chapter v. changes in labor relations 1....

70
Chapter V. Changes in Labor Relations 1. Introduction Some time ago, Dunlop proposed the concept of industrial relations system to refer to the basic values, laws, institutions and organizational practices that govern employment relations (Dunlop, 1958). Later, in Foucault’s theory and in post- structuralism, the system notion was criticized and the lattice or constellation concept was proposed to take into account less rigid relations, with discontinuities, dispersions, contradictions, and hard relations (cause-effect) together with more lax relations (impressions, illustrations). Thus we may consider the industrial relations system as a constellation of relations that are not all functional in relation to the whole, or in other words, a not entirely coherent “system.” On the other hand, Dunlop’s definition is strongly biased with its accent on the “regular” character of industrial relations, with shared values and clearly established norms accepted by the actors, forming a system with their institutions, similar to a Parsonian social system. It would seem that there are no grounds for anomalistic conflict, and if it appears, it is only within the framework of what the system itself has foreseen. Behind this functionalist conception of the industrial relations system is the appearance of “organized capitalism,” linked to the interventionist, benefactor State with its intention to harness interclass conflict within legally sanctioned norms and channel it through mediating institutions (Hyman, 2001). All of this has been part of the reality of 20 th century relations between capital and labor, but not all of these forms of relations may be reduced to the “industrial relations system,” and less so in an underdeveloped country in which the double logic of these relations is evident on a daily basis. In any case, the industrial relations concept remits to various levels of analysis which, without building a system, may be linked to other levels characteristic of labor relations. In that respect, Katz and Kochan (1988) affirm that collective negotiation —the center of industrial relations— may be contemplated at three levels: Strategic: the objectives, structures and strategies of labor unions and management;

Upload: others

Post on 09-Nov-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Chapter V. Changes in Labor Relations 1. Introduction

Some time ago, Dunlop proposed the concept of industrial relations system to

refer to the basic values, laws, institutions and organizational practices that govern

employment relations (Dunlop, 1958). Later, in Foucault’s theory and in post-

structuralism, the system notion was criticized and the lattice or constellation concept

was proposed to take into account less rigid relations, with discontinuities, dispersions,

contradictions, and hard relations (cause-effect) together with more lax relations

(impressions, illustrations). Thus we may consider the industrial relations system as a

constellation of relations that are not all functional in relation to the whole, or in other

words, a not entirely coherent “system.” On the other hand, Dunlop’s definition is

strongly biased with its accent on the “regular” character of industrial relations, with

shared values and clearly established norms accepted by the actors, forming a system

with their institutions, similar to a Parsonian social system. It would seem that there are

no grounds for anomalistic conflict, and if it appears, it is only within the framework of

what the system itself has foreseen. Behind this functionalist conception of the industrial

relations system is the appearance of “organized capitalism,” linked to the interventionist,

benefactor State with its intention to harness interclass conflict within legally sanctioned

norms and channel it through mediating institutions (Hyman, 2001). All of this has been

part of the reality of 20th century relations between capital and labor, but not all of these

forms of relations may be reduced to the “industrial relations system,” and less so in an

underdeveloped country in which the double logic of these relations is evident on a daily

basis.

In any case, the industrial relations concept remits to various levels of analysis

which, without building a system, may be linked to other levels characteristic of labor

relations. In that respect, Katz and Kochan (1988) affirm that collective negotiation —the

center of industrial relations— may be contemplated at three levels:

Strategic: the objectives, structures and strategies of labor unions and management;

Functional: the collective negotiation process itself, implying a legal labor framework,

institutions and procedures, as well as customs and traditions; and

Workplace: how industrial relations and collective negotiation translate into a workplace.

Kochan and Katz refer in reality to the impertinence of separation between

industrial relations (IR) and labor relations (LR). This last concept is commonly referred

to as “the forms and mechanisms for interrelation used by subjects in the framework of

production organization for the purpose of making decisions on the conditions for

carrying out work and the distribution of results" (Bronstein, 1995). In other words,

interpenetration occurs between IR and LR depending on the problem under analysis, and

these concepts remit rather to capital-labor relation levels, not limited to the two named

(IR and LR) but also others which may be specified and revealed in each particular case.

The capital-labor (C-L) relation in Mexico is composed of spaces and levels not

necessarily found in the same way in all countries. Some are direct levels in the

workplace and others are mediated through institutions and organizations:

1) C-L relations in the work process. Similar to Kochan’s definition for the workplace,

although the accent need not be exclusively placed on those relations which point toward

worker integration into company purposes in the workplace or increased productive

efficiency. If we open the concept, leaving space for the dysfunctional, incoherencies and

conflict, we are left in part with coded relations (by the organization or by collective

contracting), and in part with practices which follow labor customs and the labor cultures

of workers and management that are not always shared or part of a system. There is no

reason to suppose that C-L work process relations form part of a single system, nor that

values are shared, nor that total integration is required for work process efficiency. For

example, it is important to consider the possibility of coercion in the work process

through not necessarily consensual norms vertically imposed by management. It is

evident that there are uncertain and undefined spaces in the work process, with mobile

borders in terms of coding, however there are also spaces characterized by implicit

negotiations and power balances among actors.

2) In the circulation of the labor force: factors related to worker income (wages) and

employment volume (labor market), among others. These relations have been an area

exclusively reserved for the collective bargaining process.

3) In the social reproduction of the labor force: may be broken down into management of

the labor force by the State, and management of the labor force by companies and labor

unions.

4) That of conflicts and collective negotiation, which may be present without having been

exhausted in the three previous levels. Levels related to negotiation and conflict would

include those found in relations between labor unions and the State, and in the labor law

system. The formal, practical aspect of the process of collective negotiation should be

included at another level, or as in Mexico, in “the two frameworks of collective

negotiation,” where the informal is not simply that which fills the spaces left by the

formal, but that which on occasion substitutes it. And finally, we would also have to

consider conflicts as including the level of the labor movement, understood as collective

worker action.

5) Union relations with the “political system,” including political parties, social

movements, NGOs, legislatures, and the governmental administrative apparatus.

6) Broader relations between labor unions, the State, and business organization (historic

agreements, corporatism, etc.).

In synthesis, the capital-labor relation in Mexico ranges from the workplace to

formal collective negotiation, State relations and the labor movement. To consider them

related within a system is not very realistic. In any case it would be a “system” filled with

contradictions, incoherencies, asynchronous changes and discontinuities. As a system it

would be of marginal use, in terms of revealing its dynamisms, and with that conception

we would be forced to focus on normative analysis instead of analyzing reality, which in

Mexico are aspects which quite possibly correspond to different frameworks.

The international controversy around the flexibility of the labor force began

around 1980. The connotations of this controversy are academic (Taylorism-Fordism

crisis) or related to management strategy (Toyotism), State posture (flexibilization

policies in labor law or the exclusion of labor unions in State policy design), and labor

unions (resistance to or negotiation of flexibility) nature.

According to some of these theorizations, Taylorism-Fordism has reached its limit

in fomenting increased productivity and linking mass production and mass consumption.

Flexible organizational forms are becoming alternatives to take its place.

-The flexibility of the labor force or flexible use of the labor force may consist of

various dimensions:

Numerical flexibility: flexible adjustment of the size of the labor force according to

production and market needs. This dimension may take the form of adjustment in full-

time, permanent personnel; temporary worker employment; outsourcing; and classified,

white-collar personnel.

Flexibility in the use of the labor force in the work process: its main forms may be

internal mobility and a multi-skill focus. Also included in this modality may be flexibility

in applying sanctions, elimination of blind promotions, and decreasing the categories in

the job scale.

Wage flexibility: flexibility in the work year, with per-hour pay and especially, income

according to individual or group productivity or performance.

Proposals for labor force flexibility have taken different forms, such as the

flexibilization of collective bargaining agreements, flexibilization of labor laws,

flexibility in productive process practice, and labor market flexibility. But labor

flexibilization may be unilateral or it may be bilateral with labor unions or workers.

2. Changing Labor Relations

During the era of the new economic model (1982 to the present), Mexican labor and

industrial relations have been transformed through three stages:

a) First stage: Unilateral flexibilization. Between 1985 and 1992 there was a general

tendency toward the flexibilization of labor relations and the loss of labor union presence

in the designing of State economic and labor policy. Some of the most important

collective bargaining agreements went through a flexibilization process during this period

(in aviation, oil, iron and steel, telecommunications, and automotive industries, to give

some examples), and flexibility meant unilateral, management power in production

decisions. Flexibility was particularly numerical and functional, but not wage-oriented

(De la Garza, 1998) (Pozas, 1992) (Montiel, 1991) (De la O and Quintero, 1992) (Rueda,

1993) (Quintero, 1993). There were many disputes related to the flexibilization of

collective bargaining agreements in large companies during this period, especially in

government-owned companies prior to their privatization. These disputes were resolved

against labor union positions, with the exception of Telmex. Government-linked labor

unions attempted one last show of resistance without breaking their relationship with the

State in the late 1980s, when they criticized neoliberalism and vindicated the ideology of

the Mexican Revolution, but due to the loyalties and policies maintained by labor union

leaders, to the exclusion of the interests of the rank and file, the resistance movement did

not reach a significant stage. Independent unions resisted as far as their limited capacities

allowed, but in general were defeated.

b) Second stage: Negotiating. The second stage covered a period from 1992 to 1994,

coinciding with the government’s promotion of productivity agreements with bonus

schemes as a form of wage recovery —a new wage concept, and the possibility of a new

social pact between labor unions, companies and the State to substitute that of the

Mexican Revolution. This is also when discussion focused on the crisis in State

corporatism, and the need for new State-allied but also company-allied unionism in the

battle for the competitive edge. This process officially began with signing of the National

Agreement on Increasing Productivity and Quality (Acuerdo Nacional para la Elevación

de la Productividad y la Calidad—ANEPC, 1992), in which labor unions are

acknowledged on paper as interlocutors in negotiations with management on corporate

modernization. This pact details the government’s proposed productivity agreement

adopting the latest total quality concepts; establishes bilaterality between companies and

labor unions; and enunciates a complete industrialization model. In the following section

we will analyze the path taken by the productivity pacts that emanated from this

agreement (De la Garza, 1993).

We can classify the productivity agreements in two types: active and passive. In

the first, labor unions are given the role of active interlocutors in corporate restructuring

plans, and the opportunity for broad participation in their design, implementation and

evaluation. With regard to the productivity program, labor unions may intervene in

decision-making involving technological, organizational, training, work conditions and

environment, and productivity measurement aspects and in determining the criteria for

distributing economic benefits.

Passive productivity pacts limit action by labor unions to merely accepting

management projects in exchange for preserving certain work conditions and especially

defining productivity incentives. In this case, labor unions do not participate in designing

the corresponding plans or determining productivity indicators. It is an instrumental pact

which does not modify labor relations between companies and labor unions. In other

words, it signifies giving companies free reign, in exchange for some supplementary

income for workers.

Starting at the outset of 1994 and in relation to NAFTA, the Mexican government

induced the establishment of productivity agreements between companies and labor

unions. The government also promised changes in the formula for annual wage increases,

from a calculation based on the following year’s projected inflation rate to a new formula

which would also take into account the previous year’s productivity increase.

In 1994, the Metropolitan Association of Industrial Relations Executives

(Asociación Metropolitana de Ejecutivos de Relaciones Industriales) conducted a

Productivity Agreements survey, and following are some of the most important results of

that survey:

• Most companies did not establish productivity agreements until 1994, in other

words, under pressure from the October 1993 Economic Pact between labor

unions, company owners and government.

• Individual bonus payments predominated.

• 58% of companies that signed collective bargaining agreements in early 1994 and

established agreements fixed the amount of 2% of base wages for bonuses, the

same as that established by the Pact for minimum wages.

The Labor Ministry carried out its own Productivity Agreements survey in 1994,

the results of which may be summarized as follows:

- Productivity agreements were highly concentrated in large companies; 87.8% of

agreements corresponded to companies with more than 300 workers.

- Only 50% of agreements mentioned measuring, diagnosing and economically

stimulating increased productivity.

- In 1994, 79.4% of agreements allocated 2% or less per bonus and these agreements

encompassed 87.2% of workers.

- Most agreements only considered general company performance and did not measure

individual, group or department productivity.

- The most common goals were reduced to merely attendance and punctuality.

All agreements used similar terms to declare each party’s commitment to confront

globalization challenges, promote a new work culture, and involve labor unions and

workers in productive modernization. They also recognized needs for new contents in

training and to move from confrontation and distrust between capital and labor toward a

climate of cooperation and collaboration. Differences exist among agreements as to

whether they promote individual, group or mixed bonuses. Some contemplate mixed

commissions while others make no such mention, or assign their occasional functions to

traditional labor union entities. Some agreements which include mixed commissions

assign them broad functions, approaching what we have called active strategy. The

determination of parameters for measuring and the forms of payment are established both

unilaterally and bilaterally. Some establish a maximum bonus amount in relation to base

wages while others do not indicate limits of any sort. The conditions for receiving

bonuses also vary: bonuses are rewarded in some cases simply for fulfillment of certain

previously established goals, while in others the percentage which may be received upon

surpassing certain previously-reached values in productivity is left open. Total resources

designated to bonuses may be previously established indicating an upper limit, or they

may depend on results obtained, with no established limit. Finally, it may be noted that

some companies offered productivity bonuses in exchange for flexibilization of collective

bargaining agreements, allowing a multi-skill focus, or reducing categories in wage

scales.

c) Third stage: Progress and limitations in flexibilization.

In the third stage of changes in labor relations, from December 1994 to the

present, the strategy for establishing productivity agreements and bonuses was initially

minimized, in response to the economic crisis initiated in December 1994 which

depressed real wages considerably and disabled the effect of bonuses on worker income.

Nevertheless, in mid-1995 the Mexican Workers Confederation (Confederación de

Trabajadores de México—CTM) and the Mexican Employers Confederation

(Confederación Patronal de la República Mexicana) began negotiations toward a new

labor culture. The negotiations were finalized in August 1996 and proposed a new

relationship between labor unions and companies, focused on cooperation instead of

confrontation, with the aim of winning the battle for competitiveness. The document

incorporates the best-known total quality and just-in-time doctrines and it may be

considered an agreement of principles among labor and employer organizations for labor

law reform.

Over approximately the past ten years we have witnessed the flexibilization of

some of the most important collective bargaining agreements in Mexico. It may be that a

flexibility model is being defined —without bilaterality signifying the involvement of

labor unions.

The intensity of the flexibilization of collective bargaining agreements in Mexico

depends on various factors:

1) Depending on the previous model. From the point of view of labor force

flexibility, collective bargaining agreements in Mexico have been dominated by the

“Mexican Revolution model,” although there have been three other sub-models

influenced by the first:

- The Mexican Revolution model is illustrated in the collective bargaining

agreements of the former, large state-owned corporations, especially the monopolies,

with strong corporatist unions and important PRI and government influence (oil,

electricity, railroads, telecommunications, etc.). This model also applied to large national

or transnational corporations with private capital and strong labor unions. These

collective bargaining agreements incorporated extensive economic benefits with

numerous lucrative advantages for the union as an organization, and strong protection for

workers in terms of job security, no internal mobility or multi-skill focus in the

production process, upon threat of sanctions. The agreements implied broad bilateral

relationships with labor unions in these areas but not in corporate strategic planning or in

technological or organizational changes (Mondragón, 1993) (Mondragón, 1994) (Mora et

al., 1990). This model is the one that has experienced the most transformation since the

1980s. Only some aspects remain to date without flexibilization, such as in the collective

bargaining agreement of the Mexican Electrical Workers Union and some of the

industrial branch agreements referred to as legal contracts (Boston Consulting Group and

Bufete Industrial, 1988).

- The sub-model in small and medium companies, which we might consider the

younger sibling of the model just described, since that is the ideal it follows. However,

these collective bargaining agreements are generally more flexible and unilateral (Morris,

1997) (Mercado, 1992).

- The sub-model focused on labor regulation of government employees, based on

the laws stipulated by ISSSTE, work in government offices, and general work conditions

(GWC). It is unilaterally rigid at the level of the mentioned laws (for example, in the

areas of job permanence, task assignment and benefits system), while flexible in the areas

of GWC due to its unilateral character and other aspects of labor force use. In the 1980s

and 1990s, flexibilization has also been applied to GWCs, although in some cases labor

unions have been able to play an active role in practice (Tiburcio, 1992).

- The sub-model in corporatist yellow unionism —linked to companies, not the

State. This model has always been flexible, with labor unions more concerned with

economic benefits than control over the work process. This model has changed little with

flexibility policies.

Flexibilization in Mexico has most affected the first-order collective bargaining

agreements —long presented as a conquest of the Mexican Revolution, in the sense of a

long process characterized by a historic alliance between the workers movement and the

State (Rodríguez, 1992). If we make a comparison according to the number of years a

company has been in operation, experience shows in general that the collective

bargaining agreements in the newer companies are more flexible than in older companies,

within the same branches.

The flexibilization implemented has most affected the following aspects:

introduction of new technology, work methods, work organization, and corporate

organizational structure, as well as other factors such as:

- use of temporary workers,

- use of outsourcing,

- classification of white-collar workers,

- internal mobility,

- multi-skill focus,

- reducing categories in wage scales,

- elimination of blind promotions, and

- greater management capacity to make adjustments in full-time, permanent

personnel.

In general we are looking at flexibilization that is not based on reaching

agreements, that has been achieved with either passivity or resistance on the part of labor

unions, and has tended to exclude those unions from important decision-making on the

use of the labor force in work processes and technological or organizational changes.

This is what we call unilateral flexibility, as opposed to a type of flexibility which, rather

than letting capital do as it wishes in the work process, looks for consensus, participation

and involvement from labor unions, in the interest of productivity and quality. Alongside

unilateral flexibility, we are witnessing the expansion of new forms of work organization

that presuppose worker involvement —however that involvement can take place either

with intervention by labor unions or with their exclusion, and the latter has been the most

common (Weeks, 1999).

2) The intensity of flexibility in collective bargaining agreements in Mexico also depends

on whether productivity and quality are at the immediate center of corporate strategy

(driven by competition). The greater the importance of productivity and quality for

remaining in the market in Mexico, the greater the tendency toward the flexibilization of

collective bargaining.

Within certain limits, flexibility allows companies to increase productivity (the

Marxist distinction between productivity and labor intensification is obscured in

neoclassic economic theories) because it allows more precise use of the labor force. If

this is modernizing flexibility (Toyotism), then we might also add the contribution to

productivity and quality represented by the interest, initiative and imagination of workers

who have a commitment to capital.

In general, management strategies focused on productivity tend to place emphasis

on:

- technological changes,

- changes in work organization, and/or

- changes in capital-labor relations.

3) Government policy with regard to companies and labor is also a factor in the intensity

of flexibility in collective bargaining. The Mexican government (through the Department

of Labor, for example) continues to maintain an important role with respect to

flexibilization in collective bargaining (Córdova, 1976). Companies, especially those

foreign-owned, sometimes demand flexibility in labor and labor union relations as a

comparative advantage (Cavazos et al., 1993). While this type of negotiation is not made

totally public, we have knowledge of some important cases such as the Ford plant in

Hermosillo, where the company obtained a flexible collective bargaining agreement in

advance —through authorities and labor union leaders— that is very different from the

agreements reached in other Ford plants in Mexico. On other occasions, it is not so much

through negotiations, but rather there is a tacit agreement in which Department of Labor

officials and labor union leaders understand that a new investment will require favorable

conditions, including flexibility in collective bargaining (De la Garza, 1992) (ACLAN,

1997).

4) Union strategy vis-à-vis flexibilization also plays a role. Here, it is important to

reiterate that unionism in Mexico may be divided into three broad tendencies: corporatist

(with its dependence on State policy), independent, and yellow (with dependence on

companies instead of on the State) unionism.

Each of these forms of labor unionism has adopted a different strategy in relation

to flexibilization in collective bargaining:

a) Corporatist unionism has adopted two strategies. In the first and most common,

no opposition is given to flexibilization, and in the best of cases, efforts are made to see

that the Federal Labor Law (Ley Federal de Trabajo—LFT) is respected. The second,

corresponding to some sectors of CTM, CROC and SNTE, consists of negotiating

proposals between labor unions and companies, to ensure that the labor union functions

as an interlocutor in the flexibilization process.

b) Independent unionism has also adopted two different positions. The most

common in this case is opposition, generally followed by defeat. And the second is to

attempt to function as interlocutors in the possible reorganization of work and collective

agreements, which is what FAT and UNT have done. (De la Garza and Melgoza, 1991).

c) Finally, yellow unionism has continued in its historic tradition of submission to

company policies.

The positions taken by labor unions have influenced the reconversion process in

the following ways: passive unions have allowed the most far-reaching examples of

reconversion and flexibilization; unions presenting opposition and resistance have not

detained these processes, however sometimes they have prevented them from being fully

imposed; and unions willing to negotiate compromises have managed to vary the form

and scope of reconversion, without submitting themselves to the weakening process

suffered by those offering resistance.

These labor union positions having an impact on the intensity of flexibilization

also vary according to the democracy practiced in the specific labor unions. Passive

strategies are almost always adopted with only marginal consultation with the rank and

file; unions negotiating compromises tend to consult with members and there is a certain

mobilization and discussion among members; and unions that take a confrontational

stance involve the rank and file membership to a greater degree in mobilization efforts.

5) The tradition of struggle and the worker’s culture. This element, intermixed with labor

union strategies, also has an impact on the intensity of flexibility. Some sectors of

workers have traditions of struggle that are part of their historic memory (Brief and Nord,

1990). The Mexican Electrical Workers Union is one example. These memories may

cause labor unions to consider certain forms of flexibility in collective bargaining as

lacking legitimacy, not only due to the consequences for workers but also because of the

threat to what unions view as their “legacy” won through many years of struggle and

negotiation. However, in addition to this historic memory of past struggles, it is also a

matter of socially acceptable working conditions, possibly influenced by the labor culture

in the region, and the type of worker. One reason that maquila factories are located along

the northern border may be because a new type of worker has been sought (young women

without experience in labor unions or collective bargaining). By locating in zones without

a broad-based social culture in terms of manufacturing labor, it is easier to establish

flexibility conditions that would not be readily accepted by workers in other zones

(Carrillo and Ramírez, 1990).

Taking into account the six factors that potentially have an impact on the intensity

of flexibilization in collective bargaining in Mexico, we can identify two types of

flexibility at the two poles of the spectrum that have been manifested so far in relation to

these factors:

1) First, at one pole we find maximum flexibility and unilaterality on the part of

companies in using the labor force in the work process. This situation can be found

especially in the new export-oriented industry in northern Mexico, combined with new

forms of work organization; with passive or yellow unions, coinciding with a government

policy aimed at attracting investment by offering the comparative advantage of low

wages coupled with work flexibility; with a working class lacking significant job or

collective bargaining experience; and located in zones not previously industrialized and

with undemocratic labor unions.

2) Secondly, we have moderate flexibility without total corporate unilaterality (De

la Garza and Melgoza, 1994). This can be found particularly in the old, reconverted

industry where new forms of work organization have also been applied; with

government-linked, neo-corporatist or independent unions; with a less rigid and unilateral

government policy than in the first case, for the purpose of avoiding employer-worker

and political conflicts; with an older working class having job and labor union

experience, and with a culture of protecting job positions; and with labor unions that are

more active and democratic than in the first. This second pole can be found in private,

modernized industry and government-owned industry.

2. Work flexibility in practice, in manufacturing production

The introduction of new organizational forms in Mexico does not lead to the same

level of numerical flexibility, or direct flexibility or outsourcing. In manufacturing

companies in the formal sector, full-time workers hired for indefinite periods of time

predominate, while part-time and hourly work is marginal. There may be two

explanations for this tendency. One is the long-standing monopoly maintained by labor

unions over the labor market and their historic demand for job security. It may be that the

last recourse offered by corporatist unions for workers in large Mexican companies is a

certain guarantee for job permanence, although the tendency is decreasing. However,

perhaps the most important explanation comes from management strategies with regard

to personnel, which take into account the potential negative effects on productivity from

extreme labor instability, combined with the fact that full-time workers are not so

expensive as to consider substituting them with temporary workers or outsourcing.

Table V-1: PERCENTAGE OF FULL-TIME, PART-TIME, HOURLY, AND

OUTSOURCING WORKERS IN MANUFACTURING ESTABLISHMENTS IN 1991,

1994 AND 1999

Size Full-time Part-time

1991 1994 1999 1991 1994 1999

Total 85.6 85.5 88.2 0.5 0.4 0.67

Large 86.5 88.4 87.1 0.2 0.09 0.2

Medium 86.2 86.4 86.2 0.3 0.09 0.4

Small 89.1 91.8 90.0 0.8 0.6 1.0

Micro 77.1 78.4 89.7 1.3 0.7 1.2

(Continued)

Size Hourly Outsourcing

1991 1994 1999 1991 1994 1999

Total 0.1 0.03 0.36 1.9 0.2 1.0

Large 0.03 0.03 0.1 1.8 0.3 2.1

Medium 0.06 0.01 0.1 1.6 0.0 0.9

Small 0.4 0.02 0.8 1.7 0.3 1.0

Micro 0.1 0.05 0.6 2.7 0.0 0.2

Source: INEGI (1992, 1995, 1999), ENESTYC.

Note: The reason that the totals for 1999 do not add up to 100% is because there is also a

group of workers who earn salaries. This percentage is also extremely small for all sizes

of establishment —which may be one of few keys left for achieving stability in the area

of labor, and for the survival of one type of corporatist unionism.

As seen in the previous table, the percentage of full-time workers did not decrease

during the 1990s, while non-full time or temporary labor varied only slightly and

remained very secondary.

With regard to the various aspects of functional flexibility, we included them in our

analysis of new forms of work organization in Chapter IV.

In reference to wage flexibility, as we have mentioned, the National Agreement

on Increasing Productivity and Quality (Acuerdo Nacional para la Elevación de la

Productividad y la Calidad—ANEPC) was signed in 1992 among the highest-level labor

union, business and government officials. Its objective was to pressure companies to sign

productivity agreements with labor unions, in an attempt to convert those labor unions

(through an impulse coming from the top) into key players representing capital in

productivity programs, and to establish bonuses or incentives based on productivity. Up

until October 1993, no significant repercussions could be noted from ANEPC, but in that

month a new economic agreement established the partial indexing of minimum wages

with an increase in productivity, and called on company owners to sign productivity

agreements and to raise wages, in part because of that increased productivity. The result

was that by January 1994, the number of productivity agreements began to increase

rapidly. Can this be interpreted as a reverse of the ten-year trend toward unilateral

functional and numerical flexibility but not wage flexibility?

The percentage of workers subject to agreement and wage revision which

included bonuses reached a maximum of 56.5% in 1994, subsequently dropping to 12.1%

in 1996 and holding at that range to the present date. Total agreement and wage revisions

which included bonuses reached a maximum of 13.7% in 1995, dropping to half that

percentage in 1997, and remaining below the 1995 level to date. In other words, the

importance of bonuses has tended to diminish with respect to the number of companies

and workers involved, having reached the highest levels during the first two years of

application (1994 and 1995). Most of the agreements with bonuses correspond to

revisions at the local jurisdiction level, but the majority of workers affected were at the

federal level, although this is the sector that has decreased the most over the years.

Table V-2: AGREEMENT AND WAGE REVISIONS THAT INCLUDE BONUSES OR

INCENTIVES

Year National Federal Local

Revisions Workers Revisions Workers Revisions Workers

1994 2 629 1 203 071 1 505 1 126 555 1 124 76 516

1995 4 351 621 920 1 913 527 915 2 438 94 005

1996 2 870 273 655 832 216 550 2 038 57 105

1997 2 089 280 197 859 252 555 1 230 27 642

1998 2 700 314 099 1 044 282 916 1 656 31 183

1999 2699 314 788 932 274849 1767 39 939

2000 3 092 414 210 1183 365 504 1909 48 706

2001 2 898 344 987 880 304 346 2012 40 641

Source: STyPS (2001) Labor Statistics.

The global results from the policy of granting bonuses and incentives to workers, in terms

of any increase in their wages, are not encouraging: 90% of agreements signed in 1994

allotted a 2% increase for productivity, the same percentage assigned to minimum wages,

and any impact on wages has been extremely minimal (Ruiz Durán, 1998). By 1995, the

policy for recuperating real wages through productivity bonuses was cancelled out, given

a 51.9% inflation rate and an average productivity bonus rate of 1.2%.

Table V-3: WAGE INCREASES OBTAINED IN FEDERAL JURISDICTION

REVISIONS (Percentage of annual increases)

Year Direct

increase in

wage scale

From

adjustment

From

productivity

In benefits From

recalculating

wage scale

1996 21 0.6 0.4 1.3 0.0

1997 19.5 0.05 1.2 2.1 0.09

1998 17.7 0.05 1.2 1.5 0.08

1999 16.5 0.03 1.0 1.6 0.1

2000 12.4 0.04 1.8 1.4 0.1

2001 9.1 0.04 1.6 2.4 0.06

Source: STyPS (2001) Labor Statistics.

Table V-4: PERCENTAGE OF MANUFACTURING ESTABLISHMENTS OFFERING

PRODUCTIVITY BONUSES TO THEIR WORKERS AND PERCENTAGE OF

WORKER WAGES CORRESPONDING TO BONUSES, WHEN OFFERED (1994)

SIZE ESTABLISHMENTS WITH

PRODUCTIVITY

BONUSES

PERCENTAGE OF

WAGES

CORRESPONDING TO

BONUSES

Total 5.3 10.3

Large 36.8 8.6

Medium 29.1 8.9

Small 17.6 8.4

Micro 3.9 11.1

Source: INEGI (1995), ENESTYC.

The articulations between companies and their surroundings, specifically in terms of

where suppliers and clients are located, and the forming of productive chains through

outsourcing, were also analyzed in Chapter IV.

As explained in the Annex, numerical, functional and wage Flexibility Indexes

were calculated, and then used to calculate a General Flexibility Index, first using MIM

and ENESTYC surveys, later for a random sample of 1,000 collective bargaining

agreements under federal jurisdiction, and finally for another sample under local

jurisdiction.

The General Flexibility Indexes (MIM, 1994) are averages, and large

establishments are more flexible than medium and small establishments. As for the

differences between exporting and non-exporting manufacturing establishments as well

as those with national versus foreign capital, one might assume that exporting companies

and those with foreign capital would have more modern sociotechnical configurations.

We should first mention that since the survey did not discriminate among large exporters,

conclusions may not apply to companies with high exporting levels. However,

differences in overall flexibility did not vary significantly between exporters and non-

exporters, or according to national versus foreign capital. The more important variations

in flexibility may be observed by looking at company size, especially macro companies

(with more than 500 workers). Similar conclusions may be obtained from calculating the

general flexibility index on the basis of ENESTYC data.

Table V-5: General Work Flexibility Indexes in 1994

Flexibility Index

Total 0.51

Macro 0.59

Large 0.54

Medium 0.5

Small 0.47

Exporters or non-exporters

Exporters 0.50

Non-exporters 0.51

Source of capital

National 0.50

Foreign 0.51

Source: Based on MIM (1994) survey. Index varies between 0 and +1.

As for worker involvement in production, high involvement levels are infrequent in

exporting and non-exporting companies as well as those with national and foreign capital.

Low involvement of workers clearly predominated in all cases.

Table V-6: WORKER INVOLVEMENT LEVEL (Percentage of establishments)

(1994)

INVOLVEMENT EXPORTER SOURCE OF CAPITAL

Yes No Foreign National

Low 70.7 72.5 74.4 71.1

Medium 23.9 22.1 23.1 22.7

High 5.4 5.4 2.5 6.2

Source: MIM (1994).

We have built two indexes on bilaterality between labor unions, companies and

workers, on the basis of MIM survey data. The first (labor union bilaterality) looks at

whether labor unions participate with companies, formally or informally, in making

decisions regarding employing and not employing personnel, the work process,

organization, and technological changes. The second index (total bilaterality) also considers

full-time, permanent workers, in addition to labor unions, while using the same dimensions

of formal or informal co-participation.

The results indicate that high levels of bilaterality in any of its forms are infrequent,

although more common in large establishments.

Table V-7: High Levels of Formal, Informal and Total Bilaterality in Manufacturing

Industry (Percentage of establishments)

Labor union bilaterality Total bilaterality

Formal Informal

Large 8.3 5.3 14.3

Medium 5.6 1.4 0.0

Small 0.6 1.5 0.0

Source: MIM (1994).

In reference to companies negotiating with labor unions and workers on matters

of employment, production process, wages, technology and work organization, the

following two tables show low levels of total bilaterality (formal and informal, with labor

unions and/or workers) in exporters and non-exporters, with insignificant variations

between them. The index is also low among both national and foreign-owned companies,

while lower in foreign-owned.

Table V-8: TOTAL BILATERALITY INDEX 1994 (Percentage of establishments)

BILATERALITY INDEX EXPORTERS CAPITAL

Yes No Foreign National

Low 52.1 53.0 64.8 48.9

Medium 35.7 36.9 30.7 38.0

High 12.1 10.1 4.5 13.1

Source: MIM (1994).

Table V-9: FORMAL LABOR UNION-COMPANY BILATERALITY INDEX

(Percentage of establishments)

FORMAL BILATERALITY

INDEX

EXPORTER CAPITAL

Yes No Foreign National

Low 77.4 78.2 83.3 75.0

Medium 17.1 18.7 13.5 19.7

High 5.5 3.1 3.1 5.3

Source: MIM (1994).

When all the data on flexibility in labor relations is analyzed together —looking at

numerical aspects (facility to hire and fire personnel), functional aspects (multi-skill focus

and internal mobility), and wage aspects (wages based on productivity or quality)— we find

that it is likely that flexibility has advanced in Mexico, especially in large companies. The

level it has maintained, however, is not particularly high but rather at a mid-level.

With regard to zone-based differences in work flexibility and total bilaterality, we

find that in all cases the flexibility level was most often low, however bilaterality was

homogenously low in Tijuana and Yucatan, while in Aguascalientes and Orizaba it was

average in small and medium-sized industry and between low and average in large

companies in Orizaba. This indicates that modernization in work organization in large

companies in Tijuana and Aguascalientes has not been accompanied by bilaterality with

unions or workers. What has taken shape is possibly a modern authoritarian style of control

—different from the traditional authoritarian style in small and medium-sized companies in

Yucatan. The mid-level bilaterality found in Orizaba cannot be explained by new

management conceptions of participation and involvement by workers and unions, but

perhaps by its location in a zone characterized by an old style of unionism which, although

corporatist, preserves remnants of participation with companies in decision-making,

supported by collective bargaining agreements that are different from those in more recently

industrialized areas.

3. Labor unions and flexibility

In Mexico the unionization rate in manufacturing companies changed little between 1991

and 1998, as opposed to most countries, where this rate diminished. The explanation may

be twofold: first, as a consequence of the corporatist agreement for mutual protection

between the State and unions. Although the agreement has suffered from neoliberalism, it

has not been broken. Union leaders have less and less to offer their members but they

have been useful in supporting policies on wage contention and flexibility in large

companies. The logic of sweetheart contracts has predominated in management policies,

even in relations with marginally authentic unions. In Mexico it is considered preferable

to have a union managed by leaders with whom State-supported agreements can be

reached, instead of risking the eventual formation of independent unions.

Table V-10: Percentage of Manufacturing Establishments with Labor Unions in 1998

Size Total Large Medium Small Micro

Percentage of

establishments

with unions

8.1 90.1 79.9 42.7 4.2

Percentage of

unionized

workers

46.0 68.2 56.4 34.9 8.6

Source: INEGI (1999), ENESTYC.

Table V-11: Correlation Coefficients between Unionization Rate and Productive Process

and Labor Variables

1991 1998

Productivity 0.545 0.548

Percentage with new technology 0.272 --

Percentage that made changes in production

organization

0.949 0.83

Percentage of full-time workers 0.47 (1994)

Percentage that used temporary workers 0.791 0.603

Percentage that used outsourcing 0.897 0.206

Percentage with worker involvement 0.818

Average remuneration per worker 0.59 0.70 (1994)

Percentage of establishments with productivity

bonuses

0.74 (1994)

Source: Based on INEGI data (1992, 1999), ENESTYC.

The above table illustrates a positive correlation between the presence of unions

in manufacturing plants and productivity, new technology, changes in work organization,

full-time employment, employment of temporary workers, use of outsourcing, worker

participation in improving productivity, wages, and productivity bonuses.

It is certainly true that a high positive correlation between unionization and

company modernization does not necessarily signify that labor unions are active,

participative agents in that modernization. In fact, our bilaterality measures indicate the

opposite, but at least we find that labor unions are not an obstacle for innovation in

companies and work flexibility.

Large companies are the most innovative and at the same time show the highest

unionization rate. MIM survey results also show positive correlations between

unionization and productivity, as well as between unionization and average remuneration

per worker.

Table V-12: Unionization and Level of Productivity in Manufacturing Industry, 1994

(percentage of establishments)

Presence of union Low productivity Average productivity High productivity

Yes 88.3 0.51 11.2

No 94.9 0.0 5.1

Source: MIM (1994).

Close relations between labor unions and the State continue in Mexico, despite the

weakening of unions and the difficulty in eradicating the tradition of Department of

Labor intervention in labor relations (De la Garza, 1993b) (Middlebrook and Quintero,

1998). These relations are, however, in the process of being redefined in the aftermath of

the PRI’s electoral defeat in the year 2000. It is difficult to use the number of labor strikes

as an indicator of conflict. The calls to strike, strikes, and number of striking workers

diminished in 1994, and the downward trend continued throughout the decade, although

the number of striking workers rebounded notably in 1999. On the other hand, the

number of labor claims filed that did not imply a call to strike increased in 1995 and then

remained high. For some time now this appears to have become the legal channel for

worker discontent, and has demonstrated viability —given the way that union

representation functions in Mexico.

Table V-13: Labor Conflicts in Companies Under Federal and Local Jurisdiction

1990 1993 1994 1995 1999

Claims filed 78 956 131 931 136 170 158 664 120 774

Calls to strike registered 34 141 42 573 43 370 42 368 39 195

Strikes 829 629 588 577 257

Striking workers 68 782 48 350 47 746 31 019 61 113

Conflicts in public sector 5,026 2,564 3,026 6,543

Source: Statistical Annex of Ernesto Zedillo’s Sixth State of the Union Report (2000).

4. Changes in Collective Bargaining

1). Introduction

For collective bargaining purposes, Mexican legislation divides workers into

those governed by Constitutional Article 123, Section A and regulated by the Federal

Labor Law (LFT); those governed by Section B and regulated by the Federal Law for

Government Employees (Ley Federal de Trabajadores al Servicio del Estado); and those

not included in the above two groups and subject to other special regulations.

The first group corresponds in general to workers in the private sector and in most

state-owned companies. The second category applies in general to workers employed by

the federal government as well as by a few state-owned companies. And the third

category includes the marines, members of security forces, foreign service employees,

Federal Electoral Institute workers, and workers employed by state and municipal

governments (the latter of which are subject to their own laws with provisions similar to

those in the noted Section B).

Workers governed by Section A enjoy the Constitutional right to collective

bargaining; while workers governed by Section B and those in the exceptional category

do not.

The Law defines a collective bargaining agreement as an agreement reached

between one or various labor unions and one or various employers or employer unions to

establish the conditions for working in one or more companies or establishments.

Two or more labor unions may establish collective agreements with a single

employer, and two or more employers may establish collective agreements with a single

labor union within the same industrial branch. Collective bargaining agreements in

Mexico are generally established at the company or establishment level. The exceptions

are legal contracts established between one or several labor unions and several employers

in the same industrial sector. The only sectors with their own legal contracts are: textiles,

rubber, sugar, and radio/television. Although legal contracts establish working conditions

for the entire sector, complementary individual agreements may also be established with

specific companies.

For workers entitled to collective bargaining, a single Federal Labor Law exists at

the national level, but its application corresponds to state governments (local jurisdiction)

except in those cases considered within the law to be under federal jurisdiction.

Generally, the latter correspond to the sectors which are the most important economically

and in terms of number of workers (railroad, mining, oil, textiles, federal concession

transportation, telephone and telegraph communications, education, film, rubber, sugar,

petrochemical, metallurgic, iron and steel, automotive, pharmaceutical, cellulose and

paper, vegetable oils, food packaging and canning, beverage bottling, limestone, lumber,

glass, and tobacco) or companies operating in two or more states.

Generally there is one collective agreement per company or establishment which

is signed by the majority union, although its effects extend to all the workers. Collective

bargaining agreements in Mexico often include exclusion or closed shop clauses for

worker entry (only union-proposed workers may be hired) and termination (employer is

obligated to fire workers who are expelled or withdraw from the union).

Collective bargaining agreements signed by labor unions and employers should be

registered with the Conciliation and Arbitration Board, at the local office in each state for

those under local jurisdiction and at the federal office for those corresponding to federal

jurisdiction.

In the following section we will analyze the quantitative expansion of collective

bargaining in Mexico in recent years and the primary changes that took place in the

1990s. In the largest companies there are, of course, higher rates of unionization and of

formal regulation. Regulations are more frequently found in the definition of the

functions of job categories, employment of temporary workers, personnel selection,

productivity (possibly resulting from signing of specific agreements), and training. It

should be noted that the percentage of manufacturing establishments with no formal labor

regulation is a clear majority, although this percentage is minimal in large companies and

small in medium and small-sized establishments.

Table V-14: Rate of Labor Regulation in Manufacturing Industry in 1999

Total Large Medium Small Micro

Job

categories

7.23 74.08 64.69 36.56 3.98

Turnover 4.19 28.19 22.18 17.82 2.84

Temporary

workers

7.23 64.6 52.5 25.6 4.97

Outsourcing 1.61 16.84 9.8 4.91 1.16

White-collar

positions

3.18 26.19 22.75 16.14 1.86

Personnel

cutbacks

2.31 28.42 19.33 10.31 1.35

New

technologies

2.99 24.56 19.54 12.37 1.97

Changes in

work

3.74 27.14 21.7 14.76 2.58

organization

Personnel

selection

6.07 55.83 43.88 29.02 3.63

Quality and

productivity

8.61 53.85 42.89 35.14 6.0

Training 9.27 79.07 69.87 45.5 5.49

Promotion 5.17 61.46 51.6 27.23 2.64

Other 1.58 2.63 2.37 2.02 1.53

None 78.42 5.67 9.71 24.52 83.56

Source: INEGI (1999), ENESTYC. The rate of regulation is calculated as the percentage

of total establishments in which each dimension is formally regulated by contract or

agreement.

Approximately 15,000 collective bargaining agreements are registered with

Mexico’s Federal Conciliation and Arbitration Board. As for agreements under local

jurisdiction, there are 104,064 registered at the Mexico City (Federal District) Local

Conciliation and Arbitration Board alone. The number of legal contracts is very low

because only a few industrial sectors are subject to this legal regimen (seven, four of

which are textile industry sub-branches). Nevertheless, contracts may be legally

registered but inactive for reasons such as the following: a) because the company or

union no longer exists, however notification was not given, or b) because the union

decided not to submit to revision. The Law allows but does not require ordinary revision

every two years. It is assumed that some contracts not subjected to revision, when both

union and company exist, are probably sweetheart contracts. A sweetheart contract is

registered with the Conciliation and Arbitration Board but is unknown to the workers,

and therefore may remain unchanged for long periods of time. However, a sweetheart

contract may be fictitiously reviewed and newly registered with the Board without

workers knowing if there were changes. In this case it statistically appears as active

although in reality it is fictitious. In other words, there is no reliable statistic to estimate

the number of sweetheart contracts in the country. Obtaining such an estimate would

require a field investigation, with all the political and safety implications.

Without assuming that the number of inactive contracts is equal to that of

sweetheart contracts, nor that all active contracts are not sweetheart contracts, it is

interesting to observe the percentage of contracts revised or the number of purely wage

revisions undertaken annually.

Table V-15: Number of Total Wage and Agreement Revisions (federal and local)

Year Revisions Workers affected

1994 26 489 2 127 801

1995 31 691 2 208 438

1996 34 940 2 258 029

1997 32 220 2 213 3454

1998 35 170 2 308 966

1999 38 747 2 492 762

2000 38 611 2 924 640

Source: STyPS (1999), Labor Statistics.

In 1998, approximately 11,792,520 waged workers potentially could have been

covered by a collective bargaining agreement according to the Labor Law (waged

workers older than 14 years of age, in establishments with more than 20 workers, without

considering the possibility that national unions may affiliate workers in establishments

with fewer than 20 workers, and excluding public administration and national defense

workers who are prohibited from signing collective bargaining agreements). According to

Table V-15, in that year alone, 19.6% underwent wage or agreement revisions, which are

presumably the workers with an active collective bargaining agreement. Between 1994

and 2000 the average yearly number of wage or agreement revisions was 33,981, and the

average number of affected workers was 2,361,997. Of the total revisions on average

between 1994 and 2000, 12.2% corresponded to those under federal jurisdiction, while in

number federal workers represented 66.3% of total revisions.

Table V-16: Wage and Agreement Revisions under Federal and Local Jurisdiction

Federal Local

Year Revisions Workers Revisions Workers

1994 3 170 1 525 739 23 319 602 062

1995 3 633 1 491 367 28 058 717 071

1996 3 686 1 491 454 31 254 766 575

1997 4 074 1 495 224 30 146 718 121

1998 4 525 1 567 955 30 645 741 011

1999 4 671 1 567 936 34 076 792 482

2000 5358 1 819 022 33 253 1 056 080

Source: STyPS (1999), Labor Statistics.

Table V-17: Collective Bargaining Agreements Registered with the Federal Conciliation

and Arbitration Board, by Type of Labor Confederation

Year CT CTM CROC CROM Indepen

1994 3 454 2 553 574 201 790

1995 3 165 2 231 573 161 619

1996 3 622 2 622 578 131 664

1997 3 673 2 568 632 176 691

1998 3 808 2 652 646 156 733

1999 3 964 2 593 757 206

2000 4 456 2 899 814 238 894

2001 4 495 2 901 893 225 1 176

Source: STyPS (2001), Labor Statistics.

CT: Labor Congress (Congreso del Trabajo); CTM: Mexican Workers Confederation

(Confederación de Trabajadores de México); CROC: Laborers and Small Farmers

Regional Confederation (Confederación Regional de Obreros y Campesinos); CROM:

Mexican Laborers Confederation (Confederación Obrera Mexicana); Indepen:

Independents.

Between 1994 and 2000, an average of 4,160 collective bargaining agreements were

registered with the Federal Conciliation and Arbitration Board. The Labor Congress

(Congreso del Trabajo — CT) accounted for 81.8% of the bargaining agreements

registered during that period. Independent and yellow unions accounted for 18.2% of the

contracts. Within the CT, CTM signed 76.1% of the collective bargaining agreements on

average; CROC 19.2%, and CROM only 5.3%. Since normal contract revisions are

biannual, we may estimate a total of 10,029 federal bargaining agreements under revision

in 1999 and 2000. In other words, of a total of 15,000 federal agreements, 66.9% are

active.

Table V-18: Branch Contracts Revisions Year Branch

Contracts

Workers Companies Individual

supplementary

contracts

Workers

1995 7 103 823 1 206 50 35 019

1996 7 101 760 1 228 66 30 419

1997 6 56 018 1 127 67 21 620

1998 7 101 188 1 472 62 63 125

1999 7 103 693 1 598 47 64 022

2000 8 148 631 1 690 25 9366

2001 4 53 635 1 447 20 7 752

Source: STyPS (2001), Labor Statistics.

Eight Branch contracts are subject to revision in Mexico, affecting an annual

average of 102,519 workers between 1995 and 2000. Over the years, the number of

workers protected by legal contracts has not changed much. In 2000, 8.2% of the total

workers affected by federal collective bargaining agreements and wage revisions at a

federal level were subject to Branch contracts. In 1999, only 2.9% had also signed single

agreements at a plant level apart from being ruled by a legal contract. 61.7% of the

workers were covered by this type of contract, however this percentage subsequently

decreased.

As far as the local collective bargaining agreements are concerned, between 1994

and 1999, there was an average of 29,583 agreement and wage revisions per year

engaging an average of 722,887 workers. In 1999, local revisions accounted for 87.9% of

the total revisions, but involved only 31.8% of the workers. An average of 335.7 workers

per revisions were involved in federal hiring and wage revisions, whereas only 23.2

workers were involved in local revisions.

The number of collective agreements reviewed locally may be very small in

relation to the total registered agreements. For example, in 1999 only 8,623 agreements

were reviewed in Mexico City out of a total of 104,064, i.e., 8.28%, (Mexico City Local

Conciliation and Arbitration Board 1999 Report, Labor Policy Report, No. 16, Mexico

City Labor Studies Executive Office). While some inactive bargaining agreements may

correspond to companies no longer existing, but not reported to the corresponding Board,

others may be sweetheart contracts, legal agreements whose very existence is unknown to

the workers.

Federal wage reviews in 1996 were -13.4 percentual points below that year’s

inflation and only 3.4 percentual points above the minimum wage increase. 1998

revisions were 1.8 points above inflation and 1.8 points above the minimum wage

increase, and 1999 figures were 2.2 and 2.5 respectively. As may be seen, minimum

wage increases continue to serve as parameters for the behavior shown by contracted

wages. Besides, the differences between minimum and contracted wages in average

percentual points were minimal. Between 1996 and 1999 that percentual difference was

only 2.5 points on average, which may be an indicator of union inefficiency in recovering

its members’ wages since minimum wage increases apply to all workers regardless of

union membership.

A. Federal Bargaining Agreements

The companies and unions that register their collective bargaining agreements with the

Federal Conciliation and Arbitration Board are companies that have establishments in more

than one state. They may thus be assumed to be the bargaining agreements of the largest

companies, which have been most protective of their employees. For the purpose of an

analysis of numerical, functional and wage flexibility, a random sample was taken by branch

(as classified by the Federal Conciliation and Arbitration Board) of approximately 10% of

the universe of collective agreements (n=1000 contracts), using the same dimensions and

indicators as the MIM survey. The Indexes of Numerical, Wage and Functional Flexibility

were calculated as explained and may be found in the Annex. These indexes vary between –

1 and +1. Based on a survey of collective bargaining agreements carried out by the

Department of Labor, factorial analysis was conducted in order to determine numerical,

functional and wage flexibility coefficients and thereby estimate a general index of

flexibility.

The survey of federal collective bargaining agreements shows that in most

companies the items used to measure labor flexibility did not change between 1990 and

1996. However, in those cases where they did change, the trend toward greater flexibility

prevailed. The prevalence of provisions that had remained without changes is probably due

to the fact that the sample did not discriminate between large companies and companies of

other sizes, and that contract flexibility concentrates in large businesses.

Table V-19: CHANGE TOWARD COLLECTIVE BARGAINING AGREEMENTS IN

THE 1990s (percentage of federal companies) n=1000 (1996)

Dimension Low Moderate High Undefined in

agreement

I-B 2.7 1.7 4.7 90.9

II-B

4.0

__

10.3

85.7

III-B Union

participates in

changes in labor

intensity

20.5

--

19.5

59.9

I-A

8.8

54.5

15.1

21.6

II-B

15.6

7.9 10.2 66.3

III-B

0.1

39.2

9.3

51.3

IV-A

5.0

15.1

1.1

78.8

IV-B

0.2

16.3 23.5 60.0

V-B 0.2 8.7 18.9 72.2

VI-B 0.5 5.5 8.8 85.2

VII-B 11.1 7.3 1.8 79.8

VIII-B 3.3 30.8 11.8 54.1

IX-B 1.8 19.2 26.7 52.2

X-B 17.1 11.4 28.2 48.2

I- C 78.6 6.1 12.2 3.1

II-C 16.8 -- 19.9 63.4

III-C Productivity or

quality bonuses

16.5

--

17.9

65.5

Source: CCT-JF-96.

1) Functional flexibility is high in federal collective bargaining agreements (which does not

mean this flexibility is applied in practice, but that in most cases agreement provisions are

not an obstacle for functional flexibility). This also confirms an old thesis we have been

working with since the last decade: that the collective bargaining model emerging from the

Mexican Revolutionary is about circulation, i.e. it includes job tenure and wage protections

(the purchase of labor force) but with low formal participation of the unions in the work

process. As far as functional flexibility (in the work process) is concerned, what prevails is a

lack of definition in the collective bargaining agreement, and, secondly, companies’ explicit

unilaterality in decision-making. Manifest stipulated rigidity is infrequent and there is very

little formal limitation on internal mobility, both mobility between shifts and geographic

mobility. Limitations are moderated to the worker’s multi-skilled nature. Seniority in

general is not the sole criterion for promotion, and working overtime or on mandatory rest

days does not depend solely on the worker’s will.

2) In contrast, regulation of numerical flexibility in bargaining agreements is significantly

higher than functional flexibility. It is high in reference to temporary work, and moderate

but not predominant in reference to the use of outsourcing, the use of white-collar workers,

and personnel cutbacks.

3) With regard to wage flexibility, there is accentuated rigidity since fixed biweekly or

monthly wages per category prevail and wages are highly regulated. Little importance is

given to punctuality, attendance, productivity and quality bonuses.

The conclusion is very clear. Functional flexibility is generally high in federal collective

bargaining agreements in Mexico, whereas numerical flexibility, and particularly wage

flexibility are more rigid. This does not mean that functional flexibility combines

extensively with new forms of work organization.

Table V-20: FEDERAL CONTRACTS: GENERAL INDEX OF WORK

FLEXIBILITY BY SECTOR (1996)

BRANCH INDEX

TEXTILE 0.80

ELECTRICITY 1.47

FILM 0.76

RUBBER 0.69

SUGAR 0.26

MINING 1.22

METALURGIC &

SIDERURGIC

1.23

PETROCHEMICALS 1.43

CEMENT 1.14

LIMESTONE 1.02

AUTOMOTIVE AND

AUTOPARTS

1.03

CHEMICAL &

PHARMACEUTICAL

0.76

CELLULOSE & PAPER 0.94

VEGETABLE OILS &

FATS

0.84

FOOD PRODUCTION 1.05

BEVERAGE

PRODUCTION

0.90

BASIC WOODABLES 0.78

GLASS 1.35

TOBACCO 0.59

DIRECTLY

ADMINISTRATED OR

DECENTRALIZED

1.23

FEDERAL CONTRACT

OR CONCESSION

0.73

UNDERTAKES WORK

IN FEDERAL ZONES

0.82

Source: CCT-JF-96. Index ranges from 0 to 3.

Table V-21: FEDERAL BARGAINING AGREEMENTS: GENERAL INDEX OF

WORK FLEXIBILITY BY STATE (1996)

STATE INDEX

AUGUASCALIENTES 0.75

BAJA CALIFORNIA 1.06

BAJA CALIFORNIA

SUR

1.25

COAHUILA 1.17

COLIMA 0.82

CHIAPAS 0.93

CHIHUAHUA 0.96

FEDERAL DISTRICT

(MÉXICO CITY)

0.91

DURANGO 0.83

GUANAJUATO 1.09

GUERRERO 0.94

HIDALGO 0.94

JALISCO 0.75

STATE OF MEXICO 0.76

MICHOACÁN 0.78

MORELOS 0.81

NAYARIT 0.75

NUEVO LEON 0.93

OAXACA 0.87

PUEBLA 0.99

QUERETARO 1.04

QUINTANA ROO 0.77

SAN LUIS POTOSÍ 1.15

SINALOA 1.09

SONORA 0.94

TABASCO 0.82

TAMAULIPAS 0.95

TLAXCALA 0.86

VERACRUZ 0.78

YUCATAN 0.98

ZACATECAS 1.03

UNIDENTIFIED 1.27

Source: CCT-JF-96. Index ranges from 0 to 3.

The following can be inferred from the sample of federal bargaining agreements:

1) They tended to exclude the unions from decision-making related to changes in

technology and work methods more than from the negotiation of work intensity.

2) More flexibility is observed in the hiring of temporary workers and white-collar

workers and in defining who are rank and file workers. There was less flexibility in the

use of outsourcing.

3) Mobility from posts or categories, shifts, or geographical location; overtime; job

promotion criteria, and working on mandatory rest days tended toward flexibilization.

Multi-skilled work was less flexible.

4) Wages continued to be extremely rigid.

5) The general index of flexibility was lower in the basic wood, chemical and

pharmaceutical, sugar, and rubber industries, and higher in the following branches:

electricity, mining, metallurgy and iron and steel, petrochemicals, and glass.

6) Analysis by state showed that the general index of flexibility was lower in

Aguascalientes, Nayarit, Michoacan, Quintana Roo and Veracruz, and higher in San Luis

Potosi, Baja California Sur, Baja California, Coahuila and Guanajuato.

An analysis of numerical, functional and wage flexibility levels per branch revealed the

following results:

1) The changes in numerical flexibility per branch tended toward greater flexibility in all

branches except filming. The highest levels were observed in the rubber, metallurgy and

iron and steel, automotive and auto parts, vegetable oils and fats, basic wood, and tobacco

industries.

2) In contrast, wage flexibility tended to remain rigid in all branches.

3) Data of CCT, JF, and the Department of Labor show that the higher the number of

establishments, the higher the indexes of flexibility.

B. Flexibility in Local Collective Bargaining Agreements

Labor relations in companies that do not belong to federal jurisdiction are administrated

by the state governments.

To summarize, relations and conflicts between capital and work most often go

through the legal channels of local jurisdiction through agreements reached outside court

and individual conflicts. As far as striking is concerned, when calling a strike or going on

strike, the local sphere is much more important than the federal sphere in quantitative

terms, particularly in the case of workers and unions in small companies.

Table V-22: UNION INTERVENTION IN TECHNOLOGICAL CHANGE, WORK

METHODS, AND INTENSITY. (Local jurisdiction) (Percentage of

total collective agreements) (1998)

I II III

Yes 27.65 14.90 17.77

No 12.46 9.89 13.04

Unspecified 59.89 75.21 69.20

Source: CCT-JL-98.

I: Union intervenes in technological change.

II: Union intervenes in the establishment of new work methods.

III: Union intervenes in changes in labor intensity.

Table V-23: INDICATORS OF WORK FLEXIBILITY (Local jurisdiction agreements)

(Percentage of total agreements) (1998)

Flexibility as appears

in the bargaining

agreement

I

1.86

II

1.15

III

2.44

IV

1.86

V

3.58

VI

2.15

VII

1.58

VIII

0.57

Company - union

agreement

57.16 13.32 7.59 45.42 17.05 16.05 13.61 5.44

Prohibited to the

company

0.86 1.15 0.57 - 0.72 0.86 1.15 1.00

Unrestricted for the

company

21.06 21.35 49.71 7.88 21.78 25.07 2.58 13.75

Unspecified 19.05 63.04 63.04 44.84 56.88 55.87 81.09 79.23

Source: CCT-JL-98.

I: Contracting temporary workers

II: Use of outsourcing

III: Hiring white-collar workers

IV: Personnel cutbacks

V: Post or category mobility

VI: Shift mobility

VII: Geographic mobility

VIII: Multi-skilled work

Table No V-24: MAIN JOB PROMOTION CRITERIA IN LOCAL COLLECTIVE

AGREEMENTS (Percentage of total agreements) (1998)

Seniority, schooling level and other 30.95

Skills or qualifications 16.47

Unspecified 52.58

Source: CCT-JL-98.

Table V-25: MANDATORY WORK ON REST DAYS AND OVERTIME IN LOCAL

BARGAINING AGREEMENTS (Percentage of total agreements) (1998)

Work on rest days Overtime

Voluntary 2.44 2.01

Mandatory 14.76 15.62

Company-union agreement 39.83 45.7

Unspecified 42.98 36.68

Source: CCT-JL-98.

Table V-26: BONUSES FORESEEN IN LOCAL BARGAINING AGREEMENTS

(Percentage of total agreements) (1998)

Punctuality and

attendance

Productivity or quality Other

Yes 17.34 15.33 20.92

No 12.32 10.60 55.16

Unspecified 70.34 74.07 23.92

Source: CCT-JL-98.

Based on our sample of local collective bargaining agreements conducted in 1998

summarized in the tables above, we can infer the same conclusion as that for the federal

collective bargaining agreements: that most local collective agreements were already

flexible long before the flexibility doctrines took root in Mexico. As explained in Chapter

I, a portion of Mexican companies have a traditional form of organization, which implies

important levels of arbitrariness in task performance, what we have called pre-Taylorist

flexibility. This non-scientific flexibility remains present and impacts the flexibility

indexes. Functional flexibility is higher than numerical or wage flexibility, and unions

hardly participate in changes in technology, organization and methods of work. The

unions, however, have also had to flexibilize, although most of them remain as flexible as

they used to be, particularly with regard to unspecified topics in the agreements, possibly

associated with non-systematic forms of organization and labor relations in which the

informal components are of greatest importance.

Table V-27: INDEXES OF FLEXIBILITY IN LOCAL COLLECTIVE AGREEMENTS

(1998)

Functional Wage Numerical General

Aguascalientes 0.34 -0.20 0.60 0.30

Jalisco -0.20 -0.29 0.25 -0.10

State of Mexico -0.07 -0.28 0.21 -0.05

Morelos 0.13 -0.09 0.34 0.11

Queretaro 0.38 -0.09 0.46 0.28

Sonora 0.01 -0.04 0.22 0.06

Veracruz 0.11 -0.22 0.25 0.07

Yucatán 0.26 -0.53 0.26 0.07

TOTAL STATES 0.07 -0.27 0.27 0.04

Source: CCT-JL-98. The Index ranges from –1 to +1.

C. Labor Legislation

Mexican labor laws have not yet been modified. A debate on the need for greater labor

law flexibility began in 1988, and still continues into the present. This debate intensified

following the implementation of NAFTA. The first modification proposals came from

employer organizations CONCANACO (employers in trade) and COPARMEX

(employers’ union). The debate focused on work flexibility. This focus was justified by

the new context of globalized markets and production, the modernization of the

productive process, the need to increase the investors’ level of trust, and, above all, the

need to increase productivity and quality (De Buen, 1989).

These initial proposals included the three classic aspects of work flexibility, as

well as boundaries for the conflict between workers and employers. In relation to

numerical flexibility, a revision of the notion of a compensation for job termination,

retirement simplification and the notion of back wages, was proposed together with a

reformulation of the agreement rescission process. Functional flexibility proposed

flexibilizing the workday, establishing multi-skilled work, and productivity commissions.

Wage flexibility proposed reformulating the notion of remunerative wages; and

estimating wages in relation to each company’s productivity and economic conditions; as

well as reformulating the notion of economic benefits and having them depend on the

company’s capacities, and establishing wages per hour.

With regard to worker-employer conflicts, the proposals included banning

solidarity strikes, establishing union responsibility when strikes are declared non-existent,

and greater restrictions to striking in public services.

In 1989, the PRI labor caucus persuaded the National Congress to undertake a

popular consultation on possible modifications to the Federal Labor Law. The

Department of Labor formed a tripartite commission to develop a bill, but no public

results were ever emitted. Since then employers have periodically called for a new labor

law and unions have been divided between those opposed to any amendment

(independent unionism, CTM, Mexican Electrical Workers Union), and those accepting

the modifications that do not affect the rights they have gained, especially those calling

for a new chapter in modernization and productivity (Mexican Telephone Workers

Union—STRM, Authentic Labor Front—FAT).

In 1994, employer organizations COPARMEX, CONCANACO and

CANACINTRA (industrialists) presented president-elect Ernesto Zedillo (PRI) with a

document that included a systematic proposal by the employers with a section on labor.

This document justifies changes in labor legislation as a means to achieve higher

competitiveness. According to the employers, the main points to be modified would be:

1) Functional and geographic mobility with multi-skilled work;

2) Temporary agreements, by hour or reduced workday;

3) Rationalizing causes for agreement rescission;

4) Limitations on labor lawsuit responsibilities in the payment of back wages;

5) Hourly wages;

6) Democratization of strikes: to certify the will of the majority of workers through

secret ballot before going on strike and in taking the decision to conclude the strike;

7) Elimination of conciliation and arbitration boards;

8) Elimination of legal contracts;

9) Establishment of training agreements that do not imply a labor relation;

10) Elimination of the blind wage scale and replacement with skill-based scale;

11) Establishment of labor and union benefits according to the conditions in each

company (which implies questioning how the social security system operates);

12) Elimination of the exclusionary clause for entry and termination;

13) Freedom to join a union, and

14) Apolitical unionism; eliminating relationships with political parties.

Employer organizations have not presented a common front to the labor law reform bills.

The Employer Coordination Council (Consejo Coordinador Empresarial—CCE),

Mexico’s largest employer organization, has most decidedly supported the government’s

economic policy and while the State did not insist on labor reform, the CCE did not

consider it indispensable either. CONCAMIN adopted a similar position. In other words,

CONCANACO and COPARMEX have been the most insistent. Carlos Salinas de Gortari

promised a new labor law since the beginning of his presidential campaign (in 1988), but

his presidential period came to an end without such a reform. Upon completing his term

he identified two major pending reforms: labor and social security. The CTM was

initially not entirely opposed to reform (1989), but following presentation of the

COPARMEX-CONCANACO proposal, which was partially anti-corporatist, CTM

changed its position radically and since then has been reluctant to amendments. Between

May 1990 and May 1992 the State ceased to insist on reform, while employers continued

to claim it was necessary to make amendments and the CTM continued to oppose. A

truce of sorts between CTM and employers was established between May 1992 and

November 1993 in order to avoid hindering NAFTA negotiations. Since then, employers

have insisted on reform, CTM has opposed it, and the State has declared it is necessary

(De la Garza and Bouzas, 1998).

The controversy around the Federal Labor Law reform in 1995 was reinforced by

the proposals for labor market flexibilization contained in Zedillo’s National

Development Plan. Until 1996, the Department of Labor’s drive to reform the labor law

moved forward gradually, calling on CTM and COPARMEX to come to an agreement.

Negotiation was resumed with the mutual recognition of the need for a new labor culture.

It is in this context that the National Action Party (Partido Acción Nacional—

PAN) presented its labor reform bill. The PAN bill, formulated by Nestor de Buen, a

prestigious lawyer, contains two main new components: different aspects of work

flexibility, thus essentially coinciding with the COPARMEX and CONCANACO bills;

and the democratization of labor organizations, distanced from both the government’s

bills, and those of the labor and employer elites.

With regard to labor flexibility, the PAN bill changes basic principles of the labor

law prevailing in Mexico by denouncing the State’s protective role toward the weakest

part in the labor relation and replacing it with the role of guarding the balance between

the production factors. The other important change in the principles is the replacement of

the notion of social justice by the promotion of employment and productivity. Along this

line, labor flexibility appears in the bill in its three classic forms: numerical flexibility is a

company’s capacity to hire or fire personnel according to production needs; the notion of

an apprenticeship contract with a trial period; flexibilization of the termination of a labor

relation including a seniority premium, regardless of the cause of termination, which

replaces the 20 days per year plus three months’ wages and the previous premium

corresponding to 12 days’ wages per year of seniority; flexibilizes discontinuous work,

and regulates the use of outsourcing. On internal flexibility, the bill specifies that work

conditions may be subject to upward or downward changes. A company’s power to

change workers from their post, geographical location and shifts is extended, and the

distribution of time throughout the work week is also flexibilized (40 hours per week are

proposed) at the employer’s discretion according to production needs. Workers may be

made to work overtime and on mandatory rest days if production so requires. This

obligation, however, is not applicable to the weekly days of rest. In promotions, the bill

privileges capacity over seniority. With regard to wage flexibility (wages according to

productivity or quality), the bill does not propose one unique form of wages, such as

hourly wages, but rather opens clearer possibilities to multiple forms of payment than the

current laws. In summary, the PAN bill mainly proposes employer unilaterality. Except

for the two cases that are mentioned below, it is imposed flexibility without any previous

agreement with the workers. These two cases are: when employment is affected by

changes in technology or work organization. There are many changes in technology or

organization that do not imply personnel reduction, and they are left to the employer’s

discretion. The other aspect subject to bilaterality is productivity and training programs.

These programs follow the current productivity agreement model promoted by the

Department of Labor, noting that it is necessary to specify the program’s goals and

actions, productivity indicators, type of information workers are to be provided with, the

amount of the bonuses, and training.

The other great novelty in the PAN bill refers to labor organization

representativity and democratization. This theme in turn has two central aspects. The

elimination of the obligation to notify the Department of Labor of the creation of any

labor organization; where the workers are free to unionize or not, eliminating

exclusionary clauses, allowing collective and individual agreements to coexist, and

opening channels for white-collar workers to unionize; and, finally, eliminating

mandatory ratification of labor agreements before the Conciliation Boards, which are

replaced by Social Tribunals that depend on the judiciary branch.

The other important aspect of the democratization of labor organizations is the

creation of company committees, a different category from unions, which the bill in fact

places as the signatories and supervisors of labor agreements and as those in charge of

calling a strike. Unions are thereby reduced to a sort of open membership trend that may

participate with candidate teams in elections for the company committee, but do not

represent workers as such in collective bargaining. There is one exception in that the bill

foresees that bargaining should be articulated as an umbrella, from branch to company.

At the branch level, the majority union would represent the workers.

The bill draws on European experiences in the creation of company committees,

which represent all workers whether they are union members or not. These committees

are an expression of representative democracy through delegates with strong participation

of the rank and file in assemblies and strict supervision of the electoral processes. The

decision to call a strike is democratized by mandating worker assemblies as decision-

making bodies, while conciliation is considered voluntary. The company committee is

responsible for calling a strike and may desist at any moment. After a month’s strike, any

of the parties may request the strike be qualified. Time constraints are established for

strikes in branches that deliver services to the community. The bill retains the principles

prohibiting workers from being replaced during a strike or that a minority continue

working.

The Democratic Revolution Party (Partido de la Revolución Democrática—

PRD) recently developed a labor law bill. This bill recognizes the need to moderately

flexibilize labor relations and insists on eliminating government controls over union

registration, collective bargaining agreements and strikes. In 1998, the Department of

Labor called the official unions and the new workers’ confederation coming out of the

official lines, the National Workers Union (Unión Nacional de Trabajadores—UNT) to

negotiate possible labor law reforms with employer organizations. Very little progress

had been made, however. Only a preliminary bill of the Federal Code of Labor

Procedures, which has not yet been presented for approval to the National Congress.

Current positions are divided as follows: the Labor Congress (CT) and the UNT accept

the amendment as long as it does not infringe on acquired rights; employer

organizations and the government insist on flexibilization; PAN and PRD accept the

amendment, but only through their own bills; the May 1st Inter-union Organization

(Intersindical Primero de Mayo), which brought independent unionism together,

opposed the amendments. The recently created Mexican Labor Union Front (Frente

Sindical Mexicano), headed by the Mexican Electrical Workers Union (SME), also

opposes the amendments.

In the last days of November 2002, the PRI caucus presented the Working

Commission of the Chamber of Deputies with a new Labor Law bill that both employer

organizations and the Labor Congress had agreed upon. A few weeks earlier, the PRD

and the National Workers Union (UNT) had done the same. This was the peak point of a

long process begun in 1988, when both CONCANACO and COPARMEX started a

debate on the labor reform. Since then both organizations have defined the core aspects

the employers demand the reform should include: work flexibility in order to increase

company competitiveness, to favor modernization and to encourage investors' trust in

economic liberalization and globalization.

The last phase of the debate on the labor reform started with the creation of the Central

Decision-Making Group in mid-2001. Three different stages have unfolded since the bill

was presented: In the first stage, from July 2001 to February 2002, the Department of

Labor made attempts to get the employers, unionists of the Labor Congress and the UNT

to agree to a bill by consensus. The bracket method was followed during this period, i.e.,

only clauses that are agreed to by consensus are included, otherwise, the clauses where

there is disagreement are placed in brackets for the final decision to be taken by the

Mexican Congress in due time. Progress was minimal in this stage because of differences

between the UNT, on the one hand, and the Department of Labor, employer organizations

and the Labor Congress, on the other.

In the second stage, from February to July 2002, the UNT without abandoning the

Central Decision-Making Group developed and finally made its own bill public. The

PRD did the same and this forced the Department of Labor to speed up the process and

come up with a first draft in July 2002. In the third stage, from July to November 2002,

the two positions at the Central Decision-Making Group separated their paths, attacking

each other until in early November the UNT reached an agreement with the PRD and

they both presented their bill to the commission in charge at the Chamber of Deputies.

Some weeks later, the opposition headed by the Department of Labor also presented a bill

through the PRI’s workers caucus.

The labor law bill promoted by the Department of Labor started with a “Conceptual

Framework for the Modernization and Updating of the Labor Law” that set forth a radical

change in the principles of labor law prevailing in Mexico. It includes core elements of

the social doctrine of the Catholic Church, such as the notion that both workers and

employers enjoy the same human essence, the idea that law is based on the respect for the

human person and that a company must be conceived as a community of interests. The

principles of the Church’s social doctrine intertwined with elements of the managerial

doctrine of total quality through the concept of a new labor culture. This bill has two

main themes: work flexibility and restrictions to freedom of association, hiring and strike.

As far as work flexibility is concerned, it covers three dimensions although unequally.

Numerical flexibility —adjusting the number of workers to the product’s market

conditions— establishes contracts for undefined time with a trial period of 30 days

without the employer being responsible for paying a lay-off compensation, and training

contracts for up to three months. Functional flexibility or flexibility within the productive

process sets forth the possibility of discontinuous workdays, extension of tasks that is

agreed to, and changing the rest days contained in the agreements, as well as the

flexibilization of the workday may be adjusted on a daily basis according to production

needs without exceeding the total weekly or monthly hours. Performance and training are

also established as the main criteria for promotion. Wage flexibility is poorer than

numerical and functional flexibility and there is no explicit commitment to sharing

productivity profits through bonuses. At the most it proposes extending the training

commissions to productivity, but in this field the commissions only propose the

management make changes in machinery, work organization and labor relations, without

mentioning the distribution of profits.

On the contrary, this bill includes a detailed list of requirements to sign a collective

bargaining agreement: All labor union members must sign, the union registration office

must recognize the union’s leadership, their by-laws specifying that the company they

intend to sign an agreement with is within their field of action, as well as a list of union

members. Something similar happens with the procedure to call a strike for the signature

of the collective bargaining agreement: certified proof of the union’s registration, that its

by-laws specify that the company is within their field of action, a signed list of all the

workers in the union, certification by the authorities that the workers are part of the

union; when there is a collective agreement certification process, no similar lawsuit will

be accepted until a resolution is reached, and the secret ballot certified by the Department

of Labor has been established for calling a strike.

In other words, the Department of Labor bill summarizes most of the employers’

historical demands regarding a flexible reform. No mention was made of payment per

hour, benefits according to the company’s financial capacity or the elimination of

dropped wages. However, as a possible exchange between the interest of both employers

and the Department of Labor in flexibilizing, and the unions of the Labor Congress in

preserving their quasi-monopoly of labor representation, leaving aside the elimination of

exclusionary clauses, the prohibition of affiliating unions to political parties, sanctions to

union leaders who do not provide the workers with a copy of the union’s by-laws and the

collective bargaining agreement, the secret and direct ballot for the election of leadership,

and a new institute to register bargaining agreements and unions with open information

for those with a judiciary interest. Although these three last issues appeared in one of the

last drafts of the bill, they were eliminated upon delivering it at the Chamber of Deputies.

In other words, the Abascal bill, as it is known, provides the companies with labor

flexibility, imposes additional requirements to the registration of collective agreements,

to the signature of these agreements and to striking, and does not modify the current

situation for union registration. In terms of freedom of association, hiring and striking, it

is the employers, the CT union leaders and the government itself who end winning when

they agree to the continuity of corporatist labor relations that have ensured labor peace

for so long.

The bill presented by the UNT and the PRD comes from a functionalist and

institutionalist conception of industrial relations and sets forth the need for a social pact

between workers, employers and the State, implicit in the negotiation experience between

the telephone workers’ union and Telmex, the telephone company. This bill focuses on

the procedural aspects related with freedom of association, collective bargaining and

striking. It preserves the exclusionary clause for entry to work, but not for separation,

establishes the secret and direct ballot for the election of union leaders, and the national

registration of unions and collective contracts, the possibility of signing collective

contracts per branch and chains of production. It creates a new institution (National

Institute of Wages, Employment and Productivity). The Chamber of Deputies fixes the

minimum wages, as well as the distribution of profits, it proposes a 40 hour workweek

and a one and only minimum wage. As far as productivity is concerned, like in Abascal’s

bill, development is also limited. It adopts the concept of broadened productivity

contained in the telephone workers’ collective contract, which assumes the creation of

mixed productivity and training commissions in charge of diagnosing, developing

programs, evaluating programs, and proposing the distribution of the profits due to an

increase in productivity.

To conclude, the Abascal bill, apart from its substantial and procedural implications

on labor rights, can be interpreted as a step toward restoring corporatist relations between

employers, the State and the CT unions, but with a relative marginalization of political

parties. The bill synthesizes a large-scale exchange between the two main actors in labor

relations, labor flexibility and the workers’ quasi-monopolistic representation. This

refoundational agreement will require a definition of the new everyday practical rules of

labor relations at a federal level. The PAN governors, however, for some time now have

been in a modus vivendi with PRI unions. It is the workers and the unions that lose in this

situation; particularly the leadership of the telephone workers’ union which believed that

through their proposal for the creation of a new social pact in production, which had

turned out successful in Telmex, they would head the reforms, but this process proved

that it is not enough to have new ideas unless one has the necessary power to promote

their growth.

ANNEX

Methodology to estimate indexes of flexibility based on different sources of information.

A-1: DIMENSIONS OF WORK FLEXIBILITY FOR CCT-JF-96 AND

CCT-JL-98

I : Dimensions of Work Flexibility

Union or workers intervention in changes in technology and/or work organization (to be informed=A;

to participate in the decision to make a change=B; to participate in implementing changes=C; to

participate in the evaluation of the changes=D)

II: Employment Flexibility

Union or workers intervention in the selection of new personnel.

Note: Participation may include the union proposing new personnel, a mixed selection commission

that prepares, supervises and evaluates the tests for the new workers. Exclusionary clauses assume

union intervention in this area.

Readjustment negotiated by personnel between the company and the union or workers and/or job-

termination compensation over and above what is stipulated in the Federal Labor Law.

Note: Any condition for layoff or readjustment of personnel over and above what is stipulated in the

Federal Labor Law should be considered in this item.

Limitations to the employment of temporary workers (hired for a specific task or period of time).

Note: Limitations may range from establishing percentages for occasional and temporary worker to

the simple consideration that the union must be in agreement.

Limitations on the use of outsourcing.

Note: Similar to the previous point.

Limitations to the creation of new jobs for white-collar workers or to increasing their numbers.

Note: Simply listing the white-collar posts is already a limitation.

III: Work Process Flexibility

Existence of a catalog of basic posts.

III-B: Workers’ express unwillingness to multi-skilled work.

Note: A restriction to multi-skilled work may appear as a precise definition of a job’s functions,

explicit prohibition to workers being assigned tasks that are different from those for which they

were hired, or a simple negotiation between the company and the union when it is the workers’

functions that need to be changed.

Restrictions to internal mobility from categories, job posts, departments, shifts, or job locations.

Regulations over and above what the Federal Labor Law stipulates for overtime.

: It includes more mandatory rest days than what the Federal Labor Law stipulates.

Participation of the union or workers whenever workers are sanctioned.

Participation of the union or workers in defining work methods, production or productivity norms,

or quality parameters.

Note: Participation may range from the existence of productivity or method commissions to

having to include the union in agreeing on the changes.

Participation of the union or workers in health, safety or training commissions.

IV: Wage Flexibility. Bonuses or incentives for:

IV.1. punctuality and attendance,

IV.2. productivity and attendance, or

IV.3. other aspects.

1. ENESTYC

Numerical flexibility: percentage of part time, hourly, outsourced and temporary

workers; percentage of white-collar workers (a simple aggregated index was formed with

the percentages) (Fn)

Functional flexibility: internal turnover (Ff)

Wage flexibility: percentage of bonuses in total remunerations (Fs)

A general index of flexibility was formed using factorial analysis of the form

IF = a Fn +bFf +cFs

2. Industrialization Models

The same indicators corresponding to the dimensions of Schematic A-I.

Numerical flexibility: employment of temporary workers, outsourcers, white-collar

employees, limitations to personnel cutbacks; Functional flexibility: multi-skilled work,

internal mobility, elimination of the blind scale, workday elasticity; Wages flexibility:

wages according to productivity, punctuality and attendance, training.

3. Federal and local collective bargaining agreements (CCT-JF-96, CCT-JL-98)

The dimensions used to measure flexibility are the same as those used in the Model

survey (MIM-94).

Two calculations are possible with this data: the percentage of bargaining agreements that

changed toward flexibility, and an index of change toward flexibility (IF) with the

following formula:

Assessment of each item in each contract

IF= Number of items for each type of flexibility Number of bargaining agreements with changes in flexibility

Finally, the analysis of work flexibility is defined according to the different dimensions

for which indexes of flexibility are constructed.

A-2: ESTIMATED INDEXES OF FLEXIBILITY BASED ON COLLECTIVE BARGAINING

AGREEMENT REVISIONS

A) FUNCTIONAL FLEXIBILITY

QUESTION LOW (-1) MODERATE (0) HIGH (+1) UNDETERMINED

I.B

I. UNION INTERVENTION IN

TECHNOLOGICAL AND

ORGANIZATIONAL CHANGE

Bilateral

determination

(2)

Obligatory

consultation

(1)

Unilateral

determination

(3)

Unspecified

(4)

II.B

II. UNION INTERVENTION

ESTABLISHING WORK METHODS

YES

(1)

Not considered

NO

(2)

Unspecified

(4)

III.B

III. UNION PARTICIPATION IN

CHANGES IN LABOR INTENSITY

YES

(1)

Not considered

NO

(2)

Unspecified

(4)

IV.B

VII. MOBILITY BETWEEN POSTS

OR CATEGORIES

Prohibited

(3)

Limited by Collective

Bargaining

Agreement

(1 and 2)

Unrestricted

(4)

Unspecified

(5)

V.B

IX. MOBILITY BETWEEN SHIFTS

Prohibited

(3)

Limited by Collective

Bargaining

Agreement (1 and 2)

Unrestricted

4)

Unspecified

(5)

VI.B

X. GEOGRAPHIC MOBILITY

Prohibited

(3)

Limited by Collective

Bargaining

Agreement

(1 and 2)

Unrestricted

(4)

Unspecified

(5)

VII.B

XI. MULTI-SKILLED WORK

Prohibited

(3)

Limited by Collective

Bargaining

Agreement (1 and 2)

Unrestricted

(4)

Unspecified

(5)

VIII.B

XII. PRIMARY PROMOTION

CRITERION

Seniority

(1)

Schooling, seniority

and other

(4 and 5)

Skills, training

( 2 and 3)

Unspecified

(6)

IX.B

XIII. OVERTIME

Voluntary

(1)

Agreement

(3)

Mandatory

(2)

Unspecified

(4)

X.B

XIV. WORK ON REST DAYS

Voluntary

(1)

Agreement

(3)

Mandatory

(2)

Unspecified

(4)

B) EXTERNAL NUMERICAL FLEXIBILITY

QUESTION LOW (-1) MODERATE (0) HIGH (+1) UNDETERMINED

I.A

IV. HIRING TEMPORARY WORKERS

Prohibited

(3)

Limited by Collective

Bargaining

Agreement (1 and 2)

Company is free

(4)

Unspecified

(5)

II.A

V. USE OF OUTSOURCING

Prohibited

(3)

Limited by Collective

Bargaining

Agreement (1 and 2)

Company is free

(4)

Unspecified

(5)

III.A

VI. HIRING WHITE-COLLAR

EMPLOYEES

Prohibited

(3)

Limited by Collective

Bargaining

Agreement

(1 and 2)

Company is free

(4)

Unspecified

(5)

IV.A

VII. WORKER CUTBACKS

Prohibited

(3)

Limited by Collective

Bargaining

Agreement (1 and 2)

Company is free

(4)

Unspecified

(5)

C) WAGE FLEXIBILITY

QUESTION LOW (-1) MIDDLE (0) HIGH (+1) UNDETERMINED

I.C

XVA. FORM OF PAYMENT

Per day or per

Base wage plus

week (2) commission

(4)

Per hour or per intensity

(1 and 3)

Unspecified

(5)

II.C

XVI. PUNCTUALITY OR ATTENDANCE

BONUSES

No

(2)

Yes

(1)

Unspecified

(3)

III.C

XVII. PRODUCTIVITY OR QUALITY

BONUSES

No

(2)

Yes

(1)

Unspecified

(3)

Note: The numbers in brackets correspond to the options in the questions of the questionnaire applied to

analyze each collective bargaining agreement. These numbers per question were normalized between -1

and 1. Situations were also found in which the item was not specified in the Agreement.

An index for each type of flexibility (numerical, functional and wage) will be estimated

with the aforementioned formula. A general index of aggregated flexibility will be

constructed:

IF= aFn + bFf + cFs

Coefficients a, b and c were assumed to be the same as those obtained through factorial

analysis of the survey of bargaining agreements made by the Labor Department.

For the analysis of numerical, functional and wage flexibility, a random sample was taken

per branch (as classified by the Federal Conciliation and Arbitration Board) of

approximately 10% of the universe of collective bargaining agreements (n=1000 contracts).

The same dimensions and indicators used for the MIM survey were applied. The numerical,

wage and functional indexes were calculated as explained in chapter I, with variations

between –1 and +1. As explained in chapter I, factorial analysis was conducted of the survey

of collective bargaining agreements to determine the coefficients of numerical, functional

and wage flexibility and thereby estimate a general index of flexibility.

ESTIMATING WEIGHT FACTORS FOR THE INDEX OF WORK FLEXIBILITY APPLIED TO THE

SURVEY OF INDUSTRIALIZATION MODELS AND TO THE SAMPLES OF COLLECTIVE

BARGAINING AGREEMENTS

Three factorials were made based on Department of Labor Collective Bargaining Agreements, one for

each dimension of flexibility (numerical, functional and wages).

As can be seen in the following table, the specific weight factors were taken from the final matrix for

each item of each dimension.

With this very same base, each item was multiplied by its specific weight factor, and the items of each

dimension were added (the indexes of numerical, functional and wage flexibility in that base).

The aggregation of the three indexes of flexibility constitutes the index of work flexibility.

Simple aggregate indexes were estimated for each dimension (without weighting).

Absolute weight factors were obtained per dimension by dividing the total aggregation of weighted

indexes per dimension between the total aggregations of the corresponding indexes without weighting.

These absolute weight factors were standardized (adding up to 100) and relative weight factors were

obtained to estimate the indexes of flexibility in models and both federal and local collective

agreements.

NUMERICAL

FLEXIBILITY

FUNCTIONAL

FLEXIBILITY

WAGE

FLEXIBILITY

TOTAL AGGREGATION OF INDEXES WITH FACTORIAL

POWER

0.14 -0.01 -0.01

TOTAL AGGREGATION OF SIMPLE INDEXES -0.24 0.08 0.4

ABSOLUTE WEIGHT FACTORS -0.583 -0.125 -0.025

RELATIVE (final) WEIGHT FACTORS 0.795 0.170 0.034

Note: Carlos Salas made the calculation of factorial indexes

A-3: INDEX OF WORK FLEXIBILITY, DEPARTMENT OF LABOR

COLLECTIVE BARGAINING AGREEMENTS (1999)

WEIGHTING FACTORS PER VARIABLE OF EACH DIMENSION OF FLEXIBILITY

NUMERICAL

FLEXIBILITY

FUNCTIONAL

FLEXIBILITY

WAGE

FLEXIBILITY

P11 .813

P12 .788

P13 .930

P14 .557

P22 .861

P23 .889

P24I .929

P25 .920

P26 0.666

P27 0.738

P28 0.670

P29 0.243

P30 0.324

P31 0.080

P32 0.470

P33 0.518

P34 0.512

P35 0.537

P36 0.600

P37 0.399

P38 0.555

P39 0.336

P40 0.403

P47 0.165

P51 0.254

P52 -0.074

P53 0.273

P54 -0.049

P57 0.129

P59 0.280

P60 0.110

P61 0.151

P63 0.197

P49 0.16382918

P102 0.02369231

P103 0.14376119

P105 0.11598784

P106 0.18862785

P107 0.56892359

P108 0.55359542

P109 0.27489621

P110 0.59118127

P111 0.46615302

P112 0.59721258

P113 0.75192175

P114 0.70133279

P64 0.004

The following equation resulted:

IF = 0.795Nf + 0.17 Ff + 0.034 Wf

where IF = general index of flexibility

Nf = Index of numerical flexibility

Ff = Index of functional flexibility

Wf = Index of wage flexibility

A-4: INDEXES OF WAGE FLEXIBILITY PER BRANCH (1996)

BRANCH INDEX STANDARD

DEVIATION

MINIMUM MAXIMUM NO.

CASES

TOTAL -0.49 0.64 -1.00 1.00 906

1 TEXTILE -0.49 0.72 -1.00 1.00 36

2 ELECTRICITY -0.91 0.27 -1.00 0.00 19

3 FILMING -0.93 0.29 -1.00 1.00 106

4 RUBBER -0.76 0.42 -1.00 0.00 11

5 SUGAR -0.33 0.00 -0.33 -0.33 1

6 MINING -0.79 0.43 -1.00 0.00 14

7 METALLURGY AND IRON AND STEEL -0.29 0.65 -1.00 1.00 35

8 HIDROCARBONS 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0

9 PETROCHEMICALS 0.11 0.19 0.00 0.33 3

10 CEMENT -0.42 0.60 -1.00 1.00 21

11 LIMESTONE -0.63 0.52 -1.00 0.00 8

12 AUTOMOTIVE AND AUTOPARTS -0.48 0.52 -1.00 0.33 40

13 CHEMICAL AND PHARMACEUTICAL -0.57 0.51 -1.00 0.33 104

14 CELLULOSE AND PAPER -0.33 0.51 -1.00 0.33 12

15 VEGETABLE OILS AND FATS -0.70 0.48 -1.00 0.00 10

16 FOOD PRODUCTION -0.31 0.71 -1.00 1.00 138

17 BEVERAGE PRODUCTION -0.51 0.63 -1.00 1.00 84

18 RAILROADS 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0

19 BASIC WOOD -0.64 0.50 -1.00 0.00 14

20 GLASS 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 3

21 TOBACCO -1.00 0.00 -1.00 -1.00 2

22 DIRECTLY ADMINISTRATED / DECENTRALIZED -0.10 0.63 -1.00 0.33 7

23 FEDERAL AGREEMENT OR CONCESSION -0.29 0.85 -1.00 1.00 152

24 COMPANIES WORKING IN FEDERAL ZONES -0.45 0.44 -1.00 0.67 86

Source: CCT-JF-96. Index ranges from –1 to +1.

A-5: INDEXES OF WAGE FLEXIBILITY BY STATE (1996)

STATE INDEX STANDARD

DEVIATION

MINIMUM MAXIMUM NO. CASES

TOTAL -0.49 0.64 -1.00 1.00 906

1 AUGUASCALIENTES -0.30 0.84 -1.00 1.00 10

2 BAJA CALIFORNIA -0.40 0.64 -1.00 1.00 24

3 BAJA CALIFORNIA SUR -0.28 0.75 -1.00 0.50 3

4 CAMPECHE 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0

5 COAHUILA -0.45 0.67 -1.00 1.00 22

6 COLIMA -0.47 0.51 -1.00 0.00 5

7 CHIAPAS -0.38 0.83 -1.00 1.00 7

8 CHIHUAHUA -0.43 0.58 -1.00 0.67 14

9 FEDERAL DISTRICT

(MÉXICO CITY)

-0.47 0.62 -1.00 1.00 230

10 DURANGO -0.46 0.66 -1.00 1.00 13

11 GUANAJUATO -0.51 0.68 -1.00 1.00 30

12 GUERRERO -0.50 0.72 -1.00 1.00 10

13 HIDALGO -0.64 0.69 -1.00 1.00 20

14 JALISCO -0.57 0.64 -1.00 1.00 86

15 MÉXICO -0.48 0.65 -1.00 1.00 134

16 MICHOACÁN -0.80 0.43 -1.00 0.33 15

17 MORELOS -0.26 0.92 -1.00 1.00 9

18 NAYARIT -0.71 0.60 -1.00 0.67 8

19 NUEVO LEON -0.27 0.78 -1.00 1.00 34

20 OAXACA -0.81 0.46 -1.00 0.33 12

21 PUEBLA -0.47 0.67 -1.00 1.00 31

22 QUERETARO -0.36 0.69 -1.00 1.00 11

23 QUINTANA ROO -0.61 0.44 -1.00 0.00 6

24 SAN LUIS POTOSI 0.10 0.53 -1.00 0.50 7

25 SINALOA -0.44 0.58 -1.00 1.00 21

26 SONORA -0.61 0.52 -1.00 0.50 23

27 TABASCO -0.67 0.58 -1.00 0.00 3

28 TAMAULIPAS -0.58 0.62 -1.00 1.00 24

29 TLAXCALA -0.37 0.79 -1.00 1.00 9

30 VERACRUZ -0.55 0.64 -1.00 1.00 64

31 YUCATÁN -0.60 0.59 -1.00 0.50 8

32 ZACATECAS -1.00 0.00 -1.00 -1.00 5

99 UNSPECIFIED -0.58 0.61 -1.00 0.33 8

Source: CCT-JF-96. Index ranges from –1 to +1

A-6: INDEXES OF NUMERICAL FLEXIBILITY BY STATE (1996)

STATE INDEX STANDARD

DEVIATION

MINIMUM MAXIMUM NO. CASES

TOTAL 0.37 0.40 -1.00 1.00 931

1 AUGUASCALIENTES 0.36 0.39 0.00 1.00 10

2 BAJA CALIFORNIA 0.43 0.38 0.00 1.00 25

3 BAJA CALIFORNIA SUR 0.19 0.17 0.00 0.33 3

4 CAMPECHE 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0

5 COAHUILA 0.30 0.40 -0.33 1.00 22

6 COLIMA 0.07 0.68 -1.00 0.67 5

7 CHIAPAS 0.21 0.44 -0.33 1.00 7

8 CHIHUAHUA 0.29 0.38 -0.33 1.00 14

9 FEDERAL DISTRICT (MÉXICO

CITY)

0.45 0.40 -0.67 1.00 240

10 DURANGO 0.45 0.44 0.00 1.00 13

11 GUANAJUATO 0.44 0.40 -0.33 1.00 30

12 GUERRERO 0.52 0.41 0.00 1.00 10

13 HIDALGO 0.31 0.36 0.00 1.00 20

14 JALISCO 0.40 0.39 -0.50 1.00 88

15 MÉXICO 0.47 0.40 -1.00 1.00 138

16 MICHOACÁN 0.35 0.33 0.00 1.00 15

17 MORELOS 0.69 0.32 0.33 1.00 9

18 NAYARIT 0.29 0.36 0.00 1.00 8

19 NUEVO LEON 0.22 0.39 -0.50 1.00 34

20 OAXACA 0.18 0.31 -0.33 0.67 12

21 PUEBLA 0.10 0.39 -1.00 1.00 37

22 QUERETARO 0.32 0.27 0.00 0.67 11

23 QUINTANA ROO 0.33 0.56 -0.33 1.00 6

24 SAN LUIS POTOSÍ 0.24 0.30 0.00 0.67 7

25 SINALOA 0.19 0.26 0.00 1.00 21

26 SONORA 0.29 0.47 -0.33 1.00 23

27 TABASCO 0.11 0.19 0.00 0.33 3

28 TAMAULIPAS 0.32 0.43 -0.33 1.00 25

29 TLAXCALA 0.29 0.28 0.00 0.75 10

30 VERACRUZ 0.31 0.36 -0.33 1.00 64

31 YUCATÁN 0.13 0.25 -0.33 0.33 8

32 ZACATECAS 0.28 0.39 0.00 0.75 5

99 UNSPECIFIED 0.02 0.69 -1.00 0.75 8

Source: CCT-JF-96. Index ranges from –1 to +1

A-7: INDEXES OF FUNCTIONAL FLEXIBILITY BY STATE (1996)

STATE INDEX STANDARD

DEVIATION

MINIMUM MAXIMUM NO. CASES

TOTAL 0.11 0.24 -0.40 0.90 841

1 AUGUASCALIENTES 0.06 0.26 -0.30 0.60 10

2 BAJA CALIFORNIA 0.19 0.22 -0.20 0.80 24

3 BAJA CALIFORNIA SUR 0.13 0.40 -0.30 0.50 3

4 CAMPECHE 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0

5 COAHUILA 0.20 0.34 -0.30 0.80 22

6 COLIMA 0.00 0.35 -0.30 0.30 4

7 CHIAPAS 0.09 0.30 -0.30 0.40 7

8 CHIHUAHUA 0.07 0.23 -0.30 0.40 14

9 FEDERAL DISTRICT

(MÉXICO CITY)

0.16 0.21 -0.30 0.90 220

10 DURANGO 0.13 0.23 -0.30 0.50 12

11 GUANAJUATO 0.15 0.28 -0.30 0.70 30

12 GUERRERO 0.05 0.23 -0.30 0.40 10

13 HIDALGO 0.10 0.29 -0.30 0.60 18

14 JALISCO 0.04 0.21 -0.30 0.60 70

15 MÉXICO 0.10 0.19 -0.30 0.60 120

16 MICHOACAN 0.06 0.19 -0.30 0.30 13

17 MORELOS 0.11 0.14 -0.20 0.20 8

18 NAYARIT -0.04 0.18 -0.30 0.20 5

19 NUEVO LEON 0.09 0.22 -0.30 0.50 33

20 OAXACA 0.08 0.23 -0.30 0.40 11

21 PUEBLA 0.15 0.24 -0.40 0.70 30

22 QUERETARO 0.20 0.28 -0.30 0.70 11

23 QUINTANA ROO 0.12 0.43 -0.30 0.80 6

24 SAN LUIS POTOSI 0.17 0.16 0.00 0.50 7

25 SINALOA 0.18 0.29 -0.20 0.80 21

26 SONORA 0.06 0.26 -0.30 0.60 22

27 TABASCO -0.17 0.23 -0.30 0.10 3

28 TAMAULIPAS 0.03 0.28 -0.30 0.60 23

29 TLAXCALA 0.04 0.29 -0.30 0.50 8

30 VERACRUZ 0.03 0.24 -0.30 0.60 55

31 YUCATÁN 0.01 0.27 -0.30 0.40 8

32 ZACATECAS 0.00 0.42 -0.30 0.60 5

99 UNSPECIFIED 0.09 0.21 -0.20 0.40 8

Source: CCT-JF-96. Index ranges from –1 to +1

A-8: INDEXES OF FUNCTIONAL FLEXIBILITY BY BRANCH (1996)

BRANCH INDEX STANDARD

DEVIATION

MINIMUM MAXIMUM NO. CASES

TOTAL 0.11 0.24 -0.40 0.90 841

1 TEXTILE 0.08 0.19 -0.40 0.60 37

2 ELECTRICITY 0.09 0.22 -0.30 0.60 19

3 FILMING -0.25 0.16 -0.30 0.90 106

4 RUBBER 0.15 0.11 0.00 0.30 11

5 SUGAR 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0

6 MINING 0.14 0.16 -0.10 0.40 14

7 METALLURGY AND IRON AND STEEL 0.17 0.19 -0.10 0.70 34

8 HIDROCARBONS 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0

9 PETROCHEMICALS 0.27 0.23 0.00 0.40 3

10 CEMENT 0.54 0.21 0.20 0.80 21

11 LIMESTONE 0.16 0.18 -0.10 0.40 8

12 AUTOMOTIVE AND AUTOPARTS 0.17 0.26 -0.20 0.70 39

13 CHEMICAL AND PHARMACEUTICAL 0.19 0.20 -0.20 0.80 91

14 CELLULOSE AND PAPER 0.12 0.14 -0.10 0.40 12

15 VEGETABLE OILS AND FATS 0.17 0.13 0.00 0.40 9

16 FOOD PRODUCTION 0.17 0.16 -0.10 0.70 132

17 BEVERAGE PRODUCTION 0.19 0.17 -0.20 0.60 73

18 RAILROADS 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0

19 BASIC WOOD 0.26 0.09 0.20 0.40 8

20 GLASS 0.30 0.10 0.20 0.40 3

21 TOBACCO 0.35 0.35 0.10 0.60 2

22 DIRECTLY ADMINISTRATED / DECENTRALIZED -0.08 0.17 -0.30 0.10 6

23 FEDERAL AGREEMENT OR CONCESSION 0.16 0.15 -0.20 0.60 132

24 COMPANIES WORKING IN FEDERAL ZONES 0.03 0.17 -0.20 0.50 81

Source: CCT-JF-96. Index ranges from –1 to +1

A-9: INDEXES OF NUMERICAL FLEXIBILITY PER BRANCH (1996)

BRANCH INDEX STANDARD

DEVIATION

MINIMUM MAXIMUM NO. CASES

TOTAL 0.37 0.40 -1.00 1.00 931

1 TEXTILE 0.19 0.41 -1.00 1.00 47 2 ELECTRICITY 0.02 0.23 -0.50 0.67 19 3 FILMING -0.03 0.16 -1.00 0.75 106 4 RUBBER 0.45 0.44 -0.33 1.00 14 5 SUGAR 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 1 6 MINING 0.32 0.37 0.00 1.00 14 7 METALLURGY AND IRON AND STEEL 0.52 0.32 0.00 1.00 36 8 HIDROCARBONS 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0 9 PETROCHEMICAL 0.19 0.39 -0.25 0.50 3

10 CEMENT 0.23 0.24 -0.33 0.50 21 11 LIMESTONE 0.21 0.25 0.00 0.67 8 12 AUTOMOTIVE AND AUTOPARTS 0.33 0.31 0.00 1.00 40 13 CHEMICAL AND PHARMACEUTICAL 0.51 0.29 -0.33 1.00 106 14 CELLULOSE AND PAPER 0.15 0.19 0.00 0.50 12 15 VEGETABLE OLIZ 0.13 0.17 0.00 0.33 10 16 FOOD PRODUCTION 0.65 0.35 -1.00 1.00 138 17 BEVERAGE PRODUCTION 0.26 0.30 -0.33 1.00 84 18 RAILROADS 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 0 19 BASIC LUMBER 0.35 0.46 -0.33 1.00 14 20 GLASS 0.22 0.38 0.00 0.67 3 21 TOBACCO 0.50 0.71 0.00 1.00 2 22 DIRECTLY ADMINISTRATED / DECENTRALIZED 0.26 0.35 0.00 1.00 7 23 FEDERAL CONTRACT OR CONCESSION 0.61 0.42 -1.00 1.00 159 24 UNDERTAKE WORKS IN FEDERAL ZONES 0.19 0.37 -1.00 1.00 87

Source: CCT-JF-96. Index ranges from –1 to +1

BILATERALITY INDEX

A standardized index was built to analyze bilaterality, starting from the union in each establishment

and workers’ formal and informal levels of intervention. Four aggregate scales were constructed the

results of which were summed and divided by four. The result of that division was standardized and

divided into three ranges: high, moderate, and low bilaterality indexes.