hours worked over the business cycle in oecd countries · pdf file ·...

44
Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 - 2010 Lee E. Ohanian y UCLA Andrea R. Ra/o z Federal Reserve Board Abstract This paper constructs a new dataset for total hours worked at the quarterly frequency for 14 OECDcountries over the last fty years. We nd that key cyclical features of labor markets across countries di/er markedly from the empirical regularities reported in the literature based on just U.S. data or on international employment data. We document that total hours in many OECD countries are about as volatile as output, that the volatility of total hours relative to output volatility has increased over time in almost all countries, and a large fraction of labor market adjustment takes place along the intesive margin outside the United States. We also nd a number of puzzles regarding labor wedges in Europe. In recessions, the cyclical labor wedges for European countries constructed using employment appear to be much too large, while the labor wedges constructed using hours appear to be much too small. The Great Recession in many OECD countries represents a major puzzle in that both hours-based and employment-based labor wedges are roughly zero, while those in the U.S. Great Recession - and those in previous European recessions - are roughly an order We thank our discussant, T. Van Rens, and participants at the 77 th Meeting of the Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy "Advances in Labor Market Dynamics". Michelle Olivier provided outstanding research assistance. The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not be interpreted as reecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any other person associated with the Federal Reserve System. y Corresponding authors: [email protected] z Email: andrea.ra/[email protected]

Upload: lynhan

Post on 25-Mar-2018

212 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Hours Worked over the Business Cycle inOECD Countries, 1960 - 2010∗

Lee E. Ohanian†

UCLAAndrea R. Raffo‡

Federal Reserve Board

Abstract

This paper constructs a new dataset for total hours worked at the quarterly frequency

for 14 OECD countries over the last fifty years. We find that key cyclical features of labor

markets across countries differ markedly from the empirical regularities reported in the

literature based on just U.S. data or on international employment data. We document that

total hours in many OECD countries are about as volatile as output, that the volatility of

total hours relative to output volatility has increased over time in almost all countries, and

a large fraction of labor market adjustment takes place along the intesive margin outside

the United States. We also find a number of puzzles regarding labor wedges in Europe. In

recessions, the cyclical labor wedges for European countries constructed using employment

appear to be much too large, while the labor wedges constructed using hours appear to be

much too small. The Great Recession in many OECD countries represents a major puzzle in

that both hours-based and employment-based labor wedges are roughly zero, while those in

the U.S. Great Recession - and those in previous European recessions - are roughly an order

∗We thank our discussant, T. Van Rens, and participants at the 77th Meeting of the Carnegie-RochesterConference on Public Policy "Advances in Labor Market Dynamics". Michelle Olivier provided outstandingresearch assistance. The views in this paper are solely the responsibility of the authors and should not beinterpreted as reflecting the views of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System or of any otherperson associated with the Federal Reserve System.†Corresponding authors: [email protected]‡Email: [email protected]

Page 2: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

of magnitude larger. This indicates that understanding many OECD recessions requires

analyzing why and how their labor markets changed so much in the last few years, and

why these labor markets during recessions appear to be inconsistent with theories of firing

costs.

1

Page 3: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

1 Introduction

Documenting and understanding cyclical changes in hours worked has been a primary

focus of business cycle research since at least Kydland and Prescott (1982) and Hansen

(1985), and the very different labor market outcomes observed during the 2008-09 recession

across countries have generated renewed interest in the evolution of labor input during

fluctuations. However, this research has usually focused on the U.S. due to the very limited

availability of systematic measures of aggreate hours worked in other countries, including

other high income countries. Consequently, what is known about cyclical changes in labor

input and productivity in other countries is largely based on measures of employment.

This means that studies of cyclical fluctuations in other countries largely abstract from

documenting and analyzing changes in the intensive labor margin, and that these studies

of international fluctuations are not comparable to analyses of U.S. fluctuations. This

omission of the intensive margin is an important limitation for a number of reasons. One

reason is that it limits the extent that conclusions about cyclical changes in labor can be

drawn across these countries. Another is because it is generally accepted that hiring and

firing costs are much higher in Europe than in the U.S., which suggests that the relative

size of fluctuations in the intensive versus extensive margin may be very different. Since at

least the influential work of Hopenhayn and Rogerson (1993), many economists argue that

European labor markets provide an excellent setting for quantifying the impact of labor

market distortions and policies, but this laboratory is significantly limited for addressing

cyclical fluctuations due to data limitations on hours worked.

This paper addresses these shortcomings by first constructing a new dataset for total

hours worked at the quarterly frequency which covers 14 OECD countries and spans the

last fifty years. The dataset draws on a variety of international sources, including data from

national statistical offi ces, establishment surveys, and household surveys. There are two

contributions. One is to provide the most comprehensive, international database of hours

2

Page 4: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

worked that can be used by other researchers. The second is to document and interpret

cyclical fluctuations in hours by comparing fluctuations between the U.S. and other coun-

tries, with a focus on the relative importance of hours per worker versus employment as

a determinant of changes in hours worked, the cyclical properties of hours versus employ-

ment, and the cyclical patterns of the labor and productivity wedges and their implications

for understanding fluctuations.

This paper addresses these issues by presenting quarterly measures of total hours worked

for a number of OECD countries from 1960 to 2010. We construct these measures con-

sistently across countries according to national income and product account constructs.

We use these measures to compare business cycle properties of total hours worked across

OECD countries, including the U.S. We focus our analysis on three questions: (1) How

sensitive are accepted business cycle features in OECD countries based on employment to

using hours? (2) What fraction of fluctuations in labor are due to hours versus employ-

ment, and how have these features changed over time? (3) What fraction of fluctuations in

output and labor across countries is accounted for by labor versus productivity wedges? (4)

How does the Great Recession in other OECD countries, using hours versus employment,

compare to that in the U.S.?

This last question is important, as Ohanian (2010) documents large differences in this

recession between the U.S. and other advanced economies. He finds that in the U.S.,

productivity is close to trend, and that the U.S. Great recession is almost entirely due to

a very large decline in hours worked. Moreover, the source of lower U.S. hours is related

to an historically large distortion in the relationship between the aggregate marginal rate

of substitution between consumption and leisure and aggregate labor productivity. In the

other G7 countries, in which labor input is measured using employment, he finds that the

Great Recession is largely the consequence of large productivity declines, with only very

small employment declines and no distortion in the marginal rate of substitution -marginal

product of labor relationship. This paper uses hours worked to re-assess Ohanian’s analysis

3

Page 5: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

of the Great Recession, which is important to pursue, as the small changes in Western

European employment may reflect large firing costs, and that labor may have declined

considerably through declines in hours per worker.

Our main findings contrast with commonly held views in some cases, and raise sig-

nificant puzzles in other cases. Specifically, employment is a poor proxy for labor input

in many OECD countries, as changes in hours per worker are about as large as changes

in employment. We also find that employment-based labor wedges are much too large in

Europe, given high European firing costs, while hours-based labor wedges are much too

small. Finally, we find that the Great Recession is a substantial puzzle in Europe, as both

employment-based and hours-based labor wedges are nearly zero in many European coun-

tries. This stands in sharp contrast to labor wedges in the U.S. during the Great Recession,

or wedges in other European recessions, both of which are an order of magnitude larger.

The paper is organized as follows. Section 2 describes the data sources and the approach

we use to construct the hours measures. Section 3 compares standard business cycle fea-

tures, including the cyclical volatility of hours, employment, and productivity, and their

correlation with output across countries. Section 4 uses the business cycle accounting ap-

proach developed by Cole and Ohanian (2002), and Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2007),

to construct labor and productivity wedges using both emloyment and hours for recessions

since 1960, with a specific focus on assessing the relative importance of these wedges during

the Great Recession. Section 5 concludes.

2 Data

In this section, we briefly discuss our methodology to construct time-series of hours per

worker across countries. The Appendix presents details about the country-specific estima-

tion procedures and sources.

Hours per worker

4

Page 6: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Offi cial series for quarterly hours worked in advanced economies are typically short

and their comparability across coutries is often considered problematic. In our sample,

hours worked series collected from the national agencies start around 1980. Moreover, the

underlying surveys used to construct these series, whether sampling establishments or the

labor force, are not uniform across countries and, in some cases, for the same country at

two different dates.

Establishments surveys have been conducted in many countries at a quarterly or even

monthly frequency since the 1960s, but they often collect hours paid for and not hours

actually worked for. Thus, they do not account for differences across countries in important

elements of labor contracts such as paid vacation or sick days. In addition, these surveys

do not sample all sectors of the economy. For instance, the government sector is often

neglected by these surveys.

Labor force surveys tend to be more comprehensive since they sample directly indi-

viduals in the labor force, but they suffer from several shortcomings as well. First, it is

well-known that these surveys present an upward bias for the estimated working time due

to self-reporting. In addition, there are methodological differences across countries in the

construction of these surveys which might also affect the concept of working time measured,

thus undermining their comparability1. Last, but not least, in many countries labor force

surveys have been conducted primarily at a annual frequency until very recently.

Our methodology to construct quarterly series of hours per worker consists of three

elements, namely a dataset of annual hours worked that deals with the aforementioned

issues, a dataset of quarterly indicators for hours worked (which we construct), and a

procedure to adjust the quarterly indicators using the information contained in the annual

dataset.1For instance, some countries do not include in their questionnaires a distinction between contractual

hours and hours not worked because of illness or holidays.

5

Page 7: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Annual estimates of hours worked are currently available through the Conference Board

Total Economy Database (TED). This database, originally developed by the Groningen

Growth and Development Centre (GGDC) and subsequently updated in partnership with

the Conference Board, is the main source of estimates of hours worked per person employed

that are somewhat comparable across countries. These series are adjusted to reflect most

sources of variation in hours worked (contracted length of the workweek, statutory holidays,

paid vacation and sick days, days lost due to strikes) and are consistent with aggregate

measures of output. The TED dataset covers a large set of developed and developing

countries, in many cases starting in the 1950s, and is currently the benchmark source of

data for analysis of trends in hours worked across countries2.

We construct a dataset of quarterly indicators of hours per worker as follows. For

all countries, we first collect offi cial series of hours per worker that are consistent with

the national accounts from national agencies3. We then extend the offi cial series using

measures of hours per worker collected from the International Labor Offi ce (ILO) and from

the OECD Main Economic Indicators (MEI)4. Although both publications are constructed

primarily using information from establishment surveys, we opted for adopting the ILO

series to extend the offi cial series for three main reasons:

(1) The ILO series often measure total hours actually worked, and not just paid for;

(2) The ILO series cover the non-agricultural sector (i.e. manufacturing, mining and

quarrying, construction, commerce, transport and services) whereas the OECD-MEI series

typically cover the manufacturing sector only;

(3) The ILO series have statistical properties in terms of trends and variability closer

to the offi cial series, suggesting that the underlying surveys were primary sources used by

the national agencies.

2See, for instance, Rogerson [2006], Ohanian et al. [2008].3The Japanese series excludes the agriculture sector, so we construct an employment-weighted series

using annual levels in this sector as estimated in the EU-Klems database.4In particular, we used several paper issues of the ILO Bulletin of Labor Statistics and the ILO Inter-

national Labour Review.

6

Page 8: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

We then construct our extended series for hours per worker as follows. For each country

i, we estimate an econometric model of the offi cial hours series (hit) as a function of a

constant (c), current and lagged values of the ILO hours series(h̃it−k

), and a time trend:

hit = c+ β0h̃it + ...βkh̃

it−k + γt+ εit

A growing literature has documented that the volatility of output has declined sig-

nificantly after 1984 (Great Moderation). In this spirit, we only use observations up to

1984Q4 to estimate this model to document the behavior of labor input before and after

1984. We select the parameter governing the lag length (k) using standard information

criteria (Akaike and Schwarz) and perform Lagrange Multiplier tests on the residuals to

test whether the residuals are white noise. Using the coeffi cient estimates, we then extrap-

olate the offi cial hours series backwards to the early1960s. This estimation procedure is

applied to Australia, Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, Norway, and Sweden. Since

the offi cial series for Austria, Finland, Ireland, and Korea start after 1984, we use the entire

sample to extrapolate the offi cial series for these countries. No estimation is applied to the

United States (the BLS series we use begins in 1947) and the United Kingdom (for which

only the offi cial series, which starts in 1971, is available)5.

Finally, we use Denton’s (1971) method to adjust our constructed quarterly indicators

with the TED values. This method minimizes the (weighted) adjustments imposed on the

constructed quarterly indicator subject to the constraint that the sum of the quarterly ad-

justed series equals the value of the annual TED series. Specifically, we chose the weigthing

matrix in order to minimize the distance between the growth rates of the adjusted and the

indicator quarterly series, so that no discontinuity emerges at the end of each year as a

result of the adjustment6. The table below presents the countries and their time periods

5Eurostat produces a series of hours per worker in Spain which starts in 1995. However, we were notable to find consistent survey data covering the previous years. Thus, we opted to include Spain only inthe analysis of the Great Recession.

6This would be the case if we were to choose to simply allocate pro rata the discrepancy in a given yearin each quarter (i.e. the weigthing matrix is the identity matrix). For a more articulated discussion on the

7

Page 9: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

considered in our sample.

Table 1. Hours per Worker: Sample

Australia 1970-2010 Italy 1960-2010Austria 1965-2010 Japan 1960-2010Canada 1960-2010 Korea 1970-2009Finland 1960-2010 Norway 1960-2010France 1960-2010 Sweden 1975-2010Germany 1960-2010 UK 1971-2010Ireland 1960-2010 U.S. 1960-2010

Other data

Data on employment, unemployment and population aged 16-64 are from collected from

national statistical offi ces and the OECD-Economic Outlook database. We construct labor

force participation as the sum of employment and unemployment. Our wage series are

(nominal) total compensation as constructed from the National Accounts and are obtained

from the OECD. We first divide these series by total hours so as to obtain a measure of

nominal compensation per hours and then deflate them using the country-specific GDP

deflators.

National accounts series for nominal variables (output, consumption, public consump-

tion, and investment) are from the OECD-Economic Outlook and are deflated using their

specific price deflator.

3 Descriptive Statistics

This section presents volatility and correlation measures of our constructed hours work with

other variables and compares them to employment. We construct total hours worked (Ht)

implications of alternative weighting matrix, see Denton (1971). For a broader discussion about interpola-tion methods, the reader is invited to check the Handbook of Quarterly National Accounts Compilation.Incidentally, the BLS uses this methodology to derive quarterly estimates of U.S. manufacturing output.

8

Page 10: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

as the product of average hours worked per worker (ht) and employment (Et), normalized

by the size of the population aged 15-64 years old (Pt).

Ht =ht

h∗ EtPt

(1)

Since we are also interested in the role of the intensive and the extensive margin in

response to business cycle shocks, we further decompose the employment rate into the

product of the labor force participation rate (LFPt) and the employment to labor force

rate (i.e. one minus the unemployment rate ut). That is,

Ht =ht

h∗ Et + Ut

Pt∗(1− Ut

Et + Ut

)(2)

Ht =ht

h∗ LFPt ∗ (1− ut)

Throughout the analysis, statistics refer to the first difference of the natural logarithm

of the series, as often reported in the empirical literature7.

3.1 Total Hours: Volatility and Correlation

Table 2 presents the volatility of total hours worked and the volatility of output, together

with the ratio between the two volatilities, for G-7 countries (Canada, France, Germany,

Italy, Japan, the U.K., and the U.S.) plus the mean and the median of the distribution

of countries contained in our dataset. The bottom panels of the table present these same

statistics for the pre- and post-1984 periods.

[Insert Table 2 here]

7See, for instance, Gali’ [1999], Fisher [2007], Gali’ and Gambetti [2010], Barnichon [2010]. Resultsusing HP-filter and BP-filter are also available upon request.

9

Page 11: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Table 2 shows that, across countries, total hours are as volatile as output over the busi-

ness cycle, thus confirming the typical pattern documented in U.S. data. As documented

in Gali’ and Gambetti [2010] (GG hanceforth), the absolute volatility of total hours in

the post1984 period has declined in the United States, but it has increased relative to

the volatility of output. Among G-7 countries, we find that this pattern is also present

in Canada, France, Italy, and, to a lesser extent, in Germany, but not in Japan and the

United Kingdom. More generally, the volatility of total hours across countries has, on av-

erage, increased both in absolute terms and relative to output. Since GG interpret the U.S.

evidence as consistent with an increase in labor market flexibility, our findings suggest that

this explanation should be tested against the various outcomes observed across countries.

Different labor market institutions, such as firing costs, generous unemployment bene-

fits, but also work-sharing arrangements, are likely to affect the extent to which firms adjust

labor input along the extensive or the intensive margin. To shed some light on this issue,

we further decompose the extensive margin into changes in labor force participation and

changes in employment relative to the labor force (i.e. one minus the unemployment rate).

Then, we calculate what fraction of the variance of the (first difference of the logarithm

of) total hours can be accounted for by changes in hours per worker, changes in labor force

participation rate, and changes in the employment to labor force rate. Table 3 presents the

result of this calculation.8

[Insert Table 3 here]

Two striking facts emerge. First, the adjustment in labor input across countries is,

on average, equally distributed between intensive and extensive margin. This result is in

sharp contrast with the standard characterization of labor market dynamics obtained by

looking at U.S. data, where about one third of the volatility of total hours is accounted

8We allocate the sum of all covariance terms equally among the three terms so that the share sum upto one.

10

Page 12: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

for by changes in hours per worker, and two-thirds by employment9. Second, the intensive

margin has, quantitatively, become more important over time, with changes in hours per

worker accounting for almost 65 percent of the variance of total hours in the post-1984

period. However, the contribution of changes in the employment to labor force ratio to

the variance of total hours has remained nearly constant, whereas changes in and out of

the labor force have become less responsive to cyclical conditions. Overall, these findings

are consistent with the idea that firing costs and other labor market rigidities vary to a

great deal across countries and their economic relevance has, on average, increased over

time, thus limiting the ability of firms to vary employment levels over the cycle. All told,

these two facts also suggest that the unemployment rate might be a poor indicator of labor

market conditions outside the United States, thus warranting a more general attention to

the response of total labor input to business cycle shocks.

We next analyze how the cyclical properties of total hours vary across countries and

over time in terms of comovement with output and between the extensive and the in-

stensive margin. Chart 1 presents correlation of total hours with output over the whole

sample (panel a) and in the pre- and post-1984 period (panel b). Total hours appear to be

procyclical, as typically implied by general equilibrium models, but the magnitude of this

correlation varies significantly across countries. In particular, total hours are procyclical in

Germany and the United States, but essentially acyclical in Italy and Japan. The average

correlation with output is about 0.3, lower than typically reported in the literature. Over

time, total hours have become somewhat more correlated with output in the post-1984

period, but the increase is marginal. Interestingly, this correlation has actually declined in

the United States (see also GG on this observation) and in all other G-7 countries excluding

Canada and France. In Japan, the correlation between total hours and output has actually

turned slightly negative.

9These figures for the United States are reported, among others, in Kydland [1995], Cho and Cooley[1994], Hall [2007].

11

Page 13: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

[Insert Chart 1 here]

Turning to the intensive and extensive margin (panels c and d) we note two important

patterns. First, hours per worker and employment are only weakly correlated, suggesting

the timing of the adjustment between the two margins is not contemporaneous. Second,

this correlation has weakened significantly over time, becoming even negative in France,

Germany, and Italy.

3.2 Labor Productivity: Volatility and Correlation

We construct series for labor productivity as the ratio between real output and total hours

and present its properties across countries and over time. As shown in Table 4, labor

productivity tends to be slightly more volatile than output, with the average value for the

ratio of volatilities near 1.2. Among G-7 countries, productivity is more valatile than output

in France, Italy, and Japan, and less volatile in the remaining countries. As documented in

GG, the volatility of labor productivity in the United States has fallen significantly during

the Great Moderation, but it has in increased relative to output volatility.10 We find that

this is the case in our sample of countries as well, with notable expection being Japan

and, to a lesser extent, Germany, where the absolute volatility has increased overtime. In

sum, our evidence suggest that the Great Moderation has been associated with an overall

decline in the volatility of productivity but an increase in the volatility of total hours.

Both variables have actually become more volatile than output in the post-1984 period.

Since a proportional reduction in the variance of the shocks generating fluctuations would

have preserved relative volatilities, our evidence is consistent with the hypothesis that the

Great Moderation was not due to "good luck". Yet, the variety of outcomes observed

across countries in terms of changes in absolute volatilities and magnitude of these changes

warrant a more systematic investigation of the structural changes proposed in the literature.10We note that in our data the increase in the U.S. volatility of labor productivity is less marked than

in the GG’s dataset. This difference might be due to the fact that we use measures of output and totalhours for the whole economy, whereas GG use series that refer to the nonfarm business sector only.

12

Page 14: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

[Insert Table 4 here]

In the U.S. data, it is a well-established fact that labor productivity and total hours are

weakly correlated, a feature of the data that is diffi cult to account for in a standard real

business cycle model à la Kydland and Prescott. Benhabib et al. [1991] show that a model

that incorporates home production is able to reproduce the low correlation between hours

and labor productivity. Christiano and Eichenbaum [1992], on the other hand, consider

shocks to government expenditure, and the wealth effect associated with these shocks, as

a key mechanism to account for this correlation. In addition, GG document that this

correlation has been falling over time and the evidence provided in Barnichon [2010] is

also consistent with this finding. GG concludes that the change in the productivity-hours

correlation and in the volatility of hours over time are clearly inconsistent with a strong

version of the good luck hypothesis to explain the Great Moderation (i.e. the variance of

all shocks affecting the cycle has experienced a roughly proportional fall). Similarly, the

cyclical properties of labor productivity vis-à-vis output bear important implications on the

nature of fluctuations driving business cycles.11 Thus, since the sign of these correlations

and their time changes have received much attention, it is important to explore what the

international data imply for these features of the data. Chart 2 summarizes the evidence

on these moments.

[Insert Chart 2 here]

We find that, over the period 1960-2007, labor productivity has been procyclical, with

the average correlation around 0.6 (panel a). Among G-7 countries, productivity tends

to be strongly procyclical in European countries and Japan, whereas in the United States

and Canada this correlation is in line with the average value. However, this correlation

11Gali’and van Rens [2010] argue that a reduction in labor market frictions can account for these factstogether with the increase in the volatility of real wages that occurred during the Great Moderation.

13

Page 15: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

has generally weakend over time (panel b), thus suggesting that the evidence provided in

GG and Gali’and Van Rens [2010] (GVR henceforth) applies to a larger set of advanced

economies. Nevertheless, we note that even in the post-1984 sample, labor productivity

remains procyclical.

The negative correlation between labor productivity and total hours, found in the U.S.

data, is also a robust feature across countries. We find that this correlation is negative for

the United States (nearly -0.25) and the cross-country average is even more negative (-0.45).

Among G-7 countries Italy stands out as an outlier on the low end of the distribution (-0.6)

while Germany on the high end (-0.13). We also provide evidence that this correlation has

declined in the post-1984 period, in accordance with the U.S. evidence. The decline has

been particularly pronounced in the United Kingdom, where the sign of this correlation

has indeed switched sign.

3.3 Real Wages, Total Hours, and Labor Productivity

So far we have focused our attention on describing the behavior of total hours worked and

labor productivity across countries and over time making use of the new dataset constructed

for this analysis. We next turn to the cyclical patterns observed in real wages and the

interaction between labor input and wages.

[Insert Table 5 here]

As shown in Table 5, real wages, constructed as real total compensation per hour, are

quite volatile over the cycle as they fluctuate more than output, labor productivity, and

total hours worked in almost all countries. Among G-7 countries, the absolute volatility

of real wages has increased over time only in the United States, as also reported in GVR,

whereas it has declined dramatically in France, Italy, and the United Kingdom. On average,

the absolute volatility of real wages has edged down across countries.

14

Page 16: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Perhaps more remarkable is the observation that real wages have become more volatile

relative to output and, to a lesser extent, labor productivity in the post-1984 period. Once

again, there is quite a bit of variation across countries, with the Great Moderation in Italy,

the United Kingdom, and the United States associated with sharp increases in real wage

volatility relative to output volatility. Interestingly, the volatility of wages relative to total

hours worked has declined significantly after 1984, consistent with our earlier finding that

hours have become much more volatile during the Great Moderation. Canada and the

United States stand out as countries where the volatility of wages relative to total hours

has instead increased.

[Insert Chart 3 here]

The cyclical properties of wages are presented in Chart 3. We note that wages are

acyclical, with the correlation with output even falling over time (top panels). Along this

dimension, the variation across countries is also limited. The correlation with hours, how-

ever, is strongly negative across countries, with France, Italy, and the United Kingdom

standing out. In the post-1984 period this correlation has, on average, become more neg-

ative. Finally, wages tend to closely follow the behavior of labor productivity and this

relationship has generally strengthened over time, with the notable exception of the United

States.

4 Business Cycle Diagnostics

4.1 The Diagnostic Framework

Cole and Ohanian (2002) and Chari, Kehoe, and McGrattan (2007) present a diagnostic

methodology for broadly evaluating the classes of theories that may potentially account

for fluctuations. This process has been used implicitly in one form or another by much of

the real business cycle literature, including Kydland and Prescott (1982), and in general

15

Page 17: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

equilibrium analyses of fluctuations that focus on channels other than productivity, includ-

ing Hall (1997), Cole and Ohanian (2004), Gali’, Gertler, and Lopez-Salido (2007), Shimer

(2009), and Mulligan (2010).

This process involves using time series data on output, consumption, investment, and

labor input to measure wedges from the first order conditions in a parameterized optimal

growth model, and then use those wedges as diagnostics for constructing economic theories

of fluctuations. This section uses this analytical framework to measure such wedges in

two ways. For the sample of OECD countries considered, we first construct these wedges

using the standard measure of employment as labor input, and we then compare them to

wedges constructed using the measures of hours worked reported earlier in this paper as

the measure of labor input.

The theoretical framework is given as follows. Preferences are:

maxE0

∞∑t=0

βt{ln(Ct) + φ ln(1− Lt)}.

The technology, resource constraint and the law of motion for capital are given by:

AKθt L

1−θt = Yt = Ct + It +Gt,

(1 + g)Kt+1 = (1− δ)Kt + It,

where the variables are, respectively, per-capita measures of consumption (C), fraction of

time devoted to market activities (L), capital stock (K), real output (Y ), investment (I),

and government spending (G). The variable A denotes total factor productivity, and g is the

exogenous growth rate of technology, respectively. All per-capita variables are detrended

at a two percent annual rate. The appendix describes the sources and construction of these

data.

The parameters are chosen as follows. We set β to 0.99, θ = 0.36, δ = .0175, g = .005,

16

Page 18: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

and φ is chosen so that steady state hours worked is 1/3 of the time endowment. Typically,

this framework is used to construct four deviations, or wedges: (1) a productivity wedge,

which is the Solow Residual, (2) a labor wedge, which is the difference between the marginal

rate of substitution between consumption and leisure and the marginal product of labor, (3)

a capital market wedge, which is the difference between the intertemporal marginal rate of

substitution and the return to capital, and (4) a resource constraint wedge that measures

changes in the allocation of output between consumption, investment, and government

spending. We will focus on productivity and labor wedges as these are typically the most

important quantitatively in terms of accounting for fluctuations. These deviations are given

as:

Zt =Yt

AKθt L

1−θt

Xt =(1− θ)(Yt/Lt)(1− Lt)

φCt

For the U.S., we measure these wedges for all NBER recession dates from 1960 through

2007. For other countries, we measure the deviations using recession dates between 1960 and

2007 identified by the Economic Cycle Research Institute (ECRI), who use a methodology

to date recessions that is very similar to that of the NBER.

For the 2008-09 recession, we measure these wedges for all countries using common

dating, from 2008:1 - through 2009:4, which is the hours trough of the U.S. recession. We

use this trough dating convention because of our interest in the evolution of labor input,

and because labor continues to decline significantly following the NBER trough date. (For

other NBER recession trough dates, labor input is closer to its trough value).

This approach will allow us to compare our findings to those of Ohanian (2010), who

measured these deviations in the U.S. using both hours and employment as labor input,

but for the other G7 countries (Canada, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, and the United

Kingdom) used just employment as hours were unavailable. Note from these equations that

17

Page 19: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

the two alternative measures of labor input affect TFP, and in particular, the labor wedge.

We conduct separate analyses for the Great Recession, and for all other recessions. For

each of these analyses, we make two comparisons. We first measure the size of labor and

productivity distortions across countries using both employment and total hours worked.

To understand the relative importance of these deviations for fluctuations, we compare their

size to average trough recession levels of output and employment, and we then measure

the relative contributions of productivity and labor deviations by simulating the model

economy with each deviation individually, and measuring the fraction of output and labor

change accounted for by each distortion.

4.2 Cross-Country Differences in Employment Protection andImplications for Diagnostics

Before turning to the findings, we note that this collection of countries has very different

labor market institutions and regulations that are broadly defined as employment protection

legislation. The OECD produces employment protection rankings for OECD countries

that measures the strength of these policies, and we summarize the OECD’s ranking here

(OECD, 2004). The OECD index is based primarily on (i) the strength of protection of

permanent workers against individual dismissal, (ii) the specific requirements for collective

worker dismissal, and (iii) regulations on temporary employment contracts.

Several of the European countries studied here have relatively high levels of employment

protection. Specifically, Spain ranks 4th highest in protection (out of 28 countries), while

France is 6th, Sweden is 7th, Norway 8th, and Germany is 10th. At the other end of

the scale, the UK is 27th out of 28 countries, and moreover has employment protection

far below that of the other countries, and the U.S. has the least amount of employment

protection, and is ranked 28th.

These large cross-country differences in employment protection indicate large differences

in hiring and firing costs across countries, and thus provides an interesting way to interpret

18

Page 20: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

the findings we present below. Specifically, higher firing costs decrease the incentive to cut

workers during recessions, and at the same time, increase incentives to reduce hours per

worker in order to reduce labor input. This suggests we should observe particular cross-

country patterns in these deviations, including that the difference between hours-based

and employment-based labor deviations should be considerably larger for much of Western

Europe than for the United States and the UK.

4.3 Labor and TFP Wedges in OECD Recessions: 1960-2007

We first compare the size of recessions across countries to help understand the relative size

of the labor and productivity wedges we present below. Table 6 shows average trough levels

for real GDP and labor (both employment and hours) for several countries.

[Insert Table 6 here]

The data indicate that U.S. recessions were somewhat less volatile than European re-

cessions before 1983, but that U.S. recessions became much less volatile than European

recessions afterwards. Specifically, the average U.S. recession trough output level declined

by more than half after 1984 (-5.1 percent before 1984, to -2.2 percent afterwards), but

the average Western European trough output level was roughly unchanged over this pe-

riod (-5.3 percent before 1984 and -5.1 percent afterwards). This suggest that the Great

Moderation - as measured by recession troughs - was primarily a U.S. phenomenon, rather

than an international phenomenon.

We next present statistics on labor and productivity wedges at recession troughs. Table

7 shows the size of labor wedges for all recessions other than the Great Recession, and also

splits these recessions into two groups, recessions before the Great Moderation (1984 and

before) and those for the Great Moderation (1984 - 2007).

[Insert Table 7 here]

19

Page 21: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

The most striking finding regarding the labor wedges is that the European wedges at

recession troughs do not conform to the hypothesized patterns based on both cross-country

differences in hiring and firing costs and on the fact that the standard deviation of log-

differenced hours per worker is higher in most Western European economies than in the

U.S.. The fact that hours per worker is more variable in Europe suggests that their labor

wedges should differ considerably when measured using employment versus hours worked.

We begin with the U.S. labor wedges, where firing costs are are the lowest in the OECD’s

ranking. The U.S. labor wedges constructed using hours worked are about twice as large

during recessions compared to those constructed using employment (-2.8 percent compared

to -1.2 percent, measured using quarterly data from 1960 - 2007). The hours wedge is

about three times as large before 1984 (-3.0 percent compared to -1.1 percent), and there

is a small decline in the hours-based wedge during the Great Moderation.

We now compare these U.S. labor wedge values to those from Western Europe. The

European wedges feature two suprising patterns. One is that the employment-based labor

wedges are much larger than those in the U.S. Specifically, the size of these wedges should

be relatively low, ceteris paribus, as high firing costs should limit employment loss during

a recession. However, the European employment-based labor wedges are about four times

higher than those in the United States before 1984 and even higher during the Great Mod-

eration; the average for Western Europe for 1960 through 2007 is -4.9 percent, compared to

-1.2 percent for the U.S. This five-fold difference is also large even after correcting for the

fact that Western European recessions on average have been deeper than U.S. recessions.

The second suprising feature of these labor wedges is that the size of the hours-based

European wedges seem too small relative to the employment-based measures. To see this,

recall that the hours-based wedges in the U.S. are about twice as large as the employment-

based wedges. This ratio should tend to be larger in Europe because high firing costs

increase the incentive for European firms to adjust labor input more on the intensive

margin than the extensive margin (recall findings in Table 3), which is consistent with

20

Page 22: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

higher European firing costs.

We do not observe this pattern among the European wedges, and the difference between

the actual and hypothesized pattern is particularly striking during the period when firing

costs are relatively high. To see this, note that the hours-based labor wedge in Europe

is moderately higher than the employment-based wedge between 1960-1984, —6.6 percent,

versus -4.1 percent. However, the employment-based and hours-based wedges are about

the same magnitude after 1984 (-7.4 percent compared to -7.3 percent). This similarity

between the two wedges is striking because the anecdotal evidence and our measure of

EPL suggest that labor market rigidities have probably fallen overtime in Europe (many

European countries introduced labor market reforms in the 1990s) and yet the behavior of

the European labor wedge has diverged even more from the U.S. labor wedge.

These European recession wedge results are puzzling, both from the perspective of the

incentives associated with firing costs and the fact that the importance of the intensive

margin is higher in Europe. To resolve the observation that the volatility of the intensive

margin is higher in Europe, but that hours-labor wedges are relatively small, first note

that the volatility statistics on hours, employment, and hours per worker, reported earlier

were calculated for all time periods, whereas the labor wedges are those for peak-to-trough

calculations. We therefore constructed the labor wedge for all dates, and constructed the

standard deviation of both hours and employment-based wedge measures.

These statistics suggest that the reason that the European hours-based and employment-

based wedges are so similar is because the relative share of labor adjustment between hours

and employment during recession episodes are markedly different than during expansion

episodes. Specifically, the standard deviation of the log change in the hours-based labor

wedge in Western Europe measured during both recessions and expansions after 1984 is

about 40 percent higher than the employment-based wedge, compared to a difference of

about 18 percent in the U.S. This suggests that relatively less adjustment in labor input

takes place on the intensive margin during ECRI-dated recessions than during other times.

21

Page 23: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Before turning to TFP, we finally note that the labor wedge is countercyclical in most

countries, thus confirming that standard competitive models would underpredict the busi-

ness cycle fluctuations observed in hours worked, given the measured consumption to output

ratio. Yet, as extensively discussed in Shimer [2010], standard search frictions models as in

Mortensen and Pissarides (1994), which are the starting point of most research on imper-

fectly competitive labor markets, would also have problems in accounting for this property

of the data. These models, in fact, deliver a labor wedge that rises in booms and falls in

recession, which is counterfactual. Future research should then provide more insights in

explaining why the labor wedge is countercyclical and what accounts for the differential

behavior in the labor wedge across countries.

Table 8 compares TFP wedges across countries. For the U.S., since hours are more

variable than employment, TFP declines more during recessions for employment-based

labor than for hours-based labor (-2 percent for hours-TFP compared to -2.8 percent for

employment), and both measures decline considerably during the Great Moderation to -0.9

percent and -1.4 percent, respectively. These 50 percent declines in cyclical U.S. TFP is

consistent with the findings of Arias et al (2007), who report a similar drop in TFP volatility

and that such a decline can approximate the decline in the volatility of U.S. output and

hours.

[Insert Table 8 here]

In comparison with other countries, before 1984, Western Europe featured smaller re-

cession TFP declines for both hours-based and employment-based measures of labor input,

despite the fact that European recessions were somewhat deeper. However, this pattern of

relatively small Western European TFP declines is reversed during the Great Moderation,

as the large moderation in U.S. TFP decline is not mirrored in Europe. Specifically, both

hours-based and employment-based measures of European TFP are higher than their U.S.

counterparts after 1984 (-1.9 percent for hours, -1.8 percent for employment for Western

22

Page 24: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Europe, compared to -0.9 percent and -1.4 percent, respectively). These statistics also

indicate that the Great Moderation was primarily a U.S. event - that largely involved less

volatile productivity - and not an event that had a systematic impact in Europe.

4.4 OECD Labor and TFP wedges and Implications for the GreatRecession

We now turn to constucting these statistics for the Great Recession, with a focus on com-

paring the findings to those of Ohanian (2010). Ohanian finds that the productivity and

labor wedges differ remarkably between the U.S. and the other advanced countries during

the Great Recession. Specifically, he shows that the U.S. Great Recession is almost entirely

due to a very large decline in labor input that is associated with an historically large labor

wedge, and that productivity is on trend during this recession. In contrast, the recessions in

other G7 countries are virtually the opposite of that in the U.S., as other G7 recessions are

almost entirely due to negative productivity wedges, with only small employment declines

and with no quantiatively important labor wedges.

These very different patterns for the Great Recession between the U.S. and the other

G7 countries led Ohanian to suggest that the underlying source and/or propogation mech-

anisms for the Great Recession may have been very different between the U.S. and these

other countries, and that these different patterns pose a challenge for the widely held view

that all of these recessions were the result of similar banking crises that operated through

the same economic channels. But Ohanian’s analysis for the other G7 countries was based

entirely on employment. We now assess whether quantitatively import labor wedges emerge

in the other countries when hours rather than employment are used as labor input.

[Insert Table 9 here]

Table 9 shows output, labor, labor wedge and productivity wedge for the Great Re-

cession across countries. There are two key findings. First, when we use total hours as

23

Page 25: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

labor input instead of employment in constructing the labor and productivity wedges in

non-U.S. countries we find that the size of labor wedges for Western Europe is essentially

unchanged. Specifically, note that the U.S. hours-labor wedge is nearly -10 percent at the

trough of U.S. hours worked in the Great Recession, while the hours-labor wedge is only

-0.7 percent on average for Western Europe and is little different from its value measured

using employment (0.1 percent).

The second key finding is that the European labor wedges - measured using hours or

employment - are remarkably small during the Great Recession when compared to their

size during previous recessions described above. To see this, we compare the relative size

of labor wedges and output loss during the Great Recession to all other recessions. The

average peak-to-trough hours-labor wedge for Western Europe between 1960 and 2007 was

about 6 percent, when output fell about 5 percent. These numbers for the Great Recession,

in contrast, are about 1 percent and 9 percent, respectively. This implies that if the pre-

Great Recession relationship between the labor wedge and output was also operative during

the Great Recession, then the hours-labor wedge would have been around 11 percent (given

the 9 percent output decline), more than an order of magnitude bigger than it was.

Not surprisingly, the labor wedge accounts for very little of the Great Recession in

Europe. Table 10 shows the percentage of trough output and labor accounted for by the

model in response to the labor wedge and the productivity wedge, using both employment

and hours worked as labor input.12 While the U.S. hours-labor wedge accounts for almost

all of U.S. output, and more than the full decline in hours worked, the European hours-

labor wedge accounts for very little of the drop in European output and hours. In contrast,

productivity in the U.S. explains only about 30 percent of the drop in output, and almost

none of the drop in hours in the U.S., whereas productivity overaccounts for output and

hours on average in Western Europe.

[Insert Table 10 here]12We label these experiments as Model 1-4.

24

Page 26: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

These large differences in the size of labor and productivity wedges, and their relative

contributions to the Great Recession across countries, pose a challenge for the common view

that the coincident recessions across countries in 2008-2009 were the consequence of very

similar banking crises that depressed economies through very similar economic channels

and forces. Instead, these results point to considerable differences between the U.S. and

Western Europe, and suggest that different economic forces were operative in the U.S.

compared to much of Western Europe.

Moreover, the fact that both hours and employment labor wedges are about an order of

magnitude smaller than their normal recession size during the Great Recession in Europe

raises an additional, and intriguing, puzzle of : why were the dynamics of employment and

hours per worker so much different during the worst postwar European recession compared

to other recessions?

While the results indeed indicate that the U.S. is an outlier compared to much of

Western Europe, Table 9 and Table 10 also presents the labor and productivity wedges

for some OECD countries that were not analyzed by Ohanian (2010). In particular, both

Spain and Ireland have very large labor wedges (around -15 percent), measured using either

hours or employment. This similarity between the U.S., Spain, and Ireland suggests a new

avenue for understanding cross-country experiences. One possibility relates to the housing

market. Specifically, some economists have argued that in the U.S., very large housing

price declines, coupled with government policies designed to cushion the impact of falling

prices on borrowers, including mortgage modification programs, changed the incentives for

unemployed individuals to take new jobs or for homeowners to relocate from relatively

depressed areas to areas with better job prospects (see Mulligan, 2008, and Herkenhoff and

Ohanian, forthcoming).

While it is beyond the scope of this paper to pursue this idea in detail, we do present

some limited evidence on the relationship between the labor market and housing. Chart

4 shows percentage changes in house prices and construction employment for the U.S.,

25

Page 27: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Canada, Western Europe (as defined in the previous tables), Spain, and Ireland.13 It is

interesting that the three countries which have large labor wedges - the U.S., Spain, and

Ireland - have also experienced large declines in house prices and construction activity.

[Insert Chart 4 here]

5 Summary and Conclusions

Cyclical labor fluctuations are a central focus of business cycle research, but this research

has been significantly limited by the fact that typically only employment, rather than total

hours worked, is available for many OECD countries. This paper has constructed quarterly

time series of total hours worked for 14 OECD countries covering the past 50 years of

history, with a focus on constructing hours that are consistent with national income and

product account constructs. These hours measures provide new labor data that can be

used by others studying international fluctuations.

We present empirical regularities across countries that stand in sharp contrast to many

common views about cyclical labor market dynamics. First, we show that for several coun-

tries employment is a very poor proxy for cyclical labor input, and consequently provides

poor measures of productivity, as about 50 percent of labor adjustment occurs along the

intensive margin. Another finding is that employment fluctuations in much of Western Eu-

rope appear to be much too high compared to the U.S., given much higher hiring and firing

costs in Europe. And given the large fluctuations in European hours, employment-based

labor wedge fluctuations in Europe are too high, and hours-based labor wedge fluctuations

are too low. Our findings also have implications for the international Great Recession.

13We obtain house price series from the OECD. However, there are some issues about the comparabilityof these measures across countries as the underlying methodology adopted by individual countries mayvary quite dramatically. For instance, the series for Spain, which is based on appraisals, is believed tounderestimate the actual decline in house prices. Similarly, for the United States, the CoreLogic NationalPrice House Index and the Case-Shiller index show, over the same time period, a 35 percent drop in houseprices, whereas the OECD series is based on the FHFA index.

26

Page 28: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Specifically, there is a common view that the Great Recession across countries was the

result of very similar responses to very similar banking crises. The findings presented here

contrast with that view, as Western European recessions feature very small labor wedges

compared to the U.S., measured either with employment or hours, and instead feature

much larger productivity shocks than the U.S..

Future research should aim to address these puzzles, with a focus on understanding why

the intensive margin adjustment is so small during European recessions, and why labor

wedges are virtually non-existant in many European countries during the Great Recession,

and why they are so large in the U.S..

27

Page 29: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

References

[1] Arias, A., Hansen, G. and L., Ohanian, [2007], "Why Have Business Cycle Fluctuations

Become less Volatile?", Economic Theory, vol. 32, 1, 43-58.

[2] Barnichon, R. [2010], "Productivity and Unemployment over the Business Cycle",

Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 57, 1013-1025.

[3] Benhabib, J., Rogerson, R., and R., Wright, [1991], "Homework in Macroeconomics:

Household Production and Aggregate Fluctuations", Journal of Political Economy,

vol. 99, 6, 1166-87.

[4] Christiano, L.J. and M. Eichenbaum, [1992], "Current Real Business Cycle Theories

and Aggregate Labor Market Fluctuations", American Economic Review, 82, 430-50.

[5] Chari, V. V., P. J. Kehoe, and E. R. McGrattan, [2007], "Business Cycle Accounting",

Econometrica 75(3): 781-836.

[6] Cho, J. and T. F. Cooley, [1994], "Employment and Hours over the Business Cycle",

Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 18, 411-432.

[7] Cole, H. and L. Ohanian [2004], "The U.S. and U.K. Great Depressions Through the

Lens of Neoclassical Growth Theory", American Economic Review, vol. 92, 2, 28-32.

[8] Cole, H. and L. Ohanian [2004], "New Deal Policies and the Persistence of the Great

Depression: A General Equilibrium Analysis", Journal of Political Economy, vol. 112,

4, 779-816.

[9] Denton, F.T., [1971], "Adjustment of Monthly or Quarterly Series to Annual Totals:

An Approach Based on Quadratic Minimization", Journal of the American Statistical

Association, vol. 66, 333, 99-102.

28

Page 30: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

[10] "The Conference Board Total Economy Database", January 2011, available at

http://www.conference-board.org/data/economydatabase/

[11] Fisher, J. D. M., [2006], "The Dynamic Effects of Neutral and Investment-Specific

Technology Shocks", Journal of Political Economy, vol. 114, 3, 413-52.

[12] Galí, J., [1999], "Technology, Employment, and the Business Cycle: Do Technology

Shocks Explain Aggregate Fluctuations?", American Economic Review, vol. 89, 1,

249-71.

[13] Galí, J. and L. Gambetti, [2009], "On the Sources of the Great Moderation", American

Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1:1, 26-57.

[14] Galí, J., Gertler, M., and D. Lopez-Salido, [2007], "Markups, Gaps, and the Welfare

Cost of Economic Fluctuations", Review of Economic and Statistics, vol. 89, 44-59.

[15] Galí, J. and T. Van rens, [2010], "The Vanishing Procyclicality of Labor Productivity",

unpublished working paper, CREI.

[16] Hall, R.E., [1997], "Macroeconomic Fluctuations and the Allocation of Time", Journal

of Labor Economics, vol. 15, 1, 5223-50.

[17] Hall, R., [2007],

[18] Hansen, Gary D. [1985], "Indivisible Labor and the Business Cycle", Journal of Mon-

etary Economics, vol 16, 3, 309-27.

[19] Herkenhoff, K. and L., Ohanian, [2011], "", working paper.

[20] Hopenhayn, H. and R., Rogerson, [1993], "Job Turnover and Policy Evaluation: A

General Equilibrium Analysis", Journal of Political Economy, vol. 101, 5, 915-38.

[21] Kydland, F, and E. Prescott [1982], "Time to Build and Aggreagate Fluctuations",

Econometrica, 50(6):1,345-70.

29

Page 31: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

[22] OECD [2004], OECDEmployment Outlook, http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/8/4/34846856.pdf.

[23] Mulligan, C., [2008], "A Depressing Scenario: Mortgage Debt Becomes Unemployment

Insurance", NBER Working Paper 14514.

[24] Mortensen, D. and C. Pissarides [1994], "Job Creation and Job Destruction in the

Theory of Unemployment", Review of Economic Studies, 61(3):397-415.

[25] Ohanian, L., [2010], "The Economic Crisis from a Neoclassical Perspective", Journal

of Economic Perspectives, vol. 24, 4, 45-66.

[26] Ohanian, L., A. Raffo, and R. Rogerson, [2008], "Long-Term Changes in Labor Sup-

ply and Taxes: Evidence from OECD Countries 1956-2004", Journal of Monetary

Economics, vol. 55, 1353-62.

[27] O’Mahony, M. and M.P. Timmer, [2009], "Output, Input and Productivity Measures

at Industry Level: the EU-KLEMS Database", Economic Journal, 119(538), pp. F374-

F403.

[28] Rogerson, R., [2006], "Understanding Differences in Hours Worked", Review of Eco-

nomic Dynamics, vol. 9, 3, 365-409.

[29] Shimer, R., [2010], "Convergence in Macroeconomics: The Labor Wedge", American

Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 1(1): 280-297.

[30] Shimer, R., [2010], "Labor Markets and Business Cycles", Princeton University Press.

30

Page 32: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Chart 1. Cyclical Properties of Total Hours Worked

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Output

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0 25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Canada France Germany Italy Japan U.K. U.S. Mean

Correlation with Output

0 25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Canada France Germany Italy Japan U.K. U.S. Mean

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

0.75

Correlation: Hours per Worker and Employment

0.75

Changes in Correlation: Hours per Worker and Employment

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Canada France Germany Italy Japan U.K. U.S. Mean

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

C d F G I l J U K U S M

Correlation: Hours per Worker and Employment

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation: Hours per Worker and Employment

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Canada France Germany Italy Japan U.K. U.S. Mean

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Canada France Germany Italy Japan U.K U.S. Mean

Correlation: Hours per Worker and Employment

0 75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation: Hours per Worker and Employment

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Canada France Germany Italy Japan U.K. U.S. Mean

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Canada France Germany Italy Japan U.K U.S. Mean

Correlation: Hours per Worker and Employment

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation: Hours per Worker and Employment

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Canada France Germany Italy Japan U.K. U.S. Mean

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

Page 33: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Chart 2. Cyclical Properties of Labor Productivity

0.75

1.00

Correlation with Output

0.75

1.00

Changes in Correlation with Output

0 00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Correlation with Output

0 00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Changes in Correlation with Output

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Correlation with Output

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Correlation with Output

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

0 25

0.50

Correlation with Total Hours

0 25

0.50

Changes in Correlation with Total Hours

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Correlation with Output

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

Correlation with Total Hours

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

Changes in Correlation with Total Hours

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Correlation with Output

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-1.00

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

Correlation with Total Hours

-1.00

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

Changes in Correlation with Total Hours

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Correlation with Output

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

1.00

Changes in Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-1.00

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

Correlation with Total Hours

-1.00

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

Changes in Correlation with Total Hours

Pre-1984 Post-1984

Page 34: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Chart 3. Cyclical Properties of Real Wages

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Output

0.25

0.50

0.75Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

0 75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Output

-0 75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

0 25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

0 25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

Pre-1984 Post-1984

0 25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with LP(H)

0 25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with LP(H)

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with LP(H)

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with LP(H)

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Output

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75Correlation with Output

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with Total Hours

Pre-1984 Post-1984

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with LP(H)

-0.75

-0.50

-0.25

0.00

0.25

0.50

0.75

Correlation with LP(H)

Pre-1984 Post-1984

Page 35: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Chart 4. Housing Sector During the Great Recession

90.00

100.00

110.00

120.00

B. Great Recession: Construction Employment

60.00

70.00

80.00

90.00

100.00

110.00

120.00

A. Nominal House Prices

US Canada Average Western Europe Spain Ireland

40.00

50.00

60.00

70.00

80.00

90.00

100.00

110.00

120.00

B. Great Recession: Construction Employment

US Canada Average Western Europe Spain Ireland

60.00

70.00

80.00

90.00

100.00

110.00

120.00

A. Nominal House Prices

US Canada Average Western Europe Spain Ireland

Page 36: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

CAN FRA GER ITA JAP UK US Mean Median

Standard Deviation

1960:Q1 - 2007:Q4 Total Hours 0.76 0.57 0.59 0.98 0.79 0.62 0.66 1.00 0.71

Output 0.86 0.97 0.92 0.94 1.23 0.95 0.84 1.05 0.96

Ratio 0.88 0.59 0.64 1.05 0.64 0.65 0.78 0.92 0.74

1960:Q1 - 1984:Q4 Total Hours 0.86 0.67 0.61 1.12 0.71 0.49 0.79 0.93 0.75

Output 1.01 1.24 1.00 1.15 1.24 1.22 1.07 1.18 1.22

Ratio 0.85 0.54 0.61 0.98 0.57 0.40 0.74 0.78 0.66

1985:Q1 - 2007:Q4 Total Hours 0.63 0.38 0.54 0.77 0.87 0.66 0.48 1.03 0.69

Output 0.63 0.44 0.81 0.51 0.96 0.50 0.50 0.81 0.64

Ratio 1.01 0.85 0.67 1.52 0.90 1.32 0.97 1.23 1.02

Table 2. Volatility of Total Hours Worked

Page 37: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

CAN FRA GER ITA JAP UK US Mean Median

Var(x) Relative to Var(Total Hours)

1960:Q1 - 2007:Q4 hours 0.33 0.34 0.55 0.49 0.67 0.54 0.40 0.54 0.55

LFP 0.35 0.56 0.21 0.40 0.25 0.19 0.25 0.27 0.25

Unempl. rate 0.32 0.11 0.24 0.10 0.07 0.27 0.35 0.18 0.16

1960:Q1 - 1984:Q4 hours 0.25 0.23 0.54 0.40 0.45 0.33 0.37 0.46 0.42

LFP 0.42 0.72 0.21 0.48 0.44 0.32 0.25 0.33 0.31

Unempl. rate 0.34 0.05 0.26 0.12 0.11 0.36 0.38 0.21 0.13

1985:Q1 - 2007:Q4 hours 0.50 0.69 0.61 0.73 0.84 0.64 0.49 0.65 0.64

LFP 0.21 0.09 0.20 0.22 0.11 0.15 0.25 0.19 0.18

Unempl. rate 0.29 0.23 0.19 0.05 0.05 0.21 0.26 0.17 0.16

Table 3. Extensive vs Intensive Margin

Page 38: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

CAN FRA GER ITA JAP UK US Mean Median

Standard Deviation

1960:Q1 - 2007:Q4 LP(H) 0.84 1.07 0.82 1.20 1.40 0.91 0.72 1.26 1.05

Output 0.86 0.97 0.92 0.94 1.23 0.95 0.84 1.05 0.96

Ratio 0.98 1.11 0.89 1.28 1.14 0.96 0.86 1.19 1.09

1960:Q1 - 1984:Q4 LP(H) 0.97 1.31 0.79 1.30 1.26 1.22 0.88 1.31 1.24

Output 1.01 1.24 1.00 1.15 1.24 1.22 1.07 1.18 1.22

Ratio 0.96 1.06 0.79 1.14 1.01 1.00 0.82 1.11 1.02

1985:Q1 - 2007:Q4 LP(H) 0.60 0.48 0.74 0.84 1.35 0.67 0.50 1.12 0.78

Output 0.63 0.44 0.81 0.51 0.96 0.50 0.50 0.81 0.64

Ratio 0.95 1.09 0.92 1.66 1.40 1.34 1.01 1.39 1.22

Table 4. Labor Productivity: Volatility

Page 39: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

CAN FRA GER ITA JAP UK US Mean Median

1960:Q1 - 2007:Q4Absolute STDev* 0.87 0.98 0.92 1.54 1.39 1.16 0.73 1.43 1.27

Relative to: Output 1.01 1.00 1.00 1.64 1.13 1.23 0.87 1.34 1.26

LP(H) 1.04 0.91 1.13 1.28 1.00 1.27 1.02 1.18 1.12

Total Hours 1.15 1.72 1.56 1.56 1.76 1.87 1.12 1.57 1.64

1960:Q1 - 1984:Q4Absolute STDev* 0.92 1.10 0.93 1.72 1.42 1.52 0.70 1.36 1.42

STDev Relative to: Output 0.91 0.89 0.93 1.50 1.15 1.24 0.66 1.18 1.24

LP(H) 0.94 0.84 1.18 1.32 1.13 1.25 0.79 1.14 1.16

Total Hours 1.07 1.65 1.52 1.54 1.99 3.11 0.89 1.81 1.65

1985:Q1 - 2007:Q4Absolute STDev* 0.80 0.48 0.71 1.07 1.11 0.89 0.77 1.27 1.27

STDev Relative to: Output 1.28 1.08 0.87 2.10 1.15 1.79 1.56 1.59 1.59

LP(H) 1.35 0.99 0.95 1.27 0.83 1.33 1.55 1.24 1.24

Total Hours 1.27 1.26 1.31 1.38 1.28 1.35 1.61 1.39 1.39

* Statistics refer to the standard deviation of (the first difference of the logarithm of) real compensation per hour.

Table 5. Real Wages: Volatility

Page 40: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

(1) US (NBER recessions)Output Hours Empl.

All recessions (except Great Recession) -4.3 -3.5 -2.1Pre-1984 recessions -5.1 -3.9 -2.3Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -2.2 -2.4 -1.6

(2) Other high income countries (ECRI recessions)

Canada France Germany Italy UK Canada France Germany Italy UK Canada France Germany Italy UKAll recessions (except Great Recession) -9.1 -3.3 -5.1 -4.3 -7.0 -7.3 -2.7 -5.7 -2.2 -5.2 -6.0 -1.6 -3.6 -2.4 -3.0Pre-1984 recessions -9.5 -3.5 -5.4 -4.2 -7.7 -8.0 -3.3 -6.8 -1.5 -4.4 -6.9 -1.9 -3.9 -1.8 -2.3Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -8.6 -3.0 -4.8 -5.0 -5.6 -6.6 -1.8 -4.0 -4.6 -6.8 -5.1 -1.3 -3.2 -4.8 -4.5

(3) Average Western Europe: France, Germany, Italy, UK, Austria, Spain, Sweden (ECRI recessions)*

Output Hours Empl.All recessions (except Great Recession) -5.3 -5.0 -3.8Pre-1984 recessions -5.6 -5.5 -3.4Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -5.2 -5.3 -5.1

(4) Japan, Korea (ECRI recessions)**

Japan Korea Japan Korea Japan KoreaAll recessions (except Great Recession) -4.8 -7.3 -4.2 -8.1 -1.2 -4.4Pre-1984 recessions -5.8 -6.3 -3.3Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -4.5 -5.4 -3.5 -8.1 -0.5 -4.4

*Note: ECRI recession dates only available for the above countries**Note: Data available from 1990 onwards for Korea

Empl.

Empl.

Output Hours

Output Hours

Table 6. Output, Hours, and Employment at Trough, Average Deviation from Peak

Page 41: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

(1) US (NBER recessions)Hours Empl.

All recessions (except Great Recession) -2.8 -1.2Pre-1984 recessions -3.0 -1.1Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -2.3 -1.4

(2) Other high income countries (ECRI recessions)

Canada France Germany Italy UK Canada France Germany Italy UKAll recessions (except Great Recession) -8.8 -2.8 -6.3 -2.3 -6.0 -7.7 -1.9 -4.0 -2.3 -3.4Pre-1984 recessions -9.4 -3.8 -7.9 -0.2 -4.0 -8.7 -2.4 -4.3 -0.7 -1.3Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -8.2 -1.2 -4.0 -8.3 -9.9 -6.7 -1.0 -3.6 -9.1 -7.7

(3) Average Western Europe: France, Germany, Italy, UK, Austria, Spain, Sweden (ECRI recessions)*

Hours Empl.All recessions (except Great Recession) -6.2 -4.9Pre-1984 recessions -6.6 -4.1Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -7.3 -7.4

(4) Japan, Korea (ECRI recessions)**

Japan Korea Japan KoreaAll recessions (except Great Recession) -5.5 -17.4 -0.4 -10.2Pre-1984 recessions -9.1 -3.5Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -4.3 -17.4 0.6 -10.2

* Note: ECRI recession dates only available for the above countries** Note: Data available from 1990 onwards for Korea

Empl.

Hours Empl.

Hours

Table 7. Labor Wedge at Trough, Average Deviation from Peak

Page 42: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

(1) US (NBER recessions)Hours Employment

All recessions (except Great Recession) -2.0 -2.8Pre-1984 recessions -2.4 -3.4Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -0.9 -1.4

(2) Other high income countries (ECRI recessions)

Canada France Germany Italy UK Canada France Germany Italy UKAll recessions (except Great Recession) -4.7 -1.5 -1.5 -3.3 -3.8 -5.5 -2.2 -2.8 -2.8 -5.2Pre-1984 recessions -4.9 -1.3 -0.9 -3.7 -4.8 -5.6 -2.2 -2.8 -3.1 -6.2Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -4.5 -1.8 -2.4 -1.8 -1.8 -5.5 -2.1 -2.8 -1.6 -3.3

(3) Average Western Europe: France, Germany, Italy, UK, Austria, Spain, Sweden (ECRI recessions)*

Hours EmploymentAll recessions (except Great Recession) -1.9 -2.8Pre-1984 recessions -1.8 -3.2Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -1.9 -2.0

(4) Japan, Korea (ECRI recessions)**

Japan Korea Japan KoreaAll recessions (except Great Recession) -3.1 -1.2 -5.0 -3.6Pre-1984 recessions -4.0 -5.9Post-1984 recessions (except Great Recession) -2.8 -1.2 -4.6 -3.6

*Note: ECRI recession dates only available for the above countries**Note: Data available from 1990 onwards for Korea

Hours Employment

Hours Employment

Table 8. Productivity Wedge at Trough, Average Deviation from Peak

Page 43: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Output Hours Employment Hours Employment Hours Employment

US -7.2 -8.3 -7.0 -9.9 -9.0 -1.4 -2.3

Canada -8.1 -4.4 -2.9 -2.0 -0.5 -5.9 -6.7France -6.7 -2.8 -2.1 0.8 1.0 -5.2 -5.6Germany -6.8 0.5 1.7 4.1 6.3 -7.0 -7.8Italy -10.8 -5.8 -5.4 -3.5 -3.8 -6.4 -6.6UK -10.2 -4.5 -3.1 -3.9 -2.6 -7.4 -8.3

Average Western Europe* -9.0 -3.2 -2.3 -0.7 0.1 -7.0 -7.5

Spain -9.0 -8.9 -10.0 -14.0 -16.4 -4.1 -3.3Ireland -16.4 -14.4 -13.1 -15.5 -15.6 -8.0 -8.9

Japan -7.6 -4.2 -0.7 -1.8 4.0 -4.4 -6.6Korea -2.7 -2.3 -1.2 -4.6 -2.4 -1.9 -2.6

*France, Germany, Italy, UK, Austria, Finland, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden

Data Productivity wedgeLabor wedge

Table 9. Great Recession, Deviation from Peak (US hours trough)

Page 44: Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries · PDF file · 2014-11-16Hours Worked over the Business Cycle in OECD Countries, 1960 ... of substitution between consumption

Output Hours Employment Output Hours Output Employment Output Hours Output Employment

US -7.2 -8.3 -7.0 -6.8 -9.8 -5.9 -8.7 -2.2 -0.5 -3.5 -0.8

Canada -8.1 -4.4 -2.9 -1.3 -1.9 -0.3 -0.5 -9.0 -3.1 -10.1 -3.2France -6.7 -2.8 -2.1 0.5 0.7 0.7 0.9 -7.9 -2.7 -8.3 -2.6Germany -6.8 0.5 1.7 2.6 3.6 4.0 5.4 -10.8 -3.9 -11.6 -3.8Italy -10.8 -5.8 -5.4 -2.3 -3.3 -2.4 -3.6 -9.8 -3.5 -9.8 -3.1UK -10.2 -4.5 -3.1 -2.5 -3.7 -1.7 -2.5 -11.5 -4.1 -12.4 -4.1

Average Western Europe* -9.0 -3.2 -2.3 -0.5 -0.7 0.1 0.0 -10.9 -3.8 -11.3 -3.6

Spain -9.0 -8.9 -10.0 -9.8 -13.9 -11.5 -16.3 -6.2 -2.1 -4.8 -1.5Ireland -16.4 -14.4 -13.1 -10.9 -15.7 -10.8 -15.6 -12.6 -4.2 -13.5 -4.2

Japan -7.6 -4.2 -0.7 -1.2 -1.7 2.5 3.6 -6.8 -2.2 -9.9 -3.0Korea -2.7 -2.3 -1.2 -3.3 -4.0 -1.5 -2.2 -2.8 -1.0 -3.9 -1.0

*France, Germany, Italy, UK, Austria, Finland, Netherlands, Norway, Sweden** Model 1 = labor wedge, hours; Model 2 = labor wedge, employment; Model 3 = productivity wedge, hours; Model 4 = productivity wedge, employment

Predicted, Model 4Predicted, Model 1 Predicted, Model 2Data Predicted, Model 3

Table 10. Great Recession, Deviation from Peak (Hours Trough)