lqg cambridge bernd [read only]

Upload: aloke-chatterjee

Post on 09-Apr-2018

225 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    1/49

    1Page

    Morgan Stanley Investment Management

    Portfolio Management Today A Tour Around Recent Advances in PortfolioConstruction

    Dr. B. Scherer, September 2008

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    2/49

    2Page

    Table of Contents

    Section 1 The Evolution of Risk Measures

    Section 2 Postmodern Portfolio Theory (PMPT)

    Section 3 Estimation Error: Bayesian Estimates versus Robust Estimation

    Section 4 Fairness in Asset Management

    Section 5 Optimal Leverage: About Feathers and Stones

    Overview

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    3/49

    3Page

    Axioms on Random Variables versus Behaviour

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    Statistics versus Financial Economics

    Why do we need a goodrisk measure?

    - Pricing in incompletemarkets

    - Portfolio selection

    Can we invent riskmeasures arbitrarily?

    Actuarial research / Statistics (Axioms on random variables)

    define a set of reasonable axioms

    deduce a risk measure or criticize risk measures

    dependent on the appropriateness of axioms

    Financial economics (Axioms on behaviour)

    Decision making under uncertainty(NEUMAN/MORGENSTERN)

    deduce a risk measure or criticize risk measures

    dependent on the appropriateness of axioms

    Without a good risk (better risk/reward) measure there is nomeaningful portfolio selection

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    4/49

    4Page

    Decision theoretic Foundation

    Above holds as long as returns are not too non-normal(MARKOWITZ/LEVY, 1979); many studies confirm this

    Caution: An often made mistake (maximizing net presentvalue and utility optimization have nothing in common)

    Modern Finance is about the separation of preferences andvaluation, see your favourite corporate finance textbook(only actuaries ignore this)

    ( ) ( )( ) 21/

    arg max arg max 1w

    w w w wnP P T T

    i iiw

    Neumann Morgenstern MARKOWITZ

    E U Wealth E U w r =

    = = +

    ( )

    ,

    2 1 1! max

    = + shareholder i

    i

    CFT T

    i COEw w w

    Why did we ever look at volatility?It seemed an approximation to maximizing expected utility

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    5/49

    5Page

    Volatility Is Not Always An Ideal Risk Measure but not as bad as you think

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    Disadvantages

    Simply not true for many return series and seriously wrong for optionedportfolios

    Advantages (Why do people still use it?)

    Ok for large diversified long/short portfolios and/or long time horizons Degree of non-normality is not too large for monthly (typical revision

    horizon) return series

    Symmetry (uses all data): small estimation error

    Easy portfolio aggregation & time aggregation

    Consistent with earlier asset pricing models Computational solutions readily available

    Ok for elliptical distributions

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    6/49

    6Page

    Disadvantages Quintile measure; ignores risks within the tail

    Might induce taking of extreme risks (BASAK/SHAPIRO, 2001)

    Diversification can lead to higher Risk (not sub-additive)

    Not convex, i.e. impossible to use in optimization problems

    Advantages

    More perceived than real / would Value at Risk have beenpromoted if deficiencies would have been known earlier?

    Value at Risk definitely worse than you think

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    Problem: despite all itsdeficits, no practitioner will bewilling to give it up as it isuniversal and can beexpressed in $

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    7/49

    7Page

    Scenario Manager 1 Manager 2 Manager 1+2 Probability

    1 -20% 2% -9% 3%

    2 -3% 2% -0,5% 2%

    3 2% -20% -9% 3%

    4 2% -3% -0,5% 2%

    5 2% 2% 2% 90%

    Table 1. Data Manager Combination: Active Return

    Risk Measure Manager 1 Manager 2 Manager 1+2

    Volatility 3,80% 3,80% 2,63%

    Value at Risk(95%)-3% -3% -9%

    LPM0 5% 5% 10%

    CVaR -13,20% -13,20% -5,60%

    Table 2. Risk Measures in Multiple Manager Example

    The reason for these

    paradoxical results

    directly lies in the

    concept of value at risk.

    It ignores the large -20%

    losses that are waiting

    undetected in the tail of

    the distribution. However,when we average across

    portfolios these returns

    will be diversified into the

    portfolio risk measure

    and increase risk as they

    have been ignoredbefore. )

    Value at Risk gives wrong diversification advice!

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    8/49

    8Page

    Coherent, but also economically

    sensible? Are you risk neutral in the tail?

    Neglected approximation issue

    Nonparametric & unconditional

    Large estimation error

    Driven by rare events

    Only uses few data points

    Implicit momentum

    Up markets (momentum)show little risks: Japan fallacy

    Explains superiority in back-tests

    Risk measure depends onreturn estimate!!

    Conditional Value at RiskOnly marginally better

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    MSCI Japan, annual data 1975 - 1992

    -40%

    -30%

    -20%

    -10%

    0%

    10%

    20%

    30%

    40%

    50%

    60%

    1975

    1976

    1977

    1978

    1979

    1980

    1981

    1982

    1983

    1984

    1985

    1986

    1987

    1988

    1989

    1990

    1991

    1992A

    nnualreturnin%

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    9/49

    9Page

    Lower partial moments

    Semi-variance

    Mean absolute deviation

    Omega ratio

    Minimum Regret

    Some Other Risk MeasuresAll of them equally problematic

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    Utility theory is used as ex-

    post sanctification, i.e.academic fig-leave

    Necessary utility functionsimplausible with observedbehaviour / preferences

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    10/49

    10Page

    Spectral Risk Measures: Theory

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    Value at Risk places all weight on a single quintile (implies investordoes not care about tail risk)

    Conditional Value at Risk places an equal weight to all tail quintilesand zero else (implies investor is risk neutral in the tail)

    ACERBI (2004) allows us to include risk aversion in the risk measureby allowing a (subjective) weighting on quintiles

    If (p) is a non-decreasing function, spectral risk measures arecoherent

    Weighting quintiles

    ( ) ( )

    ( )( )1

    1

    0X

    lossweighting

    quantilefunction

    M X p F p p dp =

    Giving larger weights to

    more extreme quintiles issuper close to

    maximizing expected

    utility for reasonable

    utility functions

    Weights all cases fromworst to best

    Advantage: weighting

    function allows to merge

    the risk measure with risk

    preferences

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    11/49

    11Page

    Spectral Risk Measures: Example

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    Weighting quintiles

    I assume an exponential weighting scheme derived from the

    exponential utility function DOWD/COTTER (2007)

    Larger risk aversion leads to a larger risk measure

    This effect tails out for the normal distribution but is unchanged for

    the t-distribution

    ( )( )( )

    ( )

    exp 11 exp

    a a p

    ap

    =

    a Normal-Dist T-Dist1 0,27 3,8

    5 1,08 18,26

    10 1,50 34,69

    25 1,95 79,69

    100 2,51 274,79

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    12/49

    12Page

    Portfolio Construction under Non-Normality

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    Use of downside risk measures

    If you feel you must, but I would advise against it

    Approximate Utility Optimization

    Quadrature methods

    Higher order expansions of utility functions: number of higher co-moments grows extremely large for large number of assets

    In the co-skewness and co-kurtosis matrix we are in need to calculaten(n+1)(n+2)/6and n(n+1)(n+2)(n+3)/24 different entries

    Full Scale Direct Optimization Theoretically and practically most convincing

    See KRITZMAN (2007) for convincing out of sample results

    What are our options?

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    13/49

    13Page

    In Summary: A Vicious Research Cycle

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    After 60 years we are back to our roots

    Utility OptimizationNEUMANN/MORGENSTERN, 1944

    Spectral Risk MeasuresACERBI, 2004

    VaR and CvaR optimization(ROCKEFELLER/URYASEV, 2000)

    Mean Variance Optimizationas an approximation to Utility Optimization

    (MARKOWITZ, 1955)

    Lower partialMoments

    (FISHBURN/SORTINO 1990)

    Expected utility is a riskadjusted performancemeasure

    Expected utility can not begamed

    Expected utility explainswhy some people buy andothers sell options

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    14/49

    14Page

    Case Study: Risk Measures and the Credit Crunch

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    Investment universe: UK equities (FTSE), Emerging market bonds

    (EMBI), Commodities (GSCI), Emerging markets equities (MSCI)

    Take five years of monthly data up to June 2007 to get the followingweights

    Leads to the following characteristics

    In Sample Optimization

    Portfolioweights

    EmergingMarket Bonds

    UK EquitiesGSCI

    CommoditiesEM Equities

    Mean Variance 24,63% 34,12% 1,82% 39,43%Mean Absolute Deviation 31,83% 26,19% 0,00% 41,99%

    Semi-Variance 21,35% 39,67% 1,21% 37,78%

    Minimizing Regret 40,92% 13,09% 0,00% 46,00%

    Conditional Value at Risk 19,31% 44,22% 0,00% 36,47%

    Volatility Value at RiskConditional

    Value at RiskSemivariance

    CumulativeDrawdown

    Worst month Return

    Mean Variance 2,29% -2,73% -3,59% 1,75% -5,10% -4,89% 1,67%

    Mean Absolute Deviation 2,30% -2,65% -3,77% 1,81% -5,85% -4,81% 1,67%

    Semi-Variance 2,35% -2,71% -4,06% 1,88% -6,77% -4,71% 1,67%

    Minimizing Regret 2,29% -2,50% -4,06% 1,72% -4,93% -4,93% 1,67%

    Conditional Value at Risk 2,30% -2,34% -3,36% 1,73% -4,95% -4,95% 1,67%

    See SCHERER/MARTIN(2005) for complete codeincluding URYASEV VARapproximation

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    15/49

    15Page

    Case Study: Risk Measures and the Credit Crunch

    Section 1: The Evolution of Risk Measures

    No clear picture

    Minimizing regret (close to robust and very pessimistic) does best

    CVAR does worst; out of sample UK and Emerging market equitiesdid worst while Emerging bonds and Commodities did best

    (sampling error seriously affects CVAR)

    Out of Sample Performance

    Volat ility Value at RiskConditional

    Value at RiskSemivariance

    CumulativeDrawdown

    Worst month Return

    Mean Variance 3,81% -6,83% -7,98% 2,79% -14,32% -7,98% -0,33%

    Mean Absolute Deviation 3,71% -6,57% -7,88% 2,79% -14,34% -7,88% -0,30%

    Semi-Variance 3,61% -6,03% -7,34% 2,42% -13,76% -7,34% -0,18%

    Minimizing Regret 3,86% -7,08% -8,29% 2,88% -14,98% -8,29% -0,39%

    Conditional Value at Risk 3,90% -7,30% -8,64% 2,99% -15,81% -8,64% -0,47%

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    16/49

    16Page

    What is Postmodern Portfolio Theory?

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    Proponents are SHARPE (2007) and COCHRANE (2007)

    Asset pricing takes the distribution of wealth as given and derives

    asset prices using arbitrage principles and return characteristics

    Portfolio theory takes asset prices as given and derives the utilityoptimal allocation of wealth.

    Postmodern portfolio theory (PMPT) unites asset pricing and portfoliotheory by aligning risk neutral and real world distribution with the use ofstate price deflators.

    The new book by SHARPE (2007) is an impressive collection of realworld applications that allows for a much richer framework than the one

    currently used by practitioners.

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    17/49

    17Page

    PMPT: The Theoretical Framework

    Optimize utility or other objective function under the Pmeasure while

    constraints are governed by the Qmeasure

    Far superior to what the industry has done so far. Some examplesinclude

    Eliminates arbitrage from MV optimization (allows us toinclude options into portfolio optimization)

    Implicitly solves dynamic optimization problems (we canwrite down any payoff for final wealth as long as thebudget constraint is satisfied)

    Tracking dynamic trading strategies

    Combines P and Q measure

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    [ ] ( )

    ( )[ ]1

    arg maxQ

    o

    P

    E W W c

    E U W= +

    =w

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    18/49

    18Page

    How can we rescue implied returns?

    Step 1. Build pricing kernel from utility function

    Step 2. Expected returns for all assets are the same under theabove pricing measure

    Solve fordi for alternative utility functions and risk aversions

    What happen if we leave MV efficiency?

    This approach (GRINOLD,

    1999 and SHARPE, 2007)works under arbitraryutility functions and showsthe power of neo portfoliotheory by merging theliterature on asset pricingand asset allocation.

    ( )

    ( )

    ,*

    ,1

    1

    1

    s s bs S

    s s bs

    U R

    U R

    =

    +=

    +

    ( )* *, ,1 1S S

    s s i i s s bs sR d R

    = =+ =

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    19/49

    19Page

    Building More Meaningful Implied Returns

    More risk averse investors

    place larger weight on tailsof the distribution andhence require much largerexcess returns to bewilling to hold a negativelyskewed asset

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    Source: Scherer (2007, chapter 9 )

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    20/49

    20Page

    Example: Replication of CPPI Strategies

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    We suggest solving the following problem. Minimize the tracking error between the

    continuous CPPI trading strategy and our static buy and hold tracking portfolio

    ( )1

    2*

    , , 1,min rT

    i T i c S T i c iiW w e w S w C

    subject to a budget constraint

    ( )10 , 1,

    6000 6000rT rT

    i c S T i c iiW e w e w S w C = + + =

    and a non-negativity constraint on individual asset holdings

    10, 0, 0, , 0

    mc S c cw w w w

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    21/49

    21Page

    Example: Replication of CPPI Strategies

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    We also need a cardinality constraint for the number of instruments (assetsn ) involved:

    { }

    { }

    { }

    { }

    1 1 1

    large number , 0,1

    large number , 0,1

    large number , 0,1

    large number , 0,1m m m

    c c c

    S S S

    c c c

    c c c

    w

    w

    w

    w

    Note that each equation provides a logical switch using a binary Variable that takes

    on a value of either 0 or 1. Let us review the case for cash to clarify the calculations.

    As soon as 0cw > by even the smallest amount, cash enters the optimal solution in

    which case 1c = to satisfy the inequality. If 0cw = instead, it must follow that 0c =

    Computationally the large number should not be chosen too large, i.e. it depends

    how large cw can become . Finally we need to add the dummy variables to count

    the number of assets that enter the optimal solution.

    1 mc S c c assetsn + + + +

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    22/49

    22Page

    Example: Replication of CPPI Strategies

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    Stock market

    OBPIminusCPPI

    4000 6000 8000 10000 12000 14000

    -1500

    -100

    0

    -500

    0

    Figure 2. Hedging error of a static option hedge. We used 6assetsn = to track a given CPPI

    strategy. Note that hedging errors (difference between CPPI and OBPI payoff) are small around thecurrent stock price of 6000 and much larger where tracking is less relevant, i.e. where the real worldprobability is low.

    Source: Scherer (2007, chapter 8 )

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    23/49

    23Page

    Example: Replication of CPPI Strategies

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    # of admissable instruments

    Tra

    ckingerror

    4 6 8 10 12

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    1.2

    1

    .4

    Figure 3. Reduction of hedging error and number of admissible instruments. As the number ofinstruments rises, the tracking error decreases. Note that tracking error is expressed as annualpercentage volatility, meaning 0.2 equals 20%. The tracking advantage tails off quickly with more than8 admissible instruments.

    Source: Scherer (2007, chapter 8 )

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    24/49

    24Page

    Strike

    Impliedvola

    tility

    5000 5500 6000 6500 7000

    0.1

    0

    0.1

    5

    0.2

    0

    0.2

    5

    Ordinary least squaresRobust regression

    Figure 4. Fitted implied volatilities for linear and robust regression. The crosssectional regression is run using both OLS as well as robust regression. Fitted linesare either dashed or dotted, while the raw data are provided in Table 4.

    Example: Utility Optimization

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    ( )( ) ( )( ) ( )( )

    ( )

    1 1 1 1

    2

    1

    , , 2 , , , ,i impl i i impl i i impl i

    i i

    C S S C S S C S SrT

    i S Se

    + +

    +

    +

    =

    Source: Scherer (2007, chapter 8 )

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    25/49

    25Page

    Stock price

    Riskneutra

    ldensity

    5000 5500 6000 6500 7000

    0.0

    0.005

    0.0

    10

    0.015 Lognormal PDF

    Option implied PDF

    Figure 5. Lognormal volatility versus option implied volatility. Implied risk neutral densities areprovided for both a lognormal model (with 11% historical volatility) as well as for the coefficientestimates of the robust regression.

    Implied Density

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    Source: Scherer (2007, chapter 8 )

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    26/49

    26Page

    111

    , 1u W for

    =

    ( )1

    1,1

    maxi T ii

    W

    ( )0 ,6000 6000rT rT

    i c S T iiW e w e w S= + =

    Risk aversion Implied volatility Lognormal volatility

    2 100.00% 100.00%

    5 74.54% 78.91%10 37.51% 39.45%

    50 7.54% 7.89%

    Optimal equity allocations

    Example: Utility Optimization

    Section 2: Postmodern Portfolio Theory

    Forward looking riskmeasure that uses themarkets risk perceptionrather than unconditionaldistribution

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    27/49

    27Page

    Some Frustration with Bayesian MethodsWhere we have been stuck

    The main reason for thesuccess of theBLACK/LITTERMANmodel was its anchoringin the market portfolio.

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

    The BLACK/LITTERMAN model looks (very) tired Many problems yet unsolved

    BAYES and Non-normality

    Informative priors and missing data

    Partial solutions: various ways to deal with estimation error. Whats the

    best combination?

    Interesting new development: Economic priors by McGULLOCH

    Required subjectivity (information) is deemed too high by many users; (too)

    great level of arbitrariness, too much subjectivity, too much responsibility

    Practitioners want the solution to be built into the optimisation process;

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    28/49

    28Page

    Reaction 1: Create Robust SolutionsSolutions that dont change too much

    Section 3 The Robust Contra-Revolution

    Upper and lower bounds: JAGANNATHAN/MA (2003), can be viewedas leveraging up the respective entries in the covariance matrix

    1/n rule: DEMIGUEL/GARLAPPI/UPPAL (2007), equal weighting ishard to beat

    Vector norms: DEMIGUEL/GARLAPPI/UPPAL/NOGALES (2007)

    Concentration measures: KING (2008)

    Most of the above can be shown to be equivalent

    to Bayesian shrinkage!

    Percentage contribution to risks

    Weight baseddiversification constraints

    Risk based diversificationconstraints

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    29/49

    29Page

    Reaction 2: Create Robust InputsCombat estimation error impact by making forecasts that dont differ too much

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

    Create ordinal scores (+1 for outperform and -1 for underperform). For diagonalcovariance matrix this leads to

    Percentile ranks as in SATCHELL/WRIGHT (2003)

    Ordering information as in CHRIS/ALMGREN (2006)

    Robust statistics as reviewed in SCHERER/MARTIN, 2005

    In my view this iswidespread in active quant

    strategies

    ( )11 1

    i ii iw

    =

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    30/49

    30Page

    Reaction 3: Robust OptimizationBuild solution into optimization process

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

    An early attempt: Ttnc/Knig (2004) Try to find good solutions for all possible parameter realizations

    How do we define the set of all possible parameters? Imposing shortsale constraints this simplifies to

    matricescovarianceallofSet:

    rsmean vectoallofSet:

    minmax,

    S

    S

    TT

    SS

    wwww

    confidencegivenaforofelementmaximal:

    confidencegivenaforofelementminmal:

    max0

    S

    S

    h

    l

    h

    T

    l

    T

    wwww

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    31/49

    31Page

    The Perils of Being Too Afraid

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

    Mean vector represents the lower 5% quintile entries, whilecovariance represents the upper 5% entries. Risk Aversion of 2.

    Data From Michaud (1998)

    Eq.Can Eq. Fra Eq.Ger Eq.Jap Eq.UK Eq.US Fi.US Fi.EU

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    Asset Class

    WeightAllocation

    Ad hoc way to define mean vectorand covariance matrix

    Leads to very cornered portfolios

    Poor rooting in classic decisiontheory

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    32/49

    32Page

    The Structure of Estimation Error

    For the purpose of this presentation we assume

    Could also allow for different error structures, that allowuncorrelated estimation errors and make diversification ofestimation errors optimal

    Note that as the number of assets rise the matrix becomesincreasingly difficult to estimate

    /n=

    21

    2

    2

    0

    0

    n

    n

    =

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    33/49

    33Page

    Robust Portfolio Optimization: The Contender

    CERIA/STUBBS (2003) derive the following objective function

    and after some tedious algebra (see SCHERER, 2006) we

    can get

    ( ) ( )12 2

    , 2, 1

    T T

    m p pL n

    = + w w w 1

    12

    ,

    1* 2

    ,

    12

    ,

    1* 2

    ,

    1 1* 11

    1 1

    *

    min

    1

    1

    m

    p m

    m

    p m

    Tn

    rob T Tn

    n

    specn

    +

    +

    = +

    = +

    1 1w 1

    1 1 1 1

    w w

    12

    ,

    1* 2

    ,

    0 1 1m

    p m

    n

    n

    +

    The careful reader will realize thatthe previous result essentiallyviews robust optimization asshrinkage estimator

    As long as estimation error

    aversion is positive this term willalways be smaller than one.

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    34/49

    34Page

    Fi.EUFi.USEq.USEq.UK

    Eq.JapEq.GerEq. FraEq.Can

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    Traditional Optimization

    Fi.EUFi.USEq.USEq.UKEq.JapEq.GerEq. FraEq.Can

    0.0

    0.2

    0.4

    0.6

    0.8

    1.0

    Robust Optimization

    Figure 1. Robust versus traditional portfolio construction ( 0.01, 60, 99.99%, 1000n S = = = = ). Robust

    portfolios react less sensitive to changes in expected returns. Given the high required confidence of 99.9%= ,robust portfolios invest heavily in assets with little estimation error. This is entirely different with our intuition

    that error in return estimates become less and less important as we move towards the minimum risk portfolio.

    The data are taken from Michaud (1998). The abbreviations used are FI.EU (fixed income Europe), FI.US (fixedincome US), Eq.US (equity US), EQ.UK (equity UK), EQ.Jap (equity Japan), EQ.Ger (equity Germany), EQ.Fra

    (equity France) and EQ.Can (equity Canada).

    How do solutions differ?

    The least risky asset isover-weighted in the

    solution

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    35/49

    35Page

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    Robust optimization

    0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7

    0

    10

    20

    30

    40

    50

    Traditional optimization

    Out of sample utility

    PercentofTotal

    Out of sample utility

    Some corner portfolios dontdo well out of sample

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    36/49

    36Page

    Small sample size (n = 60)

    = 95% = 97.5% = 99.99%

    = 0.05 9.7 bps(20.16)

    68.5%

    8.7bps

    (17.76)

    63.4%

    7.79bps

    (16.09)

    61.0%

    = 0.025 -3.13bps(-18.23)

    39.14%

    -5.54bps

    (-14.84)

    32.6%

    -6.96bps

    (-11.85)

    28.8%

    = 0.01 -19.8bps(-49,6)

    13.0%

    -24.09bps

    (-63.33)

    8.1%

    -26.14bps

    (-70.07)

    6.8%

    Out of sample performance for full investment universe (m=8). The table shows the relative performance of

    robust portfolio optimization relative to traditional portfolio optimization. The 1st

    number is the difference inexpected utility, which we can interpret in terms of a security equivalent (i.e. basis points of monthly

    performance). The 2nd

    number (in round brackets) represents the t-value of the difference in expected utility (avalue of about 2 would be significant at the 5% level, for a two sided hypothesis), while the third number

    represents the percentage of runs, where robust optimization generated a higher out of sample utility than

    traditional optimization.

    Out of sample utility

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    37/49

    37Page

    Summary

    Section 3: The Robust Contra-Revolution

    Robust methods based on estimation error are equivalent toshrinkage estimators and leave the efficient set unchanged

    Robust methods come at the expense of computational difficulties(2nd order cone programming), but at the advantage of automatedsolutions

    Yet difficult to calibrate uncertainty and risk aversion

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    38/49

    38Page

    Fairness in Asset Management

    Section 4: Fairness In Asset Management

    Implementation of views

    Clients differ in benchmarks, constraints, investment universe,risk budgets

    How do we make sure that all clients receive the sameinformation, i.e. that all client portfolios are consistent?

    Trading and transaction costs

    Asset management firms manage multiple accounts

    Asset manager is seen as mediator and guarantor of fairness intrading decisions

    Treat clients fairly

    FSA Principle #6: A

    firm must pay dueregard to its customersand treat them fairly

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    39/49

    39Page

    Portfolio Factory: Consistent View Implementation

    Section 4: Fairness In Asset Management

    Step 1: Start with unconstrained model portfolio (otherwise views are

    contaminated by constraints) Step 2: Back out implied returns

    Step 3: Run optimisation with client specific constraints whereby thesame implied returns are used for all clients

    Client portfolios will still differ in total and active weight (dispersion),but not in input information!

    (Step 4: Overcome organisational resistance: Portfolio factory

    weakens the role of the portfolio manager, portfolio constructionbecomes commodity, optimizer as the poor mans portfolio manager,portfolio manager loose out to analysts, i.e. information providers)

    How can we ensure all portfolios receive the same information/attention?

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    40/49

    40Page

    Optimization Across Multiple Accounts

    Section 4: Fairness In Asset Management

    Why is this a problem?

    ,1iw

    ,2iw

    Trade in asset i

    for account 1,2

    ( )w

    =

    ( )1

    ww

    =

    ( )1

    ww

    =

    TC allocated bytrading desk

    TC in independentoptimizations

    Marginal TC differ

    Total, marginal,

    averageTC

    Nonlinear transactioncosts create an externality

    from one account oneanother

    The literature provides twosolutions

    - NASH solution (CERIA,2007)

    - Collusive, Pareto optimalsolution (OCINNEIDE/SCHERER/XU, 2006)

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    41/49

    41Page

    Optimization Across Multiple Accounts

    Section 4: Fairness In Asset Management

    Two accounts of different size, s, that trade one asset n.

    Quadratic transaction cost function

    Standard preferences for each account (note that the cost term

    reflects cost sharing, i.e. both accounts trade simultaneously

    Model Set Up (joint work with Steve Satchell)

    ( )2

    1 1 2 22n s n s = +

    ( ) ( )( )2 22 2i i i i i i i j j i i VA n s n s n s n s n s = +

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    42/49

    42Page

    Stand Alone Solution

    Section 4: Fairness In Asset Management

    Optimal trading

    Optimize accounts separately without taking interactions into account (batch job)

    ( ) ( )( )2

    2 222 2arg max

    ii

    SAi i i i i i i s

    nn n s n s n s

    + = =

    0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4

    n2

    0

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    n1

    ( )

    2 2

    22

    SA SAi jVA VA

    + =

    +

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    43/49

    43Page

    COURNOT/NASH-Solution

    Section 4: Fairness In Asset Management

    First order condition (solving leads to reaction functions below)

    Interaction is accounted for but treated as given

    2 2 2 12 0

    i

    i

    dVAi i i i i j i j dn

    s n s n s n s s = =

    0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4

    n2

    0.1

    0.2

    0.3

    0.4

    n1

    ( ) ( )

    ( )( )

    2 2

    2 2

    2

    3 2

    3 20

    j j

    j

    CN SA

    j j s s

    s

    n n

    + +

    + +

    =

    =

  • 8/8/2019 Lqg Cambridge Bernd [Read Only]

    44/49

    44Page

    Collusive Solution

    Section 4: Fairness In Asset Management

    Combined objective function (monopoly)

    Leads to less trading and higher value added (risk adjusted client

    performance)

    Full interaction is accounted for

    ( )( ) ( )( )2 2 2 22 2 2 2i j i i i i j j i i j j i i j j j j VA VA VA n n n s n s n s n n n s n s n s = + = + + +

    ( )( )

    2 2

    22 2

    12 2 3 2

    0C CNi iVA VA

    + + = >

    2

    4 2

    1 1/C CNi in n

    +

    =