public investment and regional growth and convergence: evidence from greece

26

Click here to load reader

Upload: andres-rodriguez-pose

Post on 02-Oct-2016

214 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Public investment and regional growth and convergence:Evidence from Greece*

Andrés Rodríguez-Pose1, Yannis Psycharis2, Vassilis Tselios3

1 Department of Geography and Environment, London School of Economics, Houghton St, London WC2A 2AE,UK (e-mail: [email protected])

2 Department of Economic and Regional Development, Panteion University of Social and Political Sciences, 136Syngrou Avenue, 17671 Athens, Greece (e-mail: [email protected])

3 Department of Economic Geography, Faculty of Spatial Sciences, University of Groningen, Landleven 1,NL- 9747AD Groningen, The Netherlands (e-mail: [email protected])

Received: 28 June 2011 / Accepted: 13 April 2012

Abstract. This paper estimates the impact of public investment on regional economic growthand convergence at the NUTS 3 level in Greece. Using a new database of public expenditure perregion for the period 1978–2007, it proposes a model which captures not just the impact ofpublic investment in Greek prefectures, but also the spillover effects related to the existence ofexternalities from neighbouring regions. The results point to a positive long-run impact of publicinvestment per capita on regional economic growth – but not on convergence – which alsogenerates considerable spillover effects. However, the returns vary according to different typesof public investment, with education and infrastructure spillovers having the highest impact. Ingeneral, public investment externalities seem to be more relevant for regional growth than directpublic investment in each region. Finally, the impact of different types of public investment inGreece is mediated by politics and political factors, but the effect of politics disappears once wecontrol for political-period-specific spatial-invariant variables.

JEL classification: R11, R12, R53, R58

Key words: Public investment, economic growth, spillover effects, convergence, Greece

1 Introduction

Fiscal policy, in general, and public investment, in particular, have regained attention since theonset of the Great Recession in 2008. Discretionary fiscal action and the initial implementation

* We are grateful to the special issue editors and to the anonymous referees for their helpful suggestions to earlierversions of this paper. An earlier version of the paper was presented at the ERSA Conference in Barcelona in 2011. Theresearch leading to this paper has benefited from the support of the European Research Council under the EuropeanUnion’s Seventh Framework Programme (FP7/2007-2013)/ERC grant agreement no 269868 and of a Leverhulme TrustMajor Research Fellowship. The research is also part of the Prociudad-CM programme and of the UK Spatial EconomicsResearch Centre. The views expressed are those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of the funders.

doi:10.1111/j.1435-5957.2012.00444.x

© 2012 the author(s). Papers in Regional Science © 2012 RSAI. Published by Blackwell Publishing, 9600 Garsington Road,Oxford OX4 2DQ, UK and 350 Main Street, Malden MA 02148, USA.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 2: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

of stimulus packages, intended to stabilize the economy and promote economic growth andemployment, have revived the interest on the macroeconomic consequences of fiscal and publicpolicies (Krugman 2005; Solow 2005).

The potential returns of public investment have, however, always been hotly disputed.Starting at least with Keynes, public investment has variously been portrayed as a stabilizer ofthe economy (Musgrave 1959), as a generator of economic development and growth (Hirschman1958), and as an instrument for the redistribution of national wealth, both among income groupsand across geographical areas (e.g., Oates 1972). These views had a tremendous influence onpolicy, leading to the implementation of massive public works programmes both in the US andin Europe, especially during the ‘New Deal’ and after the Second World War.

The expansion of public investment in the post-war decades was followed, after the crises ofthe 1970s, by a period of greater introspection in which the potential returns of investment bythe state became contested. While some (e.g., Aschauer 1989a, 1989b, 1989c 1990; Munnell1990a, 1990b; 1992), extolled the virtues of public investment, and especially of public infra-structure, in increasing productivity and economic growth, others questioned whether thesereturns ever materialized (e.g., Hulten and Schwab 1991; García-Milá and McGuire 1992; Evansand Karras 1994; Holtz-Eakin 1994; Holtz-Eakin and Schwartz 1995; García-Milá et al. 1996),reflecting an increasing political scepticism in public investment that characterized governmentsacross the developed world.

The aim of this paper is to contribute to this debate and analyse the short-/medium- andlong-term returns of public investment in Greece, a country where public intervention has beenmuch maligned of recent. We will assess whether public investment in Greek regions (prefec-tures or NUTS 3 regions) has delivered greater regional growth and convergence. During theperiod of analysis successive Greek governments – regardless of their political orientation –have made regional growth and convergence one of their main economic policy priorities.However, so far, there has been little research assessing the impact of these interventions.

The scarcity of research in this field is partly the result of the lack of reliable and consistenttime series containing public investment data at the level of prefectures. We overcome thisproblem by gathering a deflation-adjusted dataset of public investment expenditure in Greece atNUTS 3 level for the period 1978–2007. The data were collected using different official datasources and processed together in order to generate a complete and comprehensive source ofstatistical data on different types of public investment for Greek prefectures over three decades,considering both the direct regional impact of intervention and the externalities it generates.

In order to achieve this aim, the paper is structured around six sections. First, this shortintroduction is followed by a section looking at the literature on public investment and growth.Section 3 introduces the data sources and some key stylized facts about public investment inGreece. The econometric model is presented in Section 4, which is followed by the interpreta-tion of results in Section 5. The paper concludes with some policy recommendations andproposals for future work.

2 Public investment, spillovers, polities and growth

2.1 Public investment, spillover effects and growth

There is much controversy in the literature about the economic returns of public policy inter-vention on territorial development. Two opposing camps are clearly defined. On the one hand,there are those who tend to view public investment as a generator of economic growth anddevelopment and as a source of regional convergence. Neoclassical economics is firmly withinthis camp. The works of Solow (1956) or Barro (1990) have emphasized the equalizing role of

2 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 3: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

public capital, in general, and of investment in physical capital, in particular, as a consequenceof the existence of constant or decreasing returns to scale for capital accumulation. But perhapsthe greatest defender of public investment in recent decades has been Aschauer. Aschauer(1989a, 1989b) posits that differences in the stock of physical capital – and, consequently, ofpublic infrastructure – are the fundamental factors explaining differences in territorial levels ofoutput and development. According to Aschauer (1989a, 1989b), a good endowment of publicinfrastructure significantly contributes to a productivity rise in the private sector and to eco-nomic growth. This view has been supported by a relatively large number of studies (i.e.,Munnell 1990a, 1990b; Berndt and Hansson 1992; Nadiri and Mamuneas 1994).

This positive perception of the returns of public investment is, however, far from being thenorm. Many researchers have challenged Aschauer’s views by demonstrating that the impact ofpublic infrastructure investment has either been insignificant or negligible. Most of this litera-ture tends to underline the lack of any clear and positive link between public capital and privateoutput, regardless of geographical context (e.g., Sturm and de Haan 1995; Pereira and Roca-Sagalés 2003).

The controversy between both camps is not just the result of different theoretical stand-points. It may also reflect other factors, such as the “different sources of data upon whichscholars have based their contributions”, the “geographic scale at which the analyses wereconducted”, and, “the absence of geographical consideration” and of a more precise specifi-cation of “inter-regional economic links of public infrastructure impacts” (Mikelbank andJackson 2000, p. 251). In particular, the lack of consideration of the role played by geo-graphical spillover effects may be crucial in the inconclusive nature of the literature on thereturns of investment in infrastructure (Pereira and Roca-Sagalés 2003; Moreno and López-Bazo 2007).

The relatively recent introduction of geographical aspects and spillovers in the analysis ofthe impact of public investment has often led to results that are somewhat less polarized. By andlarge, studies that are more sensitive to the spatial dimension tend to highlight that publicinvestment plays a role in the geographical distribution of economic activities and that itgenerates externalities which may diffuse across regional borders (Kamps 2005; Välilä et al.2005; Rodríguez-Pose and Crescenzi 2008; Kemmerling and Stephan 2008; Ottaviano 2008).Whether changes in the distribution of economic activity as a result of public investment aremore or less beneficial for economic growth and convergence varies from one analysis to theother. Most studies tend to find some returns of public investment on output and growth, but aregenerally more cautious on its impact on regional convergence. Välilä et al. (2005) and theEuropean Commission (2007), for example, show that public investment in the European Union(EU) plays a non-negligible role as a determinant of output across Europe. Similarly, a numberof studies analysing the impact of investment by the European Structural Funds have found apositive – albeit to a varying degree according to the different studies – relationship betweenEuropean investment and regional growth in the EU (Cappelen et al. 2003; Rodríguez-Pose andFratesi 2004; Puigcerver-Peñalver 2007).

The views on the impact of public investment on regional convergence are, by contrast, lessclear cut. Contrasting results abound. Most, however, report little firm evidence of a widespreadconvergence linked to public investment expenditure. This is the case, for example, of the Italianregions, where Daniele (2009) finds that, for the period 1980–2007, public expenditure hascontributed to cross-regional convergence in labour productivity, but has had a very limitedimpact on convergence in GDP per capita. Progressive territorial policies have often resulted ina growing divergence between the North and the South of the country (Padovano 2007).Lago-Peñas and Martínez-López (2009) reach the same conclusion for Spain: despite thepresence of strong redistributive policies from a territorial perspective, public investment did notgenerate regional convergence across Spanish regions during the 1980s and 1990s. And similar

3Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 4: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

results are found by Pereira and Andraz (2006) for Portugal and by Checherita et al. (2009) forthe whole of the EU.

2.2 Polity and growth

One of the key shortcomings of this type of analysis is that it tends to overlook the role playedby political and institutional factors. Most of the research on the returns to public investment hasfundamentally concentrated on levels of investment and endowments, using other regionaleconomic variables as controls. Yet, it is well-known that the returns of public investment arelikely to be strongly mediated by local political and institutional factors. Political decisions playan important role in determining public resource allocation across space. Numerous studies havedocumented that public expenditure is more often the result of political considerations –pork-barrel politics – than a response to social welfare or economic efficiency needs (Yamanoand Ohkawara 2000; Johansson 2003; Castells and Solé-Ollé 2005; Cadot et al. 2006).

The influence of pork-barrel politics in decisions about where to locate public expenditureacross countries of Europe is becoming increasingly well documented, with many studieshighlighting that ‘politics matter’ for the allocation of public investment (e.g., Estache 2006;Romp and de Haan 2007). Kemmerling and Stephan (2008) have, for example, shown that in thecase of France, Germany, Italy and Spain political factors play a determinant role in the regionaldistribution of infrastructure investment, although the impact of these factors is less importantthan what the authors had anticipated. Specific country evidence tends to be stronger. In the caseof Italy, Golden and Picci (2008) find that powerful individuals in the ruling party manage tosecure greater infrastructure investments for their localities of origin. Similarly, Castells andSolé-Ollé (2005) demonstrate that, in the case of Spanish provinces, efficiency criteria played avery limited role in the geographical distribution of government infrastructure investment, withpolitical factors being more prominent in decisions about where to allocate infrastructure. HenceSpanish governments tend to invest more in the regions where electoral productivity is higher,with partisan alignment having an important influence on the amount of public grants awardedto municipalities (Solé-Ollé and Sorribas-Navarro 2008). The role of pork-barrel politics andelectoral considerations has been further documented in the cases of France (Cadot et al. 2006)and Sweden (Johansson 2003, p. 883), where “intergovernmental grants are used in order to winvotes”.

The limited research on pork-barrel politics in Greece has, in contrast to the above men-tioned analyses for other European countries, presented little evidence of an influence ofpolitical factors on decisions about where to allocate public investment. Lambrinidis et al.(2005) have found that the percentage of votes in a prefecture in favour of the governing partyat national level has not played a significant role in the regional allocation of public investmentin infrastructure. We will revisit this issue in this paper.

3 Public investment in Greece

3.1 Public investment in Greece – setting the context of analysis

Public investment in Greece has been the main and arguably the most popular way to tackle boththe country’s backwardness relative to the EU average, as well as its strong internal territorialimbalances. Public investment programmes have been used by successive Greek governments asa way to promote convergence towards the standards of living of the EU and to reduce domesticregional asymmetries.

4 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 5: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Between 1978 and 2007 public investment represented on average 4 per cent of the annualGDP of the country. There were, however, important yearly fluctuations in the amount of fundsdevoted to public investment. As a general rule, public investment was strongest in the secondhalf of the period considered. The main reason for this has been the considerable influx of EUStructural Funds since their reform in 1989. During the period between 2000 and 2006, transfersfrom the EU represented, on average, an estimated 48 per cent of all public investment in Greece(European Commission 2007). Public investment peaked in 2002, reaching 6 per cent of GDP(Psycharis 2008).

Whether this significant effort has paid off in terms of greater growth both at the national andat the regional level and of greater regional convergence remains unclear. Most previous studiesdealing with the impact of public policy in Greece have focused on the impact of publicinfrastructure on economic growth at national level. These studies have paid particular attentionto transportation and have generally indicated that public infrastructure investment has been animportant determinant of aggregate growth (Christodoulakis and Segoura 1993; Mamatzakis2007) and of the performance of private manufacturing in Greece (Rovolis and Spence 2002).

The geographical dimension of public investment has attracted, by contrast, virtually noattention. Yet, aggregate growth and regional convergence are not necessarily complementaryobjectives. Aggregate growth can often be achieved by generating greater territorial inequities,especially if it leads to the agglomeration of economic activity in core areas. Hence, the mainquestion of this paper is to estimate the contribution of public investment to regional economicgrowth, in order to determine whether any potential greater aggregate growth has been evenlydistributed across prefectures in the country or has been accomplished at the cost of increasingregional asymmetries. In order to do this, we use a new dataset which allows us to assess to whatextent different investment categories (i.e., transportation, education, health and social welfare,housing, etc.) affect regional economic growth and convergence in Greece. Our starting hypoth-esis is that the returns of public investment on economic growth matter, but depend on the typeof public investment under consideration. Different categories of public investment may havedifferent impacts on outputs, as they tend to pursue different aims that depend on the relation-ship with the territory (Moreno and López Bazo 2007). In addition to the different categories ofpublic investment, we will also consider the geographical dimension of public investment.Public investment in one region is bound to have a significant impact on neighbouring regions,generating a level of spatial dependence which has so been neglected in analyses of publicinvestment in Greece. In this paper we will use recent advances in spatial econometrics in orderto determine better the effects of public investment on regional growth in Greece.

3.2 Data sources and units of analysis

The analysis conducted in this paper rests on a new dataset of regional public investment inGreece. The variables in the dataset include all payments by different tiers of the Greekgovernment – payments by national government at ministerial level, as well as payments by theweaker regional, prefectural, and local tiers of government – channelled through the GreekPublic Investment Budget (PIB, also known as the Public Investment Programme). The PIB isa part of the Greek annual budget and requires parliamentary approval. It represents the mainmechanism for providing the Greek economy with different types of public ‘infrastructures’,encompassing also the Structural Funding from the EU.

The PIB, managed by the Ministry of Economics and Finance, started to operate in 1952(Law N.2212/52). Its establishment reflected a growing international trend towards putting agreater emphasis on infrastructure investment. The PIB includes expenditure on construction,machinery and physical infrastructure, as well as technical assistance explicitly related to these

5Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 6: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

works. In 1989, and as a result of the influence of the European Union Community SupportProgrammes, the PIB was divided into two parts: the first containing projects co-financed withthe European Union and the second including projects not eligible for structural assistance andconsequently financed only by national funds. Another influence of the EU structural assistanceis that since 1996 the PIB also encompasses investments in human capital (Law N.2601/98).

The dataset includes information on public capital investment for 51 prefectures over aperiod of 30 years, implying a total of 1,530 observations per variable. The informationincluded in the dataset contains only the 55 per cent of total public investment which, duringthe study period, could be allocated to a specific prefecture. The remaining 45 per cent couldnot be assigned to any specific region, and included national projects deemed to affect either theentire country or subsets of geographical areas other than prefectures. The ‘total’ public invest-ment used in the paper thus includes the sum of regionally identifiable public investmentexpenditures.

We use sectoral deflators for the different categories of infrastructure investment in order toobtain a measure of public investment at constant prices. All data is expressed in euros at 2000prices. Table 1 presents some descriptive statistics of the main variables used in the analysis.

The territorial units used in the analysis are the prefectures (in Greek, ‘nomos’). Greece isdivided into 51 prefectures, which correspond to level 3 of the Nomenclature of Territorial Unitsfor Statistics (NUTS) of EUROSTAT, the Statistical Office of the European Union. The averagesurface of a prefecture is 2,587 km2 (ranging from a minimum of 356 km2 to a maximum of5,461 km2). Prefectures have traditionally been the key spatial level for regional developmentpolicy. The regions, which, despite their still almost non-existent autonomy, today play a role inregional policy, were only created in 1986 and did not become fully functional until after 1997.

The population and wealth of the different prefectures is very unequal (see AppendixTable A1). Attiki, where the capital Athens is located, accounts for, with more than four millioninhabitants, 36.2 per cent of the total population of the country. Thessaloniki, with 1.1 million,represents 10.2 per cent of the total. These marked inequalities are also reflected in thegeography of production. Attiki and Thessaloniki jointly represent more than 59 per cent of thetotal GDP of Greece.

Table 1. Descriptive statistics of the initial database

Summary statistics

Variables Mean Minimum Maximum Std.deviation

Range Coefficient ofvariation (%)

GDP per capitaa 9,056.400 4,043.151 33,520.345 2,752.633 29,477.193 30.4Population density 71.533 10.326 1,039.049 129.630 1,028.723 181.2Total Public Inv 278.806 54.214 3,703.001 178.914 3,648.787 64.2Transport 35.963 0.000 3,185.876 103.534 3,185.876 287.9Productive 57.784 0.000 3,193.652 112.984 3,193.652 195.5Education 18.084 0.000 188.438 21.986 188.438 121.6Housing 2.885 0.000 139.733 8.832 139.733 306.1Health 9.455 0.000 246.032 18.955 246.032 200.5Decentralized 147.400 1.421 950.527 107.951 949.105 73.2Miscellaneous 10.024 0.000 266.072 20.795 266.072 207Percentage of votes NDb 42.6 19.2 57.7 6.1 38.5 14.3Percentage of votes PASOKb 44.5 24.7 65.9 6.6 41.2 14.8

Notes: Total number of observations 1,530 (30 years for 51 observations per year). a In euros at constant prices 2,000.b ND denotes New Democracy, the Liberal Party; and PASOK denotes the Socialist Party.

6 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 7: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Disparities in terms of GDP per capita are also significant. Voiotia and Attiki, the twowealthiest prefectures, have a GDP per capita which is respectively 3.3 and 2.75 times higherthan that of Ileia and Rodopi, the two poorest. Attiki also experienced one of the highest levelsof GDP per capita growth among Greek prefectures for the period 1996–2007, leading to afurther polarization of the country’s internal asymmetries.

4 Econometric specification and variables

In order to assess the impact of public investment across Greek prefectures during the period1978–2007, we adopt an econometric model based on the theoretical approach and the empiricalapplications described in Section 2. Our basic model is derived from the neoclassical b –convergence model proposed by Barro (1991), whereby the average regional growth rate duringany given political period – determined by the terms in power of different political parties – isa function of the relative wealth of each Greek prefecture and of the level of public investmentin each prefecture and in neighbouring prefectures. The model adopts the following form:

1 0

0

0 01 2 3T

Y

Ya Y PublInv WPubl

i t

i ti t i t

Tln ln,

,, ,

+⎛⎝⎜

⎞⎠⎟

= + ( ) + +β β β IInv x ut i i t i to⎡⎣ ⎤⎦ + +β4 0 0, ,

where Yi t, 0is the average GDP per head for region i at political period t0, PublInvi t, 0

is the publicinvestment for region i during political period t0 and WPublInvt i0

⎡⎣ ⎤⎦ is the public investment inneighbouring regions i during political period t0. We use a spatial econometric specification asa means to test for the occurrence of regional public investment externalities and to estimatetheir magnitude (López-Bazo et al. 2004). The specification of the regional public investmentinteraction is represented by a spatial weights matrix W. In our empirical specification, W is abinary matrix equal to 1 in the case of the k–nearest neighbouring regions, with k = 5, 7 and 9,and 0 otherwise. We use different weights matrices in order to check for the sensitivity of theresults. b1 represents the coefficient on the initial regional GDP per head. This coefficient allowsus to test for the presence of regional convergence in Greece. b2 denotes the coefficient on publicinvestment in each region, and b3 denotes the coefficient on public investment in neighbouringregions. b2 represents the internal returns to public investment, while b3 represents the externalreturns to public investment, capturing public investment externalities across prefectures. Inorder to minimize the risk that b3 captures effects other than ‘true’ public investment externali-ties, we also include a vector of regional specific characteristics xi t, 0

, representing some of thebasic structural features of each prefecture. b4 is the coefficient on these regional specificcharacteristics. ui t, 0

is the error term and a is the constant.The above empirical specification represents a spatial cross-regressive econometric model

examining the potential impact of regional and interregional public investment on regionaleconomic growth over different political periods. The political periods are determined by theparty in office following successive Greek elections. There are two main parties in Greece,which have alternated in governance since the restoration of democracy in 1974: PASOK (alsoknown as the Socialist Party) and New Democracy Party (also known as the Liberal Party).PASOK was the governing party between 1982–1989 1994–1999 and 2000–2004 while NewDemocracy Party was in office during the periods 1978–1981 1990–1993 and 2005–2007 (forthe date of the election, party in office, and political period, see Table 2). The political periodsnot only mark changes in the orientation of the government, but also important milestones inGreece’s European integration process: membership of the European Community in 1981, theMediterranean Integrated Programmes in 1985, the First Community Support Framework 1989–

7Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 8: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

1993, the Second Community Support Framework 1994–1999, entry into the European Mon-etary Union in 2000, and a large section of the Third Community Support Framework 2000–2006.

We also introduce spatial dependence among the observations for the Greek regions in eachpolitical period. Since the value of the public investment observed in each region is jointlydetermined with that of neighbouring regions, ignoring spatial dependence may result in biasedestimates. Spatial dependence in our empirical growth model is of the substantive type, as it islikely to be caused by technological and pecuniary externalities (Fingleton and López-Bazo2006). In addition, by introducing spatially lagged independent variables, we not only explorethe interactions among neighbouring regions, but also minimize their effect on the residuals(Rodríguez-Pose and Crescenzi 2008).

The analysis covers 357 observations, corresponding to 51 Greek prefectures or regions over7 political periods (t0+T) (Table 2). The limited time span of our political periods may produce,as convergence is a long-run process, biased results and misleading conclusions (Arbia et al.2005). As a means to minimize this problem we resort to panel data analysis, in order to considerboth geographical and temporal variation in growth. Panel data analysis has the additionaladvantage of increasing the degrees of freedom and reducing collinearity among explanatoryvariables, thus improving the efficiency of the econometric estimates (Hsiao 2003). This impliesthat an interregional externality is generated in a region and incorporated by other regions overseven political periods. Although in our specification, spatial dependence is a substantivephenomenon, we also test for spatial dependence as a nuisance using the Moran’s I test (Cliffand Ord 1981) adapted to the regression residuals.

In our econometric model, the error term is specified as ui t i t i t, ,0 0= + +ω ξ ε , where wi is the

unobservable regional specific effects, xt denotes time-dummies (political-period-dummies),and εi t, 0

is the disturbance term. This model allows for unobserved heterogeneity through theregional effect wi, capturing the combined effect of time-invariant regional omitted variables.Moreover, our model controls for all time-specific (political period-specific) spatial-invariantvariables through xt.

Our model thus includes both a spatial and a temporal dimension. The former dimensionpertains to a set of cross-regional units of observations, while the latter pertains to periodicobservations (based on political periods) of a set of variables characterizing those cross-regionalunits over a particular time-span (Rodríguez-Pose and Tselios 2009). The empirical model isestimated by fixed effects (FEs) in order to control for time-invariant characteristics. Thisestimator controls for the effects of the omitted variables that are peculiar to each region (NUTS3) and accommodates spatial heterogeneity through wi. It wipes out all the space-specific

Table 2. Political periods

Year ofelection

Date ofelection

Party inoffice

Politicalperiod

Length of a politicalperiod (years)

t0 t0+T

1977 20–Nov ND 1978–1981 4 11981 18–Oct PASOK 1982–1984 3 2 11985 02–Jun PASOK 1985–1989 5 3 21990 08–Apr ND 1990–1993 4 4 31993 10–Oct PASOK 1994–1996 3 5 41996 22–Sep PASOK 1997–1999 3 6 52000 09–Apr PASOK 2000–2003 4 7 62004 07–Mar ND 2004–2007 4 72007 16–Sept ND

Notes: ND: New Democracy, Liberal Party; PASOK: Socialist Party.

8 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 9: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

time-invariant variables, and also reduces the risk of obtaining biased estimation results (Baltagi2005). However, this reduction in bias comes at a significant cost, as it removes cross-sectionalvariation from the data, potentially affecting the efficiency of the parameter estimates (Higginsand Williamson 1999; Rodríguez-Pose and Tselios 2010). The higher the cross-sectional varia-tion, the lower the efficiency of the FEs estimator. Since the FEs estimator disregards persistenteffects when used alone, it can lead to misleading results when most of the variation iscross-sectional (Partridge 2005; Tselios 2009). We therefore calculate the within and betweenvariation from the data and when the cross-sectional variation is high, the model is alsoestimated by ordinary least squares (OLS). Pooled OLS will be consistent and efficient in casesof no individual heterogeneity. When heterogeneity exists, a trade-off between bias and preci-sion emerges. Bearing this in mind, FEs coefficients are interpreted as time-series effects (orshort/medium-run effects), as they reflect within-region time series variation, whereas thepooled OLS coefficients reflect long-run effects (Mairesse 1990; Durlauf and Quah 1999;Partridge 2005).

The suitability of the above estimators is checked using different specification tests. Thep-values of Breusch and Pagan’s (1980) Lagrange multiplier (LM) statistic test the validity ofthe pooled OLS models, while the p-values of Hausman’s (1978) statistic test the random effects(REs) estimator as an appropriate alternative to the FEs estimator.

Finally, if there is no great difference between the significance of the homoscedasticity andthe heteroscedasticity consistent covariance matrix estimator (White 1980), the determinants ofregional economic growth can be considered robust to the model specification about the errorterm, and for the sake of brevity, we do not report the robust standard errors. Our base model isestimated by FEs, with the Breusch and Pagan’s (1980) statistic showing whether the OLS is analternative to the FEs estimator and the Hausman’s (1978) statistic whether the REs estimatoris an alternative to the FEs estimator. All these models are calculated with and without timedummies (xt) in order to highlight the role of the time-specific (election-specific or political-period specific) spatial-invariant variables. If these variables are statistically significant, theiromission could bias the estimates in a typical time-series study (Baltagi 2005). However, as ouranalysis juggles political periods and not annual time-span, depending on the variation, themagnitude and the significance of the time-dummies, they could be replaced by a dummyvariable which takes the value of 1 if the governing party is New Democracy (for t = t0) and 0if the governing party is PASOK.

4.1 Independent variables

The precise independent variables included in the analysis are as follows:

4.1.1 Initial regional economic development ln ,Yi t0( )( )

The logarithm of the initial level of per capita GDP is introduced in the model because, first, thelevel of development of a prefecture may affect its capacity to absorb public investment and totransform it into economic growth and, second, to test for conditional b – convergence.

4.1.2 Regional and interregional public investment (PublInvi t, 0

and WPublInvt i0⎡⎣ ⎤⎦ , respectively)

Regional public investment is measured by (i) the total regional public investment expendi-ture and (ii) the per capita regional public investment expenditure. These variables are later

9Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 10: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

decomposed into the following types of regional public investment expenditures: (1) total publicinfrastructure expenditure, which includes transport infrastructure (roads and highways, bridges,harbours and maritime signalling, airports, railway communications, and urban transportation)and other types of infrastructure (agriculture, manufacture, tourism and culture, water supplyand sewage, extra works, specific infrastructures, such as stadia, related to the 2004 OlympicGames); (2) education and research public expenditure; (3) housing public expenditure; (4)health and social welfare public investment expenditure; (5) decentralized public investmentexpenditure; and (6) miscellaneous public investment expenditure. The same variables arecalculated for the neighbouring regions in order to capture the potential spillovers linked tointerregional public investment expenditure. Regional and interregional public investmentexpenditure enters the empirical specification in logarithms. Overall, it is expected that thegeographical location of a region and differences in public investment expenditure amongprefectures will play a major and positive role in explaining growth.

4.1.3 Control variables xi t, 0( )

Based on the review of the theoretical literature and on data availability, we identify thefollowing set of time-variant control variables:

1 Political power: We proxy political power using two variables. First, as in the case ofLambrinidis et al. (2005), the percentage share of votes in the region in favour of the partygoverning at the national level. The second political power variable is the difference in thepercentage share of votes in any given prefecture in favour of the governing party (PASOK orND) relative to the main opposition party. As we expect that “governments, irrespective oftheir ideological preferences, attempt to influence in their favour the outcome of a forthcom-ing election by adopting expansionary policies and increasing public expenditures in theperiod preceding an election, especially if the re-election prospects for the governing party areuncertain” (Lambrinidis et al. 2005, p. 1233), the coefficients of both variables representingpolitical power could be positive. The percentage share of votes in the region in favour in thegoverning party denotes the ‘absolute’ political power of the governing party relative to themain opposition party, while the difference of the percentage share of votes in a region infavour of the governing party denotes the ‘relative’ political power. The value of the lattervariable for a particular region can be negative in those cases where the percentage share ofvotes in that region in favour of the governing party is lower than the percentage share of votesin the same region in favour of the main opposition party. When considering the politicalpower variables, the number of observations is reduced to 306, because of missing data on thepercentage share of votes for t0 = 1 (1978–1981).

2 Population and population density: Population is a proxy for the size of regional markets andpopulation density is normally used in the literature in order to denote regional agglomera-tions. We expect the coefficient of both variables to be positive, because, large and denselypopulated regions will act as a magnet for economic activities (Krugman 1991).

3 Other controls (Source: Cambridge Econometrics database): We also control for additionaleconomic variables (see Tselios 2008; Rodríguez-Pose and Tselios 2009; Tselios 2009;Rodríguez-Pose and Tselios 2010). These include (i) regional gross value added (gva) invest-ment as a share of gva which is a proxy for capital growth; (ii) sectoral composition, measuredby the share of agricultural gva to total regional gva (base category), the share of industrialgva to total regional gva and the share of service-sector gva to total regional gva; (iii) thelocation quotient for the above sectors; and (iv) employment measured by the number ofemployees in the region.

10 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 11: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

The above control variables are introduced in our model to account for differences insteady-states values across economies, because the conditional b – convergence model encom-passes the structural differences among regional economies which converge to different steady-states (see Tselios 2009).

5 Regression results

The empirical analysis exploits the panel structure of the dataset for the 51 Greek prefecturesincluded in the analysis over the period 1978–2007 (over seven political periods). The analysis isdeveloped in two stages. First, we resort to a traditional neo-classical growth model whichexamines the impact of overall public investment on regional growth. Second, we propose aspatial cross-regressive economic model, capturing not only the impact of public investment aswell as its different components in each Greek prefecture on economic growth, but also thespillover effects related to the externalities generated by public investment in neighbouringregions.1

5.1 Impact of public investment on growth

Table 3 and 4 display the FEs and OLS regression results, respectively. The p-values of Breuschand Pagan’s LM test fail to reject the validity of the pooled OLS estimator (apart from Regression1). We can thus safely assume that the unobserved regional specific effects are uncorrelated withthe explanatory variables. Since both cross-sectional and time-series variation of the explanatoryvariables are high (see Appendix Table A2), the FEs coefficients can be interpreted as short/medium-run effects, and the pooled OLS coefficients as long-run effects. The p-values ofHausman’s test reject the GLS estimator as an appropriate alternative to the FEs estimator forRegressions 2–4, 6 and 8–12 and fail to reject it for Regressions 1, 5 and 7, showing the sensitivityof this test to the empirical specification. Overall, the theoretical interpretation of the estimators,the within and between variation in the data and the specification tests point to the FEs and OLSmodels as the most appropriate. Finally, as there is not much difference between the significanceof the homoscedasticity and the heteroscedasticity consistent covariance matrix estimator, for thesake of brevity, we do not report the robust standard errors.2

The results of the analysis point towards the presence of a strong positive associationbetween public investment per capita and regional growth across Greek prefectures in thelong-run (Table 4). But, the short-run impact is positive and statistically significant only once wecontrol for election-specific spatial-invariant variables (Table 3). Thus political period dummiesplay a significant role in the short-run effect of public investment per capita. The long-runconnection is, however, not reproduced when public investment per capita is replaced by theoverall level of public investment (Table 4: Regressions 3 and 4). These results are robust to theintroduction of the political control variables, as well as to controlling for population, populationdensity, regional gva, investment as a share of gva, sectoral composition and the locationquotient for the agricultural, industrial and service sectors.3

The political variables also display some interesting results. While, as in Lambrinidis et al.(2005), the impact of the percentage share of votes in the region in favour of the governing party

1 We have also calculated the impact of different types of public investments per capita without spatial externalities,but we do not report them for the sake of brevity. However, the results can be provided upon request.

2 These standard errors can be provided upon request.3 Due to the very high correlation between population, population density, employment and regional gva, we display

the regression results for population density only. The rest can be provided upon request.

11Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 12: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Tabl

e3.

Tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

(FE

ses

timat

or):

Dep

ende

ntva

riab

leis

grow

thof

GD

Ppe

rca

pita

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

(11)

(12)

Ln

ofG

DP

per

capi

ta0.

0932

-0.2

276

0.08

38-0

.225

20.

0996

-0.2

372

0.10

67-0

.233

7-0

.035

0-0

.220

4-0

.006

1-0

.253

4(0

.036

)**

(0.0

44)*

**(0

.036

)**

(0.0

44)*

**(0

.038

)***

(0.0

45)*

**(0

.038

)***

(0.0

45)*

**(0

.043

)(0

.051

)***

(0.0

46)

(0.0

51)*

**L

nof

tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.04

460.

0193

0.05

250.

0232

0.05

170.

0234

0.04

120.

0279

0.04

260.

0273

(0.0

17)*

**(0

.016

)(0

.021

)**

(0.0

17)

(0.0

21)*

*(0

.017

)(0

.020

)**

(0.0

18)

(0.0

20)*

*(0

.017

)L

nof

tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

re0.

0507

0.01

38(0

.016

)***

(0.0

16)

Perc

enta

gesh

are

ofvo

tes

inth

ere

gion

infa

vour

ofth

ego

vern

ing

part

y

0.00

000.

0014

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

Dif

fere

nce

inth

epe

rcen

tage

shar

eof

vote

sin

the

regi

onin

favo

urof

the

gove

rnin

gpa

rty

0.00

060.

0004

0.00

130.

0003

0.00

120.

0003

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)*

*(0

.001

)(0

.001

)**

(0.0

01)

Den

sity

0.88

47-0

.321

41.

3982

-1.2

219

(0.6

46)

(0.6

01)

(0.6

67)*

*(0

.677

)*In

vest

men

tas

ash

are

ofgv

a0.

3806

0.06

080.

3879

0.06

24(0

.111

)***

(0.1

26)

(0.1

17)*

**(0

.124

)Sh

are

ofag

ricu

ltura

lgv

ato

tota

lre

gion

algv

aB

ase

Bas

eca

tego

ryca

tego

rySh

are

ofin

dust

rial

gva

toto

tal

regi

onal

gva

0.08

570.

0573

(0.1

41)

(0.1

58)

Shar

eof

serv

ice–

sect

orgv

ato

tota

lre

gion

algv

a0.

5005

0.11

70(0

.111

)***

(0.1

81)

Loc

atio

nqu

otie

nt(a

gric

ultu

re)

0.01

87-0

.069

1(0

.021

)(0

.024

)***

Loc

atio

nqu

otie

nt(i

ndus

try)

0.07

14-0

.124

0(0

.045

)(0

.056

)**

Loc

atio

nqu

otie

nt(s

ervi

ces)

0.50

12-0

.395

5(0

.134

)***

(0.2

00)*

*Po

litic

al–p

erio

ddu

mm

ies

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

Con

stan

t-1

.334

42.

0128

-1.5

632

1.99

42-1

.491

51.

9500

-1.5

456

1.84

57-0

.618

11.

5896

-1.1

629

2.85

14(0

.327

)***

(0.4

45)*

**(0

.349

)***

(0.4

84)*

**(0

.409

)***

(0.4

71)*

**(0

.394

)***

(0.4

66)*

**(0

.419

)(0

.601

)***

(0.4

53)*

*(0

.705

)***

LM

test

4.91

0.23

0.09

1.96

0.60

2.24

0.52

2.01

0.12

1.25

0.10

1.76

(0.0

266)

(0.6

316)

(0.7

588)

(0.1

611)

(0.4

382)

(0.1

346)

(0.4

709)

(0.1

559)

(0.7

280)

(0.2

635)

(0.7

559)

(0.1

846)

Hau

sman

test

2.54

33.9

519

.48

24.7

11.

1531

.79

2.09

64.1

632

.45

47.9

225

.38

24.7

8(0

.280

3)(0

.000

0)(0

.000

1)(0

.001

7)(0

.765

3)(0

.000

0)(0

.553

2)(0

.000

0)(0

.000

0)(0

.000

0)(0

.001

3)(0

.024

7)

Obs

erva

tions

357

357

357

357

306

306

306

306

306

306

306

306

R-w

ithin

0.06

180.

3586

0.07

000.

3571

0.06

020.

4086

0.06

480.

4053

0.23

170.

4082

0.20

860.

4281

Not

es:

Stan

dard

erro

rsin

pare

nthe

ses;

***

p<

0.01

,**

p<

0.05

,*p

<0.

1.

12 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 13: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Tabl

e4.

Tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

(OL

Ses

timat

or):

Dep

ende

ntva

riab

leis

grow

thof

GD

Ppe

rca

pita

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

(11)

(12)

Ln

ofG

DP

per

capi

ta0.

0478

-0.0

244

0.05

21-0

.029

60.

0665

-0.0

104

0.06

50-0

.008

00.

0380

-0.0

467

0.03

59-0

.054

8(0

.020

)**

(0.0

20)

(0.0

22)*

*(0

.021

)(0

.021

)***

(0.0

21)

(0.0

21)*

**(0

.021

)(0

.025

)(0

.026

)*(0

.025

)(0

.026

)**

Ln

ofto

tal

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta0.

0609

0.04

300.

0581

0.04

380.

0573

0.04

320.

0357

0.03

330.

0416

0.03

20(0

.011

)***

(0.0

10)*

**(0

.012

)***

(0.0

11)*

**(0

.012

)***

(0.0

11)*

**(0

.013

)***

(0.0

11)*

**(0

.013

)***

(0.0

11)*

**L

nof

tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

re-0

.002

0-0

.005

4(0

.007

)(0

.006

)Pe

rcen

tage

shar

eof

vote

sin

the

regi

onin

favo

urof

the

gove

rnin

gpa

rty

-0.0

004

0.00

09(0

.001

)(0

.001

)

Dif

fere

nce

inth

epe

rcen

tage

shar

eof

vote

sin

the

regi

onin

favo

urof

the

gove

rnin

gpa

rty

0.00

030.

0004

0.00

050.

0003

0.00

070.

0003

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)

Den

sity

-0.0

341

-0.0

261

-0.0

131

-0.0

302

(0.0

43)

(0.0

39)

(0.0

44)

(0.0

39)

Inve

stm

ent

asa

shar

eof

gva

0.21

79-0

.001

70.

1942

-0.0

062

(0.0

77)*

**(0

.081

)(0

.080

)**

(0.0

81)

Shar

eof

agri

cultu

ral

gva

toto

tal

regi

onal

gva

Bas

eB

ase

cate

gory

cate

gory

Shar

eof

indu

stri

algv

ato

tota

lre

gion

algv

a0.

2176

0.28

70(0

.081

)***

(0.0

75)*

**Sh

are

ofse

rvic

e–se

ctor

gva

toto

tal

regi

onal

gva

0.28

860.

2338

(0.0

74)*

**(0

.076

)***

Loc

atio

nqu

otie

nt(a

gric

ultu

re)

0.04

19-0

.028

3(0

.017

)**

(0.0

21)

Loc

atio

nqu

otie

nt(i

ndus

try)

0.13

460.

0003

(0.0

41)*

**(0

.049

)L

ocat

ion

quot

ient

(ser

vice

s)0.

4496

-0.0

413

(0.1

26)*

**(0

.159

)Po

litic

al–p

erio

ddu

mm

ies

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

Con

stan

t-1

.124

5-0

.177

4-0

.371

90.

5056

-1.2

390

-0.3

721

-1.2

340

-0.4

463

-0.9

989

-0.1

848

-1.4

354

0.20

56(0

.221

)***

(0.2

36)

(0.1

97)*

(0.1

97)*

*(0

.248

)***

(0.2

46)

(0.2

48)*

**(0

.247

)*(0

.258

)***

(0.2

70)

(0.2

90)*

**(0

.396

)

Obs

erva

tions

357

357

357

357

306

306

306

306

306

306

306

306

R-s

quar

ed0.

1007

0.30

430.

0167

0.26

960.

0977

0.31

900.

0983

0.31

840.

1709

0.35

150.

1704

0.35

60

Not

es:

Stan

dard

erro

rsin

pare

nthe

ses;

***

p<

0.01

,**

p<

0.05

,*p

<0.

1.

13Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 14: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

on regional growth (‘absolute’political power) is not statistically significant in both the short- andthe long-run (Tables 3 and 4: Regressions 5 and 6), the impact of the difference of the percentageshare of votes in the region in favour of the governing party (‘relative’ political power) is positiveand statistically significant in the short-term once we add control variables (Regressions 9 and 11),but disappears when we control for political period dummies (see Regressions 10–12).4 Hence, itis not the overall share of the vote for the governing party which is translated into greater levelsof economic growth, but how big the gap between the governing and the main opposition party is,which presumably would allow the Greek national government to have a greater leeway ondecisions about public policy expenditure in those regions where it enjoys a greater ‘relative’political power. ‘Absolute’ political power seems to matter less, as the opposition may also havesubstantial support at regional level. However, as the standardized coefficients for the aboveregressions5 show, the influence of ‘relative’ political power on economic growth is trumped bythat of public investment expenditure per capita, meaning that, in the case of Greece, publicinvestment seems to have a higher impact on growth than political forces.

The coefficients of the logarithm of GDP per capita are sensitive to the empirical specifi-cation of the estimators (FEs or OLS), the inclusion of control variables and the inclusionof political-period dummies. The results therefore reject the hypothesis of conditionalb-convergence across Greek prefectures during the period of analysis.

A fundamental issue encountered in exploring the association between public investmentand growth is connected to the size of the units of analysis. Greek prefectures vary enormouslyin production and population (i.e., the prefectures of Attiki and Thessaloniki represent almost 60per cent of the total GDP and 40 per cent of the population). It is therefore legitimate to askwhether larger regions should carry more weight than smaller ones (Tselios et al. 2012). Sinceour goal is to see how regional economies work with each region viewed as a separate realizationof certain underlying economic processes, each region should be weighted the same (Firebaugh2003). In other words, we are interested in growth in GDP per capita, and not, particularly, ingrowth levels of GDP. Nevertheless, we have re-estimated the analysis using growth levels ofGDP, and the regression results underline the robustness of our results: total public investment(whether per capita or not) has a positive impact on growth of GDP levels which is stronger inthe long-run than in the short-run (Table 5).

The above findings are also robust to replacing political-period dummy variables with adummy variable which takes the value of 1 if the governing party is New Democracy (for t = t0)and 0 if the governing party is PASOK.6

5.2 Impact of different types of public investment and their externalities on growth

Taking Regressions 7 and 8 in Tables 3 and 4 as our benchmark, we proceed to examine theimpact of the different types of public investment expenditure per capita considered and theirexternalities by means of a spatial cross-regressive neoclassical growth model, putting greateremphasis on the transport part of regional public investments. This model captures the combinedeffect of (total and different types of) public investment in Greek prefectures and the spillovereffects related to the existence of externalities emanating from neighbouring regions. Table 6presents the FEs regression results (short-run effects) and Table 7 the pooled OLS regressionresults (long-run effects), with and without political-period dummies. These results are robust to

4 Even if control variables are included in Regressions 5 and 6, the coefficient of the ‘absolute’ political power is notstatistically significant in both FEs and OLS models. The results can be provided upon request.

5 The results can be provided upon request.6 These results can be provided upon request.

14 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 15: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Tabl

e5.

Tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

(FE

san

dO

LS

estim

ator

):D

epen

dent

vari

able

isgr

owth

ofG

DP

leve

l

FEs

OL

S

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

Ln

ofG

DP

0.10

24-0

.250

50.

0954

-0.2

519

0.01

410.

0043

-0.0

204

-0.0

266

(0.0

33)*

**(0

.045

)***

(0.0

33)*

**(0

.045

)***

(0.0

06)*

*(0

.006

)(0

.010

)*(0

.009

)***

Ln

ofto

tal

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta0.

0417

0.02

020.

0611

0.03

99(0

.020

)**

(0.0

17)

(0.0

13)*

**(0

.012

)***

Ln

ofto

tal

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

0.04

350.

0155

0.03

220.

0325

(0.0

20)*

*(0

.017

)(0

.013

)**

(0.0

11)*

**D

iffe

renc

ein

the

perc

enta

gesh

are

ofvo

tes

inth

ere

gion

infa

vour

ofth

ego

vern

ing

part

y

0.00

060.

0004

0.00

060.

0004

0.00

060.

0008

0.00

070.

0009

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)*

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)*

*

Polit

ical

–per

iod

dum

mie

sN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SC

onst

ant

-2.5

592

4.96

66-2

.640

54.

9814

-0.9

697

-0.4

529

-0.0

461

0.03

50(0

.676

)***

(0.9

47)*

**(0

.681

)***

(0.9

60)*

**(0

.248

)***

(0.2

33)*

(0.1

21)

(0.1

07)

LM

test

0.30

1.08

0.00

3.39

(0.5

840)

(0.2

982)

(0.9

553)

(0.0

656)

Hau

sman

test

8.23

18.7

917

.18

102.

85(0

.041

4)(0

.000

9)(0

.000

6)(0

.000

0)O

bser

vatio

ns30

630

630

630

630

630

630

630

6R

–with

in0.

0648

0.38

040.

0668

0.37

90R

–squ

ared

0.07

660.

2832

0.03

080.

2771

Not

es:

Stan

dard

erro

rsin

pare

nthe

ses;

***

p<

0.01

,**

p<

0.05

,*p

<0.

1.

15Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 16: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Tabl

e6.

Tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

and

bydi

ffer

ent

type

san

dsp

illov

ers

(FE

ses

timat

or):

Dep

ende

ntva

riab

leis

grow

thof

GD

Ppe

rca

pita

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

Ln

ofG

DP

per

capi

ta0.

0307

-0.2

271

0.04

08-0

.233

60.

0953

-0.2

383

-0.1

471

-0.2

422

-0.1

077

-0.2

499

(0.0

39)

(0.0

45)*

**(0

.039

)(0

.045

)***

(0.0

38)*

*(0

.047

)***

(0.0

43)*

**(0

.046

)***

(0.0

44)*

*(0

.047

)***

Ln

ofto

tal

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta0.

0499

0.02

54(0

.020

)**

(0.0

17)

W_L

nof

tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.24

750.

0648

(0.0

47)*

**(0

.046

)

Ln

ofto

tal

publ

icin

fras

truc

ture

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.00

320.

0019

0.00

66-0

.002

7(0

.007

)(0

.006

)(0

.007

)(0

.007

)

W_L

nof

tota

lpu

blic

infr

astr

uctu

reex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.06

350.

0368

0.07

700.

0289

(0.0

12)*

**(0

.016

)**

(0.0

14)*

**(0

.018

)

Ln

oftr

ansp

ort

publ

icin

fras

truc

ture

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.00

18-0

.000

20.

0010

-0.0

005

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

W_L

nof

tran

spor

tpu

blic

infr

astr

uctu

rein

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.00

780.

0015

0.00

530.

0005

(0.0

03)*

*(0

.003

)(0

.003

)(0

.003

)

Ln

ofot

her

type

sof

publ

icin

fras

truc

ture

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.00

280.

0058

0.00

790.

0014

(0.0

06)

(0.0

05)

(0.0

06)

(0.0

06)

W_L

nof

othe

rty

pes

ofpu

blic

infr

astr

uctu

reex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.01

670.

0197

0.03

870.

0048

(0.0

14)

(0.0

17)

(0.0

15)*

**(0

.018

)

Ln

ofed

ucat

ion

and

rese

arch

publ

icex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.00

430.

0030

0.00

410.

0030

(0.0

01)*

**(0

.001

)**

(0.0

01)*

**(0

.001

)**

W_L

nof

educ

atio

nan

dre

sear

chpu

blic

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.01

11-0

.000

40.

0120

0.00

01(0

.002

)***

(0.0

03)

(0.0

02)*

**(0

.003

)

Ln

ofho

usin

gpu

blic

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

-0.0

005

-0.0

018

-0.0

001

-0.0

018

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)*

*(0

.001

)(0

.001

)**

16 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 17: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

W_L

nof

hous

ing

publ

icex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta0.

0056

-0.0

032

0.00

60-0

.003

9(0

.001

)***

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)*

**(0

.003

)L

nof

heal

than

dso

cial

wel

fare

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

-0.0

005

-0.0

002

-0.0

006

-0.0

004

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

W_L

nof

heal

than

dso

cial

wel

fare

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

-0.0

041

-0.0

043

-0.0

043

-0.0

047

(0.0

02)

(0.0

03)

(0.0

03)

(0.0

03)*

Ln

ofde

cent

raliz

edpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.03

130.

0251

0.02

730.

0206

(0.0

20)

(0.0

19)

(0.0

21)

(0.0

19)

W_L

nof

dece

ntra

lized

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.09

450.

0522

0.08

260.

0458

(0.0

42)*

*(0

.046

)(0

.044

)*(0

.047

)

Ln

ofm

isce

llane

ous

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

-0.0

013

-0.0

008

-0.0

008

-0.0

008

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

W_L

nof

mis

cella

neou

spu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.00

850.

0084

0.00

980.

0083

(0.0

05)*

(0.0

05)

(0.0

05)*

(0.0

05)

Dif

fere

nce

ofth

epe

rcen

tage

shar

eof

vote

sin

the

regi

onin

favo

urof

the

gove

rnin

gpa

rty

0.00

110.

0005

0.00

140.

0005

0.00

110.

0004

0.00

130.

0006

0.00

110.

0005

(0.0

01)*

*(0

.001

)(0

.001

)**

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)*

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)*

*(0

.001

)(0

.001

)**

(0.0

01)

Polit

ical

–per

iod

dum

mie

sN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

LM

test

0.00

2.13

2.90

8.90

0.83

6.88

3.61

4.22

1.50

2.38

(0.9

611)

(0.1

445)

(0.0

886)

(0.0

028)

(0.3

634)

(0.0

087)

(0.0

574)

(0.0

399)

(0.2

208)

(0.1

232)

Hau

sman

test

21.6

160

.11

24.9

853

.00

17.1

131

.83

64.3

133

.92

138.

7263

.78

(0.0

002)

(0.0

000)

(0.0

001)

(0.0

000)

(0.0

089)

(0.0

004)

(0.0

000)

(0.0

129)

(0.0

000)

(0.0

000)

Con

stan

t-3

.917

30.

9567

-1.3

579

1.55

11-1

.222

21.

8936

-2.2

626

0.63

68-1

.866

81.

2275

(0.5

86)*

**(0

.782

)(0

.329

)***

(0.4

90)*

**(0

.351

)***

(0.5

12)*

**(0

.850

)***

(1.0

31)

(0.9

04)*

*(1

.007

)O

bser

vatio

ns30

630

630

630

630

630

630

630

630

630

6R

-squ

ared

0.15

770.

4101

0.14

800.

4127

0.11

160.

4075

0.34

560.

4586

0.30

900.

4523

Not

es:

Stan

dard

erro

rsin

pare

nthe

ses;

***

p<

0.01

,**

p<

0.05

,*p

<0.

1.

17Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 18: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Tabl

e7.

Tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

and

bydi

ffer

ent

type

san

dsp

illov

ers

(OL

Ses

timat

or):

Dep

ende

ntva

riab

leis

grow

thof

GD

Ppe

rca

pita

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

(5)

(6)

(7)

(8)

(9)

(10)

Ln

ofG

DP

per

capi

ta0.

0658

-0.0

053

0.03

19-0

.020

70.

0508

-0.0

181

-0.0

015

-0.0

125

0.00

37-0

.008

7(0

.021

)***

(0.0

22)

(0.0

24)

(0.0

23)

(0.0

23)*

*(0

.023

)(0

.025

)(0

.023

)(0

.024

)(0

.023

)L

nof

tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.04

780.

0417

(0.0

12)*

**(0

.011

)***

W_L

nof

tota

lpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.07

280.

0154

(0.0

25)*

**(0

.024

)

Ln

ofto

tal

publ

icin

fras

truc

ture

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

-0.0

002

-0.0

027

-0.0

027

-0.0

057

(0.0

04)

(0.0

04)

(0.0

05)

(0.0

05)

W_L

nof

tota

lpu

blic

infr

astr

uctu

reex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.03

090.

0093

0.01

560.

0141

(0.0

09)*

**(0

.010

)(0

.011

)(0

.012

)

Ln

oftr

ansp

ort

publ

icin

fras

truc

ture

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.00

190.

0014

0.00

170.

0013

(0.0

01)*

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

W_L

nof

tran

spor

tpu

blic

infr

astr

uctu

rein

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.00

720.

0015

0.00

260.

0019

(0.0

03)*

*(0

.003

)(0

.003

)(0

.003

)

Ln

ofot

her

type

sof

publ

icin

fras

truc

ture

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

-0.0

043

-0.0

037

-0.0

029

-0.0

056

(0.0

04)

(0.0

04)

(0.0

05)

(0.0

04)

W_L

nof

othe

rty

pes

ofpu

blic

infr

astr

uctu

reex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.00

160.

0005

-0.0

048

-0.0

047

(0.0

10)

(0.0

10)

(0.0

11)

(0.0

13)

Ln

ofed

ucat

ion

and

rese

arch

publ

icex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.00

200.

0005

0.00

200.

0006

(0.0

01)*

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)*

(0.0

01)

W_L

nof

educ

atio

nan

dre

sear

chpu

blic

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.00

94-0

.000

90.

0093

-0.0

004

(0.0

02)*

**(0

.003

)(0

.002

)***

(0.0

03)

Ln

ofho

usin

gpu

blic

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

-0.0

014

-0.0

025

-0.0

014

-0.0

026

(0.0

01)*

(0.0

01)*

**(0

.001

)*(0

.001

)***

18 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 19: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

W_L

nof

hous

ing

publ

icex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta0.

0045

-0.0

055

0.00

51-0

.005

1(0

.001

)***

(0.0

02)*

*(0

.001

)***

(0.0

02)*

*L

nof

heal

than

dso

cial

wel

fare

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.00

090.

0006

0.00

080.

0005

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

(0.0

01)

W_L

nof

heal

than

dso

cial

wel

fare

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

0.00

10-0

.001

20.

0012

-0.0

014

(0.0

03)

(0.0

03)

(0.0

03)

(0.0

03)

Ln

ofde

cent

raliz

edpu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.00

570.

0200

-0.0

009

0.01

41(0

.014

)(0

.013

)(0

.014

)(0

.013

)

W_L

nof

dece

ntra

lized

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

-0.0

717

-0.0

048

-0.0

557

0.01

19(0

.030

)**

(0.0

30)

(0.0

30)*

(0.0

31)

Ln

ofm

isce

llane

ous

publ

icin

vest

men

tex

pend

iture

per

capi

ta

-0.0

024

-0.0

011

-0.0

024

-0.0

009

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

(0.0

02)

W_L

nof

mis

cella

neou

spu

blic

inve

stm

ent

expe

nditu

repe

rca

pita

0.00

310.

0113

0.00

330.

0126

(0.0

04)

(0.0

05)*

*(0

.004

)(0

.005

)***

Dif

fere

nce

ofth

epe

rcen

tage

shar

eof

vote

sin

the

regi

onin

favo

urof

the

gove

rnin

gpa

rty

0.00

020.

0004

0.00

080.

0008

0.00

050.

0007

0.00

080.

0009

0.00

070.

0008

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)*

(0.0

00)*

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)

(0.0

00)*

(0.0

00)*

*(0

.000

)(0

.000

)*

Polit

ical

–per

iod

dum

mie

sN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

NO

YE

SN

OY

ES

Con

stan

t-2

.029

2-0

.645

2-0

.705

50.

2026

-0.4

703

0.29

200.

7751

-0.1

704

0.83

26-0

.160

1(0

.368

)***

(0.3

98)

(0.2

07)*

**(0

.224

)(0

.215

)**

(0.2

20)

(0.5

19)

(0.5

08)

(0.5

17)

(0.5

17)

Obs

erva

tions

306

306

306

306

306

306

306

306

306

306

R–s

quar

ed0.

1227

0.31

940.

0672

0.28

490.

0656

0.28

740.

1886

0.34

400.

1911

0.34

59

Not

es:

Stan

dard

erro

rsin

pare

nthe

ses;

***

p<

0.01

,**

p<

0.05

,*p

<0.

1.

19Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 20: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

the choice of the spatial weights matrix.7 The p-values of Breusch and Pagan’s LM test aresensitive to the empirical specification (they fail to reject the validity of the pooled OLSestimator in Regressions 1, 2, 5, 9 and 10, and reject it in Regressions 3, 4, 6, 7 and 8). Thep-values of Hausman’s test reject the generalized least squares (GLS) estimator as an appro-priate alternative to the FEs estimator in all regressions. Once again, the FEs and OLS estimatorsare considered as the most appropriate by the different tests.

The results of Tables 6 and 7 indicate that economic growth is affected in different ways bydifferent types of per capita public investment expenditure and that the spillovers of certaintypes of public investment – and mainly investment in transport infrastructure – is crucial forregional economic growth in Greece.

Both in the short- and in the long run, three types of public investment stand out as keydrivers of regional economic growth: education and research; public infrastructure; and housing.In the short run (Table 6, Regressions 7–10) education and research public expenditure percapita is always positively and significantly associated with regional growth. Prefectures with ahigher level of investment in education and research tend to perform better than prefectureswhere investment in human capital and research is less of a concern. Investment education andresearch also generates positive spillovers (Regressions 7 and 9), although the coefficients aresensitive to the introduction of political period dummies. Investment in public, mainly transport,infrastructure per capita has no significant direct effect – regions which benefit from a higherlevel of investment do not achieve higher levels of growth – but a discernible indirect effect viaspillovers: prefectures surrounded by other prefectures where public infrastructure is a toppriority (Regressions 3 and 4), and especially those which have invested heavily in transportinfrastructure (Regression 5), tend to grow faster in the short run. Investment in housing, bycontrast, has a negative association with regional growth, once political periods are controlledfor (Regressions 8 and 10).

In the longer run the results point in a similar direction. If we take into account theregressions which can be accepted according to the OLS specification tests (Table 7, Regres-sions 1, 2, 5, 9 and 10), education and research, public investment and housing again stand out.In the longer run education and research continue to yield significant positive results in terms ofeconomic growth and generate positive spillovers, although the effect is sensitive to the intro-duction of time dummies (Regressions 9 and 10). Public infrastructure investment not onlycontinues to generate considerable spillovers, but, in the longer-term, also leads to greatergrowth (Regressions 1 and 2), a result which is reproduced when transport infrastructureinvestment is taken into account (Regression 5). However, both for overall public infrastructureinvestment and for transport public infrastructure investment the dimension of the coefficientsfor the variables measuring externalities is also greater than that of direct public investment(Table 7, Regressions 1, 2 and 5). This implies that while both public investments internal andexternal to the region generate economic returns, it is often the case that the impact of growthis greatest through the aggregate investment in neighbouring prefectures than through specificlocalized investments in the region. Housing investment is again detrimental for regional growthand generates negative spillover effects (Regression 10).

The decomposition of public investment into its different categories does not alter theinfluence of ‘relative’ political power on economic growth. Greek prefectures where the differ-ence in the percentage share of votes between the governing party and the main opposition partyis greatest, tend to grow faster than those where the gap between the two main parties is smaller,but this effect disappears once we control for political period dummies in the FEs models

7 We use the k – nearest neighbours matrix and report the results for k = 7. The results for k = 5 and k = 9 are verysimilar and are omitted here for the sake of brevity. They are available from the authors upon request.

20 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 21: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

(Table 6). Finally, the regression results confirm the absence of conditional convergence in GDPper capita for Greek regions.

6 Conclusions

In this paper we have analysed the economic returns of public investment across Greek prefec-tures. The analysis deals with a topic which has attracted relatively little attention, despite theimportance awarded both by the Greek government and the EU to public investment as amechanism to promote greater economic growth and regional convergence. The paper has a seriesof novelties. The first one is the introduction of a unique and comprehensive dataset of publicinvestment which spans over three decades. The second is related to the distinction betweendifferent types of public investment per region, including transport infrastructure, education andresearch, housing, health and social welfare, and decentralized public investments. Finally, thepaper introduces the geographical dimension, by exploring the role of public investment exter-nalities on the economic growth of Greek prefectures, an area of research which have beenneglected by the literature until now.

The results of the analysis are very much in line with the international literature on the topic.While, on the one hand, we find that total public infrastructure expenditure per capita and, morespecifically, transport infrastructure investment, have a positive and significant impact onregional growth in Greece (Mas et al. 1996; Pereira and Roca-Sagalés 2003; Salinas-Jiménez2004; Pereira and Andraz 2006; de la Fuente 2008; Daniele 2009), the evidence of any effect onregional convergence is much more nuanced (Rodríguez-Pose and Fratesi 2004; Padovano 2007;Checherita et al. 2009; Lago-Peñas and Martínez-López 2009). There is no clear indication thatpublic investment has contributed to narrow the development gap across Greek prefectures. Thisimplies that either Greek development policy was either not territorially progressive enough orthat public investment may have been more efficient in more developed regions. The results thusreflect the growing consensus in the literature about the growth enhancing effect of publiccapital (Romp and de Haan 2007), but also about its limited potential to rein in processes ofterritorial polarization (Vickerman et al. 1999).

Different types of public investment also seem to have different impacts on economicgrowth. In particular, investment in education and research has yielded the greatest directreturns, while public and transport infrastructure investment has had a more indirect effect, viageographical spillovers.

The external returns to this type of investments have clearly outweighed internal ones. Thismeans that public (transport) infrastructure investment in one region tends to complementinvestment in other regions, making the influence of intervention felt well beyond the borders ofthe prefecture where it takes place.

Finally, some political variables, such as the difference in the percentage share of votesbetween the governing and the main opposition party exert a non-negligible influence on growthrates across Greek prefectures since the restoration of democracy, but this result is sensitive tothe introduction of political-period-specific spatial-invariant variables.

Our research has reached the conclusion that in a country such as Greece, where publicintervention is often considered to lead to spillage and wastage, public investment over the lastthree decades has had a moderately positive effect on regional economic growth, although itsimpact on reducing internal disparities has been somewhat more muted. The results also showthat in certain areas, such as transport infrastructure, the benefits not necessarily come fromdirect intervention in specific regions, but from the spillovers that are generated as a result ofmultiple types of public intervention across the country. However, the results also raise a numberof interesting questions regarding the potential equity, efficiency, redistributive and political

21Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 22: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

effects of the allocation of public investment in Greece. Only further research on these issueswill allow us to determine how the returns of public investment can be maximized.

Appendix

Table A1. Selected demographic and economic indicators for the NUTS 3 regions of Greece

Code Name Population Surface Population Density GDP per capita

2006 2006 2006

NUTS 3 Inhabitants km2 Inh./km2 R PPS € GR = 100 R EU 27 = 100

GR111 Evros 148,800 4,242 35.1 40 15,700 71 29 67GR112 Xanthi 106,400 1,793 59.3 16 14,400 65 39 61GR113 Rodopi 111,200 2,543 43.7 30 11,500 52 50 49GR114 Drama 100,400 3,468 29 44 13,600 61 44 58GR115 Kavala 140,100 2,111 66.4 12 15,900 72 27 67GR121 Imathia 144,100 1,701 84.7 7 15,200 68 36 64GR122 Thessaloniki 1,395,000 3,683 309.4 2 20,000 90 9 85GR123 Kilkis 86,200 2,519 34.2 41 19,400 87 14 82GR124 Pella 145,100 2,506 57.9 17 14,100 64 41 60GR125 Pieria 128,200 1,516 84.6 8 13,700 62 43 58GR126 Serres 188,400 3,968 47.5 27 12,200 55 48 52GR127 Chalkidiki 100,200 3,254 30.8 43 17,500 79 21 74GR131 Grevena 31,400 2,291 13.7 50 17,100 77 23 72GR132 Kastoria 53,700 1,720 31.2 42 15,700 71 29 67GR133 Kozani 154,300 3,516 43.9 29 19,800 89 10 84GR134 Florina 54,200 1,924 28.2 46 15,500 70 32 66GR141 Karditsa 116,200 2,636 44.1 28 11,900 54 49 50GR142 Larisa 285,600 5,381 53.1 23 16,500 74 24 70GR143 Magnisia 20,400 2,636 77.4 9 19,600 88 12 83GR144 Trikala 130,700 3,384 38.6 37 13,400 60 45 57GR211 Arta 7,100 1,662 42.7 32 13,200 59 46 56GR212 Thesprotia 42,700 1,515 28.2 45 16,100 73 26 68GR213 Ioannina 179,100 4,990 35.9 39 18,700 84 16 79GR214 Preveza 57,300 1,036 55.3 19 15,400 69 33 65GR221 Zakynthos 40,300 406 99.3 6 21,800 98 5 92GR222 Kerkyra 126,800 641 197.8 3 15,900 72 27 67GR223 Kefallinia 3,800 904 42 34 19,400 87 14 82GR224 Lefkada 22,300 356 62.6 15 15,300 69 35 65GR231 Aitoloakarnania 217,900 5,461 39.9 36 13,100 59 47 56GR232 Achaia 340,200 3,271 104 5 16,500 74 24 70GR233 Ileia 179,800 2,618 68.7 11 10,900 49 51 46GR241 Voiotia 125,400 2,952 42.5 33 36,600 165 1 155GR242 Evvoia 206,600 4,167 49.6 24 18,200 82 18 77GR243 Evrytania 19,600 1,869 10.5 51 14,300 64 40 61GR244 Fthiotida 166,500 4,441 37.5 38 18,300 82 17 78GR245 Fokida 37,700 2,120 17.8 49 15,700 71 29 67GR251 Argolida 102,500 2,154 47.6 26 17,200 77 22 73GR252 Arkadia 88,400 4,419 20 48 21,300 96 7 90GR253 Korinthia 14,600 2,290 63.8 13 23,900 108 4 101GR254 Lakonia 92,900 3,636 25.6 47 13,900 63 42 59GR255 Messinia 164,300 2,991 54.9 20 14,500 65 38 61GR300 Attiki 4,046,900 3,808 1.062.70 1 30,500 137 2 129GR411 Lesvos 106,200 2,154 49.3 25 15,100 68 37 64GR412 Samos 42,700 778 54.9 21 15,400 69 33 65GR413 Chios 5,200 904 57.5 18 17,900 81 19 76GR421 Dodekanisos 194,700 2,714 71.7 10 21,700 98 6 92GR422 Kyklades 110,800 2,572 43.1 31 24,600 111 3 104GR431 Irakleio 29,900 2,641 113.2 4 19,800 89 10 84GR432 Lasithi 75,400 1,823 41.4 35 20,800 94 8 88GR433 Rethymni 80,600 1,496 53.9 22 17,800 80 20 75GR434 Chania 150,300 2,376 63.3 14 19,500 88 13 83

GR Greece 11,192,600 131,957 84.8 22,200 100 94

22 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 23: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Table A2. Descriptive statistics of the transformed database

Variable Mean Std. Dev. Min Max Observations

Growth of GDP per capita overall 0.067823 0.0948181 -0.1755181 0.456404 N = 357between 0.0342307 0.0019933 0.1760615 N = 51within 0.0885352 -0.1801079 0.421213 T = 7

Ln of GDP per capita overall 9.096925 0.2418485 8.638805 10.35576 N = 357between 0.1957685 8.791503 9.945979 N = 51within 0.1442614 8.679303 9.665029 T = 7

Ln of total public investmentexpenditure per capita

overall 12.43332 0.4519743 11.35308 13.79646 N = 357between 0.3374544 11.74684 13.33416 N = 51within 0.3038495 11.60626 13.44716 T = 7

Ln of total public investmentexpenditure per capita of theneighbouring regions

overall 12.41022 0.2452241 11.70031 13.04608 N = 357between 0.1609957 12.10848 12.76563 N = 51within 0.1861508 11.82592 12.89375 T = 7

Ln of total public investmentexpenditure

overall 17.13069 0.7890384 15.43434 21.57098 N = 357between 0.7278346 15.93656 20.47478 N = 51within 0.3190086 16.2643 18.22688 T = 7

Percentage share of votes in theregion in favour of thegoverning party

overall 45.32539 5.863099 30.42 65.9 N = 306between 3.933326 37.8841 57.00155 n = 51within 4.377042 20.55675 64.4152 T = 6

Difference in the percentageshare of votes in the region infavour of the governing party

overall 3.34771 11.28558 -31.72549 46.7 N = 306between 6.788575 -13.13485 24.10859 n = 51within 9.057317 -52.48637 37.11487 T = 6

Population overall 201.9408 501.5664 19.45 3,905.475 N = 357between 504.606 21.64643 3,604.046 N = 51within 35.11547 -174.3388 503.3697 T = 7

Density overall 0.0716859 0.1301283 0.0104066 1.025597 N = 357between 0.1308824 0.0117607 0.9464407 N = 51within 0.0095865 -0.027127 0.1508427 T = 7

Regional gross value added (gva) overall 1,851.878 5,323.196 110.945 56,110.74 N = 306between 5,206.049 159.9679 37,101.33 N = 51within 1,295.293 -6,287.335 20,861.29 T = 6

Employment overall 77.99757 204.4363 0 1,829.5 N = 357between 203.1201 6.040476 1,452.343 N = 51within 35.0968 -192.012 455.1547 T = 7

Investment as a share of gva overall 0.2564266 0.0706925 0.1449932 0.4436591 N = 306between 0.0466981 0.1787531 0.3505835 N = 51within 0.0534085 0.193149 0.4404795 T = 6

Share of agricultural gva to totalregional gva

overall 0.1634259 0.0812845 0.0061129 0.3854895 N = 306between 0.0681644 0.0101267 0.3063645 N = 51within 0.0451326 0.0564208 0.3233061 T = 6

Share of industrial gva to totalregional gva

overall 0.2118924 0.1115079 0.0564368 0.6709269 N = 306between 0.1025841 0.0816602 0.6235168 N = 51within 0.0456401 0.0762582 0.392866 T = 6

Share of service–sector gva tototal regional gva

overall 0.6246818 0.1185916 0.2571158 0.8914089 N = 306between 0.1027077 0.2878322 0.8481105 N = 51within 0.0607293 0.4463109 0.7609797 T = 6

Location quotient (agriculture) overall 1.799752 0.8304992 0.0787967 4.096764 N = 306between 0.7574971 0.1079048 3.403411 N = 51within 0.3540249 0.8172568 3.214066 T = 6

Location quotient (industry) overall 0.9672284 0.5077056 0.2674293 3.127595 N = 306between 0.469741 0.3742122 2.853596 N = 51within 0.2018062 0.3822788 1.833371 T = 6

Location quotient (services) overall 0.9052145 0.1612705 0.3675106 1.282515 N = 306between 00.1487658 0.4174971 1.229345 N = 51within 0.0651131 0.6267361 1.054203 T = 6

Notes: Columns ‘minimum’ and ‘maximum’ present, respectively, the minimum and maximum values of x1T for the ‘overall’ line,xi for the ‘between’ line and x x xit i− + for the ‘within’ line (Fávero and Belfiore 2011).

23Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 24: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

References

Arbia G, Elhorst PJ, Piras G (2005) Serial and spatial dependence in the growth process of EU regions. Paper preparedfor Workshop on Spatial Econometrics, Kiel Institute for World Economics, Kiel, Germany, 8–9 April.

Aschauer DA (1989a) Does public capital crowd out private capital? Journal of Monetary Economics 24: 171–188

Aschauer DA (1989b) Is public expenditure productive? Journal of Monetary Economics 23: 177–200Aschauer DA (1989c) Public investment and productivity growth in the group of seven. Federal Reserve Bank of

Chicago, Economic Perspectives 13: 17–25Aschauer DA (1990) Why is infrastructure Important? In: Munnell AH (ed) Is there a shortfall in public capital

investment? Federal Reserve Bank of Boston, Boston, MABaltagi BH (2005) Econometric analysis of panel data. John Wiley, ChichesterBarro J (1990) Government spending in a simple model of endogeneous growth. The Journal of Political Economy 98:

S103–S125Barro J (1991) Economic growth in a cross-section of countries. Quarterly Journal of Economics 106: 407–443Berndt ER, Hansson B (1992) Measuring the contribution of public infrastructure capital in Sweden. The Scandinavian

Journal of Economics 94: S151–S168Breusch TS, Pagan AR(1980) The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics.

Review of Economic Studies 47: 239–253Cadot O, Roller L–H, Stephan A (2006) Contribution to productivity or pork barrel? The two faces of infrastructure

investment. Journal of Public Economics 90: 1133–1153Cappelen A, Fulvio C, Jan F, Bart V (2003) The impact of EU regional support on growth and convergence in the

European Union. Journal of Common Market Studies 41: 621–644Castells A, Solé-Ollé A (2005) The regional allocation of infrastructure investment: The role of equity, efficiency and

political factors. European Economic Review 49: 1165–1205Checherita C, Nickel C, Rother P (2009) The role of fiscal transfers for regional economic convergence in Europe.

Working Paper Series. European Central Bank, Frankfurt am MainChristodoulakis N, Segoura I (1993) Inadequate infrastructure and rising cost: The decline of Greek manufacturing.

Discussion Paper 94–01, Department of International and European Economic Studies. Athens University ofEconomics and Business, Athens

Cliff AD, Ord JK (1981) Spatial processes: Models and applications. Pion, Londonde la Fuente A (2008) Inversión en infraestructuras, crecimiento y convergencia regional. Colección Estudios Económi-

cos 20–08. FEDEA, MadridDaniele V (2009) Regional convergence and public spending in Italy: Is there a correlation? MPRA Paper 14344,

University Library of Munich, GermanyDurlauf SN, Quah DT (1999) The new empirics of economic growth. In: Taylor JB, Woodford M (eds) Handbook of

macroeconomics, vol 1A. Elsevier, AmsterdamEstache A (2006) Infrastructure: A survey of recent and upcoming issues. The World Bank, Washington, DCEuropean Commission (2007) Growing regions, growing Europe: Fourth report on economic and social cohesion.

Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, LuxembourgEvans P, Karras G (1994) Are government activities productive? Evidence from a panel of US states. The Review of

Economics and Statistics 76: 1–11Fávero LP, Belfiore P (2011) Cash flow, earnings ratio and stock returns in emerging global regions: Evidence from

longitudinal data. Global Economy and Finance Journal 4: 32–43Fingleton B, López–Bazo E (2006) Empirical growth models with spatial effects. Papers in Regional Science 85:

177–198Firebaugh G (2003) The new geography of global income inequality. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MAGarcía–Milá T, McGuire TJ (1992) The contribution of publicly provided inputs to states’ economies. Regional Science

and Urban Economics 22: 229–241García–Milá T, McGuire TJ, Porter RH (1996) The effect of public capital in state-level production functions Recon-

sidered. The Review of Economics and Statistics 78: 177–180Golden MA, Picci L (2008) Pork-barrel politics in postwar Italy 1953–94. American Journal of Political Science 52:

268–289Hausman JA (1978) Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica 46: 1251–1271Higgins M, Williamson J (1999) Explaining inequality the world round: Cohort size, Kuznets curves, and openness.

NBER Working Paper No. 7224. National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MAHirschman AO (1958) The strategy of economic development. Yale University Press, New Haven, CTHoltz-Eakin D (1994) Public-sector capital and the productivity puzzle. The Review of Economics and Statistics 76:

12–21

24 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 25: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Holtz-Eakin D, Schwartz AE (1995) Spatial productivity spillovers from public infrastructure: Evidence from statehighways. International Tax and Public Finance 2: 459–468

Hsiao C (2003) Analysis of panel data. Cambridge University Press, CambridgeHulten CR, Schwab RM (1991) Public capital formation and the growth of regional manufacturing industries. National

Tax Journal 44: 121–134Johansson E (2003) Intergovernmental grants as a tactical instrument: Empirical evidence from Swedish municipalities.

Journal of Public Economics 87: 883–915Kamps C (2005) Is there a lack of public capital in the European Union? EIB Papers 10: 72–93Kemmerling A, Stephan A (2008) The politico-economic determinants and productivity effects of regional transport

investment in Europe. EIB Papers 13: 36–61Krugman P (1991) Increasing returns and economic geography. Journal of Political Economy 99: 483–499Krugman P (2005) Is fiscal policy poised for a comeback. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 21: 515–523Lago-Peñas S, Martínez-López D (2009) Convergence and public investment: Regional policies revisited. In: Stierle-

von Schutz U, Stierle MH, Jennings Jr FB, Kuah A (eds) Regional economic policy in Europe: New challenges fortheory, empirics and policy. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

Lambrinidis M, Psycharis Y, Rovolis A (2005) Regional allocation of public infrastructure investment: The case ofGreece. Regional Studies 39: 1231–1244

López–Bazo E, Vayà E, Artís M (2004) Regional externalities and growth: Evidence from European regions. Journalof Regional Science 44: 43–73

Mairesse J (1990) Time-series and cross-sectional estimates on panel data: Why are they different and why they shouldbe equal. In: Hartog J, Ridder G, Theeuwes J (eds) Panel data and labor market studies. North Holland, New York

Mamatzakis EC (2007) EU infrastructure investment and productivity in Greek manufacturing. Journal of PolicyModeling 29: 335–344

Mas M, Maudos J, Perez FJ, Uriel E (1996) Infrastructures and productivity in the Spanish regions. Regional Studies 30:641–649

Mikelbank BA, Jackson RW (2000) The role of space in public capital research. International Regional Science Review23: 235–258

Moreno R, López–Bazo E (2007) Returns to local and transport infrastructure under regional spillovers. InternationalRegional Science Review 30: 47–71

Munnell AH (1990a) Why has productivity growth declined? Productivity and public investment. New EnglandEconomic Review January/February: 3–22

Munnell AH (1990b) How does public infrastructure affect regional economic performance? New England EconomicReview September: 11–32

Munnell AH (1992) Infrastructure investment and productivity growth. Journal of Economic Perspectives 6:189–198

Musgrave RA (1959) The theory of public finance: A study in public economy. McGraw–Hill, New YorkNadiri MI, Mamuneas TP (1994) The effects of public infrastructure and R & D capital on the cost structure and

performance of US manufacturing industries. The Review of Economics and Statistics 76: 22–37Oates WE (1972) Fiscal Federalism. Harcourt Brace Jovanovich, New YorkOttaviano GIP (2008) Infrastructure and economic geography: An overview of theory and evidence. EIB Papers 13:

8–35Padovano F (2007) The politics and economics of regional transfers: Decentralization, interregional redistribution and

income convergence. Edward Elgar, CheltenhamPartridge MD (2005) Does income distribution affect US state economic growth? Journal of Regional Science 45:

363–394Pereira AM, Andraz JM (2006) Public investment in transportation infrastructures and regional asymmetries in Portugal.

Annals of Regional Science 40: 803–817Pereira AM, Roca-Sagalés O (2003) Spillover effects of public capital formation: Evidence from the Spanish regions.

Journal of Urban Economics 53: 238–256Psycharis Y (2008) Public spending patterns: The regional allocation of public investment in Greece by political period.

GreeSE Paper No 14, Hellenic Observatory Papers on Greece and Southeast Europe, AthensPuigcerver-Peñalver M-C (2007) The impact of structural funds policy on European regions’ growth: A theoretical and

empirical approach. The European Journal of Comparative Economics 4: 179–208Rodríguez-Pose A, Crescenzi R (2008) R&D, spillovers, innovation systems and the genesis of regional growth in

Europe. Regional Studies 42: 51–67Rodríguez-Pose A, Fratesi U (2004) Between development and social policies: The impact of European Structural Funds

in objective 1 regions. Regional Studies 38: 97–113Rodríguez-Pose A, Tselios V (2009) Education and income inequality in the regions of the European Union. Journal of

Regional Science 49: 411–437

25Public investment and regional growth in Greece

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.

Page 26: Public investment and regional growth and convergence: Evidence from Greece

Rodríguez-Pose A, Tselios V (2010) Inequalities in income and education and regional economic growth in WesternEurope. The Annals of Regional Science 44: 349–375

Romp W, de Haan J (2007) Public capital and economic growth: A critical survey. Perspektiven der Wirtschaftspolitik8: 6–52

Rovolis A, Spence N (2002) Promoting regional economic growth in Greece by investing in public infrastructure.Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 20: 393–419

Salinas-Jiménez MDM (2004) Public infrastructure and private productivity in the Spanish regions. Journal of PolicyModeling 26: 47–64

Solé-Ollé A, Sorribas-Navarro P (2008) The effects of partisan alignment on the allocation of intergovernmentaltransfers: Differences-in-differences estimates for Spain. Journal of Public Economics 92: 2302–2319

Solow RM (1956) A contribution to the theory of economic growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 70: 65–94Solow RM (2005) Rethinking fiscal policy. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 21: 509–514Sturm JE, de Haan J (1995) Is public expenditure really productive? New evidence for the USA and the Netherlands.

Economic Modelling 12: 60–72Tselios V (2008) Income and educational inequalities in the regions of the European Union: Geographical spillovers

under welfare state restrictions. Papers in Regional Science 87: 403–431Tselios V (2009) Growth and convergence in income per capita and income inequality in the regions of the EU. Spatial

Economic Analysis 4: 347–370Tselios V, Rodríguez-Pose A, Pike A, Tomaney J, Torrisi G (2012) Income inequality, decentralisation and regional

development in Western Europe. Environment and Planning A forthcoming. doi:10.1068/a44334Välilä T, Kozluk T, Mehrotra A (2005) Roads on a downhill? Trends in EU infrastructure investment. EIB Papers 10:

18–39Vickerman R, Spiekermann K, Wegener M (1999) Accessibility and economic development in Europe. Regional Studies

33: 1–15White H (1980) A heteroskedasticity consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity.

Econometrica 48: 817–838Yamano N, Ohkawara T (2000) The regional allocation of public investment: Efficiency or equity? Journal of Regional

Science 40: 205–229

26 A. Rodríguez-Pose et al.

Papers in Regional Science, Volume •• Number •• •• 2012.