vladilvira p. timoshenko

25
THE NEW AGRICULTURAL POLICY OF SOVIET RUSSIA 1 VLADIlViraP. TIMOSHENKO UNIVERSITY OF I~ICHIGAN As we understand the new ag¡ policy of Soviet Russia, ir 91 the policy accepted by the communist party of Russia and puf into effect after the fifteenth congress of the party in the winter 1927-28. Its purpose is to replace the small peasant farms by large-scale agricultural enterprises such as large state farms--sovkhozQor cooperative farms, organized in a somewhat different manner, the so-called kolkhoz. During the last two years, 1929 and 1930, this policy has been put into effect with great vigor. In order to understand the reasons for this new policy, and the methods of its execution, it is necessary to give a short review of the agricultural policy of Soviet Russia begin- ning with 1917. To a certain degree the new agricultural policy of Soviet Russia is a return to the princip]es which dominated the agricultural policy of the Soviet government during the per- iod of so-called war- or militant communism, from 1919 to 1921. The Russian communist party, or the bolshevist group of the Russian social-democratic party, has always been a partisan of large-scale farming. Ir has always declared that in agriculture as well as in manufacturing large-scale enterprises have a com- petitive advantage over small ones and tend to supplant them. Ir does not recognize the existence of a special form of evolution in agriculture, different from that of industry. ttowever, the communist party, being a partisan of large-scale agricultural enterprŸ and not admitting any advantage in small farming, was, at the same time, quite conscious of the great popu- larity among Russian peasants of the idea of a subdivision of large estates and of a leveling of land holdings. Accordingly, in its struggle for power during the first steps of the revolution the communist party, in order to get the support of the peasantry, accepted an agricultural policy which was not of its own making and did not correspond to its principles. In fact, the leaders of the left wing of the socialist-revolutŸ party, with whom the communists had united their forces during the first steps of the communist revolution, were even permitted to formulate the first agricultural policy and to prepare the first agrarian law (the law of February 19, 1918). Paper read at the joint meeting of the American Farm Economic Association and the American Statistilal Association at Cleveland, Ohio, December, 1930. (280)

Upload: others

Post on 16-Oct-2021

8 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

THE NEW AGRICULTURAL POLICY OF SOVIET RUSSIA 1

VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO UNIVERSITY OF I~ICHIGAN

As we understand the new ag¡ policy of Soviet Russia, ir �91 the policy accepted by the communist party of Russia and puf into effect after the fifteenth congress of the par ty in the winter 1927-28. I ts purpose is to replace the small peasant farms by large-scale agricultural enterprises such as large state farms--sovkhozQor cooperative farms, organized in a somewhat different manner, the so-called kolkhoz. During the last two years, 1929 and 1930, this policy has been put into effect with great vigor. In order to understand the reasons for this new policy, and the methods of its execution, it is necessary to give a short review of the agricultural policy of Soviet Russia begin- ning with 1917. To a certain degree the new agricultural policy of Soviet Russia is a return to the princip]es which dominated the agricultural policy of the Soviet government during the per- iod of so-called war- or militant communism, from 1919 to 1921.

The Russian communist party, or the bolshevist group of the Russian social-democratic party, has always been a partisan of large-scale farming. Ir has always declared that in agriculture as well as in manufacturing large-scale enterprises have a com- petitive advantage over small ones and tend to supplant them. Ir does not recognize the existence of a special form of evolution in agriculture, different from that of industry.

ttowever, the communist party, being a partisan of large-scale agricultural enterprŸ and not admitting any advantage in small farming, was, at the same time, quite conscious of the great popu- larity among Russian peasants of the idea of a subdivision of large estates and of a leveling of land holdings. Accordingly, in its struggle for power during the first steps of the revolution the communist party, in order to get the support of the peasantry, accepted an agricultural policy which was not of its own making and did not correspond to its principles. In fact, the leaders of the left wing of the socialist-revolutŸ party, with whom the communists had united their forces during the first steps of the communist revolution, were even permitted to formulate the first agricultural policy and to prepare the first agrarian law (the law of February 19, 1918).

Paper read at the joint meeting of the American Farm Economic Association and the American Statistilal Association at Cleveland, Ohio, December, 1930.

(280)

Page 2: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricultural Policy of Soviet Russia 281

The chief aim of this law was to create equalization in the use of land. I t proclaimed that all ownership in land was abo]ished and that the land was transferred, for use, to all the working people; that all land was to be distributed on the principle of equalized land possession; and that every citizen in principle acquired the right to use the land. Thus the reform embraced not only the confiscated estates but the land of the peasants as well; "socialization" was to level all the existing inequalities of land possession.

The peasantry in its revolutionary activity did not follow ex- actly the principle of a thorough equalization of land through all the eountry but a considerable leveling of land holdings within narrower boundaries took place. Large estates were taken and subdivided, including all belonging to them--buildings, inven- tories, livestock, etc. The " s u r p l u s " lands from individual farms of wealthier peasants were also cut off and subdivided. But what is of greatest importance, all large-scale agricult/lral enterprises and even middle-sized farms, disappeared. In the entire country there was left in the hands of the Soviet govern- ment not more than two or three per cent of the arable and pas- ture lands. The land fell into the individual possession of the local population. But in spite of the extensive subdivision of large estates, the average size of peasant holdings did not in- crease appreciably. Many landless peasant householders ob- tained lands; even many city workers returning to the country obtained land; although the process of subdividing the larger peasant househo]ds proceeded very rapidly, the number of peasant householders increased likewise.

Such were the conditions when, early in 1919, the Soviet government, after the rupture with the left wing of the socialist- revolutionary party, tried to formulate its agricultural policy more nearly in accord with the principles of the communist party. The decree of February 14, 1919, declared the p¡ of the "socialistic organization or agricu]tural production." All land was proclaimed " a single state fund" ; "al l forms of individual land possession" were declared " to be dying out" ; "b ig soviet farms, communes, communal land cultivation, and other forms of associated farming" were pronounced to be " the best means toward organizing a farming system on s.ocialist lines." Ac- cording to this decree, the land reserve is to be used in the first place, for satisfying the needs of the soviet farms and com- munes; in the second place, for satisfying the needs of artels,

Page 3: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

282 Vladimir P. Timoshenko

associations and other collective farm units. Individual cultiva- tors, desiring land as a means of subsistence, occupy only third place.

In this way the policy of preference of state farms and of collective farms was proclaimed by the Soviet government as early as the beginning of 1919. But at that time this policy could not be applied. As was mentioned above the Soviet govern- ment by this time held reall$ only from two to three per cent of the arable land and pasture land, only the remnants of the former large estates, which had been to a great degree subdivided by the peasantry. The Soviet government could utilize for the organi- zation of large state farms only these remnants of former large estates. Likewise the "communes" (collective farms) were or- ganized mostly on the land previously belonging to large estates. The peasants at this time were unwilling to depart from lands which they had taken from large estates or to organize their own farming on collective lines.

The attempts of the Soviet government to retain from ten to twelve million acres of land taken from large estates connected with sugar factories already nationalized by the Soviet govern- ment, and to organize on these lands large state farms for the production of sugar beets was unsuccessful. Ir succeeded in keeping on]y two or three million acres, the rest being held by the peasantry in small lots.

Thus the first attempt to organize a large farming enterprise in the form of state farms or collective farms was unsuccessful. Only a small percentage of the agricultural area, not more than 2 per cent of the total tillable land, was he]d by state farms and by communes, and even these few large farms were not success- ful. This is recognized even by official historians of the Soviet agricultural policy. One of them, Mr. Swidersky, in the article written in connection with the tenth anniversary of the Soviet government 2 says that from four to five thousand state farms containing about tire million acres and located in all provinces of Soviet Russia, could not produce sufficient food even for their personnel and for their livestock. They rented more than hali ~ of their land to peasants. 3 After the introduction of the new eco- nomic policy (NEP) in 1921, many of these state farms were abandoned because they could not continue without financial help

~Swidersky, A. T., Agr icu l tura l policy over period of 10 years. " P u t i Selskogo Khoziaistva," M¡ periodical of the Commissar ia t o~ Agriculture, 1927, N 10, pp. 18-49.

3 Whieh shows that 8mall-~cale peasaat farming at that time w~~ more effir ~h.~r~ f � 91 in largo state farms, " " "

Page 4: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agriculturat Policy of Soviet Russia 283

from the state whereas the policy of the state was to keep them on a self-supporting basis.

The collective farms of this period were not much more suc- cessful in spite of the fact that they obtained buildings and part of their livestock and inventories by confiscating them from large estates. By May of 1921 there were about fourteen thousand such collective farms with about three anda hall million acres of land. During the period from 1921 to 1926 the number of collective farms and their agricultural area decreased rather than in- crease& At the beginning of 1927 official statistics estimated the number of collective farms at from fourteen to fifteen thousand and the land involved at from five to six million acres but with only 1,700,000 acres of crops, while the ~otal crop area of the country was estimated at 280,000,000 acres. That is, collective farms produced a little more than a half of 1 per cent of the total crops. Together with state farms they accounted for only a little more than 1 per cent of the total crop atea of the country.

Thus during that period of revolution the Soviet government was quite unsuccessful with its first experiments in large-scale farming. As ir was several times officially stated, state farms were too far from the ideal to serve as examples of efficient and rationally organized farming for the neighboring peasantry. They could not produce for the government even a small part of the food necessary for city population. The government was obliged to confiscate all the food necessary for the city popula- tion from the small peasant farms. Ir is known that this policy of confiscating all the agricultural surpluses of the peasants was in a large measure responsible for the complete disorganization of agricultural production durŸ the first period of the Russian revolution. Ir is not the purpose of this paper to discuss the agricultural policy of that period.

In 1921 the Soviet government was obliged to proclaim a new economic policy which was, likewise, a new agricultural policy. The prospect of an immediate socialistic organization of agri- culture was abandoned. The Soviet government decided to leave more freedom of initiative to the peasants. The policy of con- fiscating all surpluses of agricultural products was replaced by fixed taxation of the peasants in kind. The market for agricul- tural surpluses was reopened. The purpose of the government was to stimulate the development of the productive activity of small- and medium-sized peasant farms, to increase their pro- duction beyond their needs for consumption, and to solve the food

Page 5: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

284: Vladimir P. Timoshenko

problem for the city population in this way. The best exposition of the agricultural policy of the period of NEP is probably the Land Code of 1922.

After proclaiming solemnly the principle of nationalization of land and the abolition of private rights to land, the Code of 1922 recognized practically unlimited tenure, in time, for agricultural use by the actual holders of the land. The Code did not impose on the peasantry new forros of land tenancy; on the contrary, ir recognized the equality of all previously existing forms �9 the com- munity of land, the individual holdings in open fields, and the holdings in c]osed fields (khutor or otrub). The Land Code, in abolishing private rights to land, without doubt did not permit such transactions as the purehase and sale, or mortgaging of land, but peasant 's lands in Russia could not be freely sold or mortgaged even in pre-revolutionary times. Only after the agrarian reform of 1907 (Stolypin's reform) was it possible to establish full private property rights on allotted peasant lands. ttowever, the Land Code of 1922 permitted the leasing of agri- cultural lands, though with certain limitations. Ir also permitted the use of hired labor in ~agriculture, which had been excluded by previous laws of the Soviet government. A few years later, in 1925, the Soviet government allowed even more freedom for leases of agricultural land- ir permitted leases of twelve years ' duration (even longer--two rotation periods ir they were longer than six years). I t also permitted rented land to be worked with hired labor. This had been forbidden by previous Soviet legislation and, without doubt, prevented the renting of land by the well-to-do peasantry. The use of hired labor in agriculture was still more facilitated by the temporary regulations of 1925 concerning hired labor on peasant farms, for agriculture was per- mitted several exceptions from the regulations of the laws pro- tecting hired labor, which are very severe in Russia. Agricul- ture, for instance, was permitted a longer working da$--longer than eight hours.

Ir appears, then, that the policy of the Soviet government from 1922 to 1925 was to give some concessions to the peasantry, to conciliate the peasantry as a whole and to stimulate their pro- ductive activity. The food supply policy of the government was based on the production of small- or medium-sized peasant farms and ir should be recognized that this agricultural policy was to a certain degree successful. During the period 1922-26 the Rus- sian peasantry made a great effort to equal the pre-war and pre-

Page 6: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricultural Policy of Soviet Russia 285

revolutionary agricultural production. In 1922, the year of the greatest decline in agricultural production in Soviet Russia, the total crop area was only about 60 per cent of the pre-war area; in 1926 the total crop area of Soviet Russia was not very far below the pre-war level2 That is, peasant agricultural produc- tion during the five year period increased about 50 per cent.

Itowever, this policy of conciliating the peasantry did not con- tinue long. The Soviet government clearly understood that in order to increase the quantity of marketable agricultural goods ir had to favor well-to-do peasants, because only this group of peasants produced a considerable surplus of goods. A middle peasant produced for market a comparatively smaller percentage of his gross product a n d a peor peasant had practically no sur- plus. In order to have a sufficiently large surplus of agricultural products, large enough to cover the needs of the city population and to permit exports, the Soviet government had to favor the stronger farmer. But this was contrary to the political interests of the communist par ty and to its communistic scheme. The communist par ty considered the wealthier peasants as class enemies and that ir had to fight against them to prevent their further growth and to keep them from power.

This conflict between the necessity of developing the produc- tive forces of agriculture on the one hand and the communist policy on the other hand, caused continual vacillation in the agricultural policy of the Soviet government. The Soviet Government after 1922 made considerable effort to increase the productivity of agriculture, to supply the peasantry with agri- cultural machinery, to develop agronomic assistance, and to or- ganize agricultural credit. On the other hand its taxation policy was more and more directed against the well-to-do peasant. The progression of agricultural taxes became so great that ir pre- vented the increase in the size of farms and encouraged their sub- division into smaller units, which was detrimental to ah increase in the productivity of agriculture.

The Communist par ty became suspicious of welI-to-do peas- antry a t a very early date. Firs t there began the anti-kulak pol- icy of the so-called "opposi t ion" in the communist par ty (the group headed by Trotsky). This group demanded that the possi-

' T h e estimate of the total crop area of the U.S.S.R. by the State P l a n n i n g Committee (Gosplan) is, for 1926, 98.3 per cent if 1913 equals 100 per cent. More cautious estimates by N. P. Oganovsky, an authority on agricultural statistics in Soviet Russia, pu t this per- centage at 94.3 per cent, le t t ing 1913 equal 100. See article, "Decline, Recovery and Re- construetion of Agriculture dur ing 10 Years," Ekonomicheskoe Obozrenie, 1927, No. 10, pp. 55-72.

Page 7: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

286 Vladimir t). Timoshenko

bilities for growth of power of the well-to-do peasantry be lim- ited. With this in mind, the opposition insisted upon decreasing agricultural prices in proportion to industrial prices so that a rapid industrialization of the country would be effected. At the same time the economic growth of the well-to-do peasants who were the principal sellers of ag¡ surpluses would be re- tarded. The ruling group of the communist party did not oppose such a policy very long.

The low ratio of agricultural to industrial prices was perhaps more characteristic of Soviet Russia after the war than of any other country. The recovery of agriculture after 1922, thanks to the initiative of the peasants, was more rapid during the early part of this period than that of manufacturing which was con- trolled by the government. When later, industry had recovered its quantity production, ir was notable to lower the cost of pro- duction sufficiently. A s a result, the ratio of agricultural to in- dustrial prices was always to the disadvantage of agriculture. Yet the intent of the Soviet governent was to keep this ratio on a low level.

Even the ratio of wholesale indexes of agricultural to indus- trial prices shows agriculture at a disadvantage.

~AWIOS OF T~~ ~~DEX OV WHOLESALE AOR~C~LT~RAL eR~CES T O T H E I N D E X O F W H O L E S A L E I N D U S T R I A L P R I C E S

1 9 1 3 e q u a l s 1 0 0 1 9 2 2 - 2 3 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5 2 . 4 1 9 2 3 - 2 4 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6 2 . 2 1 9 2 4 - 2 5 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 6 . 7 1 9 2 5 - 2 6 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 5 . 3 1 9 2 6 - 2 7 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7 9 . 6 1 9 2 7 - 2 8 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 8 3 . 3 1 9 2 8 - 2 9 . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 9 0 . 9

In 1924-1925 the ratio increased considerably, but this was due to the crop failure of 1924.

A still greater discrepancy of prices is shown in the ratios of prices which peasants received for agricultural products to prices which they paid for industrial products. The so-called "peasant indexes," oflicially published by the Institute of Busi- ness Conditions, Commissariat of Finance, indicate that during the fall of 1926 these ratios were, for different agricultural re- gions, between 60 and 70, while the ratio of wholesale prices was at the level of 80 to 85--that is, the farmer received for bis prod- ucts in 1926--when the ratios had improved somewhat--not more than two-thirds and very often much less than what he received in 19132 Ir should be stated that the ratio of agricultural to i

B T h e same study shows the ratios ot prices paid for agricultural p r o d u c t s b y t h e g o v - e r n m e n t a l pu~chasing organization to the index of retail prices, Such a ratio is published

Page 8: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricultural Policy of Soviet Russia 287

industrial prices in Russia before the war was also unfavorabte for agriculture, on account of the great protection given to in- dustry during that time. After the war an increase in the ratio of agricultural to industrial prices was greeted with approval in other countries and the policies of the governments were directed to that end. In Soviet Russia, on the contrary, when agricultural prices increased in 1924-25 (due to the crop failure) the govern- ment sought to lower them as soon as possible with the result that in 1925-26 and 1926-27 agricultural prices declined consid- erably.

An offŸ study of the cost of production of small grains in Soviet Russia demonstrated that the return f o r a labor day en- gaged in the production of grain sold at prices prevailing during 1926-27 and 1927-28 was considerably below the wages of hired labor in agriculture. 6

Unprofitable agricultural prices affected negatively all agri- cultural production but particularly that of the larger farms pro- ducing goods for market. The low percent• of marketable goods to total agricultural production was perhaps the greatest evil in agricultural conditions of post-war Russia. This percent- age was low even before the war, and since the war ir has de- clined considerably. Gosplan calculated that the percentage of all agricultural products sold on city markets to the total agri- cultural production was

22.2% in 1913 16.3% in 1924-25 16.5% in 1925-26 16.9% in 1926-27

Some specialists in agricultural statistics state that the estimated percentage of marketable goods for 1913 is perhaps too low and for the post-war years somewhat too high. 7 But accepting them as true, they show a considerable decline in the percentage of marketable products in agriculture. This is due to the subdi- vision of large estates and to the equalization of peasant farms. To a certain degree this decline is also the result of the price policy of the Soviet government.

Changes in the prices of one group of agricultural products as

by the State P lanning Committee ((~osplan), showing that in 1925-26 a peasant received on]y 66.2 per cent of pre-war prices, and in 1926-27--63.7 per cent. See "Kontrolnye Tsifry for 1929-30," by Gosplan, Moscow, 1930, p. 580.

e See article, "Problems of Price Formation in Agriculture," by Sh. J. Turetskii, Planovoe Khoziaistvo, 1929, No. 6, p. 94.

Eccnomic Bulletin of the Conjuncture Institute, 1927, Moscow; No. 11-12, p. 52.

Page 9: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

288 Vladimir P. Timoshenko

compared to another resulted in increase or decrease of produc- tion the next year. That the Russian peasant is very sensitive to this fluctuation in the price of different products, and regulares bis crops accordingly may be illustrated by several examples. For instance, during 1925 and 1926 the prices of some intensive crops such as sunflowers and sugar beets, were fixed relatively lower than those for other agricultural crops, particularly grain. As a result, in 1926 the production of intensive and technical crops de- clined relatively to the grain production level. However, from 1927 on, grain prices dropped to the lowest of all agricultural products. This situation resulted in an increase of crop acreage of technical and intensive crops, while the grain crop acreage did not increase and even declined. Since 1927 Russia has had her greatest difficulties with the grain supply?

In order to establish complete control of the agricultural mar- ket and of agricultural prices, the Soviet government during re- cent years (especially since 1925) has developed with increasing vigor a system of monopolization for the purchasing of agricul- tural products. For this purpose several administrative meas- ures were passed in order to eliminate private competition com- pletely from the agricultural market. In 1925 ah order was is- sued by which grain and other agricultural products from pri- vate dealers were given the lowest ranking in the category of goods transported by rail. This meant practically the complete elimination of "p r iva t e " agricultural products on the railroads. Somewhat later the railway rates for such private consignments were increased 50 to 100 per cent in comparison with what was charged for similar consignments of the state. Another condi- tion unfavorable to private shipments was found in the fact that generally no shelter was available for "p r iva t e " grain in rail- way stations. At the same time that the rates were increased, the government ordered complete nationalization of private flour mills. And a further step in this direction was taken when bank credit was forbidden to private persons engaged in the grain trade.

In this way private competition was practically eliminated in the purchasing of grain--although it was not forbidden by the law. Before the above-mentioned mea sures were put into ef- fect "pr iva te" grain amounted to 20 to 22 per cent of all the grain transported by rail, while at the end of 1926 the transpor-

. . . .

a Economic Bulletin of the Conjuncture Institute 1~ C Finance, ~oscow, 1927, No. 11-12, pp. 50-51.

Page 10: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricultural Policy of Soviet Russia 289

tation of "p r iva t e " grain amounted to only 1.5 to 2 per cent of all the grain transported by rail2

The monopolization of the grain market was followed by the monopolization of other agricultural products. The government is now trying to monopolize the market for vegetables and for animal products.

Along with the monopolization of markets there was also de- veloping the control of prices. The grain market was completely monopolized first, and then grain prices were lowered drastically in 1926. The index of grain prices from 161.1 in 1925-26 (1911-14 equals 100) was down to 124.6 in 1926-27 and was kept at the low level of 134.6 during 1927-28. The prices which govern- mental purchasing organizations paid were still lower.

The market of animal products was at that time (1927-28) less monopolized by the government and the index of prices of ani- mal products continued to increase after 1925-26, although ir v~as on a higher level in 1925-26 (1925-26--158.8, 1926-27--172.2, 1927-28--174.6). Consequently peasants tried to increase their production of those products for which the market was less mo- nopolized by the state a n d a t the same time they lowered the production of monopolized products. As a result the crop area of grains practically did not increase between 1926 .and 1930. The Soviet government encountered the greatest difficulties in pro- curing grain during the winter of 1927-28. After this time the Soviet government was obliged to resort to such methods of pro. curing grain as were practiced during the period of militant com- munism in 1918-27. Grains were not purchased at fixed prices but were requisitioned and if ir was discovered that stocks were being concealed by peasants, they were confiscated and heavy fines (ti ve times the value of the concealed grain) were levied upon the offenders. An implacable struggle against the well-to- do farmer was proc]aimed, the fifteenth congress of the com- munist party which was held during the winter of 1927-28 has formulated a new agricultural policy directed against the well- to-do peasantry, the so-called "kulak."

The fourteenth congress of the communist party, in 1925, had continued to grant some concessions to the well-to-do peasant (the above mentioned facilities for the rent of land and for the use of hired labor). The fifteenth congress on the other hand proclaimed ah agricultural policy which was directed definitely against the well-to-do peasantry: there were introduced stricter

I Haensel, P., The Economie Policy of Soviet Russia, London, 1930, pp. 68-69.

Page 11: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

290 VladimŸ P. TŸ

limitations for rent of land; leases longer than for six years were forbidden; "kulaks" were limited as to the use of hired labor; the inclosure of lands for individual farms was restricted or com- pletely forbidden; the progression of agricultural taxes was made still greater.

However, the leaders of the communist party were fully aware that their agricultural policy could not be put into effect simply by limiting the activities of the well-to-do peasantry.

This practice alone would mean a decrease in the quantity of marketable agricultural goods, which up to this time had been produced mostly by the well-to-do peasantry; stagnation of agri- cultural production; and its degeneration to the production for home use only. lo It was necessary therefore to replace the pro- duction of the "kulaks" with the production of some organiza- tion which could be controlled and directed by the Soviet govern- ment. For this reason the fifteenth congress of the communist party passed a resolution favoring the stimulation of coopera- tion among agricultural producers, not only for marketing but especially for production. The same measures which limited the activities of the wealthier peasants favored at the same time the development of collective farming: the purchasing of agricul- turM machinery by well-to-do peasants was to be limited and this machinery was to be sold to the collectives; the granting of credit was to be refused to the well-to-do peasants, but ir was to be extended more Iiberally to the collective farmers ; the inclosure of l ands by the individual well-to-do peasants was to be forbidden and at the same time the collective farmers were to be en- couraged in the inclosure of their land, even though it might upset the production of individual farmers.

Furthermore, very soon after the fifteenth congress, the cen- tral committee of the communist par ty adopted a resolution (June, 1928) for the development of a very ambitious program of state grain farming. It was resolved to organize a grain trust, the organization to include many very large state farms which, during the following five-year period were to be developed to such a degree that they would yield yearly from 1,600,000 to 1,700,000 tons of marketable grain, mostly wheat.

Thus ir appears that in 1927-28 the Soviet government returned to its old project of the development of large-scale farming

See "The ProbIem of Socialistic Reorganization of Agriculture," edited under the di- rection of Mr. J. A. Jakovleff, Moscow, 1928, preface, pp. XXVII-XXRrIII . ~Ir. Jakovleff actually is the Commissary of Agriculture of the U.S.S.R.

Page 12: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricult~tral Policy of Soviet Russia 291

along two lines ; collective farms and state farms. We have seen that during 1919-21 this project had failed and the Soviet govern- ment had been obliged to renounce ir. However, the Soviet gov- ernment considered itself now better prepared to start once more. Then, too, the political reasons for their policy were per- haps more urgent than they had been at the time of the first ex- periment. The difficulties encountered in supplying the city popu- lation with grain, to say nothing about exports which had been discontinued early in 1927-28, demonstrated clearly to the Soviet government the danger of the situation. These difficulties had been caused mainly by the resistance of the well-to-do peasant to selling surpluses of grain, ir any, at the low prices fixed by the government. These political considerations, more than any other reasons, induced the Soviet government to make itself inde- pendent of the well-to-do peasantry. The possibility of the de- velopment of agricultural production, based upon the initiative of the well-to-do peasantry was recognized as an alternative, but ir was rejected for political reasons and because this way was considered ca pitalistic and incompatible with communist prin- ciples. 11

The advocacy of such a "capita]istic" policy was laid by the ruling group at the door of the " r ight opposition" in the party. The ruling group itself accepted the policy of eliminating the in- dividual well-to-do farmers and replacing them by large state and collective farms although even in 1928 the efficiency of the exist- ing state farms was questioned by communist experts on agri- cultural problems su ch as the actual Commissary of Agriculture, and was considered to be lower than the efficiency of the large estates organized b y landlords in pre-war times. TM

The experience of 1919-21 had shown that ir was impossible to take lands for state farms from the peasants in the greater part of European Russia. For this reason, from the beginning, the organization of large-scale grain production on huge state farms was planned for unoccupied lands in sparse]y populated regions. In European Russia such unoccupied lands were to be found only in the regions east of the Volga and in the south-eastern corner, north of the Caucasus Mountains. These regions suffered the most from the famine of 1921 and the peasantry up to 1927- 28 could not occupy all the land here. As early as September, 1928, about 5,000,000 acres were set aside for the state grain

I' Op Cit., pp. XXVlI-XXVIII. Op. Cit., pp. XXVIII, 811-812.

Page 13: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

292 Vladimir P. Timoshenko

farms in this region. The other half of the planned 10,000,000 acres to be puf into state farms for the territory of western Si- beria and in the steppe region of central Asia. All these unoc- cupied lands may be characterized as semi-dry: the yearly rain- fall in all these regions is from ten to fourteen inches. Also there are great fluctuations in precipitation from year to year. The settlement of the peasant population on such lands is a risky enterprise because fa ihres of crops over several consecutive years are not infrequent and the support of a dense population on such lands during the periods of drought is a difficult prob- lem. This is one of the reasons why from the beginning the state farms in these regions were planned to be who]ly mechanized with a minimum of human labor and of livestock. All work was to be done by tractors and modern machinery, such as combines. The second reason for such an organization was that the Soviet government needed to obtain the largest possible surplus of grain from its farms. In order to utilize machinery and tractors most efficiently the state grain farms were planned to be of enormous size. By 1929 the average size of the 121 farms of the Grain Trust was given by official statistics at about 140,000 acres per farm. Many of them are much larger.

The first plan for the state grain farms, accepted in June, 1928, contemplated ah aggregate area of 10,000,000 acres, with a total production of marketable grain of about 1,600,000 to 1,700,000 tons. But early in 1929 this project was more than doubled, for ir was resolved during the five-year period to ex- tend the area of state grain farms from 25,000,000 to 30,000,000 acres, of which ]7,000,000 to 18,000,000 acres were to be in re- gions east of Ural, 8,000,000 to 9,000,000 acres in the basin of middle and lower u and in the North-Caucasian regions, and 4,000,000 to 5,000,000 acres in other regions of European Russia. In 1929-30, according to official data, 121 such farms were or- ganized with a total area of 17,000,000 acres, 2,500,000 of which were under crops in the summer of 1930.

The execution of this project required from the State the in- vestment of an enormous amount of capital. Ir was estimated that the organization and equipment of such farms, with a full suppy of tractors and modern tilling and harvesting machinery (mostly combines), would require about $15 per acre. Many Soviet authorities considered this estimate too low. Experience with estimates on other constructive works in Soviet Russia had shown that generally actual costs of construction were much

Page 14: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricultural Policy of Soviet Russia 293

higher than preliminary estimates. But even accepting this es- timate, the total investment in state grain farms would be not lar from a half billion dollars.

It is dii¡ to estimate at this time how suc~essful this ambi- tious project will be. Only two years have passed and ir is, of course, only for this short period that we know the results. In the year 1930 the weather was favorable to dry farming and ac- cordingly the yield must have been good, especially on prairie lands ploughed for the first time. As a matter of faet, most of the state farms were made up of virgin land. There are no re- liable data as to eosts of production on the state grain farms. It may be supposed that extensive small-grain farming on large farms supplied with modern machinery may be profitable if the management is ei~eient, but experience with state farms existing about 1919-20, in several regions of European Russia, indicated that generally their management was rather ineffieient. Further- more, in 1928 after several years of experience and reorganiza- tion, production on state farms was often less ei~eient than on small peasant farms. This situation was elearly reeognized in 1928 by the director of the agrieulturM policy of Soviet Russia. 1~

This may be said quite de¡237 even now, concernŸ the project of the Grain Trust: the investment by the state of enor- mous capital in such a hazardous enterprise m ay be considered very questionable at this time when Soviet Russia is suffering from a defieiency of capital for many other very important proj- eets. Ir would be mueh more reasonable to encourage invest- ments in agriculture by the peasants. State funds should be re- served for such projects as the development of transportation system, especially in new and sparsely populated regions ; recla- mation of lands, etc. But, as was said above, the policy of com- bating the well-to-do peasantry has discouraged them from sav- ings and investments. As we shM1 try to show later, even the or~anization of collective farms is going on largely on account of investments made for the most part by the state. Further- more, the recent agriculturM policy of the Soviet government has resulted in a very serious disorganization of the livestoek industry and now the Soviet government is obliged to start the new, and perhaps still more ambitious project, of organizing the animal industry on large state farms, united in trusts, sueh as "Skotovod" (cattle breeding trust), "Ovtsevod" (sheep breeding trust), "Svinovod" (hog-breeding trust), dairy trust,

ir See "The Problem of Socialistic Reconstruction of Agriculture," mentioned above, p. 822 .

Page 15: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

294 Vladimir P. Timoshenko

etc. These new state enterprises may well require still larger investments. Ir seems that these new and unexpected invest- ments in large agricultural enterprises are in a large me asure responsible for the unbalanced financial situation in Soviet Rus- sia last year and for the monetary inflation which exists unques- tionably. And the depreciation of the monetary unit may put many new difficulties in the way of the agricultural developments of Soviet Russia.

The organization of large-scale collective farms is a second line of socialistic reorganization of the Russian agricultural sys- teta. Ir was stated above that during the period 1921-27 collec- tive farms made little progress, and on the adoptŸ of the new economic policy (NEP) these farms passed through a serious crisis. Unprepared for doing business on a monetary basis com- parable with that of the ordinary cooperative farms with which they must compete, thecommunes and artels (different forros of collective farms) were broken up. According to statistics of the Central Statistical Office, out of 15,800 collective farms reported at the end of 1921, there remained by April, 1924, only 10,600.1~ The decrease was greatest in those organizations which were most socialistic~--the communes. The simpler voluntary associa- tions for the tillage of the soil were reduced to a lesser degree. In 1924 the decline in the number of collective farms ceased, and there was even a slight revival--the total number of producing associations increasing in one year by nearly 25 per cent. In 1925 there were 13,100 small collective farms. After that time, however, they increased at a slower rate and on June 1, 1927, official statistics give the number of all forms of collective farms at 14,800, which is less than in 1921. The increase since 1925 was due entirely to the fact that a simpler type of association was set up with the result that since 1928 their number has prac- tically trebled, while communes and artels have declined in num- ber. By the middle of 1927 all forms of collective farms con- sisted of less than 1 per cent (0.8%) of the total number of peas- ant households, and these sowed on]y 0.7 per cent of the total crop area. Thus their percentage of output in the total agricul- rural production of Soviet Russia was of minor importance.

During the period 1924-27 the government had granted some privileges to the agricultural collectives, such as tax reduction, special consideration in the supply of agricultural equipment,

14 Bulletin of the Central Statistical Office of the U.S.S.R. No. 102, July, 1925, pp. 73-75, and No. 116, Fob., 192{}, pp. 117-118.

Page 16: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricultural Policy of Soviet Russia 295

preferential treatment in land settlement, and so on, but these privileges were no longer of the exclusive character which ex- isted during the period when producers' associations were so much in voguew1919-20. I)uring this period official opinion ir- self did not estimate too highly the importante of collective farm- ing. Ir recognized the advantages of communes and artels from the point of view of socialist theory but did not regard them asa " t runk road" toward socialism, but merely a s a "branch road."

The situation changed completely after 1928. The Soviet gov- ernment, after proclaiming its poliey of eliminating the well4o- do peasants, decided to replace their marketable surpluses of agricultural products by those of co]lective tarros, and directed all its resources toward aiding these collectives, giving them in- numerable privileges, and at the same time, depriving the wealthier individual farmers of alI possibilities for development. The monopo]y which it had of agricultural markets and of the system of distribution for industrial products gave enough power to the government to enable it to follow such a policy. The colleetive tarros received considerable finaneial support in the form of cash credits and of special credits for the purchase of machinery. At the same time they obtained preferential treat- ment in the matter of purchasing machinery, while individual well-to-do farmers were limited in the machinery whieh they could buy. There were some kinds of machinery, such as trac- tors and other complex agricultural ma~hinery, which it was not permissible to sell at all to the "kulak ." The collective farms had also special privileges with reference to inclosing their land from community lands. This they could do at any time, without the approval of the community, even though this inclosure brought about a complete ehange in a recently established land organization of the community. (Decree, April 30, 1928.) By a decision of the Soviet government, the bulk of the expenses in- volved in consolidating the ]and into colleetive farms was as- sumed by the state, while individual tarros had to pay from their own resources at least part of such expenses. The tax payments of collective tarros were considerably redueed. Often these farms were entirely exempted from the payment of certain taxes. The granting of loans to collective tarros was so liberal that half or more of their means of production were acquired through state eredit (survey of collective tarros in 1928). Sometimes the credit obtained from the state exceeded the total value of the means of production of the collectives; that is, a part of the credit received

Page 17: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

296 Vladimir P. Timoshenko

by the collectives was used in the individual households of mem- bers. TM

Ir must be emphasized that the progress of collective farming in Soviet Russia was not a spontaneous movement of the peas- antry. I t was based on the privileges granted by the govern- ment to collectives and was limited in its development by the amount of ¡ assistance which the government w,as ready to grant. This fact is quite openly recognized by the Council for Collective Farms of the U.S.S.R. 16 Since in 1927-28 the Soviet government had more financial resources and could give more help to protected groups of peasants in the form of agri- cultural machinery than ir had been able to give during 1919-20, the development of co]lective farming after 1927 was much more rapid and extensive. Using official statistics of the progress of collectivization in Soviet Russia the following table may be given:

D E V E L O P M E N T OF COLLECTIVE FARMS IN SO~�91 R U S S I A

D ate l~umber of Col-

lective Fa rms ( I n thousands)

Number of l=[ouseholds iYlembers of Collective Farms

( I n per cent of total ( I n thousands) number of peasant

households)

J u n e 1, 1927 . . . . . . . . . . . 14.8 J u n e 1, 1928 . . . . . . . . . . . . 33.3 J u n e 1, 1929 . . . . . . . . . . . 57.0 October 1, 1929 . . . . . . . . . 67.4

195 0.8 417 1.7

1.003 3.9 1.919 7.4

0ver a period of less than two years and a half the number of peasant families involved in collective farming increased about ten times and by the fall of 1929 collective farms became a con- siderable factor in the agricultural activity of Soviet Russia.

Ir may be of interest to state that the growth of the idea of col- lective farming was not so rapid on all territory of Soviet Rus- sia as in the regions of surplus production of small grain, such as the steppe area. Several reasons may be mentioned why col- lective farming deve]oped more extensively and rapidly in the surplus grain producing regions. First, as we have seen, it was the policy of the government to increase the production of mar- ketable grain by collectives because ir was in the production of marketable grain that the government had met most of its diffi- culties. But there were other factors involved : crop production, and particularly small grain production, is the ¡ where col-

1~ See Gaister, A., "Dostizheniia i T rudnos t i Kolkhoznogo Stroitelstva (The Results and the Difliculties of the Organizat ion of Collective F a r m s ) , Moscow, 1929, pp. 33-34.

"Problems and Perspectives of the Organizat ion of Collective Fa rms . " The project of flve-year plan for 1928-1932-33, Moscow, 1929, pp. 41-102.

Page 18: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricultural Policy of Soviet Russia 297

lective farming by a group of former individual small farmers, may have some technical advantages, especially if the collective farm is supplied with modern agricultural machinery, which the small individual farmers either lack completely, or cannot use efficiently on their small holdings. Exactly these conditions were found to prevail in the steppe regions of Russia where there was a large percentage of peasant households without working live- stock and agricultural implements. This semi-proletarian peas- antry had increased its land holdings during the revolution, i t i s true, but had not enough means of production at its command to work its land efficiently. The character of this semi-proletarian peasantry was also a factor. Ir must be borne in mind that in Soviet Russia the development of collective farming has not been a peaceful process. Its evolution has been a kind of class strug- gle. The government has tried to enlist the support of the prole- tarjan and semi-proletarian groups in its struggle against the "capi ta l is t ic" elements in the country. In the steppe regions, with a sparser population composed largely of the well-to-do and semi-proletarian groups, the peasant class was, in general, less homogeneous than ir was in the more densely populated regions of central Russia, and ir was therefore easier to organize an in- tenml class struggle by giving privileges to some and withhold- ing them from others.

Furthermore, the method of farming in the steppe regions lends itsetf more readily to collectivization. Ir may be characterized as extensive since undiversified grain farming is predominant. The livestock industry is of secondary importance. All experi- ments with collective farming in Soviet Russia have shown that animal husbandry is the most difficult industry to collectivize and is least successful when accomplished. Generally speaking, col- lective farms are not stocked with livestock to the same extent as peasant farms and this is especially true with regard to cattle and other productive livestock. Individual peasant household- ers, joining collective farms, prefer to keep their cows, pigs, and sheep on theŸ own individual farms. For this reason, the re- gions devoted largely to animal husbandry, as opposed to grain production, are less adaptable to collectivization. Therefore, government help in supplying machinery to collective farms in these regions is of minor importance since machinery is of little use in this industry. The advantages of machinery are not enough to counterbalance the disadvantage involved in the col- lectivization of the livestock industry.

Page 19: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

298 Vladimir P. Timoshenko

Quite recently, following the failure of the collectivization caro- paign in the livestock industry during the past winter, the Soviet government granted further privileges to the collective farms, favoring the coIlectivization of livestock. For example, ir ex- empted from all taxation for two years the livestock of the mem- bers of collectives (see Resolution of the Central Committee of the communist party of April 2, 1930). If we take into con- sideration that the taxation of livestock of the individual farm- ers is very heavy and that it increases very rapidly with the in- crease in the number of head of livestock, the importance of the last privilege will be more evident.

We have tried to give some reasons for the rapid development of collective farming during the last two or three years. We shall now mention some of the limitations of this movement. One of the limitations has just been mentioned: collective farming de- velops more or less successfully only on crop farms. On the other hand, in animal husbandry collective farming up to the present has not been successful. For this reason the possibility of organizing collective diversified farming is questionable. It is true that there is a possibility of organizing collective crop farms, reserving animal husbandry to the individual households of the members of the collective farm. But it is against such a form of organization that the Soviet government contends. It fears that this practice would develop individualistic and capi- talistic tendencies in some of the members of the group. Another difficulty is the fact that the development of specialized collective grain farms does not correspond well to the type of agriculture prevalent in many regions of Soviet Russia. Furthermore, the distribution of labor throughout a y e a r is very uneven on the specialized collective grain farms, no better, in fact, than on the individual smM1 farm of the same kind.

A s a second limita tion that may be mentioned collective farms up to 1929 were too small to use successfully and efficiently such modern machinery as tractors, combines, etc. They included on the average ten to fifteen families, with seventy-five to one hundred and twenty-five acres of crops, which is not larger than the average individual farm in America. All attempts of the Soviet government up to 1930 to increase the size of the collective farms were rather unsuccessful. In 1930 the size of the collec- tire farms sharply increased, but about the methods of collectivi- zation during the winter 1929-30 we shall speak later.

Collective farms are very unstable in thei r organization and

Page 20: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agriculturat Policy of Soviet Russia 299

their membership. The fluid character of the membership of col- lectives was emphasized by all ofiicial studies of collective farms. The turnover of membership in the collective farms is so large that they have been called ironically "house with thorough- fare ." During each year of the period 1927-29, 15 to 25 per cent of the total membership left the collectives and was replaced by new members. At the same time yearly, about 20 to 30 per cent of the total number of collective farms were dissolved and new ones organized instead. Such an instability of membership and of the collective farms themselves without doubt, has interfered very much with a rational organization of farming. Official pub- lications have frequently emphasized the fact that collective farming introduces a more rational crop rotation of from six to eight years ' duration instead of the traditional three years ' ro- tation more common on the individual peasant farms. However, this statement must be challenged a s a t least too premature, be- cause after two or three years of experience it is difficult to say that a six to eight years ' rotation has been really successfully introduced.

Too much hurry and precipitation is perhaps the greatest dis- advantage in the campaign for collective farming in Soviet Rus- sia. It was mentioned above that during 1927-28 the number of peasant households involved in collective farming increased about tenfold. But this tempo (this word is actually very much in vogue in Soviet Russia) is nothing compared to the develop- ment of collective farming in Soviet Russia during the winter of 1929-30. What happened during this winter is difficult to under- stand. From 1927 to 1929 the principal method of stimulating the development of collective farming was the granting of privi- leges to the collective farms and to their members as opposed to the individual farmers. During the winter of 1929-30 the Soviet government, anxious to replace the production of the well- to-do peasantry by that of the collectives, and to "exterminate" the kulaks as a class, resorted to admfnŸ coerc/on and pressure on the peasantry to compel them to join collective farms. The fact of coercion and pressure was officially recog- nized by Stalin himself, in bis letter of March 2, 1930. In this letter, and in further publications of the communist press, nu- merous examples were given of stringent administration meas- ures used by local administrative officers to force peasantry into collectives. Stalin tried to disparage these measures and to make the local administration responsible for them. However, ir is

Page 21: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

300 Vladimir P. Timoshenko

difficult to believe that in Soviet Russia with its complete cen- tralization ir was possible for the local administration over a period of months to continue a policy which was contrary to the plans of the central government. Ir seems evident that it was the po]icy of the central government and that ir was only when it produced very dangerous unrest in the country that it was de- cided to retract a little and to put the responsibility on the local administration.

The pressure on the middle peasantry to join collectives was accompanied by a bitter struggle against the wealthier peasantry, the kulaks, by confiscation of all their property, and by expelling them from their residences.

To accept the wealthier peasants as members in collective farms was forbidden. They could not be accepted as simple workers on collective farms even after wholesale confiscation of their property. The fact that a cruel class struggle was wage'd and that the property of the kulaks was confiscated has been officially admitted, but the policy of the communist press has been not to go much into the details. However, it is quite clear that during the winter of 1929-30 a real civil war raged through Russian villages. This social revolution which swept over the country during that winter may turn out to be the most important since 1917.

The speech of the actual Commissary of Agriculture of the U.S.S.R. at the sixteenth congress of the communist party 1~ gave some interesting statistics as to the amount of confiscation of property from "kulaks." He stated that by the summer of 1930, 15 per cent of the capital of all collective farms consisted of property confiscated from "kulaks ." This calculation related only to buildings, machinery, equipment and livestock. Land was not included. When we take into consideration the fact that by the summer of 1930 from 40 to 50 per cent of peasant house- holds in some of the principal grain regions had become a part of the collective farm system and that the "ku laks" represent 3 to 5 per cent of the total number of peasant households, ir may be understood what great losses were suffered by them. The "kulaks" lost also all, or the greater part of their land.

In the same speech Mr. Jakovleff stated that two-fifths of the capital of the collective farms was covered by state credit, so that about three-fifths of the total capital of collective farms was given by the state or represented confiscations of property of

1~ See daily paper of the communist party, "Pravda , " No. 190, July 12, 1930.

Page 22: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricultura~ Policy of Soviet Russia 301

other peasants, who themselves were not admitted in the col- lective farm organization. Such were the "incentives" which brought the mass of semi-proletarian peasants to the collective movement.

The results of this double policy of coercion and of bribery were at first sight striking. 59.3 per cent of the total number of peasant households in Soviet Russia became members of the collective system on March 1, 1930.18 In some of the most im- portant agricultural regions with surplus grain production, the percentage of collectivization was announced still higher--70, 80, and 90 per cent. Thus, ah agricultural organization which had existed for hundreds of years was radically changed in a few months, 25,000,000 peasant households being affected. How- ever, this did not continue long. On March 2, 1930, Stalin pub- lished his famous letter which proclaimed that peasants were not to be forced into the collective system but could join them voluntarily, and there immediately began an outpour of forced peasants from collectives. Two months later, by May 1, 1930, officiaI statistics 19 showed that the percentage of collectivŸ peasant households was only 24.1 per cent, a de crease of more than one-half since March 1. On the other hand, there are some communist writers who doubt that many peasant households were actually members of the collective system on March 1, 1930, expressiag their opinion that many of the collective farms were listed only on paper. 2o Nevertheless, the process of the forma- tion of "collectives" as well as their dissolution (even if only " p a p e r " collectives) was not "painless." The second question raised was how many of the collectives reported on May 1, 1930, were real collectives. Statistics given out by the head of the Council of National Economy of Soviet Russia, Mr. Kuybyshev, show the percentage of collectivized peasant households on Oc- tober 1, 1930, to be 21.5 per cent, 21 that is, 2.5 per cent lower than on May 1, 1930. Is this ah actual decline, or simply a matter of having more exact statistics on this question?

tIowever, even if we accept the last estimate, this one-fifth representing collectivized peasant households can be a very im- portant factor in the agricultural situation in Soviet Russia, es- pecially if we take into consideration the fact that in the major

See article, "The Problems of Collectivization of the Country," by ~f. Kraev, Planovoe Khoziaistvo, 1930, No. 5.

1~ See "Agricultural Statistics of the U.S.S.R.," published by the Lenin Academy of Agri- cultural Sciences (in English), !~oscow, 1930, p. 42.

~o See above mentioned article of M. Kraev. See New York Times, December 1, 1930.

Page 23: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

302 Vladimir P. Timoshenko

grain surplus regions this pereentage is from thirty to fifty per cent. The question is only how vital are all these collec- tives. The fact that the percentage of collectivized peasant households may fluctuate during one $ear (from 7.4 per cent on Oetober 1, 1929, to 59.3 per cent on March 1, 1930, and 21.5 per cent on October 1, 1930) indicates that the situation cannot be said to be stable $et. Methods of promotion of the collective farm system and the difficulties of organizatŸ are important factors governing the situation. The authoritative Soviet or- ganization which controls collective farming in all the U.S.S.R. - - the Council for Co]lective Farms-- in its five-$ear plan for col- lectivization (1928-29 to 1932-33) recognizes these difficulties. For instance it states ~2 that ir is impossible to create successful collective farms without furnishing them with tractors and mod- ern agricultural machinery, yet only a sma]l percentage (not more than 15 per cent) of recently organized co]lective farms have tractors and the other farms continue to work with peasant horses and peasant implements. The greater number of tractors are found on the state grain farms. The total number of tractors in Soviet Russia is not large, a liberal estimate plaeing them at 70,000 to 75,000 on October 1, 1930.

The same Council recognizes that the organization of large collective farms is a much more difficult and complex problem than the organization of large state farms. I t was estimated that for the collectivization of 16 per cent of the peasants' households during the five-$ear period, ir would be necessary to engage a staff of eleven to twelve thousand college trained agriculturists, and ir would be necessary to reorganize all agricultural educa- tion of Soviet Russia for this purpose (p. 81). ttowever, one $ear later, in 1929-30, the Soviet government found ir possible to collectivize a much greater percentage of peasant farms and accomplished this in the one year, though without a sufficient number of trained agriculturists, and before the reorganization of the agricultural colleges was completed.

The result was that the collective farms were insufficiently staffed with trained agriculturists and were without competent assistants to organize even the simpler forms of accounting. ~3 At the same time, the size of these collective farms continued to in- crease so that, without question, they required the guidance of

0p. Cit., p. 16. "Problems and Perspectives of the Organization of Collective Farms," Moscow, 1929.

�9 8 See article, " In the Regions of Thorough Collectivization," by ~�91 Solomonov, Planovoe Khoziaistvo, 1930~ No. 2, Moscow, p. 239.

Page 24: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

New Agricultural Policy of Soviet Russia 303

experts, especially in organizing the work which, in the nature of the case, was radically different from the traditional form of peasant farming. On May 1, 1930, the collective farms, on the average, consisted of from sixty to seventy households, with a crop area of about 1,200 to 1,300 acres. In some of the regions much larger farms were found. The greatest difficulty encoun- tered in the organization of these large collective farms resulted from the low level of intelligence of the Russian peasantry and the lack of trained specialists. The Soviet government mobilized coercively all college trained agriculturists and sent them to the collective " f r o n t " (making use of militaristic terminology). Ir is perhaps incorrect to speak of " fo rced" labor in connection with these trained specialists, but ir is quite reasonable to desŸ nate this labor as "militarized."

What is especially dangerous for the stability of the new agri- cultural system in Soviet Russia--introduced in such a hur ry - - is the fact that ir was puf into effect with coercive methods, the system being forced on the peasantry, and being accompanied by a cruel campaign against the well-to-do peasantry.

As a result, in organizing agriculture into collective farms, the Soviet government disorganized all the social life of the countryside, and destroyed invaluable capital goods accumulated by the we]l-to-do peasantry during the preceding ten years. An illustration may be found in the great decrease in the number of livestock in the year 1929-30, a decrease so formidable that it would seem incredible if it were not confirmed by many authori- tative sources. :4 During one year the number of horses de- creased by 10 per cent, or 2,500,000 head, the number of cattle by one-fifth, or 15,000,000 head, the number of sheep by one-third, or 43,000,000 head, the number of swine by two-fifths or 8,000,000 head. Such a decrease of livestock in one year had never been known in RussŸ history. Even after the lamine of 1921 the losses of livestock were smaller, although millions of human beings were lost. This decline in the number of livestock dem- onstrates clearIy what a catastrophe occurred to Russian agri- culture during the last winter. Trying to so]ve one problem, to in crease grain production, the Soviet government destroyed a still more important, or at any rate, a branch of agriculture more dii¡ to recover. The policy of forced collectivization and the struggle against the well-to-do peasantry were responsible for

24 See speeches of Stalin and Jakovleff at the sixteenth congress of the communis~ party, Pravda, No. 177, June 29, 1930, and No. 190, July 12, 1930; also "Agricultural Statistics of the U.S.S.R.," mentioned above.

Page 25: VLADIlVira P. TIMOSHENKO

304 J. G. Ohsot

this catastrophe. The well-to-do peasant preferred to slaughter bis livestock rather than to have ir confiscated. The middle peas- ant, forced to join a collective farm, preferred before joining to selI or to slaughter bis livestock, for if he brought ir to the col- leetive fama it was accepted at a very low valuation. ~5 Many peasants joining collective farms expected that the government would give them enough tractors and equipment to enable them to work their land. Official propaganda in some regions designed to promote collectives, was perhaps responsible for such a be- lief. ~6

Now, in order to repair the damage to the livestock industry which its policy has caused, the Soviet government has started a new project of state organization of the livestock industry on huge state farms managed by the Trusts which have already been mentioned. These projects are still in their infancF and ir is impossible to say anything definitive about them, except that the application of bureaucratic forms of organization to this branch of agriculture may well be considered as still more ques- tionable than their application to the organization of grain pro- duction.

Discussios BY J. G. 0HSOL NEW YORK

I should like to ask Professor Tflnoshenko whether ir would not be more correet to explain the recent f a rm collectivization policy of the Soviet government by the impossibil t ty of coordinat ing large-sca]e p lanned state indus t ry wRh twenty-four million small peasant fa rms with very f luctuat ing returns~

Fur thermore , the very fac t t ha t within two years over tire million small farms have been merged into collectives would seem to indicate tha t this process of col- lectivization has been suppor ted by the bu]k of the peasantry~ else i t would have been impossib]e to keep them together by any eompu]sory means. Likewise this year~s inereased re turns of the grain harvest by 18 to 20 per cent eertain]y show tha t the large state grain and co]lective farms have met w i th ' apprec i ab le suceess.

This fa]]~ a f te r the peasants became convinced tha t the collective fa rms really insure be t te r yields and bet ter re turns for their labor they are apply ing in large num- bers for the admission to eollective farms.

Speaking of livestock farming~ one should remember tha t model beef eattle and dairy farms in this country are found among the largest~ not among the smallest farms. Wou]d ir net~ therefore, be fa i r to assume tha t the Soviet Union might a]so suceeed with the organizat ion of ]arge-scale livestoek farms~ Should we not rather await some positive proof befere pronouneing any deflnite judgment~

See article, "In the Regions of Thorough Collectivization," by M. Solomonov, mentioned above, p. 235.

Ibid~ pp. 235-236.