wealth distribution and bequests

20
Wealth Distribution and Bequests Prof. Lutz Hendricks Econ821 February 9, 2016 1 / 20

Upload: others

Post on 18-Jan-2022

7 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Wealth Distribution and BequestsProf. Lutz Hendricks

Econ821

February 9, 2016

1 / 20

Page 2: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Contents

Introduction 3

Data on bequests 4

Bequest motives 5

Bequests and wealth inequality 10

De Nardi (2004) 11

Research Ideas 17

Other Relevant Papers 19

2 / 20

Page 3: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Introduction

The questions:

• How important are bequests for wealth inequality?

• Do bequests increase or reduce inequality?

• Why do people leave bequests?

3 / 20

Page 4: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Data on bequests

Aggregate size:

• around 2% of GDP ($200 billion).

• estimates vary widely.

Size distribution:

• inheritances are probably more concentrated than wealth.

• 70% never inherit.

• top 2% account for 70% of inheritances.

Source: My calculations

4 / 20

Page 5: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Bequest motives

The literature proposes and tests several theories.No consensus as to which motives are important.

Household problem:

U (k1, ...) = max E

T∑t=1

βt u (ct) + βT V (kT+1, ...)

subject tokt+1 = Rkt + yt − ct

5 / 20

Page 6: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Bequest motives

Accidental bequests:

• V (.) = 0.

• Bequests arise because households do not hold annuities.

Joy of giving:

• V (kT+1) is an arbitrary utility function.

• The amount given provides utility.

• Easy to implement, but vacuous unless the utility function is known.

Altruism:

• V (kT+1, ...) = U (kT+1, ...).

• Parents derive utility from utility of their children.

• Theoretically appealing, but harder to compute.

• Problems if parents and children overlap: strategic interaction.

Two-sided altruism:

• Children also value utility of their parents.

• If all have the same discount factors: family behaves as if a single decision maker(Laitner).

Strategic / exchange motive:

• Parents derive utility from children’s behavior (e.g. visiting the parents).

• Parents "buy" that behavior from the children by promising bequests or by givinginter-vivos transfers.

• Problem (in my view): the promise of bequests is not time-consistent.

6 / 20

Page 7: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Evidence on Bequest Motives

Intended bequests

Pro:

• Households often do not dissave in retirement.

Con:

• Households without children do not dissave faster than households with children(Hurd).

• Parents do not take advantage of tax-exempt inter-vivos transfers: Poterba (2001)

7 / 20

Page 8: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Altruism

Most bequests are divided equally between children.

• Richer children receive at most marginally smaller inheritances (Laitner and Ohlsson,2001)

• Seems to contradict altruism (Wilhelm).

Parental income shocks have little effect on child consumption

• not consistent with full risk sharing implied by operative altruism

• Hayashi et al. (1996)

Exchange theories

Children who interact more with parents receive larger transfers.Also consistent with altruism.

8 / 20

Page 9: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Summary

Results are very mixed.

Each motive that has been tested has also been rejected. This suggeststhat households may be influenced by several motives, or that the importanceof each may vary across households. (Gale and Perozek, 2001)

This suggests an alternative approach:Use a CGE model to measure the relative importance of alternative bequest motives.

9 / 20

Page 10: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Bequests and wealth inequality

Findings in the literature are very diverse.

Accidental bequests:

• increase wealth inequality: Gokhale et al. (2001)

• reduce wealth inequality: Nishiyama (2002)

• have little effect on wealth inequality: Huggett (1996)

Intended bequests:

• increase wealth inequality: Castaneda et al. (2003), Laitner (2002), De Nardi (2004)

• findings disagree whether bequests help account for large wealth holdings.

10 / 20

Page 11: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

De Nardi (2004)

De Nardi (2004) finds: bequests greatly improve the model’s ability to account for top 1%of wealth holdings.

Key model features:

1. Stochastic mortality

2. Joy of giving bequest motive:

φ (b) = φ1 (1 + b/φ2)1−σ

3. Parents and children overlap

4. Chilren’s earnings are correlated with parental earnings at age 40.

11 / 20

Page 12: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Calibration

1. Model period is 5 years.

2. Earnings approximate an AR(1) with 3 states.

3. Var of initial earnings matches earnings Gini.

4. φ1: matches transfer wealth ratio of 60%

5. φ2: matches (small) size of bottom 30% of estates (about 7% of average earnings)

Transfer wealth = the amount of wealth that a person holds that is “due to” inheritancesand inter-vivos gifts.

• not clear how it is defined here

• simply not a useful calibration target

12 / 20

Page 13: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Results

754 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES

TABLE 5Results for the U.S. calibration

Capital–output Transfer wealth Wealth Percentage wealth in the top Percentage with negativeratio ratio Gini 1% 5% 20% 40% 60% or zero wealth

U.S. data3·0 0·60 0·78 29 53 80 93 98 5·8–15·0

No intergenerational links, equal bequests to all3·0 0·67 0·67 7 27 69 90 98 17

No intergenerational links, unequal bequests to children3·0 0·38 0·68 7 27 69 91 99 17

One link: productivity inheritance3·0 0·38 0·69 8 29 70 92 99 17

One link: parent’s bequest motive3·0 0·55 0·74 14 37 76 95 100 19

Both links: parent’s bequest motive and productivity inheritance3·0 0·60 0·76 18 42 79 95 100 19

TABLE 6Results for the Swedish calibration

Wealth–output Transfer wealth Wealth Percentage wealth in the top Percentage with negativeratio ratio Gini 1% 5% 20% 40% 60% or zero wealth

Swedish data1·7 >0·51 0·73 17 37 75 99 100 30

No intergenerational links, equal bequests to all2·0 0·73 0·67 7 26 68 90 98 22

No intergenerational links, unequal bequests to children1·9 0·42 0·69 7 28 71 93 99 26

One link: productivity inheritance1·9 0·43 0·70 8 30 72 93 100 28

One link: bequest motive1·5 0·46 0·74 9 32 76 96 100 33

Both links: bequest motive and productivity inheritance1·5 0·47 0·75 10 34 78 96 100 33

6.1. No intergenerational links

Line 2 in Table 5 shows that an overlapping-generations model with no dynastic links and equaldistribution of bequests has serious difficulties in generating enough skewness to match the U.S.distribution of wealth. The lower tail of the wealth distribution is too fat, and its upper tail is fartoo thin.

The large number of people at low asset levels is a common problem of overlapping-generations models. The households are born without savings that could be used to absorbnegative productivity shocks; hence, all young consumers who get a bad productivity shock hitthe borrowing constraint. As households work and get older, they gradually accumulate assets for

To explain the data for 20-year-old people, a theory of inter vivos transfers would, in my opinion, be required. The 20year olds are also excluded from the U.S. data on the distribution.

at University of N

orth Carolina at Chapel Hill on February 6, 2015

http://restud.oxfordjournals.org/D

ownloaded from

Bequests increase fraction of wealth held by top 1% from 8% to 18%.Still quite a bit short of the data (29%)

13 / 20

Page 14: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Size distribution of estates758 REVIEW OF ECONOMIC STUDIES

0 5 10 15 20 25 30

0·1

0·2

0·3

0·4

0·5

0·6

0·7

0·8

0·9

Estate size, normalized by median income

Perc

entil

es

FIGURE 3Cumulative distribution of estates, solid = model, dash–dot = AHEAD data

distribution generated by the model actually compares very well to the AHEAD data until the70-th percentile of the estate distribution. From that point on, the model predicts larger bequeststhan those observed in the AHEAD data. The discrepancy is partly due to the fact that AHEADmisses some large estates. As Davies and Shorrocks (2000) point out, over-sampling the rich isnecessary to obtain a good representation of the asset holdings of the richest.

The model’s implications about the elasticity of the old people’s savings to permanentincome are consistent with recent microeconomic estimates. Altonji and Villanueva (2002) useU.S. data from the PSID to estimate the effect of an increase of 1 dollar of permanent income onthe asset holdings of the 70-year-old people. They find that this effect is rather small. To checkwhether this can be consistent with a model with voluntary bequests such as mine, they run thesame regressions on the actual data and on data simulated using the models in this paper forthe U.S. They find that the effect of a dollar of permanent income on the old people’s savingsgenerated by my model with voluntary bequests is consistent with the magnitudes that theyestimate in the data.

Now look at some of the features generated by the model to better understand itsfunctioning. Figure 4 displays the strictly positive range of the bequest distribution for a 40-year-old person, conditional on the person’s parent’s observed productivity level, should the parentdie during that period. At that age, the probabilities of receiving zero bequests are, respectively,54%, 27%, 4% and 0%, for people with parents in the lowest, second lowest, second highest andhighest productivity levels. The average bequests expected are, respectively, 3, 5, 10 and 21 yearsof average labour earnings. Even in the presence of a bequest motive, the parents run down theirassets after retirement, so the expected bequest declines. The fraction of people whose parentlives up to the final age of the model economy and who do not receive a positive bequest are97%, 95%, 90% and 56%, respectively. The average bequest that they expect at that point in lifeis about 1·4, 1·7, 2·6 and 6·6 years of average labour earnings.

Figure 5 shows the strictly positive range of the bequest distribution for 40-year-old Swedishagents, should their parent die this period. For people whose parent was at the lowest productivitylevel at age 40, the average bequest is 0.6 years of average labour earnings, and the probability

at University of N

orth Carolina at Chapel Hill on February 6, 2015

http://restud.oxfordjournals.org/D

ownloaded from

The model matches the 30th percentile by construction.The top 10% of estates are far too large

14 / 20

Page 15: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Importance of Inheritances

There are no rich households without inheritances.DE NARDI WEALTH INEQUALITY AND INTERGENERATIONAL LINKS 761

25 30 35 40 45 50 55 600

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Age

Wea

lth

FIGURE 7U.S. calibration. Wealth quantiles: 0·1, 0·25, 0·5, 0·75, 0·85, 0·95, conditional on not having inherited

25 30 35 40 45 50 55 600

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Age

Wea

lth

FIGURE 8U.S. calibration. Wealth quantiles: 0·1, 0·25, 0·5, 0·75, 0·85, 0·95, conditional on having inherited

physical capital. Poorer families will tend to have poorer children, thus generating persistence inthe lower end of the wealth distribution. At the upper tail of the distribution, rich children mightwant to save less because they expect large bequests. However, they will also be richer (becauseof their dominant income process and the bigger transfers they receive from their parents); hence,they might want to save more. At the aggregate level, this will increase or decrease persistenceat the upper end of the wealth distribution, depending on which effect dominates. Most likely, ifthe altruism toward their children is strong enough for the richer people, the desire to leave large

at University of N

orth Carolina at Chapel Hill on February 6, 2015

http://restud.oxfordjournals.org/D

ownloaded from

DE NARDI WEALTH INEQUALITY AND INTERGENERATIONAL LINKS 761

25 30 35 40 45 50 55 600

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Age

Wea

lth

FIGURE 7U.S. calibration. Wealth quantiles: 0·1, 0·25, 0·5, 0·75, 0·85, 0·95, conditional on not having inherited

25 30 35 40 45 50 55 600

1

2

3

4

5

6

7

Age

Wea

lth

FIGURE 8U.S. calibration. Wealth quantiles: 0·1, 0·25, 0·5, 0·75, 0·85, 0·95, conditional on having inherited

physical capital. Poorer families will tend to have poorer children, thus generating persistence inthe lower end of the wealth distribution. At the upper tail of the distribution, rich children mightwant to save less because they expect large bequests. However, they will also be richer (becauseof their dominant income process and the bigger transfers they receive from their parents); hence,they might want to save more. At the aggregate level, this will increase or decrease persistenceat the upper end of the wealth distribution, depending on which effect dominates. Most likely, ifthe altruism toward their children is strong enough for the richer people, the desire to leave large

at University of N

orth Carolina at Chapel Hill on February 6, 2015

http://restud.oxfordjournals.org/D

ownloaded from

15 / 20

Page 16: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Comments

1. The paper could use more data on inheritances.

(a) especially on correlation with earnings / wealth(b) what fraction of high wealth holders in the data did not inherit?

2. The paper should use a better measure of aggregate bequests

Overall: the question remains open.

16 / 20

Page 17: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Research Ideas

Use more data

1. match size distribution of inheritances (SCF)

2. match inheritances of the wealth rich

3. account for the fact that estates are split between multiple children + charities (estatetax data)

17 / 20

Page 18: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

To motivate: some data from SCF and PSID

A3

Table 6. Lifetime inheritances by family income (SCF)

Percentile 20 40 60 80 100

Fraction of total inheritance 3.6 3.9 9.4 14.1 69.0

Mean inheritance 0.2 0.3 0.7 0.9 5.0

Mean family income 0.1 0.3 0.5 0.7 2.5

Ratio inheritance / family income 164% 93% 160% 131% 200%

Notes: Based on 1989 Survey of Consumer Finances. Inheritances and family incomes are expressed as multiples of mean earnings per civilian employee.

Table 7. Lifetime inheritance by family lifetime earnings (PSID)

Percentile 20 40 60 80 100

Fraction of total inheritance 13.9 19.9 42.1 58.7 100.0

Mean inheritance 0.6% 0.2% 0.9% 0.7% 1.7%

Mean family lifetime earnings 0.3 0.6 0.9 1.2 2.0

Ratio inheritance / family lifetime earnings

2.0% 0.3% 1.0% 0.6% 0.9%

Notes: N = 888. Based on sample of PSID households with at most one surviving parent. Inheritances and family lifetime earnings are discounted to age 50 and expressed as multiples of mean lifetime earnings.

Source: my calculations

The point: inheritances are, on average, a small fraction of lifetime earnings.

18 / 20

Page 19: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

Other Relevant Papers

A survey: Cagetti and De Nardi (2008)Models with bequests: Ocampo and Yuki (2006), Cagetti and De Nardi (2009)Data on bequests: Hurd and Smith (2001), Joulfaian (1994)

19 / 20

Page 20: Wealth Distribution and Bequests

ReferencesCagetti, M. and M. De Nardi (2008): “Wealth inequality: Data and models,”

Macroeconomic Dynamics, 12, 285–313.

——— (2009): “Estate Taxation, Entrepreneurship, and Wealth,” The American EconomicReview, 99, 85–111.

Castaneda, A., J. Diaz-Gimenez, and J. V. Rios-Rull (2003): “Accounting forthe US earnings and wealth inequality,” Journal of political economy, 111, 818–857.

De Nardi, M. (2004): “Wealth inequality and intergenerational links,” The Review ofEconomic Studies, 71, 743–768.

Gale, W. G. and M. G. Perozek (2001): “Do estate taxes reduce saving?” RethinkingEstate and Gift Taxation, 216, 217–218.

Gokhale, J., L. J. Kotlikoff, J. Sefton, and M. Weale (2001): “Simulatingthe transmission of wealth inequality via bequests,” Journal of Public economics, 79,93–128.

Hayashi, F., J. Altonji, and L. Kotlikoff (1996): “Risk-Sharing between andwithin Families,” Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 261–294.

Huggett, M. (1996): “Wealth distribution in life-cycle economies,” Journal of MonetaryEconomics, 38, 469–494.

Hurd, M. D. and J. P. Smith (2001): “Anticipated and actual bequests,” in Themesin the Economics of Aging, University of Chicago Press, 357–392.

Joulfaian, D. (1994): “The Distribution and Division of Bequests in the US: Evidencefrom the Collation Study,” OTA paper, 71.

Laitner, J. (2002): “Wealth Inequality and Altruistic Bequests,” The American EconomicReview, 92, pp. 270–273.

Laitner, J. and H. Ohlsson (2001): “Bequest motives: a comparison of Sweden andthe United States,” Journal of Public Economics, 79, 205–236.

Nishiyama, S. (2002): “Bequests, inter vivos transfers, and wealth distribution,” Reviewof Economic Dynamics, 5, 892–931.

Ocampo, I. P. and K. Yuki (2006): “Savings, Intergenerational Transfers, and theDistribution of Wealth,” Macroeconomic Dynamics, 10, 371–414.

Poterba, J. (2001): “Estate and gift taxes and incentives for inter vivos giving in theUS,” Journal of Public Economics, 79, 237–264.

20 / 20