on the declining balance) were allowed to charge up

to 42% annual interest. Although expensive, Russell Sage calculated that this was what small

loan companies would need to charge in order to make loans profitably and legally. Early

consumer advocates, as well as the loan sharks that profited from illegal lending, accused Russell

Sage of promoting usurious interest rates. Eventually 26 state legislatures were won over and

passed small loan laws modeled on the Russell Sage Foundation model. Loan sharks in these

states disappeared virtually overnight.53 Between Russell Sage, the Morris Bank network, and

the growing number of charitable pawn shops, social progressives in the interwar period came to

see personal credit on reasonable terms as a boon to working-class Americans.

In the wake of World War II, the logic of public support for consumer credit shifted to

organized labor. When the Federal Reserve, under direction of the Treasury Department,

imposed restrictions on downpayment and repayment periods for installment loans under

                                                            

51 Russell Sage Foundation Archives (RSF), Rockefeller Archives Center, Box 25, Folder 191, Letter from Clark Williams, President of Industrial Finance Corporation, to Robert W. deForest, vice president of Russell Sage Foundation, May 28, 1917.

52 Elgin R. L. Gould, “The Meeting Ground of Business and Philanthropy,” in Lindsay Russell, ed., America to Japan (New York: Putnam’s Sons, 1915, p 136.

53 RSF, Box 24, Folder 186, Letter from Shelby M. Harrison, RSF, to Jeremiah Milbank, President of the Provident Loan Society of New York, April 25, 1935.

Page 31: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

30  

Regulation W during the Korean War, the American Federation of Labor fought it

vociferously.54 It argued that restricted credit would reduce demand, and that this in turn would

cause unemployment. It also supported state legislation to liberalize usury restrictions for bank

and retail lending in order to extend credit access for workers.55 There were two reasons for labor

support. First, employers and organized labor both saw credit as feeding a virtuous cycle, in

which higher demand drove manufacturing scale, productivity, and wages. Higher wages in turn

drove new demand. Moreover, credit gave workers access to the benefits of new household

products after years of wartime thrift. Second, labor unions in the early 1950s relied on credit to

finance strike actions. During the wave of Appalachian mine strikes of the late 1940s and 1950s,

workers primarily relied on credit from retailers and finance companies to hold out. In some

cases, labor unions pre-negotiated lines of credit or moratoria on interest payments in preparation

for a strike. For creditors, strikers to secure long-term wage contracts made workers even more

reliable repayers. Even company stores almost always extended credit to striking workers.56

Credit financing had one critical drawback. Workers were serious about repaying their debts, and

unions quickly realized that they could not call a new strike before debts from the previous strike

had been settled.

By the late 1960s, trade unions had become far less enthusiastic about the merits of credit

for their workers. They now supported more restricted credit policies, and fought in state-level

campaigns to lower usury caps. But public attention in the credit debate had by that time already

shifted to issues of credit access for previously marginalized groups. Women’s and civil rights

advocates in particular embraced the idea of credit access as a basic right. Most prominent of                                                             

54 Wall Street Journal, December 9. 1950. 55 J. Albert Woll, “Organized Labor Views of the Loan Shark Problem,” Law and

Contemporary Problems 19/1 (1954), p 99. 56 Edward J. Lally, “Coal Strikers,” Wall Street Journal, October 31, 1949.

Page 32: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

31  

these was the National Welfare Rights Organization (NWRO), an advocacy organization

targeting single, mainly black mothers on welfare. In 1969, the NWRO launched a national

campaign to get retailers to extend credit to their membership. When Sears refused, on the

grounds that welfare mothers did not meet their risk criteria, the NWRO launched a 2 year

boycott against them. Other large retail chains, including Montgomery Ward, Gimbels and

Federated Department Stores, all signed nationwide agreements with the NWRO.57 The NWRO

campaign, and a range of similar private and public efforts to extend credit to poor urban blacks,

had been inspired in part by the findings of the Kerner Commission investigation into the sources

of urban riots that had been plaguing most major inner cities in the late 1960s. The Kerner

Report argued that racial tensions could be alleviated in part by greater financial access. “Rather

than rejecting the American system, [the rioters] were anxious to obtain a place for themselves in

it.”58 The NWRO and similar movements laid the groundwork for subsequent credit-access

policies, including the 1977 Community Redevelopment Act and federally-supported low

income credit unions.

As the NWRO campaign was coming to an end (repayment rates had proven

disappointingly low), women’s advocacy groups began to focus on credit access for white,

middle-class women. The National Organization for Women (NOW) spearheaded a campaign to

bring their plight into the light. As documented in thousands of testimonial letters, the greatest

problems afflicted married and divorced women. Married women could only get credit in their

husband’s name; women’s salaries were either not recognized or heavily discounted in home

mortgage applications, on the grounds that they were likely to have kids and quit their jobs;

                                                            

57 Wall Street Journal, December 9, 1969; New York Times, May 9, 1970. 58 Kerner Commission, Report of the National Advisory Commission on Civil Disorders,

1968, p 7.

Page 33: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

32  

many lenders requested so-called “baby letters” from doctors ensuring that a woman was

infertile or on birth control. Once divorced, women had no credit rating of their own, and even

professional women were unable to get credit.59 The NOW campaigns led to further legislative

reforms, including the 1974 Equal Credit Opportunity Act60 banning discrimination based on sex

or marital status, and an Amendment to the 1970 Fair Credit Reporting Act requiring credit

agencies to keep separate records for married women. The message was clear: to be a

functioning member of society required credit, and that meant that credit access must be treated

as a right, not a privilege.

The French Case: Credit and Consumer Protection

The United States was by no means unique in interpreting credit as a strategy for

improving social welfare. France had been experimenting with social credit long before it was

discovered in the United States. Earliest of these was the charitable pawn shop, or mont-de-

piété.61 The first mont-de-piété was opened in by the Franciscan monk Théophraste Renaudot in

1637, though it lasted only 7 years. The idea was revived in 1777 by Jacque Necker, Louis XVI’s

liberal finance minister. For most of the next two centuries, France’s monts-de-piété enjoyed a

monopoly on the domestic pawn market in return for helping the poor. They served the poor in

two ways: offering low-interest (9% to 15%) loans at a time when personal credit was available

only on exorbitant terms, and transferring excess interest income to charitable hospitals. Until

                                                            

59 Archives of the National Organization for Women (NOW), Schlessinger Library, Box 211, File 41. Billie Venable Sessoms, Suzanne Nelsen, and Patricia Smith, “A Preliminary Report on Women and Cedit,” National Organization for Women, Durham, North Carolina Chapter, October 15, 1973, p 11.

60 ECOA antidiscrimination provisions were extended to include race and color in 1977. 61 American reformers regularly traveled to Europe to study the small lending institutions

there. These included Arthur Morris, founder of the Morris Plan Banks, Edward Filenes, who advocated for the founding of credit unions, and at least one Congressional research team.

Page 34: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

33  

World War I, the monts-de-piété had functioned independently of the state. That changed with

the onset of war. Under partial German occupation, non-payment rates rose, and the government

placed a ban on auctions of unclaimed pawn. This drove the monts-de-piété into insolvency.

With the end of the war, and amid great social dislocation, the government began for the first

time to offer direct financial aid to recapitalize the monts-de-piété. The effect was to make

consumer lending a function of state welfare policy. Following World War II, the functions of

the monts-de-piété were enlarged. They began offering low-cost salary loans to public

employees, and, later, provided advances on welfare payments. In order to shed the social stigma

that had traditionally been associated with the monts-de-piété, the institutions were rebranded as

“municipal credit unions,” and they continued to function as a part of France’s formal welfare

system.

Two features of France’s early experiments with social credit differentiated its experience

from the United States. First, the direct involvement of the French state painted credit in a very

different light. If credit in America was seen as an alternative to an expansive welfare state,

French social credit became an integral (if relatively small) function of the welfare state. And

because lending by the monts-de-piété and municipal credit unions was explicitly state-

sponsored, the idea of credit as socially beneficial never fully extended to private credit markets.

Credit could be beneficial, in some cases, but the conditions under which it was offered had to be

carefully controlled.

The second difference in the French experience was a general hostility of organized labor

toward credit. If American labor saw credit as a means to fight loan sharks, finance strike actions

and secure the fruits of industrialization for workers, French labor leaders saw it as mainly

negative in its effect. At a minimum, they complained that high interest charges on consumer

Page 35: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

34  

credit reduced worker purchasing power.62 There was also a strong perception that credit

contributed to the de-radicalization, or embourgeoisement, of the working class.63 Leftist

commentator René Creussol warned in 1956: “Employers hope that the need for regular

repayment will cause workers to lose their combativeness and even, at the limit, their class

consciousness, since they have to allocate a share of their salary at the end of each month toward

paying their debts.”64 Concretely, he observed that workers with debts to pay were more

reluctant to strike. France’s communist party (CGT) was even most strident in its critique. For

them, the interest paid on credit was simply another means to exploit workers once employers

had reached the limits of wage restraint. “The challenges of increasing [worker] exploitation

have made it necessary to resort to indirect means to recover salary payments.”65 With concerted

opposition from labor, and with no other societal groups pushing actively for greater credit

access, the idea of credit as socially progressive simply never took root.

Debates about consumer credit in postwar France instead focused on its implications for

economic reconstruction. Officials at the Banque de France worried that free access to consumer

credit would have two especially negative effects: that retailers would compete on providing

credit rather than on price, resulting in inflation, and that consumer credit would reduce the

capital available for industrial investments.66 What is striking about each of these objections is

that they had very little to do with concerns about individual welfare. Early consumer finance

companies worked hard to address these concerns. They argued repeatedly that credit drove scale                                                             

62 Max Léon, “Rien à Payer,” Humanité, July 3, 1956. 63 René Sédillot, La vie Française, February 5, 1954. 64 René Creussol, “Le Developpement des ventes a crédit,” Economie et Politique 22

(1956), pp 78-9. 65 CGT, Le crédit à la consommation: facilité ou contrainte (CGT: May 1978), p 113. 66 BdF CNC, 1427200301, Box 111: Crédit à la Consommation et vente au Crédit;

Gilbert Mathieu, "Le gouvernement fixera-t-il un taux d’intérêt maximum pour les crédits consentis aux acheteurs ?" Le Monde, January 4-5, 1953.

Page 36: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

35  

in production, and that this led to lower prices for consumers, while also helping French

exports.67 They also repeatedly argued that consumer credit encouraged savings. Their idea was

that regular installment payments taught consumers discipline, and that they would continue to

restrain their consumption even after the loan was paid off. Rather than crowding out industrial

investment, French lenders argued that consumer credit would increase savings and thus make

more capital available for industrial investment.68 Cetelem, one of France’s early general-

purpose sales finance companies, made this point clearly with their logo of a house depicted as a

change bank, with a coin poised over a slot in the roof. Their case for consumer credit was not

that it was good for workers or for the poor, but that it was good for France as a whole.

Conclusions

Market regulation has conventionally been justified in terms either of the public interest

in correcting market failures or of the social welfare interest in restricting market functions. Each

kind of account relies on features of markets to justify regulation. The case of consumer credit

suggests that the historical context in which markets have been constructed as legitimate matters

for the way in which they are regulated. For consumer credit, the goal of early regulation was to

define a logic of consumer lending and borrowing that differentiated legitimate new practices

from historically exploitative practices. The basis for that legitimacy proved to be very different

in France and the United States, and those historical differences went on to shape the conditions

of credit market regulation over the longer term.

                                                            

67 Jean Chicoye, “Les achats a credit,” Revue de l’action populaire 140 (July-August 1960), p 794; Pierre Locardel, “L’extension du credit à la consummation sera reserve à certains articles utilitaires,” Le Figaro, 14 April 1953.

68 Cetelem Historical Archives, Promotional material for launch of Cetelem, “Note d’information concernant le CETELEM,” September 1953, p 2.

Page 37: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

36  

Two features of the historical context proved consequential for the way in which credit

came to be legitimated. The first was the role of banks. The core challenge of early consumer

lending was not repayment risk—workers were in general reliable repayers—but instead the high

administrative costs of making small loans. These costs, coupled with restrictions on how much

lenders could charge, made consumer lending a largely unprofitable business. It was the

fragmented and highly competitive banking sector in the United States that led banks to offer

credit, and especially revolving credit, as an inducement to attract new depositors. American

retailers also provided credit, subsidized out of sales, to attract new customers. And because the

goal of these loans was to attract and retain customers, the terms of lending tended to be humane.

In France, banks were making profitable industrial loans to projects that were being supported

through coordinated government policies. Despite periodic pressure from the state to enter the

consumer lending business, most banks stayed away. Without the legitimacy that would have

accompanied bank participation, French lending continued to be viewed with public skepticism.

The second feature that set France and the United States on different trajectories was the

divergence in attitudes about credit of progressive non-government organizations, including

trade unions and other welfare and rights groups. In France, the relationship between credit and

welfare was contested. France was a pioneer with early forms of social credit, including

charitable pawn, but these forays into credit-based welfare were managed directly by the French

state. This lent consumer credit a limited sort of legitimacy: so long as it was carefully regulated,

it could provide benefits, but those benefits did not automatically emerge with free credit access.

The labor left was generally opposed to consumer credit, which they saw as reducing worker

purchasing power, and also potentially reducing worker militancy. Nor did other advocacy

groups push credit access for socially marginalized groups. France’s tradition of republican

Page 38: Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in ... Files/11-047.pdf · Regulating for Legitimacy: Consumer Credit Access in France and America Gunnar Trumbull November 2010

37  

citizenship implied equal treatment by the state, but not universal access to all products and

services in the marketplace. In particular, the idea of “positive discrimination” in promoting

market access was antithetical to the republican ideal.69

In the United States, an evolving coalition of lenders and non-profit societies pushed the

idea of credit access as welfare improving: from anti-loan shark campaigns in the 1920s, to early

postwar credit intended to give workers access to new household products, to campaigns in the

1970s to extend credit to urban blacks and middle-class women. The center-left “third way”

movement of the 1990s continued to embrace expanded credit access as a means to improve the

welfare of the worst-off in society. In a sense, it is hardly surprising that American consumers

came to perceive consumer credit as a path to prosperity. For nearly three generations, coalitions

of progressive activists and conservative industrialists assumed that access to credit generated

positive social outcomes.

                                                            

69 Luc Matray, Director General of the Credit Municipal de Paris, “Introduction,” La Bacarisation des nouveaux marchés urbains, a study commissioned of the US credit markets, 2004, p VI.