xiv international economic history congress, helsinki … · xiv international economic history...

23
1 XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in the Eurasian Continuum Kayhan ORBAY University of Vienna Ottoman Central Administration and War Finance, Late Seventeenth Century The course of the 16 th and 17 th centuries, which is recently called the “transformation period” in the Ottoman historiography, was a crucial period of changes, economic crises and social turmoil. 1 The Ottoman fiscal system witnessed significant changes in the same period. The Ottoman finance department experienced structural reorganization, fiscal practices and the taxation system underwent several changes. 2 Some changes in the fiscal sphere were fundamental and long lasting whereas some financial measures were rather temporary and developed as relatively prompt respond to meet urgent fiscal needs. To mention a few of these changes during the 17 th century, the taxation burden laid on large masses of the population increased as some customary and extraordinary taxes were combined and regularly levied, as well as new taxes were assessed. Some methods supplying cash to the treasury for its immediate needs were applied more largely in tax collection. These changes and several other fiscal arrangements of the 17 th century such as debasements and tax reforms were mainly connected with the crucial matter of war finance. However, the central administration was in 1 It has been a commonly held argument in the contemporary historiography that the Ottoman Empire passed through a period of transformation, and experienced an economic and fiscal crisis, as well as social disturbances in the late sixteenth century and in the seventeenth century. For the general account of and major developments in this period see Halil ønalcÕk, “The Ottoman Decline and Its Effects Upon the Reaya”, in The Ottoman Empire: Conquest, Organization, and Economy, London, Variorum Reprints, 1978, XIII, 338-354; Idem, “Military and Fiscal Transformation in the Ottoman Empire, 1600-1700”, in Studies in Ottoman Social and Economic History, London, Variorum Reprints, 1985; Mustafa Akda÷, Türkiyenin øktisadi ve øçtimai Tarihi 2 (1453-1559), østanbul, Cem YayÕnevi, 1995. 2 ønalcÕk, “Military and Fiscal Transformation”; Ahmet Tabako÷lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken OsmanlÕ Maliyesi, østanbul, Dergah YayÕnlarÕ, 1985; Linda Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy; Tax Collection and Finance Administration in the Otoman Empire 1560-1660, Leiden, E.J. Brill, 1996; Idem, “Ottoman Fiscal Administration: Decline or Adaptation?”, The Journal of European Economic History, 26/1, Spring, 1997.

Upload: leliem

Post on 28-Jul-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

1

XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in the Eurasian Continuum

Kayhan ORBAY University of Vienna

Ottoman Central Administration and War Finance, Late Seventeenth Century

The course of the 16th and 17th centuries, which is recently called the “transformation

period” in the Ottoman historiography, was a crucial period of changes, economic crises and

social turmoil.1 The Ottoman fiscal system witnessed significant changes in the same period.

The Ottoman finance department experienced structural reorganization, fiscal practices and

the taxation system underwent several changes.2 Some changes in the fiscal sphere were

fundamental and long lasting whereas some financial measures were rather temporary and

developed as relatively prompt respond to meet urgent fiscal needs. To mention a few of these

changes during the 17th century, the taxation burden laid on large masses of the population

increased as some customary and extraordinary taxes were combined and regularly levied, as

well as new taxes were assessed. Some methods supplying cash to the treasury for its

immediate needs were applied more largely in tax collection. These changes and several other

fiscal arrangements of the 17th century such as debasements and tax reforms were mainly

connected with the crucial matter of war finance. However, the central administration was in

1 It has been a commonly held argument in the contemporary historiography that the Ottoman Empire passedthrough a period of transformation, and experienced an economic and fiscal crisis, as well as social disturbancesin the late sixteenth century and in the seventeenth century. For the general account of and major developmentsin this period see Halil nalc k, “The Ottoman Decline and Its Effects Upon the Reaya”, in The Ottoman Empire:Conquest, Organization, and Economy, London, Variorum Reprints, 1978, XIII, 338-354; Idem, “Military andFiscal Transformation in the Ottoman Empire, 1600-1700”, in Studies in Ottoman Social and Economic History,London, Variorum Reprints, 1985; Mustafa Akda , Türkiyenin ktisadi ve çtimai Tarihi 2 (1453-1559),stanbul, Cem Yay nevi, 1995.

2 nalc k, “Military and Fiscal Transformation”; Ahmet Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken OsmanlMaliyesi, stanbul, Dergah Yay nlar , 1985; Linda Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy; Tax Collection andFinance Administration in the Otoman Empire 1560-1660, Leiden, E.J. Brill, 1996; Idem, “Ottoman FiscalAdministration: Decline or Adaptation?”, The Journal of European Economic History, 26/1, Spring, 1997.

Page 2: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

2

desperate need of money under the pressure of growing military expenditures and compelled

to resort to some other tools for financing warfare as well.

The fiscal needs of the Empire and the following fiscal transformations were closely

related to the developments in the military field in the 16th and 17th centuries. Growing size of

the standing army in these centuries expanded the salary payments, and together with the long

wars on several fronts put an increasing pressure on the treasury. Increasing military

expenditures eventually led to large budget deficits thus asked for additional financial

measures. It is striking that beside the well-known and most-resorted measures to increase

revenues such as extra taxation and borrowing, the fisc looked at the resources held by the

charitable foundations (waqfs) for its finance, more precisely for war finance. Although many

waqfs were regularly supporting the central treasuries through transfers from their budget

surpluses, drawing large sums directly from the waqf revenues was a completely new option

for state finance which was indeed applied once or perhaps twice in the 17th century. This

particular case, which depicts the state treasury in desperate need for war finance and

supposes further implications for the waqf system is given a particular emphasis in the present

study.

Waqf Funds for the Financing of Wars after the Vienna Defeat

When the Ottoman central administration attempted to draw financial resources for its

warfare from the waqfs at the end of the 17th century, the glorious victories of the Empire had

already belonged to past days. For more than a century, the Empire had waged long and

exhaustive wars on several fronts against strong armies of Iran, Venice, the Habsburgs and

Poland. The military campaigns in the 17th century were not bringing large profits through

Page 3: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

3

territorial expansion as before, on the contrary they resulted in large budget deficits, and with

territorial losses at the end of the century, the central treasury lost revenue sources as well.

The waqfs, in particular the imperial waqfs the largest economic and social institutions

in the Ottoman Empire, were already contributing to the central treasury and hence to the

campaign budgets through regular deliveries from their budget surpluses. However, after the

Ottoman defeat at Vienna in 1683, the Ottoman Empire had to fight against the armies of the

Sacred Alliance of the Habsburgs, Venice and Poland in the following years. As the central

budget went into fiscal straits due to this costly warfare, it sought for more funding from the

foundations. In 1688, the Ottomans lost Belgrade, a large town in a highly strategic location

for maintaining sovereignty over the Balkans. The army was being prepared for the recovery

of Belgrade in spite of the drained treasury. In the year 1689, and then probably again in

1693-94, the central administration required the delivery of payments for six months’ salary

of the waqfs’ employees. The reason for this was that the treasury fell into difficulty due to

the military campaign.

“Military Revolution” in and against the Ottoman Army

The changes taking place in the Ottoman Empire’s fiscal administration and practices

during the 16th and 17th centuries were associated with the changes and needs in the military

sphere and all these changes were usually defined as “military and fiscal transformation” in

Ottoman historiography.3 The military transformation in the Ottoman Empire was stimulated

and forced by the contemporary military developments in the West. It has been widely

recognized in historiography that the European warfare experienced a “military revolution” in

3 nalc k, “Military and Fiscal Transformation”.

Page 4: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

4

the 16th and 17th centuries.4 The “military revolution” is defined –among others- with

reference to the increasing military effectiveness of the firearms and consequent changes in

army composition and in battle tactics accompanied by the spreading use of handguns and

field artillery. Engineering in new fortification designs called “trace italienne” was developed

against new threats of the battlefield with siege cannons. The growing size of the standing

armies is also argued as one of the fundamental developments in the “military revolution”

conception.

With regard to the military field, the “military revolution” is supposed to result in

Western military superiority over the Ottomans first halting their advance in Europe and then

overcoming them. In the fiscal sphere, the “military revolution” brought about the overall

increase in warfare budgets with the bigger standing armies demanding larger salary

payments, costly fortifications to build, and the increasing costs of logistics coming with the

procurement, maintenance and deployment of diversified ordnance, as well as with the

reforms in administrative apparatus to support the new warfare.

Mentioning briefly the military developments in the Ottoman Empire and its reaction to

the European “military revolution”, it seems that the number of soldiers in the central

Ottoman army had already begun to increase towards the end of the 16th century.5 In addition,

4 For the “military revolution” discussion in historiography see Clifford J. Rogers, “The Military Revolution inHistory and Historiography”, in The Military Revolution Debate, ed. Clifford J. Rogers, Westview Press, 1995,1-10. Also see Michael Roberts, “The Military Revolution, 1560-1660, in The Military Revolution Debate, ed.Clifford J. Rogers, Westview Press, 1995, 13-35; Geoffey Parker, The Military Revolution, Military Innovationand the Rise of the West, 1500-1800, Cambridge University Press, 1988; The term ‘revolution’ itself isdisputable as a term accurately defining the developments against the fact that changes and innovations givingway to military transformation and a new warfare took place in a process. The period which the “militaryrevolution” is ascribed to is also controversial, see Geoffrey Parker, “The ‘Military Revolution, 1560-1660’ – AMyth?”, in The Military Revolution Debate, ed. Clifford J. Rogers, Westview Press, 1995, 37-54; Jeremy Black,“A Military Revolution? A 1660-1792 Perspective”, in The Military Revolution Debate, ed. Clifford J. Rogers,Westview Press, 1995, 95-114.5 For the “military revolution” discussion in the context of Ottoman history, as well as for its military and fiscalconsequences see John F. Guilmartin, “The Military Revolution: Origins and First Tests Abroad, in The MilitaryRevolution Debate, ed. Clifford J. Rogers, Westview Press, 1995, 299-333; Rhoads Murphy, Ottoman Warfare,1500-1700, London, UCL Press, 1999; Jonathan Grant, “Rethinking the Ottoman ‘Decline’: MilitaryTechnology Diffusion in the Ottoman Empire, Fifteenth to Eighteenth Centuries”, Journal of World History,Vol. 10, No. 1, 1999; Colin Imber, The Ottoman Empire, Palgrave MacMillan, 2002; Gabor Agoston, Guns for

Page 5: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

5

the Ottoman army recruited mercenary troops equipped with firearms in the 17th century. In a

similar way to the developments in the Western armies, handguns diffused and field artillery

deployed on a large extent.6 Recent research reveals that the Ottoman army was not inferior to

its counterparts and even superior in some aspects. But it was the changing international

politics and balance of power that forced the Ottomans to engage long and multi-front wars.7

At the same time, the Ottoman Empire had to cope with the financial pressure of the increased

costs of new warfare. As the cost of warfare went up due both to the larger standing army and

the increasing ordnance and provisioning costs, and as the Empire engaged in long wars

fought on two fronts against Iran and the Habsburgs in the late 16th century, the central

treasury’s need for ready cash had increased.8

Fiscal Deterioration in the 17th Century

In addition to the rising military expenditures due to the frequent military campaigns

and long wars, during the 17th century, the size of the waged army further grew, almost

doubling the wage payments between the mid-16th and mid-17th centuries, and making the

salary payments for military personnel a considerable part of the central budget. This put an

the Sultan; Military Power and the Weapons Industry in the Ottoman Empire, Cambridge University Press,2005.6 Murphy, Ottoman Warfare; Virginia Aksan, “Ottoman War and Warfare 1453-1812”, in War in the EarlyModern World, ed. Jeremy Black, UCL Press, 1999, 147-175; Agoston, Guns for the Sultan. Also see HalilInalc k, “The Socio-Political Effects of the Diffusion of Fire-Arms in the Middle East”, in The Ottoman Empire:Conquest, Organization, and Economy, London, Variorum Reprints, 1978, XIV, 196-201; R. C. Jennings,“Firearms, Bandits, and Gun-Control: some evidence on Ottoman policy towards firearms in the possession ofreaya, from judicial records of Kayseri, 1600-1627”, Archivum Ottomanicum, VI, 1980, 339-358.7 Murphy, Ottoman Warfare; Agoston, Guns for the Sultan.8 Caroline Finkel, The Administration of Warfare: The Ottoman Military Campaigns in Hungary, 1593-1606,Wien, VWGÖ, 1988, Beihefte zur Wiener Zeitschrift für die Kunde des Morgenlandes; Caroline Finkel, “TheCost of Ottoman Warfare and Defence”, Byzantinische Forschungen, XVI, 1991, 91-103; Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy; Murphy, Ottoman Warfare; Agoston, Guns for the Sultan. In the same period, theOttoman naval fleet experienced an expansion. Logistics required large investment into production facilities,transportation means, organizational structure, storing etc. however, some researchers argue that firearmtechnology contributed marginally to the total cost of warfare. Instead, the size of the waged-army was the majordeterminant of the costs, I. A. A. Thompson, “Money, Money, and Yet More Money!” Finance, Fiscal-State, andthe Military Revolution: Spain 1500-1650”, in The Military Revolution Debate, ed. Clifford J. Rogers, WestviewPress, 1995, 273-298.

Page 6: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

6

additional pressure on the state budget. The army experienced another expansion between

1683 and 1699 increasing the salary payments further.9 In this period, the salary payments for

the military amounted to 50-60% of the central budget and even to 80% in the campaign

years.10

In the 1690s, together with warfare against the Sacred Alliance, the central treasury

experienced a series of severe budget deficits in the campaign years.11 The Outer Treasury

drew large sums frequently from the Inner Treasury, the private treasury of the Sultan himself

in these years.12 The budget deficit of the years 1687-88 and 1690-91 were particularly large

and many extraordinary financial arrangements coincided with the financial troubles of these

years. 13

As the Ottoman Empire experienced an inflationary period parallel to the European

“price revolution of the 16th century”, but especially following the debasement of 1585, the

prices, pushing up the costs of employing, equipping and provisioning an army had steeply

risen at the end of the 16th century.14 Although prices fluctuated up and down throughout most

of the 17th century, they were more than twice as high as before and tending to increase in the

last three decades of the century.15 The price risings of the late 16th century worsened the

budget balance as the inflation increased the expenditures while the revenues from taxation

were relatively rigid to keep pace with the price rises.

9 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 189.10 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 183-193, 209f.11 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi; Murphy, Ottoman Warfare.12 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 37.13 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 15f, 74-80.14 Ömer Lütfi Barkan, “The Price Revolution of the Sixteenth Century: A Turning Point in the Economic Historyof the Near East”, International Journal of Middle East Studies, 1975, 6, 3-28; Cf. Haim Gerber, “The MonetarySystem of the Ottoman Empire”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient, vol. XXV, Part III,1982, 308-324, and Holm Sundhaussen, “Die Preisrevolution im Osmanischen Reich wahrend der zweitenHalfte des 16. Jahrhunderts”, Südost-Forschungen, 1983, 42, 169-181; evket Pamuk, “The Price Revolution inthe Ottoman Empire Reconsidered”, International Journal of Middle East Studies, 33, 2001, 69-89; Idem,“Prices in the Ottoman Empire, 1469-1914”, International Journal of Middle East Studies, 36, 2004, 451-68.15 evket Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, New York, Cambridge University Press, 2000;Idem, Istanbul ve Di er Kentlerde 500 Y ll k Fiyatlar ve Ücretler, 1469-1998, Ankara, Devlet IstatistikEnstitüsü, 2000.

Page 7: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

7

Besides, large rebel armies were roaming through Anatolia plundering the villages and

even attacking towns in the late 16th and in the first half of the 17th century. The widespread

and large-scale revolts disrupted the revenue collection and despoiled the tax base, thus they

further exacerbated the fiscal balance.16 The uprisings were followed by depopulation and

then a population decline which is defined to the extent of “demographic catastrophe” by

some historians.17 The demographic decline accompanied by the stagnating rural and town

economy and by the commercial losses due to the changing international trade routes further

reduced the revenue sources of the central treasury.

In the military sphere, as a result of the aforementioned developments in military

technology, the timariots, namely the provincial cavalry troops using traditional arms

gradually lost their previous importance against the new military troops equipped with

firearms. The timar system was a prebendal system in which the timariots were awarded

certain tax revenues in return for military service. Therefore its gradual disappearance brought

about a change in revenue collection. The revenue sources in the timar system were allocated

according to the land surveying system (tahrîr). Even long before the timar system

disappeared, the land surveying ceased to be performed and was replaced by the “avâr z”

surveys in the late 16th century. The tax farming system (iltizâm) was applied extensively in

16 Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy. For the rebel movements and their effects on economy and societysee Ça atay Uluçay M., XVII. As rda Saruhan’da E kiyal k ve Halk Hareketleri, stanbul, Manisa HalkeviYay nlar ndan Say : XI, 1944; nalc k, “Military and Fiscal Transformation”; William J. Griswold, The GreatAnatolian Rebellion 1000-1020 / 1591-1611, Berlin, Klaus Schwarz, 1983; Karen Barkey, Bandits andBureaucrats, New York, Cornell University Press, 1994; Mustafa Akda , Türk Halk n Dirlik ve DüzenlikKavgas , Celali syanlar , stanbul, Cem Yay nevi, 1995.17 For the depopulation and population decline in Anatolia in the 17th century see Ronald C. Jennings, “UrbanPopulation in Anatolia in the Sixteenth Century: A Study of Kayseri, Karaman, Amasya, Trabzon, andErzurum”, International Journal of Middle East Studies, VII, 1976, 21-57; Bruce McGowan, Economic Life inthe Ottoman Europe; Taxation, Trade and the Struggle for Land, 1600-1800, Cambridge, Cambridge UniversityPress, 1981; Mehmet Öz, XV.-XVI. Yüzy llarda Canik Sanca , Ankara, Turk Tarih Kurumu, 1999; Oktay Özel,“Population Changes in Ottoman Anatolia During the 16th and 17th Centuries: The “Demographic Crisis”Reconsidered”, International Journal of Middle East Studies, 36, 2004, 181-205; Idem, “State, Banditry andEconomy: On the Financial Impact of the Celali Movement in Ottoman Anatolia”, in The Proceedings of theIXth Congress of Economic and Social History of Turkey, Dubrovnik 20-23 August 2001, Ankara, Türk TarihKurumu, forthcoming.

Page 8: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

8

tax collection to meet the state’s demand for ready cash in the 17th century.18 In this system,

the collection of state revenues was farmed out under a contract for a cash-sum. The life-time

renting system (mâlikâne), which supplied cash revenue to the state, was also applied first

from the last years of the 17th century onwards.19 With the introduction of new methods of tax

assessment and collection, and as will be seen later, along with the new impositions and

changing weights of various taxes in the central budget, the fiscal administration experienced

a reorganization. The finance department grew and some bureaus underwent an expansion and

diversification as well.20

Fiscal Measures to Increase Revenues

To review briefly, long and costly wars on several theaters in the late 16th and 17th

centuries and the rising military expenses to maintain a larger standing army brought about

fiscal difficulties which were exacerbated as the budget imbalance grew with the increasing

expenditures in the overall budget due to the inflationary period of the late 16th and late 17th

centuries. As the treasury began to experience constant fiscal straits and faced budget deficits,

the government was compelled to re-organize its financial system to find additional

revenues.21

In search for additional cash resources for the treasury, the Ottoman central

administration resorted to a variety of means ranging from coining copper money to the new

18 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi; Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy;nalc k, “Military and Fiscal Transformation”, pp. 322-327, 333f.

19 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi; nalc k, “The Ottoman Decline and Its Effects”,pp. 341, 349; idem, “Çiftliklerin Do u: Devlet, Toprak Sahipleri ve Kirac lar”, in Osmanl Toprak Mülkiyetive Ticari Tar m, eds. Ç. Keyder, F. Tabak, stanbul, Tarih Yurt Vakf , 1998, pp. 22-24; Akda , Türkiyeninktisadi ve çtimai Tarihi, pp. 294, 317; Bruce McGowan, “The Study of Land and Agriculture in the Ottoman

Provinces within the Context of an Expanding World Economy in the 17th and 18th Centuries”, InternationalJournal of Turkish Studies, 1981, vol. 2, no. 1, 57-63.20 Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy.21 Akda , Türkiyenin ktisadi ve çtimai Tarihi, pp. 281, 287; Halil nalc k, “The Ottoman State: Economy andSociety, 1300-1600”, in An Economic and Social History of the Ottoman Empire, 1300-1914, eds. Halil nalc kwith Donald Quataert, New York, Cambridge University Press, 1994, 11-409, p. 24.

Page 9: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

9

methods in tax collection that were mentioned above.22 The Ottoman Empire applied an

expansive monetary policy through debasements and coinage in the years of fiscal difficulty.

After a long period of monetary stability, the central government debased the akça (silver

coin) in the late 16th century in order to create additional income for the treasury.23 The

decades following this debasement are known as the period of fiscal and monetary instability

in Ottoman history.24 Although the debasements brought a relief to the treasury, their adverse

effects coming with the debasement-pushed inflation were not late to show up in the central

budget.

The large group of irregular taxes known as “avâr z” taxes paid in time of war was one

of the most important revenue sources of the central treasury. In the early 17th century, these

extraordinary impositions (avâr z-i dîvâniyye) and customary levies (tekâlîf-i ‘örfiyye) were

combined and they became an annual and a regular revenue item in the central budget.25 At

the same time, some extraordinary obligations that were traditionally being paid in kind were

now collected cash. In the late 17th century, the revenues coming from these taxes constituted

about 20% of the central budget.26

Beside the increasing taxation, the central administration sought for the widening of the

tax base to increase revenues.27 As mentioned before, the large-scale rebel movements and

22 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, pp. 279-82; Yavuz Cezar, Osmanl MaliyesindeBunal m ve De im Dönemi, Alan Yay nc k, 1986.23 Pamuk, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire.24 evket Pamuk, “The Monetary Crisis of the 17th Century”, in Histoire Economique et Sociale de L’EmpireOttoman et de la Turquie (1326-1960), Actes du sixieme congres international tenu a Aix-en-Provence, ed.Daniel Panzac, Paris, Peeters, 1995, 243-250; Idem, “In the Absence of Domestic Currency: Debased EuropeanCoinage in the Seventeenth-Century Ottoman Empire”, Journal of Economic History, vol. 57, 2, June 1997, 345-366; Idem, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire.25 Halil nalc k, “The Heyday and Decline of the Ottoman Empire”, in The Cambridge History of Islam, vol. 1,The Central Islamic Lands, eds. P. M. Holt et al., London, Cambridge University Press, 1970, p. 345; Akda ,Türkiyenin ktisadi ve çtimai Tarihi, p. 295; Idem, Celali syanlar , pp. 54-58, 79-80; Darling, Revenue-Raisingand Legitimacy; Idem, “Ottoman Fiscal Administration”, pp. 164, 168-172.26 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, pp. 156-164.27 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi; Cezar, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunal m; Darling,Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy.

Page 10: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

10

ensuing social turmoil in Anatolia caused mass peasant flights and renomadization.28 Peasants

migrating to the towns and other villages or turning to the nomadic life meant the loss of

taxable sources because the lands remained uncultivated and immigrants were not registered

for taxation. Therefore, after long and fierce struggles to oppress rebellions, the central

administration encouraged the peasant masses to return to their homes through granting tax

exemptions, and applied a policy of sedentarization of nomads.

The Late Seventeenth Century

The years following the Ottoman defeat in Vienna and offensive movements of the

Sacred Alliance in the late 17th century, provides us with some quite good examples for the

relationship between the military needs and fiscal policies. In this period, the central

administration carried out some substantial reforms in the taxation system but it also resorted

to some ad hoc measures.

During the financially hardest years of the central treasury in the last two decades of the

17th century, new silver mines were opened as well as some mines and mints that had been

closed for a long time due mainly to the influx of American silver were operated again.29

Moreover, precious objects were taken out from the Inner Treasury to be minted. The most

striking monetary policy of the treasury to meet its need for ready cash was the excessive

coinage of copper money which was also overvalued against the akça between 1688-91.30

28 Suraiya Faroqhi, “Rural Society in Anatolia and the Balkans during the Sixteenth Century, II”, Turcica, RevueD’Etudes Turques, tome XI, 1979, 103-153.29 For the closing down of the mints see Halil Sahillio lu, “The Role of International Monetary and MetalMovements in Ottoman Monetary History 1300-1750”, in Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and EarlyModern Worlds, ed. J. F. Richards, Durham, Carolina Academic Press, 1983, 269-304.30 Sahillio lu, “Ottoman Monetary History 1300-1750”; Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken OsmanlMaliyesi, pp. 276-282.

Page 11: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

11

Following this inflationist policy, the central administration tried to establish a new monetary

system based on the Ottoman “guru ”, a silver coin larger than the existing “akça”.31

The poll tax on non-Muslims (cizye) was another important source of income. The

method of assessment of this tax was reformed in 1690. It was diversified in three categories

in accordance with the taxpayers’ capacity which resulted in an enormous revenue increase,

about 240 million akça, for the treasury.32

In addition to the arrangements in already existing taxes and regularization of some

taxes, new ones called the “imdâd- seferiyye” and the “imdâd- hadariyye” were levied in

order to finance military expenses.33 The “imdâd-i seferiyye” was a wartime levy first

assessed in 1688 but regularized in the next century, and the “hadariyye” was basically the

same tax for peacetime that was levied in the first quarter of the 18th century.

The Ottoman central administration even demanded “cash substitute” called “bedel-i

timar” from the timariots who were originally from among the tax-exempt military class. It

was a tax on timar holders who did not go on campaign.34 Several other taxes associated with

military expenses were levied such as “kassabiye” which was a levy on the wealthy to

subsidize meat sales to Janissaries.

The central administration did not borrow from international banking or moneylenders,

however, central treasury drew funds through forced loans from state officials and the

wealthy.35 In addition, high-officials were requested to provide fully equipped troops in the

31 Pamuk, “The Monetary Crisis of the 17th Century”; Idem, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire.32 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, pp. 136-149, 276.33 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, pp. 266-69; Cezar, Osmanl MaliyesindeBunal m, pp. 54-64.34 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, pp. 272f; Finkel, The Administration of Warfare,p.255-5935 Finkel, The Administration of Warfare, p. 261f.

Page 12: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

12

1690s.36 In this period, confiscations increased in frequency and property of high-ranking

state officials was forfeit on their death.37

The central administration tried also to cut budget expenditures. In the 1690s, the central

administration performed a survey for the employees in state offices and achieved a

significant reduction in salary payments.38 As mentioned before, the years immediately

preceding the 1690s and the 90s as well were the financially worst war years. The central

treasury postponed the debt repayments and late salary payments till the end of military

campaigns in 1689-90.39 In 1686 and then in 1688, six month salaries of the class of

mütekâ‘ids the retired pensioners and of the du’âgûyân the prayers, who were being paid their

salaries from the customs revenues of Istanbul and its surroundings as well as from the tax

farm and poll-tax revenues, were detained by the central administration. The imperial decree

relevant to this arrangement explains the reason for detainment as an aid for the provisioning,

ordnance and salaries of the troops participating in the military campaign.40 Lastly, in 1689,

the central administration requested the financial contribution from the hundreds of waqfs

dispersed throughout the Empire.

Imperial Waqfs and Their Financial Contributions to the Central Treasuries

The waqf system occupied a significant place in economic order of the Ottoman Empire,

in particular the imperial waqfs called “evkâf- selâtîn”, which were established by the ruler

and his family, and the large waqfs of the high officials called “vüzerâ” and “agayân” waqfs

were the largest economic institutions holding vast agricultural lands and diverse revenue-

36 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 191.37 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi; Darling, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy.38 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 261f.39 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 263f, p. 263 note 11 also see notes 12 and 13there.40 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 271.

Page 13: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

13

yielding real estates.41 They performed various charitable services and functioned as an

instrument of poor-relief in the society.42 The imperial waqfs distributed food to the poor and

needy through public kitchens (‘imâret), provided free cure for the patients in their hospitals

(dârü’ ifâ, bîmârhâne), paid stipends to some sections in the society from their income

surpluses.43 The imperial waqfs employed a large number of employees in various offices.

The salary payments were usually the major expense items in the waqf budgets.44 Through the

salary payments to their employees and to the beneficiaries, the imperial waqfs undertook a

re-distributive function in the economy and society.45

The imperial waqfs were not completely independent in terms of their administration

and financial decision-making. The central administration was the ultimate authority

supervising their operations. The most effective tool for regular monitoring and control of the

waqfs was the annual account books submitted by the waqfs to the central offices.46

Many imperial waqfs together with hundreds of other waqfs were forwarding funds to the two

Holy Places of Mecca and Medina as stipulated in their endowment deeds. The collection and

delivery of these funds as well as other revenues devoted to the Holy Places was the

responsibility of two central offices, the Two Holy Places Accountancy (Haremenyü’ -

41 For the importance of the imperial waqfs in the Ottoman economy, see Ömer Lütfi Barkan, “Edirne veCivar ndaki Baz maret Tesislerinin Y ll k Muhasebe Bilançolar ”, Türk Tarih Belgeleri Dergisi, I/2, 1964, pp.236-237; Bahaeddin Yediy ld z, “XVIII. As r Türk Vak flar n ktisadi Boyutu”, Vak flar Dergisi, 18, 1984, 5-41; Haim Gerber, “The Waqf Institution in Early Ottoman Edirne”, Asian and African Studies, 17, 1983, 29-45.42 For the charitable aspect of the waqfs and the waqfs as poor-relief institutions see Oded Peri, “Waqf andOttoman Welfare Policy”, Journal of Economic and Social History of the Orient, XXXV, 1992, 167-186; AmySinger, Constructing Ottoman Beneficence, An Imperial Soup Kitchen in Jerusalem, State University of NewYork Press, 2002; Miriam Hoexter, “Charity, the Poor, and Distribution of Alms in Ottoman Algiers”, in Povertyand Charity in Middle Eastern Contexts, edi. M. Bonner et al., State University of New York Press, 2003.43 Miri Shefer, “Charity and Hospitality”, in Poverty and Charity in Middle Eastern Contexts, edi. M. Bonner etal., State University of New York Press, 2003, pp. 121-143. The retired members of the Ottoman “militaryclass”, some religious persons and widows were entitled to receive stipend from the waqfs.44 Ömer Lütfi Barkan, “ maret Sitelerinin Kurulu ve leyi Tarz na Ait Ara rmalar”, stanbul Üniversitesiktisat Fakültesi Mecmuas , 23/1-2, (1962-63), 239-296; Haim Gerber, Economy and Society in an Ottoman

City: Bursa, 1600-1700, Jerusalem, The Hebrew University, 1988.45 For the re-distributive function of the waqfs see Barkan, “Edirne ve Civar ndaki Baz maret Tesislerinin”, pp.235f, Inalc k, “The Ottoman State: Economy and Society”, p. 47. Also see Murat Çizakça, “Cash Waqfs ofBursa, 1555-1823”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient, 38,3, 1995, p. 351.46 During the 16th and 17th centuries, several central offices were charged with the supervision and inspection ofthe waqfs. These were the offices of Chief Black Eunuch (Dârü’s-sa‘âde A as ), Chief White Eunuch (Bâbü’s-sa‘âde A as ), eyhü’l-islâm Efendi, the Grand Vizierate (Sadr- ‘Alî), and some local judges were alsosupervising the waqfs as well.

Page 14: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

14

erifeyn Muhâsebesi) and the Two Holly Places Tax Farms (Haremenyü’ erifeyn

Mukâta‘as ). In the year 1691, the revenues held by these offices were 25 and 20 million akça

respectively, which formed 5% of the central budget.47 In the following year, these revenues

declined to 12 and 19 million akça respectively and provided about 3% of the budget income

in the 90s. The revenues accumulated in these offices were not supporting only the Holy

Places but also the Outer Treasury and its military expenditures.

In addition to the above mentioned waqf contributions, at the end of each accounting

year, some of the imperial waqfs forwarded large sums from their budget surpluses to the

treasury of the office of Chief Black Eunuch as seen in plenty of delivery records in the waqf

account books. An archival register records the aggregated figures for the financial

contributions (‘avâ’id) and the deliveries from budget surpluses (zevâ’id) of the waqfs to the

treasury of the Chief Black Eunuch between 1670 and 1679.48 In this register, the total

amount of the contributions from the waqfs was nearly four million akça in 1670 and it

amounted to more than 31 million akça for nine years. Another register compiled from the

reports for the revenue collections and expenditures submitted by the Chief Black Eunuch to

the Sultan shows that beside some other expenditure, the largest part of the treasury of Chief

Black Eunuch was transferred to the Inner Treasury.49 The same register provides the total

figures for the collections as contributions (‘avâ’id) and as surpluses (zevâ’id) from the waqfs

and records the sum that remained uncollected (bâkî) as well. According to this register, about

eight million akça were expected to be collected in 1640. The treasury delivered two and a

half million akça to the Inner Treasury from the mentioned sum, as well as the salaries of

some employees in the imperial dockyard, which were normally paid by the Outer Treasury,

were paid from the treasury of the Chief Black Eunuch.

47 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 104f.48 EV-HMH 236.49 MM 6040.

Page 15: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

15

Financing the Warfare Through the Waqfs

According to the available budget figures, the revenues of the central treasury were

about 700 million akça in the fiscal year of 1687-88. The expenditures exceeded the revenues

about 200 million akça in the same year. In the following fiscal year, the budget deficit rose to

247 million akça and the budget deficit occurred in every single year throughout the 1690s.50

Such large deficits called for extraordinary financial measures, and one of them was drawing

money from the revenues held by the waqfs.

It seems that the central administration first conducted surveys to find out the available

funds from the waqfs. Then, the imperial decrees were sent out to the provincial governors

and to the waqf administrators, as well as the revenue collectors were appointed. The receipts

and the remaining amounts from the requested waqf funds were recorded in the separate

registers through which the extent of the funds supplied by the waqfs can be partially seen. I

suggest that the financial contribution of the hundreds of waqfs –though the total sum is

unknown- amounted to considerable sums and therefore should be taken into account with

regard to both the relationship between the central treasury and the foundations and to the

waqfs’ role in financing warfare.

As far as I could know, Tabako lu has first mentioned the demand of the central

administration for the financial contribution from the waqfs. He dealt with this subject briefly

by using mainly the records in the registers of important affairs (mühimme defterleri) and

wrote that in 1689, about sixteen and a half million akça was collected from the waqfs of

sultans, viziers and of some other persons. He also noted that the central administration

50 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 14-16; Pamuk, A Monetary History of theOttoman Empire, p. 133.

Page 16: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

16

requested six months salaries from the waqfs in Istanbul, in Jerusalem and in Damascus in the

same year.51

As mentioned before, the annual account books of the large imperials waqfs and the

books of many waqfs under the authority of the Two Holy Places Accountancy have been

audited in central offices. It seems that based on the data in these accounts the central

administration wanted to know how much revenue could be drawn from the waqfs. An

archive register for instance, which was compiled in 1688 upon the imperial decree, contains

the main revenue and expenditure figures of all the imperial – including that of the high

officials- and several other waqfs that were under the authority of the Two Holy Places

Accountancy.52 The register first records the waqfs under the supervision of the grand

vizierate, then the waqfs belonging to the other offices follow. The register gives the annual

expected revenue and expenditure figures for each waqf. The total expenditures are singled

out as simply the expenses and the salary payments; in other words, only the salary payments

were stated precisely in recording expenditures. Lastly, based on these figures, the budget

surplus was estimated for each waqf. The register gives a particular emphasis recording of

these surpluses, certain parts of which were annually sent to the central treasuries. The salary

payments of the waqfs, which -as will be seen- will be requested a year later, were also given

a particular importance in the register. For instance, additional notes are written for each waqf

showing the monthly sum of salary payments while all the other records give only the annual

aggregated figures.

The importance given to the record of salary payments can be seen at the end of each

section in the book. After the waqfs under the supervision of the grand vizierate, the register

records the total sum of the expected waqf revenues as more than fifteen million akça. Then

the total amounts of the salaries and expenditures are recorded. The salary payments are,

51 Tabako lu, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, p. 271 note 34 and p. 272 note 35.52 MM 1876.

Page 17: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

17

however, recorded both on a monthly and annual basis. And lastly the expected amount of

budget surpluses is recorded which is more than three million akça. It is striking that only the

monthly sum of salaries and the total amount of waqf budget surpluses were recorded in red

ink, which implies that the registrar was specifically instructed to highlight these records.

The register also recorded the other waqfs whose supervision was under the authority of

the office of the eyhü’l-islâm, of the Chief White Eunuch and of judge of Istanbul. The total

expected revenues of the waqfs is given as more than fifty-three million akça. Almost half of

this sum, nearly twenty-four million akça is to be paid for the salaries.

In the remaining parts of the register, the waqfs located in the provinces of Anatolia and

Rumili (Ottoman Balkans) under the supervision of the office of the Chief Black Eunuch are

recorded in the same manner. At the end of the register, the sum of monthly salaries for the all

waqfs was written in red ink as 3.352.382 akça which means that the central administration

would draw nearly twenty million akça from the waqfs by demanding six months salaries.

The register in question preceded the central administration’s request for the waqf funds and it

is therefore an examination for estimating the available resources.53 Although the registers are

not available, the central government must have ordered the compilation of similar registers

for the waqfs in the other parts of the empire as the registers recording the collection of

salaries from such waqfs clearly imply.

After the total amount of revenue to draw from the waqfs had been estimated, the

imperial decrees were sent, ordering the actual collections in 1689. Few archival registers are

available today to reveal the whole process of financing warfare by the waqf funds. In a

register compiled for the collections from waqfs in the province of Tripoli, each waqf is

recorded with its six months salaries.54 According to the register, 73.209 akça was collected

from the waqfs in the town of Tripoli and 316.260 akça was collected from the waqfs in the

53 The register MM 4774 seems to be the same type of register showing the sums of salary payments for manywaqfs under the authority of “haremeynü’ erifeyn mukâta‘as ”.54 MM 1864.

Page 18: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

18

rest of the province. In another register, the waqfs in the Province of Damascus are recorded

each with its annual and six months salary levels which latter totals about two million akça.55

The contribution from the waqfs in the province of Karaman was about half a million akça

according to another register of the same type.56

Let me remind you that the central administration had ordered compilation of a register

in 1688 in order to be informed about the financial situation of the imperial, the viziers’ and

some other large waqfs under the authority of the Two Holy Places Accountancy, another

register probably dated 1689 was kept, in which the actual collections from these waqfs were

recorded.57 In this register, each waqf was recorded with its annual salary payments and then

the sum of salaries for six months was calculated. A certain part of this sum was removed

from the total sum for several reasons. For instance, some funds were allocated to the

distribution of meals, and some were needed for important waqf affairs or expenses

(mühimme), and the salaries of part of the personnel etc. were not requested and left to the

waqfs, and the rest was collected for the central treasury. The remaining sums, which could

not be collected, are also recorded. According to the register, more than eight million akça

was collected while about two million akça was removed from the initially planned sum, and

about 300.000 akça remained uncollected. The same register also recorded the waqfs whose

contributions were not delivered yet or more correctly their collection of requested funds was

not started at all. The total sum expected to collect from these waqfs was exceeding one

million akça. In addition, more than three million akça was received from the budget

surpluses of three imperial waqfs in Istanbul.

55 MM 1883.56 MM 5917. Another register MM 18518 was compiled for the district of Aleppo. In this register, not the actualcollections but the waqfs from which collection was not possible are recorded.57 MM 7042. The register of MM 14935 dated 1100/1689 is a small register of two pages. It contains the recordsof collections only from two waqfs under the supervision of the Two Holy Places Accountancy. A longexplanatory writing is also provided in the register which tells that recording of the annual sum of waqf salariesand the collection of six months’ equivalents was ordered by the central for the reason that the central treasuryfell into difficulty due to the military campaign.

Page 19: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

19

The central treasury followed the arrears (bakâyâ) in separate registers. Another register

dated 1690, for instance, records the arrears from the waqfs in the province of Karaman which

totals about half a million akça.58 It is likely that the central administration requested funds

from the waqfs for financing warfare again in 1105/1693-94 as several registers kept for the

waqfs in Istanbul and in Sivas imply.59

Concluding Remarks

In a process beginning from the late 16th century, in which the military needs of the

Empire and the financing of war occupied a particular place, the Ottoman fiscal system went

through changes and transformations and fell into a fiscal crisis. In the 17th century, in order

to increase revenues several wartime taxes were combined and assessed on a regular basis,

and new taxes were levied. To meet the treasury’s need for ready cash, new methods of tax

collection were applied. The last two decades of the 17th century were the time of multi-front

wars and were particularly difficult years of the central treasury. In this period, the central

administration introduced new taxes, attempted to coin copper money excessively, detained

the salary payments as well as resorted to some other financial measures which were

previously unheard of in the Ottoman financial system.

The waqfs were traditionally enjoying tax-exempt status, the central administration

could not intervene with this since the waqfs were made in accordance with the long-

established traditions and Islamic law. However, the central administration still sought a way

for drawing vast resources from these institutions. Some waqfs devoted certain parts of their

revenues to the Holy Places. The funds for this purpose were collected in the central treasury

and these were partly transferred to the expenditure items of the central treasury. At the same

time, several imperial waqfs were forwarding their income surpluses to the treasury of the

58 MM 1874.59 For Istanbul see MM 1881 and EV-HMH 811. For the province of Sivas see MM 3687. The register MM 5303for the province of Erzurum seems to be a similar register.

Page 20: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

20

Chief Black Eunuch. This treasury was also supporting both the Inner and Outer treasuries.

However, the central administration asked for more contribution from the waqfs directly for

the reason that these funds would support the army on campaign. The central administration

demanded the delivery of six months’ salaries of the waqf employees in 1689 and maybe in

1693-94. These contributions from the waqf salaries were imposed on the waqfs as a forced

loan as the central administration ordered the high officials to lend in the same period.

The money transfers from waqfs to the central treasury have profound implications for

the waqfs. The regular contributions of the waqfs through their budget surplus left very

limited resources for the waqfs better to perform their services and more importantly to make

any investment for additional revenue sources. Secondly, the waqfs, in particular the large

imperial waqfs, were redistributive institutions. Their salary and stipend payments, which

constituted half of the waqf budgets, functioned as one of the most effective tools for income

distribution. When the central authority requested the delivery of large funds normally to be

paid for salaries, it interfered directly with the redistributive function of the waqfs and re-

determined it according to its own priorities. In this case, it requested not only the waqf

sources but also the daily earnings of a large section, thereby directly affecting their daily life.

Thus, these financial contributions from the waqfs reveal the financial and social effects of the

warfare on the social institutions and society at large.

Archival Registers 60

MM 6040 dated 1639-40 MM 1876 dated 1100/1689 MM 1881 dated 1105/1693-94MM 4774 dated 1099/1688 MM 1883 dated 1100/1689 MM 3687 dated 1105/1693-94EV-HMH 236 dated 1091/1680 MM 5917 dated 1100/1689 MM 7042 dated 1105/1693-94MM 1864 dated 1100/1689 MM 14935 dated 1100/1689 EV-HMH 811 dated 1105/1693-94MM 1874 dated 1100/1689 MM 18518 dated 1100/1689 MM 5303 dated 1106/1694-95

60 All the registers are housed in the Prime Ministerial Ottoman Archive (Ba bakanl k Osmanl Ar ivleri) inIstanbul. MM is for the “Maliyeden Müdevver” Collection, EV-HMH is for the “Nezaret Öncesi Evkaf”Collection.

Page 21: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

21

References

Agoston Gabor, Guns for the Sultan; Military Power and the Weapons Industry in the Ottoman Empire,Cambridge University Press, 2005.

Akda Mustafa, Türkiyenin ktisadi ve çtimai Tarihi 2 (1453-1559), stanbul, Cem Yay nevi, 1995.

Akda Mustafa, Türk Halk n Dirlik ve Düzenlik Kavgas , Celali syanlar , stanbul, Cem Yay nevi, 1995.

Aksan Virginia, “Ottoman War and Warfare 1453-1812”, in War in the Early Modern World, ed. Jeremy Black,UCL Press, 1999, 147-175.

Barkan Ömer Lütfi, “ maret Sitelerinin Kurulu ve leyi Tarz na Ait Ara rmalar”, stanbul Üniversitesiktisat Fakültesi Mecmuas , 23/1-2, (1962-63), 239-296.

Barkan Ömer Lütfi, “Edirne ve Civar ndaki Baz maret Tesislerinin Y ll k Muhasebe Bilançolar ”, Türk TarihBelgeleri Dergisi, I/2, 1964, 235-377.

Barkan Ömer Lütfi, “The Price Revolution of the Sixteenth Century: A Turning Point in the Economic Historyof the Near East”, International Journal of Middle East Studies, 1975, 6, 3-28.

Barkey Karen, Bandits and Bureaucrats, New York, Cornell University Press, 1994.

Black Jeremy, “A Military Revolution? A 1660-1792 Perspective”, in The Military Revolution Debate, ed.Clifford J. Rogers, Westview Press, 1995, 95-114.

Cezar Yavuz, Osmanl Maliyesinde Bunal m ve De im Dönemi, Alan Yay nc k, 1986.

Çizakça Murat, “Cash Waqfs of Bursa, 1555-1823”, Journal of the Economic and Social History of the Orient,38,3, 1995, 314-354.

Darling Linda, Revenue-Raising and Legitimacy; Tax Collection and Finance Administration in the OttomanEmpire 1560-1660, Leiden, E.J. Brill, 1996.

Darling Linda, “Ottoman Fiscal Administration: Decline or Adaptation?”, The Journal of European EconomicHistory, 26/1, Spring, 1997.

Faroqhi Suraiya, “Rural Society in Anatolia and the Balkans during the Sixteenth Century, II”, Turcica, RevueD’Etudes Turques, tome XI, 1979, 103-153.

Finkel Caroline, The Administration of Warfare: The Ottoman Military Campaigns in Hungary, 1593-1606,Wien, VWGÖ, 1988, Beihefte zur Wiener Zeitschrift für die Kunde des Morgenlandes.

Finkel Caroline, “The Cost of Ottoman Warfare and Defence”, Byzantinische Forschungen, XVI, 1991, 91-103.

Gerber Haim, “The Monetary System of the Ottoman Empire”, Journal of the Economic and Social History ofthe Orient, vol. XXV, Part III, 1982, 308-324.

Gerber Haim, “The Waqf Institution in Early Ottoman Edirne”, Asian and African Studies, 17, 1983, 29-45.

Gerber Haim, Economy and Society in an Ottoman City: Bursa, 1600-1700, Jerusalem, The Hebrew University,1988.

McGowan Bruce, “The Study of Land and Agriculture in the Ottoman Provinces within the Context of anExpanding World Economy in the 17th and 18th Centuries”, International Journal of Turkish Studies, 1981, vol.2, no. 1, 57-63.

McGowan Bruce, Economic Life in the Ottoman Europe; Taxation, Trade and the Struggle for Land, 1600-1800,Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1981.

Page 22: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

22

Grant Jonathan, “Rethinking the Ottoman ‘Decline’: Military Technology Diffusion in the Ottoman Empire,Fifteenth to Eighteenth Centuries”, Journal of World History, Vol. 10, No. 1, 1999.

Griswold William J., The Great Anatolian Rebellion 1000-1020 / 1591-1611, Berlin, Klaus Schwarz, 1983.

Guilmartin John F., “The Military Revolution: Origins and First Tests Abroad, in The Military RevolutionDebate, ed. Clifford J. Rogers, Westview Press, 1995, 299-333.

Hoexter Miriam, “Charity, the Poor, and Distribution of Alms in Ottoman Algiers”, in Poverty and Charity inMiddle Eastern Contexts, edi. M. Bonner et al., State University of New York Press, 2003.

Imber Colin, The Ottoman Empire, Palgrave MacMillan, 2002.

nalc k Halil, “The Heyday and Decline of the Ottoman Empire”, in The Cambridge History of Islam, vol. 1, TheCentral Islamic Lands, eds. P. M. Holt et al., London, Cambridge University Press, 1970, 324-353.

nalc k Halil, “The Ottoman Decline and Its Effects Upon the Reaya”, in The Ottoman Empire: Conquest,Organization, and Economy, London, Variorum Reprints, 1978, XIII, 338-354.

nalc k Halil, “The Socio-Political Effects of the Diffusion of Fire-Arms in the Middle East”, in The OttomanEmpire: Conquest, Organization, and Economy, London, Variorum Reprints, 1978, XIV, 196-201.

nalc k Halil, “Military and Fiscal Transformation in the Ottoman Empire, 1600-1700”, in Studies in OttomanSocial and Economic History, London, Variorum Reprints, 1985, 283-337.

nalc k Halil, “The Ottoman State: Economy and Society, 1300-1600”, in An Economic and Social History of theOttoman Empire, 1300-1914, eds. Halil nalc k with Donald Quataert, New York, Cambridge University Press,1994, 11-409.

nalc k Halil, “Çiftliklerin Do u: Devlet, Toprak Sahipleri ve Kirac lar”, in Osmanl Toprak Mülkiyeti veTicari Tar m, eds. Ç. Keyder, F. Tabak, stanbul, Tarih Yurt Vakf , 1998, 17-35.

Jennings Ronald C., “Urban Population in Anatolia in the Sixteenth Century: A Study of Kayseri, Karaman,Amasya, Trabzon, and Erzurum”, International Journal of Middle East Studies, VII, 1976, 21-57.

Jennings R. C., “Firearms, Bandits, and Gun-Control: some evidence on Ottoman policy towards firearms in thepossession of reaya, from judicial records of Kayseri, 1600-1627”, Archivum Ottomanicum, VI, 1980, 339-358.

Murphy Rhoads, Ottoman Warfare, 1500-1700, London, UCL Press, 1999.

Öz Mehmet, XV.-XVI. Yüzy llarda Canik Sanca , Ankara, Turk Tarih Kurumu, 1999.

Özel Oktay, “Population Changes in Ottoman Anatolia During the 16th and 17th Centuries: The “DemographicCrisis” Reconsidered”, International Journal of Middle East Studies, 36, 2004, 181-205.

Özel Oktay, “State, Banditry and Economy: On the Financial Impact of the Celali Movement in OttomanAnatolia”, in The Proceedings of the IXth Congress of Economic and Social History of Turkey, Dubrovnik 20-23August 2001, Ankara, Türk Tarih Kurumu, forthcoming.

Pamuk evket, “The Monetary Crisis of the 17th Century”, in Histoire Economique et Sociale de L’EmpireOttoman et de la Turquie (1326-1960), Actes du sixieme congres international tenu a Aix-en-Provence, ed.Daniel Panzac, Paris, Peeters, 1995, 243-250.

Pamuk evket, “In the Absence of Domestic Currency: Debased European Coinage in the Seventeenth-CenturyOttoman Empire”, Journal of Economic History, vol. 57, 2, June 1997, 345-366.

Pamuk evket, A Monetary History of the Ottoman Empire, New York, Cambridge University Press, 2000.

Page 23: XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki … · XIV International Economic History Congress, Helsinki 2006 Session 106: State and Finance in the Early Modern Times in

23

Pamuk evket, Istanbul ve Di er Kentlerde 500 Y ll k Fiyatlar ve Ücretler, 1469-1998, Ankara, Devlet IstatistikEnstitüsü, 2000.

Pamuk evket, “The Price Revolution in the Ottoman Empire Reconsidered”, International Journal of MiddleEast Studies, 33, 2001, 69-89.

Pamuk evket, “Prices in the Ottoman Empire, 1469-1914”, International Journal of Middle East Studies, 36,2004, 451-68.

Parker Geoffey, The Military Revolution, Military Innovation and the Rise of the West, 1500-1800, CambridgeUniversity Press, 1988.

Parker Geoffrey, “The ‘Military Revolution, 1560-1660’ – A Myth?”, in The Military Revolution Debate, ed.Clifford J. Rogers, Westview Press, 1995, 37-54.

Peri Oded, “Waqf and Ottoman Welfare Policy”, Journal of Economic and Social History of the Orient, XXXV,1992, 167-186.

Roberts Michael, “The Military Revolution, 1560-1660, in The Military Revolution Debate, ed. Clifford J.Rogers, Westview Press, 1995, 13-35.

Rogers Clifford J., “The Military Revolution in History and Historiography”, in The Military Revolution Debate,ed. Clifford J. Rogers, Westview Press, 1995, 1-10.

Sahillio lu Halil, “The Role of International Monetary and Metal Movements in Ottoman Monetary History1300-1750”, in Precious Metals in the Later Medieval and Early Modern Worlds, ed. J. F. Richards, Durham,Carolina Academic Press, 1983, 269-304.

Shefer Miri, “Charity and Hospitality”, in Poverty and Charity in Middle Eastern Contexts, edi. M. Bonner etal., State University of New York Press, 2003, 121-143.

Singer Amy, Constructing Ottoman Beneficence, An Imperial Soup Kitchen in Jerusalem, State University ofNew York Press, 2002.

Sundhaussen Holm, “Die Preisrevolution im Osmanischen Reich wahrend der zweiten Halfte des 16.Jahrhunderts”, Südost-Forschungen, 1983, 42, 169-181.

Tabako lu Ahmet, Gerileme Dönemine Girerken Osmanl Maliyesi, stanbul, Dergah Yay nlar , 1985.

Thompson I. A. A., “Money, Money, and Yet More Money!” Finance, Fiscal-State, and the Military Revolution:Spain 1500-1650”, in The Military Revolution Debate, ed. Clifford J. Rogers, Westview Press, 1995, 273-298.

Uluçay Ça atay M., XVII. As rda Saruhan’da E kiyal k ve Halk Hareketleri, stanbul, Manisa HalkeviYay nlar ndan Say : XI, 1944.

Ünal Mehmet Ali, XVI. Yüzy lda Çemi gezek Sanca , Ankara, Türk Tarih Kurumu, 1999.

Yediy ld z Bahaeddin, “XVIII. As r Türk Vak flar n ktisadi Boyutu”, Vak flar Dergisi, 18, 1984, 5-41.