migration policy and autocratic power

Upload: gt57

Post on 02-Jun-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    1/34

    Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    Michael K. Miller

    Margaret E. Peters

    Abstract

    Throughout history, control over the movement of citizens has been a central source of au-

    tocratic power. Yet modern autocracies vary considerably in how much they limit the freedom

    to emigrate. Although mass exit can threaten autocratic leaders, emigration can also stabilize

    regimes by expelling dissidents and encouraging remittances. We disentangle these effects by

    analyzing the interaction between migration flows, democratic change, and regimes strategic

    choices of emigration policy, something that has been neglected in the literature. Despite glob-

    alization, we show that emigration freedom has been steadily declining in autocracies since

    1980. Using a half-century of bilateral migration data, we calculate the level and targets of

    expected emigration given exogenous geographic and socioeconomic characteristics. We find

    that when citizens are more likely to emigrate to democracies, autocracies lower emigration

    freedom in response. Nevertheless, these countries remain more likely to democratize. Sur-

    prisingly, total expected emigration, which tracks the feasibility of exit, predicts autocratic

    stability and greater emigration freedom.

    Prepared for delivery at the 2014 Annual Meeting of the American Political Science

    Association, August 2831, 2014

    Michael K. Miller is an Assistant Professor of Political Science at George Washington Univer-sity. Margaret E. Peters is an Assistant Professor of Political Science at Yale University. Sendall correspondence to: [email protected].

    1

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    2/34

    Introduction

    Autocratic leaders have long used restrictions on emigration and internal movement to

    bolster their power. Under feudalism, autocratic rulers throughout Europe fixed peasants to

    the land to preserve the existing power structure. In the 20th century, Communist rulers

    strictly prevented exit of most of their citizens. Yet countries like Mexico tacitly encouraged

    emigration and autocratic regimes in Spain, Portugal, Greece, and North Africa promoted

    emigration by signing bilateral labor migration treaties (Peters 2013). Why do some autocratic

    leaders restrict emigration while others encourage it?

    Emigration is a double-edged sword for autocratic rulers. On one hand, large flows of em-igrants can signal mass discontent with the regime. As Hirschman (1970, 1978) argues, exit

    is the companion to voice and of particular utility in autocracies with limited opportunities

    for expression. By voting with their feet, emigrants can signal that the regime has failed to

    provide for them, either materially or politically. As graphically illustrated by East Germany,

    mass emigration can then trigger protest and regime breakdown. Emigration to democracies

    is especially problematic as migrants transmit democratic ideas back home and can return

    with tools to make democratization happen.

    On the other hand, emigration can be a boon to autocratic leaders. Discontented citizens

    can leave or be expelled, making it less likely they will exercise their voice. Those who remain

    tend to be more loyal to the regime. Emigrants also send back remittances, increasing the

    standard of living and promoting growth at home through multiplier effects. Further, remit-

    tances increase during recessions (Yang 2008), tamping down opposition at a critical point of

    vulnerability.

    We argue that autocratic leaders are strategic in their choice of emigration policy. Emigra-

    tion is not just the choice of individual actors within a state but is regulated by the state itself.

    Autocratic leaders thus restrict emigration when they believe it will threaten their survival

    and encourage it otherwise. Specifically, they balance their economic motives and desire to let

    undesirable citizens leave against the dangers of allowing citizens an exit option.

    2

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    3/34

    Using data on bilateral migrant flows, we analyze the choice of emigration policy and the

    effect of emigration on regime stability. To preview our results, we show that emigration free-

    dom influences emigrant flows in autocracies, especially for high-skill migrants. This confirms

    that autocracies can use policy to affect individual choices to migrate. We then show that au-

    tocrats strategically anticipate likely emigration flows when deciding policy. The core of our

    empirical strategy is a prediction of bilateral migration, based on exogenous geographic and

    socioeconomic variables. Using these predictions, we find that autocratic leaders generally en-

    courage emigration, but restrict it if emigrants are likely to go to democracies. Finally, overall

    expected emigration stabilizes regimes, but emigration to democracies predicts democratiza-

    tion. Thus, autocrats policy choices fit as a rational response to this threat.

    Our paper addresses a critical missing piece of the international migration puzzle: the

    politics of autocratic sending countries. We further show that emigration policy is a neglected

    component of how modern autocracies fight for survival. Lastly, we provide strong evidence of

    emigration as a mechanism of democratic diffusion.

    After reviewing the relevant literature, we describe the empirical puzzle by examining how

    emigration freedom has changed over the past 30 years. We then discuss theoretically how

    emigration influences autocratic stability, followed by our empirical strategy and results. We

    conclude with how our results should influence immigration policy in developed democracies.

    Past Work on Migration and Politics

    This article addresses a lacuna in both the migration and autocracy literatures. Scholar-

    ship on migration has tended to focus on immigration policies in wealthy democracies (Massey

    1999). When migration scholars have addressed emigration, they have focused on individual

    choices to emigrate and the resulting effects on local communities. Several single-country

    studies investigate the local political consequences of international migration, based on sur-

    veys or electoral outcomes (Pfaff and Kim 2003; Perez-Armendariz and Crow 2010; Pfutze

    2012; Mahmoud et al. 2014; Chauvet and Mercier forthcoming). However, they generally omit

    3

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    4/34

    the strategic role of the state in encouraging or discouraging emigration to suit its needs.1

    Some scholars have examined the effects of remittances on autocratic stability, but tend to

    neglect the specific role of emigration (Ahmed 2012; OMahony 2013).

    Although Hirschman (1978) theorizes that emigration can affect autocratic stability, the

    autocracy literature has largely ignored emigration as a source of threat. This is surprising

    given that scholars such as Boix (2003) have argued that capital mobility is a critical factor in

    democratization. Emigration and remittances can also reduce the need to redistribute wealth,

    further encouraging democratization (Boix 2003; Bearce and Hutnick 2011).

    A few cross-national studies connect migration to democratic change. Spilimbergo (2009)

    shows that foreign-educated students promote democracy, but only if they are educated in

    democracies. Bearce and Hutnick (2011) demonstrate that higher net emigration is positive

    for democratization, which they argue accounts for the resource curse. Ahmed (2012) argues

    that remittances can help prop up patronage networks, supporting autocratic leaders. Doc-

    quier et al. (2013) find that greater emigration flows to OECD countries predict increases in

    democracy and institutional quality.

    There are several shortcomings with these and related studies. First, the richness of the

    data on migration varies considerably. Many analyze only total migration (Bearce and Hut-

    nick 2011; Aleman and Woods 2014), and therefore overlook the critical dimension ofwhere

    migrants move to. Others consider only emigration to OECD countries (Docquier et al. 2013;

    Fitzgerald et al. 2014).2 Studies of bilateral emigration often use cross-sectional data from a

    single point in time (Breunig et al. 2012).

    Second, there is little consideration of regimes responses to emigration, one of the many

    sources of endogeneity in connecting emigration to democracy. Like this paper, several studies

    instrument for migration using geography (e.g., Docquier et al. 2013; Ortega and Peri 2014).

    However, spurious results could still arise if countries react to the propensity for emigration.

    Some research considers the political sources of migration, but remains focused on receiving

    1 Fitzgeralds (2006) study of Mexico and Iskanders (2010) study of Mexico and Morocco areexceptions.

    2 Although the primary flow is from poor to wealthy countries, almost half of migrants cur-rently move between countries in the developing world (Ozden et al. 2011).

    4

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    5/34

    countries immigration policies (Bertocchi and Strozzi 2008; Mayda 2010; Fitzgerald et al.

    2014). Breunig et al. (2012) argue that democracy predicts more emigration and less immi-

    gration. Although they claim this results from the differing policies of democracies, they do

    not test this mechanism. We place the mediating effect of emigration freedom at the center of

    our empirical strategy.

    Third, there is little analysis of how effects vary by regime. Clearly, different autocracies

    have taken different approaches to emigration, with fairly open policies in Mexico and Taiwan

    and highly restrictive ones in Cuba and North Korea. Specific regimes may also be more

    sensitive to the political effects of emigration.

    Emigration Freedom

    Determining the freedom of citizens to emigrate represents a critical tool of autocratic

    power and a policy choice of major economic and political significance. To test this, we measure

    emigration freedom using CIRIs three-point rating of the freedom of foreign movement and

    travel (Cingranelli and Richards 2008). In this coding, 0 = severely restricted, 1 = some-

    what restricted, and 2 = unrestricted. For ease of interpretation, we recode this to take

    values of 0, 0.5, and 1. Besides blanket restrictions on exit, the measure tracks limitations

    on the duration and location of travel and rights of return for citizen refugees. The middle

    category is used for restrictions that are limited in nature or that target specific groups, such

    as ethnic minorities. The measure does not track the freedom of domestic movement, which

    has its own separate variable. To date, this measure (and emigration policy in general) has

    been largely ignored by political scientists.3

    Emigration freedom varies in several puzzling ways. First, we examine its association with

    democracy and how this has changed over time. The top panel of Figure 1 displays average

    3 An exception is Aleman and Woods (2014), who run regressions showing that emigrationfreedom positively correlates with democracy levels. However, this may result from reversecausation, as democracies implement freer emigration policies. Also see McKenzie (2007) onpassport costs and legal barriers to emigration.

    5

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    6/34

    values of emigration freedom for autocracies and democracies in each year from 1981 to 2010.4

    Clearly, democracies allow freer emigration than autocracies (Breunig et al. 2012; Aleman

    and Woods 2014). Further, this difference has widened over time, with autocracies steadily

    becoming more restrictive. This is surprising given rising globalization and the fact that a

    similar relationship is not found for the freedom of association (displayed in the bottom panel,

    from Cingranelli and Richards 2008), for which the autocratic average is flat across time.5

    Further detail is presented in Figure 2, which shows the average emigration freedom for

    eachPolityvalue in two time periods (Marshall and Jaggers 2010). This measure tracks sev-

    eral institutional features of democracy, with repressive dictatorships at the low end, liberal-

    ized autocracies in the middle, and full democracies at the high end. In the 1980s, emigration

    freedom was largely unrelated to Polity, with the exception of slightly lower values for the

    most repressive regimes. This flat relationship changed by the 2000s, when emigration free-

    dom became strongly related across the full range ofPolity. We can further see that the fall in

    emigration freedom was concentrated in relatively autocratic countries (i.e., those withPolity

    values below 0). Why are these regimes increasingly restricting emigration?

    We argue that this shift is in response to two threats. The first is the increasing num-

    ber of global democracies, which autocrats do not want to give their citizens exposure to. In

    1972, at the beginning of democracys Third Wave, only 36% of emigrants hailing from an au-

    tocracy moved to a democracy. In the 2000s, 59% did so. 6 The resulting normative influence

    is especially damaging in highly repressive and ideologically based states, so these regimes

    choose to confine their citizens. A second factor is the increasing feasibility of exit over time.

    Autocracies face a systemic danger from high emigration, whereas democracies can appeal

    to citizens through voice and policy responsiveness. As transportation and other technologies

    lower the natural barriers to exit, autocracies are forced to prevent exit by legally restrictingemigration. In simple terms, Threat of exit = Feasibility of exit + Emigration freedom. Thus,

    to manage the threat, increased feasibility must be met with reduced emigration freedom.

    4 Democracy is defined using a threshold of 6 on the Politydemocracy rating (Marshall andJaggers 2010).

    5 Freedoms of speech and religion and workers rights are also largely flat across time.6 This is based on emigrant stocks data from Ozden et al. (2011).

    6

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    7/34

    This is further illustrated by Figure 3, which shows the average emigration freedom by an

    autocracys number of neighbors (Correlates of War Project 2007). This tracks the geographic

    feasibility of exit since neighbors are by far the easiest and cheapest targets for emigration.

    Accordingly, we see a strong negative relationship between emigration freedom and neighbors.

    Islands and autocracies with one or two neighbors average about 0.7, whereas autocracies

    with eight or more neighbors (eight distinct countries) average about 0.2. This relationship is

    absent in democracies and absent or much weaker in autocracies for other freedoms. The next

    section explores why autocracies respond to the threat of exit by restricting emigration.

    Migration and Autocratic Power

    Emigration is a double-edged sword for autocratic leaders. On one side, there is the threat

    of exit and exposure to democracies that may lead to mass protests and the overthrow of the

    regime. On the other side, emigration enables autocrats to get rid of potential challengers

    and attract remittances. Autocratic leaders will thus balance the positives and negatives to

    determine migration policy.

    Migration as Threat of Exit

    The ability to emigrate is a powerful source of citizen pressure on autocratic regimes. The

    clearest expression of this idea comes from Hirschman (1970, 1978), who argues that citizens,

    customers, and other beneficiaries have two types of responses when dissatisfied with an

    organization: voice and exit. Because voice in autocracies is generally ineffective, exit is the

    dominant option. By reducing populations, tax bases, and legitimacy, large-scale emigration

    can exert serious harm and even regime collapse. In models of mass protest, such as Kuran

    (1991) and Lohmann (1994), successful protests occur when citizens believe that enough of

    their fellow citizens will join them. High levels of emigration can provide this crucial signal to

    citizens who remain at home. The exit of certain citizens, such as the highly educated, doctors,

    7

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    8/34

    military experts, and the wealthy, may be especially threatening if they are highly visible or

    damaging to the economy and government services.7

    Perhaps the most significant example of political pressure through exit is the mass ex-

    odus from East Germany in 1989 when Hungarys border with Austria was briefly opened

    (Hirschman 1993; Pfaff and Kim 2003). The exit of more than 30,000 East Germans forced

    the regime to close its borders with the Communist bloc in October, triggering rising protest

    as the level of opposition became clearer. When the border with Czechoslovakia reopened in

    November, the resulting stream of refugees crippled the regime, forcing the entire cabinet to

    resign only 12 days later. Allowing direct travel to West Germany then proved incompatible

    with the survival of East Germany as a Communist regime.

    The threat of exit has been a recurrent problem throughout history. As Hirschman (1978:

    104) argues, the very existence of the state is incompatible with the virtually costless avail-

    ability of exit.8 While democracies typically allow low-cost exit, they decrease the desire to

    exit by providing their citizens with public services and a voice in the political process. Be-

    cause citizens can exercise voice, exit becomes a less desirable option (Hirschman 1970). In

    contrast, autocracies do not grant their citizens voice and therefore are motivated to limit the

    power of exit through population control and migration policy. This power is especially press-

    ing if citizens have more feasible options for exit, such as neighbors with a shared language

    and lax immigration policies.

    Easy exit has prompted a variety of responses from states, with many repressing and con-

    straining populations to manage the threat. Feudalism represents an extreme in the control

    of exit and movement, particularly in Eastern Europe. In the Early Middle Ages, Western

    European peasants had the threat of exit to towns, which necessitated tying them to the land.

    However, following the Black Death, Western European monarchs began to encourage peas-

    ant exit to weaken nobles (Anderson 1974; Fukuyama 2011: 376-77). In contrast, rulers in

    7 Known as brain drain, emigration of the highly educated has reached endemic propor-tions in some countries (Docquier and Rapoport 2012). According to the OECD (2008), theshare of citizens with college degrees who emigrate has reached 27% in Kenya, 67.5% inHaiti, and 71.5% in Guinea-Bissau.

    8 Also see Herbst (1990) on the gradual control of exit and its effects on state consolidationin Africa.

    8

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    9/34

    Eastern Europe strengthened feudalism to gain the support of the nobility (Anderson 1974;

    Peters 2014). At the nadir, Russian peasants were permitted to travel only one day per year

    around St. Georges Day and even this freedom was restricted through payments and fees. In

    large part, this political restriction was borne from the ease of exit for Russian peasants, who

    faced few natural barriers and the lure of free Cossack communities across Russias borders

    (Fukuyama 2011: 397).

    Elsewhere, states have allowed higher wages and political concessions to entice workers to

    stay. In 19th century U.S. and Australia, the working class had high bargaining power due

    to labor scarcity and easy exit to the frontier (Hobsbawm 1975: 118-19), which encouraged

    early extensions of universal suffrage in frontier states like Wyoming, Utah, and South Aus-

    tralia. The polar opposite effect was seen in early 20th century Argentina, where a massive

    immigrant population, including a majority of adult males in major cities, eliminated domes-

    tic labors threat of exit. This freed elites to repress and even deport labor organizers and to

    defer the enfranchisement of the lower class (Waisman 1989: 80).

    States that cannot allow effective suffrage or voice are more likely to resort to restrictive

    measures. Thus, modern autocracies that feel threatened by exit will tend to enact legal re-

    strictions on emigration. The implication is that autocracies whose citizens have a high feasi-

    bility of exit (for geographic, economic, or historical reasons) should limit emigration freedom,

    especially in the most repressive regimes.

    Migration and Democratic Diffusion

    The danger to autocrats arises not just from the exit option, but the potential exposure

    to democratic norms and practices. Several studies demonstrate that the presence of democ-

    racies in a countrys neighborhood or region predicts democratization (Brinks and Coppedge

    2006; Gleditsch and Ward 2006), but have struggled to identify the supporting mechanisms

    (Lankina and Getachew 2006; Torfason and Ingram 2010). Levitsky and Way (2010) instead

    claim that democracies pressure electoral autocracies to liberalize not based on their proxim-

    ity, but their linkage through trade, cultural exchange, and travel to the U.S. and European

    9

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    10/34

    Union. We adopt a similar perspective and argue that emigration to democracies should exert

    an especially strong effect.

    Even brief periods living in well-functioning democracies can shift attitudes about democ-

    racy (Camp 2003; Spilimbergo 2009; Kapur 2010). Migrants also have opportunities for polit-

    ical participation (such as protest and membership in civil society groups, including unions)

    that can build critical political capacities and social capital. Over time, large migrant popula-

    tions can then influence mass attitudes about democracy and behavior back home. Based on a

    survey in Mexico, Perez-Armendariz and Crow (2010) find that international migrants trans-

    mit democratic norms both by returning home and communicating with their native country

    while abroad. Chauvet and Mercier (forthcoming) find that migrant returnees in Mali improve

    local electoral participation, including among non-migrants. Finally, Mahmoud et al. (2014)

    find that communities in Moldova with migrants traveling to Western Europe increased their

    support for democratic parties compared to those sending migrants to Russia.

    Several historical cases further illustrate the political effects of emigration. Moses (2011)

    claims that Norwegian emigration to the U.S. in the 19th century heavily influenced Norways

    politics. In addition to creating a labor shortage, emigrants sent back reports of greater eco-

    nomic opportunities and freedoms in the U.S., causing increased labor agitation, higher wages,

    and ultimately suffrage reform. Emigration was a political crowbar used by Norways labor

    movement for political and economic gains (Moses 2011: 111).

    Portugals high level of emigration to Western Europe also exerted strong pro-democratic

    pressure in the 1970s. Inflated by the risk of conscription for Portugals unpopular colonial

    wars, hundreds of thousands left Portugal in the early 70s, with more than 150,000 emigrating

    within Europe in 1970 alone (Bermeo 2007: 392). Besides magnifying labor power due to the

    shortage of able-bodied men, this population flux helped to spread democratic norms (Brettell

    1984; Bermeo 2007). As Bermeo (2007: 392) writes, [C]itizens with experience abroad became

    a constituency for democracy. This proved pivotal for democratization after the 1974 military

    coup, when elections in 1975 and 1976 revealed overwhelming popular support for moderate

    pro-democratic parties.

    10

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    11/34

    A key question for this literature, however, is whether those who migrate to democratic

    countries had democratic leanings to begin with. For example, in the 1960s, migrants from

    North Africa could choose to migrate to Western Europe under a bilateral labor migration

    treaty or to the Persian Gulf. Migrants who valued a more open society likely migrated to

    Europe while those who valued a more traditional society migrated to the Persian Gulf. The

    former may not have changed their attitudes about democracy, but may have gained tools to

    help challenge the autocrat. Other migrants go to a democracy simply because it is the easiest

    place to travel for work. Regardless of their feelings about democracy, Mexicans migrated to

    the U.S. because it was close and had high wages. For these migrants, their experience abroad

    may change their attitudes about democracy or make them more salient. Because of the risk of

    endogeneity in locational choices, we instrument for emigration destinations using exogenous

    geographic variables.

    Autocracies will be motivated to restrict emigration if citizens are likely to emigrate to

    democracies, where they will be exposed to democratic ideals and the organizational tools

    of democracy. This is especially true in ideologically based states. At the extreme of worries

    about ideological diffusion, pre-Meiji Japan and pre-1850s China almost entirely eliminated

    interactions with the outside world. Today, the magnitude of this threat may be increasing

    even for electoral autocracies that adopt a democratic facade. Exposure to liberal democracies

    provides citizens higher standards for electoral conduct, as well as resources for building civil

    society movements. When they return, former emigres may use the tools they have learned

    in democracies to agitate for a more robust democracy. Thus, all types of autocracies should

    prefer limited citizen exposure to democracies.

    Motives for Emigration

    So far, we have highlighted two dangers of emigration for autocrats: the threat of exit and

    exposure to democracy and alternative ideologies. Left at this, we would expect autocrats to

    restrict emigration as much as possible. In reality, there is a great deal of variation, with

    many autocracies, such as Mexico and Taiwan, encouraging emigration and foreign study. To

    11

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    12/34

    explain this, we highlight some of the positive effects of emigration for autocratic leaders.

    Taking account of the balance of motives can help to explain the variation in emigration

    freedom.

    First, states have economic motives to encourage emigration. Remittances from foreign

    workers are a major source of citizen income in poor countries, reaching $529 billion world-

    wide in 2012 and 25% or more of GDP in several countries (Kapur 2014: 490; also Pfutze

    2012). While remittances go directly to citizens, unlike income from natural resources, they

    can be used to prop up patronage networks (Ahmed 2012). Remittances are often used by their

    recipients to provide private forms of public goods, such as the use of wells instead of connec-

    tions to public water systems (Adida and Girod 2010; Bhavnani and Peters 2014). Since the

    autocrat does not have to provide public goods to these citizens, he can spend more money to

    neutralize other threats. Importantly, remittances also increase during economic recessions

    and after natural disasters (Yang 2008), softening their potential to destabilize the regime.

    Second, trade and investment often flow along migrant networks. Migrant flows increases

    trade flows because migrants have a taste for home goods and provide information about

    opportunities for trade with their home country (Gould 1994). Migration is associated with

    foreign direct investment, as the diaspora invests at home and makes investors from the

    receiving country more comfortable investing in the home country (Leblang 2010). Addition-

    ally, migrants may return home with technical skills and networks developed in the receiving

    country. Emigration can also increase reciprocal flows of immigration, which provides cheap

    and politically powerless labor. Thus, migration can help grow the economy, leading to greater

    regime stability over time.

    Third, emigration may also reduce the pressure for redistribution, as it shifts poorer citi-

    zens abroad (Bearce and Hutnick 2011). Wages should also increase for those left behind. For

    instance, ORourke and Williamson (1999) find that emigration helped to close the wage gap

    between the New World and Europe during the 19th century. As citizens become wealthier,

    there may be less need for redistribution.

    12

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    13/34

    Fourth, autocracies may desire the exit of some citizens as a safety valve. In post-feudal

    Europe, states encouraged emigration to the colonies, only in part for economic development.

    Shifting some of the poor abroad helped to lessen poverty and social spending at home. In

    addition, emigration allowed states to expel political dissidents, including thousands of Irish

    activists deported by the U.K. to Australia. Hirschman (1978) argues that these dual effects

    promoted liberalization in Europe, as they made the extension of suffrage less threatening.

    Similarly, in the early 20th century, Japan encouraged emigration of the outcast Burakumin

    social class from the most politically unstable regions (Endoh 2009). The practice of encour-

    aging (or at least tolerating) the exit of selected populations continues today, with opposition

    voters and party leaders and non-allied ethnic groups the most likely targets. Millions of po-

    litically disaffected citizens have left Zimbabwe and Russia in the past decade, thinning the

    ranks of the opposition (Kapur 2014: 483). Further, a disproportionate number of migrants

    are unemployed or underemployed young men, the same group from which most opposition

    and insurgent groups draw from. Moving these men out of the country and into jobs overseas

    should lead to less support for the most dangerous opposition movements.

    To sum up, emigration freedom should result from a balance of positives and negatives,

    with the former mainly predicted by structural economic factors and the latter varying by

    the feasibility of citizens leaving and their likely destinations. We concentrate on testing the

    latter effects. Geographic and socioeconomic features that predict easy exit can motivate lower

    emigration freedom, although the positives of emigration mean that this will vary across

    autocracies. In particular, the threat of exit and safety valve effects may balance against each

    other. In addition, expected emigration to democracies should encourage democratization and

    predict lower emigration freedom in response.

    Empirical Approach and Data

    We now turn to testing the argument. Our empirical tests look at the interaction between

    migration flows, emigration freedom, and political stability. We first confirm that emigration

    freedom matters for migration flows, especially for the well-educated. Using exogenous ge-

    13

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    14/34

    ographic variables, we then predict emigration freedom from the feasibility of exit and how

    democratic the likely emigration targets are. Finally, we show how these factors predict demo-

    cratic change.

    Sample and Main Variables

    For predicting emigration rates, we use a directed dyadic panel, consisting of ordered pairs

    of countries in each year. For predicting emigration freedom and democratic change, we in-

    stead use a country-year panel. We focus on a sample of autocracies, which are defined as

    scoring below a threshold of 6 on Polity. We also replicate the democratization results us-

    ing Boix et al.s (2013) dichotomous indicator of democracy.9 As discussed above, Emigration

    Freedomis a three-point rating (re-scaled from 0 to 1) from Cingranelli and Richards (2010),

    which is available for 1981 to 2010.

    For information on bilateral migration, we primarily rely on data from the World Bank

    (Ozden et al. 2011), which provides migrant stocks for each pair of countries every 10 years

    from 1960 to 2000. We also use this to calculate migrant flows for each decade. Results are

    replicated or extended using two other bilateral migration data sets: Abel and Sander (2014)

    provide the net change in migrant populations over each five-year period from 1990 to 2005,

    and Docquier and Marfouk (2005) provide migrant stocks for 1990 and 2000, distinguishing

    migrants by college education.

    Identification Strategy

    The core of our identification strategy is an estimation of directed bilateral migration from

    autocracies using geographic and basic socioeconomic variables. From this, we impute ex-

    pected migration, and then calculate its effect on democratic change and emigration freedom.

    The approach is similar to an instrumental variables setup, although we also use the imputed

    values to calculate the democratic nature of expected emigration targets.

    9 These two measures agree for 93.7% of our sample.

    14

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    15/34

    We begin by estimating a regression of the following form:

    ln(Emijt) = ln(P opulationit)+ln(P opulationjt)+ln(Distanceijt)+Xijt +Wit +Zjt +t +ijt (1)

    whereE mijt is the stock of migrants from country i to country j in year t. This is taken from

    the most recent value in Ozden et al. (2011), up to 2010. The sample is limited to autocratic

    sending states, but all receiving states are included. Equation (1) is known as a gravity model,

    similar to those used in the trade literature, as it includes logs of distance and the respective

    country populations. These are logged so that their distributions are approximately normal.

    X,W, andZ are control variables that refer respectively to dyadic characteristics, the source

    countryi, and the target j .tis a linear control for the year.

    Our main specification includes the following variables, chosen to be exogenous to both

    democracy and emigration policy. For dyadic factors, we include logged capital distance, dum-

    mies for six categories of contiguity (which includes information on shared borders and sepa-

    ration by water), an indicator of colonial history, and a dummy for shared language. We control

    for each countrys logged population and logged average income. Finally, we include interac-

    tions between the target countrys population and distance, population and shared borders,

    and the same interactions for income. Large, wealthy neighbors may be especially attractivetargets for emigration. Further details are included in the discussion of control variables.

    This equation allows us to calculate imputed valuesdEmijt . From this, we compute a coun-trys expected total emigration as a share of its population:

    dEmit(P op. Share) =P

    jdEmijt

    P opulationit

    We also calculate the average democratic rating ofis expected emigration targets:

    dEmit(P olity Average) =P

    jdEmijt PolityjtP

    jdEmijt

    The above is calculated from Polity, which runs from -10 to 10 (Marshall and Jaggers 2010).

    As a robustness check, we replace this with the dichotomous coding from Boix et al. (2013).

    15

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    16/34

    Lastly, to test for a policy diffusion effect, we repeat the above calculation with the emigra-

    tion freedom of receiving countries:

    dEmit(EF Average) =P

    jdEmijt EFjt

    PjdEmijt

    whereEFstands forEmigration Freedom.

    Empirical Tests

    We begin by showing that emigration freedom has an effect on actual emigration flows in

    autocracies. This is tested through an expanded version of Equation (1), using actual flows

    as the dependent variable (since were interested in the near-term effect). We test this with

    the World Bank data (Ozden et al. 2011) and separately for populations with and without

    college degrees, using Docquier and Marfouk (2005). Our estimator is regression with robust

    standard errors clustered by country dyad.

    We then test whether a higher feasibility of exit and democratic targets of emigration pre-

    dict emigration freedom in autocracies. Using the imputations from Equation (1), we predict

    emigration freedom using an ordered probit:

    EFit =dEmit(P op. Share) +dEmit(P olity Average) +dEmit(EF Average) + Xit+t+it

    whereXitis a set of control variables.

    This model structure is then used to test our prediction that democratic targets of emigra-

    tion lead to democratic change. Our main dependent variable for testing this is the countrys

    shift inPolityover the following five years.10 Thus, we run regressions of the following form:

    Polityit(5-year) =dEmit(Pop.Share) +dEmit(P olity Average) + Xit+t+it

    We also run probits predicting democratization (within the following five years) using the

    dichotomous measure from Boix et al. (2013).

    10 The five-year structure follows Spilimbergo (2009) and Bearce and Hutnick (2011).

    16

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    17/34

    Control Variables

    The first tests predict logged emigration flows. Our main variable of interest is Emigration

    Freedomin the sender. We also control for the senders Population(logged, from Heston et al.

    2011),GDP/capita(logged, in real 2000 dollars, from Haber and Menaldo 2011; World Bank

    2011), and Polity score (Marshall and Jaggers 2010). All are known to influence the size of

    migrant populations. The same variables are included for the receiving state.

    We further control for several dyadic variables. Reciprocal Flowis the logged flow of immi-

    gration, which captures a reciprocal effect and controls for omitted dyadic characteristics. We

    include the loggedDistancebetween capital cities (in miles, from Gleditsch and Ward 2001)11

    and a dummy for a Shared Border (Correlates of War Project 2007) to capture critical geo-

    graphic factors.Colonyis a three-valued indicator equal to 1 if the sender is a former colony

    of the receiver, -1 for the reverse, and 0 otherwise. Shared Language is a dummy variable

    indicating whether the countries share an official language (Melitz and Toubal 2012). Imports

    and Exports are trade measures (in billions of U.S. dollars, from Barbieri and Keshk 2012),

    which could confound our findings since these also fit a gravity-type relationship. Alliancein-

    dicates whether the two countries share a formal military alliance (Correlates of War Project

    2013) and War indicates involvement on opposing sides of an inter-state war (Sarkees and

    Wayman 2010).

    For predictingEmigration Freedom, our variables of interest are the three imputed emi-

    gration measures. We also control for the countrys Polityscore, population, average income,

    mean imports and exports, its number of neighbors, and Economic Growth (the average per-

    centage change in GDP/capita over the past two years). The models predicting democratic

    change are identical except for an added control for Emigration Freedomand the omission of

    dEmit(EF Average). All models control for the year as a linear term.

    11 This dataset lists the two Congos as having 0 distance apart, which skews the imputedemigration calculations since both countries are predicted to have extremely high bilateralmigration. We changed this to the smallest value in the remaining data. The final results aresubstantively unchanged.

    17

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    18/34

    Empirical Results

    Predicting Emigration Flows

    Table 1 displays results predicting actual emigration flows. Model 1 uses total flows, Model2 those without a college degree, and Model 3 those with a college degree.

    As expected, the sendersEmigration Freedom is significantly positive for emigration across

    all models. Model 1 implies that moving from 0 to 1 onEmigration Freedomincreases yearly

    emigration by about 8%. According to Model 3, the effect is larger for flows of the college-

    educated. This suggests the relative ease of controlling professionals who have a greater need

    for legal emigration and documentation. Results are similar for the Abel and Sander (2014)

    data. Emigration Freedom in the receiver, which may correlate with freer immigration poli-

    cies, is also significantly positive, but only in the first model. In sum, the results support our

    assumption thatEmigration Freedomis a tool for influencing emigration.

    Most of the controls yield expected results. Both states populations are positive. Average

    income in the receiver strongly predicts emigration as workers seek out economic opportuni-

    ties. Income in the sender is also positive, albeit much smaller in magnitude, which is con-

    sistent with the poverty trap literature that argues that the poorest of the poor cannot afford

    to migrate and lack the human capital needed to seek jobs abroad (Clemens 2014). Polityfor

    both countries is predictive, which likely indicates freedom to move in the sender and the

    attraction of more democratic receiving states.12 Reciprocal Flowis positive, indicating that

    emigration and immigration co-vary. A smaller distance, a shared border, exports, military al-

    liance, colonial history, and a shared language are all significantly and robustly predictive of

    emigration flows, demonstrating the importance of geography and geopolitical relationships.

    12 Even so, migrants disproportionately flow between similar regime types. Between 1960and 2000, 80% of migrants originally from a democracy worked in another democracy. Incomparison, only 45% from an autocracy worked in a democracy.

    18

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    19/34

    Predicting Emigration Freedom

    Table 1 displays results predictingEmigration Freedom in autocracies, with the models

    successively adding controls. Model 1 includes the three imputed variables and Polity, Model

    2 adds the remaining controls, and Model 3 adds interactions between Polity and two of the

    imputed variables. Again, we predict that autocracies restrict emigration if citizens have a

    high feasibility of exit or will likely emigrate to democracies.

    Surprisingly, the feasibility of exit, indicated bydEmit(P op. Share), is positively predictiveofEmigration Freedom. However, the effect is substantively smallholding other variables at

    their medians, expecting an additional 10% of the population to emigrate increases the like-

    lihood of the lowest category ofEmigration Freedomby less than 2%. This suggests that the

    exit threat and safety valve effects balance one another on average. Further, the interaction

    with Polityin Model 3 is insignificant. However, in line with Figure 3, Neighborsis strongly

    negative in all models. Thus, the net effects of feasibility remain uncertain.

    We find much clearer results fordEmit(P olity Average), which is significantly negative inModels 1 and 2. This result suggests that autocracies are much more concerned about emigra-

    tion when their citizens are likely to emigrate to a democratic country. Shifting

    dEmit(P olity Average)up its full range increases the likelihood of the lowest category ofEmi-

    gration Freedom by 12%. Further, Model 3 finds a significantly positive interaction withPolity.

    To interpret this, Figure 4 displays the marginal effect ofdEmit(P olity Average) for differentvalues ofPolity. What we see is that in the most repressive dictatorships, autocracies limit em-

    igration if citizens will move to democracies. This offers a partial explanation for the freedom

    of emigration in autocratic Mexico and Taiwan. Both experienced heavy population exchange

    with the U.S., but did so as liberalized autocracies that strongly encouraged international

    trade and were not as threatened by democratic ideas.

    Among the other variables, the coefficient ondEmit(EF Average) is strongly positive, sug-gesting a diffusion effect or a deliberate coordination of migration policies. Polityhas a posi-

    tive direct effect. Surprisingly, more populous countries have stricter emigration policies, even

    19

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    20/34

    when we control for expected emigration.Yearis negative, again indicating a tightening over

    time in autocracies. Finally, trade, average income, and recent growth have no effect.

    Predicting Democratic Change

    Table 1 displays results predicting democratic change in autocracies. Models 1 and 2 pre-

    dict Polityover the succeeding five years, whereas Models 3 and 4 predict democratization

    within five years (from Boix et al. 2013).

    Estimated emigration as a percent of the population, dEmit(P op. Share), is negative fordemocratic change in each model and significantly so in Models 3 and 4. This supports the

    safety valve mechanism, whereby emigration enables autocrats to expel dissidents. In Model

    3, expecting an additional 10% of the population to emigrate lowers the five-year likelihood of

    democratization by a modest 2.4%.

    Again, sharper results are found for the estimated emigration by regime type,

    dEmit(P olity Average), which has a strong positive effect on democratic change. Thus, greateremigration to democracies leads to a higher likelihood of democratization. Shifting

    dEmit(P olity Average)up its full range increases Polityby about 3.5 points (Model 1) and the

    five-year likelihood of democratization by about 16% (Model 3). To see if this is simply re-producing the familiar democratic contagion effect, Models 2 and 4 control for the regions

    Polity average (excluding the country itself), which has been shown to predict democratiza-

    tion (Brinks and Coppedge 2006).13dEmit(P olity Average) remains significantly positive andRegional Politydoes not approach significance. Moreover, Regional Polityis significantly pos-

    itive forPolity ifdEmit(P olity Average)is removed, suggesting that findings on regional con-tagion may in fact be driven by migration flows.

    Both of these effectsthe negative of feasibility of exit and the positive of democratic

    receiversare logically consistent with the findings on Emigration Freedom. The same char-

    acteristics that predict democratization also lead autocrats to restrict emigration in response.

    13 The eight regions are Latin America, North Africa and the Middle East, Post-Communist,sub-Saharan Africa, Western Europe and the British settler colonies, East Asia, SoutheastAsia and the Pacific, and South Asia.

    20

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    21/34

    Among the controls, more populous, low-growth, and poorer countries are more likely to

    democratize. Contrary to Aleman and Woods (2014), Emigration Freedom does not have a

    significant direct effect in any model. For the transition models, imports are positive and

    exports are negative, possibly indicating a need to repress labor and remain autocratic in

    export-oriented economies.

    Extensions

    We now consider several alterations to the above tests.14 First, do other characteristics of

    receiving countries besides democracy influence emigration freedom? For instance, is emigra-

    tion encouraged if citizens are likely to travel to especially wealthy or fast-growing countries?

    This was tested by altering the calculation ofdEmit(P olity Average)to determine the averageincome and growth levels of expected receiving countries. Surprisingly, neither influences the

    choice of emigration freedom. Thus, there appears to be something special about the influence

    of external democracies.

    Second, what is the effect ofimmigrationrather than emigration? Our focus has been on

    the latter given our interest in Emigration Freedom and theoretical expectations that the

    movements of citizens are of paramount importance. However, we extended our results by

    imputing immigration flows, again using the World Bank data. Unfortunately, these are very

    highly correlated with imputed emigration flows, so they display similar results in the main

    models. When both are tested, multicollinearity leads to null results. More interesting find-

    ings result from testing the expected difference between emigration and immigration (as a

    share of population). Net emigration is significantly negative for Emigration Freedom and

    significantly positive for full democratization,15 but not predictive ofPolitychange.

    Third, what is the effect ofactual emigration totals and the democratic character of emi-

    gration receivers? We replicated all of our measures using actual rather than imputed emigra-

    tion. As we have emphasized, these are highly endogenous to emigration freedom, democracy,

    14 Further details on these results will be provided in an online appendix and are currentlyavailable upon request.15 This is consistent with Bearce and Hutnick (2011), although they use actual, rather thanimputed, values.

    21

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    22/34

    and the policies of receiving countries, and thus results must be interpreted carefully. In par-

    ticular, predictions for Emigration Freedomare unsound due to reverse causation. However,

    results for democratic change are broadly supportive. Using either stocks or flows of emigra-

    tion, average democracy in receiving states is significantly positive for democratization. Total

    emigration (as a share of population) is generally null, but is significantly positive for Polity

    change when using stocks. Our main results suggest that this fragile finding is spurious.

    Fourth, how do democracies differ? Running the same models as Table 1, Emigration Free-

    domhas a slightly stronger effect on emigration flows in democracies, suggesting that their

    legal rules have greater efficacy. The imputation strategy was then applied to a sample of

    democracies. The effects on Emigration Freedom run in the opposite directionhigher ex-

    pected emigration tightens emigration policy and more democratic receivers loosen it. The

    latter effect implies that regimes generally prefer that their citizens are exposed to similar

    regime types. Replicating Table 3, expected emigration is strongly positive for democratic sur-

    vival, but this does not hold for Politychange. Democratic-centered emigration has no effect.

    Conclusion

    The number of international migrants has almost doubled from 92 million in 1960 to more

    than 200 million today (Ozden et al. 2011), with 42 million emigrating between 2005 and 2010

    alone (Abel and Sander 2014). Yet we have little understanding of the effect of this migration

    on politics in sending countries. Most migration scholarship examines immigration policies

    and the effects of immigration on receiving countries. Other scholars have examined how

    emigration affects local communities and the economy, but not politics at the regime level.

    This paper addresses this lacuna by analyzing how autocrats determine emigration policy

    and providing one of the first tests of how emigration affects regime type.

    Emigration is a double-edged sword for autocratic leaders. On the one hand, the loss of

    citizens, even temporarily, can signal a loss of legitimacy and harm the economy. Emigration

    to democracies may be especially problematic as emigrants learn the benefits of democratic

    systems and gain the tools to make democratization happen. On the other hand, emigration

    22

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    23/34

    can serve as a safety valve, allowing the state to expel potential dissidents. Further, emi-

    gration usually brings remittances and a variety of economic benefits. Given these costs and

    attractions, autocratic leaders strategically determine the freedom of emigration.

    We find that emigration policy is predictive of emigration flows, showing that autocrats

    have agency in influencing whether or not their people emigrate. We then find that autoc-

    racies with greater expected levels of emigration encourage it as a safety valve or for eco-

    nomic reasons, but this effect is small. More significantly, we show that when emigrants are

    more likely to go to democratic receiving countries, autocratic regimes restrict emigration.

    This suggests that autocrats fear that their citizens will be influenced by their time abroad

    and may bring back the tools to take down the regime. Finally, we find that autocratic lead-

    ers should not fear emigration in generalthere is a negative effect of predicted emigration

    on democratizationbut should fear emigration to democratic countries, which robustly pre-

    dicts democratization. Thus, general emigration may serve as a safety valve but emigration to

    democracies can empower citizens to fight for democracy at home. Among other implications,

    this elucidates a clear mechanism for the local diffusion of democracy.

    As a final point, this article suggests that developed democracies have yet another rea-

    son to open their doors to immigration. Whereas domestic politics and globalization have led

    developed democracies to restrict immigration, both economics and a desire to spread democ-

    racy caution against this. Greater immigration would not only increase economic growth with

    relatively few (material) distributional consequences, our results imply that it can effectively

    spread democratic norms and capacities. The implication is a more effective and much less

    expensive way to foment regime change than our current policies.

    23

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    24/34

    References

    Abel, Guy J., and Nikola Sander. 2014. Quantifying global international migration flows.Sci-ence343: 1520-22.

    Adida, Claire L. and Desha M. Girod. 2010. Do migrants improve their hometowns? Remit-

    tances and access to public services in Mexico, 1995?2000.Comparative Political Studies.

    Ahmed, Faisal Z. 2012. The perils of unearned foreign income: Aid, remittances, and govern-ment survival.American Political Science Review106(1): 146-65.

    Aleman, Jose, and Dwayne Woods. 2014. No way out: Travel restrictions and authoritarianregimes.Migration and Development.

    Anderson, Perry. 1974.Lineages of the Absolutist State. London, NLB.

    Barbieri, Katherine, and Omar Keshk. 2012. Correlates of War Project Trade Data Set Code-book, Version 3.0. Available at: www.correlatesofwar.org.

    Bearce, David H., and Jennifer A. Laks Hutnick. 2011. Toward an alternative explanation

    for the resource curse: Natural resources, immigration, and democratization. ComparativePolitical Studies44(6): 689-718.

    Bertocchi, Graziella, and Chiara Strozzi. 2008. International migration and the role of insti-tutions.Public Choice137: 81-102.

    Bhavnani, Rikhil, and Margaret Peters. 2014. Migration, politics and public goods: Evidenceusing new data from Kerala. Working Paper. Madison, WI and New Haven, CT. Universityof WisconsinMadison and Yale University.

    Boix, Carles. 2003.Democracy and Redistribution. Cambridge. Cambridge University Press.

    Boix, Carles, Michael K. Miller, and Sebastian Rosato. 2013. A complete data set of political

    regimes, 18002007.Comparative Political Studies46(12): 1523-54.Brettell, Caroline B. 1984. Emigration and its implications for the revolution in Northern Por-

    tugal. In: Contemporary Portugal, eds. Lawrence S. Graham and Harry M. Makler. Madison,University of Wisconsin Press, pp. 281-298.

    Breunig, Christian, Xun Cao, and Adam Luedtke. 2012. Global migration and political regimetype: A democratic disadvantage.British Journal of Political Science42(4): 825-54.

    Brinks, Daniel, and Michael Coppedge. 2006. Diffusion is no illusion: Neighbor emulation inthe third wave of democracy.Comparative Political Studies39(4): 463-89.

    Camp, Roderic Ai. Learning democracy in Mexico and the United States. Mexican Stud-ies/Estudios Mexicanos19(1): 3-27.

    Chauvet, Lisa, and Marion Mercier. Forthcoming. Do return migrants transfer political normsto their origin country? Evidence from Mali.Journal of Comparative Economics.

    Cingranelli, David L., and David L. Richards. 2008. The Cingranelli-Richards (CIRI)Human Rights Data Project Coding Manual Version 2008.3.13. Available at:ciri.binghamton.edu/documentation/ciri coding guide.pdf.

    Clemens, Michael. 2014. Does development reduce migration? Working Paper #359, Centerfor Global Development.

    24

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    25/34

    Correlates of War Project. 2007.Direct Contiguity Data, 18162006, Version 3.1. Available at:www.correlatesofwar.org.

    Correlates of War Project. 2013. Formal Interstate Alliance Dataset, Version 4.1. Available at:www.correlatesofwar.org.

    Docquier, Frederic, Elisabetta Lodigiani, Hillel Rapoport, and Maurice Schiff. 2013. Emigra-tion and democracy. Working paper.

    Docquier, Frederic, and Abdeslam Marfouk. 2005. International Migra-tion by Educational Attainment (19902000), Release 1.1. Available at:perso.uclouvain.be/frederic.docquier/oxlight.htm .

    Docquier, Frederic, and Hillel Rapoport. 2012. Globalization, brain drain, and development.Journal of Economic Literature50(3): 681-730.

    Endoh, Toake. 2009. Exporting Japan: Politics of Emigration to Latin America. Champaign,University of Illinois Press.

    Fitzgerald, David. 2006. Inside the sending state: The politics of Mexican emigration control.

    International Migration Review40(2): 259-93.

    Fitzgerald, Jennifer, David Leblang and, Jessica C. Teets. 2014. Defying the law of gravity:The political economy of international migration. World Politics66(3): 406-45.

    Fukuyama, Francis. 2011.The Origins of Political Order: From Prehuman Times to the FrenchRevolution. New York, Farrar, Straus and Giroux.

    Gleditsch, Kristian S., and Michael D. Ward. 2001. Measuring space: A minimum distancedatabase.Journal of Peace Research38: 749-68.

    Gleditsch, Kristian S., and Michael D. Ward. 2006. Diffusion and the international context ofdemocratization.International Organization60: 911-33.

    Gould, David M. 1994. Immigrant links to the home country: empirical implications for USbilateral trade flows.The Review of Economics and Statistics: 302-316.

    Haber, Stephen, and Victor Menaldo. 2011. Do natural resources fuel authoritarianism? Areappraisal of the resource curse.American Political Science Review105(1): 1-26.

    Herbst, Jeffrey. 1990. Migration, the politics of protest, and state consolidation in Africa.African Affairs89: 183-203.

    Heston, Alan, Robert Summers, and Bettina Aten. 2011. Penn World Table Version 7.0. Cen-ter for International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University ofPennsylvania. Available at: pwt.econ.upenn.edu.

    Hirschman, Albert O. 1970.Exit, Voice, and Loyalty: Repsonses to Declines in Firms, Organi-zations, and States. Cambridge, Harvard University Press.

    Hirschman, Albert O. 1978. Exit, voice, and the state. World Politics31(1): 90-107.

    Hirschman, Albert O. 1993. Exit, voice, and the fate of the German Democratic Republic: Anessay in conceptual history.World Politics45(2): 173-202.

    Hobsbawm, E.J. 1975.The Age of Capital, 18481875. New York, Charles Scribners Sons.

    25

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    26/34

    Iskander, Natasha. 2010. Creative State: Forty Years of Migration and Development Policy inMorocco and Mexico. Ithaca, Cornell University Press.

    Kapur, Devesh. 2010. Diaspora, Democracy and Development: The Impact of InternationalMigration from India. Princeton, Princeton University Press.

    Kapur, Devesh. 2014. Political effects of international migration. Annual Review of PoliticalScience17: 479-502.

    Kuran, Timur. 1991. Now out of Never: The Element of Surprise in the East European Revo-lution of 1989.World Politics44(1):7-48.

    Lankina, Tomila V., and Lullit Getachew. 2006. A geographic incremental theory of democra-tizaton: Territory, aid, and democracy in postcommunist regions. World Politics58: 536-82.

    Leblang, David. 2010. Familiarity breeds investment: Diaspora networks and internationalinvestment.American Political Science Review. 104(3): 584-600.

    Levitsky, Steven, and Lucan A. Way. 2010. Competitive Authoritarianism: Hybrid RegimesAfter the Cold War. Cambridge, Cambridge University Press.

    Lohmann, Susanne. 1994. The Dynamics of Informational Cascades: The Monday Demonstra-tions in Leipzig, East Germany, 1989?91. World Politics47(1): 42-101.

    McKenzie, David. 2007. Paper walls are easier to tear down: Passport costs and legal barriersto emigration.World Development35(11): 2026-39.

    Mahmoud, Toman Omar, Hillel Rapoport, Andreas Steinmayr, and Christoph Trebesch. 2014.The effect of labor migration on the diffusion of democracy: Evidence from a former Sovietrepublic. IZA Discussion Paper #7980.

    Marshall, Monty G., and Keith Jaggers. 2010. POLITY IV PROJECT: Political Regime Char-acteristics and Transitions, 18002009. Center for Systemic Peace, George Mason Univer-

    sity.Massey, Douglas S. 1999. International migration at the dawn of the twenty-first century: The

    role of the state. Population and Development Review25(2): 303-22.

    Mayda, Anna Maria. 2010. International migration: A panel data analysis of the determinantsof bilateral flows.Journal of Population Economics23: 1249-74.

    Melitz, Jacques, and Farid Toubal. 2012. Native language, spoken language, translation andtrade. CEPII. Working Paper #2012-17.

    Moses, Jonathon W. 2011.Emigration and Political Development. New York, Cambridge Uni-versity Press.

    OECD. 2008.A Profile of Immigrant Populations in the 21st Century. OECD, Paris.

    OMahony, Angela. 2013. Political investment: Remittances and elections. British Journal ofPolitical Science 43(4): 799-820.

    ORourke, Kevin H., and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 1999.Globalization and History: The Evolu-tion of a Nineteenth-Century Atlantic Economy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Ortega, Francesc, and Giovanni Peri. 2014. Migration and income: The roles of trade andmigration.Journal of International Economics92(2): 231-51.

    26

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    27/34

    Ozden, Caglar, Christopher R. Parsons, Maurice Schiff, and Terrie L. Walmsley. 2011. Whereon Earth is everybody? The evolution of global bilateral migration 19602000.World BankEconomic Review25(1): 12-56.

    Perez-Armendariz, Clarisa, and David Crow. 2010. Do migrants remit democracy? Interna-tional migration, political beliefs, and behavior in Mexico. Comparative Political Studies

    43(1): 119-48.Peters, Margaret. 2013. Immigration, delegation and international law. Working Paper. New

    Haven, Yale University.

    Peters, Margaret. 2014. War financing and the re-imposition of serfdom after the Black Death.Working Paper. New Haven, Yale University.

    Pfaff, Steven, and Hyojoung Kim. 2003. Exit-voice dynamics in collective action: An analysisof emigration and protest in the East German revolution. American Journal of Sociology109(2): 401-44.

    Pfutze, Tobias. 2012. Does migration promote democratization? Evidence from the Mexicantransition.Journal of Comparative Economics40: 159-75.

    Sarkees, Meredith Reid, and Frank Wayman. 2010. Resort to War: 18162007. Washington,CQ Press.

    Spilimbergo, Antonio. 2009. Democracy and foreign education. American Economic Review99(1): 528-43.

    Torfason, Magnus Thor, and Paul Ingram. 2010. The global rise of democracy: A networkaccount.American Sociological Review75(3): 355-77.

    Waisman, Carlos H. 1989. Argentina: Autarkic industrialization and illegitimacy. In:Democ-racy in Developing Countries, Volume 4: Latin America, eds. Larry Diamond, Juan J. Linz,and Seymour M. Lipset. Boulder, Lynne Rienner, pp.59-109.

    World Bank. 2011. Statistics retrieved 2011, from World Development Indicators Online(WDI). Available at: www.worldbank.org/data.

    Yang, Dean. 2008. Coping with disaster: The impact of hurricanes on international financialflows, 19702002.The B.E. Journal of Economic Analysis & Policy8(1).

    27

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    28/34

    Democracies

    Autocracies

    .4

    .6

    .8

    1

    AverageEmigrationFreedom

    1980 1990 2000 2010Year

    Emigration Freedom and Democracy

    Democracies

    Autocracies

    .2

    .4

    .6

    .8

    1

    AverageFreedomo

    fAssoc

    iation

    1980 1990 2000 2010Year

    Freedom of Association and Democracy

    Fig. 1: The top panel shows the average emigration freedom (which varies from 0 to 1) indemocracies and autocracies from 1981 to 2010. Democracies are defined by a threshold of 6onPolity. The bottom panel shows the same relationship for the freedom of association. Bothfreedom measures are from Cingranelli and Richards (2008). Autocracies steadily declined onemigration freedom over time, which is not observed for freedom of association.

    28

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    29/34

    2000s

    1980s

    0

    .2

    .4

    .6

    .8

    1

    Avera

    geEmigrationFreedom

    -10 -5 0 5 10

    Polity

    Emigration Freedom by Polity Score

    Fig. 2:The figure shows the average emigration freedom for each Polityvalue. This is shownseparately for the 1980s and 2000s. The positive relationship between emigration freedomandPolityis much stronger in the 2000s.

    29

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    30/34

    0

    .2

    .4

    .6

    .8

    Avera

    geEmigrationFreedom

    0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 14

    Neighbors

    Emigration Freedom in Autocracies

    Fig. 3:The figure shows the average emigration freedom in autocracies, divided by the coun-trys number of neighbors. Autocracies score below a threshold of 6 on Polity. Emigrationbecomes more restrictive when an autocracy has more neighbors, which tracks the feasibilityof exit for citizens.

    30

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    31/34

    Table 1: Regressions Predicting Emigration Flows

    (1) (2) (3)DV = Emigration(ln) Total No College College

    Sender Variables

    Emigration Freedom 0.077 0.058 0.097

    (3.39) (2.87) (5.44)

    Population(ln) 0.257 0.178 0.173

    (28.34) (19.31) (23.25)

    GDP/capita(ln) 0.036 0.008 0.025

    (3.45) (0.84) (3.05)

    Polity 0.010 0.009 0.005

    (3.83) (4.07) (2.78)

    Receiver Variables

    Emigration Freedom 0.079 0.023 0.018(3.00) (0.86) (0.81)

    Population(ln) 0.172 0.122 0.115

    (20.58) (14.67) (16.67)

    GDP/capita(ln) 0.362

    0.303

    0.339

    (27.80) (25.05) (33.47)

    Polity 0.031 0.016 0.015

    (17.91) (9.38) (11.25)

    Dyadic Variables

    Reciprocal Flow(ln) 0.193 0.196 0.294

    (12.08) (9.91) (13.76)

    Distance(ln) 0.662 0.465 0.289

    (24.16) (18.61) (15.73)

    Shared Border 1.768 2.004 0.784

    (8.75) (9.01) (5.72)

    Colony 2.134 3.081 2.568

    (5.11) (10.34) (11.86)

    Shared Language 0.296 0.402 0.419

    (6.92) (9.32) (11.37)

    Imports 0.093 0.056 0.072(1.33) (1.22) (1.57)

    Exports 0.120 0.116 0.108

    (2.19) (2.92) (3.07)

    Alliance 0.538 0.523 0.435

    (5.62) (4.91) (5.99)

    War 1.270 1.695 1.312

    (1.05) (1.89) (2.66)

    Year 0.008 0.016 0.012

    (5.45) (14.08) (12.25)

    N 163,292 103,006 115,161Countries (S/R) 104/137 104/158 104/158Adj. R2 0.403 0.385 0.423

    Notes: The table displays regressions predicting yearly emigrationflows from a sample of autocracies to each other country in the world.t statistics (based on robust standard errors clustered by countrydyad) are shown in parentheses. p

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    32/34

    Table 2: Ordered Probits Predicting Emigration Freedom

    DV = Emigration Freedom (1) (2) (3)

    dEmit(P op. Share) 0.593 0.476 0.459(2.78) (2.10) (1.71)

    dEmit(P olity Average) 0.027

    0.019 0.009

    (4.12) (2.62) (0.86)

    dEmit(P op. Share) Polity 0.004(0.09)

    dEmit(P olity Average) Polity 0.005(3.67)

    dEmit(EF Average) 1.505 1.210 1.131(12.42) (9.62) (8.83)

    Polity 0.044 0.061 0.053

    (7.14) (9.19) (7.28)

    Population(ln) 0.081 0.072

    (3.78) (3.32)

    GDP/capita (ln) 0.014 0.006(0.51) (0.20)

    Economic Growth 0.000 0.001(0.06) (0.22)

    Neighbors 0.128 0.129

    (9.39) (9.40)

    Mean Imports 0.788 0.621(1.95) (1.53)

    Mean Exports 0.488 0.341

    (1.21) (0.84)Year 0.028 0.028

    (7.55) (7.55)

    N 2,186 2,185 2,185Countries 119 119 119BIC 4,610.7 4,358.6 4,359.9

    Notes: The table displays ordered probits predictingEmigration Free-domin autocracies. t statistics (based on robust standard errors) are inparentheses. p

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    33/34

    -.05

    0

    .05

    .1

    -10 -9 -8 -7 -6 -5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5

    Polity (Sender)

    in Emigration Receivers

    Marginal Effect of Expected Polity Score

    Fig. 4:The figure shows the marginal effect ofdEmit(P olity Average)on Emigration Freedomfor different values ofPolity, calculated from Model 3 of Table 2. When likely emigrationreceivers are democratic, this causes autocracies to restrict emigration freedom, but only inthe most repressive states.

    33

  • 8/11/2019 Migration Policy and Autocratic Power

    34/34

    Table 3: Models Predicting Democratization

    Polityit (5-year) Democratization (BMR)

    (1) (2) (3) (4)

    dEmit(P op. Share) 1.283 1.306 1.861 1.861(0.73) (0.74) (2.73) (2.73)

    dEmit(P olity Average) 0.176 0.170 0.051 0.051(6.73) (5.75) (4.69) (4.23)

    Emigration Freedom 0.387 0.407 0.057 0.056(1.57) (1.60) (0.49) (0.47)

    Polity 0.219 0.222 0.072 0.072

    (9.49) (9.28) (7.85) (7.74)

    Population(ln) 0.236 0.237 0.147 0.147

    (2.86) (2.86) (4.42) (4.41)

    GDP/capita (ln) 0.306 0.299 0.119 0.119

    (3.42) (3.27) (2.36) (2.34)

    Economic Growth 0.029

    0.029

    0.018

    0.018

    (2.46) (2.46) (2.41) (2.43)

    Neighbors 0.090 0.087 0.047 0.047(1.54) (1.49) (2.03) (2.01)

    Mean Imports 0.849 0.856 2.657 2.658

    (0.78) (0.79) (3.13) (3.13)

    Mean Exports 1.167 1.203 2.946 2.944

    (1.17) (1.21) (3.06) (3.05)

    Year 0.046 0.049 0.033 0.033

    (3.38) (3.23) (5.61) (5.10)

    Regional Polity 0.020 0.001(0.45) (0.07)

    N 1,879 1,879 1,804 1,804Countries 116 116 117 117Adj./Pseudo R2 0.084 0.083 0.135 0.135

    Notes:The table displays regressions predicting the give-year change in Polity(Models 1-2) and probits predicting democratization over five years (Models 3-4).All models use a sample of autocracies. t statistics (based on robust standarderrors) are in parentheses. p