department discussion paper - world bank · department discussion paper . ... william tyler (trade)...

87
Department Discussion Paper All.GENTIRA: ECONOMIC RECOVEllY AND CllOwm 'l'IADE (Background Paper 3) December 1987 Latin .America and the Caribbean Country Operations Department IV Discussion Papers are not formal publications of the World Bank. They present preltminary and unpolished results of country analysis or research that is circulated to encourage discussion and comment; citation and the use of such a paper should take account of its provisional character. The findings. interpretations. and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author(s) and should not be attributed in any manner to the World Bank. to its affiliated organizations, or to members of its Board of Executive Directors or the countries they represent. Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized Public Disclosure Authorized

Upload: buitram

Post on 18-Aug-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • Department Discussion Paper

    All.GENTIRA: ECONOMIC RECOVEllY AND CllOwm

    'l'IADE

    (Background Paper 3)

    December 1987

    Latin .America and the Caribbean Country Operations Department IV

    Discussion Papers are not formal publications of the World Bank. They present preltminary and unpolished results of country analysis or research that is circulated to encourage discussion and comment; citation and the use of such a paper should take account of its provisional character. The findings. interpretations. and conclusions expressed in this paper are entirely those of the author(s) and should not be attributed in any manner to the World Bank. to its affiliated organizations, or to members of its Board of Executive Directors or the countries they represent.

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    Pub

    lic D

    iscl

    osur

    e A

    utho

    rized

    wb406484Typewritten Text

    wb406484Typewritten Text 66409

  • MCRE

    ADMIRA

    ANA

    BAHADE BCRA

    BONAVI

    BONEX

    CEM CEN

    CEPAL

    CD CGIAR/CGR

    CGT

    CKD CONADE

    CPI CRM

    DGI DIF DJAT

    DmI

    DNPC

    FIEL

    FONAVI FUNDECO GATT

    GDP GDFI

    GLOSSARY OF ACRONYMS

    Asociacion Argentina de Consorcios Nacionales de Experimentacion Agricola

    Asociacion Metalurgica Argentina

    Administracion Nacional de Aduanas

    Banco Nacional de Desarrollo Banco Central de la Republica

    Argentina Bonos Nacionales de Intereses

    Variables Bonos Externos

    Corporacion de Empresas Nacionales

    Comision Economica para Latinoamerica

    Certificado de Deposito

    Confederacion General de Trabajo

    Consejo Nacional de Desarrollo

    Cuenta de Regulacion Monetaria

    Direccion General Impositiva

    Declaracion Jurada de Admision Temporaria

    Declaracion Jurada de Necesidades de Importacion

    Direccion Nacional de Promocion Comercial

    Fundacion de Investigaciones Economicas Latinoamericanas

    Fondo Nacional de Vivienda Fundacion Economica

    Argentine Association of Regional Experimental Consortia

    Argentine Metallurgy Association

    National Customs Administration

    National Development Bank Central Bank of Argentina

    variable interest rate bonds

    foreign bonds (US dollardenominated Government bonds)

    Country Economic Memorandum Corporation of National

    Enterprises Economic Commission for

    Latin America (ECLA) certificate of deposit Consultative Group on Inter

    national Agricultural Research

    General Confederation of Workers

    completely knocked down National Development

    Council consumer price index Monetary Regulation Account

    (Interest Equalization Fund)

    General Tax Directorate Deposit Insurance Fund temporary admission import

    request import permit

    National Directorate of Commercial Promotion

    Latin American Foundation for Economic Research

    National Housing Fund Economic Foundation General Agreement on Tariffs

    and Trade gross domestic product gross domestic fixed

    investment

  • IBRD

    IDB

    IFS

    IICA

    IMP INDEC

    IHPE

    INTA

    IVA JNC JNG LIBOR M&LT MCBA

    NADE

    NFS PAN PEA

    PRESEX (PEX)

    RER BEER

    SIC

    SICE

    SIGEP

    SITC

    SKD SKI

    SNESR

    TAR VA VAT VNA WI YPF

    Instituto Interamericano de Cooperacion Agricola

    Instituto Nacional de Estadistica y Censo

    Institute Nacional de Planeamiento Economico

    Instituto Nacional de Tecnologia Agropecuaria

    Impuesto de Valor Agregado Junta Nacional de Carnes Junta Nacional de Granos

    Kunicipalidad de la Ciudad de Buenos Aires

    Nomenclatura Arancelaria de Exportacion

    Programa Alimentario Nacional Poblacion Economicamente Activa

    Programas Especiales de Exportacion

    Secretaria de Industria y Comercio Exterior

    Sindicatura General de

    Eapresas Publicas

    Servicio Nacional de Economia y Sociologia Rural

    Temporary Admission Regime

    Valores Nacionales Ajustables

    Yacimientos Petroliferos Fiscales

    International Bank for Reconstruction and Development

    Inter-American Development Bank

    International Financial Statistics

    Inter-American Institute tor Agricultural Cooperation

    International Monetary Fund National Institute for Stat

    istics and Census National Economic Planning

    Institute National Institute for Agri

    cultural Technology value-added tax National Keat Board National Grain Board London Interbank Offer Rate medium and long term Municipality of the City

    of Buenos Aires Customs Classification for

    Exports nonfactor services National Food Program economically active

    population Special Export Program

    real exchange rate real effective exchange

    rate Standard Industrial

    Classification Secretariat of Industry

    and Foreign Trade General Comptroller of

    Public Enterprises Standard Industrial . Trade Classification

    semi-knocked down small and medium-size

    industry National lural Economic

    and Sociological Service trade policy value added value-added tax indexed national bonds wholesale price index state oil company

  • PREFACE

    This is Background Paper 3 of a series of working notes proposed in conjunction with the Economic Recovery and Growth exercise. There were many contributors. These include the following members of the mission that visited Argentina in April 1986:

    F. Desmond McCarthy (Mission Chief)

    Constantino Lluch (Labor/Em~loyment)

    Claudio Frischtak (Industry)

    William Tyler (Trade)

    Alberto Verme (Consultant - Private Investment)

    Thomas Boyatt (Consultant - Export Marketing)

    Javier Gonzalez-Fraga (Consultant - Monetary)

    Maria Claudia Franco (Research Assistant)

    Harutaka Hamaguchi (Young Professional)

    Papers were also contributed by Professors M. Connelly, R. Dornbusch, and L. Taylor. The principal counterpart in Argentina was Mr. A. Canitrot, Secretary of Economic Coordination. Since these are working notes they often reflect intermediate stages of thinking before the final report was published. As such they were not subject to rigorous review procedures of the World Bank or the Government of Argentina.

    I would like to thank Ms. Milagros A. Divino for preparing the draft and processing the report through to publication.

  • Contents

    Page No.

    I. Export Marketing eo. e

    II. Trade and the Trade Policy Environment 150

    III. Special Purpose Export Finance Facility eo. 46

  • I. EXPORT MARKETING

    1.1 This section considers the viability of an export-led growth

    strategy for Argentina. Can Argentina improve its growth prospects by

    selling significantly more products in the world market? If so, what

    products, how can they be marketed, and what can the Government do to

    facilitate this process?

    1.2 It will take more than fiscal incentives and a favorable exchange

    rate to significantly boost Argentine exports. Many products will need an

    improvement in overall marketing strategy. This section identifies some

    approaches that may be helpful.

    Argentina's Current Export System

    1.3 "Outward-Looking vs. Inward-Looking." The major obstacle to an

    export-led growth strategy in Argentina is the nation's closed economy and

    desire for economic self-sufficiency. For the last few decades, the

    Government has taxed exports such as beef and grain in order to generate

    revenue for infrastructure, military hardware, and state industrial

    enterprises. Economic policy-makers have built an import-substitutj

    around Argentina that keeps imports out to protect Argentine

    manufacturers. For generations, the essence of Argentine trad~

    been that if a product is made or can be made in Argentina, J

    import equivalent out.

  • - 2

    1.4 These protectionist policies have led to the creation of large

    and powerful groups with a vested interest in the inward-looking status

    quoo These groups include industrialists, trade unions, the militar,y, and

    large government bureaucracies involved in state enterprises. The entire

    complex is infused with an emotional nationalism that militates againat

    change.

    1.5 The above factors will enormously complicate the Argentine

    decision-making process as the nation tries to open the economy and move

    toward an export-led growth strategy. Not only does it seem desirable to

    open the economy to a freer trade regime, but the whole Argentine way of

    doing business needs an infusion of fresh ideas.

    1.6 The Import System. Argentina's import system is extremely

    rigid. The policy of prohibiting imports of products that can be made in

    Argentina dooms export industries to using high-cost, often low-quality

    inputs manufactured in Argentina. One example will suffice. Argentina's

    fishing industr,y currently exports about US$150 million annually. These

    exports could be quadrupled if the fishing industr,y were allowed to import

    state-of-the-art nets and machinery. Because fish nets and associated

    machiner,y are made in Argentina, the Argentine fishing industr,y is using

    out-of-date, high-cost 6quipment, and the countr,y is paying an obvious

    price.

    1.7 Exchange Rates. Argentina's exchange rate has long been erratic

    and overvalued. In his study, Argentina y Brasil: Dos Estrategias Para La

  • - 3 -

    Exportacion, Elvio Baldinelli of the Fundacion de Investigaciones

    Economicas Latinoamericanas demonstrated the relative stability of Brazil's

    exchange rates compared to the wild gyrations of Argentina's. He

    identified this difference as one of the main reasons for the poor

    pe~formance of Argentine exporters compared to their Brazilian

    counterparts.

    1.8 Gove~ent Export Regimes. The Argentine Government has long

    provided a variety of fiscal, financial and institutional incentives to

    stimulate exports. These measures have changed frequently, and have often

    been flawed in implementation. The Government's recently announced PEX

    program provides special benefits equal to 15% (plus 5% for new markets) of

    the f.o.b. value of exports for firms committing themselves to expand

    exports by a minimum of US$2 million per year. Many other incentives have

    accumulated over the years, but their implementation has been uneven.

    1.9 Marketing Structure and Approach. Typically, the Argentine

    industrial manufacturer produces goods for a protected local market. When

    domestic demand declines and producers have excess capacity, they try to

    sell products manufactured for the Argentine market in external markets

    about which they often have little or no knowledge. In general, potential

    Argentine exporters are product-driven rather than market-driven.

    Problems and Bottlenecks in Argentina's Export System

    1.10 Major Problem Areas. Among more than 50 Argentine businessmen

    with whom the export system was discussed for this analysiS, there was

  • - 4

    virtual unanimity on three major problem areas:

    (a) The rules of the game for exports must be stabilized. Exchange

    rate fluctuations have already been noted. In addition, fiscal

    and financial punishments (export taxes) and rewards (rebates,

    drawbacks, subsidized financing, etc.) of the export system have

    changed significantly with every government and almost with every

    Minister of Economy. For instance, the marketing director of an

    important home products company said that from 1982 to 1986,

    governmental regulations for his product varied between a 15%

    export tax and an 11% rebate. This erratic regulatory policy

    made pricing his product grotesquely complicated, and the

    resulting wild pricing swings meant the loss of export customers

    for his company and a bad reputation for Argentina.

    Recommendation. Argentine creditors are considering major

    policy-based lending operations. President Alfonsin has already

    publicly stressed the need for stabilit,y in the trade system.

    The lending operations under consideration could provide a

    vehicle to allow Government officials to put in place a sound and

    stable export system.

    (b) The Government's role in the export system must be reduced. B.y

    Presidential Decree of Dec. 6, 1985, the Government decided to

    facilitate the paperwork required for exports by concentrating

    all export license approvals in a single office, the ventanilla

    unica. Approximately 25 separate bureaucracies were affected,

  • - 5

    and each resisted the decree. At the end of 1986, the issue was

    still in doubt. Two examples illustrate the problems caused by

    Argentina's excess bureaucracy.

    (i) Bureaucracy in the Export Field (Paperwork).

    The second stage of Plan Austral employs export credits

    and subsidies to promote Argentina's export performance.

    But for an exporter to obtain these benefits, his

    application must go through the following 29 steps:

    1. Submit application to the National Directorate for Commercial Promotion;

    2. Possible requests for further information by Directorate;

    3. Opening of a case file, analysis and evaluation;

    4. Preliminary report by Directorate;

    5. Report is submitted to the weekly meeting of the subcommittee of the National Fund for Export Promotion of the Advisory Council on Foreign Trade for its op~n~on. Report is considered in the first or second weekly meeting;

    6. For loans, information must be provided to the Banco de la Nacion, which then has 25 days to analyze the net worth and financial situation of the applicant;

    7. With steps (4), (5), and (6) completed, the Commission of the National Fund for Export Promotion meets and examines the application, which is then approved and signed by the National Directors for Trade Promotion and Exports and by the Undersecretary for Foreign Trade;

    8. A draft resolution is prepared;

    9. Funds are allotted and registered;

    10. Formal processing and submission of draft resolution;

  • - 6

    11. National Director for Trade Promotion initials the draft resolution;

    12. Draft resolution is sent to the Undersecretary for Foreign Trade under cover of memorandum;

    13. Review and initialing by Undersecretary;

    14. Resolution is signed by the Secretary for Foreign Trade;

    15. A new case file is opened with the resolution, and applicant is notified;

    16. Resolution is processed, registered and distributed;

    17. Resolution is passed to official accounting office;

    18. Treasury receives the resolution and may ask for further information;

    19. Preparation of Loan/Subsidy Agreement, signature by applicant;

    20. Signature of agreement by the Secretary of Foreign Trade;

    21. Signed agreement is added to the new (i.e., second) case file;

    22. File passes through accounting and allotment procedures;

    23. File returns to official accounting office for final control;

    24. File is passed to Treasury, where in the case of subsidies, a check is registered and issued. In the case of a loan, the authorization is passed to the Banco de la Nacion for disbursement;

    25. In the case of loans, if the amount exceeds the maximum authorized for issuance based solely on the applicant's signature, mortgages or the pledging of other collateral must be prepared, processed and signed;

    26. Disbursement of funds;

    27. Preparation of accounts by recipient;

    28. Presentation of accounts to the Directorate;

    29. Final approval of the case file.

  • - 7

    (ii) The New Export Promotion Scheme. The 15%

    benefit enacted for exports requires the candidate

    exporter to file an application composed of 11 forms, plus

    various annexes and supporting documents amounting to 25

    pages. The application (see Attachment 1) is complicated s

    and was strongly and unanimously criticized by the

    businessmen interviewed for this analysis. In fact, the

    complexities of the application have intimidated small

    firms that lack the expertise to complete the forms,

    effectively preventing them from applying. Large

    companies that do have the necessary expertise are furious

    at the time and expense required to complete the

    application.

    Recommendation. The Government should obtain consulting

    assistance to help streamline the implementation of its export

    promotion policies and programs. Clearly, the emphasis should be

    on a minimized and simplified role for the Government.

    Government should aim for a one-page application that requires

    only a list of the new products (along with volumes and values),

    plus a coherent plan of how the company intends to proceed.

    (c) The Port of Buenos Aires should be rationalized. Since much of

    Argentina's exports flow through the Port of Buenos Aires,

    facilities there must be improved. The Port is now one of the

    more expensive in the world. Port costs at Montevideo--just

    across the river--are estimated to be one-fifth of those at

  • - 8

    Buenos Aires. Yokohama, Bremen, and New York are all

    significant~ cheaper, as well. . Modern trade patterns strongly

    suggest that an integrated roll-on/roll-off facility is

    essential.

    Recommendation. An assessment is needed to determine how to make

    the Port of Buenos Aires cheaper and more efficient.

    Roll-on/roll-off container facilities should be expanded.

    Consideration should be given to financing alternative ports and

    fully containerized operations to meet medium- and longer-term

    needs.

    Specific Problems and Bottlenecks

    1.11 In addition to the problem areas discussed above, Argentine

    businessmen also mentioned the following obstacles to improved exports:

    (a) The Exchange Rate. A number of studies have emphasized the

    importance of a realistic exchange rate for exporters. A

    realistic rate could be established through a wide variety of

    trade and foreign exchange regimes.~/

    Recommendation. The Government should be encouraged to

    articulate its exchange rate policy as clearly as possible to

    1/ See Rhee, Y.W., "A Framework for Export Policies and Administration: Lessons from the East Asian Experience". Series on Industry and Finance, Vol. 10, World Bank, 1984.

  • - 9

    reduce uncertainty. This would be a positive step towards

    stabilizing the rules of the game.

    (b) The Import System. Argentina's import system is one of the most

    restrictive in the world and needs to be substantially

    liberalized. If Argentina is to have a successful

    export-led economic policy, exporters must have access to

    imported raw materials, intermediate inputs such as machinery,

    technical advice, and capital goods that generate value-added

    exports.

    Recommendation. The Government should establish automatic import

    licenses to allow exporters to bring in the raw materials,

    intermediate materials and machinery they need to manufacture

    products for export (the fishing industry is a case in point).

    Ideally, these imported goods should have a duty exemption, but

    in any case, they should be obtainable competitively with a

    drawback system. Import regimes of this nature were critical in

    the establishment of successful export-led growth in East Asia.

    (c) Governmental Export Promotion Policies. Government export

    promotion programs often fail because they are inefficient and

    corrupt, or because they are so obviously a disguised subsidy

    that they are attacked by the importing country. In the East

    Asian experience, a system of pre-export financing based on the

    wb406484Typewritten Text

  • - 10

    export letter of credit with an automatic rediscounting mechanism

    was most effectiveo This system avoids the problem of checking

    quantities. In any case, any export promotion system should be

    automatic (the benefits are automatic and not dependent upon the

    benevolence of a bureaucrat), universal (all exporters have

    access), and administratively straightforward (procedures are

    simple ).

    Recommendation. The Government should gradually eliminate export

    taxes, rebate indirect taxes on exports (GATT-acceptable), and

    establish a pre-export financing system that meets the criteria

    discussed above.

    (d) Marketing Orientation and Activity. Given the monopolistic/

    oligopolistic nature of many Argentine manufacturers, the typical

    Argentine industrialist has concentrated on production rather

    than marketing. As in all such market-protected situations, the

    result is products that are often below world quality standards

    and above world price levels.

    This production orientation should be changed. If Argentina is

    to compete in international markets, and iLdeed depend upon

    exports to advance economic growth, the nation must develop

    products that meet or exceed international quality standards at

    or below international price levels. The beginning of this

    process is to understand that product development must be driven

    by what the international consumer desires and expects. This

  • - 11

    will be a dramatic change in orientation for most Argentine

    manufacturers and processors, and it will require a knowledge of

    consumer preferences in major international markets--at least

    those in North America and Europe. Obtaining such knowledge is

    expensive and difficult, and this is an area where the Government

    could contribute significantly.

    As an illustrative example of the need to understand foreign

    markets, there is the case of an Argentine manufacturer of

    ceramic tile. "Company Xtt decided to sell its products in the

    US market, beginning with the New York metropolitan area. Having

    made this decision, Company X did not simply try to market

    products already being produced for the Argentine market.

    Instead, the company spent several hundred thousand dollars

    analyzing the needs and quality expectations of the North

    American market. Company X learned a series of very important

    facts about the market, the ignorance of anyone of which would

    have doomed the exporter to failure. First, Company X learned

    that North American consumers wanted a totally different color

    range than those in Argentina. By testing the market, the

    company learned which colors to use and changed its ink coloring

    capability. Second, the company learned that to sell basic tile

    in the US, a manufacturer had to supply an ancillary range of

    accessories (flat facings, curved facings, etc.). And third,

    Company X discovered that the moisture content of tiles for the

    US market would have to be significantly lower than for the

    Argentine market due to the greater extremes in temperature in

  • - 12

    the US. These details graphically illustrate the fundamental

    point that export success requires an intimate knowledge of the

    markets the candidate exporter wants to penetrate. This is an

    area of weakness in Argentina that could be strengthened by

    consultant 8dsistance.

    1.12 Many of the foregoing recommendations require the Government to

    change current policies, alter current programs, and/or dramatically change

    the bureaucratic status quo. No one should underestimate the political

    sensitivity and difficulty of such tasks. The highest degree of tact and

    diplomacy will be necessary to effect some of these changes. The changes

    are, however, critical to the success of an export-driven growth strategy.

    An Export Action Program

    1.13 In addition to recommendations involving existing policies,

    several new programs could facilitate an export-led growth strategy for

    Argentina. These include the following:

    (a) Fund and organize a basic export survey. In a number of

    countries, lenders provide loan packages that include a small

    component to lund surveys of local economies and local companies

    to determine export potential. But undertaking such surveys

    after loans are approved is putting the cart before the horse. A

    consulting group composed of active exporters should be sent to

    Argentina to survey the country's productive capacity and

    recommend which sectors have significant export potential.

  • - 13

    (b) Fund and organize sectoral export analyses. Once an initial

    review has established the broad outlines of export potential,

    individual companies in established export sectors should be

    surveyed to determine which have export potential, and what they

    need to do to realize this potential. This technical assistance,

    which again should be provided by experienced exporters, is

    critical to the overall success of the program, and it is an area

    where an agency such as the World Bank can make a direct and

    immediate contribution.

    (c) Establish and administer a revolving fund for loans to Argentine

    exporters for market information and developmental activity in

    targeted export markets. To avoid adding yet another government

    bureaucracy to Argentina's export system, this fund should be

    administered by an independent agency, preferably under the aegis

    of an external, non-Governmental entity. As the case of Company

    X demonstrates, market studies and other developmental activity

    will be the crucial first step in increasing exports.

    (d) Rationalized countertrade regulations. Argentina's current

    countertrade system is confused. It is not clear whether the

    Ministr,r of Commerce or the Central Bank is in charge. Argentina

    needs a functioning countertrade system to compete with neighbors

    like Brazil. It would be useful for a consultant to analyze the

    situation and recommend how to improve it.

    (e) Prevent the establishment of a Government trading company.

    Currently, YFF, the state oil company, has an affiliated trading

  • - 14

    company for goods and services connected to the petroleum

    industry. Any proposal that the Government organize a

    government-owned and operated trading company should be examined

    closely. An official Argentine trading company would inject

    politics and bureaucracy further into the export system, and

    would compete unfairly with private sector trading companies. It

    would also cost taxpayers money, and would generally complicate a

    scene that is already complicated enough. At a time when

    international financial institutions are recommending the

    privatization of government commercial enterprises to reduce

    Argentina's fiscal deficit, it is not prudent to establish yet

    another governmental commercial enterprise.

  • - 15

    II. TRADE AND THE TRADE POLICY ENVIRONMENT

    Export Performance

    2.1 Argentina's export performance was poor during the early to

    mid-1980s. During the 1970s, exports rose from US$1.8 billion (1970) to

    US$7.8 billion (1979), while imports climbed from US$1.7 billion (1970) to

    US$6.7 billion (1979). During the import splurge of 1980 and 1981, import

    levels were US$10.5 and US$9.4 billion, respectively. By 1985, imports had

    been compressed to US$3.8 billion, while exports totaled US$8.4 billion.

    The trade surplus necessary to help service the external debt under the

    deteriorated international commercial bank lending environment has been

    generated not through export expansion, but instead through import

    reduction which was produced mainly by income contraction and import

    restrictions. In fact, as indicated in Table 1, exports have stagnated.

    When adjustment is made for US dollar inflation, the deterioration in

    exports is even more dramatic. Industrial exports have paralleled the

    overall poor export performance. Despite significant growth until the late

    1970s, in the early 1980s industrial exports began a period of decline.

    Exports continue to be marginal for virtually all manufacturing firms;

    at the end of 1986, exports accounted for less than 10% of industrial

    output.

    2.2 There are several reasons for the stagnation of Argentine

    exports, among them a precipitous drop in world market prices for

    Argentina's major export commodities. Between 1981 and 1985 the real

    declines in international prices for soybeans, sorghum, wheat, and corn

  • - 16

    were 25%, 32%, 46%, and 24%, respectively. These four commodities account

    for over one-third of Argentina's exports.

    Table 1: EXPORTS BY COMMODITY GROUPS, SELECTED YEARS, 1970-85 (US$ milli ons )

    Primary Agro-based Industrial Total Year Products Products Products Exports

    1970 1975 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 /a

    683 1 ,436 3,194 4,162 3,033 3,810 3,771 3,684

    877 878

    2,951 2.886 2,487 2,639 2,868 2,492

    205 628

    1,788 2,091 2,106 1 ,386 1,468 2,220

    1,773 2,961 8,021 9,143 7,624 7,836 8,107 8,396

    /a Preliminary estimates.

    Source: INDEC, Secretaria de Comercio, and BCRA.

    2.3 On the domestic front there are a number of problems.~ First,

    the highly unstable macroeconomic policy environment has imposed additional

    risks on exporters. For example, the erratic nature of Argentine exchange

    31 An exploratory econometric analysis was undertaken using quarterly data for the period 1970-85 to examine the determinants of Argentine industrial exports. Ordinary least squares were used to estimate an export supply function for industrial products. The analysis provided evidence suggesting that: (a) the temporary admissions scheme for export production was significant in expanding exports; and (b) poor domestic demand conditions have encouraged producers to seek out export markets. The exchange rate variable was not statistically significant. There are several possible explanations for this, including an inappropriate implicit specification of the lag structure, unevenness of exchange rate expectations, and the failure of the analysis to incorporate export subsidy information into the effective exchange rate variable.

  • - 17

    rate policy has convinced producers that export activity and investment for

    export production are highly and inherently risky.3/ Overall, there seem

    to be no clearly defined rules of the game regarding economic policies in

    general, and export policies in particular. This lack of policy definition

    has resulted in very high uncertainty for economic actors, and has in turn

    impeded export growth. 4/

    2.4 Second, the economic policies pursued by the Government

    discriminate against export activity. Problems for exporters include the

    exchange rate policy, the trade policy regime, and even the special export

    incentive programs intended to offset the discrimination against other

    economic policies. Without policy changes to reduce such discrimination,

    sustained export growth, particularly of manufactured products, is unlikely

    to occur. Many producers see current government policies as evidence of a

    lack of serious commitment on the part of the Government to expand exports.

    Exchange Rate Policy

    2.5 The exchange rate constitutes one of the most important prices

    in an economy such as Argentina's. It represents the relative price of

    tradeable goods versus non-tradeables, and a real currency depreciation

    For a discussion of this policy instability, see Julio J. Nogues, "The Nature of Argentina's Policy Reforms during 1976-81 If, World Bank Staff Working Paper No. 765, January 1986.

    A common sentiment expressed by the managers of industrial firms is the negative impact of policy instability on their firms' exports. One manager of a large manufactured product exporting firm stressed that the most important thing the government could do would be to establish stable and uniformly applied rules of the game.

  • - 18

    signifies an increase in the relative prices of tradables, including both

    exportable and import-competing products. Structural adjustment of an

    economy to less attractive international economic circumstances, along with

    their concomitant balance of payments difficulties, generallY involves such

    an increase in the relative price of tradables.

    2.6 The exchange rate ranks high in importance as a policy

    instrument for the promotion of exports. The level of the exchange rate

    not only determines the competitiveness of exports, but also gives

    producers the simplest and clearest signal of the gains to be made through

    exporting. Other policy measures, such as export subsidies, are less

    immediate in their appeal. Experiences in a number of countries suggest

    that exporters respond more vigorously and more promptly to exchange rate

    changes than to other equally remunerative combinations of policy

    incentives. Furthermore, export subsidies, even if designed to offset any

    exchange rate overvaluation or fiscal discrimination, invite retaliation by

    trading partners.~ Third, nominal and real exchange rates are a fairly

    flexible policy instrument. In the context of macroeconomic policies, the

    real value of the exchange rate can be adjusted, through frequent nominal

    changes if necessary, to provide the desired real remuneration to

    exporters. During the pre-Plan Austral period of high inflation, however,

    changes of more than 1000% in nominal levels were needed to achieve 100%

    shifts in real levels.

    21 Since Argentina is now a signatory of the GATT Subsidies Code, such retaliation is more likely to occur, and more likelY to be detrimental should it occur.

  • - 19

    2.7 One way to evaluate the conduct of exchange rate policy is to

    examine the behavior of the real effective exchange rate (REER) over time.

    This rate is in essence a purchasing power parity rate (for a discussion of

    the methodology and data and a presentation of the estimates, see

    Attachment 2). It is a measure of how the purchasing power of Argentina's

    currency has changed over time in relation to the purchasing power of the

    currencies of Argentina's trading partners. For instance, when Argentina

    inflates more rapidly than the rest of the world, Argentina's exporters

    will find their costs rising more rapidly than the prices they can charge

    customers; their margins become squeezed. If the exporters raise their

    product prices in line with their costs they lose competitiveness. Either

    way there is a disincentive to exporting. Changing the exchange rate can

    restore exporter's margins. The REER also indicates, therefore, the degree

    to which Argentina's devaluations against the dollar (and, at the same

    time, the currency fluctuations of Argentina's trading partners against the

    dollar) have compensated for the difference between Argentina's inflation

    rate andthose of its trading partners. The REER index employs export

    weights based on Argentina's export markets. In essence, the index shows

    the relative movement over time of the value of the Argentina's currency

    against the country's major trading partners' currencies weighted by their

    shares in Argentina's exports after the effects of differential inflation

    rates are taken into account. An increase in the index indicates a real

    currency appreciation, while a fall indicates a real depreciation.

  • - 20

    2.8 The REER index, as estimated quarterly, is presented in

    Figure and Attachment 3.~./ The index shows that one of the major

    characteristics of Argentina exchange rate policy has been its volatility.

    The REER has fluctuated enormously, perhaps more than in any other country

    during the same period. The nominal exchange rate, pegged against the US

    dollar, remained fixed from mid-1971 until 1975. During this period,

    because of higher inflation in Argentina than in its trading partners,

    Argentina's export competitiveness eroded gradually but substantially.

    This erosion was followed by a major exchange rate adjustment in early

    1976. In the late 1970s, exchange rate policy was a major part of the

    effort to contain inflation and reduce inflationary expectations. The

    effect of this policy was to bring about a dramatic real currency

    appreciation and to undermine Argentina's export competitiveness. Between

    the end of 1977 and the end of 1980, the REER appreciated by close to 55%.

    This approach was unsustainable, and eventually the exchange rate regime

    collapsed. A subsequent and substantial adjustment had to be made in the

    real rate.

    2.9 The REER level at the end of 1985 did not appear to be wildly out

    of line relative to the level prevailing in the early 1970s. Whether the

    level at the end of 1986 was appropriate is another question. Given

    Argentina's debt service problem and the need to adj~st the economy to the

    changed international economic circumstances, it would appear that a higher

    ~ Although the REER is computed with a trade-weighted basket of currencies, a simpler procedure, involving only the US dollar and US inflation in comparison with Argentine inflation, was also employed. This estimate is the US dollar inflation adjusted real exchange rate (RER). Its movements closely approximate those of the REER. See Attachment 3.

  • --

    -21

    Figure 1

    .A, R: C~ E r-., JTIr'J./J..

    1 :;;!O

    110

    1CO

    9(,)

    dO -

    I

    R:EA.L EFF F" "'TE.:./-.J"

    4()

    :;:;~1=: 1

    11:1 -1 I

    ,~.t -t-rr"t-rr~ ,-,..T'I,-r-r'r-r"\---r'...,...."f"'-r......T-.....r~ I ' ,-r-r.,.....,.,...~~ i f ' iii .-. i , t , ~

    70 71 72 7~ 74 75 7e 77 76 79 80 81 82 83 84 85

    1']'7'::'-- 1 ~'Joe.5 F!!EEF'!: Ef'( QUu.~S o f'~J::J~ ..-Fif.. ~ F'EER-C:,;;rnlTl.

  • - 22

    REER (i.e., a more appreciated currency) would not be economically

    desirable.21 If the Government were to promote exports more aggressively

    and dismantle some existing restrictive trade policies, a lower REER would

    be warranted. The trade policy reforms necessary for more effective and

    sustained export expansion would impl~( a real depreciation.

    Trade Policy Regime

    2.10 Argentina's trade policy regime effectively restricts trade

    flows, creates distortions for resource allocation across tradeable goods

    sectors, discriminates for domestic sales against exports, and further

    contributes to economic waste by rewarding rent-seeking behavior.

    2.11 Greatly simplified, Argentina's trade policy regime consists of

    import restrictions, and export taxes and subsidies. Import restrictions

    are elaborate and nontransparent, and are applied with a strong

    discretionary component. Restrictions include tariffs, tariff exemptions,

    and, most importantly, highly restrictive quantitative limits on imports.

    2.12 Tariff protection is relatively moderate. Prior to Plan Austral,

    which increased de facto tariff rates by an additional 10%, ad valoreum

    II Between the June 1985 announcement of Plan Austral and April 1986, the nominal exchange rate was fixed despite domestic inflation of over 40%. Fortunately, the REER did not undergo a concomitant appreciation, in great part due to the weakening of the US dollar against third country currencies.

    http:desirable.21

  • - 23

    tariff rates ranged up to 48%.8/ Yet, virtually all tariff items (99%)

    carried a top rate of 38%, and nearly half of the items charged had tariffs

    of 25% or less. An import weighted average of tariffs for the first six

    months of 1985 covering those products not receiving tariff exemptions was

    19.6% (see Table 2)~' A disproportionate share of total tariff revenue is

    collected on high tariff items. For the first six months of 1985, only

    14.4% of imports paid tariffs of 38% or more but these imports generated

    43.4% of all tariff revenues (for a frequency distribution of imports and

    tariff collections according to tariff rates, see Attachment 4). Despite

    Argentina's relatively moderate tariff levels, many imported products are

    exempted from tariffs altogether by industrial promotion schemes adminis

    tered by the Government. In the first half of 1985, 34% of all imports

    were exempted. As a result, the average realized tariff rate computed for

    all imports was only 12.9% (see Table 2). The tariff exemptions created an

    estimated US$130 million tax revenue loss for the first six months of

    1985. Despite that revenue loss, tariff exemptions have grown, reflecting

    in part the arbitrary nature of the system. In 1981 the average realized

    tariff rate (tariff collections divided by total imports) was 19%. In

    creasing tariff exemptions, coupled with the decline of overall imports,

    have further exacerbated the fiscal situation of the Government, which is

    heavily dependent upon indirect taxes levied on trade flows.

    2.13 In mid-1982, import limits were intensified in an attempt to cope

    with the balance of payments crisis. These direct controls have since been

    8/ For an analysis of the tariff system, see World Bank, "Argentina: Strategies toward Industrial and Export Development", Report No. 58416-AR, September 30, 1985.

  • -24

    ;

    . Table 2: REALIZED TRADE TAXES AND SUBSIDIES AND AN',n-EXPORT BIASES. BY PRODUCT CATEGORY (Jan.-June] 985)

    ,"

    Sec. Oescri&:)tion

    Ave. Export

    Tax Rate ( y,,)

    Ave. Ex&:)ort Subsidy

    Rate ( '1. )

    Net Ex&:)ort Subsidy

    Rate (%)

    Ave. Realized

    Tari-F-F Ratell

    ( 7..)

    Ave. Nominal TariH Rate/2

    (7. )

    Nominal Anti-Ex&:)or

    Bias Rate/3

    ( %)

    o Mu,e. &c Samp les 0.0 0.0 0.0 0.2 3.0 3.0 1 Animal Products 4.5 2.7 -1.8 7.4 9.4 11.2, 2 Vegetable Products 20.1 0.3 -19.8 4.3 10.4 30.2 '3 Misc. Animal &c Veg. 14.2 0.0 -14.2 10.9 13.9 28.0 4 Food Ind. Products S.e 0.7 -7.9 4.6 5.2 13. 1 5 Mineral Products ~8.1 0.1 -SS.O 10.8 17.2 75.3 e Chemical Products 1.9 1.8 0.0 7.4 12.9 13.0 7 PlastiC Goods 1.0 3.3 2.3 20.9 22.e 20.3 9 Leather Products 12.2 0.4 -11.9 10.8 22.3 34.2 9 Wood Products 2.1 2.8 O.e 16.2 le.e 16.0

    10 Pul&:) &c Pa&:)er Prod. 1.0 2.9 1.9 le.6 20.8 19.0 11 Textiles &c Apparel 12.5 5.2 -7.2 20.1 2e.4 33.e 12 Shoes &c Other App. 4.4 O. 1 -4.3 13.7 26.4 30.7 13 Nonmet. Min. Prod. 0.8 3.5 2.7 18.4 27.0 24.3 14 Jewelry 20.3 0.0 -20.3 11.9 22.2 42.6 15 Metallurgical PrOd. O.e e.9 e.3 14.e 20.e 1.4.3 le Machinery &c Engines 0.7 3.4 2.7 12.S 22.0 19.2 17 Trans&:)ort Machinery 0.3 . 5.2 5.0 20.7 27.9 22.8 1S Precision Equi&:)ment 1.2 3.1 1.9 13.e 14.7 12.8 1.9 Wea&:)ons 0.0 4. 1 4. 1 33.e 38.2 34. 1 20 Misc. Manu~acturing 0.3 2.9 2.5 20.7 23.2 20.7 21 Art Objects 3.9 0.0 -3.9 0.0 51.7 55.6

    SUMMARY:

    Ag. &c Agr. Indus. 0.4 -1.6.5 4.9 8.e 25.1 Industry (ex. Agro) 3.4 -9.6 13.2 19.4 28.9

    of which: Capital Goods 0.5 4.3 3.8 16.S 24.4 20.6

    Total 16.0 1.1 -14.9 12.9 19.6 34.4

    . Notes: 11 The average reallzed tari~f rate is defLned and estimated as import

    tax collections divided by the value of imports. 21 The averageno;inal tarif~ rate is calculated as the average realized

    tariff rate~ except that tari~f exempted imports are excluded. 31 The nomlnal anti-export bias rate, expressed as a percentage of FOB

    value, is equal to the average nominal tariff minus the net export subsidy rate.

    Source: Computed from INDEC information. See tables in attachment for a greater disaggregation.

  • - 25

    consolidated, and they now constitute the core of the the Argentine import

    restriction and protection system.9/ All imports are now subject to prior

    permit. Importers must obtain an import authorization called a"Declaracion

    Jurada de Necesidades de Importacion" (DJNI). For goods not produced in

    the country (about 5,500 tariff positions out of 11,000), the DJNI is

    issued automatically 48 hours after an application is submitted. Issuing

    the DJNI takes four steps in two different locations: (i) the application

    is received at the Secretariat of Industry and Foreign Trade (SICE); (ii)

    the data is entered into a computer data base; (iii) the data is processed

    in a computer located in another location (the Ministry of Social Welfare)

    where both inputs and outputs must be entered manually; and (iv) the DJNI

    is handed over to the importer, back at the SICE.

    2.14 Once imports are authorized under DJNI, tariff protection for

    these goods is moderate because the ad valorem rates currently applicable

    are still the ones set at the time of the 1979 reforms: tariff rates

    ranging from 0% to 38%, with only about 1% of imports paying higher

    duties. In mid-1985, these rates were augmented 10% by a temporary surtax

    imposed as part of Plan Austral. Import data for the first six months of

    1985 (before the surtax was imposed) show that 34% of Argentina's imports

    entered the country duty free; another 31% of imports paid duty at a rate

    of 10% or lower; 12% of imports paid between 10% and 20%; and the remainder

    paid higher rates (including 14.4% of imports which paid 38% or higher).

    Overall, the ratio between tax collections and imports for that period

    indicates an average collected rate of 12.9%, excluding the surtax.

    21 The nature of the import regime is specified in Decree 4030 of December 1984. A detailed analysis is provided in World Bank, "Argentina: Strategies toward Industrial and Export Development", Ope cit., pp. 81-86.

  • - 26

    2.15 The remaining 5,500 tariff positions--covering mostly imports

    in competition with local production--are subject to discretionary

    authorizations that result in further protection of imports. For about

    4,500 tariff positions, the import permit applications are referred to

    producers' associations to determine whether there is local production

    available that could satisfY the needs of the potential buyer. As a rule,

    the producers' associations approve the issuance of import permits only if

    domestic production is not available; price competitiveness is not a

    dominant consideration. As a consequence of this cumbersome, costly system

    of prior consultations, actual protection for local producers is

    indeterminate. Although the formal decision to authorize competitive

    imports is made by the SleE, this agency seldom if ever rejects the

    producers associations' recommendations. Finally, about 1,000 tariff

    positions are subject to prior approval on the basis of public health

    considerations or compliance with international agreements.

    2.16 Although the elimination of the system of prior consultations

    with the producers' associations was part of the lMF stand-by agreement,

    the Government could not implement the elimination, and the lMF Board

    waived this condition when it released the last tranche of the stand-by. A

    gradual transition to automatic DJNl probably would have allowed the

    Government to advance in the trade regime area, reducing at least part of

    the distortion built into the system.

    2.17 The import licensing system in effect disallows competitive

    imports for a wide range of products, and protection for domestic

    production and sales is considerable. Domestic prices for such products

  • - 27

    are not constrained by international prices; they are determined by the

    interplay of domestic market forces as tempered by price controls. Since

    markets in Argentina are relatively small and commonly highly concentrated

    among a few producers, product prices and production costs are

    frequently high, and product quality poor.~/

    2.18 On the other side of the trade equation, Argentina's exports are

    also restricted by an elaborate system of licenses, permissions and taxes.

    The export licensing system uses selective export prohibitions, along with

    taxes, to keep down the domestic prices for agricultural goods. The export

    procedures are in themselves complex and involved for all products,

    frequently requiring export authorizations from a number of different

    government institutions.

    2.19 Exports are also impeded by fiscal measures. Export taxes are

    levied on a wide range of products, and are highly concentrated on

    agricultural products. Table 2 presents data on realized export taxes and

    subsidies. In the first half of 1985, the average realized tax rate on the

    exports of agricultural and agro-industrial products was 16.9%. Under Plan

    Austral, export tax rates were raised by another 8%. Since then, however,

    steps have been taken to reduce such taxes, particularly for agricultural

    products.

    2.20 Export taxes are only partially offset by a system of tax

    incentives and subsidies. Manufactured exports are exempt from the final

    production stage of indirect taxes. Moreover, an explicit fiscal subsidy

    lQ/ An analysis of an unrepresentative sample of manufactured products revealed implicit tariffs, based upon domestic and international price comparisons, ranging from 25% to 200%.

  • - 28

    has been provided to compensate producers for the payment of indirect taxes

    on previous stages of production. These subsidy rates have varied over

    time and by product. At the end of 1986, owing to governmental budgetary

    constraints, they were practically nonexistent. When the subsidies were in

    effect during the first half of 1985, the realized export subsidy rate for

    industrial exports was 3.4%. Because of the magnitude of export taxation

    (13%), these subsidies were not sufficient to offset export taxes (see

    Table 2). In the aggregate, net export taxes for all exported products

    amounted to 14.8% of the FOB value of those exports.

    Reform of the Temporary Admission Regime

    2.21 Temporary admission regimes (TAR) allow export industries to

    obtain imported inputs at international prices. Thus, they reduce the

    anti-export bias introduced by protectionist policies and increase the

    international competitiveness of exports. If the TAR is automatic and

    covers all types of inputs, exporters will operate in a simulated free

    trade regime. Argentina's TAR is deficient on several counts, and its

    value as an export promotion instrument is quite limited. Several reforms

    would make it more valuable while moving exporters towards free trade

    status. The major deficiencies of Argentina's TAR are: (i) inadequate

    administrative procedures; (ii) lack of automaticity; (iii) limited

    coverage of inputs; (iv) lack of provisions for indirect exporters; (v)

    lack of provisions for the replacement of stocks of non-duty-free imported

    inputs used to produce exports; and (Vi) lack of applicability to capital

    goods.

  • - 29

    2.22 Coverage and Automaticity. Argentina's TAR is highly

    restrictive. It applies only to inputs that cannot be supplied

    domestically, or where the price of domestic supplies exceeds by roughJY

    30% or more the c.i.f. price of the imported good. These restrictions have

    injected a strong protectionist element into the temporary admission

    system, neutralizing a good portion of its export promotion value.

    Furthermore, the restrictions generate a case-by-case review of DJAT

    (Declaracion Jurada de Admision Temporaria--a TAR import request)

    applications, which causes delays. The applications are reviewed by a

    Government committee that publicizes them, and may be obliged to review the

    complaints of affected domestic producers. Protectionist considerations

    often prevail; standards for admission or rejection are not explicit. For

    example, the 30% preference margin mentioned above has not been written in

    any law or statute. In practice, DJAT applications are hotly contested by

    producers who try to force exporters to use domestically produced inputs

    (even if uncompetitive or of inadequate quality) in an attempt to

    piggyback on the exporter's profits. Contentious, lengthy meetings are the

    rule rather than the exception when these matters are discussed, and the

    public officials are often put in the position of being judges, all of

    which contributes significantly to the above-mentioned delays.

    2.23 The TAR should be automatic, and its coverage should be broader.

    Eut this should be done gradually, since it would open up the economy to

    foreign competition. Although this opening would be limited, it would

    still likely generate widespread resistance among local producers who

    currently face low and declining sales levels. Also, still fresh in

    prOducers' memories is a fully automatic TAR that was included in the

    1979-81 experiment and became a source of legal contraband.

  • - 30

    2.24 Indirect Exporters. Argentina's TAR cannot be used by indirect

    exporters, since regulations explicitly forbid the transfer of goods

    imported temporarily. Some exporters circumvent this prohibition by

    importing via the TAR and passing on the inputs to a supplier. Customs

    considers this illegal. Extending the TAR to indirect exporters would make

    exports more competitive internationally, in turn fostering backward

    linkages in production, raising the quality of inputs, and inducing the

    development of a more export-oriented manufacturing sector. Those

    producers already using the system would. avoid the legal risks they

    currently face.

    2.25 Replacement of Stocks of Imported Inputs. Generally, a TAR can

    be used only by a producer who at the time of importing inputs knows that

    he will be exporting. Thus, the exporter must have a firm export order or,

    alternatively, he must have a steady, predictable, flow of exports. Such a

    feature builds a bias into the system, discriminating against small and

    medium-scale enterprises and first-time exporters.

    2.26 Capital Goods. Argentine customs laws do not permit the tempor

    ar,y admission of capital goods unless they are re-exported. The re-export

    of capital goods embodied in goods produced for export is not allowed.

    Including capital goods in the TAR is not likely to have any significant

    impact. Many imported capital goods enter the countr,y duty free,

    irrespective of whether they are to be sold domestically or used to produce

    for export. This duty-free entry occurs via the industrial promotion

    regime, which grants exemptions of import taxes on capital goods,

    income tax holidays, and exemptions from the value added tax. Furthermore,

  • - 31

    the Government's limited supervision capacity, coupled with the virtual

    impossibility of insuring that capital goods are used only to produce for

    export, could convert the temporary admission of capital goods into a

    virtual free-for-all, eroding the public image of the broader TAR and

    jeopardizing its survival. Further, the subsector that produces capital

    goods needs special restructuring measures, and the Government intends to

    design an action program to do this. It is recommended that the TAR not

    include capital goods for the time being. After the Government launches

    its restructuring program for capital goods and reforms its various systems

    of investment incentives, the merits of including capital goods in the TAR

    should be reviewed.

    Simplification of Import and Export Procedures

    2.27 The World Bank's 1985 report, "Argentina: Strategies Towards

    Export and Industrial Development," identified the complexity of export

    procedures as an important factor affecting the country's export

    performance. The Government concurs with this judgment and intend~ to

    initiate a program of reforms with strong private sector support. However,

    the actual course of events indicates that bureaucratic resistance to

    change is stronger than initially anticipated.

    2.28 Automatic TAR Import Requests. Automatic TAR import requests

    (DJNIs) take 48 hours to issue. This is not a significant bottleneck,

    but reducing it could be a signal to the private sector of the Government's

    determination to make the TAR system automatic. For importers in good

    standing, Customs has established a simplified import procedure to clear

  • - 32

    goods from Customs within 48 hours after their arrival. Except for the

    identification of the goods, all of Customs' verifications are made after

    the goods enter the country legally. Should Customs find any error or

    inconsistencies in the documentation submitted, the importer would be

    subject to stiff penalties, one of whjch is to be denied the possibility of

    utilizing the simplified import procedure.

    2.29 Prior Authorization of Export Shipments. The large number of

    public agencies involved in issuing prior authorizations of export ship

    ments is a deterrent to export activity, causing delays, introducing

    uncertainty about shipment dates, and increasing private sector costs.

    Towards the end of 1985, the Government decided to consolidate all such

    prior authorizations in a single procedure managed by Customs. A

    presidential decree instructed the 30 public agencies involved to appoint

    officials to work in a special area provided by Customs, the ventanilla

    unica (single window), where exporters could obtain approval from all

    agencies. Unfortunately, the same decree gave Customs the authority to

    exempt public agencies from compliance with this rule in special cases. A

    few days later, Customs issued a regulation exempting all but two of the

    public agencies involved. Predictably, the private sector complained. The

    Government reacted strongly, and Customs reversed itself and decreed that a

    public agency's prior authorization would be automatically granted unless

    that agency sent a representative promptly.

    Intervention by a Commercial Bank. Commercial banks must

    intervene in the documentation of every export shipment, a requirement

    originally made by the Central Bank to certi~ that exporters made suitable

  • - 33

    arrangements to get paid. Through their intervention, the commercial banks

    do not guarantee the inflow of foreign exchange. Rather, they are supposed

    to monitor foreign exchange inflows, and report back to the Central Bank if

    they detect that an exporter is not surrendering foreign exchange on time

    and in the established amounts. Until recently, Customs authorized the

    shipment of exports when the exporter produced the export documentation

    with a commercial bank certification. This procedure was not an obstacle

    for exporters. Some cases of fraud were detected, however, when the

    certificaion was falsified by exporters to avoid surrendering foreign

    exchange at the official rate. 11/ To guard against those actions, the

    Central Bank and Customs established an additional control. Commercial

    banks are now required to confirm their certifications daily by sending a

    special form to Customs headquarters. Shipment of the goods is authorized

    only after the exporter displays the certification, which Customs checks

    against the confirmation sent by the commercial bank.

    Elimination of Export Taxes

    2.31 Export taxes have traditionally been levied as an easy, expedi

    tious way of generating revenues, largely concentrated on agricultural

    products. Most export taxes on industrial commodities were eliminated in

    August 1985. The remaining taxes range from 5-10% of the f.o.b. value of

    exports, while those on petrochemicals range from 30-60% of f.o.b. value.

    Non-agricultural commodities currently covered by export taxes include

    11/ Exporters who cashed in their foreign exchange in the parallel market could get 30-40% more than the official rate before Plan Austral was adopted. Since then, however, the parallel rate has averaged only 10% above the official rate, and towards the beginning of July 1986, the spread had been reduced to 2%.

  • - 34

    fuels, chemicals, leather manufactures, jewelry, and some minerals. A

    program for reducing export taxes on agricultural commodities has been

    agreed on with the World Bank. Reduction of export taxes on fuels and

    chemicals is part of the ongoing discussions related to the Bank's

    proposed lending in oil and gas. Elimination of export taxes on

    manufactures is a key element in industrial export growth, and would

    constitute a clear signal of the direction of the Government's policies.

    2.32 The net effects of the Government's trade policies regime are

    considerable anti-export biases. These biases make the domestic market

    more attractive and profitable than export production and sales. Evidence

    of such anti-export biases is presented in Table 2. Lower-range estimates

    of the anti-export biases for major product groups range from 11% (animal

    products) to 75% (mineral products).~/ For all traded goods in the

    ~/ Some qualifications to these estimates are in order. First, the rates are computed on a nominal rather than an effective basis. It would be preferable to have them done on an effective basis, i.e., estimated as a percentage of value added in productive activity. Second, the effects of Argentina's extensive system of nontariff barriers are omitted. To include these effects would require a comprehensive analysis based upon domestic and international price comparisons. Instead, the average nominal tariff has been used as a proxy for protection afforded in the domestic market. Since the nominal tariffs constitute underestimates of protection, the anti-export bias rates presented in Table 2, and Attachment, Table 2, are low estimates. Third, the tax, tariff, and subsidy rates in Table 2 are computed on the basis of collected taxes and tariffs and disbursed subsidies; they are realized rates. In addition to presenting some anomalies in the aggregates, a further downward bias in the anti-export biases exists. For example, to the extent that taxes on either exports or imports are prohibitive for those trade flows, they are omitted from the estimations. Finally, the data presented in Table 2, and Attachment 4, Table 1, are provided according to the trade classification; it would be preferable to have the information organized according to the industrial classification, thereby permitting a more thorough examination of the structure of incentives. For a competent and insightful analysis conducted for 1977, the reader is referred to Julio Berlinsky, Proteccion Arancelaria de Actividades Seleccionadas de la Industria Manufacturera Argentina, Buenos Aires, Ministerio de Economia, 1977.

  • - 35

    aggregate, the nominal, lower-range anti-export bias rate has been

    estimated at 34%.

    2.33 Export taxes are one of the main reasons that Argentine

    anti-export biases are so high. If Argentina had the ability to affect

    international price levels for its exported products, the optimal export

    tax argument would justify such export taxation. But with the possible

    exception of wheat, this is not the case, and there is no welfare-

    maximizing economic rationale for Argentine export taxes. Instead,

    Argentine income and welfare are reduced by these taxes. The rationale for

    export taxation is primarily fiscal (although historically there may have

    been a confiscatory element). The Government is heavily dependent on

    export tax revenues. In the first half of 1985, export tax receipts

    amounted to approximately US$700 million (see Attachment 5).~ While the

    reduction of export taxes is highly desirable on economic grounds,

    alternative sources of fiscal revenues will have to be found if such

    reductions are to be viable. For 1986 it is estimated that these

    reductions in trade taxes will result in a fall in revenue of about A 300

    million which is equivalent to about US$318 million (at 1986 period average

    exchange rate).

    Special Export Incentives Program

    2.34 In order to offset anti-export policy biases, successive

    Argentine governments have intermittently pursued a number of export

    promotion schemes. In general, these programs are administered in a

    11/ By way of comparison, import taxes for the same period totaled US$246 million, and fiscal export subsidy expenditures were US$50 million.

  • - 36

    discretiona~ and frequently discriminatory fashion. Moreover, as a whole

    they do not overcome the policy bias against exports. There are currently

    two principal export promotion schemes--the tempora~ admissions regime

    (TAR) and the recently announced special export incentives system.

    2.35 Ideally, the TAR should be able to substantially reduce the

    anti-export bias for individual producers. The scheme is designed to

    provide exporters with access to inputs at international prices, i.e-,

    unrestricted duty free imports of products to be incorporated into the

    final exported product. Many countries (e.g., Korea, Taiwan, Brazil) have

    used such a aystem to considerable advantage in expanding exports. An

    effectively-run TAR can short-circuit the detrimental effects of the

    protection system on inputs for export manufacturing. But because of the

    way in which the TAR currently operates in Argentina, the country is denied

    the full benefits of such a system.~1

    2.36 A second major governmental program for export promotion is the

    Special Export Program (Programas Especiales de Exportacion, or PRESEX or

    PEX) to be administered by the Minist~ of Industry and Commerce. PEX

    incentives are negotiated individually with applying firms, based upon a

    firm's incremental exports over a period of up to five years. The scheme

    is aimed primarily at larger firms, but also allows participation by

    cooperatives and trading companies. To qualify, a firm's exports must have

    increased at least US$2 million per year, or US$10 million over a five-year

    period. The benefit to participating firms is a fiscal reimbursement

    111 Between 1978 and 1983 Argentina employed an automatic and unrestricted TAR for export production. Although it evidently functioned reasonably well, it was terminated primarily to protect domestic producers.

  • - 37

    of up to 15% of the f.o.b. value of the increase in the firm's exports. To

    fund these payments, an amount roughly equivalent to US$60 million was set

    aside in the 1986 central government budget.

    2.37 While it is still too early to assess the results of the PEX

    program, several effects are likely. First, as with any system based upon

    incremental exports, substantial distortions are probable. Under PEX,

    two firms producing and exporting the same product, in the same amount, to

    the same market, could receive entirely different effective domestic

    currency remuneration, with the pioneer exporting firm receiving less.

    Existing exports are not benefitted. The formation of phantom new

    exporting firms is not inconceivable, and arrangements between previously

    exporting and nonexporting enterprises to take advantage of the incremental

    export incentive would not be surprising. There is a risk that existing

    exports will be supplanted by "new" exports, leaving overall export levels

    little increased, if any. The natural government response to these sorts

    of problems may be a counterproductive further tightening of inspection,

    administrative controls, and bureaucratic requirements.

    2.38 A second probable characteristic of the PEX incentives is that

    they are bound to be highly discretionar.y and nonautomatic. Moreover, the

    process appears to be a ver.y paper-intensive and bureaucratic one. 15/

    12/ To apply for the program, a firm must complete 14 lengthy forms and 4 annexes.

  • - 38

    Because the program has a limited budget, PEX incentives are to be awarded

    on a case-by-case basis. Just what the criteria are for inclusion in the

    program is not yet known. For this reason, many firms, especially

    established exporters, view the program with skepticism. For prospective

    exporters outside Buenos Aires, the cost of chaperoning their paperwork

    through the various officials is often prohibitive.

    2.39 Third, the PEX program invites retaliation by Argentina's trading

    partners. Once the program is in place, exports that receive PEX benefits

    are likely to be subject to countervailing duties in the importing

    countries. The PEX benefits, while intended to offset discriminatory

    policy treatment of exports, will be viewed formally and legally as an

    export subsidy. Since Argentina is not a signatory of the GATT Subsidies

    Code, it is not necessary for importing countries to show injury in order

    to apply countervailing duties. Therefore, a response by Argentina's

    trading partners may be quick and detrimental to all Argentine exporters of

    the products in question.

    2.40 A likely fourth effect of the PEX program is that it may

    contribute to the uncertainty that prevails regarding overall export

  • - 39

    policy.~/ The program requires governmental fiscal resources at a time

    when fiscal constraints are particularly acute, and there is no budgetary

    provision for such resources beyond 1986. The expected difficulties in

    administering a program based upon incremental exports, and the likelihood

    of retaliation from Argentina's trading partners further contribute to

    export policy uncertainty in general, and doubts about the PEX program in

    particular.

    2.41 In addition to the TAR and the PEX program, there exist a host of

    other, less significant government programs designed to promote exports.

    While once important, a number of official export financing and credit

    incentive schemes have been severely curtailed. Obtaining credit for

    export production and/or sales does not appear to be an insurmountable

    problem for exporting firms, but such credit is only available at the very

    high real market interest rates currently prevailing in Argentina. The

    Export Finance Unit described in Section III could help address this

    problem. The Government also has an export marketing and information

    ~/ In discussing the PEX program in Argentina, reference is frequently made to the reasonably successful BEFIEX program instituted in 1972 in Brazil. There are a number of critical differences between the two programs, however. First, the major benefit enjoyed by firms participating in the BEFIEX program is duty free importation of capital goods and some intermediate inputs. (Imports for export production are unrestricted and duty free as a matter of course under Brazil's equivalent of the TAR.) Second, to the extent that a fiscal export subsidy may still exist under BEFIEX contracts, that subsidy was in place for all exporters across the board at the time the multi-year contract was signed. Furthermore, any remaining subsidization is not based upon incremental exports, as is the case with the PEX program. Third, while there have been conflicts between Brazil and its trading partners concerning the BEFIEX incentives, those conflicts have been attenuated by the fact that Brazil is a signatory of the GATT Subsidies Code.

  • - 40

    service operating through its overseas embassies. While this service is

    potentially valuable, few firms have reported export sales generated

    through it.

    Recommendations and Policy Suggestions

    2.42 Expanding exports is absolutely essential if Argentina is to

    emerge from its economic crisis and resume economic growth and

    development. A strategy for aggressively expanding exports, as reflected

    in general terms in the Government's "Guidelines of an Economic Growth

    Strategy 1985-89," merits further specification and implementation. The

    overall emphasis of such a strategy should be on increasing export

    competitiveness and productive efficiency. Doing this will require a major

    commitment on the part of the Government, and substantial and politically

    difficult changes in the overall economic policy environment. Without such

    changes, however, exports are unlikely to undergo any sustained growth, and

    economic recovery will remain elusive. It might be possible to facilitate

    such policy changes, and perhaps even build some support for them, if the

    Government were to announce its commitment to export expansion and indicate

    a target expansion of, say, 15% annually. In doing so, attention could

    then be focused on those policy changes necessary to bring about the

    achievement of the export target.

    2.43 The cornerstones of a strategy of export expansion and

    economic recovery should be: (i) the provision of a stable economic policy

    environment; (ii) relative price changes to improve Argentina's competitive

    position in international markets and to provide greater incentives for

  • - 41

    exportables; (iii) reduction of the anti-export biases in present economic

    policies; and (iv) increased automaticity and transparency in the

    administration of incentive policies, coupled with procedural

    simplification and the reduction of governmental red tape. While the

    policy changes necessary to support export-led economic growth ,are numerous

    and interrelated, two individual policies stand out as central--an

    aggressive exchange rate policy, and a viable and smoothly functioning

    system of temporary admissions for export production.

    (a) Exchange Rate Policy. In order to spur exports and growth, an

    aggressive exchange rate policy should be pursued to assure both

    the relative price relationship necessary to foster tradeable

    goods production in Argentina, and the competitiveness of

    Argentine products in world markets. In addition, a stable and

    competitive real exchange rate is crucial for sustained export

    growth, and should be a policy objective. In the present

    context, the Government, at a very minimum, should not permit any

    further appreciation of the austral.

    (b) Export Incentive System. There should be several improvements to

    the current export incentive system, primarily to reduce the

    existing anti-export biases in economic policies. They are:

    (i) Reform of the Temporary Admissions Regime (TAR) for

    Export Production. All restrictions imposed on imported

    inputs for export production should be removed, perhaps

    gradually. Such imports should be duty free and unimpeded;

    the only administrative requirement, subject to subsequent

  • - 42

    verification, should be that the inputs actually be

    incorporated in the exported production. The system should

    possess well defined and universal rules and procedures.

    Thus, it should be fully automatic and in no way subject to

    discretionary approval on the part of f,Overnment officials.

    In implementing such a reformed TAR, it may be desirable to

    proceed on a piecemeal basis, gradually expanding a positive

    list of permissible imports to include the universe of all

    tariff positions. At some later stage, the reformed system

    should be extended to indirect exporters, perhaps linked with

    an export financing system based upon a letter of credit, as

    is done in Korea. The final policy objective should be a

    completely free trade regime for export production.

    (ii) Reduction and Removal of Export Taxes. All export taxes,

    with the possible exception of the tax on wheat, should

    eventually be removed. The fiscal impact of these tax

    reductions could be minimized by initiating a revenue neutral

    export tax reduction and tariff reform. Also, since domestic

    food prices would rise as a result of these actions, some

    targeted food subsidies to low income groups may be desirable

    from the viewpoint of equity.

    (iii) Reimbursement of Indirect Taxes for Exports. The

    remaining indirect taxes embodied in exports should be

    rebated. To do this, the Government will require a

  • - 43

    better understanding of the magnitude of such remaining

    taxes paid in previous stages of production, and a

    convenient, and non-countervailable, mechanism to effect the

    reimbursement, probably in the form of a tax credit.

    (iv) Acceleration and Extension of the Ongoing Simplification of

    Export Procedures. The "sole window" for export

    authorizations should be fully implemented and the remaining

    paperwork simplified.

    (v) Elimination of Export Licensing for Most Products. While

    procedural simplifications such as the "sole window" approach

    constitute a considerable improvement, export licensing for

    nearly all products should eventually be eliminated. A

    simple export declaration, employed in many countries, could

    be instituted for statistical purposes, subject to subsequent

    verification and control.

    (vi) No expansion of the PEX Export Incentives. The PEX program

    is likely to encounter numerous economic and administrative

    difficulties and should not be expanded.

    (vii) GATT Participation. The Government should weigh the pros and

    cons of adhering to GATT as a means of more effectively

    advancing Argentina's international trading interests.

  • - 44

    (c) Reform of System of Import Restriction. Policy changes in the

    import restriction system could also help reduce the existing

    anti-export biases in economic policies. In addition, these

    changes would increase competition and productive efficiency.

    Four new policies would help bring about a significant and

    lasting reform of the import restriction system. They are:

    (i) Reduction of Quantitative Import Restrictions. The list of

    products requiring prior permit should be dramatically

    reduced. If this cannot be done in one step, it might be

    possible first to eliminate the necessar,r consultation

    procedure with local producers associations. The number of

    products requiring prior permit should then be continually

    reduced, in concert with a tariff reform and the passing of

    those products into the category of automatic import license

    approval. Eventually it might be possible to eliminate

    import licensing altogether, except for some very special

    products.

    (ii) Reduction of Tariff Exemptions. All tariff exemptions,

    except those related to the TAR or other export programs,

    should be e~iminated as part of a more generalized tariff

    reform. Not only would this make the tariff system more

    efficient, but tariff revenues would also increase.

    (iii) Tariff System Reform. The tariff system should be reformed

    in such a way as to make tariffs the major policy instrument

  • - 45

    for providing domestic market protection. As the use of

    Annexos I and II are reduced, tariffs for many products

    should be increased. In doing so, tariff dispersion and

    tariff averages will increase, at least initially. A

    suitable tariff range in the initial phase of such a reform

    might be 10-90%. If properly designed, the revenue impact of

    this tariff reform could be substantial. Over time, the

    upper limits of the tariff schedule should be reduced. As

    experience and confidence with the reform grow, more

    elaborate timetables and schedules could be formulated and

    announced.

    (iv) Modernization of Adversely Affected Sectors. To accompany

    the suggested trade policy reforms, a comprehensive program

    of adjustment assistance should be instituted for those firms

    and workers adversely affected. The adjustment assistance

    should help firms modernize their plant, re-equip if they can

    ultimately compete, restructure their assets, and improve

    their efficiency.

    2.44 The policy changes suggested here imply a fundamental change in

    economic direction and strategy. Not only does this require a major

    commitment on the part of the Government; it implies substantial technical

    work as well. To this end it may be desirable to establish a small

    inter-ministerial working group within the Government, probably under the

    auspices of the Ministry of Economy, to do the necessary analytical and

    preparatory work for implementing the desired policy reforms.

  • - 46

    III. SPECIAL PURPOSE EXPORT FINANCE FACILITY

    A. Objective

    3.1 One of the major obstacles to the growth of the Argentine export

    sector is the lack of adequate financing. A useful scheme for alleviating

    this problem is the pre-financing export program the Government is

    currently sponsoring. Consideration, however, needs to be given to the

    potential impact that additional financing could have on the money supply

    and, consequently, on inflationary expectations. One possible way of

    advancing monies to exporters, while at the same time avoiding pressures on

    monetary policy, would be the creation of a Special Purpose Export Finance

    Facility (SPEFF). This agency would reside outside Argentina and raise

    funds in the international capital markets. The principal objectives of

    the SPEFF are as follows:

    (a) To assist the Government of Argentina in financing export

    promotion programs, and to attract the foreign investment and

    foreign exchange revenue necessary to repay existing

    indebtedness;

    (b) To make existing and future export promotion programs

    more efficient and expedient for the Argentine exporter; and

    (c) To create-a link between the domestic and international capital

    markets and the export financing function, so as to increase

    private sector participation and create the framework for an

  • - 47

    eventual transfer of this responsibility away from the

    Government.

    B. Structure

    3.2 The central element of the proposed SPEFF would be an

    independent, special purpose company that raises funds in both the domestic

    and international capital markets and onlends those funds to Argentine

    exporters of goods, services and equipment.22!

    3.3 These loans will be funded by the issuance of debt securities by

    the SPEFF in the international capital markets. The type of security will

    be determined by the term of the underlying loan, as defined by the World

    Bank and the Argentine exporter's requirements. Since there are likely to

    be various sources of funds that satisfy particular term requirements, the

    type of security will also be the one that offers the lowest rate at that

    time.

    3.4 It is conceivable that the securities issued by the SPEFF could

    be sold on terms approximating those of international credit. The World

    Bank could choose to back the asset side of the balance sheet. Such a

    pass-through effect could essentially prove to be true in the markets for

    the securities because the only effective guarantor of the securities would

    be the World Bank. While the SPEFF could function as a stand-alone credit,

    the interposing of the credit of a AAA-rated private financial institution

    11/ A similar structure has been employed by the UK for the refinancing of a portion of its rescheduled credit to Brazil.

    http:equipment.22

  • - -~

    between the SPEFF and the investor would add marketability to the

    security. Specifically, the securities issued in the international capital

    markets would be supported by a surety bond to be issued by a AAA-rated

    private financial institution such as an insurance company.

    3.5 To account for the possibility of late payments by exporters on

    the SPEFF credits, and the delay before disbursement under the World Bank

    guarantee, the SPEFF structure would include a backstop revolving credit

    facility. The beneficiary of this facility would be the SPEFF itself, with

    drawings allowed solely for the purpose of making timely payments on the

    SPEFF's market obligations, pending receipt of funds from the exporter or

    receipt of disbursements under the World Bank guarantee.

    3.6 The revolving credit facility could also be used to fund initial

    disbursements of credits granted by the SPEFF pending the issue of

    securities. Such an alternative would give the SPEFF greater flexibility

    in both the size of its disbursements and the timing of its security

    issues.

    c. Mechanism of the SPEFF Structure

    3.7 The following outline assumes, for the sake of illustration, the

    issuance of floating rate notes by the SPEFF. In practice, any capital

    market instrument could serve as the underlying security. In this example,

    the World Bank acts as an export credit agency guaranteeing the Argen