k) federal reserwe bank of san francisco · 2018-11-07 · the federal reserve bank of san...

30
K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO ECONOMIC REVIEW FALL 1982

Upload: others

Post on 25-Jun-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO

ECO N O M IC R E V IE W

FALL 1982

Page 2: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

Opinions expressed in the Economic Review do not necessarily reflect the views of the management of the Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, or of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System.

The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public Information Department under the supervision of Michael W. Keran, Senior Vice President. The publication is edited by Gregory J. Tong, with the assistance of Karen Rusk (editorial) and William Rosenthal (graphics).

For free copies of this and other Federal Reserve publications, write or phone the Public Information Department, Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco, P.O. Box 7702, San Francisco, California 94120. Phone (415) 974-3234.

2

Page 3: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

“ Money- Demand and Control"

I. Introduction and Summary 5

II. An Examination of the Federal Reserve’s Strategy for Controlling the Monetary Aggregates 7

John P. Judd

.. .deviations of money from its short-run path, caused by permanent disturbances to the money and reserve markets, could be offset in a shorter period of time with relatively small increases in interest rate volatility.

Editorial Committee:Charles Pigott, Brian Motley, Roger Craine

III. Dynamic Adjustment in the Demand for Money: Tests ofAlternative Hypotheses 19

John P. Judd and John L. Scadding

...The empirical results in this paper do not support the conventional specification of short-run dynamics, in which observed money accommodates itself gradually to changes in money demand. Uniformly superior results were obtained from equations in which money demand adjusts (through changes in the price level) in response to independent changes in the supply of money.

Editorial Committee:Roger Craine, Michael Keran, AldenToevs

3

Page 4: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

4

Page 5: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

A better understanding of the public's demand formoney is important because of the impact of moneyon output and prices and the central role assump­tions about money demand play in the making ofmonetary policy. The two articles in this Reviewshed light on the inter-relationship of money de­mand and strategies to control the money supply. Inthe first article, John Judd describes and assessesthe Federal Reserve's existing strategy for short-runcontrol of the monetary aggregates. In the secondarticle, John Judd and John Scadding establish thatindependent changes in the money supply, such asthose that result from monetary control policies,affect the behavior of money demand.

John Judd, in his article notes that, through themiddle of 1982, monetary control had improved onan annual basis but monetary aggregates had be­come more volatile on a shorter term since theFederal Reserve changed the way it controlledmoney (from establishing targets for short-term in­terest rates to focusing on targets for bank reserves.)The article was written prior to the major deregula­tion of deposit interest rates at the end of 1982. Itabstracts from issues concerning monetary vari­ables targeted and annual numerical ranges formonetary aggregates raised by this development todiscuss approaches to achieving whatever monetarytargets the Federal Reserve chooses.

The Federal Open Market Committee, which setstarget ranges for the growth rate of the monetaryaggregates, has followed a strategy whereby it at­tempts to return monetary aggregates to the targetrange gradually. According to Judd, a major ration­ale for this practice is that much of the volatility isbelieved to be self-correcting. Attempts to reducesuch variations can add unnecessarily to interestrate fluctuation in the short-run.

Judd warns, however, that there are money sup­ply deviations caused by persistent disturbances tothe economy that, if left unchecked, have adverseeffects on prices and GNP. Moreover, he argues that

5

"a larger number of unnecessary reactions (on thepart of the Federal Reserve) might be less costly tothe economy than a smaller number of large persis­tent monetary control errors."

Judd focuses on the size of changes in nonbor­rowed reserves initiated by the Fed as a measure ofthe aggressiveness of monetary control actions. Heuses the Money Market model developed at the SanFrancisco Federal Reserve Bank to estimate the sizeof changes in short-term interest rates needed forvarious rates of MI re-entry into the annual targetranges.

A key element of the model is a provision for theeffect of bank loans on the money supply. Mostconventional models do not incorporate this rela­tionship.

Using the San Francisco Money Market model,Judd finds that, once the effects of a change innonborrowed reserves on both open market interestrates and bank lending are accounted for, "givenchanges in MI can be accomplished with smallerchanges in interest rates." Thus, the costs, as mea­sured by increased interest rate volatility, of closercontrol of MI are lower than conventional modelswould suggest.

He concludes that "a more aggressive approach(to returning monetary aggregates to target) wouldreduce the incidence of persistent deviations thathave significant effects on GNP and prices. Such anapproach would also reduce the risk that the Fedwould have to resort to inducing persistent swingsin short-term interest rates to eliminate large moneydeviations. Finally, a more aggressive approachmight contribute to the stability of long-term inter­est rates, which are especially important for theperformance of the economy."

Judd and Scadding, in their article, test alterna­tive specifications of short-run money demand dy­namics to find the one which best predicts the levelof real money balances. The two authors note thatthe conventional specification' 'went seriously off

Page 6: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

track" whel1 it tried to predict the shift in moneydemand from 1974 to 1976, leading some observersto question whether this was due to the conventionalassumption "thatthemoney supply is endogenous,adjusting to exogenous changes in income andinterest rates operating through the demand formoney."

Judd and Scadding question whether the conven­tional assumption is appropriate for situations inwhich shocks occur in the supply of money ratherthan the demand for money.

They believe that the correct specification of theshort-run dynamic adjustment in the money demandfunction "depends critically on which variables aremade exogenous and which endogenous." They,therefore, study nine specifications of money de­mand with different adjusting and exogenous vari­ables. The nine can, however, be grouped into twomajor categories. The first includes the convention­al specification and its variants, in which the quan­tity of money adjusts with a lag to changes in thedemand for money. Specifications in the second

6

group share thefea.ture that money demand adjustswith a lag to changes in the supply of money. Thespecifications differ among themselves as to whichargument of the money demand function bears theburden of adjustment-interest rates, income,prices, or, in one case, a combination of these.

All the equations were put into the same canon­ical fonn and estimated \vith real money balances asthe dependent variable. The sample data used in theestimation spanned the'period from the first quarterof1959 to the second quarter of 1974. The equationsthatyielded reasonable estimation results were thenused to simulate money dynamics in the period fromthe third quarter of 1974 to the third quarter of 1980.

Judd and Scadding found that "money demandequations in which prices adjust to exogenouschanges in money, interest and income outperformequations in which money is the adjusting variable.Equations in which money is the adjusting variable,in tum, outperform equations where interest ratesand income are the adjusting variables,"

Page 7: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

John P. Judd*

I. Introduction

On October 6, 1979, the Federal Reserve changedthe way it controlled money from establishing tar­gets for short-term interest rates to focusing ontargets for bank reserves. The new procedure wasexpected to result in more interest rate volatility asthe rates were freed to respond to market forces.The procedure was also intended to achieve bettercontrol of the monetary aggregates. Since October1979, interest rate volatility has increased, andmonetary control has improved on an annual basis.But surprisingly, the monetary aggregates becamemore volatile on a short-term basis.

In February, 1981, the Federal Reserve publishedresults of a System study evaluating the experienceunder the new control procedure. [ The study con­cluded that the increased volatility of the monetaryaggregates in 1980 was caused, in part, by unusual­ly large shocks to the money and credit markets.The largest of these shocks came from the SpecialCredit Control Program implemented in the Springof 1980. A second conclusion was that more accu­rate short-run control might have been achieved bymore aggressive adjustments in the reserves targetswhen the quantity of money departed from target. 2

However, the study also concluded that closer

*Research Officer, Federal Reserve Bank of SanFrancisco. I am indebted to Adrian W. Throop forenlightening discussions of the issues discussedin this paper. Lloyd Dixon provided researchassistance.

7

short-run control would most likely entail largeincreases in interest rate volatility, which couldseriously inhibit the performance of the economy.

The present study therefore has two main pur­poses. The first is to describe how the reserve­oriented monetary control procedure works, intheory and in practice.** The second is to assess theeffectiveness of the new procedure as it has beenimplemented. A key feature of any control proce­dure is how quickly it brings the quantity of moneyback to a set target when deviations occur. Theevidence in this paper for 1981 through the first halfof 1982 suggests that the Federal Reserve has con­tinued to follow procedures producing relativelygradual re-entry to the annual target ranges thatform the basis of monetary policy. But unlike theearlier study noted above, this study suggests thatdeviations could be eliminated more rapidly withoutincurring large increases in interest rate volatility.

**This paper was written in the middle of 1982,prior to the reduction in emphasis by the FOMC onMI targeting and the major deposit regulation thatoccurred in the latter part of 1982. Thus, the mone­tary control procedures described and analyzed arethose that prevailed in mid-1982.

For a discussion of the issues raised by using Mlas an intermediate target under interest rate deregu­lation, see John P. Judd and John L. Scadding,"Financial Change and Monetary Targeting in theUnited States," available from the authors.

Page 8: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

II. Money and Reserve ControlProceduresThe Federal Reserve attempts to promote full years that inflation is reduced with the smallest

employment growth at low rates of inflation by possible adverse effects on output and employment.maintaining growth rates in certain monetary aggre- In recent years, innovations in cash managementgates that are compatible with its objectives. Each have made the job of setting appropriate annualyear the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMe) growth rates. for the aggregates more difficult.sets annual growth-rate target ranges for the mone- These innovations have frequently suggested to pol-tary (and credit) aggregates. These extend from the icymakers that the public's demand for money isfourth quarter of the previous year to the fourth shifting and that growth rate objectives for thequarter of the current year. In 1982, for example, aggregates must accommodate these shifts in orderthe range for Ml is 2V2 to 51/2 percent (see Figure to avoid undesired affects on the economy. For1).3 Although ranges are specified for Ml, M2, M3 example, if the demand for money shifts down andand bank credit, only those for Ml and M2 have had supply is not also lowered, interest rates will fallmuch operational significance since October 1979. and monetary policy will have been too expansion-These ranges represent the FOMe's goals for aver- ary. In 1981, the Fed essentially aimed to keep theage annual money growth. They reflect the long-run quantity of money as measured by Ml near thepolicy of gradually lowering the rate of inflation. lower boundary of the target range because theOver the past three years, the growth rate ranges for demand for MI appeared to be shifting downward.MI have been reduced by about V2 percent each By mid-1982, the Fed was content to see Ml at theyear. The goal of this gradualist policy is to reduce top of its annual range because of a perceived up-growth in money slowly enough over a number of ward shift in the demand for MI.

Figure 1

Monthly M1-1982

oo NSAJ J1982

A MMFJ

ActualShort-Run Path

445

440

435

430

4250 N 0

1981

450

465

460

455

$ Billions

470

8

Page 9: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

The purpose of this paper is not to evaluate theFederal Reserve's attempts to achieve its macroeconomic goals, but rather to assess the Fed's pro­cedure for controlling the monetary aggregates inthe short-run. Thus, the annual growth rate objec­tives for MI are taken as the starting point, withoutevaluating whether these were the appropriatetarget ranges for achieving the Fed's macroeco­nomic goals.Short-Run Monetary Paths

The Fed's monetary control procedure can bedivided into three levels. 4 The first level involvesthe choice of short-run paths for the monetary ag­gregates (Ml and M2) by the FOMC at each of itsmeetings. In the final month of each quarter, athree-month path is chosen to cover the next quar­ter: e. g., on March 31, 1981 a path was chosen forMarch to June (see line marked (2) in Figure 2).

These quarterly paths are sometimes revised in thefinal two months of the quarter. An example of sucha revision occurred on May 18, 1981, when an Mlpath for April to June was specified-see the linedenoted (3) in Figure 2. This latter path supplantedthe original second quarter path.

The short-run paths define the FOMC's preferredrate of re-entry to the longer-run target ranges. Forexample, again consider the second quarter of 1981.At its March 31 meeting, the Committee chose agrowth rate of 5-6 percent for MI, (plotted as 51/2

percent in Figure 2 and denoted as (2) ) beginningfrom a March base that was well below the lowerboundary of the annual target range. The Marchpath "pointed" MI back toward its range, andwould have achieved the lower boundary of therange within five months (by August) if it had beenmaintained that long.

$ Billions

Figure 2

Monthly M1-1981

445

DA SONJ FM AM J J

1981

Actual

Short-Run Path

o N D

1980

440

435

430

425

420

415 ............_ ......-

Page 10: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

The paths for 1981 and 1982 suggest that theCommittee's desired rate of re-entry to the annualrange was relatively slow. 5 Each month, the Com­mittee sought to eliminate only a small part of theprevious month's deviation of Ml from the annualtarget range. The shortest re-entry horizon in 1981was contained in the first quarter path (denoted as(1) in Figure I), which would have reached thelower boundary of the annual range in early April,about three months after the January deviation justprior to the FOMC meeting in early February.The path denoted 5 would have reached the lowerboundary of the annual range in four months, andthose denoted 2 and 4 would have reached the lowerboundary in 5 months. Finally, paths 6, 7 and 8,chosen for the fourth quarter of 1981 would not haveattained the annual lower boundary by the end ofthat year. Attempted re-entry in the first half of 1982was somewhat faster. The path denoted 2 in Figure 1would have achieved the upper boundary of thetarget range in four months, while the paths denotedas 3 and 4, reach the upper boundary in three andtwo months, respectively.

The choice of a relatively slow re-entry rate ap­parently reflects the view that faster re-entry wouldinvolve excessive amounts of interest rate volatility.This point was made in the February 1981 FederalReseve Staff study of the new reserve control pro­cedures. This study concluded that a faster re-entryrate than had been used in 1980 would have pro­vided only marginally closer month-to-month con­trol of Ml at the expense of substantially greatervolatility in the Federal funds rate. 6

Paths for the Reserve AggregatesThe second level of the monetary control pro­

cedures translates the short-run paths for Ml andM2 into a path for total reserves over periods be­tween FOMC meetings. These total reserve pathsare calculated by multiplying the appropriate re­serve requirement ratios by projections of the vari­ous reservable liabilities of depository institutionsthought to be consistent with the paths for Ml andM2. 7 Since the Fed imposes different reserve re­quirement ratios on the various components of Mland M2, and on instruments not in these aggregates,the calculation of the current total reserve pathsdepends on accurate estimates of movements in thecomponents of Ml and M2 and of other reservable

10

instruments. The Fed must also project reservesheld in excess of reserve requirements. These com­positional changes require adjustments of the totalreserves paths to make them consistent with un­

changed paths for MI and M2. These so-calledtechnical, or "multiplier," adjustments are madewhen necessary on a week-by-week basis. The dis­cussion in the remainder of the paper abstracts fromthese technical adjustments, and focuses insteadon reserve changes designed to be consistent withchanges in the Ml and M2 paths.

The third level' of the control procedure involvesthe use of a reserves instrument to achieve theshort-run paths for Ml and M2. Under certain insti­tutional arrangements, the Federal Reserve has theoption of directly manipulating total reserves tocontrol money. However, this approach has notbeen feasible because of the existing practice oflagged reserve accounting (LRR). 8 This reserve ac­counting rule requires banks to hold an amount ofreserves in any given week based on deposits heldtwo weeks earlier. Banks' required reserves aretherefore predetermined in any given week. TheFed, for its part, must supply the banking systemwith enough reserves to meet the requirement. If theFed did not do so, it would force some individualbanks into a reserve deficiency beyond their con­trol. Thus under LRR, the Fed is not in a position touse total reserves as the money control instrumenton a weekly basis.

The Fed's way of dealing with this problem is touse as its control instrument the proportion of totalreserves provided to banks through the Federal Re­serve discount window. If the Fed wants to pursue atighter money policy, for example, it supplies fewerreserves outright to the market through open marketoperations (i. e., fewer non-borrowed reserves).This means that banks will have to acquire a largerproportion of their predetermined required reservesby borrowing at the discount window. Banks, how­ever, are reluctant to go to the discount windowbecause the Fed imposes restrictions on the quantityand frequency of loans it will make to individualbanks over specified periods of time. 9 Thus, whenthe Fed provides fewer non-borrowed reserves, theFederal funds rate must rise relative to the discountrate to induce banks to use up more of their availablecredit at the discount window. Such increases in thefunds rate slow growth in money and total reserves.

Page 11: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

Figure 3

lag, to slower growth in the demand by banks fortotal reserves. Thus, over periods longer than twoweeks, the demand for reserves responds to thefunds rate and so reserves and the funds rate fallfrom point B to point C.

If the Fed could predict the supply of and demandfor money and reserves with certainty, it couldalways achieve its desired paths (over periods long­er than two weeks) by setting nonborrowed reservesat a level such that RS intersects the long-run re­serves demand curve at the desired leveI of totalreserves. Unfortunately, neither Rdnor RS is knownwith certainty. For example, unexpected shifts inbanks' reluctance to borrow affect RS

. Unexpectedchanges in the public's demand for Ml and bankcredit affect Rd.

Nevertheless, monetary control procedures af­fect the extent to which the money supply is affectedby these and other shocks. For example, laggedreserve accounting allows money to be pushedaway from the target path to a greater extent thandoes contemporaneous accounting. Under LRR,sudden changes in the public's demand for moneyaffect banks' demand for reserves, and thus thefunds rate, with a lag of two weeks. Money istherefore, more susceptible to shocks because theinterest rate changes needed to moderate deviations

This method of monetary and reserve control isillustrated in Figure 3. Consider first the supply oftotal reserves, RS

, which consists of two parts. First,so-called nonborrowed reserves (RU) are providedoutright to the banking system when the Fed buysopen market securities (e. g., Treasury bills) fromthe public and pays for the securities with bankreserves. Because the Fed directly controls theamount of nonborrowed reserves, this portion oftotal reserves does not respond to the Federal fundsrate, and is depicted by the vertical portion ofRs.

Second, borrowed reserves (RB) are providedwhen the Fed lends reserves to banks through itsdiscount window. As noted earlier, the quantity ofborrowed reserves will rise only if the funds rateincreases sufficiently above the discount rate toovercome banks' reluctance to borrow. Thus banks'demand curve of borrowed reserves is upward slop­ing when the funds rate is above the discount rate.The upward sloping portion of RS represents thesum of borrowed reserves, which respond posi­tively to the funds rate, plus a fixed amount ofnonboITowed reserves. (Note that the kink in RS

occurs where the funds rate equals the discount rateand borrowed reserves are zero. Up to this point,total reserves are composed entirely of nonborrow­ed reserves, and thus RS is vertical.)

As noted above, banks' demand for total reservesis predetermined in any given week under LRR.Thus, the short-run demand for reserves, RD

sR , isvertical. However, over periods longer than twoweeks, total reserves respond to changes in thequantity of deposits banks issue. Since a higherfunds rate restrains deposit growth, the long-runreserves demand, R~.R' is negatively sloped withrespect to the funds rate.

Assume that point A in Figure 3 represents aninitial starting point, where total reserves (R*) andthe funds rate (iF*) correspond to the level ofMI onits path. Now, suppose the Fed reduces its desiredlevel for MI. This requires a tighter policy in thereserves market, which means a reduction in non­borrowed reserves from RU[* to RU 2*. In the short­run, this action raises borrowings (from RB [ toRB 2) by an equal amount and raises iF to point B,because the demand for reserves is fixed. However,the higher funds rate restrains money growth con­temporaneously, and this leads, with a two-week

II

FundsRate(iF)

FundsRate =

DiscountRate

RU~ RU~ R*Total Reserves

Page 12: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

of money from target are delayed. Under contempo­raneous reserve accounting (CRR) (where currentreserve requirements are determined by currentdeposits), these moderating interest rate changesoccur immediately, contributing to tighter monetarycontrol. The Federal Reserve has recently an­nounced its intention to switch to CRR in 1984.

The operating instrument used for monetary con­trol also has an important effect on the susceptibilityof money to shocks. In October 1979, the Fedswitched from using the Federal funds rate to usingnonborrowed reserves as its instrument of control.The funds rate approach had the disadvantage thatunanticipated changes in the demand for money andreserves were often accommodated by automaticincreases in the supply of reserves as the Fed held its

funds rate instrument constant. This accommoda­tion does not occur to the same extent under presentprocedures, since the Fed often holds nonborrowedreserves constant when unanticipated changes inmoney and reserves demand occur. With RU fixed,an increase in money and total reserves demandautomatically causes borrowed reserves to rise.Greater borrowing at the window causes the fundsrate to rise, which tends to retard the increase inmoney,· leading to"a smaller monetary control error.Some analysts argue that a total reserves instrumentwould be even more effective in this regard, but thisremains a matter in dispute. 10 The Federal Reserve'sswitch to CRR will at least give the System theoption of using a total reserves instrument, an op­tion not feasible under LRR.

III. Choosing the Nonborrowed Reserve PathAnother important feature of the monetary con­

trol procedure, and the focus of this paper, is howquickly the Fed attempts to reenter the longer runtarget ranges once deviations occur: i.e. how ag­gressively does the Fed act to offset monetary con­trol errors? The aggressiveness of monetary controlactions can be measured by the size of changes innonborrowed reserves initiated by the Fed in re­sponse to deviations of money and total reservesfrom path. For example, when money overshootsits path, nonborrowed reserves must be lowered inorder to raise the funds rate and eventually makemoney fall back to its path. All else equal, the largerthe reduction in nonborrowed reserves, the morerapidly money will go back to path.

The Fed's method of choosing nonborrowed re­serves paths involves two basic elements. The firstelement is the FaMe's choice of a so-called initialborrowing assumption. In addition to choosingpaths for Ml and M2, which are translated by thestaff into a total reserves path, the FOMC alsochooses an initial borrowing "assumption" for theinterrneeting period. The total reserves path minusthe borrowing assumption is the initial nonbor­rowed reserves path level to be aimed for by theFederal Reserve Bank of New York Trading Desk.Thus when the FOMC chooses paths for Ml and M2and an initial borrowing assumption it simulta­neously chooses a nonborrowed reserves path.

12

At each meeting the FOMC is presented by thestaff with a menu of (usually) three short-run policyalternati ves, typically representing possible"tight," "easy" and "status quo" policies. Eachalternative contains a combination of paths for Mland M2, a borrowing assumption, and a Federalfunds rate range." The staff designs each path to beinternally consistent, that is, the staff projects that agiven level of borrowing would be necessary toachieve the corresponding short-run Ml and M2paths by the end of the period they cover. Thus byconstruction, the nonborrowed reserves path(which is calculated on the basis of the initial bor­rowing assumption) is an initial guess at the level ofnonborrowed reserves consistent with achieving theshort-run monetary aggregates paths. Since the Mland M2 paths typically reflect an attempt to re-enterthe annual target range gradually, so do the nonbor­rowed reserve paths.

The second element in the Fed's choice of anonborrowed reserve path involves intermeetingadjustments of the initial nonborrowed path. SinceOctober 1979, the nonborrowed path has sometimesbeen changed between FOMC meetings in responseto projected deviations of total reserves from path.When total reserves have been projected to be de­viating from path during control periods by a signif­icant amount, nonborrowed reserves have some­times been changed in the opposite direction to

Page 13: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

speed the movement of MI back to path. Assume,for example, that total reserves are above path.Holding the path for nonborrowed reserves at itsoriginal level would limit the total reserves over­shoot to consist of borrowed reserves. Higher bor­rowing would raise the funds rate and help bring MIand total reserves back to path. The intermeetingadjustments involve raising borrowing and thefunds rate even further, by reducing the nonbor­rowed reserves path from its original level, therebyinducing MI and total reserves to move back to pathmore rapidly.

These intermeeting adjustments were used morefrequently in 1980 than in 1981 and their size hasvaried widely among control periods. In 1980, therewere six such adjustments ranging in size fromaround 25 percent of the total reserve deviation toaround 125 percent. 12 In 1981, there were two suchadjustments, one that was larger than the total re­serve deviation, and a second one that was smaller.Fewer intermeeting adjustments were made in1981, in part because MI and M2 often gave con­flicting signals-M2 was often above its path whenMl was below its path.

There have also been several control periods in1980-81 when flonborrowed reserves were changedduring intermeeting periods in the same direction astotal reserve deviations. These actions tended to

reinforce total reserve deviations rather than offsetthem. An example is in April of 1980 (during theperiod of the Special Credit Controls), when non­borrowed reserves came in below their initial pathsin an intermeeting period in which total reserveswere well below path. This development reinforcedthe weakness in MI and total reserves in that period,but cushioned the declines ·in interest rates that wereoccurring simultaneously. Two such reinforcingchanges occurred in nonborrowed reserves in inter­meeting periods in 1980, and three occurred in1981 13

As shown earlier, the FOMe's choice of initialnonborrowed reserves paths represents relativelygradual rates of re-entry to the longer-run targetranges. However, to evaluate the reserve controlprocedure as a whole, we must also take account ofthe adjustments to these initial paths made in theintermeeting periods. These latter actions serve asmid-course corrections in response to the latestdata. They do not, however, convert gradual re­entry into rapid re-entry. These mid-course correc­tions were designed to keep on the pre-determinedgradual short-run paths. Moreover, the sporadic useof intermeeting adjustments suggests that they havenot been a major factor holding Ml to its short-runpaths, especially in 1981.

IV. Rates of Re-EntryThe previous section showed that under current

operating procedures the Fed sets its nonborrowedreserves path to be consistent with gradual rates ofre-entry of Ml and M2 to the annual target ranges.The major argument advanced for gradual re-entryis that it helps stabilize interest rates. Implicit in thisargument is the point that attempts to get back to theannual target ranges more quickly would requirelarger changes in interest rates. These sharp interestrate changes, in turn, can disrupt financial flowsand weaken the performance of the economy. 14

How aggressively should policy attempt to returnMl and M2 to the annual ranges? This is an empiri­cal question the answer to which depends on severalfactors. The first issue concerns the size of theresponse in short-term interest rates elicited by thechanges in nonborrowed reserves necessary toachieve given rates of re-entry. The remainder of

13

this section examines this factor. Two other factorswill be discussed later: The relative benefits pro­vided to the economy by more stable money marketinterest rates in the short-run versus less persistentdeviations of Ml from target, and the nature ofdeviations, that is, whether or not they are selfcorrecting.

Conceptual Framework

An analysis of how much increase in interest ratevolatility will accompany faster re-entry, in part,depends on empirical estimates of the demand andsupply relationships in the markets for money andreserves. We have used the San Francisco moneymarket model to estimate the size of changes inshort-term interest rates required for various rates ofMI re-entry to the annual target ranges. The modelis a monthly structural model which describes the

Page 14: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

behavior of banks, the nonbank public, and theFederal Reserve in the markets for bank reserves,deposits and bank loans. 15

The SF model contains a conventional borrowingfunction in which banks' demand for borrowed re­serves depends positively on the funds rates, andnegatively on the discount rate, whenever the fundsrate is above the discount rate. Thus the model'ssupply of total reserves schedule looks like the oneshown in Figure 3.

In the model, banks' demand for total reservesvaries negatively with respect to the Federal fundsrate. Since banks' demand for reserves results pri­marily from reserve requirements, the reserve de­mand function reflects the response of deposits to

the Federal funds rate. The inverse relationshipbetween the funds rate and deposits depends mainlyon two relationships. First, arbitrage in financialmarkets means that rates on longer-term moneymarket instruments, like commercial paper, tend tomove up and down with the federal funds rate. Thecommercial paper rate represents the interest fore­gone from holding transactions deposits. For thisreason, increases in the paper rate induce the publicto hold fewer transactions deposits, and banks con­sequently need supply fewer of these deposits. Thisis one way in which a higher funds rate reduces Mland reserves demand. It is the channel of influencecommon to most money market models.

Second, bank loans act as a catalyst in anotherchannel of influence unique to the SF model. Bankscompete to make loans to the public by setting theirloan rates relative to rates available in direct financemarkets like those for commercial paper and cor­porate bonds. For any given level of GNP, thepublic's demand for bank loans depends negativelyon the prime rate and positively on the commercialpaper rate. Thus, as the prime rate falls relative tothe commercial paper rate, banks issue more loansin response to rising demand by the public. Sincethe proceeds of these loans are generally paid in thefonn of transactions deposits, increases in MI andreserves demand are the immediate effect of loanextensions. These newly created deposits tend tostay in the public's portfolio of assets, and thusaffect observed MI, for up to six months, accordingto the empirical estimates. 16

Changes in the funds rate affect bank loans and

14

Ml through the prime rate. For example, an in­crease in the funds rate induces a higher prime ratebecause banks set their prime rates at a variablemarkup over their cost of obtaining funds to lend.Since the funds rate forms the base of those borrow­ing costs, the prime rate tends to move up or downwith <;urrent and lagged funds rates. Thus, if theFederal Reserve takes actions that raise the fundsrate, this raises the prime rate. A higher prime ratecauses the supply of money to fall by lowering bankloans. 17

The presence of bank loan effects means thatchanges in nonborrowed reserves have a larger ef­fect on Ml and a smaller effect on money marketinterest rates. An increase in RU, for example,reduces the Federal funds rate and raises MI in twoways. First, the lower funds rate lowers the com­mercial paper rate, thereby raising the public's un­derlying demand for money. Second, higher non­borrowed reserves raise Ml via increases in bankloans, as lower funds rates cause the prime lendingrate to fall. This added response of Ml to moneymarket interest rates means that given changes inMI can be accomplished with smaller changes ininterest rates. Bank loan effects therefore have animportant implication for monetary control-thecosts of short-run control (interest rate volatility)are less than conventional models (without bankloan effects) would suggest.

Empirical Results

The money market model was used to estimatethe changes in the commercial paper rate needed toeliminate given deviations of Ml from target overdifferent periods of time. 18 The analysis applies toMI deviations that are persistent, in the sense thatthey would not be eliminated without Federal Re­serve action. The estimates are based on simula­tions of the estimated model. The model simula­tions included the assumption that the Fed changesnonborrowed reserves by enough to eliminate spec­ified percentages of initial Ml deviations eachmonth. For example, a four-month control horizoninvolves eliminating 25 percent of an initial MIdeviation each month for four straight months.Constant nominal income and a constant discountrate were two other assumptions. It should be notedthat these simulations were not attempts to replicate

Page 15: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

a sequence of nonborrowed reserves changes thatactually occurred under current procedures. Ratherthey were designed for comparison purposes to in­dicate the interest rate consequences of alternativerates of re-entry to the annual target ranges.

Table 1 shows the model's estimates of the inter­est rate consequences of alternative rates of re­entry. The numbers shown are the cumulativechanges in the commercial paper rate (in basispoints) corresponding to the various control hori­zons also shown. For example, the three-monthhorizon implies that the RU path is designed toeliminate one-third of a $2 billion Ml deviationeach month for three months. RU is then set to holdMl on path for the next three months. The rowlabeled three months in Table I shows that undersuch a horizon, a $2 billion Ml overshoot wouldimply that, in the following six months, the com­mercial paper rate would be 68, 107, 121, 69, 50 and45 basis points higher than it would have been ifthere had been no change in nonborrowed reserves.

In general, Table I suggests that shorter controlhorizons (i.e., faster re-entry rates), require largercumulative changes in the commercial paper rate,and that these larger changes must occur sooner. Forexample, two-month control requires a 152 basispoint change in the paper rate by the second monthafter the Ml deviation, while three-month controlrequires a 121 basis point increase in the paper rateby the third month. The most extreme variability

would occur with one-month control, which re­quires a 205 basis point change in the paper rate inthe first month following the M1deviation.

The large difference between the one-month andthe two-month control rules has to do with thebehavior of bank loans. Empirical evidence indi­cates that the public's loan demand responds to achange in the prime rate with a lag of one month.This presumably occurs because corporate andother types of borrowing are controlled by spendingplans which are not revised very much at the sametime that borrowing costs change. In any event, thelag in the response of bank loans to Fed policyactions means that a larger interest rate change isrequired for a given degree of monetary control.

These results suggest that the change in nonbor­rowed reserves in response to a deviation of MIfrom its annual target range could be larger than it iscurrently without large increases in interest ratevolatility. This finding implies that the Fed couldattempt to re-enter the range fOf MI within 2 to 3months, rather than the 4 to 5 month horizon oftenused, without significantly increasing the volatilityof the commercial paper rate.

The preceding analysis assumed that income andprices were unaffected by Ml deviations, but re­moving this assumption only strengthens the casefor closer monetary control. This subject is dis­cussed in the next section.

IS

Page 16: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

v. Policy Implications and ConclusionsThe Federal Reserve's current approach to re­

serve targeting involves a relatively gradual re­entry to the annual target ranges once a deviationhas occurred. According to the empirical evidencepresented in this paper the re-entry rate may beshortened at least a few months without causingsignificantly larger movements in interest rates.

However, this result by itse?fdoes not necessarilyjustify a shortening in the control horizon. Theadvisability of such a decision depends upon thesources of disturbances to the money and reservemarkets that cause the money control errors, and anassessment of the relative costs of interest rate vola­tility relative to the costs of money control errors.

An argument cautioning against a strong reactionto deviations of total reserves from path is that manydeviations are self-correcting. To illustrate, the er­ror term from an estimated money demand equationis relatively large and may account for a large num­ber of temporary MI and, therefore, total reservesdeviations. These deviations correct themselves in ashort time without Fed actions that would causeinterest rates to change. However, since it is oftenvery difficult to distinguish temporary from perma­nent disturbances, strong Fed reactions could some­times unnecessarily induce interest rate volatility.

Nevertheless, by seeking to avoid the error ofreacting when it is unnecessary, the Fed runs therisk of not reacting appropriately when disturbancesare persistent. It is the latter error that permits MIdeviations to persist long enough to have an unde­sired effect on GNP and prices. Thus, even if tem­porary disturbances occurred more frequently thanpersistent disturbances, it might be worthwhile tochoose a faster re-entry rate. In other words, a largernumber of unnecessary reactions might be less cost­1y to the economy than a smaller number of largepersistent monetary control errors.

Permanent disturbances to the market for moneyoften require very large persistent changes in inter­est rates to bring Ml back to target. For example,assume that a sudden surge in bank loans causes MIto accelerate above its targeted path. If this devia­tion were not corrected quickly enough, GNPwould also begin to accelerate. Ultimately, interestrates would have to increase to offset both the surge

16

in loans and GNP. If the Fed had taken correctiveaction early, it would only have had to offset thesurge in loans. This narrower task requires a smallerand less persistent increase in short-term interestrates.

A problem with persistent swings in short-terminterest rates is that they are likely to show up inlong-term rates. Investors can choose between buy­ing a long-term security with a maturity equal totheir desired investment period, or a series of short­term securities with maturities that add up to theinvestment period. If the Fed were to offset an MIcontrol error gradually in an investment period,short-term interest rates would rise gradually in thatsame period. Investors anticipating the rise, wouldthen prefer to buy short-term securities in series,re-investing each time at the expected higher short­term rates. They would adopt this strategy unlessthe yield on the long-term security also rose. On theother hand, they would not need this inducement tobuy the long-term security if they expected the MIcontrol error to be offset quickly by a short, sharpincrease in short-term interest rates. In this way,gradual re-entry to the MI paths means more persis­tent movements in short-term interest rates, whichin tum means that longer-term interest rates areaffected to a greater degree by monetary controlactions. These long-term interest rates are of poten­tially great importance because they affect businessinvestment and housing.

Finally, deviations of Ml from target can alsoinduce volatility in long-term rates if the deviationsare perceived by the public to be persistent enoughto affect inflation. A great deal of empirical evi­dence links higher inflation with faster growth ratesfor money. Thus, when the public sees a persistentincrease in money growth, it may anticipate moreinflation. Long-term interest rates then rise becausethey include a premium for inflation. This relation­ship between money growth and long-term rates isespecially likely to exist when the Treasury runslarge budget deficits and when Federal Reservecredibility is low. Faster rates of re-entry to the MItarget can be a more emphatic way of showing thatMl deviations will not persist long enough to affectinflation.

Page 17: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

In summary, a more aggressive approach to

short-run monetary control most likely would re­

duce the incidence of persistent MI deviations that

have significant effects on GNP and prices. Such an

approach would also reduce the risk that the Fed

would be forced to induce persistent swings in

short-tenn interest rates to eliminate large money

deviations. Finally, a more aggressive approach

might contribute to the stability of long-tenn inter­

est rates, which are especially important for the

performance of the economy.

FOOTNOTES

1. New Monetary Control Procedures, Federal ReserveStaff Study-Volumes I and II, Board of Governors of theFederal Reserve System, February 1981.

2. Stephen Axilrod, "Overview of Findings and Evalua­tion," New Monetary Control Procedures, Volume I, pp.A6 and A23.

3. M1 is the sum of currency, traveler's checks, demanddeposits, and other checkable deposits. M2 is M1 plusovernight RPs and eurodollars, non-institutional moneymarket funds, and saVings and small time deposits. In1982, M2 was redefined to include retail RPs and to excludeinstitutional money market funds. M3 is M2 plus large timedeposits, term RPs, and institutional money market funds.

4. See E. J. Stevens, "The New Procedure," EconomicReview, Federal Reserve Bank of Cleveland, Summer1981, pp. 1-17, for a detailed discussion of the reservecontrol procedures.

5. In February 1980-November 1980 M1 paths werechosen such that on average, the FOMC sought to elimi­nate 29.2 percent of the previous month's error in eachcurrent month. Peter A. Tinsley, Peter von zur Muehlen,Warren Trepeta, and Gerhard Fries, "Money Market Im­pacts of Alternative Operating Procedures," New Mone­tary Control Procedures, Volume II, and Axilrod, Febru­ary 1981, pp. B1-B4.

6. See Axilrod (1981), p. A17, and Tinsley, von zur Mueh­len, Trepeta and Fries (1981).

7. Fred Levin and Paul Meek, "Implementing the NewProcedures: The View from the Trading Desk," New Mone­tary Control Procedures, Volume II, pp. Ai-AS.

8. See Warren L. Coats. "Lagged Reserve Accounting andthe Money Supply Process," "Journal of Money, Creditand Banking, May 1976, VIII (1) pp. 167-180: Daniel E.Laufenberg, "Contemporaneous Versus Lagged ReserveAccounting," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking,May 1976, VII(1), pp. 239-246.

9. See Murray E. Polakoff and William L. Silber, "Reluc­tance of Member Bank Borrowing: Additional Evidence:'Journal of Finance, March 1967, pp. 88-92.

10. David Lindsey, et. al., "Monetary Control ExperienceUnder the New Operating Procedure," New MonetaryControl Procedures, Federal Reserve Staff Study-Vol­ume2.

11. The funds rate range has had little operational signifi­cance, except occasionally to trigger Committee consulta­tion when the funds rate violates the range.

17

12. The following equations show how to calculate thedifference between the actual value taken on by nonbor­rowed reserves in a given control period and the initialnonborrowed reserves path implicitly chosen by the FOMC.(1) R = RU + RB(2) R*= RU* + RB*(3) RU* - RD* = + RB* RB* + R* Fl*

whereR = total reservesRU = nonborrowed reservesRB = borrowed reserves* indicates current path"Bar" * indicates initial path chosen by FOMe.

By subtracting (2) from (i), we obtain(4) R R* = RU - RU* + RB - RB*.

Next we solve (3) for RS', and substitute it into (4), to obtainRU - RU*= (R R*) (RB - RS*).

Thus, the difference between RU and the FOMC's initialpath for RU equals the total reserve deviation minus thedeviation between borrowed reserves and the FOMC's ini­tial borrowing assumption.An indication of these values can be obtained from data anddescription in "Monetary Policy and Open Market Opera­tions in 1980:' and "Monetary Policy and Open MarketOperations in 1981," Quarterly Review, Federal ReserveBank of New York, Summer 1981 and Summer 1982,respectively.

13. This occurred in the control periods ending 2/6/80,4/23/80,2/4/81,4/1/81, and 12/23/81.

14. Axilrod (1981), p. A17.

15. See John P. Judd and John L. Scadding, "LiabilityManagement, Bank Loans, and Deposit 'Market' Disequi­librium," Economic Review, Federal Reserve Bank ofSanFrancisco, Summer, 1981 and "What Do Money MarketModels Tell Us About How to Implement Monetary policy?­Reply," Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, No­vember 1982, Part 2, pp.868-876. Also see Flichard G.Anderson and Robert H. Rasche, "What Do Money MarketModels Tell Us About How to Conduct Monetary>Policy,"Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, November 1982,Part 2, pp. 796-828.16. Changes in bank loans have a significant and persi~­

tent impact on the monetary aggregatesbecause money IS

a buffer stock in the public's portfolio. Money acts much likean inventory of goods in a warehous~. Such an inventory,by its very nature, Wilt represent there§idual of a whOle setof other decisions which, in the sho~frun cO(Jld keep the"inventory" from its desired level. The viewof money de­mand as largely passive in the short-run, accommodating

Page 18: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

itself to changes in the supply of money, reflects the trans­actions costs of closely managing money balances. Unan­ticipated inflows or outflows of funds cause inventories ofmoney balances in the short run to wander away from theirdesired levels because it is too costly for some moneyholders to monitor closely their accounts, and to make thenecessary purchases and sales of securities frequentlyenough to bring money balances quickly back to theirdesired levels.

This view does not dispute the importance of the emer­gence in the 1970's of sophisticated cash managementtechniques and new instruments like repurchase agree­ments.. These developments mean that trans<;ictions costsare now so low for sOme money holders, especially largeCOrporations, thatthey hold only money bal<;inces th<;itareconsistent with their underlying demands. However, small­er and less sophisticated corporations and householdscould easily hold more or less transactions balances thanthey desire for an extended period of time. Most house­holds and small corporations have relatively low moneybalances on average, and actions to adjustthose balancesto desired levels may be costly relative to the benefits ofholding exactly the desired amount of money. If money,therefore, finds its way into these "loosely" managed port-

18

folios, it may stay there for awhile. Moreover, actions of onemon~y-holder to bring tlalancesinto line may throw otherholders out of balance. For this reason, the system as awhole takes longer to adjust than does anyone householdor corporation.

Whether these effects are significant enough to make adifference is a factual question. Recent empirical estimatesat this bank suggest that buffer stock effects are significant-that the monetary aggregates can depart significantlyfrom levels desired by the public for up to six months at atime; that is, an increase in bank loans causes the level ofmoney to depart from the public's underlying demand forabout six months.

17. The commercial paper. rate affects bank loans with apositive sign. This rate also rises with the funds rate. Thismeans that theory cannot tell whether bank loans varypositively or negatively with thEl funds rate.. However, .theempirical results in the San Francisco model show an in­verse relationship.

18. See Judd and Scadding, 1982 for empirical estimatesof the key equations used in the simulations. Other equa­tions in the model can be obtained from the authors.

Page 19: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

John P. Judd and John L. Scadding*

Alternative theories of the public's demand tohold money are among the most widely tested the­ories in macroeconomics because the demand formoney occupies a central role in monetary policy.The Federal Reserve conducts monetary policy byattempting to achieve target growth rates for severalmeasures of money, with a large amount of atten­tion traditionally focused on Ml, which representsthe public's holdings of currency plus checkabledeposits. If the Fed wants to lower inflation, forexample, it reduces the growth rate of Ml. But itcan do so only by inducing the public to want to holdfewer M I balances. The conventional explanationof how this happens, in the short-run, is that the Fedraises interest rates on financial instruments that aresubstitutes for M 1. Since altemative investmentsnow have a higher yield, the public chooses to holdmore of them and less money. This process affectsprices and output of goods and services because thepublic's demand for these goods and services variesnegatively with interest rates. That is, increases inthese rates represent higher borrowing costs tofinance spending. By raising these borrowing costs,efforts to slow Ml growth tend to lower output andthe growth of prices.

Both theory and evidence point to interest rates(which measure the opportunity cost of holdingmoney), and either income or wealth as the majordeterminants of the demand for money. The quan­tity of real money balances determined by thesevariables defines the long-run equilibrium, or "de­sired," quantity of money demanded. It is generally

*Research Officers, Federal Reserve Bank ofSan Francisco. David Murray provided researchassistance.

19

recognized, however, that in the short run the quan­tity of money actually held by the public can differfrom this long-run, or desired level. The reason forthis is that it is too costly to rearrange portfoliosconstantly to keep desired and actual real moneybalances the same at every point in time. Any dis­cussion of money demand in the short run must,therefore, specify the relationship between actualmoney balances and the desired level. This is typi­cally done by specifying a dynamic adjustment pro­cess by which actual money balances and the de­sired level are made equal.

The conventional assumption is that this processof dynamic adjustment consists of the public adjust­ing the quantity of money it holds gradually overtime, until it is equal to the long-run demand for it.This version of dynamic adjustment has becomealmost universally accepted, despite the lack ofmuch research comparing it to alternative formula­tions. As we shall see, the conventional formulationis a reasonable description of dynamic adjustmentwhen the supply of money passively accommodatesitself to changes in the demand for money. It seemsless well suited to situations in which the supply ofmoney can change independently of money demand-in other words, to a world in which there can beexogenous changes in the supply of money.

This line of criticism is not new, but it has beenlargely ignored until recently. It began to receiverenewed attention when evidence emerged after1973 that the conventional equation was goingbadly off track in predicting money. I The largecumulative overpredictions of Ml from 1974through mid-1976 were explained as a so-called"shift" in the demand for money associated withrapid innovation in the financial markets that al-

Page 20: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

lowed the public to economize on its holdings ofmoney balances.

This episode of financial innovation also coin­cided with the period in which the Federal Reservepaid increasing attention to targeting the monetaryaggregates; i.e., to a strategy that was consistentwith providing a greater element of exogeneity inthe money supply. As a result, several alternativedynamic formulations of short-run money demandwere proposed and tested-formulations which itwas argued were more consistent with a world inwhich changes in the supply of money were animportant independent source of changes in theobserved quantity of money held by the public.

Unfortunately, it is practically impossible tocompare the performance of the different formula­tions in the existing literature because they were notdesigned to explain the same variable2

. Some usedmoney as the dependent variable in their regres­sions, some used prices and others used interestrates. Another reason making comparisons difficultis that the different regressions were not estimatedover the same sample period. The purpose of thispaper is to find the best specification of short-runmoney demand dynamics. Our method is to surveythe different past formulations and to provide esti­mates of them that are comparable. To this end weshow how the ostensibly different formulations areactually specific cases of a general formulation forpredicting the level of real money balances. We usethis result to investigate how successful each is in"explaining" the same variable-the level of realmoney balances-over the same sample period,1959/QI to 1974/Q2. We also investigate how suc­cessful the variants are in predicting the post­1974/Q2 period, the period in which the conven­tional specification went seriously off track.

Finding the correct specification of short-run dy­namics is an important task for two reasons. First,

20

an incorrect specification of short-run dynamics"""" "n",] aflect estmlat(~S of the elasticities of

the determinants of long-run money demand, esti­mates that are important for predicting the impact ofmoney on output and prices. This consideration isParticularly important in view of the prolongedshifts in conventional money demand equationssince 1973, and the problems these shifts cause formonetary policy.

Second, the form taken by short-run dynamicshas an important implication for the cost of closeshort-run monetary control. As shown below, theconventional specification implies that a smallexogenous change in money by the Federal Reserverequires a large change in interest rates. Since theFed historically has considered interest rate volatil­ity an important cost of short-run monetary control,reliance on the conventional specification tends todiscourage precise short-run control. The alterna­tive specifications of money demand dynamics,which are designed to be more consistent with anexogenous money supply, imply that the increase ininterest rate volatility resulting from efforts to con­trol money more closely in the short run would besmaller than typically thought.

The empirical results in this paper do not supportthe conventional specification of short-run dynam­ics, in which observed money accommodates itselfgradually to changes in money demand. Uniformlysuperior results were obtained from equations inwhich money demand adjusts (through changes inthe price level) in response to independent changesin the supply of money. Moreover, the latter equa­tions showed significantly less instability during1974-76 than the conventional dynamic specifica­tion. Specifically, the dynamic forecast error of thebest alternative equation was over 65 percent lowerthan that of the conventional equation by the end ofthis period.

Page 21: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

I. The Conventional Specification

Llm, = A(m~_1 - m H ) + ALlm~ (Lli,Lly) (2)

where Llm~ denotes the change in money demand,here shown as a function of changes in interest rates(i) and real income (y). Hence the Chow specifica­tion implicitly views the quantity of real moneybalances as adjusting to two factors. The first is afraction (A) of the difference between desired andactual money balances from last period (the first

where Ll denotes a change in a variable, m is real(price-deflated) money balances, md is desired orequilibrium money balances, shown as a function ofits arguments-interest rates (i) and real income(y)-and A is a parameter that measures the speedwith which real balances adjust to the desired level.

The conventional specification can be re-ar­ranged slightly to yield an alternative interpretation,shown in equation (2),

Most quarterly money demand specificationsallow for temporary differences between the ob­served stock of real (price deflated) money balancesin the short run, and the public's desired level ofsuch balances in the long run. Typically, a partialadjustment model is used, in which the market formoney is assumed to adjust over time to restorelong-run equilibrium after it is disturbed by shocks.This general specification raises the need to identifythe specific exogenous and endogenous variables inthe market for money. The variables causing shocksdefine the exogenous variables, while the variableswhich adjust to these shocks constitute the endoge­nous variables.

The traditional specification, as derived byGregory Chow, implicitly assumes that the moneysupply is endogenous, adjusting to exogenouschanges in income and interest rates operatingthrough the demand for money. 3 This specificationassumes that the quantity of money changes in thecurrent quarter by some fraction of the differencebetween this quarter's long-run demand and lastquarter's actual level. Money will continue to adjustover time until the actual level equals the long-rundemand. This specification is shown in equation(I ),

.lm, = A[m~ (i,y) - mH ], (1)

21

term of equation (2». The second is the currentperiod "shock" caused by changes in money de­mand originating in exogenous changes in interestand income (the latter term of (2».

This interpretation is consistent with the standarddescription of individual money demand in the pres­ence of portfolio adjustment costs. Individuals takeincome and interest rates as exogenous determi­nants of their demand for money, but because port­folio adjustment is costly, changes in these vari­ables do not induce immediate adjustment to thenew desired level of money.

Conventional Specification ProblemsThe Chow specification (or a close variant) has

become the almost universally accepted version ofthe short-run demand function for money. In largepart, its popularity is due to an influential article byStephen Goldfeld, written in 1973, that demon­strated its remarkable stability over most of thepostwar period up to then. 4 This popularity has notgone unchallenged, however, as a few authors haveargued that this specification was not necessarily asuitable specification of the dynamics of the marketfor money, whatever its merits might be as a de­scription of individual behavior. 5 In particular,these authors have argued that the Chow specifica­tion implies some rather peculiar dynamics ofmoney market adjustment when the supply curve ofmoney shifts (say, because of a change in monetarypolicy). Thus, the unanswered question is whetherthis specification is appropriate for situations inwhich shocks occur in the quantity of money, ratherthan in the arguments of money demand. Presum­ably it is this last specification that is relevant whenthere are exogenous changes in the supply ofmoney.6

There are two potential defenses of the con­ventional dynamic specification. The first is thatequation (I) is a structural equation that is agnosticabout which variable is endogenous. Thus, if themoney supply were exogenous and money demandendogenous, equation (1) simply could be rear­ranged to solve for whichever argument of moneydemand takes the burden of adjustment. In mostlarge-scale macroeconomic models, for example,

Page 22: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

the money demand function is typically used tosolve for the shorHenn rate of interest, which isviewed as the endogenous variable that adjusts toclear the market for money in the short-run when­ever the money supply is taken as exogenous.

The problem with this defense is that the conven­tional specification assumes that it takes a largechange in interest rates to induce a small change inmoney in the short-run. This result follows from thepartial adjustment of money to exogenous changesin interest rates. When the equation is turned aroundso that it predicts interest rates as a function ofexogenous money, it suggests that interest rateshave to overshoot their long-run levels in the short­run in order to induce the public to accept a changein the stock of money supplied by the Fed. 7

This result seems inconsistent with the rationalefor partial adjustment in the short run-namely,that the costs of adjusting portfolios make it sub­optimal to adjust fully. By this reasoning, when anindividual experiences an unexpected cash receipt,he presumably does not attempt immediately toreturn his cash holdings to their desired long-runvalue. Instead, the costs of adjusting his portfoliocause him to dispose of the excess cash graduallyover time. x

The same will be true in the aggregate. Whenthere is an exogenous increase in the supply ofmoney, the pressure on interest rates to change willbe relatively little in the short run as the public willtend to hold on to the increase initially. Henceadjustment costs do not point to the overshoot pat­tern of interest rates implied by the conventionalspecification. Moreover, the actual behavior of in­terest rates does not appear to conform to the over­shoot pattern either. Simulations of the Treasury billrate using the money demand function in theBoard's FMP (Federal Reserve-MIT-University ofPennsylvania) model showed "spikes" that werenot present in the actual data. 9 Since the FMPmoney demand function has a conventional partialadjustment specification, these spikes can be pre­sumed to be the product of the overshoot built intothat specification.

The second defense of the conventional partialadjustment model argues that the stock of moneywas effectively detennined by demand under theFederal Reserve's pre-October 6, 1979 procedure of

22

using the federal funds rate to try to control money.This procedure consisted of pegging short-term in­terest rates, or at least moving them only very grad­ually, in response to deviations of money fromtarget. 10 In order to do that, it is argued, the FederalReserve had to provide whatever quantity of moneythe public demanded. Hence the quantity of moneywas detennined by the demand for money. In such aworld, the conventional specification of moneymarket adjustment-which has the quantity ofmoney adjusting to changes in the demand for it­seems appropriate.

The major theoretical assault on this position isfound in the work of Brunner and Meltzer whoargue that it fails to distinguish between money andcredit. II In a world in which there are distinctmarkets for bonds (credit), as well as for money andcommodities, it is possible to have exogenouschanges in .the supply of money even when themonetary authority pegs interest rates. Suppose, forexample, that finns decide to spend more on plantand equipment. They may finance this desiredincrease in spending by floating new bonds. Hencethe increased demand for commodities (investmentgoods) is matched by an increased supply of bonds(demand for credit). The increased demand forcredit puts pressure on interest rates to rise. Toprevent this, the monetary authority increases bankreserves, allowing the banking system to purchasethe new bonds through the creation of new deposits(i.e., an increase in money supply). The finns'demand for money has not increased except transi­ently: they have borrowed the money to spend, notto hold.

At this point, there is an increase in the supply ofmoney that is not matched by any increase in thedemand for money. The change in money supply,therefore, is exogenous in the sense used in thispaper. The finns borrowing the money will spend it.The recipients of that expenditure will find them­selves with excess money balances, which they intum will get rid of by spending more. Output andprices will expand in the process until the rise in theaggregate demand for money matches the increasein money supply. Thus, even with interest rate peg­ging by the monetary authorities, it is possible forchanges in the supply of money to cause changes inthe demand for money, rather than the other wayaround.

Page 23: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

The conventional specification ofmoney demandis inadequate for describing this situation becauseits dynamics model a case in which money is en-

tirely endogenous. The purpose of the alternativespecifications described in the next section of thispaper is to provide a partial adjustment mechanismconsistent with money supply exogeneity.

II. Alternative SpecificationsThe alternative formulations of short-run money

demand are summarized in Table I. This table lists,for each specification, the variable that adjusts tochanges in the exogenous variables, as well as theexogenous, or shock, variables themselves-i.e.,the variables whose changes make observedmoneydeviate from the public's long-run demand formoney. The various specifications can be groupedinto two major categories. The first category con­sists of variants of the conventional specification,

which view the quantity of money as adjusting witha lag to changes in the demand for money. In con­trast, the members of the second group-the exog­enous money specifications-view the demand formoney as adjusting with a lag to changes in thesupply of money.Supply-adjusting equations

The conventional versions begin with the Chowspecification (I.A. I), whose properties we ex­plored extensively in the preceding section. Its use

23

Page 24: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

of money divided by prices as the dependent vari­able implies that the quantity of money adjusts fullywithin a quarter to changes in the price level. Butthe equation also assumes that there is only partialadjustment to changes in interest rates and realincome. This first feature seems implausible, andhas led others to propose I.A.2, which makes thequantity of nominal money adjust with a lag tochanges in interest rates, income and prices. 12 Athird variant, proposed by William H. White,specifies that money adjusts without any lag tochanges in money demand that are caused bychanges in interest rates (i.e., interest rates are not ashock variable), but retains the lag in response tochanges in real income and prices (I. A. 3).

Table I lists the Judd-Scadding formulation ofmoney demand as the last of the conventional spe­cifications (I.A.4). Its inclusion in this category issomewhat problematic. Like the conventional spe­cifications, it views the quantity of money as adjust­ing with a lag to changes in money demand. In thisregard, it looks very similar to the Goldfeld formu­lation (1.A.2). However, the Judd-Scadding equa­tion also recognizes that changes in the observedquantity of money can result from exogenouschanges in the supply of money.

The equation is part of a monthly money marketmodel, which incorporates the Brunner-Meltzerpoint that changes in the demand for bank loanscause exogenous shifts in the supply function ofmoney. As was outlined in Section I, costs of ad­justing portfolios cause the public to hold theseexogenous changes in money in the short run, ratherthan to try to get rid of them. The Judd-Scaddingspecification recognizes this point by adding to thepublic's observed holdings of money balances theexogenous changes in money caused by the growthof bank loans. Thus, observed money adjusts with alag both to changes in demand factors (income,interest rates and prices) and a supply factor(changes in bank loans). The authors have previ­ously found that these bank loan effects are statis­tically and economically significant in monthly datafrom 1976 through mid-1982. 13

Demand-adjusting equationsThe second class of short-run money functions­

variants I.B.I through I.B.5-consists of partialadjustment specifications in which the demand for

24

money adjusts with a lag to changes in the quantityof money. With one exception, all of these variantshave one of the arguments of money demand­either the interest rate, income, or prices-as theadjusting variable. The adjustment of money de­mand then is implicitly specified in terms of theadjustment of this variable. For example, in theArtis-Lewis formulation (1. B.2), interest rates areassumed to adjust to clear the market for money.Thus the specification is in terms of the partialadjustment of interest rates to, among other things,the quantity of money. However, since money de­mand is a function of the interest rate, this specifica­tion can be rewritten in terms of the adjustment ofmoney demand to the quantity of money.

In the same way, the Coats, Jonson and Carr­Darby formulations assume that prices adjust toclear the market for money. Again implicit in theseformulations is the idea that the demand for moneyis adjusting since the (nominal) demand for moneydepends, among other things, on prices. The oneexception to having only one variable clear themarket is Starleaf's formulation, in which the ad­justment is specified explicitly in terms of moneydemand, with no assumption made whether it isinterest rates, income or some combination of thetwo that adjusts to clear the market for money.

The three price-adjusting variants differ fromeach other in whether or not they distinguish be­tween actual and expected inflation, and betweenactual and anticipated money growth. The Jonsonformulation is the simplest, with actual prices ad­justing with a lag to changes in actual money. TheCoats formulation, on the other hand, distinguishesbetween actual and expected prices. Prices adjustfully on a contemporaneous basis to expectedchanges in prices (LlP)e. However, growth in moneythat is inconsistent with the expected change inprices creates a deviation between money and thelong-run demand for it that is ultimately removed bythe adjustment of actual inflation to the rate ofgrowth of money. Thus in the Coats formulationprices adjust with a lag not to the actual change inmoney but only to the excess of money growth overthe expected rate of inflation.

Similarly, the Carr-Darby formulation assumesthat prices adjust completely without any lag toanticipated changes in money. Partial adjustment

Page 25: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

occurs only with respect to unanticipated changes inmoney. This distinction is consistent with a rationalexpectations viewpoint, and presumably can be

justified by arguing that the costs of adjusting port­folios to anticipated changes are much smaller be­cause they can be planned for in advance.

III. The Canonical Form

This equation shows that the extent to which moneydeviates today from the long-run demand for it is afunction of two things. First is the amount of lastperiod's deviation that is carried over to today.

Although the different formulations vary in theirassumptions about which variable adjusts to clearthe market for money, they can all be expressedaccording to a general rule: i.e., they have the samecanonical form. All of the formulations are descrip­tions of how long-run equilibrium in the market formoney is disturbed by changes in certain variablesin the short run, and how long-run equilibrium isultimately restored. To illustrate, consider theChow specification (equation l.A.I, Table 1). Ithas the quantity of real money balances adjustingwith a lag to changes in the (long-run) demand formoney. This formulation can be rewritten as

m t - m? = (I-A)(mt-I - m?-I)

- (1- A)Limf(Lii,Liy). (3)

Since Ais the speed with which actual money adjuststo the demand for it, (1- A) oflast period's deviationremains after taking into account yesterday 's adjust­ment. The second contribution consists of the exog­enous disturbances to money demand in the currentperiod, caused by changes in its arguments-.-inter­est rates and income. Again, since a contempora­neous adjustment of Ais made to these disturbances,the residual deviation that remains is (1- A) of thesedisturbances.

Letting mt = mt m?be money disequilibrium,(3) can be written as,

(4)

which describes the dynamic process by which long­run equilbrium is restored, and identifies the sourceof disequilibrium, in this case, changes in moneydemand.

All the other formulations shown in Table 1 canbe put in the same canonical form. The Jonsonformulation, for example, in which prices rather

25

Page 26: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

than money do the adjusting, can be written as

(5)

Thus, the Jonson fonnulation adds changes in nom­inal money to the list of exogenous variables thatdisturb long-run equilibrium. In the conventionalfonnulation, on the other hand, it does not appearbecause it is one of the variables assumed to adjustto remove disequilibrium. Table 2 lists the can­onical version for all of the variants described in

Table I.Estimation

This canonical fonn is also used to organize theestimation results shown in Table 3, where the esti­mated adjustment parameter (A) is reported alongwith the impact elasticities for the exogenous dis­turbance variables. These impact elasticities are(1- A) times the respective long-run elasticities. Forchanges in money and prices, the long-run elastic­ities are constrained to be unity. The others­income and interest rate elasticities-are left free tobe estimated by the data.

All of the equations were estimated with realmoney balances as the dependent variable. Long­run demand, md , was expressed in terms of its basicarguments-interest rates and income-and thesearguments were used as explanatory variables. Twointerest rates were used: a short-term market rate, inthis case the four- to six-month commercial paperrate~ and the rate on passbook savings accounts.Real GNP was used as the income variable in allequations except the Carr-Datby specification,which uses permanent income. The expected infla­tion rate series used to estimate the Coats equationwas an updated series on the permanent or underly­ing inflation rate reported by Scadding (1979). Theunanticipated money series used in the Carr-Darbyequation consisted of the regression residuals fromfitting a time series model to changes in money. 14

The definition of money used throughout was MI,and the estimation period is 1959/Q 1-1974/Q 2.

The Cochrane-Orcutt procedure was used for theequations that could be estimated using ordinaryleast squares. Some of the equations, however, had

26

Page 27: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

to be estimated by nonlinear least squares (adjustedfor first-order serial correlation) because of nonlin­ear constraints on the parameters. Estimates did notconverge when an attempt was made to allow forserial correlation in the White variant (3.A.3). Forthis equation, the estimates without any adjustmentfor serial correlation are reported.Estimation results

The estimation results are presented in Table 3. Acomparison of the standard errors of the estimates ofthe equations provides a clear ordering of success.Two of the worst performances are turned in byequations 3. B. I and 3.B.2, in which income and/orinterest rates adjust to restore equilibrium. Theseequations produce standard errors of .0062 and.0056-over double the standard errors of the bestin the other groups. These errors translate into annu­alized errors of 2.5 and 2.2 percentage points, re­spectively. Furthermore, equation 3.B.2 yields anegative estimate of the adjustment parameter thatis greater than I, implying that the dynamic processis unstable.

The conventional specifications, equations3.A.I-3.AA, have significantly smaller standarderrors than those of the preceding group, with theexception of the White formulation. The Judd­Scadding and Goldfeld equations 3.A.4 and 3.A.2show annualized standard errors of 1.6 percentagepoints, while Chow (3.A.1) shows 1.8 percentagepoints. All three equations yield quite similarparameter estimates. For example, they indicatethat 20 to 25 percent of last quarter's disequilibriumis restored each quarter. In addition, they all indi­cate that the interest elasticity of money demand isrelatively small, ranging from 0.19 to 0.32 in thelong run. The White formulation, on the other hand,

gives a mediocre performance. Its standard error isthe worst of any equation by a wide margin, and itshows implausibly high income and interest rateelasticities that also have the wrong sign.

The best performance as a class is turned in by theprice adjusting equations. The Coats, Carr-Darbyand Jonson specifications have standard errors thatare 35 to 45 percent lower than the conventionalgroup. A further advantage of these specifications isthat no significant autocorrelation appears in theresiduals, whereas the conventional specificationsall have statistically significant autocorrelation.Since evidence of autocorrelated residuals mayindicate misspecification, and since it is argued bysome that the dynamics of the conventional formare misspecified, this is a potentially damagingresult for the conventional specification.

The major problem with both the Jonson andCarr-Darby equations is that real income enters withstatistically insignificant coefficients, although thesign on this variable conforms to theory. In theCoats equation, the implied long-run income elas­ticity is significant, and its value of 0.51 is compar­able to the estimates in the conventional models.These results suggest that the Coats specification, inwhich unanticipated prices adjust to changes inmoney, interest and income, yields the best per­formance of any equation tested over the sampleperiod.

Only 7 to 8 percent of disequilibrium is elimi­nated each quarter in the Jonson and Coats equa­tions, while the Carr-Darby equation has evenslower adjustment of 3 percent. This compares toadjustment of about 20 percent in the Goldfeldequation. However, this difference can be ex­plained by which variable does the adjusting. In the

27

Page 28: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

Goldfeld specification, money adjusts (relativelyquickly) to prices and other variables, whereas inthe Jonson, Coats and Carr-Darby equations, pricesadjust relatively slowly to money and other var­iables.Simulation Results

Table 4 contains the results of dynamic simula­tions over 1974/Q3-1980/Q3 of the equations inTable 3 that yielded reasonable estimation results.The White, Artis-Lewis, and Starleaf equationswere excluded because they did not meet this cri­terion.

The simulation results suggest an ordering ofperformance similar to that of the estimation results:the price-adjusting models outperform the conven­tional specifications. Specifically, the root-mean­squared-error (RMSE) over 1974/Q3-1980/Q3from Coats' equation translates into an annualized

error of 22 percentage points, with a mean error(ME) of -19 percentage points (actual minus pre­dicted). The standard Goldfeld equation has aRMSE of 38 percentage points and a ME of - 35percentage points.

The large negative mean errors of all the formula­tions reflect the well-known shift in the demand formoney in 1975-76. Clearly, all equations testedshow such a shift. However, the shift evidenced bythe price adjusting formulations is smaller than forthe conventional ones. In I977/Q I, the quarter inwhich the large cumulative shifts in all fourequations end, the" Coats, Carr~Darby and Jonsonequations are off track by from 3.6 to 6.0 percentwhile the conventional equations are off by about 10percent. Finally, the simulation of the Coats formu­lation uniformly outperforms all other equations.

IV. ConclusionsThe empirical results in this paper suggest several

conclusions. First, money demand equations inwhich prices adjust to exogenous changes inmoney, interest and income outperform equationsin which money is the adjusting variable. Equationsin which money is the adjusting variable, in turn,outperform equations where interest rates andincome are the adjusting variables. Second, theGoldfeld specification, which has been used almostexclusively in the literature, in which money is theadjusting variable, was not found to be the equationmost consistent with the quarterly data during theperiod 1959-80. The uniformly superior specifi­cation was that of Coats, in which unanticipatedprices adjust to exogenous changes in money,interest rates and income. Third, no specificationtested was free of the cumulative shift in the demandfor money in 1974/Q3-1976/Q4. However,equations in which prices are specified as the adjust­ing variable significantly reduced the size of over­predictions of Ml produced by dynamic simula­tions. The Coats specification was especially suc­cessful in this regard, producing a simulation errorwhich by 1977/Q I was 66 percent smaller than theerror from the Goldfeld equation.

Two more points are of interest. The first con­cerns interest rate volatility and monetary policy.

28

Our results indicate that it is inappropriate to use aconventional Goldfeld equation, which assumes adynamic process fitting a world with an endogenousmoney supply, to draw inferences about the interestrate volatility that would result from close short-runmonetary control. Put somewhat differently, it isinappropriate to solve a Goldfeld equation for therate of interest, and then forecast the interest rate onthe basis of changes in an exogenous money supply.This procedure, which is commonly followed inlarge econometric models, often suggests that asmall change in money growth rates would producewild interest rate swings in the short-run. This con­clusion is not reliable because it is based on amisspecified process of dynamic adjustment in themoney demand function. A specification of thatprocess depends critically on which variables aremade exogenous and which endogenous. Thus, ifthe assignment ofexogenous and endogenous varia­bles were changed (say, for a hypothetical policysimulation), the specification of dynamic adjust­ment would also need to be changed for the resultsof the simulation to be reliable.

Second, the finding that the best performancewas turned in by money demand equations withprices adjusting to exogenous changes in moneyand interest rates seems consistent with the point

Page 29: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

made by Brunner and Meltzer discussed earlier.Their point is that changes in money supply canoccur independently of changes in money demandeven if the Fed pegs interest rates. This can occur,for example, when the demand for credit rises ascorporations finance spending on new plant andequipment. The increased credit demand, which

can be independent of money demand, applies pres­sure on interest rates. In order to peg the interestrates, the Fed would increase bank reserves and themoney supply. Thus the supply of money and therate of interest can both be exogenous to the demandfor money.

FOOTNOTES

1. See Judd and Scadding (1982a).

2. Laidler (1980) has compared the empirical properties ofsome, but not all of these formulations. Also see Laidler(1980) and White (1981) for a discussion of theoreticalissues raised by alternative dynamic specifications.

3. See Chow (1966).

4. See Goldfeld (1973).

5. See, for example, Tucker (1966), Starleaf (1970) andDarby (1972).

6. It is possible to give equation (2) an interpretation inwhich changes in (nominal) money are exogenous. This isdone by noting that the left-hand variable is the change inreal balances, and that this change is simply the differencebetween nominal money growth and the rate of inflation.Hence it can be argued that it is the rate of inflation that isadjusting to money market disequilibrium, caused, amongother things, by changes in money growth. Rearranging (2)to reflect this interpretation yields

.iPt = .iMt A(m1_1-m/-1) - Mm1(lli,IlY),

in which the growth in money appears as one of the right­hand exogenous variables. The difficulty with this interpre­tation, as several writers have noted, is that it implies fullcontemporaneous adjustment of inflation to changes inmoney growth.

7. See Tucker (1966).

8. This view seems entirely consistent with inventory­theoretic money demand functions of Baumol (1952) andMiller and Orr (1966 and 1968).

9. See Modigliani, Rasche and Cooper (1972).

10. See Judd and Scadding (1979).

11. See Brunner and Meltzer (1976).

12. See Goldfeld (1976) and White (1978).

13. See Judd and Scadding (1981 and 1982b).

14. The following equation was used

IllnM\ =2.20+ .481lInM1/-1 + .111lInM1 t_ 2- .08Ut_ 1

(3.41) (4.37) (0.96) (0.71)

FF=.21 DW=1.92 SEE=2.88

REFERENCES

Baumol, William J., 'The Transactions Demand for Cash:An Inventory Theoretic Approach:' Quarterly Journalof Economics, November 1952, 66(4), pp. 545-556.

Brunner, Karl and Meltzer, Allan H. "An Aggregative Theoryfor a Closed Economy," in Monetarism. Edited by J.Stein. Amsterdam: North Holland, 1976, pp. 69-103.

Carr, Jack and Darby, Michael R. "The Role of MoneySupply Shocks in the Short-run Demand for Money,"Journal of Monetary Economics, September 1981,8(2), pp. 183-200.

Chow, Gregory C. "On the Long-Run and Short-RunDemand for Money," Journal of Political Economy,April 1966, 74(2), pp. 111-131.

Coats, Warren L., "Modeling the Short-Run Demand forMoney with Exogenous Supply:' Economic Inquiry,April 1982, 20(2), pp. 222-239.

29

Darby, Michael R. 'The Allocation of Transitory IncomeAmong Consumers' Assets," American EconomicReview, December 1972,62(5). pp. 928-41.

Goldfeld, Stephen M. "The Demand for Money Revisited:'Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1973:3,pp. 577-638.

___. "The Case of the Missing Money," Brookings Pa­pers on Economic Activity, 1976:3, pp. 683-730.

Jonson, P.O. "Money and Economic Activity in an OpenEconomy: The United Kingdom 1880-1970," Journalof Political Economy, October 1976, 84(5),pp. 972-1012.

Judd, John P. and Scadding, John L., "Conducting EffectiveMonetary Policy: The Role of Operating Instruments,"Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco EconomicReview, Fall 1979, pp. 23-37.

Page 30: K) FEDERAL RESERWE BANK OF SAN FRANCISCO · 2018-11-07 · The Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco’s Economic Review is published quarterly by the Bank’s Research and Public

"Liability Management, Bank Loans and Deposit'Markel' Disequilibrium," Federal Reserve Bank ofSan Francisco Economic Review, Summer 1981,pp.21-43.

"The Search for a Stable Money Demand Function:A Survey of the Post-1973 Literature," Journal ofEconomic literature, September 1982a, 22(3),pp.993-1023.

"Comment on 'What Do Money Models Tell Us·About How to Implement Monetary Policy?'," Journalof Money, Credit and Banking, November 1982b,14(4), Part 2, pp. 868-877.

Laidler, David E.W, ''The Demand for Money in the UnitedStates-Yet Again," in Carnegie-Rochester Confer­ence Series on Public Policy-On the State of Macro­Economics. Edited by K. Brunner and A.H. Meltzer.Amsterdam: North Holland, 1980, pp. 219-271.

Miller, Merton H. and Orr, Daniel. "A Model of Demand forMoney By Firms," Quarterly Journal of Economics,August 1966, 80(3), pp. 413-435.

''The Demand for Money By Firms: Extensions ofAnaly1ic Results," Journal of Finance, December1968,23(5), pp. 735-759.

30

Modigliani, Franco; Rasche, Robert and Cooper, J. Philip,"Central Bank Policy, the Money Supply, and theShort-Term Rate of Interest," Journal of Money,Credit, Banking, May 1970, 2(2), pp. 166-218.

Scadding, John L., "Estimating the Underlying InflationRate," Federal Reserve Bank of San FranciscoEconomic Review, Spring, 1979, pp. 7-.18.

Starleaf, Dennis R. "The Specification of Money Demand!Supply Models Which Involve the Use of DistributedLags," Journal of Finance, September 1970, 25(4),pp. 743-760.

Tucker, Donald. "Dynamic Income Adjustments to Money­Supply Changes," American Economic Review,June 1966, 56(3), pp. 433-449.

White, William H. "Improving the Demand for Money Func­tion in Moderate Inflation," International MonetaryFund Staff Paper, September 1978, 25(3),pp. 564-607.

"The Case For and Against 'Disequilibrium' Money,"International Monetary Fund Staff Paper, Septem­ber 1981,28(3), pp. 534-572.