migration, unemployment and discrimination

19
European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409 – 427 www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase Migration, unemployment and discrimination Tobias M uller Department of Econometrics, University of Geneva, 40 bd du Pont-d’Arve, 1211 Geneva 4, Switzerland Received 1 July 1998; accepted 1 May 2001 Abstract This paper uses a dynamic eciency-wage model to analyze the consequences of immigration for a small country when there is discrimination against immigrants in a dual labor market with unemployment. Discrimination is of the type ‘equal pay for equal work, but unequal work’ which is characteristic of economies with ‘guest-worker’ systems. The model exhibits three regimes for rising immigration levels. Immigration is most benecial for natives in the intermediate regime. An analysis of regime switches shows that changes attributable to ‘globalization’ and technical progress are consistent with growing opposition to immigration. c 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. JEL classication: F22; J41; J42; J71 Keywords: Migration; Dual labor market; Eciency wages; Discrimination 1. Introduction Attitudes towards immigration are shaped, to a great extent, by its economic con- sequences for residents of the host country. In the 1970s, it was often argued that migrants do not compete with natives on the labor market as they are forced to hold unattractive jobs. More recently, in a context of high and persistent unemployment in Europe, the fear of increased unemployment is often invoked in public discussions on immigration. Was the rise in unemployment responsible for the turn towards more restrictive immigration policies in Europe, or are there other factors, such as ‘global- ization’, to be blamed? According to standard models of immigration, unemployment seems to be the ideal culprit. Indeed, if the labor market is competitive with full employment, immigration yields a surplus for the host country (Berry and Soligo, Tel: +41-22-705-82-38; fax: +41-22-705-82-99. E-mail address: [email protected] (T. M uller). 0014-2921/03/$ - see front matter c 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved. PII: S0014-2921(01)00177-5

Upload: tobias-mueller

Post on 01-Nov-2016

218 views

Category:

Documents


5 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427www.elsevier.com/locate/econbase

Migration, unemployment and discriminationTobias M$uller∗

Department of Econometrics, University of Geneva, 40 bd du Pont-d’Arve,1211 Geneva 4, Switzerland

Received 1 July 1998; accepted 1 May 2001

Abstract

This paper uses a dynamic e*ciency-wage model to analyze the consequences of immigrationfor a small country when there is discrimination against immigrants in a dual labor market withunemployment. Discrimination is of the type ‘equal pay for equal work, but unequal work’ whichis characteristic of economies with ‘guest-worker’ systems. The model exhibits three regimes forrising immigration levels. Immigration is most bene5cial for natives in the intermediate regime.An analysis of regime switches shows that changes attributable to ‘globalization’ and technicalprogress are consistent with growing opposition to immigration.c© 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.

JEL classi%cation: F22; J41; J42; J71

Keywords: Migration; Dual labor market; E*ciency wages; Discrimination

1. Introduction

Attitudes towards immigration are shaped, to a great extent, by its economic con-sequences for residents of the host country. In the 1970s, it was often argued thatmigrants do not compete with natives on the labor market as they are forced to holdunattractive jobs. More recently, in a context of high and persistent unemploymentin Europe, the fear of increased unemployment is often invoked in public discussionson immigration. Was the rise in unemployment responsible for the turn towards morerestrictive immigration policies in Europe, or are there other factors, such as ‘global-ization’, to be blamed? According to standard models of immigration, unemploymentseems to be the ideal culprit. Indeed, if the labor market is competitive with fullemployment, immigration yields a surplus for the host country (Berry and Soligo,

∗ Tel: +41-22-705-82-38; fax: +41-22-705-82-99.E-mail address: [email protected] (T. M$uller).

0014-2921/03/$ - see front matter c© 2001 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.PII: S0 0 1 4 -2 9 2 1 (01)00177 -5

Page 2: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

410 T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427

1969). By contrast, if unemployment occurs due to a minimum-income guarantee,immigration increases unemployment and reduces the natives’ income (Brecher andChoudhri, 1987; Faini and Grether, 1997).

These approaches remain, however, unsatisfying not only with respect to their ex-planation of unemployment, but also because they neglect the existence of covert dis-crimination against immigrants. Indeed, it is often argued that immigrants and nativesdo not have equal access to ‘good’ jobs, especially in countries having adopted a‘guest-worker’ system. This form of discrimination against immigrants has been docu-mented in many studies (e.g. Piore, 1979; Hammar, 1985). 1

The objective of this paper is to explore the welfare consequences of immigra-tion in the context of a ‘representative’ European labor market by using a dynamice*ciency-wage model of a dual labor market in the tradition of Shapiro and Stiglitz(1984), Bulow and Summers (1986) and Kimball (1994). In this model, unemploymentresults from the assumption that primary-sector employers hire only the unemployed,but not workers holding secondary-sector jobs. Instead of postulating that native andforeign labor are imperfect substitutes, I assume in this paper that migrants diIerfrom natives only by a positive probability of return to their home country; 2 in allother respects, they are assumed to be identical to natives. As 5rms perceive the dif-ference between the two groups, this leads to discriminatory hiring behavior in ane*ciency-wage model, because the incentive not to shirk depends on the expectedtime-horizon of workers, and therefore on their return probability. Since competitionensures that 5rms do not pay diIerent wage rates to diIerent groups of workers, dis-crimination against immigrants shows up as unequal access to ‘good’ jobs. In sucha context, immigration aIects not only factor prices, as in the neoclassical model ofimmigration, but also employment opportunities of natives. One might expect immi-gration to reduce the share of natives working in the secondary sector. On the otherhand, native unemployment is also likely to increase.

It turns out that this e*ciency-wage model, embedded in a standard Ricardo–Vinermodel with sector-speci5c capital, provides a plausible representation of the Europeanpolicy stance towards immigrants. In particular, natives bene5t most from immigrationwhen there is sectoral segregation between immigrants and natives. The critical levelof the immigration stock at which maximum segregation occurs depends on structuralparameters and on the economic environment. The rising opposition to immigrationcan be linked to a fall in this critical level, which is due in particular to increasedinternational integration, to technical progress in the primary sector and, albeit to asmaller extent, to the rise in unemployment.

1 One consequence of this form of discrimination is the diIerent sectoral distribution of natives and immi-grants. Zimmermann (1994) documents this fact for the ‘guest-worker’ countries Germany and Switzerlandwhere immigrants are heavily represented in construction and manufacturing. By contrast, the sectoral dis-tribution of natives and immigrants are very similar in the United States.

2 The empirical evidence on return migration is discussed below in Section 4. In guest-worker countries,immigrants expect to remain a limited time in the host country because of the risk that the work permitis not renewed. Other motives for return migration would include: life in the host country turns out to bediIerent from expectations; the migrant’s family in the source country experiences problems.

Page 3: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427 411

In an independent contribution which appeared while this paper was under revision,Carter (1999) analyzes the role of (illegal) immigration in an e*ciency-wage modelwith dual labor markets. While they are close in spirit, there are important diIerencesbetween the two papers. Most importantly, the welfare analysis is carried out below ina dynamic framework, assuming gradual employment changes, which leads to diIerentresults from Carter (1999) who compares aggregate welfare indicators across steadystates and thereby neglects the issue of transition. Other authors have accounted eitherfor unemployment or for discrimination in the analysis of immigration, though in adiIerent framework. 3

The remainder of this article is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the dynamice*ciency-wage model of a dual labor market with unemployment and derives themodel’s regimes that appear with the presence of immigrants. Section 3 discusses thewelfare consequences of immigration in each model regime within a dynamic frame-work. In Section 4, the model is calibrated and its empirical implications are discussed.Section 5 examines the inMuence of increased unemployment, globalization and tech-nical progress on the attitudes towards immigration.

2. A model of dual labor markets and unemployment

Here, the distinctive characteristic of migrants is their probability of return migrationto their home country; in all other respects, they are assumed to be identical to natives.The return probability, �, is assumed to be exogenous and constant through time. 4

Thus, the migrants’ expected time of stay in the host country is (1=�). Moreover, atany instant of time, new immigrants arrive and replace those who leave, so that thetotal stock of migrants remains constant (steady-state assumption).

The dual labor market is modeled in a dynamic e*ciency-wage framework. 5 Workconditions in the primary and the secondary sectors are not identical. The primarysector oIers jobs with good working conditions and stable employment relationships.By assumption, workers in this sector cannot be perfectly monitored. Thus, 5rms preferto pay wages above market-clearing levels in order to induce workers to supply eIort.As a consequence, jobs are rationed in the primary sector and workers are queuing

3 Ethier (1985) shows how the hiring of immigrants can insulate native workers from employment Muctua-tions. There is discrimination against immigrants in the sense that only natives have long-term, implicit laborcontracts, whereas immigrants are hired freely at the current wage rate. Schmidt et al. (1994) analyze theimpact of immigration in the presence of trade unions in the market for unskilled labor. Winter-Ebmer andZweim$uller (1996) use an insider–outsider model of wage bargaining to evaluate the impact of immigrationon wages of young natives. By contrast to the present paper, they assume the existence of a two-tier wagesystem, where immigrants (outsiders) receive lower wages than native workers (insiders).

4 Note that this simplifying assumption is a continuous-time version of the hypothesis adopted by Galorand Stark (1990, 1991) in a discrete-time overlapping-generations framework. They discuss the impact ofthe probability of return on migrants’ savings decisions and work eIort.

5 The basic structure of this model builds on Kimball (1994), who analyzed the dynamics of the Shapiroand Stiglitz (1984) model. By contrast to Kimball, I assume the simultaneous existence of a dual labormarket and of unemployment, as proposed (in a static framework) by Bulow and Summers (1986), Jones(1987) and Perrot and Zylberberg (1989).

Page 4: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

412 T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427

up for them. However, they can always 5nd jobs in the secondary sector. These jobsare much less attractive and consist in repetitive tasks that can be monitored withoutcost. The wage rate is set competitively in this sector. Unemployment is introducedinto the model by assuming that primary-sector 5rms hire only unemployed workers. 6

In this model unemployment is involuntary in the sense that the unemployed wouldprefer to hold primary-sector jobs. However, the unemployed can always 5nd jobs inthe secondary sector.

Workers are assumed to be risk-neutral and to have identical instantaneous utilityfunctions, of the following form: u(c1; c2; e) = �(c1; c2) − e, where c1 and c2 are theconsumption levels of the two traded goods, � is a homothetic quasi-concave function,and e denotes eIort. The variable e can take only two values: 0 if the worker does notmake an eIort (i.e. if he ‘shirks’), and e¿ 0 if he does not shirk. The indirect utilityfunction is given by v(p1; p2; w; yo; e) = [(w + yo)= (p1; p2)] − e, where is a priceindex dual to �; p1 and p2 are goods prices, w is the wage rate, and yo is incomefrom other sources (e.g. capital income). Workers are assumed to maximize expectedutility over their in5nite life horizon, using discount rate r. 7

The problem of a worker in the primary sector, who has to decide whether toshirk or not, can be analyzed by relating the utility levels that he can attain in thetwo cases. Let V s

1 (V n1 ) denote the expected present value of utility of a shirking

(non-shirking) worker holding a primary-sector job. Likewise, V2 denotes expected util-ity of a secondary-sector job, Vu the corresponding value if the worker is unemployed,and V ∗ the (exogenous) utility of living in the home country (only for migrants). Torelate these situations, the asset-equation approach introduced by Shapiro and Stiglitz(1984) is followed. Following Kimball (1994), it is assumed that primary-sector em-ployment, and thus utility, change gradually (see Section 3 for further discussion of thisissue). A worker who shirks faces a probability d per unit time of being discoveredand 5red. There is an exogenous probability q per unit time for each primary-sectorjob to end; in that case the worker becomes unemployed. The probability of leavingthe country is � (where � = 0 for natives and � = � for migrants). If a worker has ajob in the primary sector, he receives wage w1 and expects a utility gain of V̇ 1 (wherethe dot designates a derivative with respect to time). He will earn the following return,according to whether he shirks or not:

rV n1 = (w1 + yo)= (p1; p2) − e − q(V n

1 − Vu) − �(V n1 − V ∗) + V̇ n

1 ; (1)

rV s1 = (w1 + yo)= (p1; p2) − (q + d)(V s

1 − Vu) − �(V s1 − V ∗) + V̇ s

1: (2)

A worker in the primary-sector does not shirk if V n1 ¿V s

1 . At equilibrium, there isno shirking and this condition holds with equality since there is no reason for aprimary-sector 5rm to pay a higher wage. Using Eqs. (1) and (2), it can be rewritten

6 This formulation has been suggested by Bulow and Summers (1986) who argue that if there are unob-servable diIerences between workers (with respect to their quit rates, or their preferences for primary-sectorwork), signaling considerations would lead primary-sector 5rms to hire only the unemployed.

7 For simplicity, agents are assumed to consume their entire current income at each period. Thus theinMuence of the return probability on the savings decision is neglected (on this issue, see Galor and Stark(1990)).

Page 5: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427 413

as follows:

d(V n1 − Vu) = e: (3)

The term on the left represents the cost of shirking, equal to the expected utility lossof a shirker whose probability of being detected and 5red is equal to d. A worker doesnot shirk if this cost is greater than the immediate bene5t of shirking, which consistsin avoiding any eIort.

If workers are unemployed, they receive unemployment compensation Tw and haveprobability � per unit time of 5nding a primary-sector job (� will take diIerentvalues for natives and migrants, as shown below), and probability �2 of 5nding asecondary-sector job. For simplicity, I assume that unemployment compensation is5nanced by a non-distortionary tax on capital income. For an unemployed worker,the return is 8

rVu =Tw + yo

(p1; p2)− e + �(V n

1 − Vu) + �2(V2 − Vu) − �(Vu − V ∗) + V̇ u : (4)

If a worker holds a secondary-sector job, he is (by assumption) not able to 5nd a jobin the primary sector. Therefore, the return to a secondary-sector job is given by

rV2 =w2 + yo

(p1; p2)− e − q2(V2 − Vu) − �(V2 − V ∗) + V̇ 2; (5)

where q2 is the exogenous probability of job breakup in the secondary sector.Using (1) and (4), and noting that (3) implies V̇ n

1 = V̇ u, the no-shirking conditioncan also be expressed as

w1 − Tw (p1; p2)

=ed

(r + � + � + q): (6)

A worker only accepts a job in the secondary sector if V2¿Vu. If this condition issatis5ed, it holds with equality because of competition among workers. Using (4) and(5), this condition becomes

w2 − Tw (p1; p2)

=e�d

: (7)

The probability of moving from unemployment to a primary-sector job, �, can berelated to the variables of the model through Mow conditions. Because of the probabilityof return migration, this probability diIers for the two population groups. Let a (a∗)denote the value � takes for natives (migrants). For native workers, the Mow out ofthe primary sector is qL1, where L1 is native employment in the primary sector. Thusnew hirings in the primary sector are qL1 + L̇1. These must be equal to aU , the Mowout of unemployment, where U is native unemployment. A native worker’s probability

8 It is assumed here that the unemployed supply the same eIort as employed workers (e.g. trainingprograms, mandatory public work, job search eIorts). No qualitative result depends on this assumption(which is adopted implicitly by Bulow and Summers (1986)). Indeed, the case where the unemployed donot make any eIort can be obtained simply by assuming that unemployment bene5ts are given in real termsby w̃= = ( Tw= ) − e, instead of Tw= .

Page 6: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

414 T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427

of 5nding a primary-sector job is therefore given by

a = (qL1 + L̇1)=U: (8)

Taking into account the return probability, the analogous condition for migrants is

a∗ = [(q + �)L∗1 + L̇∗

1 ]=U ∗; (9)

where L∗1 (U ∗) is primary-sector employment (unemployment) of migrants.

Finally, the e*ciency-wage model is embedded in a speci5c-factors (Ricardo–Viner)model, often believed to be the privileged model to study the impact of internationaltrade or factor movements on income distribution. The sector-speci5c factor is assumedto be capital. Labor is mobile between the two sectors, but the primary sector oIersonly ‘good’ jobs, paying e*ciency-wages w1, whereas the secondary sector oIers only‘bad’ jobs, paying wages w2. Both sectors are characterized by representative 5rmswith constant returns to scale producing traded goods. Following the small countryassumption, relative prices of traded goods are given. With pro5t maximization by5rms, and assuming that gross hiring never becomes negative, wage rates are equal tothe marginal product of labor at every point in time:

wi = pifiL(Ki; Li + L∗

i ); i = 1; 2; (10)

where fi is the production function of sector i and fiL denotes the partial derivative of

fi with respect to L. The equilibrium of the model is de5ned by (un)employment andwage trajectories which satisfy Eqs. (6)–(10), where secondary-sector employment ofnatives (migrants) is L2 = L − L1 − U (L∗

2 = L∗ − L∗1 − U ∗).

The capital stocks of both sectors are assumed to be entirely owned by natives. Inthe absence of 5nancial assets, agents consume their current income and thus tradeis balanced at any moment. A convenient choice for the numVeraire is (p1; p2) = 1,implying that unemployment compensation, Tw, is 5xed in real terms.

Competition between 5rms in each sector ensures that 5rms do not pay diIerent wagerates to diIerent groups of workers. As a consequence, natives and migrants cannot bothbe simultaneously in the primary and secondary sectors, since Eqs. (6) and (7) cannotbe satis5ed simultaneously for natives (�=a; �=0) and migrants (�=a∗; �=�). Thiscan be seen by considering the following three cases. First, if secondary-sector jobsare held by migrants and natives, Eq. (7) implies a∗ = a. Then Eqs. (6) cannot holdfor both natives and migrants, since �¿ 0. In this case, primary-sector 5rms prefer tohire only natives because the wage level that prevents them from shirking is lower.Second, there is the possibility of complete segregation where all natives work in theprimary sector and all migrants in the secondary sector. Third, primary-sector 5rmshire migrants alongside natives if a∗ + � = a. Then the condition �¿ 0 implies a¿a∗

and secondary-sector 5rms hire only migrants (assuming there are enough migrants)since they would have to oIer higher wages in order to attract natives. No otherconstellations than these three are compatible with the constraints of the model.

An obvious question is whether the three cases indicate the existence of multiplesteady states. In M$uller (2000) it is shown that these cases are mutually exclusive.Thus they represent diIerent model regimes; for a given level of immigration, onlyone regime applies. Indeed, rising immigration levels lead to the following steady-state

Page 7: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427 415

Fig. 1. Immigration level, wage rates and model regimes.

outcomes. Immigrants 5rst drive natives out of the secondary sector, then spread fromthe secondary sector to the primary sector (and thus to unemployment). The resultingmodel regimes can be described as follows (see also Fig. 1).Regime I (immigrants in secondary sector): If only a small number of immigrants

are present in the host country, the wage diIerential between the two sectors is notsu*cient to induce immigrants not to shirk. Thus primary-sector 5rms will not hirethem and, having no incentive to become unemployed, they all work in the secondarysector. With increasing immigration levels native employment in the secondary sectorfalls and ultimately the economy will reach a point where only immigrants work in thesecondary sector. This is due to the 5xed wage diIerential between the two sectors.Regime II (immigrants in secondary sector and natives in primary sector): In this

regime there is complete segregation between natives, all of whom work in the pri-mary sector or are unemployed, and immigrants who only work in the secondary sector.The wage diIerential is no longer 5xed and the immigrants’ (secondary-sector) wagefalls with immigration, because of decreasing marginal labor productivity, whereasthe primary-sector wage remains constant, since natives are not aIected by immigra-tion. This regime rationalizes the commonplace argument that immigrants do jobs thatnatives do not want to do.Regime III (no natives in secondary sector): At a certain immigration level primary-

sector employers agree to hire immigrants because the wage diIerential is su*cientlylarge to prevent them from shirking. Therefore, in the third regime immigrants workin both sectors (and are unemployed) whereas natives work only in the primary sectorand are unemployed.

It is now clear that migrants as a group suIer from sectoral segregation, despite thefact that natives and migrants are equally productive. Moreover, segregation results indiscrimination, as the migrants’ average wage is lower than the natives’.

Note that in regimes I and III, wage rates in the primary and secondary sectors arelinked. Deducting Eq. (7) from (6) yields a 5xed wage diIerential between the primary

Page 8: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

416 T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427

and the secondary sector, as follows:

w1 − w2

(p1; p2)=

ed

(r + q + �) (11)

with � = 0 (� = �) in the 5rst (third) regime. In regime II, there is no such relation.

3. Dynamics and welfare consequences of immigration

It is well known that in an e*ciency-wage model, the equilibrium is ine*cientsince primary-sector employment is too low and unemployment too high (Bulow andSummers, 1986). While an employment subsidy in the primary sector would increasenational income, it would not necessarily be Pareto-improving (Shapiro and Stiglitz,1984) and is not generally adopted because of its inequitable nature. Hence it isassumed that no such scheme is implemented at the initial equilibrium; there is thusscope for immigration to have a 5rst-order eIect on the welfare of natives. 9

However, the welfare impact depends on the adjustment path towards the new steadystate. As Kimball (1994) showed, the dynamic Shapiro and Stiglitz (1984) model hasa multiplicity of equilibria. Which equilibrium (path) should be selected? Bulow andSummers (1986) assume implicitly that employment variables jump instantaneously totheir new steady states. The problem with this assumption is that it is not robust withrespect to the introduction of adjustment costs. Thus Kimball (1994) argues that, amongthe multiplicity of equilibria, the one equilibrium where (primary-sector) employmentchanges gradually can be singled out, because it represents the unique limit of a modelwith adjustment costs, as these adjustment costs go to zero (Georges, 1995). In thissection, this equilibrium path is derived for the three regimes 10 and its reaction to anexogenous arrival of immigrants is analyzed.

The result of this section can be summarized as follows (see also Table 1). Theimpact of immigration on native welfare is similar in regimes I and III, despite im-portant diIerences in steady-state properties. In both regimes, the welfare of nativeworkers (owning no capital) falls with immigration as wages decrease, despite the factthat native primary-sector employment increases with immigration in regime I, but fallsin regime III. By contrast, in regime II immigration has a positive eIect on capitalincome without deteriorating the situation of native workers.Regime I: Wage diIerentials are determined by the behavior of natives, as im-

migrants only hold secondary-sector jobs. Thus the 5rst regime can be described byEqs. (6), (8), (10), and (11), with � = 0, � = a, and L∗

1 = U ∗ = 0. The evolution of

9 Moreover, it is assumed that the ‘immigration surplus’, which appears because of the variation of factorprices due to the 5xed supply of capital, cannot be redistributed from capital owners to workers. Indeed, ifthe redistribution scheme is not discriminatory, i.e. if migrant workers are entitled to the same bene5ts asnative workers, the surplus vanishes and immigration produces a net loss (Razin and Sadka, 1995; Wellischand Walz, 1998).

10 Note that Eqs. (1), (2), (4) and (5) were written assuming a continuous adjustment of primary-sectoremployment.

Page 9: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427 417

Table 1Qualitative eIects of immigrationa

Variable Immigration level (L∗)b

L∗ ¡L̃∗ L̃∗6 L∗6 TL∗ L∗ ¿ TL∗Regime I Regime II Regime III

t = 0 t = ∞ t = 0 t = ∞ t = 0 t = ∞Primary-sector wage (w1) 0 − 0 0 0 −Second.-sector wage (w2) 0 − − − 0 −

NativesPrimary employm. (L1) 0 + 0 0 0 −Second. employm. (L2) − −Unemployment (U ) + + 0 0 0 +

ImmigrantsPrimary employm. (L∗1 ) 0 +Second. employm. (L∗2 ) + + + + 0 +Unemployment rate (U∗) + +

aMarginal eIects upon impact (t=0) and in the steady state (t=∞). The sign + indicates that in5nitesimalimmigration has a positive (− negative; 0 no) impact on a variable. An empty 5eld indicates that the variableis zero in this regime.

bL̃∗ and TL∗ designate the immigration levels that delimit the three model regimes.

primary-sector employment can be derived from (6) and (8), as follows:

L̇1 =[de

(w1 − Tw) − (r + q)]U − qL1: (12)

This equation reMects the intuition that primary-sector 5rms delay the hiring of newworkers in an expansion (induced by immigration, for example) because of e*ciency-wage considerations: if all 5rms increased their hirings simultaneously, 5rms wouldhave to pay higher wages to induce their workers not to shirk.

A few manipulations are needed in order to express the right-hand side of (12) asa sole function of L1. Note 5rst that U = L − L1 − L2. Inverting (10) yields L2 =g2(w2=p2)− L∗

2 , where g2 denotes the inverse function of f2L. Furthermore, from (11),

w2 = w1 − (e=d)(r + q), such that L2 = g2{[p1f1L − (r + q)e=d]=p2} − L∗

2 . Since in thisregime L∗

2 = L∗, the evolution of L1 can be expressed as follows:

L̇1 =[de

(p1f1

L − Tw)− (r + q)

]

[L + L∗ − L1 − g2

(p1f1

L − (e=d)(r + q)p2

)]− qL1; (13)

where f1L = f1

L(K1; L1).

Page 10: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

418 T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427

Consider 5rst the steady state. Immigration ‘crowds out’ native employment inthe secondary sector because immigrants are forced to work there. Thus immigrationincreases primary-sector employment of natives, as can be seen by diIerentiatingEq. (13) at the steady state (L̇1 = 0):

dL1

dL∗ =�1

�1| 1w|

¿ 0; �1 =(

1 +UL1

)(�1

| 1w|

+�1

!1

)+ (1 + "w)

�2

| 2w|

; (14)

where �i is the share of sector i employment in total labor force, iw = pifiLL(Li +

L∗i )=wi is the elasticity of inverse labor demand in sector i, !1 is the elasticity of w1

with respect to L1 in the no-shirking condition, 11 and "w = (w1=w2) − 1. Through itsimpact on total labor supply, immigration pushes wage rates down: d log w1=d log(L +L∗) = −1=�1 ¡ 0. The intuition for these results can be gained from the conventionalspeci5c-factors model without distortions, which can be obtained as a special case of(14) by setting U="w=0 and !1 → ∞. In such a model, the elasticity of primary-sectoremployment with respect to an increase in the labor force is, loosely speaking, equalto the ratio of the elasticity of labor demand in the primary sector (in fact, 1= 1

w) tothe average labor demand elasticity (�1= 1

w + �2= 2w). Note that �1 is greater than the

latter expression in absolute value, because the increase in unemployment mitigates theemployment and wage eIects of immigration. Indeed, native unemployment increasesproportionally even more than primary-sector employment, ensuring that natives do notshirk in spite of the fall in primary-sector wages. Because of the change in compositionof native employment, the average native wage decreases less with immigration thansectoral wage rates; in some cases it might even rise. 12

The impact of diIerent policies on native welfare can be evaluated by consider-ing the reaction of a primary-sector worker’s expected life-time utility to a marginalincrease in the stock of immigrants at time t0. Indeed, the natives’ indiIerence betweensecondary-sector jobs and unemployment and Eq. (3) imply that dVu = dV2 = dV1. Thepath of a primary-sector worker’s expected utility can be described by the followingequation, derived from (1) and (3):

V̇ n1 = rV n

1 − (p1f1L + yo) + (e=d)(q + d): (15)

The dynamics of primary-sector employment and native welfare can be analyzed in aphase diagram (Fig. 2), depicting Eqs. (13) and (15). Immigration shifts the L̇1=0 locusto the right without aIecting the V̇ 1 = 0 locus. Thus the slope of the latter is decisivefor the welfare impact of immigration: if it is positive (negative), immigration has abene5cial (detrimental) impact on the welfare of native workers. This slope dependson the assumptions about the distribution of capital among natives. I will consider thefollowing two polar assumptions: (a) workers do not own any capital (yo = 0) andowners of capital form a separate population group; (b) capital is distributed equallyamong native workers, such that yo = (p1f1

KK1 + p2f2KK2)=L.

11 In the de5nition of !1, L2 is assumed constant. The no-shirking condition (6) can be written as w1 =(e=d)[r + q(L − L2)=(L − L1 − L2)] + Tw, such that !1 = eqL1(L − L2)=(U 2w1d).

12 From this steady-state property, one may be tempted to conclude (Carter, 1999) that in regime I immi-gration could enhance the welfare of native workers. Such a result is, however, based on the questionableassumption that the variables jump instantaneously to their new steady-state values.

Page 11: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427 419

Fig. 2. Dynamics of adjustment to immigration (regime I).

Under assumption (a), the slope of the V̇ 1 =0 locus is unambiguously negative sincef1

LL ¡ 0. It is clear from Fig. 2 that in this case native workers unambiguously losefrom immigration (and capital owners gain). Under assumption (b), the slope of theV̇ 1 = 0 locus is equal to 13

dV n1 =dL1 = (1=r)[d(w1 + yo)=dL1] = −(1=r)p1f1

LL[(L∗=L) − (U=L)]: (16)

To put this result into perspective, recall that in a conventional speci5c-factors modelwithout distortions, d(w1 +yo)=dL1 =−p1f1

LL(L∗=L), reMecting the fact that in the pres-ence of L∗ immigrants at the initial equilibrium, additional (in5nitesimal) immigrationleads to a redistribution of income from these immigrants towards native capital own-ers, through the variation of factor prices. This is the mechanism that underlies theBerry and Soligo (1969) result saying that 5nite immigration yields an aggregate gainfor natives. Thus a distinguishing feature of the e*ciency-wage model is the pres-ence of the unemployment rate in Eq. (16). In the redistribution process induced byimmigration, unemployment represents a ‘leak’ since the unemployed receive (by as-sumption) a share of the increased capital income. As a consequence, the smaller theunemployment rate, the greater chances are that additional immigration has a bene5cialimpact on the welfare of natives.

Now turn to the dynamic adjustment process. Assume that the economy is initially ina steady state (L0

1; V01 ). A sudden arrival of immigrants (instantaneous increase in L∗)

has the following immediate eIects. Primary-sector employment is not aIected uponimpact. Thus, (10) and (11) imply that in both sectors wage rates do not move, and thattotal secondary-sector employment does not change either. However, the welfare of na-tive workers drops upon impact (see Fig. 2). The new immigrants are hired immediatelyin the secondary sector, whereas an identical number of native secondary-sector workersbecome unemployed. Indeed, in contrast to migrants who have no chance of 5nding aprimary-sector job, natives are indiIerent between unemployment and secondary-sector

13 Indeed, d(w1 +yo)=p1[f1

LL + (K1=L)f1KL

]dL1 +p2(K2=L)f2

KL(dL2 +dL∗2 ). Because of constant returnsto scale: K1f1

KL = −L1f1LL and K2f2

KL = −(L2 + L∗2 )f2LL. Furthermore, dL2 + dL∗2 = g′2(·)(p1=p2)f1

LL dL1,where g′2(·) = (1=f2

LL). Thus: d(w1 + yo)=dL1 = (p1f1LL=L)(L − L1 − L2 − L∗2 ), leading to (16).

Page 12: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

420 T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427

jobs. According to (6), the natives’ probability of 5nding a primary-sector job, a (orits inverse, the expected duration of unemployment) is not aIected by immigration inthe very short run, as primary-sector 5rms immediately start to expand their demandfor labor such that, in Eq. (8), the rise in L̇1 oIsets exactly the increase in U .

Over time, employment expands in both sectors and wage rates fall in the process.Unemployment decreases steadily towards a steady-state level which remains, however,higher than the pre-immigration level.Regime II: In this regime, immigration has no impact on the natives’ employment

situation and labor income, since there is no link between the secondary sector, whereall immigrants work, and the primary sector, where 5rms hire only natives. In termsof the model equations, the only change from the 5rst regime is that Eq. (11) isreplaced by: L2 = 0. A sudden arrival of immigrants leads to an immediate fall of thesecondary-sector wage such that all new immigrants are hired in that sector. Since thereis complete segregation between natives and migrants, the model ‘jumps’ to the newsteady state. Depending on the distribution of capital income, native workers are eitherindiIerent (assumption (a)) or favorable towards immigration (assumption (b)), sincethe reduction of secondary-sector wages implies a rise in the return to capital in thatsector. Moreover, the discounted sum of future gains from capital income is greaterthan in the two other model regimes, because factor prices adjust instantaneously.Regime III is attained when the diIerential between primary and secondary sector

wages is su*ciently large to incite immigrants not to shirk if they work in the primarysector. As immigrants work in both sectors and are unemployed, the wage diIerentialis determined by their behavior. Formally, this regime is described by Eqs. (6) bothfor natives (� = 0, � = a) and for migrants (� = �, � = a∗), (8)–(11) for migrants(� = �), and L2 = 0. The no-shirking constraint of natives is identical to (12), withU = L − L1. For migrants, it is given by

L̇∗1 =

[de

(w1 − Tw) − (r + q + �)]U ∗ − (q + �)L∗

1 ; (17)

where U ∗ = L∗ − L∗1 − L∗

2 . Inverting (10) and using (11) yields L∗2 = g2{[p1f1

L − (r +q + �)e=d]=p2}, with f1

L = f1L(K1; L1 + L∗

1 ). For the analysis of welfare, however, itis the evolution of total primary-sector employment, L1 ≡ L1 + L∗

1 , that matters. Thedynamic behavior of L1 can be characterized by adding Eqs. (12) and (17):

L̇1 =[de

(p1f1L − Tw) − (r + q)

][L + L∗ −L1 − g2]

− qL1 − �(L∗ − g2); (18)

where g2 = g2{[p1f1L − (r + q + �)e=d]=p2} and f1

L = f1L(K1;L1).

Whereas in the 5rst regime immigrants ‘crowd out’ natives in the secondary sec-tor, in the third regime a similar mechanism takes place in the primary sector. Asteady-state relationship between primary-sector employment of natives and migrantscan be established by diIerentiating the natives’ no-shirking constraint (12):

dL1 = −CdL∗1 ; C =

| 1w|

| 1w| + !1(1 + L∗

1 =L1); 0 ¡C ¡ 1: (19)

Page 13: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427 421

To evaluate the impact of immigration on total primary-sector employment, diIerentiate(18) in the steady state. This yields: dL1=dL∗ = �1=(�3| 1

w|) ¿ 0, where

�3 =(

1 +U ∗

L∗1

)(1 +

U ∗

UC)(

�1

| 1w|

+�1

!1(1 + L∗1 =L1)

)+ (1 + "w)

�2

| 2w|

: (20)

Thus total primary-sector employment reacts similarly to immigration in regimes I andIII, which is not surprising as the wage diIerential is 5xed in both cases. 14 By contrastto regime I, however, this result implies (together with (19)) that native primary-sectoremployment diminishes with immigration. Moreover, this loss is not compensated bya fall in secondary-sector employment, and native unemployment increases as wagesfall. Are the welfare eIects therefore diIerent in the two regimes?

The welfare of natives is captured, as in regime I, by Eq. (15), with f1L=f1

L(K1; L1 +L∗

1 ). Thus, native welfare depends only on the evolution of total primary-sector em-ployment, described by Eq. (18). It is striking that, with the exception of the last term(which is small if L∗ is close to TL∗, the immigration level delimiting regimes II andIII), this equation is equivalent to (12), with L1 playing the role of L1. Therefore,the dynamic impact of immigration can be analyzed with the help of a phase diagramanalogous to Fig. 2, where the X-axis is re-labeled L1.

It appears now that regime III does not diIer qualitatively from regime I with respectto the dynamic adjustment of welfare, despite the diIerences in steady-state behavior.As in regime I, the welfare eIect of immigration depends on the assumptions concern-ing the distribution of capital. Under assumption (a), the slope of the V̇ 1 = 0 locus isnegative. Under assumption (b), it is straightforward to show that the slope is equal tothe expression given in (16), where U is replaced by (U + U ∗). Thus, as in regimeI, the welfare impact of immigration is more likely to be bene5cial for natives if totalunemployment is low.

If one assumes that both L1 and L∗1 evolve gradually towards the new equilibrium,

then a sudden arrival of migrants does not aIect wage rates (nor native unemploy-ment) ‘upon impact’. Thus new immigrants start oI as unemployed. Over time, nativeemployment falls and native unemployment increases progressively.

4. Calibrating the model

For policy discussion it matters not only whether immigration decreases wages andincreases unemployment, but by how much. Thus it is useful to calibrate the modelto check whether it is consistent with the empirical evidence. It is then possible toevaluate quantitatively the welfare implications of immigration.

Empirical evidence on the probability of return, a central parameter of the model, isscarce. Recent statistics on emigration, available in SOPEMI (1999) for some Europeancountries and Japan, indicate that return rates vary not only between countries, but also

14 Note the similarity between �1 and �3. Indeed, �3 converges towards �1 if L∗1 ; U∗ → 0 and (U∗=L∗1 ) →(U=L). In the model, however, there is no smooth transition between regimes I and III since (U∗=L∗1 ) isalways greater than (U=L) by a 5nite amount.

Page 14: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

422 T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427

Table 2Economic environment and model regimes (percentages)

Simulationa U=Lb L̃∗=L TL∗=L

Base ( Tw = 0:5; p2 = 1; $1 = 0) 7.0 10.5 12.8High unemployment ( Tw = 0:6; p2 = 1; $1 = 0) 8.5 10.2 12.5Globalization ( Tw = 0:6; p2 = 0:9; $1 = 0) 8.8 6.4 7.8Technical progress ( Tw = 0:6; p2 = 0:9; $1 = 0:05) 8.0 5.3 6.4

aL̃∗ and TL∗ designate the immigration levels delimiting the three model regimes; Tw is unemploymentcompensation, p2 the secondary-sector good price, $1 is an e*ciency parameter in the primary sector. Themodel is calibrated using the following assumptions: migrants’ return probability (� = 0:1), unemploymentrate (U=L = 0:07), unemployment compensation ( Tw=w2 = 0:5), average duration of unemployment (1=a = 12months), annual detection rate (d = 0:1), annual discount rate (r = 0:05), capital shares (f1

KK1=f1 = 0:3,f2

KK2=f2 = 0:25), consumption share (p2c2=∑

pici = 0:1), secondary-sector employment share (L2=L= 0:1).Note that the last two columns of Table 2 depend crucially on the initial secondary-sector employmentshare. The annual quit rate (q = 0:087) and the wage diIerential (w1=w2 − 1 = 0:066) are calibrated usingthe equations of the model.

bUnemployment rate measured at L∗ = 0.

among diIerent groups of migrants. 15 Return rates can be approximated by the ratioof emigration by foreigners to their stock in the host country. In 1997, average returnrates were higher in traditional guest-worker countries (4.7% in Switzerland; 8.6% inGermany) than in other North European countries (2.4–3.2% in Denmark, Netherlands,Sweden). Much higher values are attained for particular national groups (25% for Polishmigrants in Germany) or for certain legal categories (10% for foreigners holding annualwork permits in Switzerland). As most temporary migrants are excluded from thesestatistics (such as workers holding short-term or seasonal permits, and frontier workers),the probability of return migration, �, is set at 10% in the simulations, slightly higherthan currently observed values. The other parameters are chosen so as to describe atypical European economy, such as France or Germany, around 1980 (for details, seeTable 2 and M$uller (2000)).

Consider 5rst the quantitative eIects of immigration on wages and unemployment.Most empirical studies in the United States and in Europe 5nd that these two variablesare rather insensitive to immigration (Borjas, 1994; Zimmermann, 1994). In regimes Iand III of the calibrated model, a 1% increase in the labor force induced by immigrationleads to a steady-state fall in wage rates of 0.3%. 16 Because of the higher proportionof good jobs, the average native wage in regime I is only reduced by 0.2%. Thesevalues are consistent with Borjas’ (1994) survey of the literature, where he concludesthat the elasticity of native wages with respect to the number of immigrants is equalto −0:02 (p. 1698). Indeed, with immigrants representing 8% of the US population in

15 For the United States, see the survey by LaLonde and Topel (1997) who conclude that 30–40% ofimmigrants eventually return to their home country. Evidence on subjective return intentions of migrants isgiven by Dustmann (1993) for Germany. He reports that 55% of all immigrants intend to return to theircountry of origin within the next ten years.

16 In regime II, the primary-sector wage (and thus the average native wage) is not aIected by immigration,but the secondary-sector wage decreases by 2.5%.

Page 15: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427 423

1990, a 1% population increase through immigration leads according to this estimateto a variation of −0:24% of native wages.

The steady-state unemployment rate is quite insensitive to immigration. Indeed, a1% increase in the labor force pushes the aggregate unemployment rate up by only0.04 percentage points in regimes I and III. In regime II, additional immigration hasno impact on the level of unemployment, and as the labor force increases by 1% theaggregate unemployment rate is reduced by 0.06 percentage points. This leads to theresult that, compared to the base situation (L∗ = 0) and at constant capital stocks,the unemployment rate is only 0.2 percentage points higher if L∗ represents 12.8% ofthe native labor force (corresponding to the switch between regimes II and III). Con-sidering only the situation of natives, it turns out that their unemployment rate increasesmore with immigration in regime I than in regime III (+0:1 resp. +0:04 percentagepoints), which is due to the diIerent reaction of L1 in the two regimes. Again, theseresults seem to be in agreement with the empirical literature, where most studies 5ndonly a very weak (or no) eIect of immigration on unemployment.

Now turn to the welfare eIects of immigration. In relative terms, the equivalentvariation of native welfare can be measured by ZV1(=ZV2 = ZVu), divided by thediscounted expenditure of an average native in the base situation. 17 As the convergencehalf-life is only 6–7 months in this model, the adjustment path does not have muchweight in the welfare indicator. Thus the intertemporal welfare variations are wellapproximated by the steady-state eIects. It is clear from (1) and (3) that for a nativethe steady-state welfare variation is: ZV1 =(1=r)(Zw1 +Zyo). Together with the resultthat unemployment varies little with immigration, this implies that in regimes I andIII the impact of immigration on native welfare is close to the eIect that would beobtained with a static competitive model. 18 As a result, regimes I and III hardly diIerwith respect to the welfare consequences of immigration. For a native worker who doesnot receive any capital income, immigration leads to a welfare loss of 0.3% in bothregimes. By contrast, if capital income is distributed equally, the impact on welfareis close to zero (−0:05%). Natives will clearly prefer regime II, where the welfareof an average native increases by 0.2% with a 1% increase in labor force induced byimmigration, and native wages are not aIected.

Thus one would expect natives to favor immigration if the economy is in regime II,or if further immigration leads it there. 19 Therefore, even if the economy is in regimeI, but with L∗ close to L̃∗, the immigration level delimiting regimes I and II, additionalimmigration might be favored by a majority of natives. By contrast, if the immigration

17 A worker’s instantaneous cost (or expenditure) function is obtained by inversion of the indirect utilityfunction, yielding c(p1; p2; u) = (p1; p2)(u + e). Thus, equivalent welfare variation can be de5ned as:"E =

∫∞0 [c(p0

1; p02; u

1) − c(p01; p

02; u

0)] exp(−rt) dt, where exponents 0 and 1 indicate the situation beforeand after immigration. Since is the numVeraire, this simpli5es to "E = V 1 − V 0 = ZV1. A native’s totaldiscounted expenditure in the base situation is V 0 + (e=r). For an average native, this amounts to (L1V1 +L2V2 + UVu)=L + (e=r).

18 These results imply also that if aggregate native welfare is measured by L1V1 +L2V2 +UVu, as in Carter(1999), it is not appropriate to use current employment weights.

19 This result is reinforced in an alternative model version with non-traded goods, where immigration isbene5cial for all natives in regime II as native wages rise and unemployment falls (see M$uller, 2000).

Page 16: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

424 T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427

stock L∗ is greater than TL∗, the immigration level delimiting regimes II and III, mostnatives are likely to oppose additional immigration.

There is an interesting parallel between the eIect of immigration on native welfareand the degree of wage discrimination which can be measured by the diIerence betweenthe average native wage and the average immigrant wage. To see this, consider therelation between the level of immigration and the degree of discrimination. With a5xed wage diIerential in regime I, the fact that immigration ‘pushes’ natives from thesecondary sector into the primary sector, while migrants remain in the secondary sector,implies that wage discrimination increases. This is also the case in regime II, due tothe rising wage diIerential and complete segregation. The maximum of discriminationis reached at TL∗, because beyond that level of immigration, in regime III, migrantspenetrate progressively into the primary sector, reducing the gap between the averagewages of both groups.

5. The e"ects of changes in the economic environment

The turn towards restrictive immigration policies in Europe is often linked to therise in unemployment. In the model, the welfare impact of immigration depends indeednegatively on the unemployment level (see (16)). However, the quantitative inMuenceof the unemployment rate turns out to be rather limited. Indeed, increasing Tw from50% to 60% of the secondary-sector wage increases the unemployment rate from 7.0%to 8.5%, but the welfare impact of immigration is hardly modi5ed: a 1% increase inthe labor force leads to a loss in the average native’s welfare of 0.07%.

On a deeper level, the results of the preceding section suggest that regime shifts(i.e. changes in L̃∗ and TL∗) might have played an important role in the change ofattitude towards immigration. If the economy is initially in regime II (or in regime Iwith L∗ close to L̃∗), certain shocks might shift the economy into regime III, leadingto a signi5cant change in attitudes towards additional immigration.

Three types of shocks are considered. First, an increase in unemployment compen-sation (as above). Following Rodrik (1998), this can be interpreted as a consequenceof globalization since the increasing exposure to external risk has led governments ofhigh-income countries to expand spending on social security and welfare. 20 Second,another important aspect of globalization is increased import competition from devel-oping countries, which would be reMected in this model by a fall in the relative priceof secondary-sector goods. Third, technical progress has aIected labor markets in im-portant ways. It is not unreasonable to assume that productivity has improved more inthe primary than in the secondary sector.

20 In a one-sector dual labor market model taking demand uncertainty explicitly into account, Saint-Paul(1996, Chapter 4) shows that when demand becomes more volatile, primary-sector employment decreasesand secondary-sector employment increases. This result seems to indicate that if the dual labor market isinternal to 5rms, TL∗ might rise with external risk.

Page 17: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427 425

It appears that L̃∗ and TL∗ react similarly to the three types of shocks. The variationof TL∗ is given by 21

d TL∗ = (p2f2LL)−1{Cd Tw + (1 − C)w1d$1

− [(1 − C)w1(s2=s1) + w2](dp2=p2)}; (21)

where si = (@ =@pi)(pi= ) is the share of good i in domestic expenditures, and $1 isa Hicks-neutral productivity parameter speci5c to the primary sector. All three shockstend to reduce TL∗. A rise in Tw increases the unemployment rate and diminishes em-ployment in both sectors. Therefore natives leave the secondary sector, and immigrantspenetrate the primary sector, at lower immigration levels. A fall in the relative pricep2=p1 acts even more directly on the secondary sector by decreasing its labor demand,thus reducing TL∗. Finally, an increase in the primary sector’s productivity has the samequalitative eIects as a decline in p2=p1.

Quantitatively, an increase in Tw seems to produce a smaller shift of L̃∗ and TL∗ thanthe other two shocks (see Table 2). Note that the 10% fall in p2=p1 corresponds to theobserved decline, between 1980 and 1990, of EU import prices (in import-competingsectors) relative to EU export prices (OECD, 1997, Table 4:6).

The regime shift produced by these shocks is accompanied by a rise in wage in-equality among identical workers (see Fig. 1). This characteristic is reminiscent of the‘fractal’ quality of increased earnings dispersion: however narrowly one de5nes groups,one still 5nds an increase in dispersion (Atkinson, 1997).

6. Conclusions

This paper has used an e*ciency-wage model of a dual labor market with unem-ployment to analyze the welfare consequences of immigration, assuming that migrantsdiIer from natives only by their probability of return migration. As a result, there issectoral segregation, and thus discrimination against immigrants. The model exhibitsthree regimes, depending on the level of the immigrant stock. When calibrated, themodel appears to be consistent with the weak sensitivity of unemployment and wageswith respect to immigration found in the literature. However, immigration turns out tobe bene5cial for all natives only in the intermediate regime. Changes in the economicenvironment, in particular globalization and technical progress, are found to lower theimmigration level beyond which further immigration has a negative eIect on the wel-fare of native workers. This might provide an explanation of the rising opposition toimmigration, complementing the contributions on this issue by Razin and Sadka (1995)who use a model with endogenous human capital formation to show that the impactof immigration on native welfare is negative in the presence of wage rigidity or withendogenous redistribution policies. Similarly, Wellisch and Walz (1998) establish in atwo-country model with endogenous redistribution policy that social welfare is higherwith free trade than with free migration.

21 TL∗ is determined (jointly with L1) by the equations: p1f1L(K1; L1) − Tw = (e=d)[r + qL=(L − L1)] and

p1f1L(K1; L1) − p2f2

L(K2; TL∗) = (e=d)(r + q + �). DiIerentiating these equations yields (21).

Page 18: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

426 T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427

In a diIerent perspective, the model of this paper may also help to address thepuzzling questions raised by Blanchard and Katz’s (1992) empirical study of regionallabor market adjustment and by Card’s (1990) analysis of the ‘natural experiment’ ofthe Mariel boatlift. Referring to these two studies, Borjas (1994, p. 1700) states thispuzzle as follows: “Why should it be that many other regional variations persist overtime, but that the impact of immigration on native workers is arbitraged away immedi-ately?”. The arrival of the ‘Marielitos’, most of whom had little education and did nothave access to ‘good’ jobs, can indeed be analyzed in the present model as an instan-taneous increase in the number of immigrants in the Miami labor market. With 20%of Miami’s population being of Cuban origin in 1980, it seems reasonable to considerregimes II or III of the model. In regime II, immigration has no impact on the wagesand unemployment of natives, which is consistent with Card’s (1990) observations.Even in regime III, the model predicts that immigration has no instantaneous eIect onthe situation of natives.

Thus the model suggests that if immigration has no impact on the native labormarket, this is not due to ‘arbitrage’ by perfectly mobile workers, but can be explainedby the segmentation of labor markets and by the wage rigidity inherent to the dynamice*ciency wage model. Moreover, if workers are imperfectly mobile, as they probablyare, the present model is also consistent with Blanchard and Katz’s (1992) 5nding thatadverse economic shocks may reduce regional wages for up to 10 years before theyare reequilibrated by migration Mows.

Acknowledgements

I would like to thank Bernard DecaluwVe, Jean-Marie Grether, Kevin Lang, Jaimede Melo, Harald Uhlig and three anonymous referees for very helpful comments andsuggestions. Part of this research was carried out during my stay at Laval University inQuVebec, Canada. Financial support by the Swiss National Fund for Scienti5c Research(Grant 12-42011.94) and by the Programme d’analyses et de recherches VeconomiquesappliquVees au dVeveloppement international (PARADI), which is funded by the CanadianInternational Development Agency (CIDA), is gratefully acknowledged.

References

Atkinson, A.B., 1997. Bringing income distribution in from the cold. Economic Journal 107, 297–321.Berry, R.A., Soligo, R., 1969. Some welfare aspects of international migration. Journal of Political Economy

77, 778–794.Blanchard, O.J., Katz, L.F., 1992. Regional evolutions. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1, 1–61.Borjas, G.J., 1994. The economics of immigration. Journal of Economic Literature 32, 1667–1717.Brecher, R.A., Choudhri, E.U., 1987. International migration versus foreign investment in the presence of

unemployment. Journal of International Economics 23, 329–342.Bulow, J.I., Summers, L.H., 1986. A theory of dual labor markets with application to industrial policy,

discrimination, and Keynesian unemployment. Journal of Labor Economics 4, 376–414.Card, D., 1990. The impact of the Mariel boatlift on the Miami labor market. Industrial and Labor Relations

Review 43, 245–257.

Page 19: Migration, unemployment and discrimination

T. M+uller / European Economic Review 47 (2003) 409–427 427

Carter, T.J., 1999. Illegal immigration in an e*ciency wage model. Journal of International Economics 49,385–401.

Dustmann, C., 1993. Earnings adjustments of temporary migrants. Journal of Population Economics 6,153–168.

Ethier, W.J., 1985. International trade and labor migration. American Economic Review 75, 691–707.Faini, R., Grether, J.-M., 1997. L’ouverture au commerce peut-elle rVeduire la migration Nord-Sud? In:

de Melo, J., Guillaumont, P. (Eds.), Commerce Nord-Sud, migration et dVelocalisation. Economica, Paris.Galor, O., Stark, A., 1990. Migrants’ savings, the probability of return migration, and migrants’ performance.

International Economic Review 31, 463–467.Galor, O., Stark, A., 1991. The probability of return migration, migrants’ work eIort, and migrants’

performance. Journal of Development Economics 35, 399–405.Georges, C., 1995. Adjustment costs and indeterminacy in perfect foresight models. Journal of Economic

Dynamics and Control 19, 39–50.Hammar, T., 1985. European Immigration Policy: A Comparative Study. Cambridge University Press,

Cambridge.Jones, S.R.G., 1987. Minimum wage legislation in dual labor market. European Economic Review 31,

1229–1246.Kimball, M.S., 1994. Labor-market dynamics when unemployment is a worker discipline device. American

Economic Review 84, 1045–1059.LaLonde, R.J., Topel, R.H., 1997. Economic impact of international migration and of migrants. In:

Rosenzweig, M.R., Stark, O. (Eds.), Handbook of Population and Family Economics, Vol. 1B.North-Holland, Amsterdam.

M$uller, T., 2000. Migration, unemployment and discrimination. Cahiers du DVepartement d’VeconomVetrie No.2000.03, UniversitVe de Gen]eve.

OECD, 1997, OECD Employment Outlook. OECD, Paris.Perrot, A., Zylberberg, A., 1989. Salaire d’e*cience et dualisme du marchVe du travail. Revue Veconomique

1, 5–20.Piore, M.J., 1979. Birds of Passage: Migrant Labor and Industrial Societies. Cambridge University Press,

Cambridge.Razin, A., Sadka, E., 1995. Resisting migration: Wage rigidity and income distribution. American Economic

Review 85 (P& P), 312–316.Rodrik, D., 1998. Why do more open economies have bigger governments? Journal of Political Economy

106, 997–1032.Saint-Paul, G., 1996. Dual Labor Markets: A Macroeconomic Perspective. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Schmidt, C.M., Stilz, A., Zimmermann, K.F., 1994. Mass migration, unions, and government intervention.

Journal of Public Economics 55, 185–201.Shapiro, C., Stiglitz, J.E., 1984. Equilibrium unemployment as a worker-discipline device. American

Economic Review 74, 433–444.SOPEMI, 1999. Trends in international migration: Annual report. OECD, Paris.Wellisch, D., Walz, U., 1998. Why do rich countries prefer free trade over free migration? The role of the

modern welfare state. European Economic Review 42, 1595–1612.Winter-Ebmer, R., Zweim$uller, J., 1996. Immigration and the earnings of young native workers. Oxford

Economic Papers 48, 473–491.Zimmermann, K.F., 1994. European migration: Push and pull. Proceedings of the World Bank Annual

Conference on Development Economics (The World Bank).