policy review - december 2011 & january 2012, no. 170

Upload: hoover-institution

Post on 06-Apr-2018

215 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    1/93

    ELECTION 2012 : AN UNUSUALLY CLEARPOLICY CHOICE

    JAY COST

    THE PRIVATE-SECTOR PENSION PREDICAMENT

    CHARLES BLAHOUS

    CHINA: BIG CHANGES COMING SOON

    HENRY S. ROWEN

    THE SORDID ORIGIN OF HATE-SPEECH LAWS

    JACOB MCHANGAMA

    ALSO: ESSAYS AND REVIEWS BY

    JAMES W. CEASER, PETER BERKOWITZ,MARY EBERSTADT, DAVID R. HENDERSON,

    HENRIK BERING

    December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170, $6.00

    POLICYReview

    A Publ icat ion of the Hoover Inst itut ionstanford un ivers ity

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    2/93

    POLICYReviewDECEMBER 2011 & JANUARY 2012, No. 170

    Features

    3 ELECTION 2012: AN UNUSUALLY CLEAR POLICY CHOICE

    Nationalism through commerce versus egalitarianism through

    redistribution

    Jay Cost

    15 THE PRIVATE-SECTOR PENSION PREDICAMENT

    A systemic underfunding that could leave taxpayers on the hook

    Charles Blahous

    35 CHINA: BIG CHANGES COMING SOON

    Economic growth and political upheaval

    Henry S. Rowen

    45 THE SORDID ORIGIN OF HATE-SPEECH LAWS

    A tenacious Soviet legacy

    Jacob Mchangama

    59 NO THANKS TO GRATITUDE

    Struggling to keep national memory and appreciation alive

    James W. Ceaser

    Books

    75 GORDON WOODS AMERICAPeter Berkowitz on The Idea of America: Reflections on the Birth of the

    United States by Gordon Wood

    79 WITNESS TO LIFE

    Mary Eberstadt on A Point in Time: The Search for Redemption in this

    Life and the Next by David Horowitz

    83 WHEN ECONOMICS WAS YOUNG

    David R. Henderson on Keynes Hayek: The Clash that Defined ModernEconomics by Nicholas Wapshott

    88 FIGHT BY FLIGHT

    Henrik Bering on The Age of Airpower by Martin van Creveld

    A Publ i cat i o n o f th e Ho o ver I nst i tut i o nstanfo rd uni vers i ty

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    3/93

    PO

    LICYReview

    Policy Review (issn 0146-5945) is published bimonthly by the

    Hoover Institution, Stanford University. For more information,

    write: The Hoover Institution, Stanford University, Stanford ca

    94305-6010. Or visit www.hoover.org. Periodicals postage paid at

    Washington dc and additional mailing offices. POSTMASTER:

    Send address changes to Policy Review, Subscription Fulfillment,

    P.O. Box 37005 , Chicago, il 6 0 63 7 - 00 0 5 . The opinions

    expressed in Policy Review are those of the authors and do not nec-

    essarily reflect the views of the Hoover Institution, Stanford

    University, or their supporters.

    Ed i to r i al and bus i ness o ff i ces : Policy Review,

    21 Dupont Circle nw , Suite 310, Washington, d c 20036.

    Telephone: 202-466-3121. Email: [email protected].

    Website: www.policyreview.org.

    Subscription information: For new orders, call or write the

    subscriptions department at Policy Review, Subscription Fulfillment,

    P.O. Box 37005, Chicago, il 60637. Order by phone Monday

    through Friday, 8 a.m. to 5 p.m. Central Time, by calling (773)

    753-3347, or toll-free in the U.S. and Canada by calling (877)

    705-1878. For questions about existing orders please call 1-800-

    935-2882. Single back issues may be purchased at the cover price

    of$6 by calling 1-800-935-2882. Subscription rates: $36 peryear. Add $10 per year for foreign delivery. Copyright 2011 by the

    Board of Trustees of the Leland Stanford Junior University.

    December 2011 & January 20 12, No. 170

    Editor

    Tod Lindberg

    Research Fellow, Hoover Institution

    Consulting EditorMary Eberstadt

    Research Fellow, Hoover Institution

    Managing Editor

    Liam Julian

    Research Fellow, Hoover Institution

    Office Manager

    Sharon Ragland

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    4/93

    T

    he presidential election of2012 is shaping up to

    be an epic contest. It is uncommon for an incumbent presi-

    dent to be considered an underdog, yet as of this writingPresident Barack Obamas odds of winning reelection,

    according to the Intrade prediction market, stand at less

    than 50 percent. An endangered incumbent always makes for a fascinating

    political dynamic, one that will be compounded by the enormously high

    stakes of the upcoming battle. With the unemployment rate stuck at near

    nine percent and the Democrats new health entitlement set to go into effect

    relatively soon, the winner of2012 will have unusual power to set

    American domestic policy for the rest of the decade.

    But 2012 is shaping up to represent much more than even all this. It is a

    very rare event in American electoral politics that the country is faced with

    such a stark choice between two competing visions for the governments role

    in the society. Using a strict standard, there have really been only two such

    Election 2012:

    An Unusually ClearPolicy Choice

    ByJay Cost

    Jay Cost is a staff writer for the Weekly Standard and the author of SpoiledRotten (HarperCollins), a revisionist history of the Democratic Party, due out in

    May2012

    . A graduate of the University of Virginia and University of Chicago,he currently resides in Pennsylvania.

    December 2011 & January 2012 3 Policy Review

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    5/93

    4 Policy Review

    elections, those in 1832 and 1896. In other cycles, nonideological issues or

    national concerns ultimately kept the country from focusing on the ideologi-

    cal contrasts between the two parties. For instance, the election of1800 was

    fought in part over large differences in economic policies, but much of it hadto do with foreign affairs and extreme ad hominem attacks. The election of

    1936 was certainly consequential for the long-term political economy, but

    the substantial rebound from the depths of the Great Depression gave

    Franklin Roosevelt an easy valence issue to campaign on. Even the

    Election of1860 unquestionably the most important in the nations his-

    tory was confused by the presence of four candidates, each offering dif-

    ferent approaches to the slavery issue and ensuring that Lincoln could not

    claim a popular mandate.So, it is an extremely unusual event in the nations public life that the peo-

    ple are posed with such a straightforward question of ideology 1832,

    1896, and now perhaps 2012. Interestingly, the broad ideological contours

    of the 2012 contest resemble those prior contests. On the one side is a

    nationalist coalition dedicated to advancing the public interest by sponsoring

    American commerce. On the other side is an egalitarian faction that believes

    that those pro-business policies undermined the republican character of the

    government, and instead offers proposals to redistribute political power, eco-nomic resources, or both.

    The divisions roots

    The idea of a strong national government to facilitate American

    commerce and industry is as old as the nation itself. Frustrated by

    the experiences of the American Revolution, where runaway infla-tion, lack of pay for soldiers, and poor infrastructure to move men and

    materiel hampered the war effort, American nationalists were downright

    appalled by the crackup in society during the 1780s under the measly

    Articles of Confederation. Leading nationalists like Alexander Hamilton,

    John Jay, James Madison, and George Washington were prime movers in

    organizing the Constitutional Convention, where they pushed for a robust

    national government capable of solving big problems.

    One of the first articulations of this nationalist philosophy can be found

    in Hamiltons contributions to the Federalist Papers. In his famed

    Federalist No. 10, Madison focuses on the ability of a large republic to

    protect the public interest from the machinations of factions, but Hamilton

    offers a different approach in the oft-overlooked Federalist No. 11. In it,

    he suggests that a strong central government could engender national great-

    ness, in part by encouraging trade between the states:

    An unrestrained intercourse between the States themselves will advance

    the trade of each by an interchange of their respective productions, not

    Jay Cost

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    6/93

    only for the supply of reciprocal wants at home, but for exportation to

    foreign markets. The veins of commerce in every part will be replen-

    ished, and will acquire additional motion and vigor from a free circula-

    tion of the commodities of every part. Commercial enterprise will havemuch greater scope, from the diversity in the productions of different

    States.

    As secretary of the Treasury during the Washington administration,

    Hamilton was central in enacting an economic program that included the

    federal assumption of state war debts, the repayment of all debt at face

    value, and above all the chartering of the semi-public Bank of the United

    States (bus). Hamilton believed that this program would establish the cred-itworthiness of the United States, and thus promote economic growth and

    broad prosperity. In his Report on Manufactures in 1792, Hamilton went

    beyond this to anticipate much of the 19th-century Republican economic

    program by calling for protective tariffs, tax exemptions for certain raw

    materials, and facilitation of transportation.

    This view forms the foundation of the modern Republican party, especial-

    ly its conservative wing, although at first blush this might be difficult to

    appreciate. After all, todays conservatives consistently promote limited gov-ernment, whereas Hamilton and the Federalists were in favor of an activist

    government. How to bridge this apparent gap? The difference is accounted

    for in the rise of progressivism, the political philosophy developed at the end

    of the 19th century that promoted an active government to regulate business

    and redistribute income among the classes. Todays conservative

    Republicans generally favor limited government when compared to mod-

    ern progressives, but they are as activist as ever when viewed from the

    Hamiltonian perspective in that they prefer a government that encouragesAmerican commerce and industry.

    The Hamiltonian view of the federal government has long provoked

    intense backlash, with critics usually blasting the philosophy as being inher-

    ently unequal and anti-republican. This was the charge leveled by the

    Jeffersonians, who took control of the government in 1800 by demagogu-

    ing the Hamiltonians as an aristocratic clique plotting to impose monarchy

    upon the United States.

    Unfortunately, the Jeffersonians would have to learn the hard way that

    Hamiltons nationalistic policy was sound. Having all but vanquished their

    Federalist opponents, the Jeffersonian Republicans cut government spending

    to the bone and allowed the charter of the Bank of the United States to

    expire in 1811. The next year, amid a wave of nationalistic sentiment, they

    entered the country into another war with England with calamitous

    results. A lack of internal infrastructure again prohibited the efficient move-

    ment of men and supplies, a lack of a standing army left ill-prepared state

    militias to handle most of the fighting, and a lack of strong financial institu-

    tions made it extremely difficult for the government to fund the war opera-

    December 2011 & January 2012 5

    Election 2012: An Unusually Clear Policy Choice

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    7/93

    6 Policy Review

    tion. The country had to suffer the ignominy of seeing the capital city

    burned to the ground, and it was only Andrew Jacksons victory at the Battle

    of New Orleans that salvaged the national pride. The Treaty of Ghent

    accomplished none of the goals America had set when it initiated the con-flict, and the War of 1812 has been all but forgotten by 21st-century

    America.

    Yet it had a profound effect on the Jeffersonians. Almost immediately

    after the war, the party split apart based on the old Jefferson-Hamilton

    divide of twenty years prior. Moderate Jeffersonians like John Quincy

    Adams, Henry Clay, and Madison rediscovered the virtue of a strong central

    authority to promote internal development, and chartered a second bus.

    Indeed, Clay, who would dominate American poli-tics for the next 30 years, elaborated a neo-

    Hamiltonian political program that he dubbed the

    American System: a national bank to stabilize cur-

    rency and credit, protective tariffs to grow nascent

    American industries, and infrastructure improve-

    ments to promote internal development.

    Mismanagement of this second bus abetted the

    Panic of1819, but under the stewardship of presi-dent Nicholas Biddle, it contributed to the robust

    economic growth of the 1820s, when real gdp

    increased by an estimated four percent per year. Yet

    the bus had its detractors: Debtors in the South and

    West often viewed it as an institution that transferred wealth from their

    regions into the more prosperous Northeast; radical Jeffersonians consid-

    ered it an unconstitutional expansion of government and a threat to simple

    republican virtue; and a growing number of observers would articulate a cri-tique that has since become common in American political discourse the

    idea that the bus executives played political favorites and created a climate

    of cronyism and corruption.

    Andrew Jackson would come to expound all of these criticisms. His

    rough-hewn exterior belied a cunning political mind and firm belief that

    hard specie was superior to bank notes as the national currency, and

    Jackson set about to cut the power of the bank down to size, virtually from

    day one of his administration. Though Jackson would himself expand and

    enhance the powers of the presidency by vetoing bills for political purpos-

    es and by standing up to the South Carolina Nullifiers he was certainly

    no advocate of Hamiltonian, big government nationalism, believing that

    such intervention in private affairs inevitably favored the prosperous classes

    and therefore threatened the republican character of the government.

    When Biddle requested that Congress renew the bus charter just as the1832 election season began, Jacksons worst fears seemed confirmed. Biddle

    was clearly in cahoots with Jacksons opponents, above all Clay, the nomi-

    nee of the National Republicans who was casting about for an issue to

    Jay Cost

    The Jeffersonians

    would have to

    learn the hard

    way that

    Hamiltons

    nationalisticpolicy was

    sound.

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    8/93

    campaign on. Hence the petition for an early re-charter, and to Jackson a

    clear signal that an unelected financial elite were trying to influence the

    democratic process. Despite the fact that Jacksons allies in Congress gener-

    ally supported Biddles petition, the president vetoed the new charter andissued a stern rebuke in his veto message:

    It is to be regretted that the rich and powerful too often bend the acts of

    government to their selfish purposes. Distinctions in society will always

    exist under every just government. Equality of talents, of education, or

    of wealth can not be produced by human institutions. In the full enjoy-

    ment of the gifts of Heaven and the fruits of superior industry, economy,

    and virtue, every man is equally entitled to protection by law; but when

    the laws undertake to add to these natural and just advantages artificialdistinctions, to grant titles, gratuities, and exclusive privileges, to make

    the rich richer and the potent more powerful, the humble members of

    society the farmers, mechanics, and laborers who have neither the

    time nor the means of securing like favors to themselves, have a right to

    complain of the injustice of their Government.

    To this day, Jacksons veto message remains the most cogent and effective

    critique of the Hamilton/Clay approach to policy. A government that ispowerful enough to facilitate economic growth is also powerful enough to

    play favorites, and will inevitably favor the elite over the humble members

    of society. Though modern-day Democrats have since embraced big gov-

    ernment progressivism, they nevertheless still regularly invoke this

    Jacksonian critique against todays Republican Party and its pro-business

    policies, instead calling for reforms that address the injustices the hum-

    ble suffer.

    Unsurprisingly, the 1832 election became a referendum on these compet-ing ideologies. The result was a decisive win for Jackson, who carried nearly55 percent of the vote, the most for any Democrat until fdrs victory a cen-

    tury later.

    The Jacksonians dominated politics for the next quarter-century, but their

    inability to deal with the slavery issue meant that the new Republican Party

    would rise to power starting in 1860. Dominated by former Whigs, the

    Republicans would not only put an end to slavery, they would also push

    through a version of Clays American System over the next 30 years: protec-

    tive tariffs to grow American industry, a stable currency pegged to gold, and

    federal land grants to nurture education and transportation. It seemed as

    though Prince Hal, as Clay was known during his lifetime, had finally

    been crowned king; though he would lose three presidential elections, his

    economic platform was largely implemented after he died, with the result

    being fantastic economic growth for the next 30 years.

    The problem with a dynamic, industrialized economy is the persistent

    cycle of boom and bust, and the economic collapse of the 1890s was the

    worst depression the country had suffered to that point. The fallout from the

    December 2011 & January 2012 7

    Election 2012: An Unusually Clear Policy Choice

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    9/93

    8 Policy Review

    Panic of1893 exacerbated an already bad situation in the South and

    Great Plains, where indebted farmers labored to make ends meet despite a

    tight money supply, falling crop prices, and railroad monopolies that soaked

    them for every last penny. The frustration of the hardscrabble farmers gaverise to the Populist Party, whose spirit in turn overtook the Democrats in

    1896. At its convention in Chicago, the party all but disowned Democratic

    President Grover Cleveland an eastern conservative who favored the gold

    standard and nominated the young, brash William Jennings Bryan after

    he gave a stunning speech.

    The issue that year was not the bus, which had never been revived since

    Jackson killed it some 60 years prior, but rather the de facto gold standard

    the country had adopted to stabilize the currency in lieu of a central finan-cial institution. Bryan and his populist Democrats favored the unlimited

    coinage of silver, which would bring about inflation (or so they hoped) and

    thus transfer a portion of the national wealth from the creditors in the

    Northeast to the debtors in the South and West. Bryans convention address

    in praise of free silver hit on many of the same themes from Jacksons veto

    message, and has since become the template for modern Democratic poli-

    ticking:

    There are two ideas of government. There are those who believe that ifyou just legislate to make the well-to-do prosperous, that their prosperi-

    ty will leak through on those below. The Democratic idea has been that

    if you legislate to make the masses prosperous their prosperity will find

    its way up and through every class that rests upon it.

    This argument is like nails on a chalkboard for the political descendants

    of Hamilton and Clay, then and now. Their belief is that a government that

    actively encourages commerce and industry may disproportionately help afew individuals at the top, but it is of lasting benefit to all classes of people.

    The Democratic view, then and now, was that this trickle down approach

    only made the rich richer and the poor poorer.

    In 1896 the nationalists found a champion who was more than a match

    for Bryan Ohio Governor William McKinley. A bona fide expert on the

    tariff who won the gop nomination over the objection of the party bosses,

    McKinley was more than happy to fight Bryan on the issue of the currency.

    He framed his support for the gold standard in the context of the tariff and

    the entire national program for economic growth, arguing that it was all

    part of a package that had brought about vast improvements in the national

    standard of living since the Civil War, and that it would continue to do so if

    the country just retained the present course. Republican campaign literature

    hailed McKinley as the advance agent of prosperity, and the country

    agreed, electing him over Bryan by a 5146 margin, the largest presidential

    victory in 28 years.

    While the concept of an electoral realignment remains a problematic

    and controversial idea in academic circles, it is a pretty fair assertion that

    Jay Cost

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    10/93

    something substantial and enduring happened to both parties during 1890s.

    That election reaffirmed the Republican Partys commitment to the pro-

    growth, pro-development policies of Hamilton and Clay, while the conserva-

    tive Bourbons such as Cleveland in the Democratic Party lost out to thepopulists and later the progressives, both of whom advocated the use of the

    federal government to legislate to make the masses prosperous, as Bryan

    put it.

    The divisions return

    It is curious, then, that the country has not had another clear ref-erendum on the McKinley/Bryan divide since 1896. Why is it that,

    despite the fact that there are great differences between the two sides

    in terms of their core economic philosophies, Americans have not been

    forced to choose one path or the other since 1896?

    One reason is the spectacular economic growth over the last 100 years.

    Despite the persistence of the business cycle, including a nasty downturn

    after World War I, the real size of the American economy nearly quadru-

    pled between the Panic of1893 and the Great Depression. And while thelatter shaved off nearly 25 percent of the national income, the country

    began climbing out of the hole by 1934 and over the next 70 years real

    gross domestic product grew fifteen-fold. This miraculous growth seemed

    to be independent of the party in office or the ill-conceived proposals one

    side or the other cooked up; Democrats or Republicans, liberals or conserv-

    atives, the economy seemed to grow like gangbusters year in and year out.

    To put this growth in perspective, the 1970s which people today gener-

    ally remember as a period of weak growth saw real gross domesticproduct increase by some 38 percent, the private sector create some seven-

    teen million new jobs, and real disposable income per capita increase by 27

    percent.

    In light of this, both sides could have their cake and eat it, too. The

    Democrats could emphasize greater social welfare benefits without techni-

    cally redistributing wealth, as Bryan had proposed. Instead, they would

    take a relatively small slice of the annual national surplus and distribute it to

    the less fortunate. Republicans, meanwhile, were generally able to keep

    taxes low and business regulations from becoming too onerous without

    challenging the social welfare programs Americans had come to support.

    Whats more, both sides were able to dabble in policy realms usually domi-

    nated by the opposition Democrats could cut taxes and Republicans

    could enact social programs. Indeed, the domestic policies of the second

    Clinton term and the first George W. Bush term seem interchangeable; either

    man could have embraced welfare reform, No Child Left Behind, the

    Medicare prescription drug benefit, financial deregulation, school uniforms,

    the v-chip, or faith-based initiatives, and both cut taxes multiple times.

    December 2011 & January 2012 9

    Election 2012: An Unusually Clear Policy Choice

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    11/93

    But the old McKinley/Bryan cleavage is beginning to come back to the

    forefront because the American political economy has shifted decisively in

    the last few years. Two substantial problems have emerged. First, the great

    American prosperity machine has slowed noticeably. Economic growth inthe last decade has averaged less than 1.6 percent per year, compared to 3.3

    percent over the prior twenty years. Along with this slowdown in growth

    has come a decade-long jobs recession: The employment-to-population ratio

    peaked in April 2000 at nearly 65 percent and has never recovered; today it

    stands at an anemic 58 percent. More people out of work naturally means

    those still employed are less able to bargain for higher incomes, and so

    unsurprisingly the average inflation-adjusted salary per private sector work-

    er has declined over the last decade.The second problem is the inability of the federal

    government to pay its bills. This deficit problem is

    both short- and long-term in scope. Over the past

    few years, tax revenues have fallen off while gov-

    ernment efforts to stimulate the economy have

    expanded dramatically thus yielding the $1 tril-

    lion and larger annual deficits of the last few years.

    As daunting as these numbers are, they pale in com-parison to the long-term deficit problem, which is

    above all a consequence of the social welfare oblig-

    ations that politicians made generations ago, when

    gdp growth averaged nearly four percent per year

    and the retirement of the Baby Boomers was too far

    in the future for the actuaries to consider. But the day of reckoning is quick-

    ly approaching: According to the Congressional Budget Office, if all current

    policies are kept in place for the next 70 years, total federal spending willequal more than 34 percent ofgdp , nearly double what we have seen over

    the last 40 years.

    Combined, these two points offer a grim vision of the future. Economic

    growth is already slowing markedly, and to fund federal entitlement obliga-

    tions already on the books, the government will have to nearly double in

    size, further impeding the ability of the private sector to create wealth for

    subsequent generations. A continued weak economy, in turn, will put pres-

    sure on government to grow the safety net even more, which would mean

    more spending, taxes, and thus a vicious cycle.

    This means, in turn, that the ideological contrasts between the Democrats

    and Republicans will only grow sharper as the two parties articulate

    more clearly their side of the McKinley/Bryan cleavage.

    Democrats have made the first move, although one would not recognize

    that by listening to their rhetoric alone. President Barack Obama and former

    House Speaker Nancy Pelosi talk a good game about reigniting the

    American economy, but their rhetoric does not match the reality. Time and

    again, the president and his liberal allies in Congress have chosen to expand

    Jay Cost

    The American

    prosperity

    machine has

    slowed, and

    the federal

    government isunable to pay

    its bills.

    10 Policy Review

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    12/93

    the size and scope of the federal government, further hampering the private

    sector and stalling the economic recovery.

    The stimulus bill passed in 2009, for instance, promised to pump $800

    billion of borrowed money into the economy, but the point of entry waslargely through core Democratic clients: tax credits for the poor, public

    works projects that employed the trade unions, and bailouts for state gov-

    ernments full of public workers made up most of the package. Businesses

    saw very little in terms of tax incentives to spur a private sector rebound.

    With the economy supposedly fixed, Democrats turned their attention to

    redistribution of the national wealth. The cap-and-trade bill passed by the

    House in 2009 would have cut gross domestic product by nearly 0.5 per-

    cent by 2020, and cost the median household more than $200 per year.The winners in the scheme would be the environmentalist groups that are

    now essential to the Democratic coalition, the big banks and industries with

    insider connections that yielded special payoffs hidden in the legislation, and

    the poorest of Americans, who would actually receive a modest increase in

    annual income due to the redistribution programs in the bill.

    With health care, the president pitched his reforms as a way to solve some

    of the enduring structural problems with the economy. In a February 2009

    address to a joint session of Congress, he called attention to the crushingcost of health care:

    This is a cost that now causes a bankruptcy in America every 30 seconds.

    By the end of the year, it could cause 1.5 million Americans to lose their

    homes. In the last eight years, premiums have grown four times faster

    than wages. And in each of these years, one million more Americans have

    lost their health insurance. It is one of the major reasons why small busi-

    nesses close their doors and corporations ship jobs overseas. And its one

    of the largest and fastest growing parts of our budget. Given these facts,we can no longer afford to put health care reform on hold.

    Yet cost control was simply a smokescreen to win broad public support.

    An overwhelming majority of Americans have health insurance, so a reform

    plan designed mainly to expand coverage at the expense of those who

    already have it was bound to go nowhere fast. So Obama and congres-

    sional Democrats disguised what was at its core a coverage expansion bill in

    the rhetoric of cost containment. By the time the number crunchers at the

    Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services reported that the bill would

    actually increase the total cost of health care in this country and only exacer-

    bate the runaway costs of federal health subsidies, the bill had already been

    made the law of the land. The price that the public will pay for this new

    entitlement will be broad-based. Independent estimates suggest millions will

    lose their current health care coverage as businesses drop insurance plans to

    save money, and in the meantime the bill has only added to uncertainty in

    the businesses community, which has not fully figured out what the reforms

    will mean for the bottom line.

    December 2011 & January 2012 11

    Election 2012: An Unusually Clear Policy Choice

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    13/93

    12 Policy Review

    From a certain perspective, all of this seems like par for the course for the

    Democratic Party. Indeed, payouts to unions, tax credits for the poor, reams

    of new environmental regulations, and health entitlements have more or less

    been the partys bread and butter for generations. But what makes this soextraordinary is the shift in the political economy. It is one thing to pass a

    cap and trade bill when economic growth averages more than three percent

    per year; quite another when it struggles to rise above two percent. It is one

    thing to burden businesses with a health insurance mandate when hiring is

    at an all-time high, quite another when it has hit a 30-year low. It is one

    thing to promote deficit-financed public works programs when the deficit

    amounts to less than one percent ofgdp, quite another when it is nearly ten

    percent. This is not about dedicating a portion of the nations annual surplusto achieve goals of social welfare; this is about simple redistribution, about

    taking from Peter to pay Paul to equalize the slice of the national pie both

    enjoy. No doubt Bryan would heartily endorse all of these programs if he

    were alive today.

    For their part, Republicans are returning to the principles laid out by

    Hamilton, Clay, and McKinley. No longer are they promoting Democratic

    lite social welfare programs like Bushs Medicare prescription drug bene-

    fit. Instead, the bulk of the gops intellectual efforts has lately been indevising entitlement reforms, such as those proposed by House Budget

    Committee Chairman Paul Ryan, designed to keep the basic social welfare

    commitments in place without doubling the size of the government.

    Additionally, Republicans are increasingly pushing fundamental tax reform,

    something that has not been done in 25 years. Whats more, in an unprece-

    dented shift, Republicans are now talking seriously about comprehensive

    health care reform not just wiping Obamacare from the books, but

    making a serious, sustained bid to lower the costs of care. All of these ideaswould, if realized, reduce the size and scope of the federal government, alle-

    viate the burdens that are currently carried by businesses, and hopefully

    rehabilitate private sector growth. In other words, the economic crisis has

    refocused the Republican Partys attention on the ways that the federal gov-

    ernment can support American private enterprise. McKinley would surely

    be pleased.

    The 2012 decision

    One way in which 2012 will likely differ from 1832 and 1896 is

    that in those prior two contests the combatants were eager advo-

    cates of their own side, whereas Barack Obama probably will not

    be. The man who, as a candidate, declared that it was time for the country

    to make the hard choices prefers, as president, to recast the hard choices as

    false choices; he probably does not want to get pinned down in the same

    way that Jackson, Clay, Bryan, and McKinley did. Instead, if recent history

    Jay Cost

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    14/93

    is any guide, he will rather prefer to cast himself as the defender ofboth tra-

    ditions, and cast his opposition as the representatives of a radical fringe.

    Still, this might not matter. A challenger with a slender record in govern-

    ment can define himself whatever way he chooses, but a president is boundby his record; thus, President Obama faces more limitations in 2012 than

    candidate Obama did in 2008. With persistent weakness in the economy, a

    massive new health care entitlement set to go in effect, and a looming deficit

    crisis that will require either massive new taxes or major entitlement reforms

    President Obama may have no choice but to defend the political tradition

    of the liberal Democrats.

    If so, 2012 might turn out to be one of those elections that our grandchil-

    dren, and their children, talk about. It could be one of those decisive contestswhere the choice of the electorate sets the course of public policy for genera-

    tions to come. And once again, it looks to be another battle between the

    political heirs of Hamilton, Clay, and McKinley against the heirs of

    Jefferson, Jackson, and Bryan. Will the government continue to facilitate the

    expansion of the private sector, or will it further burden it with new layers of

    regulation and taxation? A year from now, we might very well know the

    answer to that question.

    December 2011 & January 2012 13

    Election 2012: An Unusually Clear Policy Choice

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    15/93

    R

    ecently there has been substantial press attention

    paid to underfunding in state and local government pen-

    sion plans, a longstanding problem made more urgentby recent troubles in the larger economy. There has of

    yet been comparatively less attention given to a similar

    (though smaller) set of mounting financial risks associated with private-sec-

    tor worker pensions covered by the Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation

    (pbgc). Yet here, too, public policy corrections are required to address

    underfunding and avoid another taxpayer-financed bailout we can ill afford.

    pbgcs latest annual report shows a net deficit of over $23 billion, of

    which roughly $21.6 billion is attributable to its single-employer insurance

    program. Whats worse, pbgc estimates its exposure to reasonably possible

    The Private-Sector

    Pension PredicamentBy Charles Blahous

    Charles Blahous serves as one of two public trustees for the Social Security andMedicare programs and is also a research fellow at the Hoover Institution. He

    previously served as deputy director of the National Economic Council, andexecutive director of the Presidents Commission to Strengthen Social Security.This material is condensed from his paper, The Other Pension Crisis: Options

    for Avoiding a Taxpayer Bailout of the PBGC, published by the MercatusCenter in March 2011.

    December 2011 & January 2012 15 Policy Review

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    16/93

    16 Policy Review

    plan terminations at approximately $170 billion. While these figures may

    appear small relative to the potential losses in state and local government

    plans, they reflect underfunding in employer-provided plans that is propor-

    tionally comparable.Elected officials face a fundamental value choice about whether employer-

    provided pensions should be funded and insured only by plan sponsors, or

    whether the dollars of others (i.e., taxpayers) should be tapped to fill the

    gap. Either policy requires substantial changes to existing law. If the former

    policy is not enforced so that pbgc is kept solvent, the approaching cost of

    the latter course should be disclosed. Each scenario requires unattractive

    actions but is nevertheless preferable to the current situation, in which tax-

    payers face a growing financial risk that is disguised rather than forestalledby the existence of the pbgc.

    The financing shortfall

    Employer-provided, defined-benefit pensions (both single-

    employer and multiemployer) are insured by the pbgc, a federally

    chartered corporation. When an insured pension plan terminates,the pbgc assumes the plans assets as well as the responsibility for paying

    promised benefits up to a cap set in law.

    To simplify the pertinent issues, I will focus primarily on the single-

    employer pension insurance system, where the vast majority of the pbgc

    financing shortfall is concentrated. Its current $21.6 billion deficit is nearly

    the largest on record, falling just behind those posted in 2004 and 2005.

    While the size of the deficit fluctuates from year to year, it has remained per-

    sistently significant over most of the last decade (that is, more than $10 bil-lion in each year since 2003, inclusive). Indeed, in each of the last eight

    years pbgcs liabilities have been measured as being at least 15 percent larg-

    er than its assets, and usually much more.

    These figures dont capture the full extent ofpbgcs potential difficulties,

    as evidenced by its estimate of reasonably possible termination exposure

    i.e., underfunding in plans with below-investment grade credit ratings

    at roughly $170 billion. pbgc s multiemployer program is also presenting

    increased risks; in 2010, reasonably possible exposure in multiemployer

    plans suddenly rose from roughly $300 million to approximately $20 bil-

    lion.

    The financing hole in Americas pensions is now of such a size that we

    cannot expect it to close unless someone pays substantially greater costs out

    of pocket than is currently the case. In October 2009, pbgc provided con-

    gressional staff with estimates indicating that to comply with existing law,

    pension contributions by plan sponsors would need to rise from roughly

    $50 billion in 2008 to more than $250 billion annually by the mid-2010s.

    Others projections show considerably smaller figures but nevertheless agree

    Charles Blahous

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    17/93

    that substantial future contribution increases will be required. Recently

    enacted funding relief could delay the full effects of these requirements, but

    that does not change the reality that markedly increased contributions will

    ultimately be necessary.A critical public policy question, therefore, is to what extent the cost of

    filling the shortfall is to be met within the current pension insurance system,

    and to what extent risks and costs will be shifted to those now perceived to

    be outside of it.

    Why the inadequate finance?

    T

    he pension insurance system was weakened when recent

    financial market declines both depressed pension-plan asset values

    and undermined the financial health of plan sponsors. From 2008

    to 2009 the size ofpbgcs net deficit roughly doubled, in part due to a

    decline in interest rates (which increased the present value of plan liabilities),

    and also due to an increase in plan terminations. In 2009, pbgc reported

    that it had become responsible for paying benefits to more than 200,000

    additional workers, the third-highest increase in its history and roughly nine

    times the number of new participants for which it had assumed responsibili-

    ty in 2008. Over the same year, pbgcs exposure to reasonably possible

    terminations drastically increased, from $47 billion to $168 billion.

    December 2011 & January 2012 17

    The Private-Sector Pension Predicament

    figure 1

    Net financial position, PBGC single-employer insurance program

    Source: 2010 pbgc Annual Report.

    10

    5

    -

    -5

    -10

    -15

    -20

    -25

    $b

    illionso

    fpresentvalue

    2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    18/93

    18 Policy Review

    Though this represented a sharp downturn in pbgcs outlook, its finances

    were on an unsustainable course even when financial markets were at their

    peak. The reasons were rooted in longstanding flaws in federal pension law.

    Although the 2006 Pension Protection Act (ppa) addressed many of theseproblems, their effects continue to permeate the pension system. The ppa

    provided up-front pension funding relief to most plan sponsors while estab-

    lishing tighter funding targets for the long term. But many of the ppas criti-

    cal reforms are being phased in only gradually, and its near-term funding

    requirements were further relaxed in subsequent legislation. Regardless, any

    positive impact of the ppa is being swamped by the financing deterioration

    resulting from worsened market conditions.

    The following is a capsule list of factors that have contributed over timeto pension underfunding. More details about all of these factors can be

    found in Pension Wise (Hoover Institution Press, 2010).

    1. Inaccurate measurements of plan assets. Plan underfunding can only be

    successfully addressed to the extent that contributions are based upon

    accurate, up-to-date measurements of plan assets, liabilities, and any

    gap between them. Prior to the ppa, sponsors could smooth asset

    valuations by blending more recent values with older valuations from

    the previous four years. Even under the ppa, the plan sponsor still hastwo years to fully recognize any discrepancy between a plans actual

    and its previously projected plan assets, though assets cannot be valued

    more than 10 percent differently than current market value. Such

    smoothing has often delayed recognition of underfunding, causing

    delays in contributions that would otherwise be required. Smoothing

    was often rationalized as being necessary to limit the volatility of and

    to prevent pro-cyclicality in contribution requirements. This rationale,

    however, conflated two separable concepts the accuracy of pensionfunding measurements on the one hand, and the policy for determining

    contributions on the other.

    2. Inaccurate measurements of plan liabilities. An accurate projection of

    plan liabilities requires both that future benefit payments be accurately

    estimated and that they are appropriately discounted into their present

    value. Accurate benefit payment projections in turn require accurate

    estimates of the number of individuals who will be receiving benefits,

    the amount and form of those benefits, and the time over which they

    will be paid. The ppa required plan sponsors to use updated mortality

    tables, addressing a problem that had long persisted before the legisla-

    tion. The ppa also now accounts for the empirical phenomenon of the

    rush to the exits i.e., the likelihood that individuals in a troubled

    plan will claim benefits at the earliest possible age and in a lump sum

    when available (both choices drain a plan of assets in the near term).

    The ppa s transition period, however, has the effect of postponing

    recognition of most of these at-risk plans. As for liability discount-

    Charles Blahous

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    19/93

    ing, what must be assessed is the degree of risk in pension benefits as

    well as the time period over which they will be paid. Current law dis-

    counts these liabilities according to a yield curve of corporate bond

    rates, which the sponsor has the option of smoothing over two years. Acorporate-bond yield curve is potentially an appropriate means of dis-

    counting. It is, however, appropriate only to the extent that worker

    benefits are at risk whenever corporate financial health is also at risk;

    that is, when benefits are not backstopped by the taxpayer.

    Furthermore, it is accurate only to the extent that smoothing and other

    interest rate specifications do not introduce a distortion of up-to-date

    market conditions. Additionally, the ppa also allowed certain political-

    ly favored industries (e.g., airlines) to employ arbitrarily higher dis-count rates in their pension funding calculations.

    3. Inadequate funding targets. A core principle of the ppa is that a pen-

    sion plans appropriate funding target is 100 percent, with plan spon-

    sors being given seven years to amortize contributions to address any

    shortfall. The ppa did not establish the 100 percent funding target

    immediately, however; even the firstsponsor payments pursuant to full

    funding were not to be required until at least five years after the ppas

    enactment. Moreover, additional funding relief was enacted in 2010that, while it did not waive the 100 percent funding target, reduced

    contribution requirements in relation to it. While it is understandable

    that Congress would choose to provide additional funding relief at a

    time when plan sponsors face unusual economic difficulties, the relief

    took immediate effect in a funding environment that was already quite

    weak.

    4. Unfunded benefit increases. Prior to the ppa, employers had the lati-tude to increase benefit promises without fully funding these increases

    before a plan was assumed by the pbgc. This had the effect of worsen-

    ing underfunding in some terminating plans. The ppa clamped down

    on such practices, imposing various limitations respectively upon lump

    sum payments, unfunded benefit increases, and in some cases even ben-

    efit accruals, though these safeguards have yet to fully take effect.

    5. Loopholes and special preferences. Pre-ppa law contained enormous

    loopholes, many of which made significant contributions to pension

    underfunding. Among these was the credit balance rule. Specifically,

    any contribution made in excess of minimum statutory requirements

    was not only counted once in adding to a plans funding percentage but

    a second time in reducing the amount of future contributions otherwise

    required. Moreover, plan sponsors were permitted to assume that the

    credit balance had appreciated in value even if the actual investment

    had not. The ppa corrected the worst abuses of credit balances but per-

    mitted the basic concept to persist. It did not, however, reform various

    December 2011 & January 2012 19

    The Private-Sector Pension Predicament

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    20/93

    20 Policy Review

    special statutory preferences for politically favored industries. It explic-

    itly permitted airline plan sponsors to use longer amortization periods

    and to employ a higher discount rate to artificially shrink the size of

    plan liabilities. More recently, one domestic automaker was also per-mitted, while receiving government assistance, to top up affiliated

    union workers pension benefits, to circumvent the spirit of pbgcs

    statutory benefit caps.

    6. Inadequate premiums. Unlike other federal insurers (such as the fdic),

    the pbgc does not have the power to levy premium assessments suffi-

    cient to pay for the cost of the insurance that it provides. In 2005, the

    Congressional Budget Office calculated that pbgc premiums would

    need to be roughly 6.5 times higher to fund the size of anticipatedclaims. Equally important, not only is the levelof premium income

    inadequate but premium assessments do not reflect the level ofrisk in a

    pension plan, arising from such factors as its investment portfolio, its

    funding percentage, and the health of its sponsor. Earlier this year, the

    Obama administration proposed that the pbgc be given increased

    authority to modify both the level and structure of premiums that

    sponsors are charged for pension insurance.

    7. Limitations upon the national pension insurer (PBGC). The pbgc has

    only limited power to enforce contribution requirements. In one exam-

    ple from recent years, one airline sponsor simply stopped making statu-

    torily-required contributions to its plan once the sponsor entered bank-

    ruptcy. As an unsecured creditor, pbgc was unable during bankruptcy

    proceedings to perfect a lien placed against the skipped contributions.

    pbgc also generally lacks the authority to regulate the investment poli-

    cies of plan sponsors, or otherwise prevent them from taking actionsthat degrade its financial position. Moreover, pbgc has an ambiguous

    position in relation to the Department of Labor, in some respects

    appearing to sit within it, in others appearing to be independent. This

    occasionally calls into question pbgcs latitude to take fully indepen-

    dent actions to defend pension plan funding. This is particularly prob-

    lematic in circumstances where a presidential administration chooses to

    advance a conflicting policy priority, whether that competing priority

    involves providing direct taxpayer-backed assistance to the automotive

    industry or attempting to stimulate near-term job creation at the

    expense of pension funding.

    8. Inadequate disclosure. Transparency and disclosure are effective spurs

    to stronger pension funding. Present funding disclosure requirements

    can only be described as inadequate. The 4010 form (pbgcs primary

    source of detailed plan funding information) is only required of plans

    deemed less than 80 percent funded. This has the dual adverse impacts

    of both limiting information about some large plans that may pose a

    Charles Blahous

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    21/93

    large aggregate risk to the pbgc and of stigmatizing the comparatively

    few plan sponsors who must file the information.

    9. Barriers to funding up during good times. During the late 1990s,

    annual contributions to pension plans shrank (and in some cases wereeliminated altogether) as plan assets rose during the stock markets dot-

    com bubble. After the bubble burst, plan funding percentages declined

    to lower levels than they would have if sponsors had overfunded

    during good times. Pre-ppa law constrained the extent to which plan

    sponsors could do so, limiting the tax-deductibility of excess pension

    contributions to 100 percent of the plans current liability. The ppa

    increased employer flexibility to fund up during good times, allowing

    sponsors to fund to 150 percent of their target liability plus expensesbased on future salary increases (a long-term reform of limited applica-

    bility in a recession environment). Current federal budget rules also

    remain a problem. Because employer pension contributions are tax

    deductible, the federal government can still raise revenue by reducing

    employer pension contributions, a tactic used as a budgetary offset for

    added federal spending in 2010. A better budget framework would

    recognize worsening pension underfunding as an increase in potential

    taxpayer exposure, rather than treat it as a cost-free source of financingfor added federal spending.

    10. Moral hazard and political economy factors. Current funding require-

    ments and premium assessments are determined not by economic reali-

    ties but rather by a political process. Elected officials remain under con-

    stant pressure to relax contribution requirements so that employer

    funds can be made available for new hiring or for more immediate

    forms of compensation (e.g., wages). Similar pressures are commonthroughout existing defined-benefit systems and have caused significant

    underfunding to arise in each of employer-provided pensions, state and

    local pensions, and in Social Security.

    11. Periodic contribution relief. One specific manifestation of the moral

    hazard inherent in the current pension system is the recurrent congres-

    sional behavior whenever previously enacted funding requirements

    begin to bind too tightly. In the early 2000s, funding relief was first

    provided by allowing sponsors to discount using a widened corridor

    around Treasury bond rates, and then later by shifting to higher corpo-

    rate bond rates. In 2006, the ppa provided additional near-term fund-

    ing relief in exchange for a tightening of long-term funding standards.

    More recent funding relief has repeatedly been justified by difficult eco-

    nomic conditions. While the funding relief may have been defensible in

    each of these individual circumstances, the overall pattern has been

    unchanging; Congress has repeatedly shifted the risks of pension under-

    funding from plan sponsors to the pension insurance system as a whole.

    December 2011 & January 2012 21

    The Private-Sector Pension Predicament

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    22/93

    Common moral hazards

    There is periodic but largely separate public attention to the

    funding issues facing Social Security, state and local pension plans,

    and employer-provided defined-benefit pensions. All of these sys-

    tems are underfunded; all suffer from inadequate accounting; and all face

    analogous moral hazards. Yet there has been comparatively little attention

    to the common factors driving underfunding in all three.

    While defined-contribution systems also face their challenges, a funda-

    mental misalignment of interests is not one of them. A workers ultimatedefined-contribution benefit is a direct function both of the adequacy of plan

    contributions and of the rate of appreciation on investments. It is clearly in

    the workers interest to see that contributions are sufficient, that they are

    profitably invested, and that administrative expenses are minimized. If any

    of these elements is poorly handled, the workers ultimate retirement income

    will diminish. While the worker may lack sufficient information or educa-

    tion to assess these factors, the workers interestis at least straightforwardly

    aligned.In a defined-benefit system, however, the interests of different actors

    diverge. Because the sponsor, rather than the worker, accepts the funding

    risk, it is in the sponsors interest to minimize his costs in providing a given

    benefit, while it is only in the workers interest to maximize his chance of

    receiving the full benefit, irrespective of who pays for it. The presence of

    pension insurance injects substantial moral hazard into this dynamic. When

    pension insurance is present, a plan sponsor can potentially reduce funding

    costs by investing in higher-risk securities (unless specifically prevented byregulation from doing so). If the upside returns are received, the sponsors

    pension liabilities are reduced; if the downside risk is realized, the pension

    insurance system is there to potentially absorb the loss. Pension insurance at

    the same time reduces the workers incentive to verify that pension contribu-

    tions are both adequate and prudently invested.

    The same problematic incentives exist in public-sector plans, including

    both state and local pension plans and the federal Social Security program.

    Elected officials responsible for controlling the finances of these plans have

    powerful incentives both to minimize costs faced by taxpayers while maxi-

    mizing benefits paid to program participants. This leads naturally to two

    predictable results; first, to aggregate underfunding (an excess of promised

    benefits over contributed revenues); second, to rising pay-as-you-go obliga-

    tions (that is, an escalation of obligations that must be financed by future

    contributors at the moment of benefit payment, as opposed to having been

    prefunded).

    The adverse funding consequences of these hazards have resulted in

    roughly one-fifth to one-quarter of future benefits being unfunded in each

    Charles Blahous

    22 Policy Review

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    23/93

    defined-benefit sector, depending on the particular estimate. State and local

    plans have frequently employed aggressive liability discount rate assump-

    tions that reduce near-term funding and increase the share of benefit pay-

    ments that must be funded by future taxpayers. Similarly, the federal SocialSecurity program continues to be operated essentially on a pay-as-you-go

    basis despite widely recognized population aging, a long-predicted decline in

    the ratio of workers to beneficiaries, and the recommendations of multiple

    bipartisan technical panels and advisory boards to shift toward partial pre-

    funding.

    Although the pbgc insures private-sector pensions, its operations are also

    greatly affected by political economy factors. Both premium assessments and

    funding requirements are established via a politicalprocess. The pbgc is not permitted to perform the

    equivalent of a private-sector insurers pricing of

    insurance coverage, nor does it have the legal

    authority to change premium assessments as finan-

    cially necessary. And each time that legislators must

    vote on a bill to determine premium levels or fund-

    ing requirements, they are subject to enormous polit-

    ical pressure to relax each of these relative to what isrequired to achieve a fully funded pension system.

    Unless the process itself is changed, this phenome-

    non should be expected to continue.

    A striking parallel between the three major forms

    of defined-benefit pensions is the extent to which near-term funding relief

    has often been provided through the manipulation of asset and liability mea-

    surements in all three sectors. Asset and liability smoothing, artificially high

    discount rates, credit balances, and other techniques have delayed recogni-tion of underfunding in employer-provided pensions. In state and local

    plans, the chief accounting tool by which liabilities have been understated

    has been the use of aggressive liability discount rate assumptions. In Social

    Security, Trust Fund accounting is the primary culprit, where Trust Fund

    assets are deemed to reduce future funding shortfalls even though these

    assets are simply a further debt obligation facing federal taxpayers. A classic

    example of the manipulation of this accounting occurred last December,

    when Congress cut payroll taxes by over $100 billion for 2011 but stipu-

    lated that additional debt would be issued to the Social Security Trust Funds

    just as though the additional taxes were being collected.

    In each of these defined-benefit systems, the ongoing battle over transpar-

    ent accounting is fought along predictable interest group lines. In the

    employer-provided pension world, plan sponsors often argue for asset/liabili-

    ty smoothing and higher discount rates, while the opposing case is made by

    those responsible for the health of the pension insurance system. With state

    and local plans, state officials and public employee unions both advocate

    high discount rates, while pushback comes from academics, taxpayer-watch-

    December 2011 & January 2012 23

    The Private-Sector Pension Predicament

    While defined-

    contribution

    systems also face

    their challenges, a

    fundamental

    misalignment ofinterests is not

    one of them.

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    24/93

    24 Policy Review

    dog groups, and federal officials concerned about pressure for a federal

    bailout. In Social Security, the beneficiary-advocacy group aarp has defend-

    ed current Trust Fund accounting methods, while counter pressure has come

    from bipartisan technical expert panels and fiscal watchdog groups.Unfortunately, in each of these cases, those who have argued to disguise

    funding inadequacy have generally carried the day, contributing to the signif-

    icant funding shortfalls in all three systems.

    Avoiding a taxpayer bailout ofpbgc

    Regardless of the future structure ofpbgc, certain reformprinciples should be observed. Specifically:1. Limit asset smoothing to the extent practicable. Pension funding policy

    cannot be sensibly constructed if it is not built on a foundation of mea-

    surement accuracy. The only properly imposed limitation on the accu-

    racy of asset measurements should reflect limits on practicability for

    plan sponsors. If requiring an asset measurement on a specified date

    proves to be particularly disadvantageous for a plan sponsor, this out-

    come is best avoided by allowing the sponsor to select from valuation

    dates within a narrow time window. To the extent that minimizing

    smoothing causes real asset volatility to be formally recognized, fund-

    Charles Blahous

    table 1

    Moral hazards operating in defined-benefit systems

    system risks shifted to method(s) result

    Employer-provid-

    ed pensions

    pbgc pension

    insurance system

    Asset/liability

    smoothing, dis-

    count rates, loop-

    holes, inadequate

    funding rules

    Underfunded

    State and local

    pensionsFuture taxpayers

    Aggressive dis-counting assump-

    tions

    Underfunded

    Social Security Future taxpayers

    Trust Fund

    accounting; pay-

    go financing

    Underfunded

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    25/93

    ing rules should be designed to limit volatility in annual required con-

    tributions rather than relying on smoothed asset valuations. Asset

    and liability valuations should be conducted to produce the most accu-

    rate information about plan finances, not to steer toward a particularfunding policy result.

    2. In liability measurements, limit smoothing, use up-to-date mortality

    tables, and account accurately for worker behavior. Like asset measure-

    ments, liability measurements should be as accurate and up-to-date as

    is practicable. Specifically, liability measurements should reflect the

    most up-to-date mortality tables as well as the best available informa-

    tion about how and when workers are likely to claim benefits. This in

    turn requires that the pension insurer is able to ascertain the risk of arush to the exits due to the sponsor itself becoming a credit risk. As

    with asset valuation, periodic fluctuations in liability discount rates are

    better handled by allowing a narrow time window during which a

    sponsor can choose a discount rate, rather than by smoothing with

    long outdated discount rates.

    3. Eliminate special deals for politically-favored industries. Rules of play

    should be applied fairly across the board. There should be no specialexemptions for politically favored industries as exist under current law.

    A private insurer would not be allowed to discriminate between cov-

    ered entities based on political preference; the public pension insurance

    system should be bound by a similar ethic.

    4. Enforce prohibitions on unfunded benefit increases by underfunded

    plans. Even where plan sponsors are suffering from economic forces

    beyond their control, little good can arise from permitting plan spon-

    sors to promise benefits that they cannot pay. Recent funding relief leg-islation has permitted plan sponsors to escape restrictions on unfunded

    benefit increases by allowing funding valuations to be made based on

    pre-recession conditions. However faultless a sponsor with respect to

    the broader financial market decline, it should not then take the further

    irresponsible step of making further benefit promises that it cannot

    fund.

    5. Increase disclosure of funding information. Sunshine and transparency

    are useful spurs to stronger pension funding. The 4010 submission

    requirements should be expanded to provide pbgc with the informa-

    tion necessary to gauge the likelihood of further financial hits on the

    pension insurance system. This would also help to destigmatize those

    plan sponsors who provide it. To prevent small employers from undue

    burdens and to focus information on the largest potential threats facing

    the pbgc, 4010 filing requirements should be based on aggregate plan

    underfunding rather than on a funding percentage. This filing threshold

    should be reestablished at a level low enough to enable pbgc to see at

    December 2011 & January 2012 25

    The Private-Sector Pension Predicament

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    26/93

    26 Policy Review

    least the majority of the underfunding in plans for which it is reason-

    ably likely to become responsible.

    Three frameworks for reform

    Elected officials should choose between three basic options

    for comprehensive reform of the employer-provided pension insur-

    ance system.Option #1: Empower PBGC with the tools necessary to fill the shortfall

    in the national pension insurance system. Ifpbgc is to remain financially

    viable without taxpayer funds, it must be provided with the resources

    required to close its funding shortfall. These must include enhancements of

    its financial, legal, and organizational tools. Among them:

    1. Premium income. An insurance system cannot survive if it cannot ade-

    quately charge for the cost of insurance provided. The pbgc currently

    lacks the authority to charge premiums that are sufficient to fund

    anticipated claims. President Obama has recently proposed that pbgc

    be given the authority to raise premiums as necessary to prevent a gov-

    ernment-financed rescue. Different methods of doing so are available

    that reflect different potential value choices. A higher flat-rate premi-

    um for all participants would reflect a judgment that the cost of filling

    the shortfall should be spread among the greatest number of plan

    sponsors (including those with well-funded plans). Alternatively,

    greater reliance on risk-based premiums would reflect a judgment that

    Charles Blahous

    table 2Three options for pension insurance reform

    option #1Empower pbgc with the tools necessary to fill the shortfall in

    the national pension insurance system.

    option #2Eliminate pbgc and replace it with compulsory private

    insurance that would charge market rates to participants.

    option #3

    Unless and until the federal government requires that pbgcs

    financing risks be resolved via Options #1 or #2, treat the

    shortfall for federal budgetary purposes as an obligation

    facing U.S. taxpayers.

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    27/93

    higher costs should be imposed on those sponsors who pose the great-

    est risk to the insurance system. A truly risk-based premium would

    provide greater incentives for full funding and should thus be a part of

    any solution. At the same time, it is unlikely that weak sponsors ofunderfunded plans will themselves be able to provide sufficient addi-

    tional revenue to fill pbgcs financing hole, necessitating an increase

    as well in the flat premium paid by all plan sponsors.

    2. Adequate funding rules. The law should be revised to undo recent

    complexity creep and to once again provide all plan sponsors with

    a single amortization schedule (with 100 percent funding as the ulti-

    mate funding target). Under almost any scenario, future contributions

    by plan sponsors will ultimately need to be much larger than theyhave been in the recent past. Interim funding relief should therefore

    be limited only to that required to offset recent economic events, and

    notaim to avoid the funding increases eventually required even under

    more typical economic conditions. One way of implementing this

    would be to adopt a single 2 + 7 policy for everyone (two years of

    interest-only payments, followed by seven-year amortization). Under

    this framework, Congress would also repeal the special discount rates

    and amortization schedules for the airline industry, as well as othertargeted exceptions to the funding rules.

    3. Strengthened legal tools for PBGC. pbgc cannot adequately protect

    the pension insurance system with its current set of crude legal tools.

    Bankruptcy code changes could be enacted to give pension plan con-

    tributions the same status as wage payments, to move pbgc ahead in

    line over other unsecured creditors. pbgc could also be given an

    authority comparable to that of the fdic, to implement cease and

    desist orders to prevent plan sponsors from taking actions injurious

    to the health of the pension insurance system.

    4. PBGC Independence. To fully empower pbgc to close its own fund-

    ing shortfall Congress would clarify in law that pbgc is an indepen-

    dent regulatory agency and no longer a part of the Department of

    Labor. The current pbgc can never be wholly independent of White

    House direction because of the constitutional unitary nature of the

    federal executive branch. It could, nevertheless, wield a degree ofdefacto independence roughly comparable to that of the fic or

    Securities Exchange Commission. The goal would be to free pbgc to

    make determinations predicated exclusively on the health of the pen-

    sion insurance system, without conscious subordination to the broad-

    er economic policy objectives of the presidential administration.

    In sum, the basics of the approach in Option #1 are to provide pbgc

    with the necessary funding rules, premium income, legal tools, and organiza-

    December 2011 & January 2012 27

    The Private-Sector Pension Predicament

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    28/93

    28 Policy Review

    tional standing to address its own financing shortfall. If Congress is unwill-

    ing to permit this within the present pbgc system, it will need to choose

    between other alternatives.

    Option #2: Eliminate PBGC and replace it with compulsory privateinsurance that would charge market rates to participants. Option #2 differs

    from Option #1 primarily in the structure of the pension insurance system;

    specifically, whether it is a compulsory system of private insurance or contin-

    ues to be a government-chartered system. Certain core elements of reform

    would be implemented in Option #2 as they would be in Option #1:

    1. Premium reforms. Just as with a strengthened pbgc, a private insurer

    would need to charge higher premiums than have been imposed to

    date and would likely increase its reliance on risk-based premiums.

    2. Adequate funding. In a private insurance system, adequate funding

    would be facilitated not via government prescription but through the

    general requirement that the new system be self-financing.

    3. Strengthened legal tools. Whether public or private, a pension insurer

    could be provided with stronger legal tools in bankruptcy proceedings,

    such as a higher claim priority given to pension plan contributions.

    4. Independence from other government departments. This would be

    implicit in any private insurance model.

    Choosing between Options #1 and #2 is therefore primarily a value judg-

    ment as to whether the above reforms are more likely to occur within a gov-

    ernment-chartered or a privately administered system. If the conclusion is

    reached that persistent legislative tinkering will always prevent reforms

    under the current pbgc structure, then the private insurance model must beconsidered as an alternative.

    The premium structure for pension insurance is of particular relevance

    when weighing whether to continue the pbgc or to transition to a private-

    sector model. A private insurer would be expected to assess premiums based

    in large part on its evaluation of risk, including sponsor default risk, under-

    funding risk, and asset-liability mismatch risk, among other factors. The

    public sector has generally shown an unwillingness to implement true risk-

    based pricing.

    An important policy specification for any private-sector successor to

    pbgc involves whether it must not only sustain its future operations, but

    also carry the burden of an inherited pbgc deficit of roughly $23 billion.

    To require pension plan sponsors to make up this deficit is in effect to

    require that their future pension insurance costs are $23 billion higher than

    the value of the insurance itself. Some advocates of private pension insur-

    ance have therefore proposed that taxpayers shoulder the cost of financing

    the current pbgc deficit so that subsequent compulsory pension insurance

    can be given a clean slate free of legacy debt.

    Charles Blahous

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    29/93

    Though pbgcs legacy debt is a thorny problem for any transition to pri-

    vate insurance, it is important to understand that the problem is not unique

    to the private insurance model. Whether pension insurance is publicly or pri-

    vately offered, the same policy dilemma exists: namely, whether to requirepension plan sponsors alone to make up the pbgc shortfall, or whether to

    pass the cost of that shortfall to general taxpayers.

    The most practicable path for transition to a private-sector system might

    be via a two-stage process: During the first stage, reforms would be imple-

    mented to drastically curtail the size of the pbgc deficit. Only in the second

    stage would a transition be effected to a private-sector framework.

    Both stages of any such two-stage process would likely need to be estab-

    lished in law from the outset to permit successfulconversion to a private-sector model. If, alternatively,

    reforms succeeded in eliminating the pbgc deficit

    withoutbeing an explicit component of a private-

    sector transition plan, the fiscal improvement would

    itself eliminate much of the political momentum

    toward such conversion. Without establishing an

    explicit two-stage process, it appears very unlikely

    that such a transition would ultimately be facilitated.Option #3: Unless and until the federal govern-

    ment requires that PBGCs financing risks be

    resolved via Options #1 or #2, treat the shortfall for

    federal budgetary purposes as an obligation facing

    U.S. taxpayers. The policy objective underlying Options #1 and #2 is to

    enable the pension insurance system to meet its obligations without an infu-

    sion of taxpayer-provided revenue. If, however, policymakers are unwilling

    both to require and to empower the pension insurance system to be self-sus-taining, there exists a substantial risk that taxpayers will ultimately be called

    upon to resolve the shortfall.

    There are a number of reasons why a taxpayer bailout of employer-pro-

    vided pension insurance is an undesirable policy outcome. First and fore-

    most, it would be inequitable. Approximately 21 percent of American

    workers have been promised defined-benefit retirement income by their

    employers meaning that the other 79 percent have not. To require these

    taxpayers to bail out pension promises made by others employers is to

    require the vast majority of taxpayers to subsidize a benefit that only a

    minority is eligible to receive.

    Beyond this, the mere potential for a taxpayer-financed bailout injects

    additional moral hazard into a retirement income system already fraught

    with it. Pension benefits represent a particular form of compensation

    promised by an employer to an employee. To the extent that resources other

    than employer funds are used to fulfill that promise, not only specific spon-

    sors but employers as a class would be compensating their employees with

    third-party (taxpayer) money.

    December 2011 & January 2012 29

    The Private-Sector Pension Predicament

    There are many

    reasons why a

    taxpayer bailout

    of employer-

    provided pension

    insurance is

    undesirable.

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    30/93

    30 Policy Review

    For general taxpayers to bail out private-sector defined-benefit promises

    also renders it difficult to draw a clear line limiting potential taxpayer expo-

    sure. If defined-benefit promises are to be made good by the federal govern-

    ment, why should there not also be relief to workers who have only defined-contribution accounts severely weakened by the recent financial markets

    plunge? Once the federal government goes down the road of assuming

    responsibility for the retirement income promises made in private employ-

    ment, there is no obvious limit at which the potential costs will be con-

    tained.

    Finally, the federal government is itself already in dire fiscal circum-

    stances. Among other obligations, the federal government is responsible for

    financing the benefits of its own Social Securityretirement program, currently projected to be insol-

    vent over the long term. The deficit of pbgc is

    smaller than the deficits in state and local public

    plans or Social Security, and could theoretically be

    financed more easily; it nevertheless lacks the direct

    claim upon taxpayer resources that the Social

    Security program has. Unless and until the federal

    government has an effective plan for financing theobligations it has already taken on, it is not in a

    position to be shouldering the retirement benefit

    obligations of the private sector.

    For these and other reasons, a taxpayer bailout of

    pbgc should be regarded as a doomsday sce-

    nario. If, however, policymakers decline to enable the pbgc pension insur-

    ance system to be self-financing, they are creating a risk that this doomsday

    scenario will come to pass. Policy Option #3 is to disclose the full amount ofthis risk to taxpayers for as long as it persists.

    The procedures for bringing the costs of systems like pbgc onto the fed-

    eral budget are not free of ambiguity; scorekeeping decisions of the

    Congressional Budget Office and the Office of Management and Budget

    sometimes diverge. To appropriately show the full extent of taxpayer expo-

    sure to the obligations ofpbgc, the mission of budget scorekeepers would

    be to assess a policy outcome in which taxpayers bear the risks of financing

    benefit payment obligations. Any net negative cash flows projected would be

    scored as a general revenue obligation facing U.S. taxpayers.

    Merely reporting this information within federal budgetary documents

    would likely be an inadequate public warning of the potential cost of a tax-

    payer bailout ofpbgc. To secure the public attention required to deflect

    momentum from a bailout, periodic separate reporting of the size of the

    pbgc obligations facing taxpayers would likely need to be required, in a

    manner similar to the annual reports of the Social Security and Medicare

    Trustees. This could be required either ofcbo, the Office of Management

    and Budget, the General Accounting Office, or ofpbgc itself.

    Charles Blahous

    No matter

    which of the

    preceding reform

    models is

    adopted, a

    contributionfunding schedule

    will be required.

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    31/93

    Any such reporting requirement should disclose not only the potential

    cost to taxpayers but also the potential losses in worker benefits. Unless

    pbgc s statutory cap on benefits is waived, even a taxpayer bailout

    would not result in taxpayers making up the entirety of the pension fundingshortfall. The remainder of the gap would be resolved by the loss of all

    worker benefits exceeding pbgcs statutory limit. Reporting these projected

    worker benefit losses could add substantial cogency to these periodic

    reports.

    Scoring the potential cost of a taxpayer bailout would have the benefit of

    deterring the use of pension funding relief as a budgetary offset for new fed-

    eral spending. In the past, Congress has raised revenue by reducing

    requirements for (tax-deductible) employer pension contributions, and hasused the revenue increases to finance its additional spending desires. This

    practice could be deterred if an increase in the projected pbgc deficit was

    simultaneously scored as a direct spending obligation facing taxpayers.

    Questions that must be answered

    The various tools provided to the pension insurer in Options#1 and #2 are designed to be sufficient to close its financing short-

    fall. This, however, does not imply that it would be optimal policy

    to require that the shortfall be made up immediately and all at once. Indeed,

    to require this in the current economic environment could well be self-

    defeating. It would require rapid increases in annual contributions to pen-

    sion plans, indeed potentially quadrupling annual contribution levels at a

    time when many employers are expected to struggle to recover from the

    recent economic downturn.Accordingly, no matter which of the preceding reform models is adopted,

    a contribution funding schedule will be required, and almost certainly one in

    which employers near-term obligations are limited to levels substantially

    lower than ultimately necessary. This inevitably means that there will be

    some persistent risk of system insolvency, even after reforms are enacted,

    before they are fully phased in.

    If past history is any guide, however, legislators relative weighting of

    near-term and long-term funding considerations will be far from optimal.

    Long before the recent financial markets downturn, legislators repeatedly

    valued near-term funding relief for employers above the long-term financing

    health of the pension insurance system. Evidence of this exists in the repeat-

    ed delivery of additional funding relief, including the provision of higher lia-

    bility discount rates in 2002 and 2004 as well as the near-term funding

    relief provided in the 2006 ppa itself. The further funding relief provided in2010 was simply a continuation of a longstanding trend of relieving previ-

    ous law funding requirements whenever they begin to have a significant

    effect on employer finances.

    December 2011 & January 2012 31

    The Private-Sector Pension Predicament

  • 8/3/2019 Policy Review - December 2011 & January 2012, No. 170

    32/93

    32 Policy Review

    There are two important considerations to bear in mind when reforming

    pbgc to better make this judgment call: first, the difficult balancing act of

    weighing employers near-term viability against the pension systems long-

    term funding needs; second, the demonstrated habit of the political systemto subordinate long-term funding considerations to near-term exigencies.

    Reforming the structure of the pbgc system would only address the second

    of these considerations. It would not by itself provide answers to the first set

    of considerations, which must be carefully handled even from the pension

    insurers narrow perspective of self-interest.

    These two sets of considerations are sometimes conflated in the public

    discussion about pension funding requirements. It is often argued, for exam-

    ple, that requiring employers to make significantly larger contributions totheir pension plans would be counterproductive, because doing so might

    actually harm pbgc by triggering additional near-term plan terminations or,

    alternatively, because doing so would interfere with employers abilities to

    create jobs.

    While these arguments can each sound similarly compelling to policy

    maker