an estimation of the aggregate wheat supply function for

57
i An estimation of the aggregate wheat supply function for Zimbabwe M.Sc. Thesis Knowledge Gweru February 2019

Upload: others

Post on 04-Oct-2021

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

i

An estimation of the aggregate wheat supply function for

Zimbabwe

M.Sc. Thesis

Knowledge Gweru

February 2019

ii

An estimation of the aggregate wheat supply function for

Zimbabwe

Knowledge Gweru

February 2019

M.Sc. Thesis

Agricultural Economics and Rural Policy Group

Wageningen University

Supervisor: dr. J.H.M. (Jack) Peerlings

iii

Table of Contents Abstract ....................................................................................................................................... i

Acknowledgements .................................................................................................................... ii

Abbreviations ............................................................................................................................ iii

Chapter 1: Introduction ........................................................................................................... 1

Background and problem statement ........................................................................................ 1

Research Objective and questions ........................................................................................... 1

Research Questions ................................................................................................................. 1

Organization of thesis .............................................................................................................. 2

Chapter 2: Wheat ..................................................................................................................... 3

Introduction ............................................................................................................................. 3

2.1 Overview of Agriculture ................................................................................................... 3

2.2 Wheat sub-sector ............................................................................................................... 5

2.3 Policy issues .................................................................................................................... 10

Chapter 3: Theory .................................................................................................................. 13

Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 13

3.1 Conceptual Framework ................................................................................................... 13

3.2 Analytical technique ........................................................................................................ 14

3.4 Profit maximisation ......................................................................................................... 14

3.5 Price equations ................................................................................................................ 16

Chapter 4 - Data ...................................................................................................................... 18

Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 18

4.1 Data Sources .................................................................................................................... 18

4.2 Data.................................................................................................................................. 18

4.3 Description of variables ................................................................................................... 19

Chapter 5: Empirical Model and Estimation ...................................................................... 22

Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 22

5.1 Empirical Model .............................................................................................................. 22

5.2 Estimation ........................................................................................................................ 25

Chapter 6: Results .................................................................................................................. 26

Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 26

6.1 Stationarity testing results ............................................................................................... 26

iv

6.2 Chow-test results ............................................................................................................. 27

6.3 Wheat supply response results ......................................................................................... 28

6.4 Diagnostic tests ................................................................................................................ 29

6.5 Short and long-run price elasticities estimates ................................................................ 31

Chapter 7: Discussion and Conclusion ................................................................................. 33

Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 33

7.1 Major Findings ................................................................................................................ 33

7.2 Conclusion ....................................................................................................................... 35

7.3 Critical reflection and possible solutions ........................................................................ 35

References ............................................................................................................................... 37

Appendices .............................................................................................................................. 45

Appendix C: Soil status in Zimbabwe ................................................................................... 45

Appendix D: Water availability............................................................................................. 47

Appendix E: Money supply ................................................................................................... 48

v

List of tables

Table 2.1: Natural Regions of Zimbabwe and Farming Systems in each Region ..................... 4

Table 2.2: Land distribution in Zimbabwe ................................................................................. 5

Table 4.1: Variables ................................................................................................................. 18

Table 4.2: Correlation matrix ................................................................................................... 19

Table 6.1: ADF stationarity testing results before differencing. .............................................. 26

Table 6.2: ADF stationarity testing results at first differences ................................................ 27

Table 6.3: F-test results ............................................................................................................ 27

Table 6.4: Regression results for wheat output response from 1965-2018 .............................. 28

Table 6.5: Diagnostic tests results ............................................................................................ 29

Table 6.6: Correlation matrix after first differencing. .............................................................. 30

Table 6.7: Short and long-run price elasticities........................................................................ 32

Table A-1: Zimbabwe Wheat production, Consumption, Imports, Acreage, Yield /ha and

Exports ..................................................................................................................................... 42

Table C-1:Soil classification in Zimbabwe .............................................................................. 45

vi

List of figures

Figure 2.2: Wheat cropping calendar ........................................................................................ 6

Figure 2.3: Wheat value chain in Zimbabwe. ........................................................................... 7

Figure 2.4: Wheat production (%) by province in 2017. ........................................................... 8

Figure 2.5: Wheat production and consumption trend from 1960 to 2018.. .............................. 9

Figure 3.1: Factors affecting wheat supply and impacts of improved wheat supply. .............. 13

Figure 6.1: No sign of heteroscedasticity ................................................................................. 31

Figure 6.2: Residuals are normally distributed ........................................................................ 31

Figure 7.1:Wheat acreage trend from 1965 to 2018................................................................. 33

Figure B-1: Plots of the variables at levels, but in logarithms..................................................43

Figure C-1: Soil map of Zimbabwe ......................................................................................... 46

Figure D-2:Water catchment areas in Zimbabwe .................................................................... 47

i

Abstract

Wheat is the second most strategic food crop in Zimbabwe after maize. The main wheat

products include wheat flour and wheat bran. Wheat flour is the most used ingredient for

making bread and other bakery confectionaries which are now taken mostly by Zimbabweans

for everyday consumption. Wheat bran is also used for making stock feeds in the manufacturing

sector. Thus, the wheat industry contributes substantially to food security and employment.

However, wheat supply has declined over the years. The widening gap between wheat supply

and increasing demand led Zimbabwe to rely on wheat imports to meet domestic demand for

wheat products. Increased wheat imports have dampened domestic wheat prices, which

disincentives local production. This study was conducted to estimate the aggregate wheat

supply function for Zimbabwe from 1965 to 2018. The output response function derived from

profit-maximising was applied to determine the effect of price and non-price factors on wheat

production. All variables were in logarithmic form and were tested for stationarity. The function

was estimated using the Nerlovian partial adjustment model. Model results reveal that lagged

real prices of wheat, lagged wheat output, lagged rainfall and land reform policy were the major

factors significantly affecting wheat output. The results indicate that lagged real price had a

positive impact with an elasticity of 0.79 and 1.72 in the short-run and long-run respectively,

suggesting that wheat farmers are relatively unresponsive to output prices in the short-run but

more responsive in the long run. The results further confirm non-price factors such as lagged

wheat output and land reform policy had a negative impact on wheat production, but rainfall

from previous season had a positive effect on wheat produced in the next season. The study

recommends further research on other important variables which were not captured in this study

to draft policy conclusions.

Key words: Aggregate, Wheat supply, Elasticity, Short-run, Long-run.

ii

Acknowledgements

Most importantly, I would like to extend my sincere thanks to my supervisor dr. Jack Peerlings,

for accommodating me to be under his supervision. I express my humble gratitude to him for

unending support and encouragement. He inspired me at every opportunity through his

professional guidance, timely feedback, and constructive criticism.

I would also like to acknowledge all lecturers who taught me at Wageningen University, for

their helpful lectures that improve my knowledge and made me finish my study.

Heartfelt thanks also go to the Gweru and Sakutoro family for their support during this

programme.

May God bless you all

iii

Abbreviations

ADS Agricultural Diversification Scheme

CPI Consumer Price Index

FTLR Fast Track Land Reform

GDP Gross Domestic Product

GoZ Government of Zimbabwe

GMB Grain Marketing Board

IMF International Monetary Fund

OLS Ordinary Least Squares

RBZ Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe

R& D Research and Development

USDA United States Department Agricultural

UDI Unilateral Declaration Independence

ZAIP Zimbabwe Agriculture Investment Plan

ZESA Zimbabwe Electricity Supply Authority

1

Chapter 1: Introduction

Background and problem statement

In the expansion of the Zimbabwean economy agriculture plays a vital role through its impact

on overall economic growth, household’s income generation and food security (Mlambo and

Zitsanza, 1997; Juana and Mabugu, 2005; Toringepi, 2016).

Wheat is progressively becoming a key staple food in Africa due to rapid urbanization and

income growth. But the African countries produces only about 30% to 40% of what is required

for domestic consumption, leading to heavy reliance on imports and making the African region

to be exposed to global market and supply shocks (Negassa et al., 2013).

Although the demand for wheat has grown to about 450,000 metric tonnes per annum

(Zvinavashe and Mutambara, 2012), wheat production in Zimbabwe has dramatically declined

since 2000. The country’s production level fell from 340,000 metric tonnes in 2000 to about

20,000 metric tonnes in 2018 (Index Mundi, 2018). In which case, for the country to meet its

annual consumption level, it requires to import 430,000 metric tonnes of wheat. The country

has however been unable to meet this target.

Wheat is the second most essential strategic food crop in Zimbabwe after maize (Kapuya et al.,

2010, Mutambara et al., 2013). This shows its importance in ensuring that the country has

adequate food supply. The increase in demand for wheat products, especially as an important

food item in urban areas, makes it imperative to understand the reasons behind the fall in

production and factors that determine the aggregate wheat supply in Zimbabwe.

Research Objective and questions

The objective of this study is to estimate the aggregate wheat supply function for Zimbabwe.

Research Questions

1. What are the trends in wheat consumption, acreage and supply levels?

2. Which factors affect wheat supply in Zimbabwe and how large is their effect?

3. How can wheat supply be increased and what is the impact of increased wheat supply?

2

Organization of thesis

The first chapter introduces and outlines the research objective of the study and provides the

research questions. Chapter 2 presents an overview of agriculture in Zimbabwe and describes

the wheat sector, wheat consumption, acreage and supply levels. Chapter 3 derives the factors

that explain wheat supply and further expresses equations for exogenous variables as well as

market price equations for quasi fixed inputs. Chapter 4 discusses the data. Chapter 5 provides

the empirical model and discusses its estimation. The estimation results are presented in chapter

6. It also discusses the policy implications. Finally, in chapter 7 conclusions are drawn, caveats

of the study identified and areas of further research provided

3

Chapter 2: Wheat

Introduction

The purpose of this chapter is to give an insight of Zimbabwean agriculture. The first section

of the chapter presents an overview of agriculture in Zimbabwe and provides a summary of

land use. The second section discusses the wheat sub-sector highlighting the production, and

consumption patterns as well as the wheat value chain. Lastly, this chapter concludes by

synthesizing police issues emerging from the review provided in the first two sections.

2.1 Overview of Agriculture

Economic growth, household income generation, and food security are mainly determined by

the agricultural sector in Zimbabwe (Dzvimbo et al., 2017). This entails that Zimbabwean

development is based on agriculture (Maiyaki 2010). More than 70% of the population highly

depends on agriculture for a living. The country produces many agricultural products including

cereals (maize, wheat, barley, and sorghum), oilseed crops, (groundnut, soya beans and

sunflower), cash crops (tobacco, cotton, horticultural crops, and sugar cane) as well as livestock.

The agricultural sector provides inputs to the industrial sector which in turn provides inputs and

services to the agricultural sector through backward and forward linkages. In addition, the

sector contributes approximately 30% to export earnings and finally accounts for about 12.5%

of the country’s Gross Domestic Product (GDP) (Index Mundi, 2018)

Zimbabwe has a total land area of 39.6 million hectares, and 83.3% of the total land area (33

million ha) is devoted to agriculture whilst the rest is set aside for forests, national parks and

urban settlement (Lyons and Khadiagala, 2010; Mushunje and Belete, 2001). The total land

area can be categorised into five natural regions based on the land use potential and rainfall

patterns (Table 2.1 and Figure 2.1).

4

Table 1.1: Natural Regions of Zimbabwe and Farming Systems in each Region

Natural Region Province Spread Area(million ha) and

% of land area

Rainfall (mm per

year)

Farming System

I Manicaland 0.792 (2%) more than 1 000 Specialised and

diversified farming

II Mashonaland

Central,

Mashonaland-East,

Mashonaland-West,

Manicaland, Harare

5.94 (15%) 750-1000 Intensive farming

III Manicaland,

Midlands

7.524 (19%) 650 – 800 Semi-intensive farming

IV Masvingo,

Matebeleland-South,

Matebeleland-North,

Manicaland,

Midlands, Bulawayo

15.048 (38%) 450-650 Semi-extensive

farming

V Masvingo,

Matebeleland

South, Manicaland,

Bulawayo

10.692 (27%) Less than 450 Extensive farming

Source : Mlambo, 2014

Figure 2.1: Zimbabwe Agro-Ecological Regions. Source: adapted from ZAIP,2017

5

Figure 2.1 shows five different Agro-Ecological Regions which have also been mentioned in

Table 2.1. The figure gives an overview of how different farming systems are distributed

around the country.

The country experiences two distinct seasons that is the winter season (May to October) and

summer season (November to April). These seasons allow farmers to alternate between summer

crop production and winter crop production, which enables them to generate income throughout

the year. However, winter production is subject to the availability of irrigation. Except for

winter crops (wheat, barley, and horticultural crops), other major crops are grown in summer

when effective rains are received for plant development (Mutambara et al., 2013).

The land use is grouped into ten different categories (Table 2.2)

Table 2.2: Land distribution in Zimbabwe

Farmer Cluster Land Category Area (Million

hectares) % Number-of

Farmers

Smallholder

Farmers

Communal 16.4 41.9 1,100,000

Old resettlement 3.5 9.0 72,000 New resettlement A1

4.1 10.5 141,656

Small -

Medium Scale

Commercial

New resettlement A2 3.5 9 8,000

Small-scale commercial farms

1.4 3.6 14,072

Large-scale

Commercial

Large-scale

commercial farms 3.4 8.7 4,317

State farms 0.7 1.8

Urban land 0.3 0.8

National parks and forest land

5.1 13.0

Unallocated land 0.7 1.8

Source: (Mlambo 2014)

The land distribution process created new resettlement schemes A1and A2 which were set to

promote small scale farms and medium to large farms respectively (Maguranyanga and Moyo,

2006; Moyo, 2011).

2.2 Wheat sub-sector

Wheat is an important cereal crop which was introduced in Zimbabwe in the 19th century by

the European missionaries (Morris, 1988). Wheat is grown in winter between May and August

as shown in Figure 2.2 below. Cropping in winter is usually done under full irrigation because

the country receives almost no rainfall which hinders crop production (Kapuya et al., 2010).

Crops grown in winter require cold weather for successful crop development and high

productivity.

6

Figure 2.2: Wheat cropping calendar. Source: (Kapuya et al., 2010)

The crop is best grown in heavy loam soils and it is usually planted in rotation with soya beans

(Negassa et al., 2013). Barley and tobacco are the major crops which compete for land with

wheat production. Deliveries of wheat to the market are between September and February

(Mutambara et al., 2013).

Since winter cropping requires irrigation, it implies that the crop requires significant initial

capital investment for dams and water reservoirs construction, drilling boreholes, purchasing

water main-lines, and power reticulation (Mutambara et al., 2013). Given this significant capital

requirement wheat is mainly produced by medium and large-scale commercial farmers.

However, smallholder farmers under smallholder irrigation schemes and on wetlands also

produce wheat even though at subsistence levels (Anseeuw et al., 2011).

The agricultural sector and wheat sector more specifically is represented by the Commercial

Farmers Union (CFU), Zimbabwe Commercial Farmers Union (ZCFU), Crop Producers

Association (CPA) and Zimbabwe Farmers Union (ZFU). Wheat prices were controlled by the

state-owned Grain Marketing Board (GMB) up until 1994 (Mutambara et al., 2013). Even

though there was market deregulation after 1994, the GMB remains the major buyer of wheat

and possesses most of the wheat storage facilities. GMB works as a grain trade and processing

company. It sells wheat, maize, soya-beans etc. But also processed products such as wheat flour

and maize flour. GMB has been responsible for announcing minimum guaranteed producer

prices since 1980. Since, the introduction of dollarization in 2009, the producer price was higher

than the import price (Kapuya et al., 2010), (Chinyoka, 2013). Consequently, the local

processors opted to import cheaper wheat and this left local producers with no ready market to

sell their produce on except for GMB which is known for inconsistent and unreliable payment

arrangements to farmers.

7

Wheat value chain

The wheat value chain in Zimbabwe can be described by means of five different levels which

consist of input suppliers, producers, traders, processors, and end market consumers

(Mutambara et al., 2013). Figure 2.3 shows the different levels and summarises the structure of

the wheat value chain in Zimbabwe.

Figure 2.3: Wheat value chain in Zimbabwe. Source: Mutambara et al. 2013

From the producers, the crop is sold to the traders (GMB, Stay-well, and others), and processors

(GMB, Blue ribbon and National foods). The processors produce flour and bran which is then

used by the end markets in the baking industry, stock feeds industry and for household

consumption.

Wheat Production: Provincial contribution

As a result of the requirements for wheat production, the main wheat producing provinces are

Mashonaland West, Mashonaland Central, and Mashonaland East contributing on average 52%,

17%, and 10% respectively to the total output of wheat produced (Figure 2.4, numbers are for

2017). These provinces have favourable climatic conditions and potential irrigation facilities

8

which contribute to wheat production. Matebeleland North province produces the least wheat

in Zimbabwe, it contributes 1% of the total output (Ministry of Agriculture, 2017).

Figure 2.4: Wheat production (%) by province in 2017. Source: Ministry of Agriculture, 2017

Wheat grows and yields higher under cool conditions; hence wheat is grown in winter under

irrigation as it is a temperate crop. However, other climatic factors like temperature, frost,

moisture, early rain, and hail affect the yield of wheat. Temperature is the main climatic factor

affecting development and yield of wheat in Zimbabwe (Chawarika et al., 2017).

Production and Consumption Analysis

Wheat is a staple crop mainly used as human food in the form of bread, pasta products, and

cake. The crop consists of 20% bran and can then be sold to stock feed millers for the

manufacturing of livestock feed. Figure 2.5 shows the widening gap between wheat production

and wheat consumption in Zimbabwe from 1960 when the crop was commercially introduced

to present.

9

Figure 2.5: Wheat production and consumption trend from 1960 to 2018. Source: Index Mundi

2018. See also table in Appendix.

Figure 2.5, shows that before 1969, Zimbabwe was a net importer because consumption was

greater than production. During that period limited research on the wheat cultivars that produce

higher yield had not been developed and irrigation infrastructure was not established

considering the fact that the crop requires relatively much water (Rukuni, 1994).

We observe an upward trend in wheat production from 1970 to 1990, with some deeps observed

in 1979, 1980 and 1984. Figure 2.5, also reveals the decline of wheat production since 2002.

The country encountered international sanctions just before its Independence in 1980, however,

it embraced an inward-looking food self-sufficiency approach and succeeded to put up with the

increase in wheat production during the period of 1960 to 1980 (Mutambara et al., 2013).

The country adopted the strategy of providing subsidized soft loans for headwork’s and

irrigation equipment for the commercial farming areas, this was accompanied with extensive

research, development, and extension (Rukuni, 1994). The strategy resulted in increased wheat

production leading to wheat exports from 1976 to 1978. Wheat self-sufficiency was a result of

improved infrastructure, improved mechanization, improved know-how and a cool winter

which favour irrigated wheat (Rukuni, 1994).

However, the dawn of Zimbabwe’s independence in 1980 saw the earlier investments in the

wheat sub-sector declining due to increasing government budgetary constraints. However, the

0

50

100

150

200

250

300

350

400

450

196

0

196

2

196

4

196

6

196

8

197

0

197

2

197

4

197

6

197

8

198

0

198

2

198

4

198

6

198

8

199

0

199

2

199

4

199

6

199

8

200

0

200

2

200

4

200

6

200

8

201

0

201

2

201

4

201

6

201

8

Tho

usa

nd

(m

t)

Years

Production (mt)

Consumption (mt)

10

wheat sub-sector enjoyed price subsidy support from 1980 to 2000 to encourage investment in

irrigation and this led to a gradual increase in production (Rukuni et al., 2006).

From 2000 to present domestic consumption surpassed domestic supply (Figure 2.5). The

country shifted from being a net exporter to a net importer of wheat. The country last recorded

exports of 88 000 mt in year 1995, thereafter the production continuously decrease (Appendix

A-I). Domestic demand for wheat has stabilized around 450 000 mt per year, however,

production has dramatically declined from a peak of 325 000 mt in 2001 to 20 000 mt in 2018

(Index Mundi, 2018). Wheat consumption has increased due to an increase in urban population

and changing in preferences thereby widening the gap between production and consumption.

This ultimately enlarge the import demand of the commodity. Since 2000, following the fast-

track land reform program, the drop in production became particularly severe (Mutambara et

al. 2013). The loss of agricultural expertise as well as the decline in investment led to a further

decrease in wheat production (Rukuni, 2006).

The international “economic sanctions” in the 1990s had a negative impact on wheat

production. Economic sanctions are actions taken by foreign countries to limit or terminate their

economic relations with a targeted country for the purpose to persuade that country to change

its behaviour or policies (Chingono, 2010). The economic sanctions caused economic

instability, they also contributed to the isolation of the country from the International

Community. For example, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) withdrew its support to

Zimbabwe in 1999. In addition, the World Bank stopped supporting the infrastructure

development in 2001 (Ministry of Finance, 2003). This has seen an unexpected decline in wheat

production due to lack of funding for expanding the irrigation infrastructure and repairing the

deteriorated equipment. In addition, economic instability resulted in currency problems that

subsequently led the dollarization in 2009. This was an approved replacement of the

Zimbabwean dollar with the U.S. dollar as a result of high inflation (Mpofu, 2015). The

acceptance of the U.S dollar prevented many farmers from planting crops as they did not have

money to purchase seed because the previous year’s crop was sold in Zimbabwean dollars

(USDA, 2009). Hence, this led to the decrease in wheat production in the country.

2.3 Policy issues

From the previous sections plus literature some important policy issues can be identified. These

policy issues will be discussed here.

11

Competition with imports

The position of Zimbabwe of depending on wheat imports means that trade policies have a key

influence on the determination of domestic prices (Kapuya et al., 2010). The local wheat

producer’s performance has turned down due to stringent competition from imports. The

country import wheat from Canada, America, Poland, Turkey and Russia. Being a landlocked

country, imports are mainly delivered through Beira port in Mozambique and then conveyed to

Zimbabwe by rail. Transaction costs of importing are very high and the country faces a rise in

wheat import bills due to increased wheat imports (Mutambara et al., 2013). To lessen the total

reliance on wheat imports, domestic wheat production must be enhanced.

No clear property rights

Farmers in Zimbabwe lease the land from year to year (“A 99-year lease”). This is a legally

binding agreement between government and landholders. However, the lease is not transferable,

making it hard for the farmers to invest more on their farms. Moreover, the government

possesses the power to withdraw the lease from the farmers. This poses a high risk for the

farmer to develop infrastructure on the farm. Farmers have limited decision making powers

regarding the land property (Richardson, 2005).

Lack of credit

As aforementioned, the non- existence of land property rights hinders farmers to access loans

from financial institutions. Lack of international finance opportunities have restricted recovery

of the wheat sector. This led farmers failing to procure inputs in time and repairing irrigation

equipment. Availability of medium to long-term financial credits to farmers positively affect

wheat production (Ahmad et al., 2018). Therefore, a favourable environment is of greater

importance for the farmers to access loans easily and to develop their infrastructure.

Delayed payment by GMB

The GMB is entirely state-owned parastatal. The provision of funds for grain purchases relies

on the government treasury, however the government has fiscal problems and no funds are

being released to GMB (USDA, 2016). Consequently, this led to the delayed payment of

farmers. Because of the delayed payments by GMB, farmers are failing to prepare themselves

well for the next seasons. They cannot access enough funds for inputs procurement. As a result,

thousands of hectares remain unutilised (Richardson, 2005). This coupled with other challenges

has negatively affected wheat production in Zimbabwe.

12

Government Support

Currently, the government is assisting the agricultural sector by pursuing contract farming. To

restore self-sufficiency and to reduce wheat imports, the government intervenes through

Zimbabwe's agro-import substitution programme (Command Agriculture). The country is

driving and expanding the programme as one of its key policies to increase wheat production

(Marufu, 2017). Through the programme, the government supply wheat inputs and repairing

farm machinery hence encouraging more farmers to participate in wheat cropping.

13

Chapter 3: Theory

Introduction

The broad objective of this chapter is to presents the economic theory. The first section of the

chapter illustrates the conceptual framework which provides the theoretical underpinnings of

the research. The second section gives an insight into the analytical technique and production

function. The third section explains short-run profit maximisation and the derivation of the

shadow prices for quasi-fixed inputs. Finally, this chapter concludes by expressing the price

and shadow price equations.

3.1 Conceptual Framework

Figure 3.1 puts forward a number of constraints that influence the supply of wheat. The

framework highlights the cause and effect relationships between wheat supply and its

constraints. Determinants of wheat supply are macroeconomic factors (e.g. exchange rate),

institutional factors (e.g. policy), labour availability and quality, technology and price

expectations. Figure 3.1 shows besides various factors that affect wheat supply that

improvement in wheat supply can lead to wheat self-sufficiency, increase in foreign currency

earnings through a reduction of imports and improved welfare expressed in poverty reduction,

more employment and improved government budget.

Figure 3.1: Factors affecting wheat supply and impacts of improved wheat supply adopted

from (Mahofa 2007).

14

3.2 Analytical technique

Micro-economic theory states that price of a product is the main factor affecting supply. Output

prices play a vital role in the economic system, as it facilitates the allocation of farm resources,

income distribution and encourages farm investment as well as capital development in

agriculture (Chabane, 2002; Shoko et al., 2016). A general increase in the level of product’s

price, ceteris paribus, permits an intensive use of variable inputs, thereby improving crop

production in the country. However, price alone is not the only explanatory variable. Therefore,

price and non-price factors are of paramount importance in the supply function (David, 2013).

Therefore, following the conceptual framework (Figure 3.1), the supply function is made

dependent on macroeconomic factors, institutional factors, the environment, technology, and

weather. These encompasses both price and non-price factors related to production (Key et al.,

2000).

Production function

Taking the prices of the productive factors as given, the producer’s task is to determine the low-

cost combination of factors of production that can produce the anticipated output. This is best

understood in terms of a production function, that expresses the relationship between the

quantities of factors used and the output produced. This can be expressed mathematically as

𝑌 = 𝑓(𝑥1, 𝑥2, 𝐿, 𝐶, 𝐺, 𝑇) where the quantity produced is a function of the combined input

amounts of each factor. In the formula, Y denotes the quantity of output. The producer is

presumed to use 𝑥1𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝑥2 as variable factors of production (for reasons of simplicity we

assume here that there are only two variable inputs), that is, factors which can vary with the

level of production. The producer is also presumed to use quasi-fixed factors, that is, factors

which cannot be varied with the level production in the short run. These includes are 𝐿 labour,

𝐶 capital, 𝐺 land, and 𝑇 technology.

3.4 Profit maximisation

In the short run, costs for quasi-fixed inputs are not relevant for profit maximisation since the

producer cannot change their quantities as they are fixed.

15

Therefore,

max𝑥1,𝑥2

(𝑝 × 𝑓(𝑥1, 𝑥2, 𝐿, 𝐶, 𝐺, 𝑇) − ( 𝑤1𝑥1 + 𝑤2𝑥2)) .............................................................(1)

Where 𝑤1 denotes the price of variable input 𝑥1 and 𝑤2 represents the price of variable input

𝑥2.

To solve a maximisation problem with multiple choice variables:

1. Take the partial derivatives of the function with respect to each variable.

2. Set each partial derivative equal to zero and solve.

First Order Conditions for the variable factors:

𝑝 ×𝜕𝑓(𝑥1,𝑥2,𝐿,𝐶,𝐺,𝑇)

𝜕𝑥1= 𝑤1........................................................................................................(2)

𝑝 ×𝜕𝑓(𝑥1,𝑥2,𝐿,𝐶,𝐺,𝑇)

𝜕𝑥2= 𝑤2........................................................................................................(3)

At the optimal level of each input, the value of the marginal product will equal the price.

First Order Conditions for the fixed factors

𝑝 ×𝜕𝑓(𝑥1,𝑥2,𝐿,𝐶,𝐺,𝑇)

𝜕𝐿= 𝑃𝐿.........................................................................................................(4)

PL denotes the shadow price of labour. As the labour amount cannot be adjusted the shadow

price show the value of labour in the production.

𝑝 ×𝜕𝑓(𝑥1,𝑥2,𝐿,𝐶,𝐺,𝑇)

𝜕𝐶= 𝑃𝐶.........................................................................................................(5)

PC represents the shadow price of capital

𝑝 ×𝜕𝑓𝑥1,𝑥2,𝐿,𝐶,𝐺,𝑇

𝜕𝐺= 𝑃𝐺 .........................................................................................................(6)

PG signifies the shadow price of land

Technology indicates the way inputs are combined into output. we assume it is represented by

the functional relationship between output and inputs. So, we cannot explicitly calculate a

shadow price for it.

16

3.5 Price equations

𝑝 = 𝑝𝑤 × 𝐸𝑅 + 𝑡𝑟𝑝 + 𝑡𝑎𝑝 + 𝑠 .................................................................................................(7)

Where pw -world price of the product, ER- exchange rate, trp - transaction cost, tap-tariffs and s-

subsidies

𝑤1 = 𝑤1𝑤1 × 𝐸𝑅 + 𝑡𝑟𝑤1 + 𝑡𝑎𝑤1 + 𝑠𝑤1...................................................................................(8)

𝑤2 = 𝑤2𝑤2 × 𝐸𝑅 + 𝑡𝑟𝑤2 + 𝑡𝑎𝑤2 + 𝑠𝑤2...................................................................................(9)

Where 𝑤1𝑤1 and 𝑤2𝑤2 are the world prices of the variable factors 1 and 2 respectively, ER-

exchange rate trw1 and trw2 transaction costs, taw1 and taw2 tariffs and 𝑠𝑤1 and 𝑠𝑤2 subsidies on

variable input 1 and 2 respectively.

Therefore, having the prices of the variable inputs and shadow prices of quasi-fixed inputs, an

empirical model can be formulated and solved. Hence, the empirical model for this paper is

built from the above equations. However, to analyse the adjustment of the quasi-fixed factors,

in the long run, the difference between the market price and shadow price of the quasi-fixed

inputs can be determined. The bigger the difference the larger the incentive to adjust the amount

of quasi fixed inputs.

For example, the difference between the shadow price and market price of capital indicates the

incentive to invest or disinvest. If the shadow price is less than the acquisition cost (market

price in case of buying a capital good) this implies that the marginal revenue of a unit of quasi-

fixed input is less than the marginal costs at the acquisition (Drabik and Peerlings, 2018). For

that reason, it is not profitable to expand the use of quasi-fixed inputs.

Furthermore, it is not profitable to sell quasi-fixed inputs if the shadow price is higher than the

salvage value. Salvage value is an estimated resale price of a quasi-fixed input at the end of its

life, i.e. the market price in case of selling a capital good (Adnan and Iqbal, 2018). Conversely,

if the shadow price is higher than the acquisition costs this implies that the marginal revenue of

a unit of quasi-fixed input is higher than the marginal cost at the acquisition. Farmers are likely

to invest when the shadow price of an additional unit of quasi-fixed input surpasses the costs of

acquisition.

Therefore, in the long run, an adjustment in the amount of quasi-fixed inputs is profitable till to

the point where the market price equals the shadow price. Below I give equations for the market

price of labour, capital, and land.

17

Labour

The market price of labour at farm level is determined by the general wage corrected for the

qualifications/skills of the labour and the transaction costs to find/hire labour.

𝑃𝐿𝑚 = 𝜛 + 𝑞 + 𝑡𝑟𝐿................................................................................................................(10)

Where 𝜛 represents the wage rate, q denotes the qualifications/skills of the labour and trL

represents transaction costs.

Capital

The market price of capital 𝑃𝐶𝑚 is assumed is assumed exogenous but there are transaction

costs involved that could be interpreted as the difference between the acquisition costs and

salvage value. Transaction costs can be also interpreted as adjustment cost of investment

(Lansink and Stefanou 1997).

𝑃𝐶𝑚 = 𝑃𝐶

𝑚 ̅̅ ̅̅ ̅̅ + 𝑡𝑟𝐶.................................................................................................................(11)

Where: 𝑃𝐶𝑚– market price of capital and 𝑡𝑟𝐶 transaction costs of capital adjustment.

Land

The market price of land 𝑃𝐺𝑚 is probably endogenous in the sense that it is determined by the

profitability of wheat production. For reasons of simplicity we ignore this and assume the price

is exogenous but we take land characteristics into account (e.g. location and land quality).

𝑃𝐺𝑚 = 𝑃𝐺

𝑚̅̅ ̅̅ ̅̅ + 𝑄𝐺𝑆𝐶...............................................................................................................(12)

𝑃𝐺𝑚- market price of land, QG – land location/quality

18

Chapter 4 - Data

Introduction

This chapter presents secondary data gathered from different sources. It describes the

variables, data sources and summary statistics.

4.1 Data Sources

Secondary data were collected from multiple sources. First, the domestic producer prices of

both wheat and barley were obtained from the Grain Marketing Board (GMB). Second, the

world prices of wheat were obtained from the United Nations Conference on Trade and

Development Statistics database (UNCTADSTAT). Third, exchange rates and inflation rate

were obtained from the International Monetary Fund through the Federal Reserve Economic

Database. Fourth, yearly data for wheat yield and acreage were obtained from the United States

Department of Agriculture (2017) through the Index Mundi website. Fifth, rainfall data was

obtained from the World Bank database.

4.2 Data

This study uses annual time series data for the period 1965 to 2018 to estimate the wheat supply

response function for Zimbabwe. Table 4.1 reports statistical summaries of the data included in

the study. Specifically, statistical calculations comprising the mean, standard deviation,

minimum and maximum values are presented for each variable.

Table 4.2: Variables

Variable Mean Std. Dev Min Max

Wheat yield (thousand tonnes) 133.87 100.91 4 325

Price of wheat (us$/tonne) 4.00 2.24 1.49 11.01

Price of barley(us$/tonne) 4.24 3.30 1.67 23.73

Exchange rate(zw$/us$) 25.51 111.53 0.57 698.22

World wheat price (us$/tonne) 2.52 0.80 1.61 5.98

Inflation rate (cpi) 568.87 3518.84 0.36 24411.03

Average annual rainfall (mm) 652.71 137.09 411.52 974.87

Acreage (thousand ha) 28.85 16.62 2 57

Land Reform 0.35 0.48 0 1

19

Table 4.2 presents a correlation matrix which shows the correlation coefficients between the

explanatory variables. All prices were converted to real prices using a GDP deflator obtained

from Index Mundi 2018. It is noted that acreage and wheat yield are highly correlated as well

as exchange rates and inflation (Table 4.2).

Table 4.2: Correlation matrix

Exchange

rate

World-

price

Rainfall Acreage Land

reform

Inflation Price of

barley

Price of

wheat

Wheat

yield

Exchange rate 1

World price 0.2483 1

Rainfall -0.0266 0.0835 1

Acreage 0.0107 0.2523 0.283 1

Land reform 0.5764 0.3653 0.1078 0.1388 1

Inflation 0.966 0.3486 -0.0837 0.0807 0.7031 1

Price of barley 0.2121 0.4327 -0.1933 0.2698 0.6642 0.4273 1

Price of wheat 0.3301 0.4176 -0.1361 0.3672 0.6928 0.495 0.8834 1

Wheat yield -0.0725 0.2294 0.2053 0.9549 0.136 0.0037 0.2655 0.4275 1

4.3 Description of variables

Annual domestic wheat yield measured in metric tonnes is used as the dependent (endogenous)

variable. The annual yield is used although winter wheat is harvested only once a year. For the

purpose of consistency and uniformity in the study an average annual wheat yield is used. The

use of wheat yield is besides economic variables influenced by the biological nature of

agricultural production as well as the influence of climate (Ozkan et al., 2011).

The annual domestic producer prices of wheat and barley are independent (exogenous)

variables, they are measured in US dollar per metric tonne. We take yearly prices for wheat and

barley despite that they are harvested only once a year. A positive relationship between wheat

production and price of wheat yield is expected. An increase in the price of a substitute (i.e.

barley) implies a reduction in wheat production (Becker, 2017). Therefore, a negative

relationship is expected between domestic barley prices and total wheat yield.

20

The nominal exchange rate is the price of the Zimbabwean dollar expressed in the US dollar.

US dollar is the main international trading currency in Africa, therefore, it was chosen. In

addition, the annual average was used for consistency and uniformity in the analysis. An

increase in the exchange rate implies a depreciation of the Zimbabwean dollar implying an

increase of the world prices expressed in Zimbabwean dollars. This makes exporting more

attractive and imports more expensive. The bulk of wheat inputs used in wheat production

becomes more expensive and forces farmers to reduce production.

The world price of wheat is another independent variable used in the study to explain the

domestic producer price of wheat in Zimbabwe. World price movements moderately affect

domestic wheat prices (Dasgupta et al., 2011). In order to accurately estimate the price

transmission between the world and domestic prices, the world prices were obtained in US

dollar per metric tonne. Moreover, for consistency, the annual average world prices were used

in the study. An increase in the world price of wheat is expected to put pressure on the country’s

foreign exchange requirements in case of imports, affecting the entire wheat value chain. An

increase in world price increases the import bill which strains foreign exchange more. Wheat

imports decrease consequently, and therefore increase demand for local wheat supply.

Depreciation of the Zimbabwean dollar increases import prices of wheat incentivizing domestic

production.

The annual inflation rate measured as the rate of change of prices (CPI) will be used as an

independent variable. Cost-push inflation occurs when a factor of production’s price increases.

Cost of production as well increases. Consequently, farmers curb their production which in turn

affects supply. Therefore, a negative relationship is expected between the annual inflation rate

and wheat production.

Total annual rainfall expressed in millimetres (mm) per annum and lagged annual average

rainfall recordings will be also used as independent variable. It is expected that annual rainfall

received previous season has a positive effect on total wheat produced. Thus, if abundant rain

is received in the previous year it means that there will be enough water to irrigate wheat in the

next season. The reverse is true in case of drought, which in turn affect wheat production.

Acreage measured in hectares is another independent variable included. This refers to the total

land area employed for wheat production annually. A positive relationship between wheat yield

and area devoted to wheat production is expected.

21

The final independent variable of the study is the dummy which captures the effect of structural

changes generated by the Fast Track Land Reform Programme (FTLRP). FTLRP started in

2000 hence the dummy variable separate two periods (before and after) (Waeterloos and

Rutherford, 2004). The dummy variable takes the value of 0 or 1 to indicate the absence or

presence of the land reform programme. The land invasion had images of theft and irrigation

equipment destruction which dominated the coverage (Scoones et al., 2011). The programme

interfered with normal farm operation in the commercial sector. Therefore, it is expected that

the programme will have a negative and significant effect on wheat yield.

A time trend is another explanatory variable. This variable acts as a proxy for technological

change. Occurrence of a technological change increases the productivity of labour, capital and

other factors of production (Doraszelski and Jaumandreu, 2018). Subsequently, this increases

crop production. Therefore, a positive relationship between wheat yield and technological

change is expected. Since, a rapid adoption of modern technology increases cereal production

(Montgomery and O’Sullivan, 2017).

22

Chapter 5: Empirical Model and Estimation

Introduction

The purpose of this chapter is to present the supply response equation. The first section explains

the empirical model derived from the profit maximising framework. The section further shows

the steps on how to formulate and estimate the reduced form equation. The second section

discusses and presents the final supply response equation.

5.1 Empirical Model

Based on the profit-maximising framework discussed in chapter 3, the supply response function

can be determined. In chapter 3, we showed that the supply response is affected by both price

and non-price factors (Key et al., 2000). Instead of calibrating and/or estimating the model in

chapter 3, I will formulate and estimate a reduced form equation. More specifically I will use

the Nerlovian partial adjustment model. The model is easy to estimate and has been applied

often for many crops in developing countries (Leaver, 2004; Ozkan et al., 2011; Mythili, 2012;

Utuk, 2014; Ogundari, 2018). Using this model, one can determine the short run and the long

run elasticities easily. Moreover, its ability to include non-price factors into the model makes it

more realistic and better able to capture the trends in agricultural production (Yu et al., 2011).

The Nerlovian partial adjustment model can be formulated as follows:

𝑌𝑡∗ = 𝛼 + 𝛽𝑃𝑡

𝑒 + 𝛾𝑋𝑡 + 𝜃𝑡, ..................................................................................................(5.1)

Where 𝑌𝑡∗ = desired level of output for time t, 𝛼 = the intercept, 𝛽 = coefficient for the

expected real output price, 𝑃𝑡𝑒= the expected real output price for time t, 𝛾 = the coefficients

associated with 𝑋𝑡, 𝑋𝑡 = the vector of non-price factors and 𝜃𝑡 = error term, E(𝜃𝑡) = 0,

𝑌𝑡 − 𝑌𝑡−1 = 𝛿(𝑌𝑡∗ − 𝑌𝑡−1) + 𝜔𝑡 ...........................................................................................(5.2)

Where 𝑌𝑡 = the actual output produced, 𝑌𝑡−1 = the output of previous year, 𝛿 = partial-

adjustment coefficient, 𝜔𝑡 = error term, E(𝜔𝑡) = 0 ,

𝑃𝑡𝑒 = 𝑃𝑡−1

𝑒 + 𝜇(𝑃𝑡−1 − 𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 ) + 𝜑𝑡 .......................................................................................(5.3)

Where: 𝑃𝑡−1 = the price of the previous year, 𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 = the expected real output price of

previous year, 𝜑𝑡 = error term , E(𝜑𝑡) = 0 and 𝜇 = expectation coefficient.

Equation 5.1, illustrates that the desired output of the crop in period t, is a function of expected

real prices and of non-price factors. Equation 5.2, shows that the actual adjustment in output

will be only a fraction of the desired adjustment. Since full adjustment of the output in the short

23

run may not be feasible. Equation 5.3, specify an equation that explains formation of price

expectations based on actual and past prices. Producers may adjust their expectations as a

fraction (𝜇) of the difference between the actual price and the expected price in the last period

(t-1).The equation to be estimated is obtained through the following steps:

From equation 5.2

𝑌𝑡 − 𝑌𝑡−1 = 𝛿(𝑌𝑡∗ − 𝑌𝑡−1) + 𝜔𝑡

𝑌𝑡 = 𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝛿𝑌𝑡∗ − 𝛿𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝜔𝑡

𝑌𝑡 = 𝛿𝑌𝑡∗ + (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝜔𝑡...............................................................................................(5.4)

Then, substitute equation 5.1 into 5.4;

𝑌𝑡 = 𝛿[𝛼 + 𝛽𝑃𝑡𝑒 + 𝛾𝑋𝑡 + 𝜃𝑡] + (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝜔𝑡

𝑌𝑡 = 𝛿𝛼 + 𝛿𝛽𝑃𝑡𝑒 + 𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡 + 𝛿𝜃𝑡 + (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝜔𝑡...........................................................(5.5)

From equation 5.3

𝑃𝑡𝑒 = 𝑃𝑡−1

𝑒 + 𝜇𝑃𝑡−1 − 𝜇𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 + 𝜑𝑡

𝑃𝑡𝑒 = 𝜇𝑃𝑡−1 + (1 − 𝜇)𝑃𝑡−1

𝑒 + 𝜑𝑡..........................................................................................(5.6)

Then, substitute equation 5.6 into 5.5

𝑌𝑡 = 𝛿𝛼 + 𝛿𝛽[𝜇𝑃𝑡−1 + (1 − 𝜇)𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 + 𝜑𝑡] + 𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡 + 𝛿𝜃𝑡 + (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝜔𝑡

𝑌𝑡 = 𝛿𝛼 + 𝛿𝛽𝜇𝑃𝑡−1 + 𝛿𝛽(1 − 𝜇)𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 + 𝛿𝛽𝜑𝑡 + 𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡 + 𝛿𝜃𝑡 + (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝜔𝑡...........(5.7)

We lag equation 5.5 by one period

𝑌𝑡−1 = 𝛿𝛼 + 𝛿𝛽𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 + 𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡−1 + 𝛿𝜃𝑡−1 + (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−2 + 𝜔𝑡−1.........................................(5.8)

Multiply equation 5.8 by (1 − 𝜇)

𝑌𝑡−1(1 − 𝜇) = 𝛿𝛼(1- 𝜇) +𝛿𝛽𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 (1- 𝜇) +𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡−1(1- 𝜇) +𝛿𝜃𝑡−1(1- 𝜇) +(1- 𝜇) (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−2 +

𝜔𝑡−1 (1- 𝜇) ...................................................................................................(5.9)

24

Then, subtract equation 5.9 from 5.7

𝑌𝑡 − 𝑌𝑡−1(1 − 𝜇)

= 𝛿𝛼 + 𝛿𝛽𝜇𝑃𝑡−1 + 𝛿𝛽(1 − 𝜇)𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 + 𝛿𝛽𝜑𝑡 + 𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡 + 𝛿𝜃𝑡 + (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝜔𝑡 – [ 𝛿𝛼(1- 𝜇)

+𝛿𝛽𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 (1- 𝜇) +𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡−1(1- 𝜇) +𝛿𝜃𝑡−1(1- 𝜇) +(1- 𝜇) (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−2 + 𝜔𝑡−1 (1- 𝜇)]..........(5.10)

𝑌𝑡 = 𝛿𝛼 + 𝛿𝛽𝜇𝑃𝑡−1 + 𝛿𝛽(1 − 𝜇)𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 + 𝛿𝛽𝜑𝑡 + 𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡 + 𝛿𝜃𝑡 + (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝜔𝑡 –

𝛿𝛼 + 𝛿𝛼𝜇 - 𝛿𝛽𝑃𝑡−1𝑒 (1- 𝜇) −𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡−1(1- 𝜇) −𝛿𝜃𝑡−1(1- 𝜇) −(1- 𝜇) (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−2 − 𝜔𝑡−1 (1- 𝜇)

+ 𝑌𝑡−1(1 − 𝜇)

𝑌𝑡 = 𝛿𝛼𝜇 + 𝛿𝛽𝜇𝑃𝑡−1 + (1 − 𝛿)(1 − 𝜇)𝑌𝑡−1 − (1 - 𝜇) (1 − 𝛿)𝑌𝑡−2 +𝛿𝛾𝑋𝑡 − 𝛿𝛾(1- 𝜇) 𝑋𝑡−1 +

𝛿𝛽𝜑𝑡 + 𝜔𝑡 −𝛿(1 − 𝜇)𝜃𝑡−1 − (1 − 𝜇)𝜔𝑡−1 + 𝛿𝜃𝑡............................................................(5.11)

The final expression is as follows;

𝑌𝑡 = 𝑏0 + 𝑏1𝑃𝑡−1 + 𝑏2𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝑏3𝑌𝑡−2 + 𝑏4𝑋𝑡 + 𝑏5𝑋𝑡−1 + 휀𝑡............................................(5.12)

Where

𝑏0 = 𝛿𝛼𝜇;

𝑏1 = 𝛿𝛽𝜇,

𝑏2 = ( 1- 𝛿) + ( 1- 𝜇);

𝑏3 = -( 1- 𝛿) (1- 𝜇);

𝑏4 = 𝛿𝛾;

𝑏5 = −𝛿𝛾(1- 𝜇) and

휀𝑡 = 𝜔𝑡 - ( 1- 𝜇) 𝜔𝑡−1+ 𝛿𝜃𝑡 - 𝛿( 1- 𝜇) 𝜃𝑡−1+ 𝛽𝛿𝜑𝑡

Equation 5.12 is a distributed lag model and it includes a lagged dependent variable. However,

it is mostly expressed in natural logarithms to interpret the coefficients easily as the elasticities

(Ogundari, 2018). From equation 5.12, using the coefficient of each independent variable, one

can estimate the short run price response directly, and to obtain the long run price response one

can divide the short run elasticities by adjusted coefficient (Leaver, 2004;Aksoy, 2012).

25

5.2 Estimation

Using the variables selected in the previous chapters, the following function will be estimated:

Supply = 𝑓 (exchange rates, inflation, world prices of wheat, price of barley, price of wheat (t-

1), wheat out-put (t-1) , wheat output (t-2), rainfall (t-1), acreage (t-1), land reform policy,

time trend)

The final equation used is expressed in logarithmic form, this is to ensure the normality of the

residuals. Logarithmic transformation ensures that the errors are normally distributed and

homoscedastic (Maddala, 2001). As highlighted previously, using the logarithmic form allows

also for an easy interpretation of the coefficients as elasticities.

From the correlation matrix in the previous chapter we noted that 𝑜𝑢𝑡𝑝𝑢𝑡𝑡−1 and

𝑎𝑐𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑡−1 are highly correlated (0.93) and this led 𝑎𝑐𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑔𝑒𝑡−1 variable to be dropped from

the final model.

Therefore, wheat supply response equation is expressed as:

𝐿𝑜𝑢𝑡𝑝𝑢𝑡𝑡 = 𝑏0 + 𝑏1𝐿𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑙𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑡−1 + 𝑏2𝐿𝑜𝑢𝑡𝑝𝑢𝑡𝑡−1 + 𝑏3𝐿𝑜𝑢𝑡𝑝𝑢𝑡𝑡−2 + 𝑏4𝐿𝑒𝑥𝑐ℎ𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑡 +

𝑏5𝐿𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 + 𝑏6𝐿𝑤𝑜𝑟𝑙𝑑𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑡 + 𝑏7𝐿𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑙𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑏𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑒𝑦𝑡 + 𝑏8𝐿𝑟𝑎𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑎𝑙𝑙𝑡−1 + 𝑏9𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑟𝑒𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑚𝑡 +

𝑏10𝑡𝑖𝑚𝑒 + 휀𝑡 .........................................................(5.13)

Where:

𝐿𝑜𝑢𝑡𝑝𝑢𝑡𝑡 = log of total wheat output produced in year t, and measured in tonnes

𝐿𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑙𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑡−1 = log of the real wheat price, measured in US dollar per tonne

𝐿𝑜𝑢𝑡𝑝𝑢𝑡𝑡−1 = log of total wheat output lagged by one year

𝐿𝑜𝑢𝑡𝑝𝑢𝑡𝑡−2 = log of total wheat output lagged by two years

𝐿𝑒𝑥𝑐ℎ𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑒𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑡 = log of the exchange rate in year t

𝐿𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 = log of the inflation rate in year t

𝐿𝑤𝑜𝑟𝑙𝑑𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑡 = log of the real world wheat price, measured in US dollar per tonne

𝐿𝑟𝑒𝑎𝑙𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑏𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑒𝑦𝑡 = log of the real barley price, measured in US dollar per tonne

𝐿𝑟𝑎𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑎𝑙𝑙𝑡−1 = log of the rainfall lagged by one year, expressed in mm

𝑙𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑟𝑒𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑚𝑡 = dummy variable for land reform ( 1 for the years when the policy was

implemented and 0 for the years with no policy)

𝑡𝑖𝑚𝑒 = simple time trend which captures technological change

휀𝑡 = error term

26

Chapter 6: Results

Introduction

The purpose of this chapter is to present the results of the model. The first section discusses

stationarity of the variables in the model. The second section explains if there was a significant

structural change due to the land reform policy. The third section presents and discusses the

estimation results. The fourth section displays the diagnostic tests carried out and their

conclusions. Lastly, this chapter concludes by presenting short and long-run price elasticities.

6.1 Stationarity testing results

The final equation of the Nerlovian model was estimated in Stata using the OLS method. All

variables were tested for stationarity for the period 1965 to 2018. For this test, the Augmented

Dickey-Fuller(ADF) unit root test was used. The stationarity test results are presented in Table

6.1 and 6.2.

Table 6.1: ADF stationarity testing results before differencing.

Variable ADF test

statistic

1% critical

value

5%

critical

value

Probability Conclusion

Acreage 3.441 4.141 3.497 0.057 Non-stationary

Land-reform 3.161 4.143 3.497 1.000 Non-stationary

Exchange rate 1.731 2.639 1.952 0.977 Non-stationary

Inflation 2.868 3.581 2.927 0.057 Non-stationary

Output 3.139 4.14 3.497 0.108 Non-stationary

Output(-1) 3.139 4.141 3.497 0.108 Non-stationary

Output(-2) 3.074 4.144 3.499 0.123 Non-stationary

Rainfall(-1) 6.390 3.563 2.919 0.000 Stationary

Real price of

barley

2.601 3.565 2.919 0.099 Non-stationary

Real price of

wheat (-1)

3.181 4.148 3.500 0.100 Non-stationary

Real-world

price

2.942 3.565 2.919 0.048 Non-stationary

: all variables are in logarithmic form except the dummy trend (land reform).

27

Table 6.2: ADF stationarity testing results at first differences

Variable Test

statistic

1% critical

value

5% critical

value

Probability Conclusion

Acreage 7.37 4.15 3.50 0.0000 Stationary

Inflation 8.67 2.62 1.95 0.0000 Stationary

Output 7.58 4.15 3.50 0.0000 Stationary

Output(-1) 7.58 4.15 3.50 0.0000 Stationary

Output(-2) 7.56 4.15 3.50 0.0000 Stationary

Rainfall(-1) 6.39 3.56 2.92 0.0000 Stationary

Real price of

barley

8.93 2.61 1.95 0.0000 Stationary

Real price of

wheat (-1)

8.54 2.61 1.95 0.0000 Stationary

Real-world

price

6.82 2.61 1.95 0.0000 Stationary

Exchange rate 2.21 4.27 3.56 0.4706 Non-

stationary

Exchange rate-

2nd Difference

6.47 4.263 3.55 0.0000 Stationary

: All variables are in logarithmic form and at first differences.

The results of stationarity tests show that all variables were non-stationary at levels except

rainfall (t-1)(Table 6.1). All other non-stationary variables became stationary after first

differencing apart from exchange rates which became stationary only after second differencing

(Table 6.2). The land reform variable was not corrected for stationarity since it is a dummy

trend.

6.2 Chow-test results

A F-test was used to check if there was a structural change after the implementation of a land

reform policy in year 2000. Land reform policy was treated as a dummy trend variable in this

model. In STATA, the F-test can be carried out using the testparm command. Table 6.3 shows

the results.

Table 6.3: F-test results

Year 2000

H0 : land reform = 0

F- statistic ( 1, 25) = 6.03 P- value = 0.0213

Table 6.3 shows that the outcome of the F-test is 6.03, with p-value 0.0213< 0.05, so it is shown

that we should not leave land reform out from the model. We can reject the null hypothesis.

Therefore, we can conclude that there was a structural change after the impementation of the

land reform policy in 2000 and afterwards.

28

6.3 Wheat supply response results

Table 6.4 presents the regression results of the wheat output response for the period 1965 to

2018. The results show that the R- squared is 0.62, which indicates that explanatory variables

in the model explain 62% of the variation in wheat output. The P-value of F-statistic for wheat

output is 0.0020< 0.05, this suggests overall significance of the relationships in the regression

at 5% level.

The coefficient of lagged output (t-1) had a negative sign with a value of -0.53 The coefficient

is significant at the 5% confidence level, implying that when the country obtains higher wheat

yields, producers tend to reduce the production in the next production season. The law of

demand supply might explains this negative sign. Higher yields may tend to lower the prices of

the crop instigating farmers to react negatively by reducing production in the next season. The

results were similar to those obtained by (Ozkan et al., 2011) who also concluded a negative

relationship between lagged output (t-1) and actual wheat output.

Moreover, the coefficient of lagged output (t-2) had also a negative sign but not significant at

the 10% confidence level, suggesting that the output for the past two years might not

significantly affect the wheat production.

Table 6.4: Regression results for wheat output response from 1965-2018

DEPENDENT VARIABLE: DLoutput

Variables Coefficients Std. Error t-statistic Probability

𝐶𝑜𝑛𝑠𝑡𝑎𝑛𝑡 -4.33 2.56 -1.69 0.103

𝑂𝑢𝑡𝑝𝑢𝑡𝑡−1 -0.53 0.16 -3.31 0.003**

𝑂𝑢𝑡𝑝𝑢𝑡𝑡−2 -0.23 0.15 -1.56 0.130

𝑅𝑒𝑎𝑙 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑏𝑎𝑟𝑙𝑒𝑦𝑡 -0.04 0.24 -0.16 0.878

𝑅𝑒𝑎𝑙 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒 𝑜𝑓 𝑤ℎ𝑒𝑎𝑡𝑡−1 0.79 0.28 2.87 0.008**

𝑅𝑒𝑎𝑙 𝑤𝑜𝑟𝑙𝑑 𝑝𝑟𝑖𝑐𝑒𝑡 -0.33 0.48 -0.68 0.501

𝐸𝑥𝑐ℎ𝑎𝑛𝑔𝑒 𝑟𝑎𝑡𝑒𝑡 -0.42 0.31 -1.36 0.186

𝐼𝑛𝑓𝑙𝑎𝑡𝑖𝑜𝑛𝑡 -0.18 0.12 -1.52 0.141

𝑇𝑖𝑚𝑒 𝑡𝑟𝑒𝑛𝑑 -0.01 0.01 -1.18 0.249

𝐿𝑎𝑛𝑑𝑟𝑒𝑓𝑜𝑟𝑚𝑡 -0.35 0.14 -2.46 0.021**

𝑅𝑎𝑖𝑛𝑓𝑎𝑙𝑙𝑡−1 0.73 0.39 1.87 0.073*

R2 = 0.62

F-stat = 4.10 (p-value 0.0020 < 0.05)

Observations = 36

**Significant at the 5% level * significant at the 10 %level

As expected, the coefficient for the real price of barley had a negative value of -0.04, since they

are competitive crops. However, the coefficient was not significant at the 10% confidence level.

This implies that the real price of barley had no significant effect on wheat production.

The coefficient of the lagged real price of wheat had a positive sign with a value of 0.79. The

estimated coefficient is significant at the 5% confidence level, implying that the lagged real

price of wheat for the previous season positively influences the wheat production in the next

29

season. These results agree with (Bhatti et al. 2011; Huq et al. 2013) who concluded that there

was a positive relationship between the lagged real price of wheat and its output.

The exchange rate, real-world price, and inflation rate negatively affect wheat production but

they were insignificant at the 10% confidence level, indicating that they insignificantly

influence the production of wheat.

Time trend which was a proxy for technological change. It has a negative sign with the value

of -0.02. The coefficient is not significant at the 10% confidence level. This is not as expected.

However, the time trend may pickup a negative trend in technology for example disinvestment

in irrigation facilities, farm machinery, higher yielding varieties and worse infrastructure.

The dummy trend variable which captures the effect of the land reform policy in year 2000 had

a negative sign with the value of -0.35. The coefficient is significant at the 5% cofidence level.

During landreform process the country experienced high loss of agricultural expertise and the

policy led to the destruction of irrigation facilities and infrastructure (Scoones et al., 2011).

Finally, the results show that lagged rainfall is positively related to wheat output. The

coefficient is significant at the 10 % confidence level. This implies that when the country

recieves more rainfall in the previous season, water sources for example dams and water

resevoirs will have enough water for wheat production in the following season.

6.4 Diagnostic tests

Table 6.5 presents diagnostic tests which were employed to validate the quality of the model.

These tests include a White test for heteroskedasticity, Jarque- Bera test for normality, the

Ramsey RESET test for the stability of the model, and Breusch-Godfrey LM test for

autocorrelation. The table also shows the mean of the variance inflation factor which also shows

the sign of multicollinearity.

Table 6.5: Diagnostic tests results

Testisting for: Method Null-

hypothesis

Outcome P-

value

Conclusion

Heteroskedasticity White

test

Constant

variance

1.88 0.1709 No sign of

heteroskedasticty

Normality Jarque-

Bera test

Normality 0.36 0.8362 Shows residuals

are normally

distributed

Stability Ramsey

RESET

test

Model has no

omitted

variables

3.48 0.1332 No sign of

misspecification

of the model

Autocorelation Breusch

Godfrey

LM test

No serial

autocorrelation

8.38 0.0786 No sign of

autocorelation

Multicollinearrity Mean

VIF

1.98 No serious

problem of

multicollinearity

30

Multicollinearity

To check for severity of multicollinearity, the Variance Inflation Factor (VIF) was obtained

from the STATA output. When there is no collinearity among the explanatory variables VIF

will be equal to 1. VIF index ranges from 1 up to infinity. However, explanatory variables are

said to be highly collinear if their VIF exceeds 10 (Ketema and Kassa, 2016). Table 6.5 shows

that the computed VIF is 1.98 which is very small and the author concludes that there is no

serious problem of multicollinearity. Table 6.6 support that there is no serious correlation

among the explanatory varibles after taking their first differences. However, acreage and lagged

output(t-1) remain highly correlated hence it was dropped from the final model.

Table 6.6: Correlation matrix after first differencing.

Land-

refor

m

Exchange

-rates

Real

world

price

Real

price of

wheat

Real

price

of

barley

Outpu

t (-2)

Outpu

t (-1)

Outpu

t

Inflation Acreag

e

Land-reform 1

Exchange-

rates

0.625 1

Real world

price

0.020 -0.052 1

Real price of

wheat

0.259 -0.028 -0.289 1

Real price of

barley

-0.096 -0.543 0.278 -0.106 1

Output(-2) -0.037 0.0724 0.156 -0.316 0.135 1

Output(-1) -0.202 -0.256 -0.210 -0.092 -0.011 -0.301 1

Output -0.263 -0.101 -0.248 0.434 -0.122 -0.176 -0.277 1

Inflation 0.272 0.273 0.059 -0.075 -0.027 0.077 0.024 -0.307 1

Acreage -0.115 -0.084 -0.182 -0.149 -0.104 -0.295 0.956 -0.283 0.083 1

Figure 6.1 and 6.2 support that there was no sign of heteroskedasticity and also the residuals

were normally distributed.

31

Figure 6.1: No sign of heteroscedasticity

Figure 6.2: Residuals are normally distributed

6.5 Short and long-run price elasticities estimates

Chapter 5 showed that equation 5.12 had to be estimated. However, due to non-stationarity of

the variables, the equation was then estimated in first differences with all variables in

logarithms.

𝑌𝑡 − 𝑌𝑡−1 = 𝑏0 + 𝑏1(𝑃𝑡−1 − 𝑃𝑡−2) + 𝑏2(𝑌𝑡−1 − 𝑌𝑡−2) + 𝑏3(𝑌𝑡−2−𝑌𝑡−3) + 𝑏4𝑋𝑡 + 𝑏5𝑋𝑡−1 + 휀𝑡

𝑌𝑡 = 𝑏0 + 𝑌𝑡−1 + 𝑏1𝑃𝑡−1 − 𝑏1𝑃𝑡−2 + 𝑏2𝑌𝑡−1 − 𝑏2𝑌𝑡−2 + 𝑏3𝑌𝑡−2−𝑏3𝑌𝑡−3 + 𝑏4𝑋𝑡 + 𝑏5𝑋𝑡−1 + 휀𝑡

𝑌𝑡 = 𝑏0 + 𝑏1𝑃𝑡−1 + (1 + 𝑏2)𝑌𝑡−1 + (𝑏3 − 𝑏2)𝑌𝑡−2−𝑏3𝑌𝑡−3 + 𝑏4𝑋𝑡 + 𝑏5𝑋𝑡−1 + 휀𝑡 … … … … . (6.51)

Where 𝑏1 is the short-run price elasticity equalling 0.79, (1 + 𝑏2), (𝑏3 − 𝑏2) and 𝑏3 are the

elasticities of the Outputt−1, Outputt−2 and Outputt−3 respectively. Given that (1 + 𝑏2) = -

0.53 and (𝑏3 − 𝑏2) = -0.23 (Table 6.4). Therefore, 𝑏3 becomes 1.30.

Table 6.6 summaries the estimated short and long-run elasticities. The short-run supply

elasticity is measured by 𝑏1 and the long-run supply elasticity is obtained through dividing the

short run elasticity by the adjustment coefficient. The adjustment coefficient is obtained by

subtracting the coefficient of the lagged dependent variables from 1 (Aksoy, 2012): (Cowling

et al. 2013). Therefore, to calculate the long run elasticity this formula can be applied

𝑏1

(1−(1+𝑏2)−(𝑏3−𝑏2)−𝑏3 =

0.79

(1+0.53+0.23−1.3) =

0.79

0.46 = 1.72

32

The short-run and the long-run price elasticities are estimated as 0.79 and 1.72 respectively. It

is noted that wheat supply is price inelastic in the short run and price elastic in the long run.

This implies that wheat producers adjust their production relatively less than the price changes

in the short run but more than proportional to the price change in the long run.

Table 6.7: Short and long-run price elasticities

Independent variable Short-run elasticity Long-run elasticity

Real wheat price 0.79 1.72

Source: Authors calculation

33

Chapter 7: Discussion and Conclusion

Introduction

The purpose of this chapter is to present the major findings and critically discuss the research.

The first section discusses the major findings of the study. The second section draws the

conclusion of the study based on these findings. Lastly, the chapter provides a critical reflection

and possible solutions to the challenges faced in the study.

7.1 Major Findings

The first research question on describing wheat production and consumption trends has been

answered using literature search. Figure 2.5 in chapter 2, illustrates the trends, showing a

widening gap between production and consumption from the year 1960 to 2018.

From 1966-1974, 1980-1986, and from 1990 to the present domestic consumption surpassed

domestic supply (Figure 2.5). This ultimately increases the import demand of the commodity

which then increases the wheat import bills and further strains the country’s budget.

Figure 7.1, shows the area under wheat production for the period 1965 to 2018. The figure

shows that from 1966-1978 there was a substantial increase in the number of hectares devoted

to wheat production. Thereafter, the area under wheat production started to fluctuate from 1978

to 2006. From 2006 to 2008 the country experienced a sharp drop in the area under production.

It fluctuates again from 2010-2014 and lastly stabilises in 2016 onwards (Figure 7.1).

Figure 7.1:Wheat acreage trend from 1965 to 2018

The estimated supply function indicates that wheat production is affected by both price and

non-price factors. Therefore, this provides answers to the second research question of the study.

The results revealed that lagged real price is one of the factors which affects wheat production.

34

It has a positive impact on the wheat output with an elasticity of 0.79, suggesting that farmers

will venture into wheat production on the basis of the previous price. The results indicate that

a 10% increase in lagged real price of wheat results in 7.9 % and 17% increase in total wheat

output in the short and long run respectively. This concludes that wheat producers adjust their

production relatively more than the price changes in the long run than in the short run. These

results concur with the results from other studies such as (Yunus, 1993; Matin and Alam, 2004;

Begum et al., 2002). Short-run results are in agreement with the results obtained by (Bhatti et

al. 2011) and (Huq et al., 2013). But, the long-run price elasticity results differs.

The lagged output (t-1) is another factor affecting wheat production in Zimbabwe. It has a

negative effect on the wheat output with an elasticity of -0.53, implying that a 10 % increase in

lagged output (t-1) results in a 5.3 % decrease in actual output. Therefore, it is concluded that

the supply conditions of the previous season will affect the production of the next season.

However, these results are in disagreement with the results obtained by (Bhatti et al., 2011))

and (Mann and Warner, 2017)). They find that previous output has a positive impact on actual

wheat output.

The results show that land reform policy which was implemented in the year 2000 is another

determinant of wheat production in Zimbabwe. The results revealed that the policy had a

negative impact on wheat output. This implies that the policy disincentives wheat producers to

a great extent. The implementation of the land reform policy led to the destruction of irrigation

equipment and infrastructure. Moreover, during the land reform process, the land was

redistributed to smallholders farmers with no agricultural expertise and enough capital to

participate in wheat production.

Lastly, lagged rainfall is another important factor that determines wheat production. Rainfall

received in the previous season had a positive impact on wheat produced in the next season.

More rainfall received in the previous year suggests that water sources such as dams and water

reservoirs will be having sufficient water for irrigation in the next season. Similar findings were

obtained by (Mann and Warner, 2017) who concluded that yields are higher in areas with

moderate levels of available water for irrigation. However, in the study by (Huang and Khanna,

2010), their findings were uncertain, they cited that changes in rainfall could lead to an increase

or decrease in wheat yields.

35

7.2 Conclusion

The major objective of this study was to estimate the aggregate wheat supply function for

Zimbabwe from 1965 to 2018. The output response function derived from profit-maximising

was applied to determine the effect of price and non-price factors on wheat production. All

variables were in logarithmic form and were tested for stationarity except for the time trend and

dummy variable. The function was estimated using the Nerlovian partial adjustment model.

Different diagnostic tests applied confirmed the fitness of the model.

As a result, it was established that wheat supply is negatively affected by the output of the

previous season and the land reform programme which was implemented in the year 2000. The

results of the study showed that wheat supply depends on the rainfall of the previous year,

suggesting that sufficient water for wheat irrigation is available if the country receives more

rainfall in the previous season. The findings of the study also revealed that wheat supply is price

inelastic in the short run, implying that farmers are relatively unresponsive to output prices in

the short run, but more responsive in the long run. It is shown that in the long run, the short-run

supply limitations will be resolved and farmers can adjust their level of production to a greater

extent. This could suggest that domestic wheat price support and price stabilisation policy might

influence the wheat supply, but more research is needed to make concrete policy conclusions.

7.3 Critical reflection and possible solutions

This study estimates the aggregate wheat supply function for Zimbabwe using secondary data.

Even though the results are important to the policy makers, in themselves they do not command

policy conclusions. This is because of the limitations of the study. Firstly, the study could not

capture all important variables explained in the theoretical chapter (e.g. fertiliser, labour and

electricity costs) due to lack of data.

Secondly, the study uses aggregate data collected from different sources. Some sources display

different figures of the same variable for example in case of the exchange rates. In addition, the

study focuses only on the aggregate wheat response to price and non-price factors while

possibly there could be a difference in response between farm level and national level.

Thirdly, the effect of the transaction costs explained in the theoretical chapter was also not

captured in the empirical model. Transaction costs which play a key role in the trading of

commodities to determining the implicit and explicit costs of the transaction.

36

Therefore, considering the limitations of the study highlighted above, the following points for

further research were recommended. Instead of using the aggregate data, one can use farm-level

data, implying that primary data will be used in the analysis. By using primary data the author

gains control over the quality and accuracy of the data. Data can also be collected with the

research questions in mind. Moreover, using farm-level data more information can be collected,

thereby increasing the number of variables in the analysis. The effect of variables that differ on

regional and farm level can be investigated e.g. farmer’s expertise. This will enable to formulate

regional policies and target specific groups of farmers.

In addition, there is need to study whether Zimbabwe has a comparative advantage of producing

wheat. More research is clearly needed on specific aspects of this, such as (i) is it an efficient

use of resources for the country to produce wheat? (ii) If it is efficient to produce wheat, what

combination of policy incentives and technological change are needed to promote domestic

wheat production?

37

References

Adnan, M., and M. Iqbal. (2018). Field Performance Evaluation of Indigenous Tractor Mounted

Reaper. Paper read at 2018 ASABE Annual International Meeting.

Ahmad, D., M. Chani, and M. Afzal. (2018). Impact of formal credit on agricultural output:

empirical evidence from Pakistan. Sarhad Journal of Agriculture 34 (3): 640-648.

Aksoy, M. A. (2012). African agricultural reforms: The role of consensus and institutions: The

World Bank.

Anseeuw, W., T. Kapuya, and D. Saruchera. (2011). Draft Zimbabwe Agriculture

Reconstruction: Present state, on-going Projects and Prospects for reinvestment. Study

done for AFD and DBSA. CIRAD, University of Pretoria.

Becker, G. S. (2017). Economic theory: Routledge.

Begum, M., F. Islam, and S. Kamruzzaman. (2002). M., Kabir, MJ and Shiblee, SMA; Supply

Response of Wheat in Bangladesh: An Application of Partial Adjustment Model.

Pakistan Journal of Biological Sciences 5 (2): 225-229.

Bhatti, N., A. A. Shah, N. Shah, F. M. Shaikih, and K. Shafiq. (2011). Supply Response

Analysis of Pakistani Wheat Growers. International Journal of Business and

Management 6 (4): 64.

Chabane, N. (2002). An evaluation of the influences on price and production in the maize

market following liberalisation. Paper read at TIPS Forum.

Chawarika, A., J. Mutambara, and T. Chamboko. (2017). Competitiveness of wheat production

in Zimbabwe. African Journal of Science, Technology, Innovation and Development 9

(3): 263-268. http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/20421338.2017.1322349.

Chingono, H. (2010). Zimbabwe sanctions: An analysis of the Lingo guiding the perceptions

of the sanctioners and the sanctionees. African Journal of Political Science and

International Relations 4 (2): 066-074.

Chinyoka, U. (2013). Analysis of socio-economic factors affecting wheat production in

Zimbabwe: a case of Nyabira, Zvimba district.

Cowling, K., D. Metcalf, and A. Rayner. (2013). Resource structure of agriculture: An

economic analysis: Elsevier.

Dasgupta, D., R. Dubey, and R. Sathish. (2011). Domestic Wheat Price Formation and Food

Inflation in India.

David, B. (2013). Acreage response of rice in Côte D’ivoire: Macro-level response and some

policy implications. International Journal of Agricultural Policy and Research 1 (9):

288-297.

38

Doraszelski, U., and J. Jaumandreu. (2018). Measuring the bias of technological change.

Journal of Political Economy 126 (3): 1027-1084.

Drabik, D., and J. Peerlings. (2018). Economics of Agribusiness [Reader]. Wageningen

Uninversity.

Dzvimbo, M., M. Monga, and T. M. Mashizha. (2017). The link between rural institutions and

rural development: Reflections on smallholder farmers and donors in Zimbabwe.

Journal of Humanities and Social Science 22 (6): 46-53.

Firoozi, A. A., A. A. Firoozi, and M. S. Baghini. (2016). A Review of Clayey Soils. Asian

Journal of Applied Sciences (ISSN: 2321–0893) 4 (06).

Gosalamang, D., A. Belete, J. Hlongwane, and M. Masuku. (2012). Supply response of beef

farmers in Botswana: A Nerlovian partial adjustment model approach. African Journal

of Agricultural Research 7 (31): 4383-4389.

Hove, L., N. Mashingaidze, S. Twomlow, P. Nyathi, M. Moyo, W. Mupangwa, and E.

Masvaya. (2008). Micro Doses, Mega Benefits Promoting Fertilizer Use in Semi-Arid

Zimbabwe. International Crops Research Institute for the Semi-Arid Tropics.

Huang, H., and M. Khanna. (2010). An econometric analysis of US crop yield and cropland

acreage: implications for the impact of climate change. Paper read at AAEA annual

meeting, Denver, Colorado.

Huq, A. A., F. M. Arshad, and G. N. Islam. (2013). Supply response of wheat in Bangladesh:

Cointegration and vector error correction analysis. African Journal of Agricultural

Research 8 (44): 5440-5446.

Index Mundi, (2018), Zimbabwe wheat production by year. Retrieved from

https://www.indexmundi.com/agriculture/?country=zw&commodity=wheat&graph=pr

oduction

Juana, J. S., and R. E. Mabugu. (2005). Assessment of small-holder agriculture's contribution

to the economy of Zimbabwe: A social accounting matrix multiplier analysis. Agrekon

44 (3): 344-362.

Kapuya, T., D. Saruchera, A. Jongwe, T. Mucheri, K. Mujeyi, L. Ndobongo, and F. Meyer.

(2010). The grain industry value chain in Zimbabwe. Unpublished draft prepared for

the Food and Agricultural Organization (FAO). www. fao.

org/fileadmin/templates/est/AAACP/eastafrica/UnvPretoria_GrainChainZimbabwe_2

010_1_. pdf.

39

Ketema, M., and B. Kassa. (2016). Impact of Technology on Smallholder Wheat Production in

Bale Highlands of Ethiopia: Application of Output Decomposition Model. Turkish

Journal of Agriculture-Food Science and Technology 4 (6): 446-454.

Key, N., E. Sadoulet, and A. D. Janvry. (2000). Transactions costs and agricultural household

supply response. American journal of agricultural economics 82 (2): 245-259.

Lansink, A. O., and S. E. Stefanou. (1997). Asymmetric adjustment of dynamic factors at the

firm level. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 79 (4): 1340-1351.

Leaver, R. (2004). Measuring the supply response function of tobacco in Zimbabwe.

Lyons, T., and G. M. Khadiagala. (2010). Conflict management and African politics: ripeness,

bargaining, and mediation: Routledge.

Maddala, G. S.,(2001) Introduction to econometrics. John Willey and Sons Inc.

Maguranyanga, B., and S. Moyo. (2006). Land Tenure in Post FTLRP Zimbabwe: Key Strategic

Policy Development Issues: African Institute for Agrarian Studies Harare.

Mahofa, G. (2007). Economic Analysis of Factors Affecting Cotton Production In Zimbabwe.

Collaborative Masters Program in Agricultural and Applied Economics.

Maiyaki, A. A. (2010). Zimbabwes agricultural industry. African Journal of Business

Management 4 (19): 4159-4166.

Makurira, H. and Viriri, N. (2017). Water permit systems, policy reforms and implications for

equity in Zimbabwe [Report]. Retrieved from http://africa.iwmi.cgiar.org/wp-

content/uploads/sites/2/2017/04/Water-Permitting-Zimbabwe

Mann, M. L., and J. M. Warner. (2017). Ethiopian wheat yield and yield gap estimation: a

spatially explicit small area integrated data approach. Field crops research 201: 60-74.

Marufu, L. (2017 November 30). Command wheat could save country $100 million. The Herald

press. Retrieved from https://www.herald.co.zw/command-wheat-could-save-country-100m/

Matin, M., and S. Alam. (2004). Demand, supply estimation and projection of wheat situation

in Bangladesh. Bangladesh J. Agric. Econ 27 (2): 25-44.

Mlambo, A. S. (2014). A history of Zimbabwe: Cambridge University Press.

Mlambo, K., and N. Zitsanza. (1997). Economies of Scale, Capacity Utilisation and

Productivity Measurement in Zimbabwean Commercial Agriculture. African

Development Review 9 (2): 15-32.

Mohanty, S., S. K. Nayak, B. Kaith, and S. Kalia. (2015). Polymer nanocomposites based on

inorganic and organic nanomaterials: John Wiley & Sons.

Montgomery, J., and F. O’Sullivan. (2017). Spatial variability of tight oil well productivity and

the impact of technology. Applied Energy 195: 344-355.

40

Morris, M. L. (1988). Comparative advantage and policy incentives for wheat production in

Zimbabwe.

Moyo, S. (2011). Three decades of agrarian reform in Zimbabwe. Journal of Peasant Studies

38 (3): 493-531.

Mpofu, R. T. (2015). Dollarization and economic development in Zimbabwe: An interrupted

time-series analysis. Risk Governance & Control: Financial Markets & Institutions 5

(4): 38-48.

Mushunje, A., and A. Belete. (2001). Efficiency of Zimbabwean small scale communal farmers.

Agrekon 40 (3): 344-360.

Mutambara, J. and Zvinavashe, A. (2012). Wheat value chain and business environmental

factors in Zimabwe. University of Zimbabwe.

Mutambara, J., A. Zvinavashe, and E. Mwakiwa. (2013). A critical review of the wheat industry

in Zimbabwe. Global Journal of Biology, Agriculture and Health Sciences, GJBAHS 2:

23-33.

Mythili, G. (2012). Acreage and yield response for major crops in the pre-and post-reform

periods in India: A dynamic panel data approach.

Negassa, A., B. Shiferaw, J. Koo, K. Sonder, M. Smale, H. Braun, S. Gbegbelegbe. (2013). The

potential for wheat production in Africa: analysis of biophysical suitability and

economic profitability.

Nyamangara, J., L. Mugwira, and S. Mpofu. (2000). Soil fertility status in the communal areas

of Zimbabwe in relation to sustainable crop production. Journal of Sustainable

Agriculture 16 (2): 15-29.

Ogundari, K. (2018). Maize supply response to price and nonprice determinants in Nigeria:

bounds testing approach. International Transactions in Operational Research 25 (5):

1537-1551.

Ozkan, B., R. F. Ceylan, and H. Kizilay. (2011). Supply response for wheat in Turkey: A vector

error correction approach. New Medit 3: 34-38.

Richardson, C. J. (2005). The loss of property rights and the collapse of Zimbabwe. Cato J. 25:

541.

Rukuni, M. (1994). "Impact of smallholder irrigation in Zimbabwe." In.: Faculty of Agriculture,

University of Zimbabwe (UZ).

Rukuni, M. (2006). Revisiting Zimbabwe’s agricultural revolution. Zimbabwe’s Agricultural

Revolution Revisited, Harare, Zimbabwe: University of Zimbabwe Publications.

41

Rukuni, M., P. Tawonezvi, C. Eicher, M. Munyuki-Hungwe, and P. Matondi. (2006).

Zimbabwe’s agricultural revolution revisited. University of Zimbabwe Publications,

Harare: 119-140.

Scoones, I., N. Marongwe, B. Mavedzenge, F. Murimbarimba, J. Mahenehene, and C. Sukume.

(2011). Zimbabwe's land reform: challenging the myths. Journal of Peasant Studies 38

(5): 967-993.

Shoko, R., P. Chaminuka, and A. Belete. (2016). Estimating the supply response of maize in

South Africa: a Nerlovian partial adjustment model approach. Agrekon 55 (3): 237-253.

Toringepi, G. (2016). The contribution of smallholder agriculture production to food security

in rural Zimbabwe: a case study of Masvingo Province, University of Fort Hare.

USDA. (2009). Zimbabwe Gain Report. Retrieved from

https://ipad.fas.usda.gov/highlights/2009/06/zimbabwe/

Utuk, I. (2014). Aggregate Agricultural Output Supply Response in Akwa Ibom State of

Nigeria: An Application of the Nerlovian Adjustment Model. Journal of Agriculture

and Veterinary Science 7 (9): 22-33.

Waeterloos, E., and B. Rutherford. (2004). Land reform in Zimbabwe: challenges and

opportunities for poverty reduction among commercial farm workers. World

Development 32 (3): 537-553.

Yu, B., F. Liu, and L. You. (2011). Dynamic agricultural supply response under economic

transformation: a case study of Henan, China. American Journal of Agricultural

Economics 94 (2): 370-376.

Yunus, M. (1993). Farmers' Response to Price in Bangladesh. The Bangladesh Development

Studies 21 (3): 101-109.

World Bank. (2017). Zimbabwe Economic Update, June 2017 : The State in the Economy.

https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/27474 License: CC BY 3.0 IGO.”

ZAIP. (2017). A comprehensive framework for the development of Zimbabwe agriculture

sector.

ZINWA. (2014). Understanding the water permit and water agreement systems in Zimbabwe.

Retrieved from https://www.zinwa.co.zw/understanding-the-water-permit-and-water-

agreement-systems-in-zimbabwe/

42

APPENDIX A:

Table A-1:Zimbabwe Wheat production, Consumption, Imports, Acreage, Yield /ha and

Exports

Market YearProduction (1000 MT) Consumption(1000MT) Imports(1000 MT) Acreage (1000HA) Yield MT/HA) Exports(1000MT)

1960 1 77 79 1 1 3

1961 1 83 85 1 1 3

1962 1 61 64 1 1 4

1963 2 81 83 1 2 4

1964 4 75 73 1 4 2

1965 4 85 85 2 2 4

1966 10 94 84 5 2 0

1967 15 82 67 5 3 0

1968 25 107 82 7 4 0

1969 40 90 58 12 3 0

1970 54 112 77 15 4 0

1971 89 124 55 23 4 0

1972 85 108 20 24 4 0

1973 86 130 65 22 4 0

1974 97 148 42 26 4 0

1975 126 143 12 32 4 0

1976 145 118 10 34 4 0

1977 173 127 0 45 4 1

1978 212 148 0 48 4 2

1979 161 172 0 37 4 8

1980 162 206 3 35 5 5

1981 201 224 17 43 5 0

1982 213 235 30 37 6 0

1983 124 240 71 23 5 0

1984 99 230 104 20 5 0

1985 205 228 86 42 5 0

1986 225 243 53 43 5 0

1987 215 260 75 40 5 0

1988 257 217 14 47 5 20

1989 284 284 8 50 6 0

1990 325 384 65 55 6 11

1991 259 380 0 46 6 0

1992 57 280 170 12 5 0

1993 275 280 33 47 6 3

1994 240 303 78 43 6 1

1995 67 186 157 18 4 88

1996 263 278 75 48 5 0

1997 250 383 133 52 5 0

1998 300 332 32 50 6 0

1999 324 336 12 57 6 0

2000 255 278 23 46 6 0

2001 325 338 13 45 7 0

2002 150 310 110 38 4 0

2003 90 260 170 30 3 0

2004 105 235 130 35 3 0

2005 120 245 125 35 3 0

2006 135 260 125 35 4 0

2007 135 260 125 45 3 0

2008 38 270 200 9 4 0

2009 12 275 250 4 3 0

2010 18 265 250 5 4 0

2011 23 261 250 12 2 0

2012 17 275 250 9 2 0

2013 25 285 250 10 2 0

2014 34 325 300 15 2 0

2015 20 300 280 10 2 0

2016 20 300 280 10 2 0

2017 20 300 280 10 2 0

2018 20 320 300 10 2 0

43

APPENDIX B:

Plots of the variables at levels, but in logarithms. The plots shows that all variables were non-

stationary at levels except for the lagged rainfall which was stationary (Figure B-III).

44

45

APPENDIX C

Soil status in Zimbabwe

By analysing Table I and Figure I, the country is dominated by soils of Order Kaolinitic. The

Order comprises Fersiallitic, Paraferrallitic and Orthoferrallitic soils. These soils are mainly

formed from granite rocks which is the parent material for the sandy soils. This implies that

sand to sandy loam soils mainly dominates the country (Hove et al., 2008). Sandy soils are

inherently infertile with low soil organic matter (SOM) and susceptible to leaching. The

kaolinite soils dominate in Natura region I, II, III, and IV. Kaolinite soils have low Cation

Exchange Capacity (CEC) (Mohanty et al., 2015). CEC refers to a soil chemical property which

acts as soil fertility indicator. It shows the ability of the soil to hold and supply plant nutrients.

Therefore, soils with high sand content have low CEC, implying that they supply less plant

nutrients (Firoozi et al., 2016).

The majority of the smallholder farmers are located in sandy soils and these farmers have

limited resources and limited agricultural expertise which hinders effective crop production in

the country (Nyamangara et al., 2000). As explained in chapter 2, wheat production is mainly

practiced in Mashonaland Central, Mashonaland East and Mashonaland West provinces, these

provinces fall in Natural region I,II and III mostly. But, these regions are dominated by sandy

to sandy loam soils with less organic content and susceptible to leaching (Hove et al., 2008).

Therefore, it is highly recommended to add organic and inorganic fertilisers to boost soil

fertility. Nitrogen (N) and phosphorus(P) are the nutrients identified to limit crop production in

Zimbabwe (Hove et al., 2008). Hence, to increase crop yields by smallholder farmers

appropriate amount of fertiliser or manure need to be applied.

Soil classification in Zimbabwe

Table 3:Soil classification in Zimbabwe

Order Description Group Typical soil

families

Agro

ecological

zone

dominated

AMORPHIC

Very little or no

horizon development

1. Lithosol-

very shallow

soils

2. Regosol-

deep and

extremely

low silt/clay

ratios

Derived

from mafic

rocks

Deep sands

derived

from

Kalahari

desert

Region IV

western and

Northern

parts

CALIMORPHIC Unleached soils with

large reserves of

weatherable minerals

3. Vertisols –

moderately

deep to deep

clay soils and

acidic

Derived

from basalt

and mafic

rocks

Region V

46

4. Siallitic –

shallow to

moderately

shallow clay

soils

Derived

from mafic

rocks

KAOLINITIC Moderately to strong

leached soils. Clay

fractions mainly

kaolinite together with

appreciable amounts

of free sesquioxides of

aluminium and iron.

5. Fersiallitic –

soils with

weatherable

minerals

6. Paraferrallit

ic – mainly

sand soils

7. Orthoferrall

itic – highly

porous and

truely

ferrallitic

soils

Formed on

granite

rocks

Region 1,

II,III and IV

NATRC Soils contains

significant amount of

exchangeable sodium

8. Sodic –

horizons in

which the

amount of

sodium is

more than 9

percent.

Soils with

excess salts.

Region V

Figure 3: Soil map of Zimbabwe

47

APPENDIX D

Water availability

Access to water is free only for basic use. Farmers who intend to use water from rivers and

dams for irrigation purposes (commercial use) are required to obtain water permits from the

Zimbabwe National Water Authority (ZINWA). Water permits help in safeguarding the

interests and allocations of permit holders. For example in times of water scarcity, farmers with

permits will be given priority to use water before new water users are taken. However, farmers

holding water permits are required to pay for the water use and this affect winter crop

production to a greater extent because most smallholder farmers are not able to pay for the water

bills for irrigation (ZINWA, 2014).

Figure 2 below shows the water catchment areas in Zimbabwe. ZINWA divided the country

into seven water catchment areas which includes; Gwayi, Mazoe, Mzingwane, Runde, Sanyati,

Save and Manyame. These are considered to be more effective accountability units for water

use. Each catchment area comprises of permanent rivers and dams which intend to supply water

to local farmers. The provinces where wheat production is mainly practiced are being water

supplied by Manyame, Mazoe, Sanyati, Save, and Runde (Figure 2).

Figure 4:Water catchment areas in Zimbabwe: (Makurira and Viriri, 2017)

48

APPENDIX E

Money supply

In 2009, Zimbabwe officially adopts the U.S. dollar as its currency. The introduction of the

U.S dollar shows a significant change in the stability of the economy (Mpofu, 2015). From

2009 to 2015 Zimbabwean economy started to normalise gradually. But, in the first quarter of

2016, cash shortages re-surfaced and the Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe introduced the bond notes

to solve the problem. Bond notes were given the same value as the U.S dollar. However, bond

notes were not legalised to be used outside Zimbabwe. The present situation implies that

Zimbabwe is trading with two types of currency; the foreign currency and the local currency.

The Government officials insisted that the two currency is at par, but, on the black market, they

have two different values. The foreign currency shortages worsened to the extent that it is only

found on the black market, suggesting hyper-inflation in the country. This causes prices of

inputs such as fertilizers, seed and agro-chemicals to rise as the currency loss value. Therefore,

this continue to hinder wheat production in the country.