capacity scarcity restaurant revenue management.pdf

Upload: chetana-didugu

Post on 05-Jul-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    1/11

    International Journal of Hospitality Management 35 (2013) 316–326

    Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

    International Journal of Hospitality Management

     j ournal homepage : www.elsevier .com/ locate / i jhosman

    Restaurant revenue management: Do perceived capacity scarcity and

    price differences matter?

    Cindy Yoonjoung Heo a,∗, Seoki Lee b, Anna Mattila c, Clark Hu d

    a School of Hotel andTourism Management, TheHong Kong Polytechnic University, 17 Science MuseumRoad Tsim ShaTsui East, Kowloon, Hong Kong b Schoolof HospitalityManagement, ThePennsylvaniaStateUniversity, 201Mateer Building University Park, PA 16802, United Statesc School of Hospitality Management, ThePennsylvania State University, 201Mateer Building University Park, PA 16802,United Statesd Beijing UnionUniversity, Beijing, China

    a r t i c l e i n f o

    Keywords:

    Restaurant revenue management

    Fairness perception

    Perceived scarcity

    Capacity limitation

    Commodity theory

    a b s t r a c t

    Revenue management (RM) has become an indispensable strategic tool in capacity-constrained service

    industries whose total revenue often depends on the abilities of  firms to use capacity efficiently. The

    restaurant business is similar enough to traditional RM industries such as hotels and airlines, but restau-

    rants also have unique characteristics that pose special challenges to restaurant operators. Among the

    unique characteristics of restaurants are the relative flexibility of service capacity and the flexible dura-

    tion of a meal, which are important subjects to be considered in the implementation of RM practices. In

    addition, when a restaurant operator practices a demand-based variable pricing policy to adjust demand,

    the magnitude of the price differences may influence fairness perceptions of the policy. Based on the com-

    modity theory and the equity theory, this study hypothesizes that two main effects, namely, perceived

    scarcity of capacity in a restaurant and price differences, influence the perceived value of a restaurant’s

    offerings andthe fairness perceptions of a restaurant’s RM practices. As hypothesized, the negative effects

    of price difference on fairness perceptions are supported by the results. However, findings suggest that

    perceived scarcity of capacity influences neither the perceived value of a restaurant’s expected offering

    nor the fairness perceptions for a restaurant’s RM practices.

    © 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

    1. Introduction

    Revenue management (RM) has become an indispensable

    strategictool in capacity-constrained service industrieswhose total

    revenues often depends on the abilities of firms to use capacity

    efficiently. As the service provider reaches capacity, limitations

    restrict ability to serve additional customers. A restaurant, for

    example, may have insufficient seating capacity during the peak

    midday period typically for serving lunches. Indeed, most service

    providers face some type of capacity constraint (Desiraju and

    Shugan, 1999) and the combination of perishability and capacity

    constraints encourage service firms to focus on efficiently capital-

    izing on existing capacity.

    The capacity of a service firm is defined as “the highest quan-

    tity of output possible in a given time period with a predefined

    level of staffing, facilities, and equipment” (Lovelock, 1992, p. 26).

    Measurement of capacity involves both physical and non-physical

    aspects. For example, physical capacity may be the number of seats

    (for airlines) and the number of rooms (for hotels). Non-physical

    ∗ Corresponding authors. Tel.: +1 852 9735 4004.

    E-mail address: [email protected](C.Y. Heo).

    capacity is usually time-based and reflects the notion of physical

    capacity occupied during certain periods of time, such as seating

    hours in restaurants and tee-times for golf courses. The capacity of 

    a service firm is usually fixed over the short term, and thus the

    rationale for RM is the efficient use of fixed, perishable capaci-

    ties by charging customers different prices for identical services

    in an attempt to balance demand and revenues per capacity unit

    (Kimes,1989a; McGilland Ryzin van, 1999). RM practitioners apply

    concepts, such as market segmentation, demand forecasting, and

    variable pricing, to ensure maximizing the service firm’s revenue

    from limited capacity by adjusting prices to thehighest possible for

    any given situation (Ng, 2007).

    Kimes (1989a, 1989b) identified a number of preconditions

    for the successful application and effective operation of RM. In

    general, to gain additional revenues and profit, RM practices suit

    service industries that have perishable inventory, fixed capacity,

    high-fixed/low-variable cost structures, variable demand, and seg-

    mentedmarkets (Kimes, 1989a, 1989b; Berman, 2005). In addition,

    reservation systems can aid management of demand forecast-

    ing by calculating inventory units prior to consumption. Airline,

    hotel, and rental car industries represent traditional RM indus-

    tries because they share those similar characteristics (Chiang et al.,

    2007).

    0278-4319/$ – see front matter © 2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

    http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijhm.2013.05.007

    http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_3/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijhm.2013.05.007http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_3/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijhm.2013.05.007http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/02784319http://www.elsevier.com/locate/ijhosmanmailto:[email protected]://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_3/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijhm.2013.05.007http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_3/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijhm.2013.05.007mailto:[email protected]://crossmark.crossref.org/dialog/?doi=10.1016/j.ijhm.2013.05.007&domain=pdfhttp://www.elsevier.com/locate/ijhosmanhttp://www.sciencedirect.com/science/journal/02784319http://localhost/var/www/apps/conversion/tmp/scratch_3/dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.ijhm.2013.05.007

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    2/11

    C.Y. Heo et al. / International Journal of Hospitality Management  35 (2013) 316–326 317

    The restaurant sector is sufficiently similar to hotels’ and air-

    lines’ operations that RM practices are applicable for strategic

    planning. However, restaurants also have unique characteristics

    that pose special challenges, requiring operators to be creative in

    developing appropriate RM strategies. Among the unique charac-

    teristics of restaurants are the relative flexibilities of capacities

    and the flexible durations of meals, and these represent impor-

    tant subjects for consideration when implementing RM practices.

    Unlike airlines and hotels, restaurants have somewhat more flexi-

    ble capacities, for example, a restaurantmay have availableoutdoor

    patios for extra seating during pleasant weather and peak patron-

    age periods. Moreover, the total available seating capacity per day

    in a restaurant is not fixed since customers’ seating durations are

    unpredictable. Restaurant operators may need to understand how

    customers perceive the capacity limitations of restaurants. This

    knowledge is important because customers are mostly familiar

    with RM practices in traditional RM industries (e.g., airlines or

    hotels) with fixed capacities; perceptions of the relatively flexible

    capacityof restaurants may influence customers’perceptions of RM

    practices.

    In addition, when a restaurant operator practices a demand-

    basedvariable pricing policy, the magnitudeof the pricedifferences

    may influence fairness perceptions of the policy. The responses of 

    customers to restaurants’ RM practices are critical to successful

    application of RM in restaurants because revenue maximization is

    only attainable when customers accept the RM practices without

    dissatisfaction. Previous literature suggested that perceptions of 

    value(e.g., Dodds,Monroe, andGrewal, 1991;Grewal, Monroe, and

    Krishnan, 1998; Monroe, 1990; Rao and Monroe, 1989) and fairness

    in service exchanges (e.g., Maxwell, 2002) are important factors

    for sustaining customer satisfaction, positive behavioralintentions,

    and consequently, long-term profitability. To sustain customer sat-

    isfaction and to maintain positive relationships with customers,

    andfor successfulimplementation of RM, customers’perceptionsof 

    RM, such as perceptions of value andfairness, arenecessaryconsid-

    erations, coinciding with the characteristics of industries (Chiang

    et al., 2007: Heo and Lee, 2009).

    RM has had application to the restaurant industry, but priorresearch offered a limited number of specific strategies for imple-

    mentation (Kimes et al., 1998; Susskind et al., 2004). Restaurants

    offering promotions, such as “happy hour” and “early bird spe-

    cials,” onlyfocus on discountsduring low-demandperiods. The core

    element of RM is to charge premium prices during high-demand

    periods based on capacity limitation. However, the potential for

    customers’ dissatisfaction have discouraged restaurant operators

    from applying various types of RM approaches, including demand-

    based pricing (Kimes and Wirtz, 2003a). Therefore, the current

    study focuses on customers’ perceptions of a scarcity of capacity

    in restaurants and customers’ varying reactions to price different-

    ials in terms of the perceived value of a restaurant’s offerings and

    the perceptions of RM practices’ fairness.

    2. Literature review 

     2.1. Restaurant revenue management 

    Capacity utilization is a major concern for restaurants when

    attempting to maximize revenue because restaurants have, by

    nature, relatively limited space, relatively high fixed costs, and no

    inventory opportunities. However, restaurants unconcerned with

    limited space, such as takeout restaurants that market the meal

    without associated space and time, may have limited interest for

    applying RM to maximize revenues. Kimes (1999) argued that the

    principles of RM can apply to restaurants given that the unit of 

    sale in restaurants is the time required for service rather than just

    the meal. RM is more applicable to restaurants enjoying demand

    greater than seating capacity during peak times (e.g., Friday din-

    ner). These types of restaurants can increase revenue by managing

    demand and controlling the customers’ seating duration.

    Kimes(1999) and Kimes et al.(1998, 1999)wereamongthe first

    to address the issue of restaurant RM. They developed a strategic

    framework for applying RM to restaurants to increase revenue by

    effectively managing seating durations and demand-based pricing.

    They proposed using therevenue peravailable seat hour (RevPASH:

    revenue accrued in a given time interval divided by the number

    of seats available during that time). RevPASH indicates the rate at

    which capacity utilization generates revenue, and it increases as

    the number of tables’ turnover increases and the length of sea-

    ting durations decrease. Kimes et al. (1998) suggested managing

    seating duration and customers’ arrival as methods for demand

    management. Seating duration (subsequently, duration of a meal)

    is the length of time that a customer occupies a seat in a restau-

    rant; its importance arises from governing the availability of seats

    (Kimes et al., 1998). By reducing variations in meals’ durations,

    restaurant operators can manage reservations and seating deci-

    sions more effectively (Kimes,1999;Kimesand Chase,1998;Kimes

    et al., 1998).

    Basedon theargument of Kimes et al. (1998), several researchers

    expanded the discussion of the relevant issues for controlling the

    duration of meals. For example, Kimes and Robson (2004) discov-

    ered that seating durations in midscale restaurants vary based on

    table characteristics such as table type and table location. Kimes

    and Thompson (2005) reported the average duration of a meal

    by party size and day of week for midscale restaurants. Bell and

    Pliner (2003) showed that meal durations increase with party size

    among several restaurant contexts. Kimes et al. (2002) discov-

    ered that Europeans preferred a significantly longer dining time,

    while North Americans and Asians share similar meal duration

    expectations. Noone and Kimes (2005) examined the effects of 

    reduced durations on the satisfaction of customers and their inten-

    tions to return to the restaurant, and found duration reduction

    strategies can directly and negatively influence customers’ satis-

    faction. Noone et al. (2007) f ound that an exceedingly fast paceduring a meal diminishes customers’ satisfaction. More recently,

    Noone et al. (2009) f ound that the overall relationship between

    a perceived service encounter’s pace and satisfaction follows an

    inverted U-shape. Thompson (2009) conducted a simulation-based

    study andfoundthat on average, therevenue bump experienced by

    decreasing dining duration is less than one-quarter of the amount

    predicted by the common assumption that a reduction in dining

    duration yields a proportional increase in revenue.

    Some researchers are more interested in maximizing rev-

    enue by increasing efficiency of restaurants’ operations. Sill and

    Decker (1999) proposed the use of capacity management science

    (CMS) as a systematic approach to evaluate the capacity potential

    and process efficiency of a restaurant. CMS includes monitoring

    every element of service and of the production delivery processwith quantifiable measurements to enhance customer satisfac-

    tion, improve employee satisfaction, and increase profitability.

    Quain et al. (1998) and Muller (1999) identified managerial fac-

    tors that may improve the efficiency of restaurants; those factors

    include defining profit centers, dispersing demand, reducing oper-

    ating hours,and decreasing service time by improvingefficiency, as

    much as possible, of restaurants’ operations. Similarly, Kimes et al.

    (1999) suggested recommendations for the application of restau-

    rant RM such as training employees,developing standard operating

    procedures, and improving table management to increase the effi-

    ciency of restaurant operation. Thompson (2002, 2003) f ocused on

    restaurants that do not allow reservations and found that having

    appropriately sizedtables in positions to allowrearrangementwith

    other tables to serve larger parties can yield additional revenue at

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    3/11

    318   C.Y. Heo et al. / International Journal of Hospitality Management  35 (2013) 316–326

    virtuallyno added cost.Bertsimasand Shioda (2003) developedtwo

    classes of optimization models to maximize revenue for a restau-

    rant. The two-step procedure proposed included using a stochastic

    gradient algorithm to decide, a priori, how many future reser-

    vations to accept, and using approximate dynamic programming

    methods to decide, dynamically, when to seat an incoming party

    during the operational day. Susskind et al. (2004) f ound that cus-

    tomers are willing to shift their dining times to off-peak hours in

    exchange for discounted pricing. Dickson et al. (2005) suggested

    incentive strategies with a reservation system that can manage

    shifting demand so that arrivals match capacities.

    Other researchers focused on fairness perceptions of various RM

    techniques in restaurants. For example, Kimcs and Wirtz (2002)

    examined perceived fairness of five types of RM pricing in restau-

    rants and found that framing demand-based pricing as discounts

    rather thanas surcharges madeconsumers perceive RM practicesto

    be fairer. However, only a fewstudies explored RM from customers’

    perspectives. These studies focused on fairness perceptions for RM

    techniques or the influence of the techniques on customers’ sat-

    isfaction. Although demand-based variable pricing has proven to

    be successful in other service businesses such as airlines and hotels

    wherecustomersfind demand-based pricing to be moreacceptable

    or fair, restaurants have greater constraints in use of demand-

    based, variable pricing (Kimes and Chase, 1998). However, Kelly

    et al. (1994) suggested demand-based menu pricing as a method of 

    managing revenue, by arguing that a 1% increase in price can yield

    as much as a 20% improvement in profits. They also claimed that a

    demand-based approach to menu pricing is predictable from cus-

    tomers’ perceptions of a restaurant’s valuebecausecustomersfocus

    more on value than on price. Kelly et al. suggested that for future

    menu-pricing strategies, restaurants should consider the demand

    fluctuation. Heide et al. (2008) also investigated different pricing

    strategies for restaurants and concluded that a potential exists

    for increased use of various revenue-enhancing strategies such as

    pricediscrimination,peak-loadpricing,and bundling.However,the

    depth of extant studies on RM practices applied to restaurants is

    fairlyshallow (Bertsimas and Shioda, 2003). A theoretical approach

    would identify the underlying factors that form perceptions of fair-ness among customers to advance restaurants’ RM practices.

     2.2. Commodity theory and perceived value

    Commodity theory explains how individuals respond to scarcity

    by claiming thatvalues of commodities reflectthe extent of unavail-

    ability (Brock, 1968). Hypothetically, a commodity represents

    anything capable of being possessed, has use, and is transferable

    from one person to another (Brock, 1968) and encompasses both

    material goods and intangible services. Value refers to increases

    in perceived utility or perceived desirability (Brock and Brannon,

    1992). Unavailability refers to scarcity and other limits on avail-

    ability. Typically, the concept has been interpreted as limits in

    supplyor inthe numberof suppliers, costsin acquiringor providing,restrictions limiting possession, and delays in providinga commod-

    ity (Lynn, 1991). In the literature, the terms “unavailability” and

    “scarcity” are commonly interchangeable.

    Based on the commodity theory, the influence of scarcity on

    the valuation of goods has been studied extensively (Lynn, 1991,

    1992; Mittone and Savadori, 2009; Verhallen, 1982; Vehallen

    and Robben, 1994). Building on the commodity theory, several

    researchers tested four propositions: A product or service will be

    more attractive (1) when the numbers of suppliers are limited;

    (2) when a supplier imposes a restriction on availability; (3)

    when a consumer has to wait to gain the product, and (4) when

    the consumer needs to exert extra effort to obtain the product

    (Brock, 1968; Brock and Mazzocco, 2004). Researchers in psychol-

    ogy and marketing found that knowledge of a product’s scarcity

    affects consumers’ perceptions and evaluations of the attractive-

    ness, desirability, expensiveness, quality, and tasteof a product. For

    example, Verhallen (1982) f ound that people showed greater pref-

    erence for a recipe book perceived to be scarce. Lynn (1989) also

    found that artwork perceived as scarce was more desirable than

    paintings perceived to be readily obtainable. Recently, Aggarwal

    et al. (2011) tested the relative effect of two types of scarcity mes-

    sages (limited-quantity and limited-time) on customers’ purchase

    intentions and found that the limited-quantity messages are more

    effective than limited-time messages in influencing the purchase

    intentions of consumers.

    Several researchers examined the influences of perceived

    scarcity on customers’ perceptions of pricing. Lynn and Bogert

    (1996) examined the effect of scarcity on an anticipated price

    appreciation and foundthat scarcity increased the anticipated price

    appreciation of collectible products. They argued that although

    scarcity does not affect the actual potential of a product for price

    appreciation, news reports of scarce collectibles that have appre-

    ciated in value might lead people to develop naive economic

    theories and associate scarcity with price appreciation. Suri et al.

    (2007) examined how perceived scarcity influences consumers’

    processing of pricing. During scarcity, consumers’ perceived qual-

    ity and monetary sacrifice showed different patterns in responses

    that depended on the relative price level and motivation of con-

    sumers to process information (Suri et al., 2007). The study found

    that a high price along with high-motivation, perceived quality

    and value as well as purchase intentions increased during scarcity,

    supporting the hypothesis that motivation to process information

    moderates the effects of scarcity on information processing. The

    researchers argued that an increase in perceived value of an offer

    depends on whether or not application of pricing serves a greater

    role to evaluate perceived sacrifice or perceived quality.

    However, a few researchers argued that the appeal of scarcity

    does not necessarily result in favorable perceptions for the scarce

    product because potentialpurchasers scrutinizean offermore thor-

    oughly(Brannon andBrock, 2001; Brock andBrannon,1992; Inman

    et al., 1997). A liberalization of the commodity theory proposed by

    Brock and Brannon (1992) included three modifications: (1) exten-sion ofthe domainfromany conveyable andpossibleobject totraits

    and skills, (2) extension to negative objects, and (3) identification

    of cognitive elaboration as a mediator between scarcity and eval-

    uative polarization. Brock and Brannon (1992) argued that when

    negatively valenced objects, for which an individual might have a

    clear aversion, are scarce, the original notion of usefulness is dis-

    carded. Moreover, a negatively valenced experience gains greater

    aversive perceptions to the extent of its rarity.

    Based on the commodity theory, the findings of the majority of 

    the research suggest that when individuals perceive a scarce prod-

    uctas uniqueor valuable,scarcitywill elicitpositivefeelings forthe

    product. From the positive perspective of scarcity, the commodity

    theory should predict an increase in attractiveness of a restau-

    rant’sscarce capacity andperceivedvalue of the dining experience.Therefore, this study proposes the hypothesis:

    H1: The perceived scarcity of capacity in a restaurant will pos-

    itively influence the perceived value of that restaurant’s expected

    offering.

     2.3. Equity theory and fairness perception

    The equity theory, proposed by Adams (1965), focuses on an

    individual’s perception of fairness with respect to a relationship.

    Thetheory postulates that individuals consider what they putintoa

    given situation relative to what they gain from it andthen compare

    the evaluation with the inputs and outcomes of others. If the rela-

    tionships are inferentially inequitable or unfair, individuals may

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    4/11

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    5/11

    320   C.Y. Heo et al. / International Journal of Hospitality Management  35 (2013) 316–326

    andWiner, 1995). According to the adaptation-level theory, assess-

    ments of stimuli differences depend on the magnitude of the

    standard against which the assessments are made, and behavioral

    responses of individuals to stimuli represent modes of adapta-

    tion to environmental and organismal forces (Helson, 1964). In

    a pricing context, the adaptation-level theory suggests that price

    perceptions rely on the actual price and on the reference price or

    adaptation level of the customer. Furthermore, the adaptation level

    is a function of the magnitude of a series of stimuli, the range of 

    stimuli, and the dispersion of stimuli from the mean.

    Second, the assimilation-contrast theory (Sherif and Hovland,

    1958) states the existence of regions that are internal to peo-

    ple’sperceptual judgments,namely,latitudeof acceptance,latitude

    of rejection, and latitude of non-commitment. A new stimulus

    that falls within the latitude of acceptance may be acceptable,

    and consequently assimilate, while the stimulus that falls within

    the latitude of rejection is unacceptable or objectionable. In the

    context of price evaluations, latitude of acceptance consists of 

    an acceptable price range encompassing a reference point; lat-

    itude of rejection translates into an unacceptable price range,

    and latitude of non-commitment constitutes a range of neither

    acceptable nor unacceptable prices. Thus, the assimilation-contrast

    theory suggests that the price differences falling within con-

    sumers’ acceptable price ranges are either accepted or assimilated

    (Blair and Landon, 1981; Liefeld and Heslop, 1985). In other

    cases, when price differences fall outside the acceptable price

    range, they are contrasted or rejected (Monroe and Petroshius,

    1981).

    When a restaurant charges different prices for the same menu

    on different days of the week, consumers may perceive the qual-

    ity of food and service to be the same, but the prices are different.

    As a result, as the price difference increases, the perceived value

    will decrease. The price difference will also have a negative influ-

    ence on fairness perceptions toward RM practices in restaurants.

    The assimilation-contrast theory suggests that price differences

    outside the acceptable range are contrasted or rejected (Monroe

    and Petroshius, 1981). Therefore, if the price during high-demand

    periods fallsoutside the acceptable range, thatconditions may neg-atively affect the perception of fairness toward the restaurant’s RM

    practices. Therefore, this study proposes the hypotheses:

    H3: The price difference between low-demand and high-

    demand periods willnegativelyinfluencethe perceived valueof the

    restaurant’s expected offerings. In otherwords, the higherthe price

    difference is, the lower is the perceived value of the restaurant’s

    expected offerings.

    H4: The price difference between low-demand and high-

    demand periods will negatively influence perceptions of fairness of 

    the restaurant’s RM practices. In other words, the higher the price

    differenceis, thelowerthe perception of fairness perceptions of the

    restaurant’s RM practices.

    In addition, Brock and Brannon (1992) argued that consumers

    tend to assume scarce things are more expensive than availableones, and that expensive things are often assumed to be of bet-

    ter quality and reflect higher status than inexpensive commodities.

    Although Brock and Brannon did not empirically test the relation-

    ships, the study proposed perceived expensiveness as a moderator

    of scarcity effect. Therefore, the positive relationship between

    perceived scarcity and perceived value of the restaurant’s expected

    offerings may be stronger when price differences between low-

    demand and high-demand periods are large than when price

    differencesare small. In addition,the positive relationship between

    perceived scarcity and perceptions of fairness of the restaurant’s

    RM practices may be stronger when the price differences are large.

    Therefore, the current study proposes hypotheses:

    H5: The price difference between low-demand and high-

    demand periods will moderate the relationship between perceived

     Table 1

    Experimental design.

    Constructs Levels

    PS (perceived scarcity) No Low High

    PD (price difference) 10% 20% 30% 40%

    scarcity of capacity in the restaurant and the perceived value of the

    restaurant’s expected offerings.H6: The price difference between low-demand and high-

    demand periods will moderate the relationship between perceived

    scarcity of capacity in the restaurant and perceptions of fairness for

    the restaurant’s RM practices.

    The basic assumption of these hypotheses, however, is that

    a restaurant in this study faces capacity limitation during high-

    demand periods. Restaurants unconcerned with limited dining

    space (for example, takeout restaurants that market the meal itself 

    rather than space and time) may not be appropriate considerations

    for this study.

    3. Methodology 

     3.1. Design of the study

    This study used three (scarcity of capacity: No, Low, or High) by

    four (price difference: 10%, 20%, 30%, or 40%) factorial, between-

    subjects design to test the hypotheses (Table 1). More specifically,

    the study adopted factorial analysis of covariance (ANCOVA) to

    examine not only main effects but also moderating effects.

    This study used written scenarios to manipulate the perceived

    scarcity of capacityin restaurants and theprice differencesbetween

    high- and low-demand periods. A sample scenario appears in

    Appendix A. Fromthe literature, unavailabilityrefers to scarcityand

    other limits on availability (Lynn, 1991); thus, these terms provide

    the basis for the concept of perceived scarcity of a restaurant’s

    capacity. The survey used in the study includes two question-

    naireitems, limitedness and availability, to perform a manipulationcheck for the perceived scarcity construct.

    This study developed a questionnaire for the context of dining

    in a casual restaurant and uses a design with relevant constructs

    based on scales adopted from previous research. Some adjust-

    ments to the questionnaire were necessary to reflect the specific

    characteristics of restaurants, and. employs a seven-point Likert

    scale to measure each item in the questionnaire. Perceived value

    represents “consumers’ overall assessment of the utility of a prod-

    uct based on perceptions of what is received and what is given”

    (Zeithaml, 1988, p.14). The survey includes three direct measures

    to capture customers’ perceived value, adopting measures from

    Cronin, Brady, and Hult (2000) with modifications for the context

    of restaurants. Consistent with the studies by Kukar-Kinney, Xia,

    and Monroe (2007), measures for procedural fairness and distribu-tive fairness use a set of four items: fair, acceptable, unfair, and

    satisfactory. Kukar-Kinney et al. (2007) adapted this measure from

    the study of Campbell (1999) and added additional items to mea-

    sure pricing policy, fairness (procedural fairness), and pricefairness

    (distributive fairness).

    In addition to the main factors, the current study includes three

    covariates in factorial ANCOVA to enhance the internal validity:

    tolerance-of-crowding, familiarity with RM, and gender. Perceived

    scarcity of capacity in a restaurant may relate to customers’ per-

    ceptions of crowding. Therefore, a tolerance-of-crowding measure,

    adopted from Machleit et al. (1994), was included as a covariate in

    the factorial ANCOVA. Moreover, previous research found that the

    familiarity of customers with RM practices has an impact on fair-

    ness perceptions toward RM (e.g., Taylor and Kimes, 2010; Wirtz

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    6/11

    C.Y. Heo et al. / International Journal of Hospitality Management  35 (2013) 316–326 321

    and Kimes, 2007). Wirtz and Kimes (2007) suggested that as cus-

    tomers become more familiar with RM practices, the unfairness

    perceptions decline, over time, because familiarity tends to adjust

    customers’ reference-points for transactions and prices, resulting

    in lower or even no impact on perceptions of pricing fairness. Thus,

    the familiarity of customers with RM practices (that is, a demand-

    based pricing policy: weekdays-versus-weekends) in restaurants

    was included as another covariate in the factorial ANCOVA. Last,

    Beldona and Namasivayam (2006) examined gender differences

    in relation to perceived price fairness and subsequent repurchase

    intentions. Beldona and Namasivayam found that females’ percep-

    tions of fairness were significantly lower throughout all pricing

    scenarios which framed both discount and surplus situations.

    Accordingly, the model in this study incorporates gender as the

    third covariate.

    The survey, initiated with a brief introduction to the nature of 

    the study, proceededwith participants reading scenarios.The ques-

    tionnaire includes two questions for perceived scarcity of capacity

    and one question for perceived price difference. Second, the par-

    ticipants answered questions regarding their perceived value of 

    the restaurant’s expected offerings and their fairness perceptions

    for the variable representing demand-based pricing policy (proce-

    dural fairness) and the price difference (distributive fairness). For

    the final portion, questions measured respondents’ tolerance for

    crowding and familiarity with RM practices in restaurants. Demo-

    graphic questions such as gender, age, ethnicity, and education

    concluded the survey.

     3.2. Pretest 

    The questionnaire underwent a pilot test, which involved 66

    undergraduates in a hospitality program at a university on the east

    coastof the United States. Afterexcluding unqualifiedand/orincon-

    sistent responses, 55responses(83.3%)remainedfor analysis of the

    pilot test. Among the respondents, 18.2% were males, and 81.8%

    were females. Assessment of the scales included checks for inter-

    nal consistency and unidimensionality (Traub, 1994). The average

    variance extracted (AVE) for each construct was above the recom-mended value of .50 (Fornell and Larcker, 1981). For all constructs,

    reliability was above the suggested cut-off point of .70 (Nunnally,

    1978). The t-test revealed that respondents perceived price differ-

    ences between weekdays and weekends for “10% vs. 40%” to be

    different (t -value: −5.09,  p-value: .00). However, post hoc anal-

    ysis shows that manipulations for perceived scarcity of capacity

    did not elicit responses consistent with the hypothesis. A revised

    description, “The tables are always unavailable on Friday and Sat-

    urday” clarified the notion of perceived scarcity of capacity in the

    “High” scarcity situation. The description of a restaurant in the

    “Low” scarcity situation had similar revision from “The tables are

    sometimes unavailable on Friday and Saturday” to “The tables are

    normallybut not always availableon Friday and Saturday.” Another

    pre-test, using the edited questions, evaluated the revised manip-ulations for perceived scarcity of capacity, resulting in appearance

    of significant differences in perceived scarcity of capacity among

    the three scenarios.

     3.3. Data collection

    The final data, collected during May 2010, represent subjects

    from a general population, who requested tourism information for

    Arizona, Florida, and Texas. Twelve thousand emails were divided

    into twelve groups and allocated to each of the twelve scenarios.

    Each respondent was asked to participate in one scenario (scarcity:

    No, Low, or High; price difference: 10%, 20%, 30%, or 40%). Two

    reminder emails, after 7 days and15 days from theinitialinvitation,

    attemptedto enhance therate of response.From the 12,000 emails,

     Table 2

    Sample’s demographics.

    Frequency Percentage

    Gender Male 119 24.7

    Female 362 75.3

    Age 20–29 27 5.6

    30–39 75 15.6

    40–49 119 24.7

    50–59 148 30.8

    60 and over 112 23.3Income US$ 20,000 or under 31 6.7

    US$ 20,001–35,000 42 9.1

    US$ 35,001–50,000 77 16.6

    US$ 50,001–75,000 102 22.0

    US$ 75,001–100,000 107 23.1

    US$ 100,001 or more 104 22.5

    Education High school or Less 116 24.1

    Associate 105 21.8

    Bachelors degree 158 32.8

    Masters 84 17.5

    Doctorate degree 18 3.7

    Ethnicity Caucasian 419 86.7

    African American 19 3.9

    Hispanic 8 1.7

    Asian 17 3.5

    Other 20 4.1

    549 respondents participated in the survey (4.6% response rate),

    and the response rate for each scenario varied from 3.5% to 5.5%.

    Of the 549 participants, 44 incomplete questionnaires disqualified

    those responses, resulting in, 505 responses remaining for analysis

    (4.2% valid response rate).

    Asseenin Table 2, the sample(n= 505) in theanalysisrepresents

    75.3% females (n= 362). The ages of respondents ranged from 20 to

    85, with a median age of 49.3 years. Respondents aged 50–59years

    old (30.8%) and 20–29 years old (5.6%) accounted for the largest

    and smallest proportions of respondents, respectively. In terms of 

    income, the respondents were fairly evenly distributed, with the

    largest group (23.1%) reporting incomes between US$ 75,000 and

    US$ 100,000, and with the smallest group (6.7%) reporting incomes

    of US$ 20,000 or under. In terms of education, the largest category

    was holders of bachelor’s degrees (32.8%), followed by high school

    diplomasor less(24.1%).Last,86.6% of respondents wereCaucasian;

    the remainder were African-American (3.9%) and of other ethnici-

    ties (3.9%).

    4. Analysis and results

    Manipulation checks included a series of one-way ANOVAs to

    determine whether or not the experimental treatments led to the

    desired significant differences in the various conditions (results

    appear in Tables 3 and 4). The study used two questions (PS1 and

    PS2) to check thedifference in perceivedscarcitybetween High and

    Low, and Low and No, and results of the two questions show sig-nificant differences between both High and Low, and Low and No

    (Table 3). The perceived price difference among 10% (mean: 4.10),

    20% (mean: 5.04), and 30% (mean: 5.75) was also significant, but

     Table 3

    Manipulation checks for perceived scarcity.

    Level N Subset for alpha = .05

    1 2 3

    PS1 High 173 2.20 – –

    Low 167 – 2.66 –

    No 165 – – 5.83

    PS2 No 165 2.33 – –

    Low 167 – 4.57 –

    High 173 – – 5.60

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    7/11

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    8/11

    C.Y. Heo et al. / International Journal of Hospitality Management  35 (2013) 316–326 323

     Table 8

    ANOVA analysisof theeffects of perceived scarcity on perceivedvalue.

    Price difference

    10% 20% 30% 40%*

    F -value 1.31 .20 .55 3.11

    P  .27 .82 .58   .05

    * It indicates two-tailed significance at 0.05 level.

     Table 9

    Post hoc analysisof the effects of perceived scarcity on perceived valuefor the40%

    price difference scenario.

    Subsetfor alpha= 0.05

    N 1 2

    Low 35 3.31 –

    No 35 3.74 3.74

    High 35 – 3.94

     Table 10

    ANOVA analysis of the effects of perceived scarcity on fairness perceptions.

    Price difference

    10% 20% 30%* 40%

    F -value .21 .67 3.53 .02

    P  .89 .52 .03 .98

    * It indicates two-tailed significance at 0.05 level.

    capacity does not influence customers’fairness perceptions toward

    the restaurant’s RM practices, and that the price difference influ-

    ences customers’ fairness perceptions. Two covariates, familiarity

    with RM practices (F -value: 108.18,  p-value: .00) and gender (F -

    value: 14.07, p-value: .00), were found to be significant, suggesting

    that familiarity with RM practices and gender affect customers’

    fairness perceptions of a restaurant’s RM practices. No difference

    appears for perceptions of difference between the 30% and 40%.

    Hence, the data from the 40% scenarios were omitted from thefactorial ANCOVA. However, additional analysis including the 40%

    of the price difference scenarios provided the qualitatively same

    results.

    This study performedone-wayANOVA to investigatewhetheror

    not the effects of perceived scarcity of capacity on perceived value

    and fairness perceptions differ for each price difference scenario.

    As presented in Table 8, no significant effects for perceived scarcity

    of capacity appeared for the 10%, 20%, and 30% price differences,

    but for the 40% price difference situation, the effect of perceived

    scarcity of capacity on theperceived value was significant (F -value:

    3.11,  p-value .05). Post hoc analysis revealed that the difference

    in perceived value appeared to be between Low and High scarcity

    situations (Table 9).

    Table 10 shows that no significant effects from perceived

    scarcity of capacity on fairness perceptions appear for the 10%,

    20%, and 40% of price differences; the effect of perceived scarcity

    of capacity was significant only for the 30% of the price difference

    situation (F -value: 3.53, p-value: .03). Consistent with the resultfor

     Table 11

    Post hoc analysis of the effects of perceived scarcity on fairness perceptionsfor the

    30% price difference scenario.

    Subsetfor alpha= 0.05

    N  1 2

    Low 35 2.62 –

    No 35 2.72 2.72

    High 35 – 3.33

    perceived value, the differential for perceived scarcity of capacity

    was present between Low and High scarcity situations, as shown

    in Table 11.

    5. Discussion

    The main purpose of this study is to examine the effects of  

    perceived scarcity of capacity and the price difference on cus-

    tomers’ perceived value for a restaurant’s offerings and their

    fairness perceptions regarding a restaurant’s RM practices. In addi-

    tion, an empirical investigation considers the interaction effect of 

    the scarcity of capacity andprice difference, proposed by Brock and

    Brannon (1992). Factorial ANCOVA tested six hypotheses.

    According to the commodity theory, knowledge of a product’s

    scarcity affects consumers’ perceptions and evaluations of attrac-

    tiveness, desirability,expensiveness, quality, and tasteof a product.

    However, the results of this study do not support the hypothesized

    positive effect of customers’ perceived scarcity of capacity for a

    restaurant on the perceived value of the restaurant’s offerings. In

    addition, the equity theory proposed by Adams (1965), suggests a

    positive effectof scarcity of capacity on customers’ fairness percep-

    tions in the context of a restaurant’s RM (H2). However, this study

    finds an insignificant effect.

    Although thecommodity theoryhas thesupportof many empir-

    icalstudies,several researchersarguedthat the scarcity of a product

    does not have a positive effect on consumers’ evaluations of the

    product in allcases.Some studies argued that the appealof scarcity

    led consumers to scrutinize an offer more thoroughly and did not

    necessarily result in favorable perceptions for the scarce product

    (Brannon and Brock, 2001; Brock and Brannon, 1992; Inman et al.,

    1997). Brock and Brannon (1992) argued that for scarce, negatively

    valenced objects, for which an individual might have a clear aver-

    sion, the original notion of usefulness is discarded. Moreover, a

    negatively valenced experience will be regarded as more aversive

    to the extent that it is considered rare, because people confronting

    scarcity have motivation to think about the message. Thus, scarcity

    can also render negative evaluations more extreme (Brannon andBrock, 2001).

    In addition, Suri et al. (2007) examined the influence of 

    perceived scarcity on consumers’ processing of price information

    in the context of product and service purchases. The results of that

    studyshowed that during scarcity, consumers’ perceptions of qual-

    ity and monetary sacrifice exhibit different patterns of responses

    depending on the relative price level and on consumers’ motiva-

    tions to process information. According to Suri et al., motivation

    to process information moderates the effect of scarcity. During

    scarcity, a high price in a high- motivation condition, increase the

    perceptions of quality and value, as well as purchase intentions. In

    the current study, the respondents read a scenario and imagined

    participating in the situation. However, their motivation to process

    given information from the scenario is unknown, perhaps explain-ing the results of the insignificant effects of perceived scarcity of 

    capacity in this study.

    The unexpected insignificant effects of perceived scarcity may

    also associate with thetypeof scarcityand thetypeof product.Gierl

    and Huettl (2010) argued that positive effects from evaluations of 

    products depend on the type of scarcity (i.e., scarcity due to sup-

    ply vs. scarcity due to demand) and the type of products (i.e., high

    vs. low suitability for conspicuous consumption). Gierl and Huettl

    (2010) combined the types of scarcity and the types of products

    and found that scarcity due to supplywould resultin more positive

    attitudes toward products than scarcity due to demand for high-

    conspicuous consumption conditions. The findings of the current

    research support the notion that scarcity due to supply enhances

    evaluations of products, but positive evaluations of the product

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    9/11

    324   C.Y. Heo et al. / International Journal of Hospitality Management  35 (2013) 316–326

    decline when attributing scarcity to high demand. Thus, in the cur-

    rentstudy, customers’perceptions of a dining experienceat a casual

    dining restaurant (whether conspicuous consumption or not) may

    affect the results. If the respondents regarded having dinner at the

    casual dining restaurant as conspicuous consumption, scarcity due

    to high demand may not affect attitude.

    Regarding the price difference factor, the current results sup-

    port the negative effect of the price difference on customers’

    fairness perceptions regarding a restaurant’s RM practices. These

    results suggest that as theperceived price differencebetweenhigh-

    demand and low-demandperiods increases, and customers tend to

    perceive a restaurant’s RM practices to be unfair. However, incon-

    sistent with the hypothesis, the results of the present study do not

    support the negative effect of the price difference on customers’

    perceived value for a restaurant’s offerings.

    The findings of this study may provide restaurant managers

    withsome practicalimplications.Based on the commodity theory, a

    restaurant’s manager may prefera marketingmessage thatempha-

    sizes the restaurant’s full capacity during high-demand periods.

    However, based on this study’s findings, such information may

    not positively affect customers’ perceptions regarding the value

    of the restaurant’s offerings or the fairness of the restaurant’s RM

    practices. In such a case, the manager may instead focus on other

    features or information in advertising. Based on the finding of this

    study, a manager may need to avoid sharing information of avail-

    able discounts that differentiate high- and low-demand periods

    with customerswho plan to dine or aredining duringhigh-demand

    periods because such information may discourage patronage; cus-

    tomers may likely forma negative perceptionof the restaurant’s RM

    practices. An important issue for future research in this regard is to

    discover the optimal level for price differences at which customers

    will not consider the price as unfair, thus allowing restaurants to

    maximize revenues.

    This study performed several additional analyses and found

    that for the 40% price difference scenario, the perceived scarcity

    of capacity (between high and low) positively affects the perceived

    value of a restaurant’s offerings. In other words, customers who

    perceive a restaurant’scapacityas very scarce consider that restau-rant’s offerings more valuable compared with the customers who

    perceive a restaurant’s capacity as less scarce when the restau-

    rant provides a 40% discount during weekdays. This finding may

    suggest that the scarcity factor plays a significant role only when

    substantial andnot marginal price differences arepresent between

    low- and high-demand periods. A restaurant manager whose

    restaurant enjoys full capacity during high-demand periods may

    want to consider heavily discounting menu offerings only dur-

    ing low-demand periods to enhance customers’ perceived value of 

    the restaurant’s offerings. This suggestion arises from the notion

    that when the restaurant provides a marginal discount during

    low-demand periods, the restaurant’s high occupancy during high-

    demand periods (i.e., high scarcity of capacity) does not positively

    affect customers’ perceptions of value.From exhaustive research, this study is the first to apply com-

    modity and equity theories to the RM context, more specifically

    for the context of restaurants. Although the results do not support

    the hypotheses regarding perceived scarcity of capacity, this study

    raises an important issue of consumers’ perceptions of scarcity of 

    service resourcesin thecontext of restaurants’ RM.In addition,pre-

    vious RM research has provided little investigation of the effect of 

    the price differences between low- and high-demand periods on

    perceived value and fairness perceptions, and the current study

    fills this gap in the literature. Previous RM literature also found

    that familiarity with RM practice is a considerable factor for fair-

    ness perceptions of RM, and this study confirms the importance

    of a respondent’s familiarity with RM practices in the restaurant

    context.

    6. Limitations and suggestions for future research

    Several limitations ofthis studyshould benoted. First,giventhat

    the respondents represent only one geographic region (i.e., U.S.),

    findings ofthe studymay not generalizefor otherregions.However,

    considering the representative sample of 505 respondents with a

    wide range of backgrounds, as shown in profile of the sample (e.g.,

    age, education, and income level) discussed in 3.3. Data Collection,

    the sample may be an adequate proxy for the general restaurant

    goers in the U.S. In addition, the nature of the scenarios, including

    scarcity, might limit the generalizability of the results of the study,

    which only analyzes the effects of scarcity in cases of no provided

    information regardingother restaurant’s practicesand alternatives.

    In a scenario of choosing a restaurant, information ofnearby restau-

    rants may be a critical factor influencing customers’ interpretation

    of signals of scarcity.

    Second, the experiment in this study is scenario-based and did

    not occur in a field setting. Online-based scenarios may not fully

    represent a restaurant’s on-going situations in the field. Capturing

    all of the nuances of the actual situation in a scenario is difficult,

    and consequently, respondents may have difficultypredicting their

    feelings (e.g., perceived scarcity of capacity and attitude toward

    the restaurant’s RM practices) in a hypothetical situation. Specifi-

    cally, the description of the high-scarcity situation (tables always

    unavailable) may not be realistic. However, after the manipula-

    tion check through the pre-test, the original manipulation for the

    scarcity measure is, apparently insignificantly different among dif-

    ferentsituations.Thus, thecase is intentionally extreme to ensurea

    significant difference among the scenarios. Furthermore, the main

    findings of theinfluenceof scarcityof capacity on value andpercep-

    tions of fairness do not appear significant even with this extreme

    case.

    Third, regarding the measures for perceived value, different

    aspects of value (e.g., hedonic vs. utilitarian values) may represent

    extensions of this research in the future. Another constraint in this

    study is the sole focus on customers’ perceptions of disadvanta-

    geous situations, because the hypothetical plans of respondents

    were for a visit to a restaurant on a Friday. Future research mayconsider examining the reactions of customers in advantageous

    situations (e.g., obtaining discounts) to a restaurant’s RM practices

    using scenarios of scarcity.

    This study is experimental in nature and one of the first few

    studies to explore the effects of perceived scarcity of capacity in

    the context of restaurants’ RM practices. Although this study did

    not find a significant effect from scarcity on perceived value and

    fairness perceptions, additional research is necessary to investi-

    gate the effects, using different settings and other factors. Future

    research are encouraged to identify other factors that could influ-

    ence consumers’ evaluations of price information to understand

    further the impact of scarcity on the valuation of service offerings

    from a restaurant. In addition, future research also can examine

    cognitive procession as a mediator to understand better the under-lying mechanism for the effects of scarcity.

     Acknowledgement

    The authors would like to thank the anonymous reviewers for

    their constructive comments on improving an early version of this

    paper. This project is partly supported by a research grant funded

    by the Hong Kong Polytechnic University.

     Appendix A. APPENDIX. Sample Scenario

    Imagine that you are planning to have a dinner with your

    family on Friday. Your friend recommended several casual dining

  • 8/16/2019 Capacity scarcity Restaurant revenue management.pdf

    10/11

    http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0240http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0235http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0230http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0225http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0220http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0215http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0210http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0205http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0200http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0195http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0190http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0185http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0180http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0175http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0170http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0165http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0160http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0155http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0150http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0145http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0140http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0140http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0140http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0140http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0140http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0140http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0140http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0135http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0130http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0125http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0120http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0115http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0110http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0105http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0100http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0095http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S0278-4319(13)00077-7/sbref0090http://refhub.elsevier.com/S02