international portability of health-cost coverage: concepts and experience

90
International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience Martin Werding Stuart McLennan SP DISCUSSION PAPER July 2011 NO. 1115

Upload: the-world-bank-social-protection-labor

Post on 31-Mar-2016

217 views

Category:

Documents


2 download

DESCRIPTION

In this paper, full portability of health-cost coverage is taken to mean that mobile individuals can, at a minimum, find comparable continuation of coverage under a different system and that this does not impose external costs or benefits on other members of the systems in the source and destination countries. Both of these aspects needs to be addressed in a meaningful portability framework for health systems, as lacking or incomplete portability may not only lead to significant losses in coverage for an individual who considers becoming mobile – which may impede mobility that is otherwise likely to be beneficial. It may also lead to financial losses, or windfall gains, for sources of health-cost funding which can ultimately lead to a detrimental process of risk segmentation across national health systems.

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

Summary Findings

In this paper, full portability of health-cost coverage is taken to mean that mobile individuals can, at a minimum, find comparable continuation of coverage under a different system and that this does not impose external costs or benefits on other members of the systems in the source and destination countries. Both of these aspects needs to be addressed in a meaningful portability framework for health systems, as lacking or incomplete portability may not only lead to significant losses in coverage for an individual who considers becoming mobile – which may impede mobility that is otherwise likely to be beneficial. It may also lead to financial losses, or windfall gains, for sources of health-cost funding which can ultimately lead to a detrimental process of risk segmentation across national health systems.

HUMAN DEVELOPMENT NETWORK

About this series...Social Protection Discussion Papers are published to communicate the results of The World Bank’s work to the development community with the least possible delay. The typescript manuscript of this paper therefore has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate to formally edited texts. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author(s), and do not necessarily reflect the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work.

For more information, please contact the Social Protection Advisory Service, The World Bank, 1818 H Street, N.W., Room G7-703, Washington, D.C. 20433 USA. Telephone: (202) 458-5267, Fax: (202) 614-0471, E-mail: [email protected] or visit the Social Protection website at www.worldbank.org/sp.

International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage:Concepts and Experience

Martin Werding Stuart McLennan

S P D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R

July 2011

NO. 1115

Page 2: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage:

Concepts and Experience

Paper prepared for the World Bank’s

Marseille Center for Mediterranean Integration

by

Martin Werding* and Stuart McLennan**

July 2011

* Ruhr Universität Bochum, Ifo Institute for Economic Research & CESifo (Corresponding author)

Address: Ruhr Universität Bochum, Dept. of Social Science, Chair in Social Policy and Public Finance,

Room GC 04/312, 44780 Bochum, Germany; phone +(49) 234 32-28971, fax +(49) 234 32-14247;

email: [email protected]

** Ruhr Universität Bochum, Dept. of Social Science, & Universität Basel, Institute for Bioethics and Medical

Ethics; email: [email protected]

Page 3: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

Abstract

Social insurance and other arrangements for funding health-care benefits often establish long-term relationships, effectively providing insurance against lasting changes in an in-dividual’s health status, engaging in burden-smoothing over the life cycle, and entailing additional elements of redistribution. International portability regarding this type of cover is, therefore, difficult to establish, but at the same time rather important both for the indi-viduals affected and for the health funds involved in any instance of an international change in work place or residence. In this paper, full portability of health-cost cover is taken to mean that mobile indi-viduals can, at a minimum, find comparable continuation of coverage under a different system and that this does not impose external costs or benefits on other members of the systems in the source and destination countries. Both of these aspects needs to be ad-dressed in a meaningful portability framework for health systems, as lacking or incom-plete portability may not only lead to significant losses in coverage for an individual who considers becoming mobile – which may impede mobility that is otherwise likely to be beneficial. It may also lead to financial losses, or windfall gains, for sources of health-cost funding which can ultimately lead to a detrimental process of risk segmentation across national health systems. Against this background, even the most advanced sets of existing portability rules, such as those agreed upon multilaterally at the EU-level or laid down in bilateral agree-ments on social protection, appear to be untargeted, inconsistent and therefore potentially harmful, either for migrants or for health funds operated at both ends of the migration process, and hence for other individuals who are covered there. Here, we develop a con-ceptual framework which can be used to clarify the implications of mobility for various types of systems covering health costs and the requirements which have to be met to en-sure full portability. We conclude that, when individuals move from one source of health-cost funding to another, compensating payments between health funds may be needed that are based on changes in expected net costs – i.e., expected health costs minus ex-pected contributions, adjusted for health-cost inflation, wage growth, long-term (non-) sustainability and properly discounted over time – in both of the systems involved. Through illustrative simulations, we show that there may indeed be sufficient leeway for this approach to be operative under real-world conditions.

JEL Classification: F22, F55, H51, H73, J6

Keywords: Social insurance, health costs; migration, international portability; fiscal ex-

ternalities, risk segmentation

Page 4: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

ii 

Acknowledgments

We are indebted to Bartosz Przywara (European Commission, DG for Economic and Fi-nancial Affairs) for kindly letting us in on detailed results of his own research regarding national health-cost profiles which we could use for numerical simulations included in this paper. We are grateful to Hans-Holger Bauer and Markus Weyres from the German Nation-al Association of Statutory Health Insurance Funds (GKV-Spitzenverband, Deutsche Ver-bindungsstelle Krankenversicherung–Ausland) and Sabine Seeböck from the Austrian Central Association of Social Insurance Funds (Hauptverband der Sozialversiche-rungsträger) for helpful discussions regarding existing arrangements for cross-border utilization of health services. We also want to thank our colleague Karolina Simonic for valuable help in accessing details of the health insurance system in Slovenia and Petra Juvančič from the public Slovenian Mutual Health Insurance Company (Vzajemna Zdravstvena Zavarovalnica) and Valentina Prevolnik from the Slovenian Ministry of Health for providing useful information regarding this system. Last but not least, we have to thank Robert Holzmann and participants of the Guid-ance Workshop on “Establishing Portability: State of the Art, Key Issues and Next Steps”, Marseille Center for Mediterranean Integration, Marseille, March 10, 2010, for helpful discussions and comments on our ideas. All remaining shortcomings and omis-sions are ours, of course.

Page 5: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

iii 

Contents

1 Introduction .............................................................................................................. 1

2 Health-care benefits and portability: important aspects .......................................... 3

2.1 Typical life-cycle profiles of health costs ......................................................... 4

2.2 Cover for health costs: elements of insurance and redistribution ..................... 10

a) Core elements of insurance .......................................................................... 11

b) Additional elements of redistribution ........................................................... 13

3 Portability of health-care benefits: international experience ................................... 15

3.1 Arrangements for portability of health-care benefits across countries ............. 16

a) EU-level rules for portability within the European Union ........................... 16

b) Bilateral agreements between ‘sending countries’ and ‘receiving countries’ 21

c) Assessment .................................................................................................... 24

3.2 Arrangements for within-country portability across health funds .................... 25

a) United States ................................................................................................. 26

b) Germany ....................................................................................................... 30

c) Slovenia ........................................................................................................ 32

d) Assessment .................................................................................................... 34

4 A conceptual framework for the portability of health-care benefits ........................ 35

4.1 Portability in unfunded systems of health-cost cover ....................................... 35

a) Expected health costs: determinants ............................................................ 36

b) Expected health costs: differentiation by risk status .................................... 37

c) Non-contributory cover for dependents ........................................................ 38

d) Long-term sustainability of financing health care ....................................... 39

e) Expected revenues for financing health care ................................................ 39

f) Expected net costs of migrants ...................................................................... 40

g) How to isolate insurance from redistribution .............................................. 42

4.2 Portability in (partially) pre-funded systems .................................................... 44

a) Fully-funded schemes ................................................................................... 45

b) Partially funded schemes .............................................................................. 48

4.3 Assessment ....................................................................................................... 50

Page 6: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

iv 

5 Policy Implications .................................................................................................. 50

5.1 Problems arising from a lack of portability ...................................................... 51

a) For potential migrants .................................................................................. 51

b) For health funds and other members of their risk pools .............................. 51

5.2 Ensuring portability .......................................................................................... 54

a) Basic options ................................................................................................. 55

b) Full portability through transfers between systems covering health costs .. 57

c) Illustrative calculations ................................................................................ 60

6 Discussion ................................................................................................................ 70

References ....................................................................................................................... 74

Page 7: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

1 Introduction

The need for health care is a life-long risk, possibly materializing at any point during

one’s life cycle. Many health-insurance schemes or other institutions catering for this

need are therefore offering, at least potentially, a life-long relationship. Possessing some

kind of cover against this risk is also vitally important from an individual’s perspective

with the costs of health care at times amounting to a notable fraction of income. Indeed,

in extreme cases, health costs incurred at the individual level can easily exceed one’s cur-

rent, or even life-time, income. In addition, expected health costs have a strong life-cycle

dimension, i.e., they are not flat over an individual’s life cycle but typically increase at

higher age by a considerable margin, while payments made by the individual to obtain

health-cost cover often do not follow this profile.

Taken together, these aspects imply that all kinds of mobility of individuals almost

necessarily raise a portability issue of some significance. This applies to changes in resi-

dence or occupational status which may trigger a switch between health funds located

within a given country as well as to various forms of international migration involving

moves between health systems operated in different countries. This paper mainly looks at

the consequences of international mobility for how health benefits are provided and, more

importantly, how they are funded, both from the perspective of the individuals affected

and from the perspective of the funding bodies. Portability problems arising within coun-

tries are nevertheless of some interest for us, since they can be similar in their nature and

since the rules applied to solving these problems may involve some lessons with respect

to our main theme. An aspect which is peculiar about international mobility and portabili-

ty in health care is that health-care benefits mostly consist of medical services which can

be delivered most easily where individuals are currently staying. Health-cost funding can

of course be provided across jurisdictional borders, but there are various scenarios in

which shifting the relevant responsibilities should nevertheless be considered.

Systems of health care and health-cost funding are rather diverse across countries. In

most countries, developed ones as well as more advanced developing ones, funding

health-care benefits for the majority of the population is subject to mandatory arrange-

ments. Funding institutions are strictly regulated and often run by the state, or benefits are

provided in-kind by tax-financed public health services. Until very recently, the US of-

fered one of the few exceptions, though a very prominent one, from any of these observa-

tions. There, private, employer-based insurance is effectively the dominant form of fund-

ing health care for working-age individuals and their families. In some other countries,

private insurance plays an important role as well, either as a substitutional form of cover

(based on differentiated membership rules in public systems, opt-out clauses, etc.) or as a

source of supplementary provisions. Here, we will try to take care of this diversity, which

Page 8: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

clearly adds to the complications of addressing the international portability of health-care

benefits, concentrating on conceptual considerations that should be relevant under any

specific arrangement, but illustrating our ideas mainly for public systems of health-cost

funding.

Thus far, the economic aspects of international portability in the area of funding

health-care benefits are largely unexplored, certainly with respect to publicly provided

forms of cover. Important exemptions are given by Holzmann et al. (2005), Avato et al.

(2009) or Holzmann and Koettl (2011), the latter providing an in-depth treatment of

health care, while the former two are less specific, dealing with portability in social pro-

tection in a broader fashion. There are a limited number of reviews of the legal frame-

work for access to health care in foreign countries (see, e.g., Sieveking 2007, Pieters and

Schoukens 2009) and of potential repercussions of cross-border utilization of health ser-

vices and international migration on national health systems (see, e.g., Sieveking 2000,

Eichenhofer 2002 or Schulte 2003). There are also a few studies on international portabil-

ity of social security and health care benefits focusing on rules applied in particular coun-

tries (e.g., Avato 2008a, 2008b) or at a regional level (e.g., Woolford 2009, Olivier 2009

or Makhema 2009). In addition, there is some amount of economic literature on portabili-

ty in the context of “internal” mobility, i.e., with respect to switches between insurance

providers within countries (see Dowd and Feldman 1992, Gruber and Madrian 1994, Pau-

ly et al. 1999 or Rashad and Rapong 2006 for the US system of employer-sponsored pri-

vate insurance; Meier 2005 or Baumann et al. 2008 for substitutional private health insur-

ance in Germany; and probably other contributions we are not aware of for arrangements

specific to other countries). To the best of our knowledge, however, practical arrange-

ments regarding compensation for health costs incurred under foreign systems have never

been analyzed regarding their appropriateness or even optimality. In this paper, we will

thus build on the limited body of literature, examining the practical experience gathered

under existing rules, and will attempt to develop a conceptual framework for designing

appropriate portability arrangements under real-world conditions.

A number of current trends add to the significance of our theme. First, international

mobility is continuously growing, the total number of international migrants is expected

to reach 214 million people in 2010, almost three times as many as in 1965 (75 million;

see Hatton and Williamson 2002 and UN 2009). Second, in developed countries and in a

growing number of developing countries demographic change may place a notable strain

on systems covering health costs,1 forcing health funds and their public supervisors to

                                                            1 At closer inspection, this strain may not only, even not mainly, be due to population ageing (see Zweifel

et al. 1999 or Breyer et al. 2010). Rather, demographic pressure appears to be strongly reinforced by the cost-side effects of medical progress. Still, throughout the world the financial situation of schemes pro-viding or funding health care is expected to deteriorate substantially in the next few decades.

Page 9: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

consider more carefully the consequences of international mobility through both inward

and outward migration for the financial viability of their schemes. Third, expected finan-

cial strain is triggering major changes in health-care systems and will continue to do so,

with partial privatization or an introduction of elements of pre-funding being among the

major options that remain in order to keep existing public schemes sustainable (see, e.g.,

Meier and Werding 2010). The portability of acquired rights in private or partially pre-

funded schemes is certainly not less complicated than in public, unfunded schemes –

even though the consequences of mobility across health funds have already been investi-

gated more for the former than they have been for the latter.

It is important to note that young, healthy immigrants are usually considered a net

asset for health systems of the countries receiving them, implying that health systems in

sending countries incur a loss when these individuals emigrate. Things may be the other

way round, if the migrants’ health status is poor or if their age is higher. For instance, this

latter scenario may apply to individuals who return home as pensioners, having worked

abroad for a substantial fraction of their active life span. Against this background, our

ambition is to shed more light on the effects of current portability regimes for health-care

benefits and to provide insights as to how these effects could be managed more actively

and more in line with the underlying economic and fiscal consequences of mobility.

The structure of the present paper is as follows. In Section 2, we will highlight two

aspects that are very important for designing portability arrangements for health-cost

cover, viz. the typical age-related profile of expected health costs as well as the various

elements of insurance and redistribution that are, or can be, involved in actual schemes

funding these costs. In Section 3, we will survey important parts of the international ex-

perience in establishing portability of health-care benefits and their funding across coun-

tries or within-country portability between health funds. We will then unfold a conceptual

framework for portability of health-cost cover in Section 4 and discuss the policy impli-

cations of our approach in Section 5. Section 6 concludes, summarizing our main obser-

vations and ideas and pointing to issues that deserve further consideration.

2 Health-care benefits and portability: important aspects

Before we can move on to discussing portability arrangements, existing ones as well as

conceptually more appropriate ones, we first need to demonstrate in more detail why por-

tability is a potentially important issue with regard to health-cost funding. There are two

features that we would specifically like to highlight. Firstly, the profile of average health

costs over the life cycle, taking into account the differentiation of these costs by health

status (Section 2.1), and second, all the elements of insurance and redistribution which

Page 10: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

are typically combined, in differing bundles, in existing systems funding health costs

(Section 2.2).

2.1 Typical life-cycle profiles of health costs

As a rule, average health costs are not flat over a given individual’s life cycle. Instead,

following relatively high costs in the year of birth and a longer period with rather low

costs, they typically increase with age from about age 45 onwards, with an accelerating

rate of increase after age 65. The increase tends to be steeper for males than for females,

the latter often having higher health costs than males between age 15 and 55, but relative-

ly lower health costs afterwards. For countries where the relevant data are available, these

observations are almost universal. However, what may differ substantially across coun-

tries is the level of these profiles, with different amounts of (age-invariant) per-capita

health costs or different shares in GDP spent on health reflecting huge differences in the

cost, quality and efficiency of health services provided in each country.

To illustrate what we have just said about age-related trends in health costs, Figure 1

shows sample profiles based on average public health expenditure for males and females

in countries of the EU-15, i.e., in the group of relatively rich countries that were EU

members already before 2004. The data is taken from a background report by Przywara

(2010, pp. 15–7), while the underlying national expenditure profiles are also shown in an

official EU-level document (European Commission and EU Economic Policy Committee

2009, pp. 118–19). For the US, with their more fragmented system of health-cost cover-

age for individuals in different age brackets, data of this kind is less easy to come by (see,

however, Herring and Pauly 2006 for some amount of relevant information).

Originally, the profiles displayed in Figure 1 were measured in terms of percentages

of GDP per capita. Here, they are converted into nominal values using per-capita GDP in

Germany in 2010. By and large, they should thus approximate health-cost profiles that

are currently observed for the German Statutory Health Insurance,2 a public scheme cov-

ering about 90 percent of the German population. Note, in any case, that they are meant

to reflect profiles of costs covered by public health insurance, not total health costs,

which is exactly what is needed to address the problems of portability that could arise in a

scheme of this kind. Patients’ co-payments, out-of pocket payments, etc. are irrelevant in

this context. For those who have it, supplementary private insurance may call for separate

considerations and calculations to become portable. But different types of cover should

not be mixed up, as the implications for portability may differ.

                                                            2 This is confirmed comparing them to corresponding data from official German sources (see, e.g., Werd-

ing 2007, Figure 4, or Werding and Hofmann 2008, Figure 3.3).

Page 11: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

Figure 1: Life-cycle profile of health costs of males and females in an EU-15 country

(calibrated to data for Germany, 2010)

Sources: Przywara (2010, Figure 7); own calculations.

It is also important to note that the age profiles shown here relate to average, or ex-

pected, health costs. They are thus the result of accidental fluctuations in annual health

costs arising for a large number of individuals around an age-related upward trend. This

upward trend, in turn, results from two components, viz. an increase in expected health

costs for individuals who are basically in good health and a growing proportion of indi-

viduals whose health status has deteriorated, so that they incur higher costs. While con-

ceptually clear, the differentiation of health costs by risk status is hard to pin down empir-

ically due to, inter alia, a lack of sufficiently detailed data. In a paper on how to optimally

insure changes in health status in a US-style context, Herring and Pauly (2006) exploit

micro-data from the US Medical Expenditure Panel Survey (MEPS) to calibrate simula-

tions regarding the cost effects of changes in health status, differentiating between just

two types of risks, that is, “low risks” in good health on the one hand and a comprehen-

sive class of “high risks” in poor health on the other. In their study, being a “high risk” is

considered a transitory phenomenon, with several years of higher expected costs follow-

ing when this has happened. To obtain a clearer distinction of risk categories, we will

change this definition, focusing on changes to a high-risk status that lift individuals to a

0

1.000

2.000

3.000

4.000

5.000

6.000

7.000

8.000

9.000

10.000

11.000

12.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Annual health costs

(€, constant prices)

Age

Males

Females

Page 12: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

higher time path of expected costs on a permanent basis. As we see it, there are thus still

two broad risk classes that can be characterized as follows.

“Low risks” are individuals who are basically healthy, but require some treatment

time and again; on average, they experience a small increase in expected health

costs as they become older.

“High risks” are individuals who have developed conditions requiring more costly

treatment more regularly, so that their expected health costs are permanently in-

creased; also, this occurs for a growing share of individuals as people get older.

If appropriate data were available, more refined classifications might be useful. However,

in order to discuss the impact of changes in health status on the portability of health-cost

cover, a simple dichotomous structure is fully sufficient. It also allows us to adapt data

and observations in Herring and Pauly (2006) to our setting and to split up average cost

profiles in the German Statutory Health Insurance system into risk-specific cost profiles

(following Baumann et al. 2008 who do the same with respect to health-cost profiles for

German private health-insurance contracts).3 The results obtained for males are shown in

Figure 2.

As a result of these calculations, expected health costs over the remaining life span

are 2 to 3 times higher for high risks than for low risks at all ages. Note that individuals

who are high risks in terms of increased annual health costs could be “low risks” in terms

of prospective life-time health costs due to considerably shorter (contingent) life expec-

tancies involved in our assumptions.4 Also, expected life-time health costs of low risks

reflect the fact that individuals in good health may become high risks with some probabil-                                                             3 See Baumann et al. (2008, pp. 300–2) for an in-depth discussion of information needed for this purpose.

First of all, translating findings based on micro-data from Herring and Pauly (2006) to the present con-text rests on the assumption that all relevant structures are sufficiently similar across countries. Also, as the MEPS data only cover individuals from age 18 to 65, some of the trends showing up there need to be extrapolated at both ends of the age distribution. Specifically, we obtain the following calibrations. – Transition probability from low-risk to high-risk status: annual probabilities of a change in risk sta-

tus within the next year are assumed to be s-shaped, going up from about .1 percent to about 3.5 per-cent over the entire life cycle; differentiation by gender does not appear to play a major role in this context.

– Mortality differential by risk status: probabilities of dying before the next year are assumed to be 10 times higher at birth for high risks than for low risks; this differential declines at accelerating speed until age 45; afterwards the decline slows down, the relevant factor converging to 1.1 at age 99; again, there is no differentiation by gender.

– Cost differential by risk status: health costs of high-risk males (in brackets: females) are assumed to be 3.5 (2.7) times higher than for low risks at age 64; this factor is symmetrically lower for younger and older individuals, being 2.0 (1.5) for individuals at birth, 3.0 (2.3) for individuals at age 100.

These assumptions are all meant to be plausible but cannot be verified because of the limited data that are available on these aspects. Our following calculations are thus mainly illustrative. Still, we think them useful to demonstrate the implications of our ideas regarding portability of health care.

4 Assumptions regarding the risk-specific mortality differential (see footnote 3) imply that life expectancy at birth is 65.3 for high-risk males and 79.4 for low-risk males, while it is 77.7 years for average risks.

Page 13: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

Figure 2: Life-cycle profile of health costs of males in an EU-15 country, differentiated

by risk status (calibrated to data for Germany, 2010)

Sources: Przywara (2010, Figure 7); own calculations.

ity at any point in time in the future. Together, these two effects could at least imply that

the differentiation by risk status turns out to be immaterial for expected life-time health

costs. However, our calculations suggest that this is not the case. The result is important

because, to the extent that is realistic,5 it has a direct impact on meaningful arrangements

for making health care and health-cost cover portable across health funds and across

countries.

Thus far, we have been looking at life-cycle profiles of health costs for a highly-

developed country which has received a substantial amount of immigration over the last

few decades (see, e.g., Geis et al. 2011). To a considerable extent, these migrants are                                                             5 The results in Herring and Pauly (2006) support the conclusion that, for individuals aged less than 65

and with a less sharp distinction of two risk classes than the one employed here, expected health costs for high risks exceed those of low risks. With simulations based on data from the US Health and Re-tirement Study (HRS), Sun et al. (2010) reach the opposite conclusion for individuals aged 65 and above (see also Webb and Zhivan 2010 for more details on their data and simulations). Potential reasons are that they may not be able to separate all individuals covered in the HRS into two risk classes, so that they effectively concentrate on a sub-group of high risks for which the cost differential vis-à-vis low risks is relatively small; or that they include costs for long-term care (which are less important for younger individuals and are not covered by the German Statutory Health Insurance scheme, hence not included in the health-cost profiles underlying our calculations). Considering the limitations of existing data, this issue clearly deserves further attention in future research for numerous reasons.

0

1.000

2.000

3.000

4.000

5.000

6.000

7.000

8.000

9.000

10.000

11.000

12.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Annual health costs

(€, constant prices)

Age

Average risk

High risk

Low risk

Page 14: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

from less developed countries where health costs may follow a similar pattern, but are

considerably lower on average. As portability arrangements will have to deal with such

differences – for young people who migrate to a developed, high-cost country and proba-

bly also for older people returning home to a less developed, low-cost country once they

have retired – we should also take a look at health-cost profiles from a typical sending

country. Traditionally, the most important source countries for immigrants to Germany

were Turkey and Yugoslavia, where the latter has now split up into a number of indepen-

dent countries, Bosnia-Herzegovina, Croatia and Serbia being the biggest ones. While

reliable, detailed data on health costs are not accessible for most non-EU countries, the

fact that Slovenia is also part of former Yugoslavia and has entered the EU in 2004 may

give us the opportunity to use comparable, good-quality from this country to provide

another set of sample profiles of health costs accruing in countries where immigrants typ-

ically come from.6

Figure 3 shows an approximation of age-related profiles of health costs covered by

the Slovenian public health insurance scheme, as reconstructed from the calculations in

Przywara (2010, pp. 15–7) regarding average public health expenditure in countries of

the EU-12, i.e., in the countries that entered the European Union since 2004. Even when

measured as a percentage of GDP per capita, average health costs in most EU-12 coun-

tries tend to be lower than in the EU-15 (see also European Commission and EU Eco-

nomic Policy Committee 2009, p. 119). The difference becomes more pronounced when

these profiles are converted into nominal values, using per-capita GDP in Slovenia in

2010 in the present case. Remember that these lower costs may reflect differences in cost,

quality, and efficiency, while we are unable to disentangle the effects of each of these

aspects.

In Figure 4, we split up the profile of average health costs for males obtained for

Slovenia into risk-specific profiles, following the same procedures and using the same

assumptions as in the case of Germany (since more specific information is again lacking).

Later on, we will use these profiles and those reflecting health costs in Germany for fur-

ther discussing portability problems related to health care for individuals migrating be-

tween similar pairs of countries.

An important aspect to keep in mind for an in-depth analysis of how to provide for

portability of health-cost cover is that all figures displayed in this section show cost pro-

files derived from a cross section, i.e., profiles that relate to different individuals at dif-

                                                            6 Clearly, data taken, say, from Turkey would be preferable in order to illustrate the consequences of

international mobility between countries with different levels of health costs. It appears that, in terms of age-invariant averages, per-capita health costs in Turkey are still considerably lower than in Slovenia (cf. OECD 2011 for some amount of information on this point). To the best of our knowledge, however, break-downs by age or age groups do not exist for Turkey.

Page 15: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

Figure 3: Life-cycle profile of health costs of males and females in an EU-12 country

(calibrated to data for Slovenia, 2010)

Sources: Przywara (2010, Figure 7); own calculations.

ferent ages in a particular year. In order to deal with expected health costs arising over

individual life cycles in a truly longitudinal fashion, one also has to consider changes in

health costs, and probably also changes in age-related health-cost profiles, over time. We

will return to this issue in Section 4, when addressing cross-country differences in ex-

pected life-time health costs and their role for portability arrangements in more detail.

As we have tried to illustrate here using two stylized examples (again, see also Euro-

pean Commission and EU Economic Policy Committee 2009, pp. 118–19), the basic

form of age-related health-cost profiles tends to be universal, while levels of costs may

differ on absolute terms and, less so, as a share in GDP per capita or by similar relative

yardsticks. Also, the way these costs are funded can be rather different across countries.

Public health care or public health-insurance schemes are mostly financed from (ear-

marked) contributions or general tax revenues that vary with income (or other tax bases)

and, for a given individual, could also be measured in terms of typical life-cycle profiles.

Increasingly, public schemes also rely on lump-sum premiums that may not vary at all by

income, age, gender or risk status. The structure of premiums collected in private health-

0

1.000

2.000

3.000

4.000

5.000

6.000

7.000

8.000

9.000

10.000

11.000

12.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Annual health costs

(€, constant prices)

Age

Males

Females

Page 16: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

10 

Figure 4: Life-cycle profile of health costs of males in an EU-12 country, differentiated

by risk status (calibrated to data for Slovenia, 2010)

Sources: Przywara (2010, Figure 7); own calculations.

insurance schemes depends on the nature and duration of those contracts. Before we can

discuss the consequences of these different regimes, we first have to take a closer look at

the differences in health-cost cover across differing types of actual arrangements.

2.2 Cover for health costs: elements of insurance and redistribution

Health insurers and other institutions covering health costs are effectively providing quite

a number of distinct services which need to be disentangled when discussing the prob-

lems involved in making cover for health costs portable across countries. Probably the

most basic service of these institutions is that they act as specialized payment agencies

collecting (and sometimes also checking) all invoices related to health services for their

customers and reimbursing health-care providers for their efforts. Besides that, one can

distinguish various further activities that are, or can be, carried out by existing health in-

surance schemes. We will divide them into a core set of elements of insurance and a

number of additional elements of redistribution. The list of elements mentioned here is

meant to be exhaustive in the sense that it incorporates, at least in a rough fashion, all

types of services involved in actual arrangements. At the same time, depending on na-

0

1.000

2.000

3.000

4.000

5.000

6.000

7.000

8.000

9.000

10.000

11.000

12.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Annual health costs

(€, constant prices)

Age

Average risk

High risk

Low risk

Page 17: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

11 

tional traditions and national attitudes regarding risk-taking and redistribution, actual

schemes may fail to comprise all of the elements listed here, even those considered to be

core services.

a) Core elements of insurance

In addition to handling payments related to health services, covering health costs often

involves one or more of the following elements of insurance:

Cover for current health costs

Insurance against prospective deterioration of one’s health status

Intertemporal burden smoothing

Cover for current health costs as the first of these elements effectively amounts to an

insurance against accidental deviations in current, i.e. annual, health costs from the re-

spective mean. Although it may be obscured by many other elements we are going to

introduce and discuss here, it is part of any arrangement of health-cost funding we are

aware of. To avoid various forms of moral hazard, insurance of this kind may be limited

by co-payments or fixed deductibles, or insured individuals may have to make out-of-

pocket payments for some types of services. Nonetheless, they are never exposed to the

risk of paying for all their health costs in a given year without any limitation, or we

would say that they have no cover for their health costs at all.

The second element, insurance against systematic changes in the individual time pro-

file of expected health costs, is even more important for insured individuals, but it is also

less wide-spread. In fact, it is conventional only in public health insurance or public

health-care systems, while it is not included in most private health-insurance contracts.

The reason is that this element requires absence of risk rating, as in most public schemes,

or long-term contracts with clauses that inhibit regular risk re-assessment, which is in fact

a rare exception rather than the rule in private arrangements.7 If the second element is

missing from a given system of health-cost coverage, individuals may end up paying risk-

adjusted premiums following risk-specific profiles of expected health costs (see Figures 2

and 4). If the health-status risk is taken care of, and if there are no further elements of

insurance or redistribution, annual premiums tend to correspond to the average profile of

expected health costs (Figures 1 and 3). The upshot of this is that risk-specific annual

premiums can become prohibitively high at higher ages. Older individuals may therefore

drop out of private health insurance with annual risk rating, using public health insurance

or public health-care systems as a fallback. If the latter is restricted by law, individuals

                                                            7 German and Austrian private health insurance contracts appear to be the only major examples – due to

common traditions in regulating this sector (see Baumann et al. 2008 for further details).

Page 18: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

12 

may be reluctant to buy private cover in the first place. By contrast, being covered by a

public system usually entails the option of a life-long membership. Indeed, it typically

offers full cover even for those who are born as high risks – a service that market-driven

insurance would never provide.

The third element, intertemporal burden smoothing, typically builds on the second

one, essentially shifting the financial burdens related to a given time profile of annual

health costs across the life cycle. As a rule, it implies that premiums exceed expected

current health costs for young individuals, while they fall short of expected current health

costs for the old. Note that this type of “age-related redistribution” does not necessarily

lead to interpersonal redistribution, as the present-value effects of these intertemporal

shifts may cancel out over time. However, this is typically not the case in public systems

where burden smoothing is mostly a by-product of age-invariant contribution rates or tax

rates, sometimes complemented with special rules defining the tax base for contributions

or taxes for workers and pensioners.8 This element can be formally reflected in some

amount of pre-funding for health cost of older individuals – an option which may become

increasingly important in the course of demographic ageing. Thus far, however, most

public schemes are unfunded, so that burden smoothing leads to implicit liabilities of

public health funds vis-à-vis younger cohorts. In private health-insurance contracts of-

fered by competing providers, burden smoothing actually requires a considerable degree

of pre-funding, plus strict regulation with carefully designed funding rules (see Baumann

et al. 2008). Again, arrangements of this kind are an exception rather than a rule.

The three elements considered thus far have in common that, in their pure form, they

are all suited to increase the welfare of individuals covered in arrangements for funding

health costs. In addition, whatever precise mechanisms apply, if health funds only pro-

vide these types of insurance, life-time premiums or contributions of each insured indi-

vidual are linked to the cost profiles presented in Section 2.1 by actuarial calculations,

even if they do not follow these profiles year by year. In reality, these elements of insur-

ance are often mixed with one or more of the elements of redistribution that are discussed

below, which renders the assessment on welfarist terms less unambiguous. Furthermore,

such additional elements can entirely disconnect contributions from benefits at the indi-

vidual level.

A further observation which is important with respect to the theme of this paper is

that in systems incorporating the second and the third of the aforementioned elements,

portability becomes an issue whenever individuals are willing to switch from one health

                                                            8 Another approach is given by differentiated membership rules for workers and pensioners, as in the US.

There, public provision for the majority of individuals sets in exactly when people retire, at least by the rules applied thus far.

Page 19: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

13 

fund to another. The reason is that these individuals are party to long-term relationships

in which payments made by the individual, and services provided by their health funds,

need no longer be balanced on an annual basis.

b) Additional elements of redistribution

Private systems of health-cost cover are basically confined by market forces to offering

insurance in the above sense. In fact, they often limit their services to the first element. In

public systems, however, a considerable amount of redistribution can be involved in how

health costs are actually funded. Again, the various forms of redistribution can be con-

densed into three basic elements that are widespread and used in different intensities and

combinations, though not universal:

Income-related redistribution

Non-contributory cover for dependents

Intergenerational redistribution

Redistribution from rich to poor as another important element of many systems of

health-cost funding reflects the fact that, in terms of normative convictions that a majority

of people would subscribe to, health is often considered a major determinant of equal

opportunities, or is subject to a kind of goods-specific egalitarianism. In any case, public

health insurance or public health-care systems are typically designed to give everyone

access to a comprehensive set of health services, regardless of individual abilities to pay

for that. Usually, this is brought about by income-related contributions or taxes which are

used to finance these schemes, while all of their members are entitled to receive a uni-

form package of benefits. As a result, individuals with higher income are paying substan-

tially more than their expected health costs, while individuals with no income at all can

effectively be free of charge.

A distinct type of redistribution involved in a number of public schemes is that child-

ren and non-working spouses of insured individuals may also have cover for their health

costs without incurring any additional charges. This is more than a corollary to redistribu-

tion from rich to poor because, where it exists, it often arises from special rules applying

to all children or all dependents, irrespective of the level income of their household. Dis-

cussing the normative background for this type of redistribution is beyond the scope of

this paper. Providing non-contributory cover for children may make sense, however, in

systems that are unfunded – or are actually funded by these children’s future earnings

capacities. It simply means that children are credited the health costs arising early in their

life cycle, while they are expected to pay back this implicit loan later on, when they have

entered their period of economic activity.

Page 20: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

14 

This leads to the last element of existing arrangements of health-cost funding which

needs to be mentioned here, viz. redistribution between subsequent generations. This

type of redistribution arises with some necessity if financial burdens through health costs

are shifted intertemporally in systems that are unfunded, as is the vast majority of public

health funds. In schemes of this kind, the present value of future benefit entitlements of

each age cohort is typically lower than the present value of their contributions – by the

margin between the market rate of interest and the internal rate of return of these

schemes, where the latter is basically given by the rate of payroll growth or the growth

rate of GDP, corrected for more than proportional increases in health costs. This differ-

ence is typically positive. It is needed to keep the systems’ implicit liabilities on a sus-

tainable time path when they are rolled over from one generation to the next one (see

Sinn 2000 for an in-depth explanation using unfunded pension schemes as an example).

All of these elements of redistribution are potentially relevant for the portability of

health-cost cover – at least, if the scheme to be left and the scheme to be entered differ in

these regards. Redistribution generally implies that there is no link between contributions

and benefit entitlements at the individual level. Nevertheless, redistribution towards poor

people and families could be arranged for in such a way that the sum of all contributions

of a given age cohort is equal to the sum of all health costs for the same group of individ-

uals. In this sense, the life-cycle health-cost profiles shown above are still a relevant

benchmark for assessing financial flows and financial obligations related to systems cov-

ering health costs. Things are different with respect to the intergenerational redistribution

involved in unfunded schemes. Here, contributions collected from a given age cohort

exceed corresponding health costs – at a rate which increases if the insured population is

ageing. In this case, the intertemporal government budget constraint effectively consti-

tutes the only binding limit for a sustainable amount of redistribution. Therefore, it also

needs to be taken into account when addressing international portability of health-care

funding with intergenerational redistribution.

Of course, preferences and majority views with respect to a desirable extent of redi-

stribution in any of the dimensions considered here may differ substantially across coun-

tries. As a consequence, international agreements regarding the inclusion of redistributive

features of national health systems in portability rules may be difficult to reach. The rules

designed for this purpose could thus be designed to reflect any differences the elements

of redistribution between national systems of health cost cover, or they could abstract as

much as possible from these differences and concentrate on the portability of insurance

elements. We will return to this issue in Chapters 4 and 5.

The things to keep in mind from the considerations made in this chapter are the fol-

lowing. First, average annual health costs are typically increasing with age. This age-

Page 21: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

15 

related trend is basically the result of two different effects. Health costs increase with age

for individuals in good health. At the same time there is an increasing share of individuals

in poor health, i.e., individuals who have developed conditions with lasting effects for the

future time paths of their risk-specific health costs. Second, any arrangement for funding

health costs which comprises more than coverage for expected annual health costs (rated

by the risk-status of each individual) may lead to portability problems when individuals

want to move to another source of health-cost funding. The various elements of redistri-

bution typically render portability even more difficult than with systems that are mainly

engaging in long-term insurance. Probably the most surprising observation is that,

through more comprehensive forms of cover, public health insurance and public health-

care systems are actually a lot more likely to give rise to portability issues than private

insurance contracts are. At the same time, quantifying these problems is not easy because

of the complicated bundles of insurance and redistribution which public systems effec-

tively offer and because of the implicit, non-contractual nature of many aspects of (man-

datory) membership in these systems.

3 Portability of health-care benefits: international experience

In an era of mobility, an increasing number of people are moving across countries for a

variety of reasons: holidays, study, retirement, and most importantly for this paper, for

work. This raises a number of important questions regarding the portability of social se-

curity entitlements across countries, including health-care benefits. For the most common

types of international mobility and the most important directions of movements, ar-

rangements have therefore been made to ensure at least some portability of health-care

benefits and health-cost cover (see Section 3.1). Here, we will review examples of these

arrangements to get an idea of what they are about, starting with the most elaborate set of

rules in this area, viz. the EU-level framework for portability of health-care benefits for

individuals moving around within the European Union. In addition, we will also look at

arrangements between countries not covered by this framework, more developed ones

that are typically receiving migrants seeking residence or work, and less developed ones

where these migrants typically come from.

International arrangements for portability turn out to have limited economic content,

so that the countries affected can never be sure whether they are winning or losing from

in- and out-migration. Therefore, we also briefly review portability arrangements that

apply to mobility within countries. In countries where private insurance with competing

providers plays a considerable role for funding health care (or in countries with differen-

tiated systems of public health-insurance), arrangements are needed for individuals who

Page 22: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

16 

are willing to switch between different health funds. As the rules applied in these cases

could contribute to our understanding of meaningful approaches to designing internation-

al portability arrangements, we will explain and discuss a few examples of this kind as

well (see Section 3.2).

3.1 Arrangements for portability of health-care benefits across countries

The customary instrument that is used for regulating portability of all kinds of social se-

curity benefits across countries are bilateral agreements. Regarding the portability of so-

cial security benefits, however, the European Union has created the “most advanced (and

complex) ... system worldwide” (Holzmann et al. 2005, p. 7) building on a multilateral

regime. The aim of both types of agreements “is to coordinate national social security

law, not to create any form of supranational social security system” (Holzmann et al.

2005, p. 17). These agreements specifically attempt to facilitate international mobility by

securing access to health services for individuals who are mobile internationally and to

provide a framework for mutual compensation for the utilization of services under for-

eign health systems where this is thought to be required. They are based on administrative

considerations rather than on economic ones, an obvious merit being that they are likely

to save on transaction costs for the social security institutions involved, while they can be

more or less favorable for migrants.

a) EU-level rules for portability within the European Union

Free mobility of workers between the EU member countries is one of the fundamental

principles of European integration, dating back to 1957 when the process of integration

started among a limited number of countries in Western Europe. The principle was sus-

pended for workers from accession countries for a few years through transitional ar-

rangements when the EU was enlarged to the South (in 1981 and 1986) and the East (in

2004 and 2007). However, with an eye on workers exercising their right to migrate freely

within the EU, it was amended with EU-level rules regarding the coordination of national

social protection law as early as in 1968 (Regulation (EEC) No. 1612/68). More recently,

the focus has shifted from providing for the mobility of workers and their families to

creating a framework for free mobility of all EU citizens across the entire union (Direc-

tive 2004/38/EC). To simplify EU law and enhance citizens’ social protection when mov-

ing within the EU, modernized social security coordination rules (Regulations (EC) Nos

883/2004 and 987/2009) were developed and entered into force on 1 May 2010.

These provisions do not harmonize national social security systems, but instead pro-

vide for their coordination to make it easier for people exercising their right to move and

to stay within EU member states. There are four main principles of coordination:

Page 23: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

17 

1) The territorial rule: a person is subject to the legislation of one country at a time

so he or she only pays contributions in one country.

2) Principle of equal treatment or non-discrimination: a person has the same rights

and obligations as the nationals of the country where he or she is covered.

3) Principle of aggregation: when benefits are claimed, previous periods of insur-

ance, work or residence in other countries are taken into account if necessary.

4) Principle of exportability: if a person is entitled to a cash benefit from one coun-

try, he or she may generally receive it even when living in a different country.

In the first instance, the coordination provisions set rules to determine which member

state’s social security legislation applies in situations involving more than one member

state. In accordance with the territorial rule, individuals are subject to the legislation of

only one member state at a time, regardless of the number of states involved. As a general

rule, individuals who are working in one member state are subject to the legislation of

that state even if they reside in another state. There are, however, a few exceptions to this

rule: posted workers, mariners and in the interest of the persons concerned. If individuals

are working in more than one member state then the principle is to determine to what

state they have the strongest links.9 Individuals who are not working are subject to the

legislation of their state of residence.10 To obtain a residence permit, they usually have to

                                                            9 The EU (2010) has set out criteria to determine this matter:

– A person working in more than one member state and residing in the state where they pursue a sub-stantial part of their activity is subject to the legislation of their state of residence.

– A person working in more than one member state and being employed by various undertakings or employers in different member states are also subject to the legislation of their state of residence.

– A person whose state of residence does not correspond to the state in which they pursue a substantial part of their activity (in the case of an employed person) or to the centre of interest (in the case of a self-employed person), the following applies. Employed persons are subject to the legislation of the member state in which their employer is registered. Self-employed person are subject to the legisla-tion of the member state in which the centre of interest of their activities is situated.

– A person who pursues both employed and a self-employed activity in different member states is sub-ject to the legislation of the state where they undertake employed activity.

– Civil servants remain under the legislation of their administration. 10 Article 11 of Regulation (EC) No 987/2009 sets out the elements for determining residence as follows:

“1. Where there is a difference of views between the institutions of two or more Member States about the determination of the residence of a person to whom the basic Regulation applies, these institu-tions shall establish by common agreement the centre of interests of the person concerned, based on an overall assessment of all available information relating to relevant facts, which may include, as appropriate: (a) the duration and continuity of presence on the territory of the Member States concerned; (b) the person’s situation, including:

(i) the nature and the specific characteristics of any activity pursued, in particular the place where such activity is habitually pursued, the stability of the activity, and the duration of any work con-tract; (ii) his family status and family ties; (iii) the exercise of any non-remunerated activity; (iv) in the case of students, the source of their income;

Page 24: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

18 

demonstrate that they have sufficient health-insurance cover, e.g. from their home coun-

try, even under the new rules for the mobility of EU citizens. However, the utilization of

health services then falls under jurisdiction of the state they are living in.

An important implication of these rules is that migrant workers who settle in another

EU country and take up a regular job there are not really subject to the coordinating law,

as they are simply given access to social security institutions in their host countries. The

same applies to members of their families who are living with these workers, provided

that coverage for them is included in the relevant schemes. On the other hand, migrant

workers’ family members who stay at home (or live in another EU country) are subject to

the EU-level rules to the extent that their benefit entitlements are derived from the work-

ers’ insurance. The rules also apply to (migrant) workers who retire and move to another

country (or actually return home) as pensioners.11 In addition, the coordination provisions

warrant protection not only for migrant workers and the members of their families but for

all EU citizens interacting with other member states. In this sense, the EU-level frame-

work can also be used as a benchmark system defining the different types of mobility that

can be addressed in international portability arrangements. Bilateral agreements and other

(e.g., unilateral) rules for international portability of health-care benefits could then be

examined regarding whether or not, and if so how, they are also providing for each of the

cases covered inside the European union.

The wide variety of health-care benefits can be divided into two major categories of

benefits: benefits in cash and benefits in kind. Benefits in cash are generally intended to

replace an income which is suspended due to sickness. These are usually always paid in

accordance with the legislation of the state where individuals are insured regardless of

where they are residing or staying, and thus would normally be paid directly to the indi-

viduals. Benefits in kind include health care, medical treatment, medicines and hospitali-

zation, certain benefits for persons reliant on care, as well as the direct payments intended

to reimburse their costs. These benefits are usually provided in accordance with the legis-

                                                                                                                                                                                 (v) his housing situation, in particular how permanent it is; (vi) the Member State in which the person is deemed to reside for taxation purposes.

2. Where the consideration of the various criteria based on relevant facts as set out in paragraph 1 does not lead to agreement between the institutions concerned, the person’s intention, as it appears from such facts and circumstances, especially the reasons that led the person to move, shall be considered to be decisive for establishing that person’s actual place of residence.” 

11 Under the EU-level framework, cover for health costs of pensioners who are mobile is provided by just one institution which is basically determined in accordance with where pension benefits are provided (see Articles 23–25 of Regulation (EC) No 883/2004): – If a pensioner has pension entitlements in the current country of residence, health-cost cover will be

provided from this country. – In all other cases, the institution from the country will be responsible whose legislation the pensioner

has been subject to for the longest period of time; if this does not lead to a clear result, the institution from the country will be responsible whose legislation the person was last subject to.

Page 25: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

19 

lation of the state in which individuals are residing or staying as if they are insured in that

state (EU 2010).

Individuals staying temporarily in a different state from which they are insured, typi-

cally tourists or students, are entitled to all benefits in kind which become medically ne-

cessary during their stay provided they are insured under a statutory health-insurance

scheme in their home state. The European Health-insurance Card (EHIC) has simplified

the process of receiving medical assistance during a temporary stay within the EU or in

Iceland, Liechtenstein, Norway and Switzerland. If medical assistance is received in a

country that charges for health care, EHIC holders will be reimbursed either immediately,

or after they have returned home. Otherwise, the institution providing assistance will be

reimbursed by the card holders’ insurance.

Frontier workers are employed or self-employed persons pursuing their occupation

in a different member state from the one in which they reside and to which they return at

least once a week. Frontier workers are insured in the state where they work. However, in

regards benefits in kind frontier workers have a choice, they can obtain these benefits

either in the state where they reside or the state in which they work. Posted workers are

individuals who are normally employed in one state but are sent temporarily to another

state to work for a maximum period of 24 months. Posted workers remain insured in the

state where they are normally employed and thus continue to pay contributions to the

social security system of that state. However, posted workers are entitled to all health-

care benefits in kind in the state to which they have been sent, regardless of whether or

not they have transferred their residence there.

Individuals who are not working, while residing in a different state from which they

are insured – for instance, family members of insured individuals, or pensioners who

moved abroad or returned home after retirement – are entitled to all benefits in kind pro-

vided under the legislation of the state where they reside. These benefits are provided by

insurance institutions of the individuals’ place of residence as if they were insured with it.

The individuals should register with the insurance institution of their place of residence

by requesting an ‘S1’ document certifying their health-care coverage from their insurance

institution. As a rule, the health-insurance institution of the place of residence will then

be reimbursed by the institution the individuals are insured with.

Article 35 of Regulation (EC) No 883/2004 sets out the guidelines for reimburse-

ments between institutions:

“1. The benefits in kind provided by the institution of a Member State on behalf of the

institution of another Member State under this Chapter shall give rise to full reim-

bursement.

Page 26: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

20 

2. The reimbursements referred to in paragraph 1 shall be determined and effected in

accordance with the arrangements set out in the Implementing Regulation, either

on production of proof of actual expenditure, or on the basis of fixed amounts for

Member States the legal or administrative structures of which are such that the use

of reimbursement on the basis of actual expenditure is not appropriate.

3. Two or more Member States, and their competent authorities, may provide for

other methods of reimbursement or waive all reimbursement between the institu-

tions coming under their jurisdiction.”

Building on these guidelines, article 62 of the Implementing Regulation (EC) 987/2009

sets out principles for assessing reimbursements based on actual expenditure.12 Article 64

defines how reimbursements in terms of fixed amounts ought to be assessed where they

are in use.13

Instead of reimbursements based on actual costs, lump-sum payments or (mutual)

waiving of payments are thus two possible simplifications included in current EU-level

rules. While lump-sum payments played, and still play, a significant role in actually han-

dling reimbursements between health funds in EU countries, the option of waiving any

payments where mutual claims are likely to be low and rather balanced are now less and

less in use14 – among other things, it appears, because of informal standards requiring

equal treatment vis-à-vis other EU countries. Lump-sum payments are also less in use

today than they were until 2009, before the modernized coordination rules came into

force.15 Most countries have thus moved in the direction of claiming reimbursements

based on actual costs, as their health funds were not satisfied with procedures and/or re-

sults of defining lump-sum payments and because the determination of actual costs has

become substantially less burdensome through recent developments in IT-based account-

ing and billing in the relevant industries.

The implications of these rules and their practical application with respect to two

standard cases we are particularly interested in are thus the following. (i) Migrant work-

                                                            12 Actual costs must derive from standard accounting procedures of the institution which has provided the

relevant benefits. They may not exceed the rates applicable to benefits in kind for persons who are sub-ject to the legislation applied by this institution.

13 Monthly fixed amounts are to be assessed based on average expenditure for insured individuals in three age groups (less than 20, 20–64 and 65 and more years of age), reduced by a deduction of 20 percent (15 percent for pensioners and family members). There is no official reason for this deduction, but it may reflect the fact that individuals staying abroad tend to consume fewer health services in their target country, even if they are registered to stay there on a permanent basis.

14 According to annex 1 of Regulation (EC) 987/2009, this option is currently applied, on a mutual basis, between the Nordic EU member countries only.

15 Annex 3of Regulation (EC) 987/2009 lists nine EU countries (e.g., Italy, Spain and Portugal from the Southern part of the EU, but also the UK, Ireland, and the Netherlands) that are continuing to claim reimbursements for health benefits in kind on the basis of fixed amounts.

Page 27: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

21 

ers who are EU nationals and move to another EU country to take up employment there

are typically covered by their host countries’ health-care systems or health-insurance

schemes, as are their family members. If family members stay in the home country, they

can receive treatment there, following the legal rules applied in their state of residence,

but their health costs are taken on by the workers’ health funds, mostly in terms of actual

costs incurred. The same happens if migrant workers or their family members go home as

tourists from time to time, to visit relatives and friends, etc. (ii) Pensioners moving to

another EU country after retirement remain insured in their home countries’ health funds.

They can receive treatment in their country of residence but, again, the health costs that

arise are reimbursed by their health funds, mostly based on actual costs. Unless they have

some pension entitlements from their home country as well, the same applies to migrant

workers who return home once they are retired – only, to avoid confusion we should say

that they remain insured in their former host countries’ health funds, with consequences

that are otherwise identical.

b) Bilateral agreements between ‘sending countries’ and ‘receiving countries’

As the EU-level framework only applies to mobility within the European Union, the legal

basis with regard to all kinds of mobility between non-EU countries, or between EU

countries on the one side and non-EU countries on the other, is quite different. However,

bilateral agreements, where they exist, may effectively provide for similar rules relating

to health-care portability. To illustrate this, we will examine the bilateral agreements

Germany and Austria have with non-EU countries. Now that most of their neighboring

countries are EU member states, the list of countries whose citizens are subject to these

bilateral agreements regarding social protection is relatively short.16 Still, those countries

where the largest groups of immigrants to both Germany and Austria come from are

represented on these lists. Traditionally, this has been Turkey and former Yugoslavia;

more recently, agreements with the latter have been extended to its successor states and in

some cases amended. Here, we will thus take bilateral agreements between this sub-set of

typical sending countries on the one side, and Germany and Austria as two countries typ-

ically receiving immigration on the other side to summarize the essence of provisions

made in such agreements.

                                                            16 Germany has bilateral agreements on social protection with 17 non-EU and non-EEA countries (among

these are the US, Canada, Japan and Australia, but also Morocco, Tunisia, Turkey and the successor states of Yugoslavia; see http://www.bmas.de/portal/13982/sozialversicherungsabkommen.html); Aus-tria has the same with 13 non-EU and non-EEA countries (again the US and Canada, Tunisia and Tur-key and most of the states in former Yugoslavia; see http://www.bmeia.gv.at/aussenministerium/aus-senpolitik/voelkerrecht/staatsvertraege/bilaterale-staatsvertraege.html).

Page 28: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

22 

As a fundamental difference to rules applied within the EU, there is no free mobility

of workers or citizens between the sending countries and receiving countries we are now

looking at. Nevertheless, there has been a period of active recruitment of workers from

Turkey and Yugoslavia to Germany and Austria in the 1950s and 1960s. This policy was

terminated following the oil-price shock and the resulting crisis in the mid-1970s. But

family re-unification for those already there continually offered a legal entitlement for

further waves of migration. The stock of immigrants from these countries – respectively,

their successor states – living in Germany and Austria has therefore continued to grow to

date.

The first bilateral agreements regarding the social protection of migrant workers and

their family members were made at an early stage in this process (in 1964, both Germany

and Austria signed agreements with Turkey; and in 1968, an agreement was signed be-

tween Germany and Yugoslavia). There have been some changes in the rules agreed upon

through up-dates of these agreements as time went by (e.g., between Germany and Tur-

key in 1984). After 1990, a wave of renewals of agreements started between Germany

and the states in former Yugoslavia, initially stating that the old agreement should con-

tinue to apply (for instance, vis-à-vis Bosnia-Herzegovina in 1992, where this is still the

state of affairs), followed by new agreements with a number of these countries in more

recent times (for instance, with Croatia, Macedonia and Serbia in 1997). Austria also

made a new bilateral agreement with what was then Yugoslavia (namely, Serbia and

Montenegro) in 1998 and entered new agreements with other successor states of Yugos-

lavia in the late 1990s (Croatia and Macedonia 1997, Bosnia-Herzegovina 1999).

The structure and provisions of all these bilateral agreements are rather similar – in

fact, the more recent ones with either Germany or Austria as one contracting party are

almost identical. Compared to the EU-level framework discussed in the previous section,

the agreements all define a territorial rule with respect to employees who, with few ex-

ceptions, are basically subject to the legislation (hence, arrangements for health-cost

funding) in their territory of employment. They also include rules regarding equal treat-

ment of individuals rightfully claiming benefits in kind in the territory of the other state

(which sometimes requires approval from their insuring body) and regarding exportabili-

ty of cash benefits. In these agreements, there are also rules regarding aggregation of

multiple benefit entitlements, but this is largely immaterial in the area of health-cost

funding.

As a result, migrant workers are again largely neglected in these agreements since,

provided they are able to obtain a work permit and to enter a regular job, they are fully

covered by health funds in their host countries. As with the EU-level law, the agreements

mainly relate to individuals who are residing or staying temporarily in the contracting

Page 29: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

23 

state that is not the one where they have health-cost cover. That is, they apply to frontier

workers (commuters) and posted workers (expatriates), to family members of migrant

workers living abroad, to retired individuals residing in the other state and also to tourists

and other people travelling there. The basic rights of all these individuals are that they

can usually receive cash benefits in accordance with the legislation of the state where

they are insured and that they have access to benefits in kind in accordance with the legis-

lation of the state in which individuals are residing or staying. For the latter case, there

are also rules regarding reimbursements between the health funds involved.

By the relevant clauses of the agreements, these reimbursements can be based on

actual costs or, alternatively, on fixed amounts (i.e., relevant averages of monthly ex-

penditure in the country where benefits have been provided). The option of mutually

waiving payments is included in the agreements only exceptionally (e.g., between Ger-

many and Turkey, since 1984), but it is effectively nowhere utilized. In fact, Germany is

nowadays claiming reimbursements from foreign institutions based on actual costs only,

while mixed regimes with lump-sum payments for differing sub-groups of individuals

covered in bilateral agreements apply to payments in the opposite direction. Austria is

still claiming and making lump-sum reimbursements vis-à-vis most of the contracting

states considered here, based on a recent series of special agreements regarding how these

payments are to be assessed. It appears that authorities in Germany as well as in Austria

would have a preference for switching to reimbursements based on actual expenditure as

a universal standard, while they acknowledge that this might be difficult to administer for

institutions in a number of their contracting states.

All in all, regarding countries such as Germany and Austria the situation created

through bilateral agreements on social protection for individual who are mobile between

these and non-EU countries is not fundamentally different from that governed by the

common legal framework applying to all EU citizens, their implications for standard cas-

es again being as follows. (i) Migrant workers are typically covered by their host coun-

tries’ health-care systems or health-insurance schemes. The same applies to their family

members, while family members who stay in the home country can receive treatment

there, but their health costs are taken on by the workers’ health funds. (ii) Pensioners

moving to the other country after retirement remain insured in the health funds of the

country where their pension benefits are provided. When they receive treatment in their

country of residence, health costs are then reimbursed by their health funds. For pension-

ers who have pension entitlements in both countries, health costs are covered from their

country of residence (while reimbursements may still apply to health costs arising during

temporary stays in the other country). In any of these cases, reimbursements are either

based on actual costs or on lump-sum payments, depending on the countries involved and

Page 30: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

24 

on the relevant category of cases, but there is a trend towards claiming, or paying for,

actual costs wherever there is room for adjusting existing agreements.

c) Assessment

Regarding the international portability of health care and health-cost funding, current EU-

level rules applying to EU citizens are interesting as they are well-known to be rather

generous to facilitate actual utilization of the union’s free-mobility rules. In addition to

that, we have also looked at relevant provisions in bilateral agreements made by Germany

and Austria with non-EU countries – as they are examples of two highly developed coun-

tries receiving a substantial amount of immigration from outside the EU. Before moving

ahead, we should briefly highlight what we think is important about the current portabili-

ty framework, concentrating on instances of international changes in residence or work

place that are temporary (but of some length) or permanent (with the option of returning

home, again on a more permanent basis, much later).17

As we see it, EU-level rules as well as the rules involved in bilateral agreements

made by Germany and Austria effectively define two broad types of arrangements re-

garding the portability of benefit entitlements vis-à-vis social protection systems in dif-

ferent countries. For migrant workers and, in most cases, also their family members, the

existing legal framework can be characterized as a “package deal”: these workers and

their relatives are usually admitted nearly automatically to the national risk pool for fund-

ing health costs as an annex to their legal status based on an official work permit (granted

to at least one member of the respective household). The package deal is relevant for the

utilization of health services by these migrants in the respective country of employment.

All other cases of international mobility give rise to some amount of “cross-border cov-

erage” of health services, with some interaction between the two health systems involved

regarding reimbursements for the costs of treatment. Among other things, this applies to

family members residing outside the workers’ country of employment or to retirees resid-

ing outside their former country of employment.

EU-level rules and bilateral agreements leave room for the package-deal solution,

while it is otherwise mostly governed by national law in the countries of employment of

migrant workers. International law then mainly takes care of the rules for cross-border

coverage, i.e., the conditions under which individuals may get access to health services in

other countries and the terms for determining any related cross-border payments between

                                                            17 In this paper, we are not concerned about health costs arising in foreign countries during short-term

stays which are usually limited to a maximum of 90 days per travel and tend to last much shorter on av-erage. We are aware of the fact that tourist visa are sometimes used as a platform for various forms of semi-legal or illegal mobility. For the moment, however, dealing with this rather complex issue is clear-ly beyond the scope of our considerations.

Page 31: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

25 

national health funds. The remarkable thing about this set up is that the package deal for

migrant workers effectively neglects the existence of portability problems involved in

international mobility of individuals who can be expected to contribute most actively to

national health funds in their former as well as their current countries of employment.

This has potentially far-reaching consequences for the structure of risks covered in na-

tional health systems in both sending and receiving countries involved in this deal. Simi-

lar problems may arise through the coordinating rules applying to pensioners with mixed

employment records as these rules allocate responsibility for their health costs to one

country, with limited attention to where they have been paying contributions or taxes

while they were still active. In any case, given the uncertainties about how to appropriate-

ly assess reimbursements, the options for shifting responsibility for covering health costs

across countries to substitute for current cases of cross-border coverage may deserve fur-

ther consideration.

3.2 Arrangements for within-country portability across health funds

In order to further explore problems that could be involved in the portability of health-

insurance cover and to learn more about potential solutions, we will now also examine

the rules applying to individuals who are willing to switch between different providers

within a given country. Specifically, the case of workers changing their jobs or occupa-

tional status, with consequences for their sources of health-cost funding that are not fully

dealt with in international law, could be a major issue for designing portability arrange-

ments applying within a given country.

However, we will be very selective in this section. First of all, we will concentrate on

private health insurance. The main reasons for doing so are that public systems with mul-

tiple, competing providers are rare, so that arrangements for portability between public

health funds often are not needed at all, while private providers are subject to market

forces which, to the extent that regulation does not set them off, could necessitate a more

careful design of portability rules where they are needed in this branch of health-cost

cover. Second, we will look at relevant rules in a very limited number of countries only.

The role and regulation of private health insurance differs substantially across coun-

tries, mainly depending on how health care is provided and funded for those under public

arrangements. If public programs are absent, or if participation in these programs is not

mandatory for a majority of the population, private health insurance can be the dominant

form of cover. When it coexists with public programs, there is a major distinction within

the domain of private insurance between “substitutional” forms of cover (insurance for

full costs, intended to replace public health insurance or public provision of health care)

and “supplementary” insurance (covering costs of services or types of treatment that are

Page 32: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

26 

not, or not fully, included in benefit packages offered by public schemes). Here, we will

briefly discuss the rules addressing portability in arrangements of any of these types, tak-

ing just three countries as interesting examples.

Specifically, we will briefly comment on relevant rules applying in the United States

(as an example of the rare case where private insurance is the main form of health-cost

cover), in Germany (where “substitutional” private insurance is effectively a niche prod-

uct, but subject to remarkable regulation), and in Slovenia (where “supplementary” pri-

vate cover is almost universal). Clearly, any of these examples has idiosyncratic fea-

tures,18 but we think that discussing them in some detail is more instructive than attempt-

ing to keep things abstract and general.

a) United States

As it has already been noted, the US is an interesting outlier in that, for working-age in-

dividuals and their families, private, employer-provided health insurance is clearly the

dominant form of cover. Indeed, the majority of the population in this country receives

private health insurance coverage through the workplace, either through their own em-

ployment or the employment of a family member (Gruber and Madrian 2002).19 Con-

tracts made by employers are almost exclusively based on group insurance, with very

limited alternative pooling mechanisms available. Alternatively, insurance may be pur-

chased in the individual market, however, this is generally very expensive, less compre-

hensive, and often not available to very unhealthy individuals.

While the workplace pooling of risks does have some advantages,20 by having health

insurance largely restricted to the workplace, insurance-induced immobility may occur.

As Gruber and Madrian (2002, p. 2) note, “[g]iven the high and variable level of health

care costs for many workers, health insurance can be a key factor in the decision to work,

to retire, to leave welfare, or to switch jobs”. In addition, the cost of providing health in-

surance varies considerably for employers, mainly depending on the size of the risk pool

for which they are seeking group insurance. Indeed, the cost is so high for some smaller

firms that, over time, an increasing number of them have stopped providing health insur-

ance altogether.21 For many observers, the potential of health insurance to impact labor                                                             18 For a much broader survey of private health-insurance arrangements in various countries and their po-

tential in the co-existence with public systems, see Preker et al. (2009). 19 This will remain true in spite of new legislation that slightly adjusts existing public programs (for wel-

fare recipients and retirees) and is otherwise meant to make health insurance basically mandatory and more affordable. 

20 Gruber and Madrian (1994, p. 86) note that this allows “for economies of scale in administration; it reduces the problem of adverse selection as long as workplaces are chosen independently of health sta-tus; and it allows individuals to take advantage of the non-taxation of employee fringe benefits.”

21 As Gruber and Madrian (2002, p. 5) put it, “[l]arge workplace pools also provide a means for individu-als to purchase insurance without the adverse selection premium that insurers demand in the individual

Page 33: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

27 

supply and job mobility has thus been of particular concern. A distinct, yet related con-

cern is that employer-based health insurance is available to many workers, but also leads

to considerable gaps in coverage.

In fact, labor economists in the US have long agreed that the provision of employer-

provided health insurance plays a significant role in decreasing job mobility, leading to

“job-lock”, where people feel unable to leave their jobs due to the fear of losing their

health insurance benefits. Since health insurance coverage in the US is not a homogenous

good, individuals are often unable to obtain comparable health insurance across jobs. A

number of barriers to switching jobs have been identified in the literature, including: in-

surance at new employment not covering pre-existing conditions; probationary periods

for new coverage; losing credit gained under previous insurance towards deductibles and

out-of-pocket payments; the costs in transitioning; new employers offering a more limited

range of insurance options, and new employers offering insurance that is too expensive,

or not providing health insurance at all (see, e.g., Bartel and Borjas 1977, Mitchell 1982,

Holtz-Eakin 1993, Madrian 1994, Gruber and Madrian 2002, Rashad and Sarpong 2006).

A number of possible solutions were suggested in the literature to address the job-

lock phenomenon (see, e.g., Gruber and Madrian 1994). These included divorcing health

insurance coverage from the employment relationship, with pooling instead occurring

elsewhere, for instance, at the regional or national level. Alternatively, it was suggested

that employer-provided insurance could be maintained, but that “full” insurance portabili-

ty across jobs could be enabled. Without discussing in much detail what this could mean,

however, Gruber and Madrian (1994, p. 89) felt that this option raised a number of diffi-

cult design issues, particularly in relation to how the responsibility for providing the in-

surance would be assigned.22 They also felt that both of these options would have funda-

mentally changed the nature of health insurance coverage in the US, so that large transi-

tion costs may render them impractical.

It was a more modest measure of “limited portability” of health insurance that was in

fact first implemented by way of “continuation-of-coverage” laws in order to address this

issue. The first continuation-of-coverage law was introduced by the State of Minnesota in

1974, which was followed by more than 20 other states before the federal government

                                                                                                                                                                                 health insurance marketplace, since the unobservable components of health will average out in large groups. For smaller groups, on the other hand, there is the risk that insurance purchase is driven by the needs of one or two (unobservably) very ill employees, whose costs cannot possibly be covered by the premium payments of healthier workers.”

22 Gruber and Madrian (1994, p. 89) argue that “[m]aking the initial employer responsible for all future insurance would lead to large distortions in initial hiring decisions and massive administrative costs in tracking employees through their job changes. Assigning responsibility to each subsequent employer would make it difficult to guarantee individuals fully comparable coverage on each job, and if coverage is less generous in alternative employment, the problem of job-lock remains.”

Page 34: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

28 

passed the Consolidated Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act (COBRA)23 in 1986 which

mandated continuation of coverage nationally (Gruber and Madrian 1994). COBRA

aimed at easing portability restrictions on employer-provided health insurance by requir-

ing employers to temporarily continue coverage after the employment contract has been

terminated (Rashad and Sarpong 2006). COBRA allowed for employees, their spouses,

their former spouses, and their dependents who were previously covered by health insur-

ance to maintain that coverage if a “qualifying event” caused them to lose coverage.24

Individuals who elected continuation of coverage could be required to pay the full cost of

the coverage, plus a 2-percent administrative charge. Thus, while the cost of continuation

coverage was often more expensive than the amount which active employees were re-

quired to pay, it was usually less expensive than individual health coverage. However,

continuation coverage was only required to be provided under COBRA for a maximum of

18 or 36 months,25 so that “limited” portability was effectively a means to bridge certain

temporary gaps in health-insurance coverage, but did not solve the job-lock problem.

This matter was further addressed in 1996 by the Health Insurance Portability and

Accountability Act (HIPAA). HIPAA limited the ability of a new employer’s health plan

to exclude coverage for pre-existing conditions, enabled credits for past insurance, pro-

vided additional opportunities to enroll in a group health plan for those who lost other

coverage or experienced certain life events, prohibited discrimination against employees

and their dependent family members based on any health factors, including prior medical

conditions, previous claims experience, and genetic information, and guaranteed that cer-

tain individuals would have access to, and could renew, individual health insurance poli-

cies.26 Gruber and Madrian (1997) have highlighted the importance of these laws in re-

ducing the occurrence of job-lock. However, while HIPAA added protections and made it

easier to switch jobs without fear of losing health coverage for a pre-existing condition,

the law had limitations that led to continued debates. For instance, HIPAA did not require

employers to offer health insurance, did not guarantee that any conditions (prior or cur-

rent) were covered by the new employer’s health plan, and did not prohibit an employer

from imposing a pre-existing condition exclusion period if an individual had been treated

for a condition during the past 6 months.

                                                            23 While officially called the Consolidated Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act 1985, because of the dis-

crepancy between the official name and the year in which it was enacted, some publications refer to it as the Consolidated Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act 1986.

24 Those events include the death of a covered employee; termination, or reduction in the hours of a cov-ered employee’s employment for reasons other than gross misconduct; divorce or legal separation from a covered employee; a covered employee’s becoming entitled to Medicare; and a child’s loss of depen-dent status (and therefore coverage) under the plan.

25 The maximum period of time for which continuation coverage must be made available depends on the type of qualifying event. 

26 For further details, see http://www.dol.gov/ebsa/faqs/faq_consumer_hipaa.html.

Page 35: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

29 

In recent years, discussions have focused on the fact that a considerable fraction of

the US population have no health-insurance cover at all (in 2009, this was true for some

50.7 million people, or 16.7 percent of the population; see U.S. Census Bureau 2010).

Following several political initiatives and heated political debates, new reforms under the

Affordable Care Act were passed in early 2010.27 This new legislation aims at a phased

introduction of mandated health insurance over a period of four years, intending to fix all

major gaps in the earlier continuation-of-coverage laws and, eventually, to push health

insurance towards universal coverage. To accomplish this, a number of changes address-

ing coverage and portability issues have already become effective over the year of 2010.

An important element of these changes is that small businesses are now eligible for tax

credits (worth up to 35 percent of employers’ contributions, 25 percent in the case of

small non-profit organizations) to help them provide health insurance to their workers.

Also, for individuals who have been uninsured for at least six months because of a pre-

existing condition, new coverage options are provided either through a temporary high-

risk pool inaugurated at the federal level or through parallel plans which have to be estab-

lished at the level of single states. Another federal program provides financial support for

employment-based plans to continue coverage for early retirees (i.e., individuals who

retire between age 55 and age 65), as well as their spouses and dependents.

Most of these provisions that have already been set into force effectively serve as a

bridge to 2014, when tax credits for qualified small businesses providing health insurance

to their workers will be increased (to up to 50 percent of employers’ contributions, up to

35 percent for small non-profit organizations) and when all discrimination against pre-

existing conditions through insurers will be banned. The non-discrimination law that is

going to take effect in 2014 does not only prohibit insurance companies from refusing to

sell or renew policies because of an individual’s pre-existing conditions, it also eliminates

their ability to charge higher rates due to health status – as well as gender – in the indi-

vidual and small group market. Starting from 2014, small businesses and individuals who

are not offered insurance through their employers, or who cannot afford the coverage

provided there, shall be referred to new marketplaces called Health Insurance Exchanges

where they should ideally be able to purchase affordable health insurance from a choice

of qualified health plans meeting certain benefit and cost standards. Last but not least,

from 2014 onwards all individuals are basically mandated to have health insurance.28

                                                            27 The health care reform law was enacted in two parts: the Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act

was singled into law on 23 March 2010 and was amended by the Health Care and Education Reconcili-ation Act on 30 March 2010. The name “Affordable Care Act” is used to refer to the final amended ver-sion of the law.

28 This new rule may not be applicable to illegal immigrants who are accounted for in the Census Bureau’s estimates cited above. Together with the other elements of reform, it is expected to expand coverage by

Page 36: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

30 

All in all, the new legislation will channel considerable amounts of public revenues

into programs assisting individuals in finding and continuing health insurance and sup-

porting their employers in paying for that. Besides, insurance companies are made subject

to strict, new regulation that is also meant to promote access to, and portability of, health-

insurance coverage for all individuals. At the same time, the new rules deliberately limit

options of insurers for designing and calculating the contracts they are offering, which

will most likely have repercussions on their business models and on the future structure

and dynamics of their market. Specifically, whether the market segment for Health Insur-

ance Exchanges will actually become sufficiently competitive and transparent under the

new regulatory framework, is thus an open question.

b) Germany

In Germany, public health insurance clearly constitutes the dominant form of health-cost

coverage, extending to about 90 percent of the population based on mandatory member-

ship rules and additional options to participate on a voluntary basis. Nevertheless, there is

also a minority of individuals who opt out of the public health-insurance scheme and seek

private cover for their full health costs instead (for descriptions of the institutional back-

ground, see Henke et al. 2010 or Werding 2007, pp. 103–6).29 This is possible because

their income exceeds a relevant threshold; it is basically attractive if risk-rated premiums

in private insurance are lower than income-related contributions in the public system, and

if additional coverage for dependents provided free of charge in the latter system does not

reverse this balance. While this way of defining the borderline between private and public

health insurance is hardly defendable on normative grounds, the specific type of contracts

made in the private sector in this country are rather interesting, especially with respect to

the issue of portability.

German private health insurance in its substitutional form is peculiar in that it offers

life-long cover for health costs rated at the risk status at the time of entry. Once a contract

has been made, the insurer is not allowed to terminate it – for reasons other than outstand-

ing premiums or fraud on the insured individuals’ side, that is. Nor is the insurer allowed

to re-assess premiums according to individual experience rating. However, adjusting

premiums across the board due to unanticipated increases in average health costs is per-

mitted. This implies that the insurance fully takes away the risk of any (further) deteriora-

tion in individual risk status, and that it is meant to fully smooth premiums over the life

                                                                                                                                                                                 more than 30 million individuals who are currently uninsured. Nevertheless, the rule is particularly con-troversial, even after the health care reform has been enacted, as opponents consider it unconstitutional.

29 Besides, there is also a market for supplementary private health insurance in Germany which can be bought voluntarily to top up benefits provided by the public health insurance scheme. By the way these contracts are designed, they are unlikely to create considerable portability problems.

Page 37: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

31 

cycle of a given individual.30 The cost of this remarkable arrangement which is backed by

strict regulation of both contracts and premiums is that, at least traditionally, insured in-

dividuals soon found themselves locked in with their current providers, as capital reserves

(termed “aging provisions”) that are very important in these types of contracts were not

portable across insurers. Switching to another insurer then meant undergoing a new risk-

rating and starting to accumulate fresh reserves with a shorter period of life where health

costs were still expected to be low, which was not at all attractive after only a few years

of insurance with an earlier provider.

The absence of portability of aging provisions has been modified through recent

changes in regulation. However, determining a portable amount of provisions for these

types of private health-insurance contracts with strong prefunding is more difficult than it

may seem. An important reason why provisions were not portable in the past was that this

helped avoiding risk segmentation within a given cohort of insured individuals. If those

who still were low risks after a certain duration of their contract could have extracted the

excess amount of their earlier premiums over their actual health costs and switch to

another insurer, this could have harmed others who had become high risks in the mean-

time. Even a portable amount of aging provisions based on the excess amount of pre-

miums over average health costs could have had the same effect. Premiums for those

turning high risks at some point in time had been calculated on the assumption that some,

but not all, of the insured members of a given age would suffer deteriorations in their

health status over time. But if low risks would leave then, attracted by low rates reflecting

their lower, state-contingent expected health costs, old contracts were in danger of losing

solvency for paying for the high risks that are left behind. In addition, high risks would be

unable to find a new insurer offering health cost cover at their current, or even lower,

rates even if aging provisions for average risks were made portable.

An ideal solution for maintaining protection against risk segmentation in existing

contracts and, at the same time, allowing for more competition between providers of pri-

vate health insurance, requires that risk-adjusted amounts of aging provisions are made

portable (see Meier 2005; or Baumann et al. 2008). Under such a scheme, low risks

would only be able to take away lower-than-average provisions to other insurers, while

high risks could take away higher-than-average ones. Effectively, any deterioration in

individual risk status in on-going contracts of this type would be reflected by a re-allo-

                                                            30 In the UK, next-to-universal, tax-financed coverage in the National Health Service can also be substi-

tuted for through private full-cost insurance. However, in contrast to the case of Germany, insurance contracts are basically made on an annual basis, with risk-rating applying to any renewal. Therefore, portability is not an issue in this system, but individuals may drop out of private insurance when they get older or when their risk status deteriorates. See Besley et al. (1999) or Propper (2000) for descrip-tions of the basic institutional set-up (and analyses of individual choices within this framework).

Page 38: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

32 

cation of parts of the aging provisions that are meant to prefund for the long-term health-

status risk – from those who continue to be low risks to those who become high risks.

While this need not become visible for those who stay with their current contracts, it has

to be made apparent for all those who want to leave.

Actual changes in regulation which have become effective in Germany in 2009 for

new contracts differ from the model just sketched. According to the new rules, aging pro-

visions for average risks in a standardized contract with relatively low cover are now

portable across insurers. While the resulting amounts of portable provisions are possibly

high enough for low risks to find more attractive offers elsewhere, they are clearly too

low for high risks who want to switch to another insurer. Therefore, the new rules may

give rise to precisely that type of risk segmentation which the old no-portability rules

were meant to exclude. However, whether this problem will actually materialize over

time remains to be seen.

c) Slovenia

In 1991, Slovenia as a new transition country faced the challenge of establishing an effec-

tive, partially privatized health-care system and defining a financially sound scheme for

funding this (see Albreht and Klazinga 2009). The solution found with respect to the lat-

ter aspect in new legislation which became effective in 1992 is a near-universal social

insurance scheme with income-related contributions corresponding to continental Euro-

pean standards, requiring a substantial amount of co-payments from insured individuals

for the benefits they receive (see also Tajnikar and Došenovič Bonča 2009). From the

very beginning, this was accompanied by the emergence of voluntary, supplementary

insurance covering these co-payments as a complementary pillar of health-care funding

in Slovenia.31 Participation in the second pillar was heavily promoted by the Slovenian

government, so that supplementary insurance with full coverage of co-payments is now

also next to universal in this country.

Over time, however, the structure of the relevant market and its regulatory frame-

work has changed considerably. Initially, voluntary supplementary insurance was also

provided by the public health insurance scheme, the latter operating as a not-for profit

insurer in this area, with just one smaller private, for-profit competitor. In 1998, the

branch offering supplementary coverage was singled out from the public scheme and

privatized in the legal form of a mutual insurance. By its size, it is still clearly the proto-

typical large incumbent, with two smaller joint-stock companies competing in the same                                                             31 In this respect, supplementary health insurance in Slovenia is similar to that in France (see, e.g., Buch-

mueller and Couffinhal 2004). There, private health insurance also mainly offers reimbursements for co-payments required in the public schemes, not coverage for special types, or higher qualities, of treatment not covered by public insurance as the main alternative.

Page 39: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

33 

market. Since the extent of coverage of supplementary health insurance is strongly de-

termined by the features of compulsory, public insurance and, hence, is subject to a great

deal of political risk,32 private insurance of this kind is typically unfunded. Nevertheless,

following another reform enacted in 2000, Slovenian private health insurance companies

started to accumulate reserves for a number of years.

At that time, insurers collected premiums that were differentiated to some extent by

gender, age (at entry) and risk status, as is conventional in such contracts. Because insur-

ers were not required to transfer funds accumulated for individuals who were willing to

switch from one insurer to another, competition for new members was distorted. Howev-

er, financial losses arising from a change in supplementary health insurance were smaller

than those arising from a change in insurance for full health costs, so that mobility was

not prohibitively costly for customers. Providers of supplementary health insurance and

their regulators would have likely had to consider this issue more closely, if pre-funding

had been a standard for a longer period of time – and not merely a by-product of a favor-

able financial situation of this sector which lasted only temporarily.

In 2003, growing deficits in the public scheme and considerable profits created in

private health insurance made politicians consider merging the two pillars, i.e., abolishing

the latter and integrating it into the former, but final decisions regarding this proposal

were postponed. In the following years, the large mutual insurance fund providing sup-

plementary insurance started to incur losses, in spite of its potential for benefiting from

huge economies of scale vis-à-vis the two smaller companies. This appeared to be mainly

the result of a less favorable age structure of its members.33 Therefore, the government

decided to introduce a risk-equalization scheme between all providers which took effect

in 2006 (see Tajnikar and Došenovič Bonča 2009, pp. 284–92, for further details and a

discussion of a few shortcomings of this scheme). Furthermore, because such a scheme is

at odds with pre-funding based on actuarial principles, funding was terminated and accu-

mulated reserves were disbursed to individual members.34 Since then, supplementary

private health insurance in Slovenia is actually operated on a pay-as-you-go basis, just

like the public scheme, though with voluntary membership and individual contributions

which are determined in a different way.

                                                            32 In fact, in the presence of supplementary private cover, redefining the benefit package covered in public

schemes can be mainly seen as an approach to shifting financial burdens involved in financing health care on to private sources. Note that, if this relates to co-payments, it is likely to undo any incentive ef-fects for the utilization of health services these policy changes could also be intended to have.

33 Besides, there are indications that this large company was less active in monitoring claims, as average claims’ costs tended to exceed those of their competitors across all age groups.

34 Individual shares in these funds were assessed based on their age at entry, length of membership and duration of the contract (for 10 years or life-long, with differing funding rules applying to these types of contracts). The risk status of an individual (or any change in this respect during membership) was neg-lected as an additional, potentially important determinant.

Page 40: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

34 

Under current rules, each insurer collects premiums that are uniform for all its mem-

bers, while premiums may vary across companies. In addition, there is a late-entry load-

ing by which individual premiums are increased (by 3 percent, to a maximum of 180 per-

cent) for each year without supplementary cover. These loadings are not imposed on in-

dividuals who are switching from one insurer to another (with less than six uninsured

months in between), which is legally possible under some restrictions.35 Therefore, indi-

viduals do not suffer any financial losses when changing their provider, while the prob-

lem of risk segmentation across insurance funds is basically taken care of through the

risk-equalization scheme.

d) Assessment

The small number of arrangements for private health insurance we have examined in this

section are clearly very diverse. Nevertheless, with respect to our main theme regarding

the portability of health-cost funding across providers, the examples effectively show a

number of common features. First of all, there appears to be a general trend towards a

lock-in of individuals in on-going private health-insurance contracts. This phenomenon

may show up only in the market for private health insurance, as it does in Germany. If

insurance is employer based, as it is in the US, this lock-in may even have a broader im-

pact on job mobility and turnover in the entire labor market. In any case, this observation

basically reflects a wide-spread lack of portability.

Another observation is that, where reduced mobility is perceived to be a problem – in

the insurance markets and even more so in labor markets – establishing something that

could be called “full portability” across different providers of private health insurance

does not seem to be very easy. To mitigate or circumvent this problem, legislators do not

only establish or adjust corresponding regulation in a way they think appropriate. In addi-

tion, they are using financial instruments such as public subsidies, or they add risk-

equalization schemes and effectively convert funded schemes into pay-as-you-go

schemes. This tendency is most visible in Slovenia, but it also plays a role in the US, tak-

ing the form of expensive tax credits for some groups of potential plan sponsors, and in

Germany, where a sophisticated approach to pre-funding private health-insurance con-

tracts has been diluted in recent attempts to provide for portability across insurers. In the

new German framework, however, it is at least acknowledged that the portability of

health insurance has financial consequences which can be, and probably should be, ad-

dressed directly through payments between health funds.

                                                            35 Mainly, individuals have to stay with an insurer for at least one year, and they have to observe a notice

period of three months.

Page 41: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

35 

The main lessons from these observations for a discussion of international portability

in health-care benefits and health-cost cover are then as follows. First, from an actuarial

perspective, switching from one health scheme to another is probably not as easy as the

current framework for international migrants in public health insurance suggests. Second,

one ought to be careful about the design of mechanisms addressing this issue, as inappro-

priate solutions can either affect the financial situation of health funds, eventually leading

to risk segmentation and jeopardizing their solvency, or may indeed have negative reper-

cussions on mobility. Third, the potential impact of portability rules on the structure and

performance of insurance markets is particularly interesting, since international mobility

may effectively introduce competitive pressure in domains that have been deliberately

exempted from competition at a national level, for instance, through the introduction of

public health care and public health-insurance schemes.

4 A conceptual framework for the portability of health-care benefits

Thus far, we have reviewed different types of materials that are important, or at least in-

teresting, with respect to designing a conceptual framework for making health-cost cover

portable across countries. Now, we want to address this question directly, discussing how

international mobility of individuals who settle, at least temporarily, in another country

typically affects the systems funding for their health costs. In this respect, the most im-

portant distinction is not between public and private systems but between unfunded and

(partially) pre-funded systems. In reality, most public schemes are indeed unfunded,

while private health insurance has to be funded if it does not just cover expected current

health costs – unless public regulation imposes another business model on the providers.

Thus, the two distinctions have large overlaps, but they are not identical. Here, we will

deal with the two relevant types of systems in turn, first developing a conceptual frame-

work for designing appropriate portability rules for unfunded schemes covering health

costs (see Section 4.1), then investigating the role of accumulated financial reserves for

the appropriate design of such rules (see Section 4.2).

4.1 Portability in unfunded systems of health-cost cover

In unfunded schemes, all transactions between insured individuals and health funds that

occurred in earlier periods – governed by the various elements of insurance and redistri-

bution described in Section 2.2 – are past history. We highlighted earlier that unfunded

health systems are implicitly offering long-term relationships in which the balance of

payments made and services received by average members systematically shifts around

over time. Yet, whenever an individual considers becoming mobile, there is nothing left

Page 42: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

36 

of premiums or contributions made until then to fund for future health costs of the indi-

vidual. Therefore, the consequences of mobility for unfunded systems of health-cost cov-

er – in sending as well as in receiving countries – need to be determined in a forward-

looking perspective: what matters are the future contributions and future benefit entitle-

ments of the individual and all dependents, as far as they are covered together with the

individual under consideration.

From the perspective of sending countries, future contributions are revenues fore-

gone, and future benefit entitlements are (implicit) liabilities that are going to be wiped

out if the individual moves away. In receiving countries, new liabilities are created and

additional revenues are going to accrue if the individual is admitted to enter an unfunded

health system there. Meaningful portability rules for health-cost cover from unfunded

systems should take all these consequences into account, while existing legal arrange-

ments either neglect them (for migrant workers) or make them a reason why other indi-

viduals (e.g., pensioners) are only admitted to the receiving countries’ health systems if

they have acquired at least some amount of pension entitlements in this country.

a) Expected health costs: determinants

To fully spell out the implications of (international) mobility for unfunded schemes cov-

ering health costs, let us consider a formal model which captures all relevant characteris-

tics of the individuals covered and all relevant features of existing health systems (see

Holzmann and Koettl 2011, Sections 3 and 5, for a similar model addressing portability

in social insurance in a broader fashion, with some applications to health care). The start-

ing point for our considerations are life-time profiles of expected health costs of a given

individual arising within a given health system, as those shown in Section 2.1. Technical-

ly speaking, these profiles are vectors, or lists, of annual health costs, jgaAHC , , for indi-

viduals of gender },{ mfg (females and males) in risk class },{ hlj (low or high)

and at age }1,0{ a ( being the age at which the survival probability is set to zero

in current life tables). For simplicity, we restrict attention to two risk classes, viz. low

risks who are basically healthy and (average) high risks whose health costs are perma-

nently increased, as in Figures 2 and 4 above.

In the following, we will effectively concentrate on annual health costs arising from

a particular age onwards at which an individual is considering to migrate to another coun-

try or to another health system, respectively. To do so, we have to consider a number of

potential changes affecting expected future health costs for this individual both over the

individual’s remaining life span and over time. First of all, we need to take into account

the probability that the individual will survive until age 1a , jga

, (with 10 , jga for

a ), and subsequently to any higher age (with 0, jg ). We assume, with some

Page 43: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

37 

sense of realism, that survival probabilities are differentiated not only by age, but also by

gender and risk status (with hga

lga

,, ). For those who are currently low risks, we also

need to take into account that they may continue to be low risks at age 1a with proba-

bility a (in the range 10 a ), or that they may experience a deterioration in their

health status with probability a1 . The way we define high risks, namely as individuals

who have developed conditions leading to a permanent increase in expected future health

costs, we do not allow for a change in health status in the opposite direction. For conven-

ience, we assume that the probability of a change in health status may vary with age but

does not significantly vary by gender.

In addition to these life-cycle changes in relevant characteristics of the individual,

there are also changes which may affect the individual’s future health costs as time passes

by. If the series of annual health costs is taken from a cross section, relating to individuals

at different ages in a particular year, we need to consider future increases in age-specific

annual health costs through an annual health-cost inflation factor, c1 , which may differ

from general price inflation and is simply assumed to be constant here. Also, to make

annual health costs measured as a longitudinal profile for a given individual comparable

across time, assessing them in terms of present values for the current year, we need an

annual discount factor, r1 , which is again assumed to be constant.36

b) Expected health costs: differentiation by risk status

Building on these ingredients, we can calculate expected future health costs, jgaEHC , ,

for individuals of gender g in risk class j and at age a. For individuals who are high risks,

expected health costs are simply given by the sum of annual health costs for a high risk

arising from age a onwards, weighted with the relevant survival probabilities, up-rated

with health-cost inflation, and discounted to form present values for the current time pe-

riod (with }1,0{ t being a time index that is equal to zero for the current year).

a

t

ta

ax

hgta

hgxt

thg

a AHCr

cEHC

1

1,,,

)1(

)1( (1)

This way of expressing expected life-time health costs for high risks is certainly very

transparent. Alternatively, we can also use a recursive formula which simply adds the

present value of annual health costs for a high risk expected for the next year of life, ap-

propriately weighted and up-rated, to expected future health costs of a high risk assessed

from the perspective of this next year. This alternative version of writing expected future

health costs for high risks reads

                                                            36 In theory, meaningful restrictions applying to both factors only imply that c > –1 and r > –1, while we

can safely assume c and r to be larger than zero, certainly in terms of long-term averages, in reality.

Page 44: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

38 

hga

hga

hga

hga EHCAHC

r

cEHC ,

1,1

,,

1

1

. (1')

A recursive formula of this type is actually needed to express expected future health costs

for individuals who are currently low risks, as they may become high risks with some

probability at any point in time in the future. Expected life-time health costs for low risks

are thus given by

hga

hgaa

lga

lgaa

lga

lga EHCAHCEHCAHC

r

cEHC ,

1,1

,1

,1

,, )1(1

1

, (2)

a generic formula for expected future health costs for individuals in any risk status being

hga

hgaa

jga

jgaa

jga

jga EHCAHCEHCAHC

r

cEHC ,

1,1

,1

,1

,, )1(1

1

. (3)

If the first term in square brackets in equation (3) is set to its high-risk value )( hj , the

probability of a change in risk status for low risks )( a cancels out from this formula, and

the equation simplifies to (1').

c) Non-contributory cover for dependents

Depending on relevant rules applied in the system of health-cost cover applying to the

individual we are looking at, we may also have to take into account health costs for a

partner and the children of this individual if they have non-contributory cover from the

same system.37 If an individual has dependents with non-contributory cover, we can re-

interpret equation (3) as a formula for assessing expected future health costs for this indi-

vidual i, with gender gi, risk status ji and age ai, the relevant intermediate result being jigi

aiEHC , . To obtain total expected future health costs linked to the coverage of health

costs for this individual, we then have to add health costs for a partner p and for each of

the N children (numbered },1{ Nn ) who are eligible for additional cover. The rele-

vant amount of expected future health costs is then given by

N

n

jngnanan

jpgpap

jigiai

jga EHCkpEHCEHCEHC

1

,,,, , (4)

where }1,0{p and }1,0{ank are eligibility counters applying to partners and child-

ren, respectively. In equation (4), expected future health costs for eligible partners, jpgp

apEHC , , are calculated as in equation (3), taking into account the partner’s gender, risk

status and age. When calculating expected future health costs for each eligible child, jngn

anEHC , , the formula stated in equation (3) must be applied to the periods until an

                                                            37 Otherwise, we should treat them in isolation, i.e., as separate individuals who are considering to migrate

elsewhere, applying the same logic as for the single individual we have looked at thus far.

Page 45: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

39 

(not an ), being the last year of age in which children can be expected to be eligible

for non-contributory cover through (one of) their parents.

d) Long-term sustainability of financing health care

Last but not least, when assessing the amount of expected future health costs arising for a

given individual within a given system of health-cost cover, we also have to address the

fact that this system may not be “sustainable” in its current form over the time horizon of

our calculations or, eventually, in terms of the intertemporal government budget con-

straint.38 In other words, based on the equations we have derived here thus far, we may

account for future health costs that may not arise at all for those who continue to have

cover from the system, for instance, because health-cost inflation c is too high, exceeding

expected price and wage inflation, or because the age composition of the insured popula-

tion is expected to deteriorate.39 The easiest way to deal with this complication is to apply

a uniform sustainability factor s1 (with 10 s ) to expenditure accruing in each year

in the future. Adjusting our earlier calculations, we then obtain sustainable future health

costs, jgaSHC , , which are given by

jga

jga EHCsSHC ,, )1( . (5)

e) Expected revenues for financing health care

Future health costs essentially turn into future expenditure saved if an individual is ac-

tually leaving an unfunded system of health-cost cover. Besides, expected financial con-

tributions to this system which the individual could have made in the future are of course

no less important. The way in which unfunded systems of health care or health insurance

are financed can be different. Around the world, ear-marked contributions specifically

collected for health funds, injections from the general-government budget that are mainly

tax-financed, or some mixture between these two approaches play a dominant role in this

area. Without a loss in generality, we may take annual “tax” revenues, )( , jgaa yT , that are

raised from each individual and are effectively channeled into the health system as the

basis for assessing expected financial contributions that turn into future revenues fore-

gone if an individual is leaving the system. The way we model them, these revenues are

derived from a generic tax function aT which may differ by the tax payer’s age and is

                                                            38 See Blanchard (1990) for a conceptual clarification of what “sustainability” means from a public-

finance point of view. In EU Economic Policy Committee (2001; 2003) it is explained and discussed how this notion is nowadays used to monitor public finances in a long-term perspective in EU countries (and, occasionally, also in other developed countries, see Hauner et al. 2007) for practical purposes.

39 In both cases, future health expenditure could not be financed using a constant share in GDP of the respective country, i.e., from constant contribution rates or a constant fraction in tax revenues in an oth-erwise unchanged environment.

Page 46: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

40 

applied to a tax base igay , which is assumed to consist of wages and pensions mainly, but

may comprise other income, consumption, or any combinations of these components as

well. In any case, the tax base may vary by gender, health status and age due to the rules

applied as well as the ability to pay taxes.

Building on a time series of annual tax payments conditioned on the relevant charac-

teristics of a given individual, we can then determine the present value of expected future

tax revenues that this individual would have to pay under current rules for the system we

are looking at. In its most generic form, the relevant formula reads

hga

hgaaa

jga

jgaaa

jga

jga ETyTETyT

r

wET ,

1,11

,1

,11

,, )()1()(1

1

. (6)

Here, the assessment of future tax revenues follows a similar logic as the assessment of

expected future health costs, see equation (3), with a recursive structure to allow for

changes in risk status at any point in time in the future. The factor w1 (with 1w )

reflects wage inflation or any increase in the average, individual-level tax base occurring.

For simplicity, we assume that the tax function is adjusted to wage inflation in such a way

that tax progression is neutralized with respect to the growth in average wages. That is,

within a given period of time the tax function aT may well exhibit progression with re-

spect to the tax base igay , , while it behaves as if it were linear in an intertemporal perspec-

tive. The function is also assumed to be stable otherwise, as we neglect potential future

increases in contribution rates, tax rates etc., making adjustments regarding the future

sustainability of the system on the expenditure side; see equation (5). If cover for depen-

dents affecting future health costs is non-contributory – as is assumed in equation (4) –

equation (6) is indeed the final version of expected future revenues linked to membership

of an individual in a given system of health-cost cover.40

f) Expected net costs of migrants

We are thus approaching the final result of our calculations regarding the financial conse-

quences of the possibility that an individual may leave an unfunded system covering

health costs, for the individual as well as for any dependents, and may then enter another

system of the same type located elsewhere. This result is given by expected future net

costs (or surpluses, as it may be) related to the membership of this individual in an un-

funded system of health-cost cover,

jga

jga

jga ETSHCENC ,,, . (7)

                                                            40 Otherwise, health costs and revenues relating to partners and children should be assessed in separate

calculations (see footnote 37).

Page 47: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

41 

Note that the ENCs calculated for a given individual (and all dependents with non-con-

tributory cover) can be larger than, equal to, or smaller than zero. They are determined by

individual characteristics of those who consider migrating as well as by features of the

health systems which would be affected. For the potential sending country A, jgAaENC ,

,

measures the net costs saved, or the surplus foregone, if a particular individual actually

leaves the national health system – compared to a situation where it has continued, and

eventually life-long, cover. For a receiving country B, jgBaENC ,

, measures net costs in-

curred, or the surplus accruing, if the individual is admitted to the health system, hence to

the national risk pool, for life-long cover in this country.

The result of our calculations regarding the financial consequences of mobility be-

tween unfunded systems of health-cost cover therefore implies the following. When let-

ting go a migrant, health funds in the sending country may effectively wish to claim jg

AaENC ,, if 0,

, jgAaENC ; they may be willing to pay up to jg

AaENC ,, if 0,

, jgAaENC . Con-

versely, when accepting a migrant, health funds in the receiving country may be willing

to pay (in brackets: they may wish to claim) jgBaENC ,

, if 0,, jgBaENC )0( ,

, jgBaENC .

Ideally, to make unfunded health-cost cover portable the two health funds involved could

thus compensate each other for any net costs avoided or net costs incurred, based on the

net-present-value positions of both health systems, if the individual becomes mobile

across the two countries instead of staying in the sending country.

The same logic can also be applied to temporary moves, provided they last long

enough that accounting for the consequences for the health funds involved appears to be

worthwhile. If this is the case, transferring the provision of insurance for health costs (in-

cluding the elements of redistribution that may be attached to it, following the rules of the

receiving countries’ system of health-cost cover) may make sense. If the temporary move

of an individual, plus any dependents, lasts for d years, health funds in the sending coun-

try may wish to claim (or pay) jgAda

jgAa ENCENC ,

,,, if this difference is negative (respec-

tively positive). That is, expected net costs accruing in the more remote future, after the

individual will have returned, need to be deducted from the result applying to a case

where mobility is open-ended or expected to last indefinitely. Conversely, health funds in

the receiving country may be willing to pay (or claim) jgBda

jgBa ENCENC ,

,,, if this differ-

ence is negative (respectively positive). Real-world scenarios of international migration

can of course be substantially more complicated, involving various sources of uncertain-

ty, unexpected changes in earlier plans, and consecutive moves in different directions.

But in any case, the formula for calculating the consequences of mobility for unfunded

national health systems that we have derived here can be easily applied pro rata temporis,

the shortest duration of an expected stay in a given country, or under the rules of a given

health system, for which this makes sense probably being one year.

Page 48: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

42 

g) How to isolate insurance from redistribution

We will discuss later on, in Section 5.2, whether the distinction between elements of in-

surance and elements of redistribution should be taken into account in designing appro-

priate portability rules (see Section 2.2 for a closer description of these components of

existing arrangements of health-cost cover). Disentangling the effects of insurance for

expected future health costs from those of redistributive elements of unfunded health sys-

tems may nevertheless be useful at this stage to see how this could be done and to prepare

for an in-depth treatment of the material issues that arise.

The design of elements of redistribution varies a lot across national systems covering

health costs. The scope of insurance which is actually involved in funded schemes also

shows some diversity, while all unfunded systems of health-cost cover next to automati-

cally provide insurance in all its basic forms distinguished above: cover for current health

costs (by which individual contributions would have to correspond to expected annual

health costs in the current year), insurance against any deterioration of one’s health status

(by which contributions would have to follow the time profile of expected average health

costs over the remaining life cycle), and some amount of intertemporal burden smoothing

(to obtain a flatter time profile of contributions over the life cycle than the one just de-

scribed). Redistribution then leads to further modifications of the total amount as well as

the life-cycle profile of contributions due, while national health systems typically give

each individual access to benefits which are fully captured by expected (sustainable) fu-

ture health costs as assessed above.

Probably the easiest way of determining contributions that cover all elements of in-

surance, but no redistribution, in an unfunded system of health-cost cover is to calculate

the per-capita amount of total annual health costs for each individual who is covered by

the system and for each year that membership can be expected to last (weighted with the

relevant survival probabilities, that is).41 Fictitious annual lump-sum premiums which are

obtained in this way cover a fair share in annual health costs and do not reflect the extra-

costs arising from changes in health status. They may also vary a bit over time, depending

on long-term trends in total health expenditure for the insured population, but they should

take away the strong, age-related trend in expected health costs observed at the individual

level. At the same time, they do not reflect the effects of redistribution by income in-

volved in actual contributions, and they attribute a price to all kinds of non-contributory

                                                            41 As in the calculations described in Sub-section c, cover for dependent children should of course be

restricted to the (maximum) period in which they can be eligible. Also, one could calculate a separate amount of per-capita costs for this group because these costs tend to be considerably lower than for an average adult (see, e.g., Figures 1 and 3) and, more importantly, because it is often unclear whether they will remain under the coverage of the current system when they start making their own decisions (to participate in the labor force, to move abroad, etc.)

Page 49: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

43 

cover. Yet, one could be more careful in neutralizing the intergenerational redistribution

that is typically involved in unfunded systems of health-cost cover.42

If expected future health costs of an individual remain unchanged, while revenues

collected from the individual are adjusted to undo the effects of redistribution, expected

future net costs will change accordingly. They will become higher (and, apart from ex-

ceptional cases, may no longer be negative) for those who must be expected to pay for the

redistributive elements of a given health system as the contributions of these individuals

are fictitiously reduced in these calculations. Conversely, expected net costs will become

lower for those at the receiving end of redistribution because their contributions are ficti-

tiously increased. The differences between expected net health costs by age, gender and

risk status will thus become smaller than when redistribution were included in the calcu-

lations, but they need not disappear. Specifically, variation of expected net health costs

by age is still likely to be substantial. The reason is that annual health costs tend to in-

crease at higher ages, while contributions – those actually paid as well as those imputed

here – are likely to be considerably lower at later stages of the life cycle. Yet, the same

individuals will typically have paid contributions exceeding their annual health costs at

younger ages. Their positive (and high) expected net health costs at old age are thus the

result of an implicit element of pre-saving which is inherent in any kind of intertemporal

burden smoothing.

One might thus wonder why we stick to our forward-looking perspective in assessing

the consequences for national systems of health-cost cover here if individuals consider

emigrating or immigrating, respectively. Instead, we might try to account for the amount

of pre-saving directly, based on past contributions and past health costs, with some ad-

justments for the effects of redistribution that may have taken place. But this would not

be appropriate, due to the element of insurance against changes in health status – at least,

if health costs differ substantially between those at low risk and those at high risk. To

provide insurance for health-status risks, irrespective of when a change in health status

occurs, funds that are fictitiously attributed to an individual need to cover future health

costs in an appropriate differentiation – an aspect which cannot be dealt with based on

figures observed in the past. (We will further elaborate on this point immediately, when

we turn to discussing systems that are actually funded; see Section 4.2.)

                                                            42 Accounting for average health costs of those actually insured in each year limits the intergenerational

redistribution to some kind of burden sharing, or mutual insurance, among all those whose life cycles overlap. More careful approaches would have to make sure that, on present value terms, life-time con-tributions of each individual are equal to life-time health costs arising for an individual at average health risk. In other words, one would have to approach the way in which only a narrow sub-set of funded health insurance schemes is actually calculated (see Section 4.2). Here, we content ourselves with ap-plying a less precise yardstick to determining the effects of unfunded insurance without redistribution.

Page 50: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

44 

Otherwise, the implications of our adjusted calculations look much the same as those

in the previous sub-section. When the effects of redistribution are neutralized, differences

in expected future net costs across different types of individuals are smaller, and net

health costs themselves are most likely positive in each case. Still, if individuals consider

migrating from one country to another, adjusted net health costs can be taken to indicate a

potential willingness to pay on the side of the national health scheme in the sending coun-

try. At the same time, net health costs assessed there reflect potential claims of the health

scheme in the receiving country. Again, the same logic can be applied to temporary mi-

grants if the provision of health insurance shall be transferred for a limited number of

years and if calculations regarding future net health costs are therefore restricted to this

period.

4.2 Portability in (partially) pre-funded systems

Instead of being operated on a pure pay-as-you-go basis, systems covering health costs

can indeed accumulate financial reserves. This is useful, in particular, to offer insurance

against changes in health status that materialize over time, to engage in intertemporal

burden smoothing, or to avoid or limit intergenerational redistribution (see, again, Sec-

tion 2.2). In schemes that are at least partially pre-funded, (international) mobility of in-

dividuals does not only appear to have an impact on the balance of expected future costs

and revenues, but also on the use of funds which have been accumulated in the past. If the

total stock of reserves remains unchanged, individuals leaving such a scheme increase the

amount of funds that are available on a per-capita basis, while individuals entering the

scheme reduce it. Therefore, the question arises whether the existence of financial re-

serves should not also play a role for designing appropriate portability rules.

For instance, when an individual considers leaving a pre-funded scheme, some share

in existing funds could be attributed to the individual and should probably be paid out,

rather than creating a windfall gain for all other individuals who remain in the scheme.

Likewise, in terms of premiums or benefit entitlements an individual who considers en-

tering such a scheme is likely to be treated very differently from individuals of the same

age and health status who have contributed to the current stock of reserves in the past.

But things could be different if new entrants were able to carry with them a portable

amount of reserves that they have built up elsewhere.

At closer inspection, however, expected future net costs and any amount of reserves

that may currently exist are strongly linked to each other. This implies that determining

the financial consequences of mobility of individuals across systems of health-cost cover

need not be fundamentally different, depending on whether these systems are funded or

Page 51: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

45 

not. This can best be seen for schemes that are indeed fully-funded. But, with some adap-

tations to such a mixed regime, it is also true for partially-funded schemes.

a) Fully-funded schemes

As a matter of fact, in fully-funded systems expected future net costs of each individual

should exactly correspond to the share in funds accumulated in these systems that can be

attributed to the same individual. In other words, expected net costs (ENC) as assessed in

the above sense (see Section 4.1) for an individual of given gender, risk status and age are

usually positive, indicating a willingness to pay for net costs avoided whenever the indi-

vidual considers leaving the system. The maximum payment that the system would be

willing to offer is equal to the amount of reserves which have been accumulated to (fully)

pre-fund for these expected net costs. Conversely, by the terms of a contract for an indi-

vidual entering a fully-funded scheme of health-cost cover, expected net costs of the new

member arising in this scheme should be zero – unless the individual is bringing some

amount of (portable) reserves. In this latter case, however, the scheme that is to be en-

tered would be willing to accept a corresponding amount of ENC.

Fully-funded systems of health-cost cover are typically based on actuarial calcula-

tions by which these links between accumulated funds and future net costs can be easily

verified. Preserving most of the notation introduced in the previous section, we should

note that fully-funded health-insurance contracts are essentially based on the condition

that expected net costs are zero at the age e when an individual first enters the system.

Being careful about the precise timing underlying our model, this implies that

1

1

1

1

)(,1

,,1

,1,

1 )1(

11 e

t

te

ex

ejgte

jgxjg

et

jgejg

e

Pr

EHC

, (8)

i.e., that future health costs and future revenues expected at this time must off-set each

other. Here, our modeling of the revenue side is meant to reflect that payments made by

the individuals covered in a fully-funded health insurance are premiums, P, rather than

income-related contributions or taxes. Note that we allow for premiums that are differen-

tiated by gender and risk status at the year of entry and may also vary with age – but not

with current risk status, as pre-funding would not be needed then.43

If, at a higher age a, an individual who has been in an average risk status of the rele-

vant age cohort, )(ej , to date considers leaving the scheme, equation (8) can be re-

written and re-arranged to form                                                             43 Correcting for the contingent survival probability jg

e,1 on both sides of the equation is needed because

we have to assume the individual to be alive at age e. Only, by our forward-looking definition of the EHCs, we effectively discount all figures entering the equation to the period when the individual was aged 1e , without any further implications.

Page 52: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

46 

a

et

ejgt

ejgt

a

txejg

x

xa

t

ejgta

ta

ax

ejgxt

ejga AHCP

rP

rEHC )(,)(,

1

)(,1

)(,1

)(,)(, 1

)1(

1

. (9)

Basically, the left-hand side of equation (9) represents expected future net costs from age

a + 1 onwards, that is, jgaENC , in a fully-funded health-insurance scheme built on actuar-

ial principles, while the right-hand side of equation (9) reflects the accumulation of finan-

cial reserves for an average individual until age a which takes place within such a

scheme. Apart from a change in the reference period and a few up-dates regarding expec-

tations which have materialized over time, the equality stated here should still be imme-

diate from condition (8).

Although equation (9) is kept as simple as it could be, the accumulation of funds de-

scribed here may require a few words of explanation. (For much more detailed calcula-

tions on essentially the same issue, see Baumann et al. 2008.) Note, first of all, that past

values of average health costs and premiums (as well as past interest rates) are no longer

subject to any uncertainties, so that we can now use actual figures. Given that, accumu-

lated funds mainly derive from an excess of insurance premiums tP over annual average

health costs tAHC incurred in the past – assuming that the time profile of premiums is

frontloaded compared to the health-cost profile to pre-fund for potential changes in risk

status and to smooth the financial burden of premiums over time. Multiplying these an-

nual differences by the interest factor(s) tr1 and summing them up until age a on

present-value terms also reflects (compound) interest earned on existing reserves. In addi-

tion, mortality observed for individuals of the same age cohort between ages e and a im-

plies that the reserves built up from premiums paid by those who died in the meantime

have been “bequeathed” to those who survived, which leads to the weighting by 1t .

Regarding the financial consequences of mobility of individual members for fully-

funded schemes of health-cost cover, excepted future net costs and accumulated funds are

thus essentially two sides of the same coin. In other words, they are just two different

ways of assessing payments that are needed to make insurance cover fully portable across

providers or even across systems.

An important complication in determining portable amounts of funds for a given

individual in a fully-funded health-insurance scheme is hidden behind the assumption of

an individual with “average” risk status in equation (9). To actually pre-fund for expected

future net costs, portable funds should be lower than average for individuals who are still

low risks at age a, while they should be higher for individuals who are high risks. The

risk status at the age of entry is usually taken into account when calculating premiums, so

that it automatically feeds through to higher reserves for individuals who were high risks

from the very beginning. However, insurance against any deterioration in risk status that

occurs later on means that those who continue to be low risks effectively contribute to a

Page 53: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

47 

higher pre-funding also for those who have just developed a relevant condition. If total

funds accumulated in such a scheme were stored in individual accounts, part of current

premiums paid by the former group would have to be channeled, year by year, into funds

covering higher expected net costs for the latter group (see Baumann et al. 2008 for an in-

depth analysis, or Pauly et al. 1995 who implicitly stress this point in their idea of health-

insurance contracts with “guaranteed renewability”). This re-allocation of funds by

changes in risk status is invisible, or even immaterial, as long as all individuals stay in

the same scheme covering their health costs. But it needs to be made explicit when an

individual is willing to leave the scheme. Otherwise, the individual would lose an impor-

tant part of long-term insurance cover (if a high-risk individual could only take away

funds needed for an average risk), or those left behind would suffer financial losses and

their contracts might become subject to risk segmentation (if a low-risk individual could

take away average amounts of funds).

Against this background, projecting expected health costs based on the characteris-

tics of a given individual – in line with how the insurance contract is calculated in general

– may thus be a simple, more targeted alternative to assessing portable shares in existing

reserves in a backward-looking fashion. Forward-looking calculations are in fact the only

way to determine how much of the funds accumulated through earlier contributions need

to be re-allocated in the case of a change in risk status, if risk-specific differences in

health costs are substantial and if this health-status risk is subject to the insurance pro-

vided by a given system of health-cost cover. Note that in fully funded systems which do

not insure the health-status risk (and do not add an element of intertemporal burden

smoothing), portability is not much of an issue as individuals are always paying pre-

miums to cover their actual current health costs. In addition, this approach could also be

applied to fully-funded systems which, backed by compulsory membership rules and ad-

ditional regulation, effectively include some elements of redistribution (e.g., cover for

dependents at less-than-actuarial premiums).

While determining the financial consequences of mobility across health funds leads

to very similar calculations for both funded and unfunded systems, there are still a num-

ber of differences between these two types of schemes. For instance, when individuals

consider leaving a fully-funded scheme, it is more likely that their former insurer is will-

ing to make a payment – rather than wishing to claim one – than in an unfunded scheme.

The reason is that fully-funded schemes typically do not involve any elements of inter-

personal redistribution (and do not give rise to intergenerational redistribution). The rele-

vant amounts of ENCs, or the funds which can be attributed to each individual, can there-

fore be assumed to be positive in virtually all relevant cases. For the same reasons, fully-

funded schemes will usually offer less favorable conditions than in an earlier, fully-

Page 54: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

48 

funded contract when individuals consider joining them – or they have to ask for com-

pensating payments. There is also a major difference between funded and unfunded sys-

tems in terms of property rights – in an economic perspective, but potentially also in a

legal sense. Claims based on a share in accumulated funds that an individual has contri-

buted to in the past may appear to be substantially stronger than those solely based on

financial consequences of mobility expected for the future. In spite of the substantial par-

allels which we have pointed out here, this aspect might become important with respect to

designing portability rules for practical purposes. Even if the basic idea remains the same,

with two health funds involved in covering health costs for individuals who are mobile

effectively compensating each other for any net costs saved or net costs incurred, related

payments may appear to be justified much better when they can also be phrased in terms

of a transfer of existing funds.

b) Partially funded schemes

In reality, systems covering health costs are not either fully funded or entirely based on

the pay-as-you-go mechanism. There is in fact a continuum of potential solutions in be-

tween these two extremes. However, schemes that do not belong to one of these pure

types will mostly be rather close to one of them. On the one hand, systems holding rela-

tively high amounts of reserves may not be operated on a strictly actuarial basis, being

constrained in this respect by public regulation or openly acknowledging that the future is

uncertain, so that actuarial calculations based on expected life-time health-care costs of

insured individuals would have to be revised from time to time anyway.44 As a conse-

quence, compared to total costs that could be reasonably expected for the future the de-

gree of pre-funding may effectively be partial only, for instance, relating to an extended,

but still limited, time horizon. On the other hand, systems that are largely unfunded may

nevertheless hold some amount of reserves, for instance, in terms of “demographic buffer

funds”. These funds result from an increase in contribution rates beyond current cost rates

and may be scheduled to continue to grow for a while. They may then be reduced and

eventually depleted to keep contribution rates stable in a period when expected costs go

up. They are thus available as an aggregate stock of funds which can be used for shaping

                                                            44 Revisions of this kind, with re-assessments of expected health-cost profiles and premiums, actually

happen in fully-funded schemes. Nevertheless, we consider them immaterial for our calculations sketched in the previous sub-section as these calculations are meant to reflect the financial conse-quences of mobility based on all information that is currently available. If future changes could be fore-seen with sufficient certainty, they should already be included in current insurance conditions. – Note that a similar problem arises with respect to assessing the future sustainability of unfunded schemes. In this regard, too, all information that is currently available should be exploited to determine the conse-quences when insured individuals are currently deciding to become mobile. It is hardly avoidable that, later on, this assessment may turn out to be imprecise.

Page 55: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

49 

the extent of intergenerational redistribution involved in an otherwise unfunded scheme,

but they are never formally attributed to individual members’ accounts.

For any partially funded scheme of health-cost cover, condition (8) does not hold, not

even for an “average” insured individual, due to the unfunded part of expected future

health costs and the intergenerational redistribution that is automatically involved. De-

termining the share of a given individual in existing funds is nevertheless possible, simp-

ly by assessing the share in expected future health costs for all current members which

can be covered from these funds. This aggregate-level share could then be applied to ex-

pected future health costs related to a particular individual. The calculation would result

in a correspondingly higher amount of funds for those who have higher expected costs

because of an unfavorable risk status or because of elements of redistribution involved in

the respective scheme. However, following the common logic for assessing the implica-

tions of (international) mobility for both unfunded and fully-funded schemes of health-

cost cover that we have developed here, calculations of this kind are not really needed.

Instead, one should once again determine expected future net costs, i.e., costs saved or

surpluses foregone if an individual moves out or in, based on equations (1) through (7) or

based on the left-hand side of equation (9) – depending on how the scheme is operated

and on the elements of insurance and redistribution it is offering. The effects of partial

pre-funding for future net costs relating to this individual as well as the individual’s role

for accumulating reserves are then implicit in these calculations.

To see this, note that in systems of health-cost cover that are mostly unfunded, but do

hold some amount of funds, existing reserves should have an impact on the future sustai-

nability of these systems. As a consequence, the “sustainability factor” introduced in equ-

ation (5) will be larger (that is, the discount for a lack of sustainability will be smaller)

than if there were no funds.45 Thus, if everything else is unchanged, expected future net

costs of a given individual tend to become larger, or less negative, in a partially-funded

scheme compared to an unfunded scheme. Therefore, if an individual who considers leav-

ing the scheme is expected to be a net contributor (with 0, jgaENC ), the scheme may

claim a lower payment; if the individual is a net recipient ( 0, jgaENC ), the scheme may

be willing to make a higher payment than in the alternative case of an unfunded scheme.

In the first case, the funds left behind reduce the losses involved in the emigration of in-

dividuals with low health costs or high capacities to make contributions. In the second

case, individuals with relatively high expected costs who are leaving the scheme are ef-

fectively endowed with part of the funds that have been built up in this scheme. Mutatis

mutandis, the same applies to the financial consequences of migrants who are entering

                                                            45 Or, in an alternative approach for assessing ENCs, expected future revenues collected from a given

individual could be correspondingly smaller.

Page 56: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

50 

into partially-prefunded systems of health-cost cover. If everything else is unchanged, the

willingness to pay for the entry of a new member will be lower than in an unfunded

scheme, as the existence of funds implies that net contributors are needed less urgently;

similarly, payments to be claimed for the admission of a new member will be higher, as

net recipients would effectively draw on existing funds otherwise.

For these considerations, the precise timing of how funds have been built up in the

past, or how they are scheduled to be spent in the future, is immaterial. What matters is

that these funds exist and that they can be used to pay for some fraction of health costs of

those who are currently under the scheme. Whether they are expected to continue to grow

through future excess-contributions or whether they will be run down fast over a limited

time horizon – all this is captured correctly in calculations regarding the present-value

effects of future contributions and future health costs.46

4.3 Assessment

In this chapter, we have been discussing in some detail what we think is an appropriate

conceptual framework for establishing international portability of health care or health-

insurance cover. We have focused specifically on potential gains and losses arising from

international mobility for the health funds involved on both sides – and, likewise, for in-

dividuals who opt out, or drop out, of long-term insurance of their health-status risk

which is an important dimension of health-cost cover in quite a number of actual arrange-

ments. We found that these gains and losses can be basically derived from the sign and

amount of expected future net costs related to each individual who wants to become mo-

bile, i.e., from expected health costs minus future contributions, adjusted for the risk sta-

tus of the individual as well as for all elements of redistribution included in the relevant

schemes. Calculating these net costs clearly requires some adjustments for how specific

systems covering health costs are designed. But their fundamental role for potential prob-

lems involved in mobility, hence for approaches to establishing portability, is largely in-

variant to the way in which different sources of health-cost funding are financed.

5 Policy Implications

Continued and potentially life-long coverage of health-care costs has a great value for the

individuals involved. This is clear for individuals who expect to benefit directly from the

insurance and redistribution involved in existing schemes, for instance, because they are

unhealthy, have low income, etc. Other individuals may expect to be net-payers in a giv-                                                            46 Keep in mind that, over time, aggregate amounts of funds can move in any direction even in a fully-

funded system, depending on the relative size of current net injections and current withdrawals arising for all insured individuals.

Page 57: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

51 

en scheme. Still, they can benefit from being protected if health risks and other relevant

risks materialize in an unexpected fashion, which is valuable from an ex-ante perspective

if individuals are risk averse. In addition, whether they like it or not, individuals who are

(expected to be) net payers are also important for the financial viability of health schemes

and, hence, for other members who are at the receiving end of insurance and redistribu-

tion provided by these systems.

Against this background, mobility across health funds and even more so across coun-

tries may lead to significant changes in mutual advantages and liabilities of individuals

and insurers if health-cost cover is not portable. Here, we will first highlight in more de-

tail the problems that may arise from a lack of portability (see Section 5.1). Then we will

move on to discuss options for establishing some form of “portability” in health care and

health-cost cover. Specifically, we will propose a solution which is based on transfers

between systems covering health costs, also providing simulations that are meant to illu-

strate how such a scheme could work under real-world conditions and what further issues

might turn up if it is put into practical use (see Section 5.2).

5.1 Problems arising from a lack of portability

As we have seen in Section 4, individuals who are willing to move between different

sources of health-cost funding are at risk of making substantial financial losses if they are

losing entitlements that have been acquired with their former insurer without being able

to find comparable cover elsewhere. On the other hand, if they are able to switch rather

easily from one source of health-cost funding to another, this may impose substantial

burdens on other members of either the former or the future risk pool. All these potential

losses – or corresponding benefits for the individual leaving a system or for other mem-

bers of one of the risk pools involved – are effectively two sides of the same coin, viz.,

the financial consequences of an individual exiting from or entering a health scheme.

In reality, these potential losses and benefits may materialize or not, depending on

how they affect the design of relevant rules as well as the behavior of individuals. There-

fore, we will also have to consider how relevant rules and behavioral responses interact

when discussing the problems arising from a lack of portability.

a) For potential migrants

An extreme form of non-portability arises if migrants drop out of their earlier system of

health-cost cover, but are not getting access to such a system in their destination country.

Under less extreme forms, migrants may no longer be able to utilize their earlier system

to get access to a full range of health services, or they may not be offered comparable

cover at comparable costs in a new system, for instance, because net-contributions they

Page 58: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

52 

have made in their earlier system are neglected there. Clearly, any of these cases may

give rise to concerns regarding the migrants’ social and financial situation (see Avato et

al. 2009, pp. 455–56), though maybe at varying degrees. In addition, the existence (or

simply the fear) of these consequences may feed back on individual decisions, creating

economic distortions and inefficient outcomes of these decisions.

Most importantly, the lack of portability of health care and health-cost cover may

discourage individuals from migrating,47 even where it can be expected to increase social

welfare (from a supranational perspective). The same may apply to decisions to migrate

home later on. It may also affect migrants’ choices between different target countries, or

between different jobs within a given country. In any of these cases, individuals tend to

respond to differences in access to health-cost cover in a way that is individually rational,

but does not lead to an efficient allocation of labor or efficient location choices of private

households. Avato et al. (2009, p. 455) point to the possibility that a lack of access to

health care or health insurance (or lack of portability thereof) may drive migrants into

working in the informal sector. In a sense, all these implications for international mobility

are a variant of what is called “job-lock” in discussions held in the US regarding their

national system of employer-based, private health insurance (see Section 3.2). Lack of

portability may thus not only be detrimental with respect to actual migrants, but also hits

potential migrants, preventing them from becoming mobile in the first place. As a conse-

quence, it may even have a negative impact on labor market performance and economic

dynamics for society at large, both in potential source and target countries.

Of course, different individuals will be affected by this “mobility-lock” in different

ways. For instance, young, healthy workers with good qualifications are typically wel-

come in any target country. They can easily get access to the health system there because,

inter alia, they are expected to be net-payers in this system.48 Things are most likely dif-

ferent with respect to individuals who are older and less healthy, so that the expected fu-

ture net costs of their health care are likely to exceed zero by a substantial margin. The

same may be true with respect to individuals with low qualifications or large families,

depending on how these characteristics are reflected in national systems for funding

health costs. Up to a point, countries receiving migration are able to discriminate between

some of these groups in their immigration laws; for instance, by rewarding youth and

qualifications in points-test systems for admitting new migrants, or by demanding health

checks before granting residence or work permits. However, restricting access to a coun-

                                                            47 In an empirical study, Geis et al. (2008) show that quality of the health-care system in the target country

appears to attract migration, while they are unable to control for the cost of financing health care in se-paration, i.e., as distinct from the negative effects of a more general “tax” measure.

48 Problems that are nevertheless related to these cases of mobility without portability show up elsewhere, namely in terms of negative effects for health systems in their home countries; see Sub-section b.

Page 59: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

53 

try (only) to avoid high expected health costs of migrants is a rather untargeted approach.

Where this is an issue, focusing on health costs and on the question of how they will be

funded is likely to be a better solution.

Differences in expected future net costs related to health care also explain the current

legal framework, with an asymmetric treatment of (young) migrant workers and their

families vs. non-workers and pensioners in portability rules that exist at an EU-level or

through bilateral agreements (see Section 3.1). Apart from special cases (such as commu-

ters and expatriates) workers and their families are effectively not addressed in these rules

because they are usually admitted to their target countries’ health systems directly, while

non-workers and pensioners must bring health-cost cover from their home countries, so

that their health costs accruing in the target country can be covered through reimburse-

ments between health systems. From a national point of view, and in the absence of fur-

ther rules addressing the portability issues involved, fully embracing immigrants who are

expected to be net-payers and restricting access to systems of health-cost cover for mi-

grants whose expected net costs are relatively high is a rational response. At least, it

means that all individuals are free to migrate. Also, if there are provisions regarding

access to health services and international reimbursements for those who remain insured

in their source countries, individuals’ decisions to migrate are not (at least, not heavily)

distorted. Still, this solution is far from ideal – with potentially adverse effects that are

probably not so much relevant for the individuals who are mobile but mainly for their

health funds.

b) For health funds and other members of their risk pools

If health funds could charge each new member with risk-adjusted premiums that are en-

tirely based on actuarial calculations, mobility of individuals and a lack of portability

would not be a problem for insurers and other immobile members of a given risk pool. In

this case, the problems that result would fall exclusively on individuals who consider

moving from one scheme of health-cost cover to another, taking on the form of financial

losses or a lock-in to a current health fund.49

However, public health-care systems or public health insurance providing the domi-

nant form of cover in most countries are typically far away from fitting to this descrip-

tion. Not only do they insure current health costs and long-term health-status risks with-

out risk-rating (relating at least to the time of entry); their funding often also involves

redistribution along several dimensions instead of being based on actuarial calculations.

This implies, among other things, that the exit of a high-income, low-risk individual or

the entry of a low-income, high-risk individual can bring about financial losses or in-

                                                            49 See Sub-section a as well as the discussion of German-type private health insurance in Section 3.2.

Page 60: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

54 

creased costs that would be a problem for an insurer faced with competition and, in any

case, imposes a burden on other members of the same risk pool. Of course, the opposite is

true for the entry of a low-risk individual or the exit of a high-risk individual.

In times when international mobility was more limited, the resulting marginal in-

creases (or reductions) in contribution rates or taxes may have been negligible. With

higher mobility, however, this has become more prominent. The ultimate problem that

arises for health funds and their immobile members is a process of risk segmentation

which could be fueled endogenously once it has reached a certain stage. Systems provid-

ing health-cost cover that are relatively expensive due to an unfavorable structure of in-

sured risks (with, on average, a relatively poor health status) are then less and less attrac-

tive for those who are relatively good risks, so that the latter have an additional incentive

to move away. At the same time, these individuals are attracted by countries with health

funds covering risk pools with a more favorable structure. This problem may have far-

reaching consequences that would not only affect national health systems but broader

prospects for economic development and social cohesion within and between the coun-

tries affected. It can become particularly pressing for countries where many young indi-

viduals emigrate or where emigration leads to a brain drain.

While risk segmentation mainly relates to the structure of health risks covered in

different systems of health insurance, a lack of portability rules can also create distorted

incentives to migrate resulting from the redistributive elements of national systems of

health-cost cover. Health funds that are rather generous in terms of redistribution may

attract migrants, specifically those with low income or many dependents who would ben-

efit most, while health funds with little redistribution may deter them. The countries

which would be hit hardest might differ from those that suffer from risk segmentation.

Also, while a process of risk segmentation leaves little room for manoeuver, distortions

of migration incentives through redistribution can be removed by scaling back the

amount of redistribution involved in the national health systems affected. But this may

lead to a “race to the bottom” which can affect national fiscal systems at large and is like-

ly to become detrimental for the incumbent populations – at least at some point.

5.2 Ensuring portability

From our discussion thus far, especially from our review of practical arrangements and

the difficulties showing up there (see Section 3), it is clear that portability can effectively

mean different things. It could refer to any kind of continuation of coverage over discon-

tinuities in a given individual’s life cycle, irrespective of the precise terms and conditions

that apply. In this weak sense, portability is established whenever the individual does not

drop out of health insurance entirely when becoming mobile. However, this rather weak

Page 61: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

55 

notion clearly avoids just the worst kinds of portability problems. Alternatively, portabili-

ty could be meant to imply that health-cost coverage is continued without any change in

the terms applying – an outcome that is rather difficult to accomplish in the context of

health-care schemes, as these are mainly providing benefits in kind which are delivered

under specific conditions and in a specific way which is to an important degree deter-

mined at the local level. This strong notion would amount to identical continuation of

coverage, rather than portability.

Somewhere in between these two extremes, portability can also be taken to mean that

individuals are transferred to a new scheme of health-cost cover, while the resulting

changes in mutual advantages and liabilities are taken care of in such a way that individu-

als are treated comparably favorable as before, given the particular features of their old

and new systems providing health care and funding health costs. Additionally, reasonable

rules for portability should make sure that other members of the systems to be left and the

systems to be entered do not suffer financial losses, or do not make windfall gains, as a

consequence of some individuals becoming mobile. Effectively, this latter notion of com-

parable continuation under a different system and the absence of external costs and bene-

fits for other members of the systems involved is what we prefer to call “full portabili-

ty”50 when finally discussing the policy implications arising from the considerations we

have made in this paper.

a) Basic options

Our in-depth analysis of the effects of mobility for both unfunded and (partially) pre-

funded systems of health-cost cover indicates that, if an individual switches from one

source of funding to another, this has an impact on expected future net costs incurred in

each system. Combining the formal framework for assessing these changes that was de-

veloped in Section 4 with the typical features of health costs and systems covering these

costs discussed in Section 2, it turns out that the sign as well as the size of these effects is

likely to depend on following aspects: fundamental levels of health costs accruing in a

given country; institutional features, such as the elements of insurance and redistribution

involved in a given system; the individual’s health status; and the individual’s age when

becoming mobile.

Against this background, the current legal framework for international portability of

health-care benefits and health-cost cover for migrant workers which has been described

in Section 3.1 appears to be untargeted, inconsistent and also potentially harmful for at

                                                            50 Holzmann and Koettl (2011, p. 11) add a third criterion. Besides the absence of “benefit disadvantages”

for migrants and their descendants and “fiscal fairness” for sending and receiving countries, they ask for “bureaucratic effectiveness” both for the institutions involved and for migrants.

Page 62: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

56 

least one of the three parties involved: individuals who consider becoming mobile, other

members of the health fund they are about to leave, or other members of the health fund

they are going to enter. The framework is untargeted because, for standard cases of mi-

grant workers51 and their family members, it simply ignores any consequences that are

specific to health-care systems and health-cost funding – making admission to a health

fund in the destination country subject to a “package deal”, i.e., an annex to their work

permit, and not taking care at all of the effects for health funds in the source country. The

framework is inconsistent as other categories of migrants, e.g., pensioners, are treated

very differently. For these cases, existing rules imply a solution with cross-border cover-

age, based on reimbursements for health services provided in the destination country that

are paid by health funds located in the source country.52

While the legal status quo can thus not be considered as a meaningful portability

regime, there are basically two options for establishing international portability of health-

care benefits, ensuring access to health services for mobile individuals and dealing with

the resulting issues in health-cost funding in an appropriate way. Following changes in

residence or work place that are permanent or temporary, but of some length,53 migrants

could (i) stay under the coverage of their source-country system indefinitely, combined

with reimbursements that are paid to health funds in foreign countries for any health ser-

vices received there; or (ii) they could be moved to the target country’s system of health-

cost funding, combined with mutual compensations based on the expected financial con-

sequences of such moves for each of the two systems involved.

The first option amounts to a generalization of the rules currently applying to pen-

sioners and other migrants who are not considered as workers or workers’ family mem-

bers. If the application of these rules is not selectively restricted to those cases in which

target-country systems are afraid of making financial losses, continued coverage for mi-

grants would be guaranteed under this solution. Access to health services and quality of

treatment would then largely depend on characteristics of the health-care system in the

destination country, and all financial consequences could be dealt with through reim-

bursements that ought to be assessed as carefully as possible in terms of actual fees for

services. While, in a stylized setting, this approach appears to be sufficiently targeted and

operative, there are also a number of limitations to it.

                                                            51 That is, neglecting special cases such as frontier workers (commuters) or posted workers (expatriates). 52 The potentially harmful consequences of the current framework, mainly the rules applying to migrant

workers and their families, have been discussed in some detail in Section 5.1. 53 We have already stressed that, in this paper, we are not so much concerned about the implications of

health costs accruing in foreign countries during short-term travels (see footnote 17). It appears that these cases can indeed be meaningfully dealt with based on reimbursements for any treatment provided, as they are under current rules – unless tourist visa are effectively used as a platform for other forms of international mobility.

Page 63: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

57 

For instance, an important difficulty arises from the question of whether migrants

should be treated according to the principles of health-cost funding effective in their des-

tination country or those effective in their source country. Applying the rules of the desti-

nation country is not only a matter of social inclusion of migrants who live in this place.

It also has an important practical side, as otherwise health funds located in this country

would have to apply foreign social-protection law of all the countries where immigrants

have been received from, which may well turn out infeasible. However, if health services

for migrants are provided in line with the destination country’s rules (“as if they were

insured there”, as under existing international agreements), health funds in the source

country are losing control over some part of the health costs they have to pay for. Manag-

ing health care, i.e., guiding providers’ as well as patients’ activities through public regu-

lation or direct contracts, is then no longer possible as far as health costs accruing for

emigrants are concerned. If the number of emigrants is low, this may not be considered

very important. With increasing mobility at an international level, however, this may well

become a problem in a growing number of countries.

The second option fully acknowledges the fact that health services for migrants can

be provided most easily in their destination country and that principles for funding these

services are often designed to fit to specific patterns of supply and demand in a given

health system. It rests on the conclusion that provision of services and sources of health-

cost funding for individuals who are internationally mobile should then be ideally located

in just one country at a time. However, moving individuals – workers, their family mem-

ber, pensioners, etc. – to another system of health-cost cover when they are willing to

settle in another country, at least for a certain period of time, also requires a potentially

two-sided system of transfers between their former and future health funds, meant to

compensate for the resulting changes in expected net costs accruing at both ends. Consi-

dering the difficulties involved in the option of continued coverage in the source-country

system of health-cost funding with reimbursements for services received abroad, this al-

ternative option is our preferred solution for ensuring full portability. It is in any case the

one which we are now going to investigate and illustrate in a little more detail.

b) Full portability through transfers between systems covering health costs

Ensuring full portability in health-cost coverage through compensating payments between

health funds is a basic idea that immediately derives from our calculations in Section 4.

In the absence of such payments, these calculations would indicate potential financial

losses arising in at least one of the two health funds involved from the exit or the entry of

mobile individuals. Essentially, expected net costs avoided in one place (or, alternatively,

expected net surpluses accruing there) have to be transferred to cover expected net costs

Page 64: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

58 

incurred (or expected net surpluses foregone) in the other place in order to guarantee cov-

erage under comparable conditions for migrants actually switching between health funds

located in different countries and to avoid further harmful consequences, such as financial

burdens imposed on other members of these health funds and a process of (international)

risk segmentation in health-cost funding.

The nature of the compensating payments we have in mind is that of severance

charges or redemption fees which are well-known also in other contexts. Here, they are

needed due to liabilities and entitlements related to the life-cycle dimension of health

risks and to the long-term cover provided for these risks in many existing arrangements

for funding health costs. Besides the elements of insurance involved in a given scheme,

elements of intertemporal burden smoothing and intra- and intergenerational redistribu-

tion may also add to the need for, and the size of, these transfers. Building on the concep-

tual framework we have developed above, payments are assessed based on (quasi-)actu-

arial principles, taking the aspects mentioned here into account. As we see it, this is not

only an obvious way of approaching the insurance side of health-cost funding. It also pro-

vides an appropriate benchmark for how to deal with the consequences of international

mobility for all kinds of redistribution which is legislated and operated at a national level.

Note that assessing transfers which are needed to establish full portability in the way

it is suggested here (see Section 4.1, Sub-section f) does not imply that the amount of

redistribution involved in national systems of health-cost cover is somehow extended to

other countries. Neither are sending countries made liable for paying for redistributive

elements of health funds as legislated in the receiving country, nor do receiving countries

have to pay for redistribution as it is implied in the legal framework of the sending coun-

try. Instead, what we are proposing is a coordinating mechanism which accommodates

the coexistence of national health systems that differ a lot in terms of the amount and the

directions of redistribution linked to health-cost funding. Each country is made fully re-

sponsible for the insurance as well as the redistribution it has promised to all individuals

who are once covered under its authority. If some of these individual move away, nation-

al health funds are asked to pay up to as much as a compensating transfer as they would

have had to spend on these individuals anyway under their current rules (or they are of-

fered up to as much as they would have extracted from these individuals under continued

coverage). Countries receiving immigrants are basically asked to offer them full health-

cost cover in line with their current rules,54 but at the same time they are offered up to as

                                                            54 Under the EU-level coordinating social law nothing else appears to be feasible, and this requirement is

also in the spirit of bilateral agreements we have reviewed here (see Section 3). Only, with the compen-sating payments we are suggesting, problems relating to the next-to-automatic inclusion of workers and their families in the receiving country’s health system will become less pressing. (Depending on the sign of expected net costs in a given case, these problems can hit health funds in the sending or in the

Page 65: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

59 

much as a compensation as this may cost (or they are asked to pay up to as much as their

health funds may benefit from these additional members). In any case, our proposal

makes sure that continuation of comparable coverage can be provided to individuals who

are willing to migrate and, at the same time, avoids external costs and benefits for other

members of the health funds involved as much as this is possible with respect to each

individual case.

Nevertheless, an alternative approach could be conceived of in which the effects of

redistribution at the national level would not be reflected in compensating transfers at the

international level, so that payments are only based on the insurance elements provided in

each place (see Section 4.1, Sub-section g). A solution of this kind is disputable: why

should sending countries bother to maintain redistribution through compensating pay-

ments vis-à-vis individuals who want to emigrate, and why should receiving countries

offer special payments for foreigners who want to enter them voluntarily, even though

they are likely to be net-payers with respect to redistributive elements involved in the

national health system? If there are doubts or reservations regarding these two questions,

the same principle, viz. a neglect of redistribution involved in health-cost funding, may

be applied to cases where countries would have to receive compensating payments to

ensure some amount of portability – because net-payers in terms of redistribution want to

emigrate or because net-recipients are seeking admission to immigrate. Such a modified

solution could keep compensating payments smaller, which could be favorable with re-

spect to the liquidity of unfunded health systems and make international agreements more

likely which are required for our proposal to become effective. However, the latter pre-

diction is far from clear as a consensus between two health systems with respect to indi-

vidual cases is dependent on whether one country’s willingness to pay comes sufficiently

close to, or even exceeds, the other country’s reasonable claims. Smaller payments may

effectively reduce the scope for agreements which appear to be acceptable at both ends.

They could also harm individuals seeking comparable cover elsewhere. Most important-

ly, the willingness of one country to pay for migrants who could contribute to redistribu-

tion there is limited by the total effects of a migrant on its net balance, including the ef-

fects of redistribution, not by an artificially reduced amount of pure insurance premiums.

Therefore, health funds who are negotiating an appropriate amount of transfers for a giv-

en case of international migration may themselves have reasons to act according to our

original proposal and to assess compensating payments in such a way that existing ele-

ments of redistribution are taken into account.

                                                                                                                                                                                 receiving country.) Furthermore, inclusion can also be offered to individuals who often would not get access to health cost-cover in their countries of residence, e.g., pensioners.

Page 66: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

60 

c) Illustrative calculations

To demonstrate in some more detail what we have in mind, we now use the conceptual

framework developed in this paper for actually estimating the direction and size of the

transfers that would be needed to ensure full portability of health-cost cover for individu-

als with differing characteristics (gender, age, health status, number of dependents, and

potentially also income or wages) who are willing to change their work place or resi-

dence. Specifically, we will present illustrative calculations based on the equations de-

rived in Section 4.1 (focusing on public, unfunded systems of health-cost coverage) and

on health-cost profiles for advanced and less advanced economies shown in Section 2.1

(again using Germany and Slovenia as examples).

Starting from the profiles of annual health costs for public health insurance schemes

operated in these two countries (as shown in Figures 1 through 4), we can first determine

expected health costs for individuals over their remaining life span, differentiated by

gender, age and health status. Information regarding age-specific survival probabilities of

males and females which is needed for this purpose is taken from current releases of na-

tional life tables (for the entire population, as provided by the statistical offices of Ger-

many and Slovenia).55 In addition, we have to define expected rates of health-cost infla-

tion and expected interest rates that appear to be plausible when applied over a longer

time span into the future. Effectively, we are setting health-cost inflation to constant real

rates of about 1.7 percent and 2.3 percent in Germany and Slovenia, respectively,56 while

the real interest rate is uniformly set to 3 percent in both cases. As an intermediate step,

the results of these operations can be displayed in terms of time profiles of health costs

expected for each additional year of life of an individual of given gender, age and health

status. Figure 5 shows a narrow selection of sample profiles, concentrating on males aged

25 (“young migrants”) and 65 (“pensioners”) and reflecting the differentiation by current

health status and the variation across countries, while disregarding the effects of discount-

ing future health costs (so that the results are displayed in terms of future real figures, not

present values).

Figure 5 also includes rough estimates of expected contributions that migrants can be

expected to pay for health insurance. To obtain these estimates, we use stylized wage

                                                            55 This implies that we are not using specific survival probabilities relating only to those insured in public

health insurance. Considering the extremely broad coverage of public schemes in these two countries (see Section 3.2), this may not create much of a distortion. Also, keep in mind that we have to estimate risk-specific mortality rates from average mortality rates using stylized assumptions (see footnote 3) which we uniformly apply to data for both countries.

56 These figures are based on annual average increases of per-capita health costs in the “EU reference scenarios” for the future development of public health expenditure in these two countries until 2060 (as projected in European Commission and EU Economic Policy Committee 2009).

Page 67: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

61 

Figure 5: Expected future health costs and contributions of males currently aged 25 and

65, differentiated by risk status

EU-15 country (calibrated to data for Germany, 2010):

a) Young migrant (male, aged 25) b) Pensioner (male, aged 65)

EU-12 country (calibrated to data for Slovenia, 2010):

c) Young migrant (male, aged 25) d) Pensioner (male, aged 65)

Source: own calculations.

profiles for males and females derived from German micro-data (in Fenge et al. 2006),57

expected real rates of future wage growth (1.7 percent in Germany, 2.3 percent in Slove-

nia, as in European Commission and EU Economic Policy Committee 2009), and current

rates of public health-insurance contributions applied in both countries (14.9 percent in

Germany, with an upper threshold on earnings subjected to contributions; 12.92 percent

                                                            57 These wage profiles are converted into multiples of current average wages to make them portable across

time and across countries, and are then applied to year-2010 average wages for active members of the German social insurance system (as officially stated by the administration of the national public pension scheme). As we are lacking comparable data for Slovenia, we decided to rescale the German wage pro-files according to Eurostat data on average wages observed in 2010 in both countries.

Note that there is no genuine differentiation by health status in the wage profiles we have constructed, as we are lacking more specific information on this issue. The (small) differences in contributions by health status that are visible in Figure 5 are effectively a result of differences in survival probabilities.

0

1.000

2.000

3.000

4.000

5.000

6.000

7.000

8.000

9.000

10.000

11.000

12.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Expected costs an

d contributions

(€, constant prices)

Age

Expectedhealth costs

Expected contributions

Averagerisk

High risk

Low risk

0

1.000

2.000

3.000

4.000

5.000

6.000

7.000

8.000

9.000

10.000

11.000

12.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Expected costs an

d contributions

(€, constant prices)

Age

Expectedhealth costs

Expected contributions

Averagerisk

High risk

Low risk

0

1.000

2.000

3.000

4.000

5.000

6.000

7.000

8.000

9.000

10.000

11.000

12.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Expected costs an

d contributions

(€, constant prices)

Age

Expectedhealth costs

Expected contributions

Averagerisk

High risk

Low risk

0

1.000

2.000

3.000

4.000

5.000

6.000

7.000

8.000

9.000

10.000

11.000

12.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Expected costs an

d contributions

(€, constant prices)

Age

Expectedhealth costs

Expected contributions

Average risk

High risk

Low risk

Page 68: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

62 

Figure 6: Expected future net health costs of males in an EU-15 country, differentiated by

age and risk status (calibrated to data for Germany, 2010)

Source: own calculations.

in Slovenia, where no such ceiling exists). From wage profiles and national benefit for-

mulas, we also estimate pension entitlements accumulated in the public pension schemes

of both countries, imposing health-insurance contributions (at a reduced rate of 5.21 per-

cent in Slovenia) on these pensions when individuals reach the statutory age limit (at age

65 in Germany, age 58 in Slovenia if the work record is sufficiently long.

After proper discounting, expected health costs and revenues can then be aggregated

(over each profile) and subtracted from each other (for individuals of a given gender, age

and health status). At this stage, we also apply a “sustainability factor”, as suggested in

Section 4.1 (a discount on future health costs of 4.2 percent for Germany, 12.2 percent for

Slovenia).58 The final results of these calculations is then given by a set of estimates for

the present value of expected future net costs of individuals, differentiated by gender, age

and risk status. Figures 6 and 7 display these results for German and Slovenian males,

                                                            58 These figures are taken from European Commission (2009), reflecting the infinite-time-horizon (“S2”)

measure of “sustainability gaps” involved in public finances of these countries. They are derived from long-term projections for several types of age-related public spending, including public health expendi-ture. A similar figure for Germany (4.5) can be found in the latest “Sustainability Report” of the Ger-man government (Bundesministerium der Finanzen 2008) based on Werding and Hofmann (2008).

‐80.000

‐60.000

‐40.000

‐20.000

0

20.000

40.000

60.000

80.000

100.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Expected net costs

(€, present values)

Age

Average risk

High risk

Low risk

Page 69: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

63 

Figure 7: Expected future net health costs of males in an EU-12 country, differentiated by

age and risk status (calibrated to data for Slovenia, 2010)

Source: own calculations.

clearly demonstrating how results vary with (current) age and health status. In addition,

the two figures also point to certain differences in risk-specific and age-related net costs

between public health insurance systems in these two countries.

Some of the results shown in these figures are also included in Table 1 (at 10-year

intervals) where they are complemented with parallel results obtained for women. Further

information that is needed to estimate expected future net costs relating to larger house-

holds, is provided in Table 2 which shows results for under-aged children who have cover

as dependents. These latter results are directly derived from expected health costs ac-

cruing until age 18,59 while these children are expected not to make any contributions

themselves as long as they have health-cost cover through their parents.

Figures 6 and 7 as well as Table 1 reveal that, according to our simulations, age-

related profiles of expected net costs of health care share some basic features across the

two countries we are looking at. Net costs for young males at low (or average) health

risks are clearly negative, indicating a considerable surplus of expected contributions

                                                            59 If non-contributory cover for dependents can last longer or shorter than this by national rules, the aver-

age age for leaving this status should be applied here.

‐80.000

‐60.000

‐40.000

‐20.000

0

20.000

40.000

60.000

80.000

100.000

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 70 75 80 85 90 95 100

Expected net costs

(€, present values)

Age

Average risk

High risk

Low risk

Page 70: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

64 

Table 1: Expected future net health costs, differentiated by gender, age and risk status

EU-15 country (calibrated to data for Germany, 2010)

Males Females

Age low risk average risk high risk low risk average risk high risk

15 -64.908 -61.801 28.569 -2.716 -26 110.289 25 -58.247 -53.902 36.636 -3.391 856 110.564 35 -37.308 -31.431 55.710 2.622 8.495 107.677 45 -11.379 -3.336 75.221 16.595 24.874 111.660 55 12.354 23.288 89.769 31.659 43.253 114.850 65 28.759 42.618 93.895 39.046 54.142 108.048 75 21.474 35.519 67.209 27.222 42.809 74.842 85 11.178 21.913 37.775 13.309 24.800 39.320 95 3.824 9.340 14.972 4.432 9.850 14.583

EU-12 country (calibrated to data for Slovenia, 2010)

Males Females

Age low risk average risk high risk low risk average risk high risk

15 -30.332 -29.147 10.867 -872 236 52.225 25 -24.291 -22.720 15.675 -46 1.708 51.784 35 -10.959 -8.870 27.342 4.867 7.310 51.925 45 4.795 7.720 40.191 13.413 16.875 55.256 55 18.931 22.931 49.656 21.790 26.483 56.541 65 17.186 21.931 40.904 17.766 23.222 43.132 75 10.473 14.722 25.085 10.056 14.720 24.481 85 4.893 8.013 13.050 4.163 7.082 10.856 95 1.738 3.282 5.038 1.294 2.571 3.703

Source: own calculations. – All figures in the table are net present values denominated in year-2010 €.

over expected costs. They become positive between age 40 and age 50 (in Slovenia a

little earlier than in Germany) and peak around the retirement age. Afterwards they are

declining as contingent survival probabilities decrease. These fundamental trends also

apply to individuals at high risk but, for obvious reasons, the curves for this group are at a

substantially higher level than for individuals in lower risk categories (so that high risks

are expected to impose net costs on their health systems throughout). All these trends are

similar for females compared to males but, across all risk categories, expected net costs

for young women start at substantially higher levels than they do for males, while they

decline somewhat faster towards the end of the life. The first of these effects is mainly

due to differences in labor-force participation and to lower wages from which contribu-

Page 71: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

65 

Table 2: Expected future net health costs for under-aged children, differentiated by gend-

er, age and risk status

EU-15 country (calibrated to data for Germany, 2010)

Boys Girls

Age low risk average risk high risk low risk average risk high risk

0 15.607 15.626 33.539 14.549 14.567 31.718 5 10.178 10.263 24.020 9.797 9.880 23.267 10 6.327 6.433 15.587 6.490 6.600 16.040 15 2.421 2.486 6.204 2.716 2.789 6.972

EU-12 country (calibrated to data for Slovenia, 2010)

Boys Girls

Age low risk average risk high risk low risk average risk high risk

0 9.297 9.308 20.114 8.650 8.660 18.750 5 5.518 5.564 13.010 5.383 5.428 12.692 10 3.213 3.267 7.917 3.317 3.372 8.160 15 1.222 1.255 3.126 1.321 1.357 3.383

Source: own calculations. – All figures in the table are net present values denominated in year-2010 €.

tions are levied. The second one derives from the fact that women’s health costs typically

increase less with age than health costs of males do (see Figures 1 and 3 above).

Besides these common features that are not just artifacts of uniform assumptions,

there are also a few differences between the age-related profiles of expected net costs in

the two countries. First of all, the increase and decrease of expected net costs for males is

far less pronounced in Slovenia compared to Germany, but differences are larger for

young men than for older men. The reason for this is that expected health costs increase

less with age in Slovenia, while the profile of expected contributions is much more front-

loaded there than in Germany (see Figure 5). Second, the spread in expected net costs

between high risks and low risks is a lot stronger in Germany than it is in Slovenia. This

is mainly driven by an equally stronger spread in expected health costs. Third, the same

applies to the spread in expected net costs between females and males because, on abso-

lute terms, cross-country differences in the gender wage gap are stronger than cross-

country differences in the gender-specific health-cost differential. The latter two effects

cumulate, of course, for females in a high-risk status.

Table 2 indicates that there is also a difference between the levels of health costs

accruing for children in the two countries, while there appears to be no further difference

in the structures of health costs by gender, age or risk status. When estimating expected

Page 72: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

66 

net costs of children with non-contributory cover, one could of course look further ahead,

not only until children no longer have cover as dependents. As a rule, they may take up

employment and enter the public health-insurance scheme of the country where they are

currently living with some probability in the more remote future. With adjustments for

additional years of health-cost inflation, wage growth and discounting, we could therefore

add the effects derived here for the future life cycle of young adults – and move on to

including an expected number of grandchildren, grand-grandchildren, etc. (see Sinn 2001

or Werding and Munz 2005 for applications of this idea in analyses relating to unfunded

public pension schemes). However, while these effects can be sizeable at an aggregate

level in terms of their expectation value, they are also subject to high variation and uncer-

tainty at the individual level. We therefore leave them aside here.60 Note that, otherwise,

our results would be qualitatively unaffected, since these additional effects would have to

be accounted for in both source and destination countries.

Now, what do the numbers displayed in the above tables tell us that matters for por-

tability in health-cost cover? If, for instance, a 25-year old male in good health migrates

from Slovenia to Germany in 2010 (intending to stay there on a permanent basis), public

health insurance in Slovenia foregoes an expected net surplus of future contributions over

future health costs of about 24,300 € (see Tables 1 and 3). At the same time, the German

public health-insurance system can expect to receive a surplus of about 58,250 €. There is

thus an overall gain of 33,950 €.61 Also, if the Slovenian system would like to claim

24,300 € to avoid negative consequences for other members, and if the German system’s

maximum willingness to pay is 58,250 €, there appears to be ample room for a mutually

beneficial agreement: both sides could share the surplus, or they could settle to the small-

er amount to make sure there are no losses – or what is left of the surplus could in fact be

disbursed to the individual.

Interestingly, if the same individual would decide to return home as a 65-year old

forty years later, the German system might again be prepared to make a compensating

payment to the Slovenian system. If the individual is still a low risk (in brackets: has

turned into a high risk), German health funds would save expected net costs of 17,000 €

(55,600 €), while the Slovenian system would have to take on expected net costs of

13,000 € (30,950 €), assessed from today’s perspective.62 The overall gain that results,

hence the room for an agreement, is 4,000 € (24,650 €) based on year-2010 present val-

                                                            60 In a sense, we assume that (implicit) contracts regarding long-term insurance for health costs are first

made when individuals start making independent decisions. These contracts may include health costs of dependents, but do not automatically extend to life-long cover for these (and all further) descendants.

61 This is effectively some fraction of what is usually called the “immigration surplus” (see Borjas 1995). 62 As such, these figures are not included in Table 2, since the results displayed there relate to individuals

(e.g., 65-year old males) who migrate today. If this happens in 40 years’ time, current effects have to be up-rated to reflect expected increases in prices of health services and then discounted.

Page 73: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

67 

Table 3: Consequences of international migration for expected future net health costs,

various examples

Changes in expected future net health costs

in Slovenia (Direction of migration)

in Germany Overall

Singles aged 25

Male at low risk 24.291 -58.247 -33.957 Male at high risk -15.675 36.636 20.961 Female at low risk 46 -3.391 -3.345 Female at high risk -51.784 110.564 58.780

Family of three* 32.894 -47.089 -14.195 * Male aged 25, female aged 25, daughter aged less than 1; all at low health risk.

Family of four** -8.321 -2.327 -10.648 ** Male aged 35, female aged 30, son aged 10, daughter aged 5; son at high risk, all others at low risk.

Singles aged 65

Male at low risk 17.186 -28.759 -11.573 Male at high risk 40.904 -93.895 -52.991 Female at low risk 17.766 -39.046 -21.280 Female at high risk 43.132 -108.048 -64.916

Retired couple*** 51.161 -120.787 -69.626 *** Male aged 70, at high risk; female aged 65, at low risk.

Source: own calculations. – All figures in the table are net present values denominated in year-2010 €.

ues – and it will look substantially larger in 2050 when this becomes relevant. If a male

aged 65 migrates in the same direction today, the overall gain is 11,600 € (53,000 €).

Combining information from the other tables, Table 3 gives a number of further ex-

amples of changes in expected net costs for public health-insurance systems in Slovenia

and in Germany through migration of individuals or households with varying characteris-

tics in one direction or the other. If, through emigration or immigration, net costs increase

in a system, there is a positive sign in the relevant column; if net cost decrease, there is a

negative sign. The “overall” column sums up the resulting changes, so that a negative

sign there indicates that total expected net costs across the two systems are decreased

through migration, while a positive sign points to an increase in total expected net costs.

Negative overall effects also imply that there is some leeway for health funds in the send-

ing and the receiving country to agree on a compensating payment for potentially harmful

losses (surpluses foregone or net costs incurred) on one side from, (“windfall”) gains (net

Page 74: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

68 

costs avoided or surpluses accruing) on the other side. If overall effects are positive, such

an agreement is difficult, as losses on one side exceed gains on the other.

The selection of examples covered in Table 3 is clearly arbitrary, but further cases

can easily be assembled from Tables 1 and 2. The scenarios we have constructed here

relate to cases where young individuals (alone or with a partner and children) would mi-

grate from Slovenia to Germany, that is, from a less advanced to a highly developed

country; or where older individuals (alone or as couples) consider migrating in the oppo-

site direction. These latter cases could be return migration of individuals who immigrated

earlier, or they could be emigration of individuals who want to spend their retirement

abroad, for instance, in regions with a better climate or with lower costs of living. All in

all, the examples have some realism to them.

In most of the cases considered here, migration with unrestricted access for migrants

to the health system in the destination country and with compensating payments dealing

with the problem of external costs or benefits appears to be easily feasible. The only cas-

es where things are different are those of young individuals at a high health risk who

want to migrate from Slovenia to Germany. As, according to our simulation, treatment of

high risks is a lot more expensive in Germany than it is in Slovenia, total expected net

costs go up if individuals actually migrate, and it may not be easy to agree on how these

extra-costs will be shared. This observation has many implications. For one, individuals

in poor health may simply be less likely to migrate. For another, countries receiving im-

migration may be interested in attracting healthy individuals, while they may not agree to

pay for any extra-costs which alleviate the immigration of individuals in poor health.

Considering the responsibility for the incumbent population (potentially including many

earlier immigrants) and for a financially sound situation of the existing social protection

system, this position is clearly defendable. Yet another aspect is that the difference in

costs may reflect differences in the quality of treatment or even in the availability of spe-

cial types of treatment. Against this background, admitting individuals at high risk with-

out claiming full compensation for the expected net health costs incurred could be a hu-

manitarian issue or, quite differently, the individuals themselves could be willing (and

able) to pay for the gap that arises. In these two latter cases, compensating payments can

serve an important function in transferring at least the amount of net costs avoided in the

source country, even if this does not cover all costs arising in the destination country.

It is probably not surprising that, even with transfers based on differences in ex-

pected future net costs, establishing portability is difficult with respect to individuals at

high health risks. Two observations from Table 2 are therefore of interest. First, we in-

cluded individuals in a high-risk status in some of the examples for families or couples

considered there. The resulting overall changes in net costs were still favorable because

Page 75: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

69 

they were dominated by reductions in expected net costs for other household members.

With this kind of “family insurance”, increased health risks are thus not necessarily harm-

ful for mobility and portability. Second, being at a high-risk status does not appear to be a

problem if individuals are willing to move from a country where their expected net costs

are relatively high to a country where these are lower. This is effectively accomplished by

the introduction of compensation for potentially harmful effects of mobility on health

funds in the destination country – and it can still mean a reduction in expected net costs

for health funds in the source country.

We have mentioned here that migration of younger and older individuals can be

linked to each other across time by processes of return migration.63 It should be noted

therefore, that moves in both directions can be feasible under the framework we are con-

sidering here. Expected net costs may decline, i.e., there may be room for mutually bene-

ficial agreements between the two health systems involved, when individuals are moving

in either direction simply because these individuals are getting older over time (so that

age-specific cost differentials across both places change) or because their health status

may definitely deteriorate in the time elapsing between migration and return migration

(so that risk-related cost differentials become more pronounced). However, where migra-

tion with full portability is difficult to establish for young individuals, limiting the period

for which portability is granted can never circumvent this problem.64

If the overall effects of mobility with compensating payments between the health

funds involved are favorable, that is, if they indicate a decline in expected net costs for

individuals with certain characteristics moving in one direction, they must be unfavorable

for individuals with the same characteristics who are willing to move in the opposite di-

rection. According to our stylized simulations, this would apply to young, healthy indi-

viduals who want to move from Germany to Slovenia or to individuals who are older

and/or less healthy and want to move from Slovenia to Germany. These asymmetries are

hardly avoidable, mostly because they are rooted in actual cost differentials and not in

administrative barriers or inappropriate rules. At the same time, this may simply be one

of the reasons why migration is mostly flowing in the directions for which portability can

be established more easily: individuals usually have incentives to migrate where migra-

tion is likely to be beneficial – not only with respect to systems of health-cost funding,

but also in terms of its overall economic effects. Appropriate rules for the portability of

                                                            63 In Section 4.1, it has also been demonstrated that changes in expected net costs, hence compensating

payments, cannot only be determined for the case that individuals switch to another source of health-cost funding for the rest of their lives but, with assessments on a pro-rata basis, also if this is considered to happen only for a considerable time period.

64 That is, the resulting increase in expected net costs can be reduced, but never removed, if it is assumed to last for a limited period of time only. This is at least true, if the form of age-related profiles of ex-pected net health costs is basically similar across all the countries involved.

Page 76: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

70 

health-care benefits can contribute to avoiding specific distortions of these incentives.

But designing these rules in such a way that fundamental incentives are reversed is diffi-

cult and probably also not advisable.

6 Discussion

In this paper, we have argued that arrangements for funding health care are very impor-

tant for the individuals covered but that portability of these arrangements in cases of in-

ternational mobility can be difficult to establish because of the long-term nature of insur-

ance provided and the additional elements of redistribution that may be included. Against

this background, we tried to clarify the consequences of mobility – and of a lack of porta-

bility – for individuals who consider becoming mobile as well as for the sources of

health-cost cover operated in potential source and target countries. We have concluded

that, to establish portability for individuals who actually move from one source of health-

cost funding to another and to avoid external costs or benefits that could arise at both

ends, compensating payments may be needed between the two health funds involved.

These payments should be assessed based on changes in expected net costs (expected

health costs minus expected contributions), adjusted for health-cost inflation, wage

growth, long-term (non-)sustainability and properly discounted over time for both of the

systems involved. This would require major changes in existing portability arrangements,

even for the most advanced sets of current rules, such as those agreed upon multilaterally

at the EU-level or laid down in bilateral agreements on social protection.

Compared to current rules (see Section 3), the solution developed in Sections 4 and 5

has a few novel features which we think important and advantageous. First of all, our

proposal includes migrant workers and their family members in the legal framework for

portability of health-cost cover. With respect to these cases, it differs from the current

“package deal”, by which migrants are admitted to the national risk pool for funding

health costs in the receiving country as an annex to their work permit, in that it actively

addresses potential external costs or windfall gains falling on other members of the two

health funds involved. Also, our proposal contributes to establishing continuation of

comparable coverage for migrant workers – to the extent that this is possible under a dif-

ferent legal framework and within a different system for providing health services.

Second, our proposal allows for a formal transfer of health-fund membership in cases of

mobile pensioners (or other types of migrants who are not working). While these individ-

uals are currently being dealt with through some form of cross-border coverage, with a

constant need for interaction between two health systems regarding provision of services

and related reimbursements, pensioners and other non-working migrants could be fully

Page 77: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

71 

included in the health system in their country of residence, again with continuation of

comparable cover. Compensating payments which have to be made just once then contri-

bute to avoiding external costs or benefits that would otherwise arise with some certainty.

The actual burden sharing for health costs at old age which results from our proposal is

also less arbitrary, and likely to be more appropriate, for pensioners with a complicated

work biography, entailing employment in more than one country. Last but not least, our

proposal is easily applicable to cases of temporary migration of some duration (say, a

year or more) for which the responsibility for health-cost coverage can be fully trans-

ferred to the receiving country, while migrants retain the right to return to full, life-long

health-cost cover in the sending country later on. In these cases, compensating payments

simply have to be assessed for the expected duration of the temporary move only.

Do we really think that our ideas can be made the basis of actual policies applied in

this area without much further thinking? There are admittedly a number of unresolved

issues, more technical ones, but also material aspects, which may imply practical limita-

tions for the application of our ideas.

As to the technical issues, one certainly needs to revisit the conceptual framework

for assessing expected future net costs of health care for migrants we have suggested in

Section 4. While the data requirements for making this framework operative are limited,

some of the information that is needed for this purpose may not exist everywhere. To

some extent, this even applies to age-related profiles of health costs which are the most

important ingredient, and also to life tables as well as age-related wage profiles that are

specific for the population covered in a given scheme of health-cost funding. In addition,

the definition of appropriate categories of health risks, related cost differentials and tran-

sition probabilities, and the impact of these risks on survival probabilities clearly need

more empirical work. In next steps of research, therefore, some effort needs to be spent

on assessing relevant micro-data from further countries (as those taken from US sources

which we have used to calibrate our illustrative calculations in Sections 2 and 5).65 Other

assumptions and procedures for calculating an appropriate amount of compensations be-

tween former and future sources of health-cost cover for migrants are not only a matter of

empirical validation, but also of agreements regarding how to deal with an uncertain fu-

ture in a reliable (or, at least, acceptable) way. For instance, this relates to health-cost

inflation and financial sustainability expected for the future and the way in which these

aspects can be reflected in the projections required for estimating expected net costs of

migrants.

                                                            65 First of all, it is an important question in this context whether changes in health status do matter at all

for expected future health costs of a given individual, taking into account the resulting differences in mortality. In our simulations, they have a rather strong impact, but as the basis for this conclusion is weak, the question deserves further attention (see footnotes 3 and 5).

Page 78: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

72 

To see whether, and how, these problems can be solved one could turn to collecting

information that is needed to make our proposal operative – age-related health-cost pro-

files in particular – for as many countries as this is currently possible. Using these mate-

rials, one could then perform sample calculations for a sufficiently large number of real-

world cases of migrants between that appear to be prototypical for mobility between dif-

ferent countries and different health systems. The results in terms of compensating pay-

ments that would appear to be appropriate building on our approach could then be com-

pared to reimbursements made under the current framework, where they apply, or to

health costs of migrant workers, where corresponding data can be obtained. Furthermore,

the results could be discussed with experts representing different aspects of relevant prac-

tical experience, that is, members of national welfare administrations, especially persons

working in international liaison offices of insurance providers and health ministries, also

officials from foreign-affairs departments, the EU, international organizations and, of

course, interested researchers.

Some of the material issues that probably need to be considered more closely have

already been noted in earlier sections of this paper. Specifically, the question of whether

compensating payments should be assessed based on the elements of insurance involved

in actual systems covering health costs or whether they should also reflect the various

elements of redistribution raises more than just practical considerations. Clearly, this al-

ternative could be looked at in the course of tests and sample calculations that we have

suggested above and they could also be discussed among experts. Basically, however, the

question calls for more fundamental clarifications regarding the rights and obligations

deriving from life-long health-cost coverage through national systems as well as the con-

sequences of the differing approaches developed or, at least, sketched in this paper for

full portability as we have interpreted this notion.

We have briefly mentioned that differences in expected health costs across countries

may reflect differences in cover and in the quality of services provided. If these differenc-

es only relate to different elements of insurance and redistribution involved in the sources

of health-cost funding in different places or countries, this raises the question of what

“comparable cover” or “comparably favorable cover” (see Section 5.2) really means,

considering the particular features of migrants’ old and new systems funding health costs.

It is in any case a reason why (part of) the surpluses of expected net costs in their former

sources of health-cost funding over those in their new systems could actually be dis-

bursed to the migrants themselves – for instance, in order to buy additional cover they

would otherwise lose. But if there are genuine differences in the quality of health-care

systems, so that comparable cover simply cannot be provided in the destination country,

this problem cannot be solved due to the dominant nature of health care as a bundle of

Page 79: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

73 

services which can be delivered most easily where individuals are currently staying. In

this case, migrants may be interested in being transferred to the health system of their

destination country only temporarily to keep up their entitlements vis-à-vis their old sys-

tem for a later period in their life, when health care becomes more important for them and

they may be able to return to their source country.

Another issue that arises is that compensating payments between health funds cannot

provide for full portability in all cases. If changes in expected net costs are such that the

maximum willingness to pay of one of the funds is smaller than the amount that the other

fund would like to claim, there is no leeway for a mutually beneficial settlement. There-

fore, even in the presence of a scheme of compensating payments that are meant to en-

sure portability, there is the possibility of unfavorable effects for migrants which can be-

come prohibitive with respect to alleviating mobility. In our discussion, we have high-

lighted that this problem has a strong economic dimension and is no longer the outcome

of administrative barriers and inappropriate rules. If this is true, it may not be in the inter-

est of one of the countries involved to agree to a solution taking care of such cases. Still,

there may be other considerations regarding how to deal with this possibility, and this

may be a subject for further debate.

This leads to a broader discussion of our proposed solution. For those who first think

about it, the idea of countries claiming or making payments related to cases of inward and

outward migration may sound unusual. Specifically, source countries may find it politi-

cally difficult to regulate emigration in a corresponding fashion – and after the fall of the

Iron Curtain they may even take pride in not doing so in an overly intrusive way. Given

that, they may also be in a weak position when attempting to direct any claims to other

countries that are currently receiving substantial amounts of immigration. Furthermore,

from an economist’s perspective the freedom to move (out) is considered to be important

as it basically represents a mechanism for voting with one’s feet (see Tiebout 1956)

which establishes competition between jurisdictions and forces them to act in their citi-

zens’ interest.66 However, some coordination is actually needed in several fields for this

particular type of competition to be genuinely fruitful. Well-known examples calling for

international agreements on a number of common basic principles are tax competition

and public redistribution (see, e.g., Sinn 2003, chs. 2 and 3). These two cases are clearly

applicable also with respect to national health-care systems and national arrangements for

health-cost funding. In addition, the list of fields where uncoordinated international sys-

tems’ competition is likely to fail may have to be augmented with the aspect of long-term

insurance.

                                                            66 For similar reasons, the right to emigrate freely is also an important human-rights issue.

Page 80: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

74 

Last but not least, we would like to mention that our ideas are to some extent remi-

niscent of the Bhagwati-tax proposal which was meant to deal with the consequence of a

“brain drain” from international migration for many sending countries (see Bhagwati and

Dellalfar 1973 or Bhagwati 1976). Here, this general idea is brought to bearing in a way

that is specifically targeted at the financial consequences of migration for national health

systems. To make sure that such a piece-meal approach does not lead to new distortions,

our proposal should probably be augmented with similar portability rules applying to

other branches of social protection systems and public finances in general, because mi-

grants who are expected to be net-payers with respect to health care and health-cost fund-

ing may be net-beneficiaries elsewhere and vice versa. Similar calculations may therefore

be needed for (public) pension schemes (see, e.g., Werding and Munz 2005) and further

systems providing insurance or redistribution to eventually assess the total (economic and

fiscal) effects of migration, the ultimate task being to create a comprehensive framework

for undistorted decisions to migrate.

References

Albreht, Tit, and Niek Klazinga. 2009. “Privatisation of Health Care in Slovenia in the

Period 1992–2008.” Health Policy 90(2): 262–9.

Avato, Johanna. 2008a. “Portability of Social Security and Health Care Benefits in Italy.”

Background paper prepared for a project done by the World Bank and the Institute

for Development Studies (IDS).

Avato, Johanna. 2008b. “Portability of Social Security and Health Care Benefits in the

United Kingdom.” Background paper prepared for a project done by the World Bank

and the Institute for Development Studies (IDS).

Avato, Johanna, Johannes Koettl, and Rachel Sabates-Wheeler. 2009. “Social Security

Regimes, Global Estimates, and Good Practices: The Status of Social Protection for

International Migrants.” World Development 38(4): 455–66.

Bartel, Ann, and George Borjas. 1977. “Middle-Age Job Mobility: Its Determinants and

Consequences.” In Men in the Pre-Retirement Years, edited by Seymour Wolfbein,

pp. 39–97. Philadelphia: Temple University Press.

Baumann, Florian, Volker Meier, and Martin Werding. 2008. “Transferable Ageing Pro-

visions in Individual Health-insurance Contracts.” German Economic Review 9(3):

287–311.

Besley, Timothy J., John Hall, and Ian Preston. 1999. “The Demand for Private Health

Insurance: Do Waiting Lists Matter?” Journal of Public Economics 72(2): 155–81.

Page 81: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

75 

Bhagwati, Jagdish. 1976. “The brain drain.” International Social Science Journal 28(4):

691–729.

Bhagwati, Jagdish, and William Dellalfar. 1973. “The Brain drain and income taxation.”

World Development 1(1-2): 94–101.

Blanchard, Olivier J. 1990. “Suggestions for a New Set of Fiscal Indicators.” OECD

Economics Department Working Paper No. 79.

Borjas, George J. 1995. “The Economic Benefits from Immigration.” Journal of Econom-

ic Perspectives 9(2):3–22.

Breyer, Friedrich, Juan Costa-i-Font, and Stefan Felder. 2010. “Ageing, Health and

Health Care.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 26(4), 674–90.

Buchmueller, Thomas C., and Agnes Couffinhal. 2004. “Private Health Insurance in

France.” OECD Health Working Papers No. 12.

Bundesministerium der Finanzen. 2008. Zweiter Bericht zur Tragfähigkeit der

öffentlichen Finanzen (Second Report on the Sustainability of Public Finances). Ber-

lin: Federal Department of Finance.

Dowd, Bryan, and Roger Feldman. 1992. “Insurer Competition and Protection from Risk

Redefinition in the Individual and Small Group Health-insurance Market.” Inquiry

29(2): 148–57.

Eichenhofer, Eberhard. 2002. “Migration in Europe and its Effects on Social Security.” In

Social Security and Changes in the World of Work, edited by International Social Se-

curity Association, pp. 95–109. ISSA Social Security Documentation No. 28.

EU Economic Policy Committee. 2001. “Budgetary Challenges Posed by Ageing Popula-

tions: The Impact of Public Spending on Pensions, Health and Long-term Care for

the Elderly and Possible Indicators for the Long-term Sustainability of Public Fin-

ances.” Document No. EPC/ECFIN/655/01-EN final.

EU Economic Policy Committee. 2003. “The Impact of Ageing Populations on Public

Finances: Overview of Analysis Carried out at an EU Level and Proposals for a Fu-

ture Work Programme.” Document No. EPC/ECFIN/435/03-EN final.

European Commission. 2009. “Sustainability Report 2009.” European Economy No.

9/2009.

European Commission, and EU Economic Policy Committee. 2009. “2009 Ageing Re-

port: Economic and budgetary projections for the EU-27 Member States (2008–

2060.” European Economy No. 2/2009.

European Union. 2010. The EU provisions on social security: Your rights when moving

within the European Union – Update 2010. Luxembourg: European Union.

Fenge, Robert, Silke Uebelmesser, and Martin Werding. 2006. “On the Optimal Timing

of Implicit Social Security Taxes Over the Life Cycle.” Finanzarchiv 62(1): 68–107.

Page 82: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

76 

Geis, Wido, Silke Uebelmesser, and Martin Werding. 2008. “How do Migrants Choose

their Destination Country? An Analysis of Institutional Determinants.” CESifo Work-

ing Paper No. 2506.

Geis, Wido, Silke Uebelmesser´, and Martin Werding. 2011. “Why go to France or Ger-

many, if you could as well go to the UK or the US? Selective Features of Immigra-

tion to the EU ‘Big Three’ and the United States.” Journal of Common Market Stu-

dies 49(4): 767–96.

Gruber, Jonathan, and Brigitte C. Madrian. 1994. “Health Insurance and Job Mobility:

The Effects of Public Policy on Job-Lock.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review

48(1): 86–102.

Gruber, Jonathan, and Brigitte C. Madrian. 1997. “Employment Separation and Health

Insurance Coverage.” Journal of Public Economics 66(3): 349–82.

Gruber, Jonathan, and Brigitte C. Madrian. 2002. “Health Insurance, Labor Supply, and

Job Mobility: A Critical Review of the Literature.” NBER Working Paper No. 8817.

Hatton, Timothy J., and Jeffrey G. Williamson. 2002. “What Fundamentals Drive World

Migration?” NBER Working Paper No. w9159.

Hauner, David, Daniel Leigh, and Michael Skaarup. 2007. “Ensuring Fiscal Sustainabili-

ty in G-7 Countries.” IMF Working Paper No. WP/07/187.

Henke, Klaus-Dirk, Melanie Lisac, Lutz Reimers, and Sophie Schlette. 2010. “Access

and Choice – Competition under the Roof of Solidarity in German Health Care.”

Health Economics, Policy and Law 5(1): 31–52.

Herring, Bradley, and Mark V. Pauly. 2006. “Incentive-Compatible Guaranteed Renewa-

ble Health Insurance Premiums.” Journal of Health Economics 25(3): 395–417.

Holtz-Eakin, Douglas. 1993. “Health Insurance Provision and Labor Market Efficiency in

the United States and Germany.” NBER Working Paper No. 4388.

Holzmann, Robert, Johannes Koettl, and Taras Chernetsky. 2005. “Portability regimes of

pension and health care benefits for international migrants: an analysis of issues and

good practices.” Discussion Paper prepared for the Global Commission on Interna-

tional Migration (GCIM).

Holzmann, Robert, and Johannes Koettl. 2011. “Portability of Pension, Health, and other

Social Benefits: Facts, Concepts, Issues.” IZA Discussion Paper No. 5715.

Madrian, Brigitte C. 1994. “Employment-Based Health Insurance and Job Mobility: Is

There Evidence of Job-Lock?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109(1): 27–51.

Makhema, Mpho. 2009. “Social Protection for Refugees and Asylum Seekers in the

Southern African Development Community.” The World Bank, Social Protection

Discussion Paper No. 906.

Page 83: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

77 

Meier, Volker. 2005. “Efficient Transfer of Aging Provisions in Private Health-

Insurance.” Journal of Economics 84(3): 249–75.

Meier, Volker, and Martin Werding. 2010. “Ageing and the Welfare State: Securing Sus-

tainability.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 26(4), 655–73.

Mitchell, Olivia. 1982. “Fringe Benefits and Labor Mobility.” Journal of Human Re-

sources 17(2): 286–98.

OECD. 2011. OECD Health Data 2011. On-line database, released 30 June 2011, access-

ible via http://stats.oecd.org.

Olivier, Marius. 2009. “Regional Overview of Social Protection for Non-Citizens in the

Southern African Development Community.” The World Bank, Social Protection

Discussion Paper No. 908.

Pauly, Mark V., Howard Kunreuther, and Richard Hirth. 1995. “Guaranteed Renewabili-

ty in Insurance.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 10(2): 143–56

Pauly, Mark V., Allison Percy, and Bradley Herring. 1999. “Individual Versus Job-based

Health Insurance: Weighing the Pros and Cons.” Health Affairs 18(6): 28–44.

Pieters, Danny, and Paul Schoukens. 2009. “The Rules within Regulation 883/2004 for

Determining the Applicable Legislation.” European Journal of Social Security

11(1–2): 81–117.

Preker, Alexander S., Peter Zweifel, and Onno P. Schellekens, eds. 2009. Global Market-

place for Private Health Insurance: Strength in Numbers. Washington, DC: World

Bank.

Propper, Carol. 2000. “The Demand for Private Health Care in the UK.” Journal of

Health Economics 19(6): 855–76.

Przywara, Bartosz. 2010. “Projecting Future Health Care Expenditure at European Level:

Drivers, Methodology and Main Results.” European Economy, Economic Papers

No. 417.

Rashad, Inas, and Eric Rapong. 2006. “Employer-Provided Health Insurance and the In-

cidence of a “Job-Lock”: Is There a Consensus?” Andrew Young School of Policy

Studies, Working Paper No. 06-53.

Schulte, Bernd. 2003. “Implications of Labour Migration for Social Security Systems in

European Countries – Activities of the Council of Europe.” European Journal of Mi-

gration and Law 4(4): 477–89.

Sieveking, Klaus. 2000. “The Significance of the Transborder Utilisation of Health Care

Benefits for Migrants.” European Journal of Migration and Law 2(2): 143–55.

Sieveking, Klaus. 2007. “ECJ Rulings on Health Care Services and Their Effects on the

Freedom of Cross-Border Patient Mobility in the EU.” European Journal of Migra-

tion and Law 9(1): 25–51.

Page 84: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

78 

Sun, Wei, Anthony Webb, and Natalia Zhivan. 2010. “Does Staying Healthy Reduce

Your Lifetime Health Care Costs?” Issue in Brief No. 10-8. Chestnut Hill, MA: Cen-

ter for Retirement Research at Boston College.

Sinn, Hans-Werner. 2000. “Why a funded pension system is needed and why it is not

needed.” International Tax and Public Finance 7(4/5): 389–410.

Sinn, Hans-Werner. 2001. “The Value of Children and Immigrants in a Pay-As-You-Go

Pension System.” Ifo Studien / CESifo Economic Studies 47(1): 77–94.

Sinn, Hans-Werner. 2003. The New Systems Competition. Oxford: Blackwell.

Tajnikar, Maks, and Petra Došenovič Bonča. 2009. “Slovenia.” In: Global Marketplace

for Private Health Insurance: Strength in Numbers, edited by Alexander S. Preker,

Peter Zweifel, and Onno P. Schellekens, pp. 369–400. Washington, DC: World

Bank.

Tiebout, Charles M. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political

Economy 64(5): 416–24.

UN. 2009. Trends in International Migrant Stock: The 2008 Revision. New York, NY:

United Nations, Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Population Division.

U.S. Census Bureau. 2010. Current Population Reports: Income, Poverty, and Health

Insurance Coverage in the United States: 2009. Washington D.C.: U.S. Government

Printing Office.

Webb, Anthony, and Natalia Zhivan. 2010. “How Much is Enough? The Distribution of

Lifetime Health Care Costs.” Working Paper No. 10-1, Chestnut Hill, MA: Center

for Retirement Research at Boston College.

Werding, Martin. 2007. “Social Insurance: How to Pay for Pensions and Health Care?” In

Demographic Change in Germany: The Economic and Fiscal Consequences, edited

by Ingrid Hamm, Helmut Seitz, and Martin Werding, pp. 89–128. Berlin, Heidel-

berg, New York: Springer.

Werding, Martin, and Herbert Hofmann. 2008. Projektionen zur langfristigen

Tragfähigkeit der öffentlichen Finanzen. Munich: Ifo Institute for Economic

Research.

Werding, Martin, and Sonja Munz. 2005. “Public Pensions and International Migration:

Some Clarifications and Illustrative Results.” Journal of Pension Economics and

Finance 4(2): 181–207.

Woolford, Geoff. 2009. “Social Protection for Migrants from the Pacific Islands in Aus-

tralia and New Zealand.” The World Bank, Social Protection Discussion Paper No.

912.

Zweifel, Peter, Stefan Felder, and Markus Meier. 1999. “Ageing of Population and

Health Care Expenditure: A Red Herring?” Health Economics, 8(6): 485–96.

Page 85: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

Social Protection Discussion Paper Series Titles No. Title 1116 Strengthening Governance of Social Safety Nets in East Asia by Sara Giannozzi and Asmeen Khan, August 2011 (online only) 1115 International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience by Martin Werding and Stuart McLennan, July 2011 (online only) 1114 Liberia’s Cash For Work Temporary Employment Project: Responding to Crisis

in Low Income, Fragile Countries by Colin Andrews, Prospère Backiny-Yetna, Emily Garin, Emily Weedon,

Quentin Wodon and Giuseppe Zampaglione, July 2011 1113 Employability and Productivity among Older Workers: A Policy Framework and

Evidence from Latin America by Edmundo Murrugarra, July 2011 (online only) 1112 Cash Transfers, Children and the Crisis: Protecting Current and Future

Investments by Ariel Fiszbein, Dena Ringold, Santhosh Srinivasan, June 2011 (online only) 1111 Severance Pay Programs around the World: History, Rationale, Status, and

Reforms by Robert Holzmann, Yann Pouget, Milan Vodopivec and Michael Weber, May

2011 (online only) 1110 Portability of Pension, Health, and other Social Benefits: Facts, Concepts, Issues by Robert Holzmann and Johannes Koettl, May 2011 (online only) 1109 Disability and Poverty in Developing Countries: A Snapshot from the World

Health Survey by Sophie Mitra, Aleksandra Posarac and Brandon Vick, April 2011 1108 Advancing Adult Learning in Eastern Europe and Central Asia by Christian Bodewig and Sarojini Hirshleifer, April 2011 (online only) 1107 Results Readiness in Social Protection & Labor Operations by Laura Rawlings, Maddalena Honorati, Gloria Rubio and Julie Van Domelen,

February 2011 1106 Results Readiness in Social Protection & Labor Operations: Technical Guidance

Notes for Social Service Delivery Projects by Julie Van Domelen, February 2011 1105 Results Readiness in Social Protection & Labor Operations: Technical Guidance

Notes for Social Safety Nets Task Teams by Gloria Rubio, February 2011

Page 86: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

1104 Results Readiness in Social Protection & Labor Operations: Technical Guidance Notes for Social Funds Task Teams

by Julie Van Domelen, February 2011 1103 Results Readiness in Social Protection & Labor Operations: Technical Guidance

Notes for Labor Markets Task Teams by Maddalena Honorati, February 2011 1102 Natural Disasters: What is the Role for Social Safety Nets? by Larissa Pelham, Edward Clay and Tim Braunholz, February 2011 1101 North-South Knowledge Sharing on Incentive-based Conditional Cash Transfer

Programs by Lawrence Aber and Laura B. Rawlings, January 2011 1008 Social Policy, Perceptions and the Press: An Analysis of the Media’s Treatment

of Conditional Cash Transfers in Brazil by Kathy Lindert and Vanina Vincensini, December 2010 (online only) 1007 Bringing Financial Literacy and Education to Low and Middle Income

Countries: The Need to Review, Adjust, and Extend Current Wisdom by Robert Holzmann, July 2010 (online only) 1006 Key Characteristics of Employment Regulation in the Middle East and North

Africa by Diego F. Angel-Urdinola and Arvo Kuddo with support from Kimie Tanabe

and May Wazzan, July 2010 (online only) 1005 Non-Public Provision of Active Labor Market Programs in Arab-Mediterranean

Countries: An Inventory of Youth Programs by Diego F. Angel-Urdinola, Amina Semlali and Stefanie Brodmann, July 2010

(online only) 1004 The Investment in Job Training: Why Are SMEs Lagging So Much Behind? by Rita K. Almeida and Reyes Aterido, May 2010 (online only) 1003 Disability and International Cooperation and Development: A Review of Policies

and Practices by Janet Lord, Aleksandra Posarac, Marco Nicoli, Karen Peffley, Charlotte

McClain-Nhlapo and Mary Keogh, May 2010 1002 Toolkit on Tackling Error, Fraud and Corruption in Social Protection Programs by Christian van Stolk and Emil D. Tesliuc, March 2010 (online only) 1001 Labor Market Policy Research for Developing Countries: Recent Examples from

the Literature - What do We Know and What should We Know? by Maria Laura Sanchez Puerta, January 2010 (online only)

0931 The Korean Case Study: Past Experience and New Trends in Training Policies by Young-Sun Ra and Kyung Woo Shim, December 2009 (online only)

Page 87: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

0930 Migration Pressures and Immigration Policies: New Evidence on the Selection of Migrants

by Johanna Avato, December 2009 (online only) 0929 Ex-Ante Methods to Assess the Impact of Social Insurance Policies on Labor

Supply with an Application to Brazil by David A. Robalino, Eduardo Zylberstajn, Helio Zylberstajn and

Luis Eduardo Afonso, December 2009 (online only) 0928 Rethinking Survivor Benefits by Estelle James, December 2009 (online only) 0927 How Much Do Latin American Pension Programs Promise to Pay Back? by Alvaro Forteza and Guzmán Ourens, December 2009 (online only) 0926 Work Histories and Pension Entitlements in Argentina, Chile and Uruguay by Alvaro Forteza, Ignacio Apella, Eduardo Fajnzylber, Carlos Grushka, Ianina

Rossi and Graciela Sanroman, December 2009 (online only) 0925 Indexing Pensions

by John Piggott and Renuka Sane, December 2009 (online only) 0924 Towards Comprehensive Training by Jean Fares and Olga Susana Puerto, November 2009 0923 Pre-Employment Skills Development Strategies in the OECD by Yoo Jeung Joy Nam, November 2009 0922 A Review of National Training Funds by Richard Johanson, November 2009 0921 Pre-Employment Vocational Education and Training in Korea by ChangKyun Chae and Jaeho Chung, November 2009 0920 Labor Laws in Eastern European and Central Asian Countries: Minimum Norms

and Practices by Arvo Kuddo, November 2009 (online only) 0919 Openness and Technological Innovation in East Asia: Have They Increased the

Demand for Skills? by Rita K. Almeida, October 2009 (online only) 0918 Employment Services and Active Labor Market Programs in Eastern European

and Central Asian Countries by Arvo Kuddo, October 2009 (online only) 0917 Productivity Increases in SMEs: With Special Emphasis on In-Service Training

of Workers in Korea by Kye Woo Lee, October 2009 (online only)

Page 88: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

0916 Firing Cost and Firm Size: A Study of Sri Lanka's Severance Pay System by Babatunde Abidoye, Peter F. Orazem and Milan Vodopivec, September 2009 (online only)

0915 Personal Opinions about the Social Security System and Informal Employment:

Evidence from Bulgaria by Valeria Perotti and Maria Laura Sánchez Puerta, September 2009

0914 Building a Targeting System for Bangladesh based on Proxy Means Testing by Iffath A. Sharif, August 2009 (online only) 0913 Savings for Unemployment in Good or Bad Times: Options for Developing

Countries by David Robalino, Milan Vodopivec and András Bodor, August 2009 (online

only) 0912 Social Protection for Migrants from the Pacific Islands in Australia and New

Zealand by Geoff Woolford, May 2009 (online only) 0911 Human Trafficking, Modern Day Slavery, and Economic Exploitation

by Johannes Koettl, May 2009 0910 Unemployment Insurance Savings Accounts in Latin America: Overview and

Assessment by Ana M. Ferrer and W. Craig Riddell, June 2009 (online only) 0909 Definitions, Good Practices, and Global Estimates on the Status of Social

Protection for International Migrants by Johanna Avato, Johannes Koettl, and Rachel Sabates-Wheeler, May 2009

(online only) 0908 Regional Overview of Social Protection for Non-Citizens in the Southern

African Development Community (SADC) by Marius Olivier, May 2009 (online only)

0907 Introducing Unemployment Insurance to Developing Countries by Milan Vodopivec, May 2009 (online only) 0906 Social Protection for Refugees and Asylum Seekers in the Southern Africa

Development Community (SADC) by Mpho Makhema, April 2009 (online only) 0905 How to Make Public Works Work: A Review of the Experiences by Carlo del Ninno, Kalanidhi Subbarao and Annamaria Milazzo, May 2009

(online only) 0904 Slavery and Human Trafficking: International Law and the Role of the World

Bank by María Fernanda Perez Solla, April 2009 (online only)

Page 89: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

0903 Pension Systems for the Informal Sector in Asia edited by Landis MacKellar, March 2009 (online only) 0902 Structural Educational Reform: Evidence from a Teacher’s Displacement

Program in Armenia by Arvo Kuddo, January 2009 (online only) 0901 Non-performance of the Severance Pay Program in Slovenia by Milan Vodopivec, Lilijana Madzar, Primož Dolenc, January 2009 (online

only)

To view Social Protection Discussion papers published prior to 2009, please visit www.worldbank.org/sp.

Page 90: International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage: Concepts and Experience

Summary Findings

In this paper, full portability of health-cost coverage is taken to mean that mobile individuals can, at a minimum, find comparable continuation of coverage under a different system and that this does not impose external costs or benefits on other members of the systems in the source and destination countries. Both of these aspects needs to be addressed in a meaningful portability framework for health systems, as lacking or incomplete portability may not only lead to significant losses in coverage for an individual who considers becoming mobile – which may impede mobility that is otherwise likely to be beneficial. It may also lead to financial losses, or windfall gains, for sources of health-cost funding which can ultimately lead to a detrimental process of risk segmentation across national health systems.

HUMAN DEVELOPMENT NETWORK

About this series...Social Protection Discussion Papers are published to communicate the results of The World Bank’s work to the development community with the least possible delay. The typescript manuscript of this paper therefore has not been prepared in accordance with the procedures appropriate to formally edited texts. The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed herein are those of the author(s), and do not necessarily reflect the views of the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank and its affiliated organizations, or those of the Executive Directors of The World Bank or the governments they represent. The World Bank does not guarantee the accuracy of the data included in this work.

For more information, please contact the Social Protection Advisory Service, The World Bank, 1818 H Street, N.W., Room G7-703, Washington, D.C. 20433 USA. Telephone: (202) 458-5267, Fax: (202) 614-0471, E-mail: [email protected] or visit the Social Protection website at www.worldbank.org/sp.

International Portability of Health-Cost Coverage:Concepts and Experience

Martin Werding Stuart McLennan

S P D I S C U S S I O N P A P E R

July 2011

NO. 1115