pdvthurs1700h.docx

10
Essay Question 2 Many fast food chains pride themselves in offering various menus by adopting various pricing strategies. For example, KFC offers discounts for students while McDonald’s offers 6 -piece nuggets at $4.40 and 9-piece nuggets at $5.70. (a) Explain the factors that are necessary for price discrimina tion to occur. [10] (b) Discuss whether price discrimina tion in the fast food industry is desirable . [15] Suggested Answer Scheme (a) Explain the factors that are necessary for price discriminatio n to occur. [10] Introduction Define price discrimination and state its purpose. Price discrimination is the practice of selling a given product at different prices to different consumers and these price differences are not caused by cost differences. Firms choose to engage in price discrimination as this would enable them to earn higher revenue which in turn would lead to increased profits. Body In order for firms to engage in price discrimination, the firms would need to ensure that the following factors/conditions are met: (Note: these are mandatory conditions that have to met in order to achieve price discrimination, whether 1 st , 2 nd or 3 rd degree price discrimination. For 3 rd degree price discrimination, there are other necessary factors to be considered.) 1) The seller must possess market power. This market power is essential before price discrimination can take place because it gives the firm control over either price or output. To price discriminate, the firm has to control prices by controlling the quantity supplied in the market/sub -market, since they are charging different consumers different prices. This is not to say, however, that the firm must be a monopoly 1 . Any firm that has even the smallest degree of market power faces a downward sloping demand curve (as opposed to the horizontal demand curve faced by price takers); thus, the consumers will have a surplus 1  Note that there is no need for the firm to be a monopoly. Mere market power, i.e. as long as there is no perfect competition, is sufficient. Being a monopoly only makes it easier. These can be seen  from various examples in real life, such as spas a nd salons, which generally opera te as monopolistically competitive firms. Salons for example, often engage in 3 rd degree price discrimination, because they offer lower rates for haircuts (especially for males) for what is essentially the same service.  

Upload: christine-chuah

Post on 14-Apr-2018

227 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 1/10

Essay Question 2

Many fast food chains pride themselves in offering various menus by adopting various pricing

strategies. For example, KFC offers discounts for students while McDonald’s offers 6 -piece nuggets

at $4.40 and 9-piece nuggets at $5.70.

(a) Explain the factors that are necessary for price discrimination to occur. [10]

(b) Discuss whether price discrimination in the fast food industry is desirable. [15]

Suggested Answer Scheme

(a) Explain the factors that are necessary for price discrimination to occur. [10]

Introduction

• Define price discrimination and state its purpose.

Price discrimination is the practice of selling a given product at different prices to different

consumers and these price differences are not caused by cost differences.

Firms choose to engage in price discrimination as this would enable them to earn higher

revenue which in turn would lead to increased profits.

Body

In order for firms to engage in price discrimination, the firms would need to ensure that the

following factors/conditions are met:

(Note: these are mandatory conditions that have to met in order to achieve price

discrimination, whether 1st

, 2nd

or 3rd

degree price discrimination. For 3rd

degree price

discrimination, there are other necessary factors to be considered.)

1) The seller must possess market power.

This market power is essential before price discrimination can take place because it gives

the firm control over either price or output. To price discriminate, the firm has to control

prices by controlling the quantity supplied in the market/sub-market, since they arecharging different consumers different prices.

This is not to say, however, that the firm must be a monopoly1. Any firm that has even the

smallest degree of market power faces a downward sloping demand curve (as opposed to

the horizontal demand curve faced by price takers); thus, the consumers will have a surplus

1 Note that there is no need for the firm to be a monopoly. Mere market power, i.e. as long as there

is no perfect competition, is sufficient. Being a monopoly only makes it easier. These can be seen

 from various examples in real life, such as spas and salons, which generally operate as

monopolistically competitive firms. Salons for example, often engage in 3rd degree price

discrimination, because they offer lower rates for haircuts (especially for males) for what is

essentially the same service. 

Page 2: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 2/10

in the transactions. Price discrimination can transfer at least some of that surplus to the

firm.

Without control over prices, only a single price would prevail in the market, as perfectly

competitive firms (with no market power) must charge whatever price the market dictates

and this would therefore completely undermine price discrimination. The market power canarise from market imperfections, such as barriers to entry, differentiated products,

consumer ignorance, etc.

With reference to the preamble (the fast food industry), firms operate in an oligopolistic

market. As they each sell a differentiated product, each firm has market power over their

specific product. Moreover, these firms have large market power due to their large market

share. They also have the ability to entrench their market power and share, because they

are able to brand themselves effectively (either via advertisement or product differentiation

or even innovation) and hence establish strong artificial barriers to entry.

2) There must be no (or in this case, practically very little) possibility of resale between the

various consumers.

As firms are selling the good to various consumers at different prices, price discrimination

would be undermined if consumers are able to resell goods to other consumers. (arbitrage)

If consumers are able to resell the goods purchased at a lower price to other consumers,

this may actually restore price equality. In a situation of 3rd

degree price discrimination,

where KFC offers students meals: if students can purchase student meals and re-sell them

to adults at higher prices, adults will choose not to buy the KFC at the adult price andinstead, choose to offer a lower price to students (but a price higher than or equal to the

student price in the resale market ). This situation therefore would undermine the price

discrimination conducted by KFC.

In real life, such a situation is unlikely to occur, and hence KFC can price discriminate

because:

i) of the nature of the good sold by the fast food restaurants.

Fast food such as burgers or fried chicken are perishable goods (i.e. they turn coldand stale easily). It is impractical for adults to re-purchase such meals from students

due to the increased likelihood of obtaining a stale meal.

ii) there is no incentive for anyone to sell the set meals as the opportunity costs

of queuing up to get the set meals and finding a buyer might not outweigh the

benefit from selling the burger (at most one or two dollars earned from the resale).

Furthermore, there are also search costs involved. A student willing to sell may not

find it easy to find an adult willing to buy. Negotiation costs may also be a factor.

(What price to sell? What price to accept?)

Page 3: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 3/10

The preamble refers to a situation of third degree price discrimination where consumers are

grouped into two or more independent markets and a separate price is charged in each

market.

In order for 3rd degree price discrimination to occur, there are two other conditions that

have to be met.

1) Markets must be identifiable and separable2.

As firms do not have perfect knowledge and wish to charge different consumers different

prices (because different consumers have different willingness and ability to pay), they will

need to find a way to identify and separate the markets.

In the given context, students can be easily identified and separated from the other

segments of the market by requiring that they show their student identity cards before they

are allowed to purchase their set meals at the cheaper price.

2) For it to be profitable, these separable markets have to have different price elasticities of 

demand.

In the context of fast food industry, the demand for fast food by working adults is less price

elastic than the demand for fast food by students. This is because the price of the set meal

constitutes a smaller proportion of their income.

Students on the other hand get allowances which are arguably smaller. Hence, the price of 

the set meal may make up a larger proportion of their meagre allowances (incomes) fromtheir parents. As a result, students would be more sensitive to price changes, more price

elastic.

Once the firm has determined the profit-maximising output, this output will be distributed

between the two sub-markets. Since the consumers in the two sub-markets have different

willingness and ability to pay, the firm will exploit that by charging them the maximum price

that each sub-group is willing and able to pay. Doing so will allow them to increase their

revenue and correspondingly, profit.

Price discrimination would therefore allow them earn greater revenue in both marketscompared to charging a single price across the two markets.

(Note that production cost should not change as the output does not vary whether under

normal pricing or price discrimination (MC=MR always determines profit-maximising

2 Note that this is also a condition that is necessary for first degree price discrimination. However,

there is a slight difference. In 1st degree price discrimination, all consumers are assumed to be willing

and able to pay different prices. Therefore, all consumers are identifiable and separable EACH as a

separate market, i.e. the consumers can be classified into infinitely separable markets. For second 

degree price discrimination, the seller does not need to exogenously divide the consumers into

classes. The schedule of prices is designed so that each consumer reveals his type by self-selecting a

quantity to purchase with the corresponding marginal price. 

Page 4: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 4/10

output). Therefore, if there are any total cost increases, it should only be due to

administrative costs as a result of the ACT/IMPLEMENTATION of price discrimination.)

(b) Discuss whether price discrimination in the fast food industry is desirable. [15]

IntroductionBriefly state that price discrimination could bring about benefits and costs to the producers,

consumers as well as the society of the fast food industry (stakeholders).

State that the benefits and costs to the producers, consumers and society could be

measured by:

1)  Producers’ profits 

2)  Consumer surplus or consumer welfare or level of consumption

3)  Society – efficiency and equity

Body

Thesis: Price discrimination in the fast food industry is desirable.

[There are two possible approaches here. Students need only offer either to obtain credit.

The preferred approach is explained here, while the alternative approach is placed at the

end of the answer]

PREFERRED APPROACH – 3rd

degree price discrimination

Producers – Increased profit

KFC conducts 3rd

degree price discrimination in a bid to increase total revenue. They do so

by dividing the market into 2 sub-markets: students and non-students (which includes

adults), as explained above.

By engaging in third-degree price discrimination, KFC could earn greater revenue in both

markets than by charging a single price (i.e. P1) across the two sub-markets.

Having determined the profit maximizing output Q1 in the combined market, KFC could

choose to price discriminate or not.

If it chooses not to engage in price discrimination, it would end up earning total revenue of 

the rectangle P1 A Q1 0. Whereas, if it chooses to price discriminate, the firm can further

increase total revenue, (P2 B Q2 0 + P3 C Q3 0) > P1 A Q1 0

To do so, it would extract the value of MC as determined in the combined market and

equate that value separately with the different MRs in the sub-markets. This leads to a

lower price, P2, charged in the student market (corresponding to their lower ability to pay).

Page 5: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 5/10

For non-students (specifically targeted at working adults), their willingness and ability to pay

is higher. Therefore, the firm would exploit this and charge the highest that the consumer is

willing and able to pay for that quantity of goods, P3.3 

As total cost does not change (since output has not changed), profits will rise as a result of 

the increased total revenue.

[Note: depending on where the student has placed the above explanation, they do not need

to repeat themselves but merely refer back if they had done so in (a)]

Consumers

Price discrimination may lead to higher prices paid by non-students and a lower price paid

by students. Hence, consumer surplus falls in the non-student sub-market whereas,

consumer surplus may rise in the student sub-market (the price falls).

The overall effect should be that consumer surplus falls. It is almost always certain that the

fall in consumer surplus in the non-student sub-market will be greater than the rise in

consumer surplus in the student sub-market (on the assumption that there is a rise in

consumer surplus in the student sub-market).

3  When a firm decides to price discriminate, the distribution of the good between the markets will 

change. Before price discrimination, the more demand price elastic consumer group pays a higher 

 price and consumes less, while the less price elastic in demand consumer group pays a lower price

and consumes more. When there is price discrimination, the tables are turned, the less price elastic in

demand consumer group has to pay a higher price and consequently, quantity demanded will fall,

but the more demand price elastic consumer group will experience a lower price and consume more.

Diagram 2: Third Degree Price Discrimination

 AR

MC

MR

Price ($) Price ($)

QtyQty Qty

MRy

 ARy

Q2

MRx  ARx

Price ($)

Q3Q1

P3

P2

MC

P1

Non-student sub-market 

0 0 0

 A B

C

Students sub-market 

Page 6: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 6/10

Society

Allows loss making firm to continue production

Price discrimination is particularly desirable when firms are unable to make normal profits in

the long run (cannot survive, hence shut down and discontinue production). Price

discrimination increases the level of total revenue that can be earned, which may allow thefirm to earn normal profit in the long run, ensuring firm survival.

This means that goods which would not have been produced due to high costs of 

production can now be produced. The gain in total revenue from price discrimination is

therefore extremely important in an industry where the average cost of production is higher

than the price that consumers are willing and able to pay at all levels of output.

Greater level of equity

As a result of different prices, some consumers are better off but some consumers are

worse off. Those who are willing and able to pay, pay higher prices and those who are less

willing, pay lower prices.

More revenue for innovation

The discriminating producer enjoys higher revenue and thus profits. This benefits society

and consumers if these profits are re-invested on innovation, i.e. R&D leading to cost

savings or product improvements.

Analyse here: It is arguable whether fast food restaurants can conduct substantial

innovation and hence improve their product. Often their product improvements are

superficial, for example, different sauces, different flavours. It is hard to imagine how the

profits can be re-invested to substantially improve consumer welfare, whether via a better

product or offering greater choice and variety. Most likely, the consumer and society will

simply lose out, since it is most likely that profits and income are redistributed towards theproducer.

 AR

MC

MR

Price ($)

QtyQ1

MC

P1

0

 AC

Page 7: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 7/10

 

Anti-thesis: Price discrimination in the fast food industry is UNdesirable.

Consumers and Society

The root of the undesirability of price discrimination lies in the fact that consumer surplus isgouged for the benefit of producers. Students can therefore link this idea to inequity as

mentioned in the previous paragraph.

Further loss in allocative efficiency

When a firm engages in 3rd

degree price discrimination, output does not increase over the

level of the nondiscriminating firm. Rather, relative to the nondiscriminating firm, the profit

maximizing output is simply redistributed among consumers. In this situation, any

deadweight loss that had existed with no discrimination still exists. (Remember that when a

firm with market power profit maximizes, they equate MR=MC, but because P=AR > MR,P>MC!)

There is, however, an additional welfare cost caused by the allocation of the good from

those whose willingness to pay is higher to those whose willingness to pay is lower4. In

other words, in this case, third-degree price discrimination is less efficient than no price

discrimination.

[Advanced: Hal Varian (a famous mathematical economist) has also argued that social

welfare will increase under third-degree price discrimination if the ability to discriminate

induces the firm to serve a new market, i.e. causes output to increase. If the single-pricefirm would choose not to serve a small market without the existence of price discrimination,

the act of price discrimination would result in the same quantity produced for the large

market and a positive quantity for the small market, resulting in a welfare gain.]

As these fast food joints are large firms which could earn supernormal profits even if there

is no price discrimination, the practice of price discrimination could worsen inequity since it

results in a redistribution of income from the consumer to the producer.

As price discrimination leads to higher profits for firms, this may lead to firms becoming

increasingly complacent and slack. If the firm can earn supernormal profit as a result of theprice discrimination, they may not find the need to keep costs at a minimum (X-

inefficiency).

Analyse here: However, these firms operate in an oligopolistic market structure. While price

competition is avoided, these firms do occasionally engage in pricing strategies. The

likelihood of X-inefficiency is unlikely, because this would affect their ability to compete on

price.

4 Please see footnote 3 for the clarification on this point.

Page 8: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 8/10

Here students may wish to link back to the point where profits are not re-invested into

product innovation.

Conclusion

Whether price discrimination is desirable may depend on the underlying purpose of their

actions. For example, if price discrimination seeks to increase total revenue so that the firmcan make normal profits, this situation is obviously desirable because it will not deprive

consumers of a good that otherwise cannot be produced.

Furthermore, how much consumer surplus is transferred to the producer may be a factor.

For example, whether the firm was already earning large amounts of supernormal profit

initially. This would only worsen the inequity already present in the society.

Students may also wish to question where the increased profits end up, in the hands of 

shareholders or are they redistributed in a different manner.

To illustrate the second point (though not relevant to this question), some pharmaceutical

companies actively conduct price discrimination on certain types of drugs (especially drugs

that combat AIDS or symptoms of AIDS). Often, prices of such drugs in the USA are very

exorbitant, while the prices of the same drugs are priced very cheaply in Africa. This is called

cross-subsidisation. Obviously, this is not relevant to the fast food industry, but a

comparison can be drawn in terms of whether this example of price discrimination can be

“desirable”. 

Page 9: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 9/10

2nd degree price discrimination approach

(note that this is a weak argument, because this example exemplifies bulk buying, rather than block pricing. This means that the consumer cannot buy 5 nuggets or 8 nuggets and pay thecorresponding price of $3.65 or $5.26)5 

The firm/McDonald’s charges different prices for different blocks of the same good/nuggets

according to the amount the consumer buys.

It sets the same price for the initial 6 nuggets sold ($0.73 cents per nugget) then a cheaperprice of $0.43 per nugget until the 9th unit. This is therefore a form of tiered pricing that is

derived from demand theory and the law of diminishing marginal returns from

consumption. The first few units of nuggets consumed tends to bring higher levels of 

satisfaction to a consumer. As a consumer consumes more of the same unit, his satisfaction

from subsequent units will diminish, which explains why they are more likely to demand the

good at a lower price. This lower price seeks to incentivize consumers buy more units of the

same good.

In the above diagram, price discrimination will allow the firm to increase revenue as they

are able to extract consumer surplus, by charging a higher initial price. There is a transfer of 

the shaded area from consumer surplus to producer revenue, which leads to an increase in

profits, ceteris paribus.

Consumer

5 Based on current McDonald’s prices, McDonald’s pricing scheme is actually based on bulk pricing,

rather than block pricing (i.e. 2nd  degree price discrimination). McDonald’s sells 6, 9 and 20 pieces at 

$4.50, $5.95 and $11.50 correspondingly. If the scheme is based on 2nd  degree price discrimination,

this means that they sell the first 6 units at $0.90 each, the next three pieces at $0.48 cents each and 

the next 11 pieces at $0.50 each. Rather, what McDonald’s is doing is charging $0.90 cents per unit 

 for 6 pieces, $0.66 cents per unit for 9 pieces and $0.575 cents per unit for 20 pieces. 

Q2

D

$0.73

$0.43

Q1

Price (per unit nugget)

Quantity

Page 10: PDvThurs1700h.docx

7/27/2019 PDvThurs1700h.docx

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/pdvthurs1700hdocx 10/10

As a result, consumer surplus falls (to the detriment of the consumer). However, consumer

welfare/satisfaction can rise because of the increased levels of consumption, more units of 

nuggets ingested.