working paper series department of economics alfred … · department of economics alfred lerner...

39
Working Paper Series * Department of Economics Alfred Lerner College of Business & Economics University of Delaware Working Paper No. 2003-05 An Assessment of the Effectiveness of International Financial Intervention James L. Butkiewicz and Halit Yanikkaya March 2003 * http://www.be.udel.edu/economics/workingpaper.htm c 2003 by author(s). All rights reserved.

Upload: truongdiep

Post on 27-May-2018

218 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Working Paper Series∗

Department of Economics

Alfred Lerner College of Business & EconomicsUniversity of Delaware

Working Paper No. 2003-05

An Assessment of the Effectiveness of

International Financial Intervention†

James L. Butkiewicz and Halit Yanikkaya

March 2003

∗http://www.be.udel.edu/economics/workingpaper.htm† c© 2003 by author(s). All rights reserved.

AN ASSESSMENT OF THE EFFECTIVENESS OF INTERNATIONAL FINANCIAL INTERVENTION

James L. Butkiewicz

Department of Economics University of Delaware

Newark, DE 19716 [email protected]

Halit Yanikkaya

College of Business and Administrative Sciences Department of Economics

Celal Bayar University Manisa, Turkey 45030

[email protected]

JEL Classifications: F34, O40

Key Words: International lending, development aid, empirical growth model

Abstract

The two global international financial institutions, the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank, frequently, and often repeatedly, extend loans to developing nations. Recently, these loans have been blamed for generating adverse economic outcomes. An empirical growth model, which controls for the other determinants of growth, is used to assess the growth impact of Fund and Bank loan programs. The primary focus is on the heavily criticized IMF lending programs. Another unique feature of this study is the use of the value of lending programs rather that the number of programs. The estimates indicate that Bank lending stimulates growth in some cases, primarily by increasing public investment. Fund lending is either neutral or detrimental to growth. The channel for this effect is a negative impact of Fund lending on private investment.

1

I. Introduction

In recent years the lending practices of the International Monetary Fund (IMF or

Fund) and the International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (World Bank or

Bank) have been subjected to ever-increasing public scrutiny, and frequent criticism.

The IMF’s lending practices, in particular, are regularly criticized as “anti-growth” and

“anti-poor”. Indeed, IMF lending, especially in “crisis” situations, typically requires

domestic governments to restrain domestic demand. However, there is frequent

recidivism among the borrowing nations, and the IMF-imposed conditions may be

necessary to address the fundamental problems existent in recidivist nations.

World Bank lending has been less criticized and less studied than IMF lending.

As Kruger (1998) argues, the IMF frequently lends to countries in the midst of a crisis

when the borrowing nations suffer from external and/or internal imbalances. This is not

the case for World Bank lending, which is typically directed toward long-term

development projects. Thus, while the IMF is criticized as too harsh, the World Bank is

often criticized as too soft in its lending practices.

This paper presents the results of an investigation of the growth effects of both

IMF and World Bank lending, within a common empirical framework. A unique feature of

this study is an analysis of the impact of fundamental economic and political conditions

on the efficacy of IMF and World Bank lending programs. The next section discusses

the relevant literature. The model and data are presented in section III. The results are

presented in section IV, followed by a discussion and a concluding section.

II. Literature Review

The IMF was established as a financial institution. Its basic functions, as

specified in the first Article of Agreement, include promoting world trade, international

financial stability, and the macroeconomic stability and growth of member countries. In

2

order to achieve these objectives, the IMF focuses on its core responsibilities: monetary,

fiscal, and exchange rate policies, and their associated institutional and structural

frameworks1. The IMF performs its functions in three ways: surveillance, provision of

technical assistance to members, and lending in three modes (crisis prevention, balance

of payments adjustment, and poverty reduction).

The World Bank has always viewed its mission as developmental. Thus, the

Bank’s core mandate is to help countries reduce poverty, particularly by focusing on the

institutional, structural and social dimensions of development. Birdsall and Londono

(1997) argue that “financial gap” models motivated World Bank lending throughout the

1970s. In the 1980s, the operational work of Bank shifted to adjustment issues. And in

the 1990s, the Bank once again made its primary focus poverty reduction, with a “new”

strategy emphasizing the acceleration of economic growth, the provision of basic social

services to the poor, and the creation of social safety nets.

Although the division of labor between the IMF and the World Bank was clear

when these institutions were established, over time, considerable overlap has developed

as the IMF and the Bank have focused on assisting developing countries and transition

economies. After the collapse of the Bretton Woods System, and especially after the

1980s debt crisis, the overlap between roles of these International Financial Institutions

(IFIs) has increased considerably. The IMF began developmental assistance in 1986

with the creation of the Structural Adjustment Facility (SAF), which evolved into the

Enhanced Structural Adjustment Facility (ESAF), and more recently became the Poverty

Reduction and Growth Facility (PRGF). These facilities brought the IMF into what had

traditionally been the purview of the Bank. Recently, in a joint statement the IMF and the

World Bank (IMF and World Bank 2002, 2) announced “the purpose of our institutions is

1 See Krueger (1998) and Bordo and James (2000) for extensive review the of the IMF’s role in the past and present.

3

to help all our member countries develop their human potential and productive

resources, thereby building the foundations for sustainable economic growth.”

Many recent studies (James 1998, Feldstein 1998, Goldstein 2000, Bordo and

James 2000, International Financial Institution Advisory Committee 2000) strongly

criticize the IMF for straying from its core competence of macroeconomic and exchange

rate policies into a host of structural policy areas such as corporate governance, trade

policy, privatization, poverty reduction, and environmental management, areas in which

the Fund does not have necessary expertise and staff resources to make timely and

sound policy recommendations2. For example, Feldstein (1998, 20) argues “(T)he IMF’s

recent emphasis on imposing major structural and institutional reforms as opposed to

focusing on balance-of-payments adjustments will have adverse consequences in the

both the short term and the more distant future.”

As the rise of structural adjustment components of IMF lending encroaches on

the division of labor between the Fund and the Bank, a case has been made for merging

the two institutions. However, the Bretton Woods Commission (1994) rejected this

recommendation, citing their differing objectives. Both the Fund and the Bank recognize

the importance of the potential overlap, and state their intention of jointly increasing

cooperation (Fischer 1997, IMF and World Bank 2002, Mussa and Savastano, 2000).

Fischer (2000a) emphasizes the need for reforming the IMF by sharpening the focus of

its activities to macroeconomic policies and the accompanying structural areas:

monetary, fiscal, and exchange rate policies, and the banking and financial sectors.

However, Easterly (2001) emphasizes that in practice neither institution proceeds with

an adjustment loan unless the other is satisfied with progress in "its" area of

responsibility. For example, Feinberg (1988) reports that only 3 of 17 of the Bank’s

2 Some studies (such as, Goldstein 2000, Stewart and FitzGerald 1996, Thacker 1999) put the blame on the powerful members of IMF for the rise in the scope of IMF programs.

4

sector loans signed during fiscal years 1979-1985 were made to countries not engaged

in Fund programs.

The Fund primarily focuses on macroeconomic policies in developing countries

(including exchange rates, trade regimes, and financial markets), while the Bank takes a

long-term perspective, analyzing real variables and directing its focus toward increasing

supply-side efficiency and domestic investment. However, both Fund and Bank

programs have common characteristics, including currency devaluations and market

determined exchange rate adjustments, the adoption of anti-inflationary and demand

restraining measures, the restoration or construction of market mechanisms including

freeing controlled prices and interest rates, reducing trade barriers, and the privatization

of state enterprises.

Although IMF programs have many different objectives, certain characteristics of

Fund programs are linked to its mandate to confront external payments problems. This

is the so-called “three-pronged approach” (Knight and Santanella 1997, Mussa and

Savastano 2000, Krueger 2000). The first component of this approach involves securing

sustainable external financing. At the onset of a crisis, external financing for borrowing

countries frequently evaporates. The IMF assists countries suffering balance-of-

payments problems with short-term loans through its Stand-by Arrangements (SBA) and

medium-term loans through its Extended Fund Facility (EFF). Another common element

of Fund programs is the adoption of demand restraining measures consistent with

available financing. These first two measures comprise the macroeconomic policies

intended to restore sustainable balance between aggregate expenditure and income in

program country by tightening fiscal and monetary policies. The last component of IMF

programs requires structural reforms intended to promote growth and adjustment in the

medium and long term. These policies aim to reduce government related distortions and

5

structural problems resulting in an inefficient allocation of resources in the economy and

hindering growth3.

Another goal of both IMF and Bank programs is the mobilization of supporting

private capital flows4. As argued by Rodrik (1995), private capital flows follow

multilateral flows only if the private sector values the information provided by IFIs. Bird

(1996b) and Rowlands (1996) review previous studies analysing the “catalyst” role of

IMF lending and concluded that the catalytic effect of IMF lending is, at best, weak. Bird

(1996b, 489) actually concludes that “the Fund’s seal of approval does not seem to carry

a very high market value.” More importantly, Rodrik (1995) shows that multilateral

lending has actually followed the other sources of capital. While IMF loans to member

countries have followed commercial bank loans, non-IMF multilateral lending has

followed bilateral transfers. Rodrik and Bird eventually claim that to the extent that

multilateral lending follows private flows, a major concern is that the multilateral

institutions end up bailing out private creditors. Although IFIs have claimed the seniority

of their monies, any multilateral lending that helps governments’ service their debt is a

form of subsidy to private capitalists. However, upon further disaggregating IMF lending,

Rowlands (1996) finds that SBA and EFF loans do induce official lending to developing

countries while private lending is neutral. It is possible that SAF/ESAF lending may

actually discourage private lending.

During the 1970s and early 1980s, Fund programs were frequently criticized in

many studies (Bird 1996b, Bordo and James 2000, and Bird 2001) and by developing

countries as being too demand oriented and too short run, not paying enough attention

3 For an extensive overview of IMF structural programs, see Goldstein 2000. He (76) concludes “my reading of the record is that on structural policies the Fund has bitten off more -- in both scope and detail -- than either it or its member countries can chew.” 4 Bird (2001) evaluates counterarguments that make the theoretical basis for catalysis ambiguous. Moreover, Rodrik (1995) argues that the insistence of multilateral lenders that their claims be senior to private claims undercuts the signaling value of their exposure.

6

to economic growth and supply-side reforms. The IMF has responded to these critics by

substantially increasing the number of structural conditions in its programs since the late

1980s and developing long-term packages in which more attention given to growth and

development issues (Knight and Santanella 1997). At the same time, Bordo and James

(2000) argue that the IMF has responded to the fundamental changes in global

environment, including the breakdown of the par value system, the increased mobility of

capital, financial deregulation, and the collapse of Soviet bloc by expanding the scope

and detail of its activities. Goldstein (2000) reports a consensus in the literature

analyzing Fund structural policy conditionality. Over the past fifteen years, conditionality

in IMF programs has increased markedly, at an increasing rate. Furthermore, since the

mid-1980s, IMF as well as Bank programs include as an objective economic growth, and

recently “high-quality growth.” For example, in a number of speeches (1994, 2000)

former IMF Managing Director, Michel Camdessus emphasizes that the IMF’s primary

goal is not only growth but “high quality growth.” Note that even he characterized this

objective as “ambitious” but argues (1994, 2) “it is the only way that the world's economic

and social challenges can be met.”

Recent critics of the Fund argue that the rise in the scope of IMF programs more

likely reduces program effectiveness, further increasing criticism of the Fund. For

example, Mussa and Savastano (2000) claim that the objectives of high output growth

and alleviating poverty are not explicitly among the Fund’s core responsibilities. They

also point out that much of the criticism of the IMF might be due to a disjunction between

its core responsibilities and broader objectives such as a high rate of economic growth,

low inflation, and the alleviation of poverty. These latter goals are medium- to long-term

objectives. Furthermore, Goldstein (2000) claims that the Fund’s charter does not

provide a basis for a broad agenda aimed at high (quality) growth. He (2000, 77) argues

7

that the “IMF mission chiefs have considerable knowledge and experience in

macroeconomic and financial policies but not in structural policy areas beyond this core

competence. Efforts to include in Fund conditionality everything but the kitchen sink

under the a loosely defined agenda of pursuing ‘high quality’ growth have taken the

Fund too far from its comparative advantage and have elicited legitimate charges of

‘mission creep’.” Regarding the argument that the IMF should not be in the poverty

business; poverty is primarily the business of the World Bank and the regional banks,

Fischer (2000b, 4) replies that “the poorest members of the world community belong to

the IMF; they have macroeconomic problems; they have a right like every other member

to access the facilities of the IMF.”

The literature on IMF programs can be divided into two parts. One strand studies

the determinants of IMF lending5; while the other strand examines the effects of IMF

lending on borrowing countries. Since IMF programs involve a number of

macroeconomic objectives including lowering inflation; restoring balance of payments

equilibrium; attaining a certain level of international reserves; resumption or expansion of

private capital inflows, exports, and investment; and a sustained high rate of growth,

5 On the determinants of IMF lending, see Bird 1996a, Knight and Santanella 1997, Thacker 1999, Przeworski and Vreeland 2000, Barro and Lee, 2002. For example, Knight and Santanella (1997) find that countries with higher external debt, depreciated currencies, low rates of investment, lower levels of GDP growth and per capita GDP are more likely to seek the Fund’s support. At the same time, they find that policy measures to improve fiscal revenues, to reduce government expenditures, to tighten domestic credits, and to adjust the exchange rate are significant factors that increase the probability of Fund approval. Thacker (1999) and Barro and Lee (2002) focus on the political determinants of IMF lending and find that political variables are important determinants of IMF lending. At the same time, Przeworski and Vreeland (2000) conclude that none of the economic variables matter for the government’s decision to remain under agreement with the IMF. The only variables that have significant effects on the government’s decision to continue participation in an IMF agreement are the sum of past years under agreements for a country and number of other countries currently under IMF agreements. Regarding the decision of the Fund to retain countries under its programs, only the balance of payments has a significant effect. Note that a number of studies (Boone 1996, Burnside and Dollar 2000, and Alesina and Dollar 2000) investigating the determinants of official aid find that aid flows are, to a large extent, explained by political factors such as colonial links, alliances, strategic interests, etc., but the recipient’s economic policies and political institutions are less important.

8

there are a number of different criteria by which IMF programs can be judged. Mussa

and Savastano (2000) argue that since encouraging growth and reducing inflation are

not among the Fund’s core objectives, it might be unfair to evaluate these programs by

looking at their effects on growth and inflation. Moreover, as Fischer (1997)

emphasizes, when evaluating the effects of IMF programs, it is important to distinguish

two issues. The first is whether IMF programs are appropriate prescriptions to

encourage growth if implemented. The second question is whether the agreed-upon

program is implemented as designed.

As reviewed in Haque and Khan (1998), Bordo and Schwartz (2000), and Bird

(2001), most studies find that IMF lending improves the balance of payments and current

account. This finding is not surprising given the fact that the primary focus of the IMF is

to correct maladjustments in its member countries’ balance of payments without

resorting to measures destructive of national or international prosperity. However, the

reported effect of IMF lending on inflation is negative but weak. With regard to the

growth effects of these programs, the literature is far from consensus. Haque and Khan

(1998) find negative effects on growth over the short-run, probably due to the demand

restraining nature of IMF conditions, while over the long-run growth increases.

Alternatively, Bird (2001,1861) concludes that “Fund programs seem to have a negative

effect on investment and possibly economic growth, often do not enable countries to

graduate from a reliance on IMF resources, more often than not remain uncompleted,

and do not catalyze external finance from other sources.”

Empirical studies analyzing the effects of IMF programs have employed a variety

of methodologies. As discussed in many studies (Haque and Khan 1998, Goldstein

2000, Bird 2001, Barro and Lee 2002), some of these methodologies have important

shortcomings. “Before-after” comparisons are not reliable because they implicitly

9

assume no change occurs except for an IMF program between the two periods being

compared. Comparison of program outcomes to targets may not be useful because

there are pronounced problems with the implementation of IMF programs and program

targets may be set too ambitiously or not ambitiously enough. Simulations using

economic models can tell us something about the effect of Fund-type policies but not

about the effects of actual Fund programs. Comparisons of outcomes for program and

nonprogram countries suffer the limitation that the two groups of countries can differ

systematically in ways that matter for economic performance. Haque and Khan (1998)

conclude that studies using before-after and with-without approaches yield less

favorable results than later studies using the General Evaluation Estimator (GEE)

methodology and simulation techniques, and that more confidence can be placed in the

results produced by the recent studies. However, Dicks-Mireaux et al. (2000) claim that

there are considerable doubts about the validity of applications of the GEE that do not

rigorously test the underlying assumptions. Given the fact that the GEE framework has

many restrictive assumptions that are necessary to define the counterfactual and to

specify in a simple framework the main determinants of important endogenous

macroeconomic variables, a major shortcoming of most applications of the GEE is the

focus on the bottom line — the estimates of the effects of IMF support — with little or no

evaluation of the validity of the underlying model. At the same time, both Hutchison

(2001) and Barro and Lee (2002) argue that Heckman’s (1979) inverse Mills ratio (IMR)

approach does not adequately control for selection bias. Besides the methodological

problems discussed in previous literature, another possible limitation, resulting from the

short period of observation used in most of these studies, is the likelihood that the

reported results reflect business cycle effects rather than the growth effects of these

programs, or some combination of these two effects.

10

Goldstein and Montiel (1986) show that IMF programs have negative effects on

growth. Conway (1994) concludes that IMF programs have only favorable growth and

investment implications in the long run. Recent studies of the macroeconomic effects of

IMF lending often report adverse growth effects. A large number of studies (Barro 1998,

Stiglitz 2000, Bordo and Schwartz 2000, Przeworski and Vreeland 2000, Hutchison

2001, and Barro and Lee 2002) claim that IMF programs do more harm than good for the

recipient countries. Yet, there is still no consensus about the growth effects of IMF

lending. There are other studies reporting positive growth effects of IMF lending (Dicks-

Mireaux et al. 2000, Mercer-Blackman and Unigovskaya 2000). These conflicting results

may arise from several sources, including differences in the types of IMF programs that

are investigated; differences in the groups of countries that are investigated (e.g. poor

developing versus emerging market economies or transition economies); differences in

the methodologies that are employed; and, perhaps most importantly, controlling for

other determinants of economic growth.

Barro and Lee (2002) examine the growth effects of IMF lending using the

instrumental variables (IV) estimation technique. After controlling for a number of

determinants of growth, and the endogeneity of IMF lending, they find that IMF

stabilization programs (SBA and EFF) have a statistically significant negative effect on

growth in the subsequent five years but not on contemporaneous growth rates.

Similarly, Hutchison (2001) investigates the growth effects of IMF stabilization programs

using the GEE. He finds that participation in an IMF-program, regardless of whether a

currency or balance of payments crisis has recently occurred, “costs” about 0.6-0.8

percentage points of real GDP growth annually. Przeworski and Vreeland (2000)

estimate a growth model using all types of IMF programs. They divided the sample into

(IMF) program observations and non-program observations and also include the inverse

11

Mills ratio in their regressions to control for selection bias. They conclude that these

programs reduce growth while countries remain under the programs, and furthermore,

the programs do not return benefits that would compensate for the losses incurred once

countries leave the program. Bordo and James (2000), using all types of IMF programs,

conclude that turning to the IMF may be harmful to a country’s real economic

performance, once account is taken of the self-selection bias, and that this effect has

been amplified since the Mexican crisis. Finally, Easterly (2001), using both IMF and

Bank structural programs, finds no systematic effect of adjustment lending on growth.

Using the GEE methodology, Dicks-Mireaux et al. (2000) evaluate the effects of

IMF lending to low-income countries eligible for the IMF’s Enhanced Structural

Adjustment Facility (ESAF). They find significant, positive effects of IMF-support

programs on growth. However, they conclude that the diagnostic tests cast doubt on the

appropriateness of the restrictive assumptions underlying the GEE and, accordingly,

about the reliability of the results. This finding raises questions about whether there are

inherent problems estimating GEE models with panel data. At a minimum, it strongly

indicates that future applications of the GEE to other data sets need to incorporate

standard diagnostic tests to ascertain whether the GEE methodology is valid for the

sample under study. Similarly, Mercer-Blackman and Unigovskaya (2000) investigate

whether greater compliance with Fund structural policy conditionality is associated with

better growth performance. They find that after controlling for other factors, transition

economies that successfully implement Fund programs, measured as greater

compliance with performance criteria, have better records of sustained economic growth

(defined as three consecutive years of positive real GDP growth); in contrast, they could

find no significant relationship between compliance with Fund structural benchmarks and

economic growth.

12

Rodrik (1995) claims that multilateral lending is not expected to affect subsequent

growth directly. Instead, using actual flows of multilateral lending over the period 1970-

1990 and OLS, he investigates whether IFIs have had an informational advantage, due

to their close monitoring of government policies, in determining which countries have

superior growth potential. He finds that the estimated coefficient on lagged multilateral

lending is uniformly negative, and becomes significant in some versions of his

regressions. Disaggregating each category of lending further, he finds that the

coefficient on net lending by the World Bank is consistently positive. However, the

estimated effect of IMF lending is always negative.

A number of case studies that analyze individual country experiences with IMF

programs also report adverse effects from these programs. Zaki (2001) argues that

Egypt’s arrangements since 1991 have successfully met the program targets, but have

experienced less success meeting targeted growth rates. He thus concludes that the

experience of Egypt demonstrates that economic reforms and liberalization in the

absence of commensurate political and institutional reforms will not produce economic

growth and prosperity for the poor.

Similarly, Yeldan (2001) claims that Turkish authorities were clearly successful in

maintaining the 2000 Disinflation Program targets both in exchange rate administration

and monetary control, as well as attaining the fiscal targets. In this sense the outburst of

the November crisis (in 2000) -and the ultimate collapse of the program in February

2001– cannot be attributed to any divergence from the monetary targets. He claims that

the collapse of the Turkish program was the result of internal inconsistencies and errors

in design, and thus modest gains in disinflation were achieved at the expense of de-

stabilization of the Turkish economy, along with a worsening of its financial and external

balances.

13

Rodrik and Kaplan (2001) argue that the appropriate counterfactual for Malaysian

capital controls in 1998 is the performance exhibited by the other countries subsequent

to their resort to IMF assistance. Using the “time-shifted difference-in-differences

methodology“ they find that the Malaysian controls produced better results than the

alternative on almost all dimensions. On the real side, the economic recovery was faster,

and employment and real wages did not decline as much as in comparable countries.

On the financial side, the stock market did better, interest rates fell more, and inflation

was lower than the comparison group.

The present study focuses on the impact of IMF and Bank lending on real

economic growth. As in Rodrik (1995), actual flows of IMF and Bank lending to

developing countries are used rather than the existence and/or number of programs per

se. Given that multilateral lending has many different objectives, depending in large part

on the circumstances of the members, and that IMF and Bank programs differ in size

and in their degree of emphasis on structural adjustment, Truman (2001, 3) claims that

“a better variable to try to capture the impact of such programs would be the size of the

program in (SDRs or dollars) per capita rather than just the number of programs

approved by the IMF and World Bank Executive Boards.” Moreover, using actual values

of multilateral lending makes more sense because there is a high level of noncompletion

in IMF programs and also because both IMF and Bank programs may not be

implemented as designed even if all loans are disbursed. It is also important to note that

since the primary focus is to assess the growth effects of IMF and Bank lending

programs, examining the separate impact of SAF/ESAF lending makes sense because

these lending programs are more likely to have growth effects. The data includes all

categories of IMF and Bank lending for 1970-1997. IMF lending includes stand-bys,

extended arrangements, structural adjustment facilities, and enhanced structural

14

adjustment facilities (recently renamed Poverty Reduction and Growth Facilities). World

Bank adjustment lending includes structural adjustment loans, sectoral structural

adjustment loans, and structural adjustment credits.

III. Model and Data

An empirical growth model is used to investigate the relationship between

international financial intervention and long-run growth. In general form, this model can

be characterized as

( ))(;,, ttttyt ZhkyF? = , (1)

where ?y t is country y’s per capita growth rate in period t, yt is initial GDP per capita, kt is

the physical capital stock per person, and ht is initial human capital per person.

Telephone mainlines per worker and life expectancy rates serve as proxies for the stock

of physical and human capital, respectively. Although the initial GDP per capita level is

employed to estimate the rate of conditional convergence, it is possible to interpret this

variable as a proxy for the stock of capital for a country. The variable Z represents a

vector of control and environmental variables, the majority of which are determined by

the decisions of governments or individuals. These variables are the value of IMF and

World Bank credits as a percent of GDP, the Gastil index, fertility rates, trade intensity

ratios, inflation rates, government consumption, war deaths, and three regional

dummies.

While GDP growth is calculated using the national accounts data come from

Easterly and Lu (GDNGD)6, initial GDP per capita levels are from Penn-World Table

6 They maintain the “Global Development Network Growth Database” on the World Bank web site.

15

5.6.7 Data for telephone mainlines per employee, life expectancy rates, fertility rates,

and inflation rates are from Easterly and Lu. The value of IMF and World Bank credits

as a percent of GDP, trade openness, government consumption, and gross domestic

investment data are from the World Development Indicators 1999 CDROM (WDI 1999).

Data for the Gastil index, which is a simple average of political rights and civil liberties,

used to measure the level of democracy in a country, are from Freedom House

database. The data have been normalized from zero to one, with one denoting the

greatest degree of freedom. Data for war deaths (WAR) are from Easterly (1999a). Use

of IMF credit indicates “repurchase obligations to the IMF for all uses of IMF resources

(excluding those resulting from drawings on the reserve tranche). These obligations,

shown for the end of the year specified, comprise purchases outstanding under the

credit tranches, including enlarged access resources, and all special facilities (the buffer

stock, compensatory financing, extended fund, and oil facilities), trust fund loans, and

operations under the structural adjustment and enhanced structural adjustment

facilities”. International Bank for Reconstruction and Development (IBRD) loans and

International Development Association (IDA) credits are extended by the World Bank

Group. The IBRD lends at market rates. Credits from the IDA are at preferential rates.

Cross-country regressions are estimated for a panel of one hundred developing

countries8 for the sample period 1970 to 1999. The number of countries is actually

limited by the availability of data. The system is a five-equation system estimated using

the seemingly unrelated regression technique (SUR) and/or three stages least squares

(3SLS) as in Barro (1997)9. The dependent variables are the average growth rates of

7Nuxoll (1994) and Summers and Heston (1991) discuss the reasons why the Summers and Heston data should be used for initial income levels while World Bank data should be used for income growth rates. 8 The list of countries is available from the authors. 9 See Greene (1997) for a detailed discussion of these techniques.

16

real per capita GDP over five periods: 1975-1979, 1980-1984, 1985-1989, 1990-1994

and 1995-1999.10

IV. Results

The estimates of the basic growth model are reported in Table 1. The model is

estimated as a five-equation panel using the seemingly unrelated regression technique.

Other than the constant terms, all coefficients are constrained to have the same value in

each equation. The range of reported R-squares spans the high and low values for the

five equations. As is the practice in the literature, the impacts of IMF and Bank credits

are estimated separately.

As expected, the proxies for human and physical capital have insignificant,

positive effects on growth, while the initial level of real GDP per capita and fertility rates

have significant negative effects. The estimated rate of convergence is consistent with

that found in several other studies. The Gastil index has the expected positive effect,

but is insignificant. Trade as a percentage of GDP (a measure of openness) has a

significant positive, albeit small, effect on growth.

Inflation, government consumption, and war all depress growth. The area-

specific dummies indicate below average growth in all three areas, but the effects are

significant only for Sub-Saharan African and Latin American nations.

Equations 1 and 2 in Table 1 report the estimated effects of IMF lending (as a

percent of GDP). Equation 1 uses the contemporaneous value of IMF lending, and

equation 2 uses a five-year lagged value. In both estimates IMF lending has a small but

significant negative effect on real growth. Equations 3 and 4 are similar estimates for

World Bank lending. The impact of contemporaneous bank lending is also negative, but

10 Estimates of the model for decade intervals obtain similar results, available from the authors.

17

neither the contemporaneous nor lagged effect of bank lending is significant. For IMF

lending, a 1% increase in lending is estimated to reduce growth by approximately 0.1%

annually. For Bank lending, the impact is much smaller. A 1% increase in lending

reduces growth by 0.01% annually.

An alternative approach is to divide the sample by income level and by level of

democracy. The rationale for this approach is that there exists considerable evidence in

the aid literature suggesting that aid flows encourage growth only when operating in a

good-policy environment. Investigation of the data indicates that middle-income and

good-democracy countries have relatively good policy measures, such as more open

economies, lower budget deficits and lower inflation. The estimated effects of IMF and

World Bank lending segregating countries by income level and degree of democracy are

reported in Table 2.11 Following Burnside and Dollar (2000) the break for the level of

income is set at real GDP per capita of $1900 at both the beginning and end of the

sample. As the Gastil index is insignificant, an alternative approach is to break the

sample into countries above and below 0.5 on the Gastil scale. As shown in Table 2,

dividing the sample by income level or degree of democracy obtains similar effects for

IMF lending. In most cases, both current and lagged IMF lending coefficients indicate a

significant negative effect. Dividing the sample according to income levels and degree

of democracy obtains different implications for Bank lending. Now, the estimated

coefficient for lagged Bank lending to low-income developing countries is positive. The

impact of current Bank lending to good-democracy developing nations is significantly

negative, while all other estimated effects are insignificant.

Some studies report positive effects of Fund lending programs. The Fund’s

recent move into development lending may account for this finding. Table 2 also reports

11 The basic model is the same for all estimates. Only the effects of IMF and Bank lending are reported. Estimates of the entire model are available upon request.

18

the results of estimates that exclude 73 observations for 26 countries with SAF/ESAF

arrangements (data from Dicks-Mireaux et al. 2000) during the period 1986-1991.12 The

magnitude and significance of the estimated coefficients is unchanged in many cases.

In those cases where the estimates change, the magnitude of the negative growth effect

increases. This suggests that the SAF/ESAF programs have either less negative or

positive growth effects. These results may explain why many studies using IMF

stabilization program data obtain negative growth effects while studies using SAF/ESAF

program data obtain nonnegative growth effects of IMF lending. These results also

suggest that IFIs, especially the IMF, should direct their lending more toward long-term

financing, which likely has a more favorable effect on growth in developing countries.

Since the IMF lends often to countries in the midst of a crisis, it is possible that a

simultaneity problem exists for estimates of the effects of IMF lending, and possibly for

Bank lending as well. To test whether simultaneity affects the estimated results, one

alternative approach is to estimate the model using average lending over the five

previous years instead of contemporaneous values, as discussed above. While using

lagged values is not a perfect solution for this problem, this alternative estimation

technique is one way to investigate the simultaneity issue. The results reported in Tables

1 and 2 do not indicate that a simultaneity problem exists.

Another approach to correct for simultaneity is to estimate the model using an

instrumental variables technique. However, a major limitation with this approach is that it

is difficult to find good instruments that are correlated with the exogenous variables but

are not correlated with the error terms.

In order to find plausible instruments, IMF and Bank credits are regressed on a

number of variables commonly used in the literature as well as variables not previously

12 The recent change to the PRGF occurred after the end of the sample period used in this study.

19

used. Table 3 reports the estimated results for the determinants of IFI lending13. One

interesting result is that countries with a British legal system received more IMF and

Bank credits (statistically significant) relative to countries with a French legal system. A

possible explanation is that both institutions conduct their business in English. Another

possible explanation can be related to the experiences of former British and French

colonies. The institutional framework of the former colonies may affect their ability to

negotiate agreements with the IFIs. Years of secondary and higher education of the

female population are significantly and negatively (positively) related to the level of Bank

(IMF) credits. Significant, negative coefficients for lagged initial income per capita and

female education are consistent with idea that low-income countries are the primary

concern of the World Bank, and that these nations are the primary recipients of Bank

credits. Significant and positive coefficients for the Sub-Saharan African and Latin

American dummies indicate that the IFIs direct their lending toward these regions. A

significant coefficient for the dummy for lagged IMF lending programs implies that

recidivist nations frequently receive IMF credits, but the similar variable is not significant

in the Bank credits regression. The significant coefficient for lagged IMF credits in the

Bank credits equations indicates that Bank credits follow IMF credits, but the reverse is

not supported by the data. The estimated coefficients suggest that foreign investment

and IMF lending are substitutes, while domestic investment and Bank lending are

complements.

The variables in Table 3 as well as current or lagged values of the variables used

in Table 1 are used as instruments for three-stage least-squares estimates reported in

Table 4. The estimated coefficients for contemporaneous IMF and Bank lending are

reported along with the SUR estimates of the same coefficients for the sample of 263 or 13 Many other commonly used variables have been tried (such as the current account balance, GDP per capita growth, trade openness, political instability measures, external debt, inflation, government consumption) but none were statistically significant.

20

205 countries. The SUR and 3SLS estimates for both IMF and Bank lending are almost

identical. Because of data availability limitations, the SUR estimates in Table 4 are for a

sample of 263 countries, compared to 407 observations for the SUR estimates in Tables

1. The similarity of the estimated coefficients for lagged and contemporaneous values in

Tables 1 and 2, and the identical SUR and 3SLS coefficients in Table 4 indicate that

simultaneity is not a problem for this sample. These estimates imply that

contemporaneous IMF lending does reduce growth in borrowing nations.

The conventional methodology used to estimate empirical growth models

includes both SUR and 3SLS. Use of alternative estimation techniques obtains different

implications for IMF and World Bank lending. Estimates using first differences and fixed

effects models are reported in Table 5. In the first differences estimates, the dependent

variable is the growth rate of GDP from 1980 to 1984 minus that from 1975 to 1979, and

similarly for other periods. The independent variables are first differences of the

variables that appear in Table1. Fixed effects estimates using the panel data allow for

both country and time effects.

In the first-difference and fixed-effect estimates, the effect of IMF lending is

statistically insignificant, except for the case of (lagged) contemporaneous lending,

where the estimated coefficient indicates a significant and negative (positive) effect in

good democracy (middle-income) developing countries. The estimated coefficients for

World Bank lending now generally indicate positive, and frequently significant, effects on

growth. These results indicate that bank lending benefits poor-democracy and low-

income-developing countries.14

It is important to note that there are substantial discrepancies in the estimated

convergence rates between the SUR estimates and fixed effects estimations. While the

14 Again, similar results are obtained excluding nations with SAF/ESAF arrangements.

21

SUR estimates indicate 2 to 3 percent annual convergence rates, fixed effects

regressions imply a 5 percent annual converge rates. Barro (1997) claims that

elimination of the cross-sectional information in the fixed effects estimation might

exacerbate measurement error bias, which would lead to higher estimated convergence

coefficients.15

It is often argued that IMF programs require demand-restraining measures that

decease domestic investment rather than increase savings. To assess this claim, the

empirical growth model framework is used to estimate the effects of IMF and Bank

lending on aggregate, public, and private investment, for the complete sample, and by

the level of income and the level of democracy.

The estimates for aggregate investment ratios are reported in Table 6. In seven

of the ten reported cases for aggregate investment, IMF lending has a significant,

negative effect on domestic investment. The results suggest that IMF lending with or

without SAF/ESAF countries likely reduces growth through reduced aggregate

investment. When public and private investment ratios are used as the dependent

variable, the results for IMF lending, reported in Table 7, imply that current IMF lending

significantly reduces both public and private investment in low-income and poor-

democracy countries.

The results in Table 6 indicate that Bank lending to middle-income developing

nations has a significant effect on investment. A 1% increase in Bank lending increases

investment in these countries by 0.5% annually.16 When public and private investment

ratios are used as the dependent variable, the results for Bank lending, reported in Table

7, imply that lagged Bank lending significantly increases public investment in three of the 15 See Barro (1997) for a more complete discussion of the issue. 16 When countries with SAF/ESAF arrangements are eliminated from the sample, IMF lending has similar results. Without the SAF/ESAF observations, current and lagged Bank lending has a positive impact in good democracy nations. Otherwise, the estimates produce similar results.

22

four groups of countries. Surprisingly, Bank lending reduces private investment in low-

income countries but has a significant, positive effect on private investment in middle-

income countries. Overall, these results are consistent with the existing evidence even

though the estimates use actual flows of multilateral lending and a different methodology

(SUR) to assess the growth effects of IFI lending.

In sum, the implications of the reported results are that IMF and World Bank

lending have different effects on growth. IMF lending does not increase developing

nation growth rates, and appears to harm growth in low-income and poor-democracy

developing nations. Alternatively, World Bank lending appears to benefit low-income

developing nations, and increases public investment in all groups of nations.

V. Discussion

The negative impact of IMF lending on growth can be due to reverse causation.

However, the cases of statistically significant lagged coefficients for IMF lending and the

statistically significant 3SLS estimates do not support this idea. Instead these results

imply that IMF lending may retard growth in some instances. The estimated results for

Bank lending are more favorable. Estimates for samples divided according to countries’

income levels and democracy levels imply that Bank lending benefits low-income

developing nations. This finding is important because low-income developing countries

are intended to be the main focus of Bank aid.

The literature contains a number of possible explanations for the failure of IMF

lending programs. Easterly (1999b) shows that international financial institution lending

had been based on the “financing gap model.” Recently, it has been recognized that

funding often fails to attain the intended results unless borrowing nations adopt sound

policies and structural reforms. The formulation of the “Washington consensus” in the

mid-1990s focuses on the development of good institutions, transparency, and good

23

governance. Thus, the conditions attached to recent loans emphasize “good

governance” and “good institutions.”17 Goldstein (2000) claims that emerging nations

with stronger corporate governance were less affected by the recent Asian crisis.

Bordo and Schwartz (2000) argue that Fund crisis management in recent years

has created a moral hazard problem that exacerbates international capital flows. Fund

crisis lending through the early 1980s avoided closures but did not prevent major

investor losses. During more recent crises, commercial banks appear to have sustained

few losses. If Fund lending drains out to private lenders, these capital account reversals

will likely increase cyclical volatility (see Meltzer 2002).

Another aspect of the moral hazard problem is the reluctance or refusal of some

national governments to assume ownership of IMF and World Bank programs, and/or

failure to implement the reforms required by the lending agreement. Killick (1995),

Stewart and FitzGerald (1996), James (1998), Bordo and Schwartz (2000), Woods

(2000), and Krueger (2000) attribute at least some of the ineffectiveness of Fund and

Bank programs to the failure of national governments to implement the necessary

reforms. Bordo and Schwartz (2000) blame lack of ownership for the failure of some

nations to develop even with fifty years of IMF and World Bank support. The success of

the Turkish economy during the late 1980s and early 1990s, and the more recent

success of Egypt, both serve as examples where implementing the required conditions

(and sometimes going further) resulted in periods of rapid economic growth.

Extensive recidivism and quasi-permanent involvement of the IMF with low-

income developing nations remains a continuing problem (Bird 1996a and 2001,

Easterly 2001). Having multiple arrangements with both the IMF and the World Bank

proves to be the rule rather than the exception. These facts demonstrate another facet

17 Woods (2000) discusses the governance conditions attached to IMF and World Bank lending.

24

of the moral hazard problem. Many developing nations experience “stop-go” cycles.

IMF aid and conditions improve both external and internal balance. However,

governments respond to the improved economic situation with monetary and fiscal ease,

which eventually result in inflation and deterioration of the balance of payments,

necessitating another IMF loan.18

VI. Conclusion

The two major international financial institutions, the IMF and the World Bank, are

important sources of capital funds for developing economies. The IMF now provides

developmental as well as “crisis” and adjustment funding, while the World Bank focuses

on developmental loans. An important question is whether the lending programs of

these IFIs have a positive impact on the growth rates of developing economies. In

particular, frequent, strenuous criticism of IMF lending raises questions about the

efficacy of its loan programs. In this study, an empirical growth model is used to analyze

the growth effects of IMF and Bank lending.

Empirical analysis indicates that contemporaneous IMF lending negatively affects

growth, probably by reducing domestic investment. However, estimates of lagged

effects and estimates obtained using alternative techniques indicate no significant

impact of IMF lending. The sum of the evidence regarding IMF lending is ambiguous.

Bank lending does appear to help low-income emerging economies, primarily by

stimulating public investment.

Structural problems in borrowing nations and/or various moral hazard problems

may account for the apparent failure of IMF lending programs. However, Fund programs

may still be more about resolving crises than promoting growth (Goldstein 2000). Also,

18 Reasons why the IFIs continue to lend to recidivist nations include failure to recognize the importance of ownership, failure to understand the internal politics of borrowing nations, and political pressure from the industrial nations to continue supporting the recidivists.

25

as emphasized by Gavin and Rodrik (1995), Rodrik (1995), Krueger (1998), Bordo and

James (2000), and Fischer (2000b), Fund lending involves more than promoting growth.

These other roles include provision and analysis of statistical data, training, and policy

advice and technical assistance. Thus, overall evaluation of both Fund and Bank

lending programs weigh the benefits of the entirety of services provided against the

costs. Unfortunately, to date, stimulating economic growth is not a benefit of IMF

lending, while a more favorable conclusion can be drawn regarding World Bank lending

programs.

26

Table 1

Estimates of the Impact of IMF and World Bank Lending in a Growth Model

SUR Panel Growth Regressions for Developing CountriesTime Period: Five five-year periods, 1975 -1979 to 1995 -1999 Dependent Variable: Real GDP per capita growth ratesRegression No. 1 2 3 4Observations 407 406 407 406Initial GDP per capita -2.75** -2.40** -2.17* -1.61

(2.75) (2.35) (2.00) (1.52)Life Expectancy (lagged) 2.30 2.57 2.16 3.35

(0.56) (0.61) (0.49) (0.77)Telephone mainlines per employee 0.77 0.77 0.74 0.57

(1.24) (1.22) (1.13) (0.87)Gastil Index 0.95 0.91 0.92 0.76

(1.65) (1.55) (1.54) (1.26)Fertility Rates (lagged) -6.72** -6.48** -6.08** -6.57**

(4.17) (3.93) (3.57) (3.84)Trade (% of GDP) 0.018** 0.017** 0.016** 0.014**

(3.70) (3.56) (3.27) (2.92)Inflation Rates -0.0015** -0.0015** -0.0015** -0.0015**

(5.22) (5.16) (5.21) (5.22)Government Consumption -0.10** -0.11** -0.11** -0.10**

(3.63) (3.78) (3.62) (3.28)War Deaths -1.00* -0.89* -0.95* -0.92*

(2.14) (1.87) (1.95) (1.88)Sub-Saharan African Dummy -1.18* -1.20* -1.26* -1.24*

(2.27) (2.25) (2.28) (2.23)Latin American Dummy -2.00** -2.06** -2.11** -2.11**

(4.17) (4.22) (4.17) (4.14)East Asian Dummy -0.27 -0.19 -0.11 -0.10

(0.46) (0.31) (0.18) (0.16)IMF credits (% of GDP) -0.10**

(3.55)Lagged IMF credits -0.07*

(2.11)WB credits (% of GDP) -0.013

(0.82)Lagged WB credits 0.017

(0.96)R-square (low-high) .18 -.50 .15 -.51 .15 -.49 .15 -.49The system has 5 equations, where the dependent variables are the GDP per capita growthrate over each five-year period. Each equation has a different constant term.Other coefficients are restricted to be the same for all periods. t-statistics are in parentheses.** Significant at the 1 percent-level. * Significant at the 5 percent-level.

27

Table 2

Effects of IMF and Bank Lending by Country Type

SUR Panel Growth Regressions for Developing CountriesTime Period: Five five-year periods, 1975 -1979 to 1995 -1999 Dependent Variable: Real GDP per capita growth rates

Low-income developing coun. Middle-income developing coun.Observations 271 198* 136 136*IMF credits (% GDP) -0.10** -0.10** -0.14* -0.14*

(3.20) (2.72) (1.77) (1.77)Lagged IMF credits -0.09** -0.13** -0.03 -0.03

(2.38) (2.52) (0.39) (0.39)IBRD credits (%GDP) 0.005 0.006 -0.08 -0.08

(0.25) (0.24) (1.10) (1.10)Lagged IBRD credits 0.04* 0.03 -0.07 -0.07

(1.92) (1.08) (1.12) (1.12)

Poor-democracy developing coun. Good-democracy developing coun.Observations 237 179* 170 155*IMF credits (% GDP) -0.10** -0.10** -0.19** -0.29**

(2.58) (2.80) (3.97) (4.40)Lagged IMF credits -0.08* -0.10* -0.09* -0.17*

(1.72) (2.28) (1.79) (2.26)IBRD credits (%GDP) 0.008 -0.011 -0.13** -0.14**

(0.37) (0.41) (3.81) (2.96)Lagged IBRD credits 0.034 -0.002 -0.05 -0.08

(1.43) (0.07) (1.41) (1.52)The system has 5 equations, where the dependent variables are the GDP per capita growthrate over each five-year period. Each equation has a different constant term.Other coefficients are restricted to be the same for all periods. t-statistics are in parentheses.** Significant at the 1 percent-level. * Significant at the 5 percent-level.* These columns exclude observations for the countries that had SAF/ESAF arrangements at some time during the period considered.

28

Table 3

Determinants of IFI lending

SUR Panel IFI Regressions for Developing CountriesTime Period: Five five-year periods, 1975 -1979 to 1995 -1999 Dependent Variables: IMF credits or WB credits (as percent of GDP)

IMF Credits WB CreditsObservations 275 200Years of secondary&high schooling 0.69* Years of secondary&high schooling -2.09**in the female population (2.07) in the female population (3.46)Landlocked dummy -2.15** Landlocked dummy -1.79*

(4.09) (2.06)Real exchange rate index (lagged) 0.007** Real exchange rate index (lagged) 0.005*

(4.49) (2.05)Aid (% of GDP, lagged) 0.11** Aid (% of GDP, lagged) 0.40**

(4.11) (6.77)Sub-Saharan African Dummy 1.46** Sub-Saharan African Dummy 3.61**

(2.71) (4.19)Latin American Dummy 1.10* Latin American Dummy 2.85**

(2.09) (3.56)East Asian Dummy -0.87 East Asian Dummy 0.77

(1.36) (0.82)British legal system 1.83** French legal system -1.49*

(4.72) (2.24)Telephone mainlines per employee -1.08** Gross domestic inv. (%GDP, lagged) 0.09*

(2.51) (2.43)Foreign direct inv.(% of GDP, lagged) -0.18* Initial GDP per capita, (lagged) -3.21*

(2.24) (2.32)IMF program dummy (lagged) 1.13** Budget Surplus (% of GDP, lagged) -0.13*

(3.39) (2.25)IMF credits, lagged 0.49**

(4.67)Mining % of GDP -8.04*

(2.42)R-square .24 -.55 R-square .30 -.76The system has 5 equations, where the dependent variables are five-year averages of IMF or WB credits. Each equation has a different constant term.Other coefficients are restricted to be the same for all periods. t-statistics are in parentheses.** Significant at the 1 percent-level; * Significant at the 5 percent-level.Gross domestic investment data are from WDI 1999; data for female education are from Barro and Lee (2000); mining data are from Hall and Jones (1999); all the other data are from Easterly and Lu.

29

Table 4

3SLS Estimates of the Effect of IMF and Bank Lending

3SLS/SUR Panel Growth Regressions for Developing CountriesTime Period: Five five-year periods, 1975 -1979 to 1995 -1999 Dependent Variable: Real GDP per capita growth rates

# of obs # of obsSUR R2 3SLS R2

IMF credits (% GDP) -0.14** 263 -0.14** 263(2.79) .18 -.54 (2.45) .16 -.55

WB credits (%GDP) -0.04 205 -0.04 205(1.34) .25 -.74 (1.52) .26 -.74

The system has 5 equations, where the dependent variables are the GDP per capitagrowth rate over each five-year period. Each equation has a different constant term.Other coefficients are restricted to be the same for all periods. t-statistics are in parentheses.** Significant at the 1 percent-level; * Significant at the 5 percent-level.Use of 3SLS to estimate growth regressions reduces the country sample to 263 (or 205)observations from 407. The loss of observations precludes county-type estimates.

30

Table 5

Fixed Effect and First Difference Estimates of the Effects of IMF and Bank Lending

Panel Growth Regressions for Developing CountriesTime Period: First differences of five five-year periods/five periodsDependent Variable: Real GDP per capita growth rates

First # of obs Fixed # of obsDifferences(SUR) R2 Effects R2

IMF credits (% GDP) -0.03 321 -0.04 86(0.65) .13 -.44 (0.69) .60

Lagged IMF credits 0.003 320 0.03 86(0.06) .12 -.45 (0.66) .60

WB credits (%GDP) -0.003 321 0.02 86(0.13) .13 -.45 (0.93) .60

Lagged WB credits 0.03 320 0.05* 86(1.41) .13 -.44 (2.05) .60

Low-income Developing Countries Middle-income Developing CountriesRegression No. First Differences Fixed Effects First Differences Fixed EffectsObservations 213 58 108 28

IMF credits (% GDP) 0.01 -0.007 -0.06 -0.09(0.21) (0.12) (0.65) (0.82)

Lagged IMF credits -0.04 0.04 0.19* 0.12(0.63) (0.67) (1.70) (1.14)

WB credits (%GDP) 0.01 0.05* 0.12 0.13(0.46) (1.98) (1.08) (1.21)

Lagged WB credits 0.05* 0.09** 0.008 0.11(1.91) (2.91) (0.07) (0.99)

Poor-Democracy Developing Coun. Good-Democracy Developing Coun.Regression No. First Differences Fixed Effects First Differences Fixed EffectsObservations 187 50 134 36

IMF credits (% GDP) 0.07 0.04 -0.08 -0.12*(0.98) (0.57) (1.38) (1.82)

Lagged IMF credits 0.04 0.09 0.02 0.004(0.45) (1.24) (0.37) (0.07)

WB credits (%GDP) 0.03 0.06* -0.08* -0.08(0.94) (2.16) (1.82) (1.53)

Lagged WB credits 0.06* 0.09** 0.009 0.02(1.80) (2.76) (0.19) (0.44)

Other regressors include the variables reported in Table 1 excluding time-invarient variables.Fixed effects estimations also includes country and time dummies (not reported).

31

Table 6

Impact of IFI Lending on Aggregate Investment

SUR Panel Investment Regressions for Developing CountriesTime Period: Five five-year periods, 1975 -1979 to 1995 -1999 Dependent Variable: Total Investment (% of GDP)Observations 401 400 401 400IMF credits (% GDP) -0.27**

(4.01)Lagged IMF credits -0.11

(1.37)WB credits (%GDP) 0.008

(0.20)Lagged WB credits 0.004

(0.10)R-square .32 -.58 .31 -.55 .32 -.55 .32 -.55

Low-income developing coun. Middle-income developing coun.Observations 266 135IMF credits (% GDP) -0.30** -0.33*

(4.19) (2.18)Lagged IMF credits -0.25** 0.17

(2.92) (0.93)WB credits (%GDP) 0.03 -0.07

(0.61) (0.38)Lagged WB credits -0.005 0.51**

(0.09) (2.79)

Poor-democracy developing coun. Good-democracy developing coun.Observations 233 168IMF credits (% GDP) -0.34** -0.18*

(3.63) (1.86)Lagged IMF credits -0.21* -0.04

(1.85) (0.36)WB credits (%GDP) 0.03 0.12

(0.69) (1.38)Lagged WB credits 0.009 0.08

(0.16) (0.90)The system has 5 equations, where the dependent variables are the investment shares over each five-year period. Each equation has a different constant term.Other coefficients are restricted to be the same for all periods. t-statistics are in parentheses.Regressors are same as in the growth model.** Significant at the 1 percent-level; * Significant at the 5 percent-level.

32

Table 7

Effects of IFI Lending on Public and Private Investment

SUR Panel Investment Regressions for Developing CountriesTime Dimension: Five five-year periods, 1975 -1979 to 1995 -1999 Dependent Variable: Public/Private Investment (% of GDP)

Public Investments Private InvestmentsObservations 315 315 315 315 309 309 309 309IMF credits (% GDP) -0.10* -0.17**

(2.05) (3.08)Lagged IMF credits -0.02 -0.099

(0.33) (1.27)IBRD credits (%GDP) 0.09** -0.07*

(3.61) (2.23)Lagged WB credits 0.08* -0.07***

(2.37) (1.89)R-square -.01 -.37 .01 -.37 .19 -.43 .11 -.42 .40 -.61 .38 -.61 .39 -.61 .38 -.62

Low-income developing coun. Middle-income developing coun. Public Private Public Private

Observations 218 213 97 96IMF credits (% GDP) -0.16** -0.19** -0.07 -0.10

(2.71) (3.18) (0.85) (0.79)Lagged IMF credits -0.11 -0.14*** 0.05 0.13

(1.49) (1.89) (0.57) (0.99)IBRD credits (%GDP) 0.11** -0.06*** 0.36** 0.10

(3.98) (1.73) (3.70) (0.66)Lagged IBRD credits 0.08* -0.07*** 0.50** 0.36*

(2.19) (1.75) (4.82) (2.07)

Poor-democracy developing coun. Good-democracy developing coun. Public Private Public Private

Observations 188 183 127 126IMF credits (% GDP) -0.19** -0.14*** 0.06 -0.14

(2.71) (1.84) (0.96) (1.65)Lagged IMF credits -0.07 -0.05 0.13*** -0.03

(0.84) (0.59) (1.77) (0.25)IBRD credits (%GDP) 0.14** -0.04 0.13** -0.04

(4.31) (1.27) (2.54) (0.58)Lagged IBRD credits 0.12** -0.07 0.10 0.03

(2.76 (1.60) (1.63) (0.33)The system has 5 equations, where the dependent variables are the investment shares over each five-year period. Each equation has a different constant term. Other coefficients are restricted to be the same for all periods. t-statistics are in parentheses.* significant at the 5 percent level** significant at the 1 percent level*** significant at the 10 percent level

33

VII. References

Alesina, Alberto, David Dollar. (2000). “Who gives foreign aid to whom and why?”, Journal of Economic Growth, 5, 33–63.

Barro, Robert J. (1997). Determinants of economic growth: A cross-country empirical study. Cambridge and London: MIT Press.

Barro, Robert J. (1988). “The IMF doesn’t put out fires, it starts them,” Business Week, 12/07/98 Issue 3607, p18, 1p, 1c.

Barro, Robert J. Jong-Wha Lee. (2000). "International data on educational attainment: updates and implications," manuscript, Harvard University, February 2000.

Barro, Robert J., Jong-Wha Lee. (2002). “IMF programs: Who is chosen and what are the effects?”, NBER Working Paper Series No. 8951.

Bird, Graham. (1996a). “Borrowing from the IMF: The policy implications of recent empirical research”, World Development, 24(11), 1753-1760.

Bird, Graham. (1996b). “The International Monetary Fund and developing countries: a review of the evidence and policy options”, International Organization 50(3), 477-511.

Bird, Graham. (2001). “IMF programs: Do they work? Can they be made to work better?”, World Development, 29(11), 1849-1865.

Birdsall, Nancy, Juan Louis Londono. (1997). “Asset inequality matters: An assessment of the World Bank’s approach to poverty reduction”, American Economic Review, 87(2), 32-37.

Boone, Peter. (1996). “Politics and the effectiveness of foreign aid”, European Economic Review, 40, 289–329.

Bordo, Michael D., Harold James. (2000). “The International Monetary Fund: Its present role in historical perspective”, NBER Working Paper Series No. 7724.

Bordo, Michael D, Anna J. Schwartz. (2000). “Measuring real economic effects of bailouts: Historical perspectives on how countries in financial distress have fared with and without bailouts”, Carnegie-Rochester Conference on Public Policy, 53, 81-167.

Bretton Woods Commission, (1994). Bretton Woods: Looking to the Future, Bretton Woods Commission, Washington, D.C.

Burnside, Craig, David Dollar. (2000). “Aid, policies, and growth”, American Economic Review, 90(4), 847-868.

Camdessus, Michel. (1994). “International cooperation for high-quality growth: The role of the IMF at 50”, Washington DC, International Monetary Fund, http://www.imf.org/external/np/sec/mds/1995/MDS9521.HTM.

Camdessus, Michel. (2000), “Development and Poverty Reduction: A Multilateral Approach”, Washington DC, International Monetary Fund, http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2000/021300.htm.

Conway, Patrick. (1994). “IMF lending programs: Participation and impact”, Journal of Development Economics, 45, 365-391.

34

Dicks-Mireaux, Louis, Mauro Mecagni, Susan Schadler. (2000). “Evaluating the effect of IMF lending to low-income countries”, Journal of Development Economics, 61, 495-526.

Easterly, William. (1999a). “Life during growth”, Journal of Economic Growth, 4, 239-275.

Easterly, William. (1999b) “The ghost of financing gap: Evaluating the growth model of the international financial institutions,” Journal of Development Economics, 60, 423-438.

Easterly, William. (2001). “IMF and World Bank structural adjustment programs and poverty”, World Bank, April 2001.

Feinberg, Richard E. (1988). “The changing relationship between the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund”, International Organization 42(3), 545-560.

Feldstein, Martin. (1998). “Refocusing the IMF”, Foreign Affairs, March/April 1998, pp. 20-33.

Fischer, Stanley. (1997). “Applied economics in action: IMF programs”, American Economic Review, 87(2), 23-27.

Fischer, Stanley. (2000a). “Presentation to the International Financial Institution Advisory Commission”, Washington DC, http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2000/020200.htm

Fischer, Stanley. (2000b). “Remarks by Stanley Fisher, Acting Managing Director”, Remarks to the Bretton Woods Committee Meeting on April 4, 2000, International Monetary Fund, http://www.imf.org/external/np/speeches/2000/040400.htm

Gastil, Raymond D. (1988). Freedom in the World: Political Rights and Civil Liberties 1987-1988. New York: Freedom House.

Gavin, Michael, Dani Rodrik. (1995). “The World Bank in historical perspective”, American Economic Review, 85(2), 329-334.

Greene, William H. (1997). Econometric Analysis. New Jersey: Prentice Hall.

Goldstein, Morris, Peter Montiel. (1986). “Evaluating Fund stabilization programs with multicountry data: Some methodological pitfalls”, International Monetary Fund Staff Papers, 33, 304-344.

Goldstein, Morris. (2000). “IMF structural programs”, NBER Woodstock Paper, (December).

Hall, Robert C., Charles Jones. (1999) “Why do some countries produce so much more output per worker than others?” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113, 83-116.

Haque, Nadeem, Mohsin S. Khan. (1998) “Do IMF supported programs work? A survey of cross-country empirical evidence.” IMF Working Paper No. 169.

Heckman, J. (1979). “Sample selection bias as a specification error”, Econometrica, 47), 153-61.

Hutchison, Michael M. (2001). “A cure worse than the disease? Currency crises and the output costs of IMF-supported stabilization programs”, NBER Working Paper Series No. 8305.

35

International Financial Institution Advisory Commission. (2000). “Report of the International Financial Institution Advisory Commission”, Allan H. Meltzer, Chairman, Washington DC, March.

International Monetary Fund and World Bank (2000). “The IMF and World Bank Group: An enhanced partnership for sustainable growth and poverty reduction,” Washington, D.C., International Monetary Fund, http://www.imf.org/external/np/omd/2000/part.htm.

James, Harold. (1998). “From grandmotherliness to governance: The evolution of IMF conditionality”, Finance and Development, 35(4), http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/fandd/1998/12/james.htm.

Kaplan, Ethan, Dani Rodrik. (2001). “Did the Malaysian capital controls work? NBER Working Paper Series No. 8142.

Killick, Tony. (1995). IMF Programmes in Developing Countries: Design and Impact, London, Routledge.

Knight, Malcolm, Julio A. Santanella. (1997). “Economic determinants of IMF financial arrangements”, Journal of Development Economics, 54, 405-436.

Krueger, O. Anne. (1998). “Wither the World Bank and the IMF?”, Journal of Economic Literature, 36(4), 1983-2020.

Krueger, O. Anne. (2000). “IMF stabilization programs”, NBER Woodstock Paper, Version:2, (November).

Meltzer, Allan H. (2002). “Back to bailouts,” The Wall Street Journal, August 7, 2002, A14.

Mercer-Blackman, Valerie, Anna Unigovskaya. (2000). “Compliance with IMF program indicators and growth in transition economies”, IMF Working Paper No. 47.

Mussa, Michael, Miguel Savastano. (2000). “The IMF approach to economic stabilization” NBER Macroeconomics Annual, 1999. V. 14, 79-122, Cambridge and London: MIT Press.

Nuxoll, Daniel A. (1994). “Differences in relative prices and international differences in growth rates”, American Economic Review, 84, 1423-1436.

Przeworski, Adam, James Vreeland. (2000) "The effect of IMF programs on economic growth", Journal of Development Economics, 62, 385-421.

Rodrik, Dani. (1995). “Why is there multilateral lending?” NBER Working Paper Series, No. 5160.

Rowlands, Dane. (1996). “New lending to less developed countries: The effects of the IMF”, Canadian Journal of Economics, 2, S443-S447.

Stewart, Frances, Valpy FitzGerald. (1996). “The IMF and the global economy: Implications for developing countries”, Quenn Elizabeth House Working Paper Series, No:3.

Stiglitz, J. (2000). “What I learned at the world economic crisis”, The New Republic, April 17.

Thacker C. Strom. (1999). “The high politics of IMF lending”, World Politics, 52(1), 38-75.

36

Truman, Edwin M. (2001). “Comment on IMF and World Bank structural adjustment programs and poverty by William Easterly”, NBER Conference on Management of Currency Crises March 28-31, 2001.

Woods, Ngaire. (2000). “The challenge of good governance of the IMF and the World Bank themselves”, World Development, 28(5), 823-841.

Yeldan, Erinc. (2001). “On the IMF-directed disinflation program in Turkey: A program for stabilization and austerity or a recipe for impoverishment and financial chaos?”, Bilkent University Working paper.

Zaki, Mokhklis Y. (2001). “IMF-supported stabilization programs and their critics: Evidence from the recent experience of Egypt”, World Development, 29(11), 1867-1883.