[email protected] -cired (cnrs, ehess, ecole des ...orar-0005 ). this work was also supported...

1
Modeling urban expansion Vincent Viguié*, Basile Pfeiffer, Quentin Lepetit . 5. References 4. Summary 2. Model (NEDUM-2D) across a panel of diverse cities 3. Applications Consequences of transport, land planning and economics policies on income repartition and slum development. (work in progress) Simulation of the share of the households earning less than the median income in Cape Town, South Africa Simulated impact of Grand Paris express metro line construction on rents Consequences of new transport infrastructures on urban development [9] Comparison of the spatial configurations of cities, and of the link with transport/land planning policies. (work in progress) Comparison of the spatial variation of rents in 7 Chinese cities [email protected] - CIRED (CNRS, EHESS, Ecole des Ponts ParisTech, AgroParisTech, CIRAD) Nogent-sur-Marne, France Taxation, building constraints and land planning policies consequences on real estate prices and urban development [2,4] Scenarios on cities future spatial expansion [6,8] Example of a scenario for Paris metropolitan area expansion between 2010 and 2100 [8] Economic-based urban expansion models can inform decision making, and derive prospective scenarios about cities future expansion/structure modification Such models can be coupled with environmental modules (flooding-prone zones, urban micro-climate, air pollution emission and dispersion…) The model we have developed, NEDUM2D, is able to dynamically assess variations in real estate prices associated with public investments or changes of urban planning regulations. This model is relatively easy to calibrate, and is based on robust and verifiable assumptions : it allows the user to easily understand the mechanisms involved and to understand clearly the uncertainty and the validity of the results obtained. Acknowledgements : These studies received financial support from the Agence Nationale de la Rercherche through the projects VITE (ANR-14-CE22- 0013-03) and DRAGON (ANR-14- ORAR-0005 ). This work was also supported by the World Bank and the French ministry of environment. Former members of the team include Stéphane Hallegatte and Paolo Avner. Much of this work was done thanks to them. Main cities studied using NEDUM-2D model The spatial structure of cities plays a key role on their energy consumption levels and on their vulnerabilities to environmental hazards. The type of urban growth that cities will experience in the next decades will therefore have major implications for climate change mitigation and adaptation. Objective In our work, we study and model the mechanisms driving the urban expansion of cities. We analyze economic, environmental and social consequences of policies aiming at impacting urban sprawl. Approach Urban shape is the result of 2 forces : State decisions : Land-use constraints, zoning, urbanism policies. . . Aggregation of multiple individual decisions taken by the inhabitants, and often reflected in a land market (these decisions can be influenced by policies, e.g. transport policies). The second force (the market) can be analyzed through economic models. We use such a model to simulate prospective scenarios of city growth and to assess the consequences of various policies. 1. Context and main ideas Using only the most fundamental economic principles from urban economics literature, NEDUM-2D model enables to model these interactions and to build scenarios on city conceivable future evolutions. It uses as inputs scenarios on the city’s future demography, transport system and land use constraints. This model is by nature an idealization of reality, but implementations on several cities on different continents have shown that it reproduces faithfully main characteristics of inhabitants residential choices, buildings construction and real estate prices across an urban area. Transport Land prices Land planning Transport, land planning policies and real estate prices each interact wit each other. Each of them impacts residential location choices of city inhabitants, which themselves act on land prices, and on transport demand. Implications of city growth scenarios in terms of greenhouse gases emissions, air pollution and natural hazards vulnerability [5,6,7] Example: simulation of air temperature change in case of heat wave, in a simulated scenario in which Paris region becomes less compact [5] Example: simulation of potential impacts on population density of a novel construction tax in Paris region. 1. Viguié, V. & Hallegatte, S. Trade-offs and synergies in urban climate policies. Nat. Clim. Change 2, 334–337 (2012). 2. Avner, P., Viguié, V. & Hallegatte, S. Modélisation de l’effet d’une taxe sur la construction. Rev. OFCE N° 128, 341–364 (2013). 3. Avner, P., Rentschler, J. E. & Hallegatte, S. Carbon price efficiency: lock-in and path dependence in urban forms and transport infrastructure. World Bank Policy Res. Work. Pap. (2014). 4. Avner, P., Mehndiratta, S. R., Viguie, V. & Hallegatte, S. Buses, houses or cash ? socio-economic, spatial and environmental consequences of reforming public transport subsidies in Buenos Aires. 1–54 (The World Bank, 2017). 5. Lemonsu, A., Viguié, V., Daniel, M. & Masson, V. Vulnerability to heat waves: Impact of urban expansion scenarios on urban heat island and heat stress in Paris (France). Urban Clim. 14, 586–605 (2015). 6. Houet, T. et al. Combining narratives and modelling approaches to simulate fine scale and long-term urban growth scenarios for climate adaptation. Environ. Model. Softw. 86, 1–13 (2016). 7. Masson, V. et al. Adapting cities to climate change: A systemic modelling approach. Urban Clim. 10, 407–429 (2014). 8. Viguié, V., Hallegatte, S. & Rozenberg, J. Downscaling long term socio-economic scenarios at city scale: A case study on Paris. Technol. Forecast. Soc. Change 87, 305–324 (2014). 9. Viguie, V. & Hallegatte, S. Urban infrastructure investment and rent-capture potentials. World Bank Policy Res. Work. Pap. (2014). Analysis of the consequencesof delays in the implementation of emission reduction at city scale [3] Relative impacts of carbon taxes on commuting- related emission levels in Paris region in 2020 for scenarios with and without public transport [3] Analysis of the trade-offs and synergies between mitigation and adaptation policies at city scale [1] Example of analysis in Paris metropolitan area[1] Adaptation and natural risk reduction Natural area and biodiversity protection Policy neutrality Housing affordability Climate change mitigation Do-nothing scenario Greenbelt policy Public-transport subsidy Zoning policy to reduce the risk of flooding

Upload: others

Post on 05-Feb-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Modeling urban expansion

VincentViguié*,BasilePfeiffer,QuentinLepetit

.

5.References4.Summary

2.Model(NEDUM-2D)

across apanelofdiversecities

3.Applications

Consequencesoftransport,landplanningandeconomicspoliciesonincomerepartitionandslumdevelopment.(workinprogress)

SimulationoftheshareofthehouseholdsearninglessthanthemedianincomeinCapeTown,SouthAfrica

SimulatedimpactofGrandParisexpressmetroline

constructiononrents

Consequencesofnewtransportinfrastructuresonurbandevelopment[9]

Comparisonofthespatialconfigurationsofcities,andofthelinkwithtransport/landplanningpolicies.(workinprogress)

Comparisonofthespatialvariationofrentsin7Chinesecities

[email protected] - CIRED(CNRS,EHESS,EcoledesPontsParisTech,AgroParisTech,CIRAD)Nogent-sur-Marne,France

Taxation,buildingconstraintsandlandplanningpoliciesconsequencesonrealestatepricesandurbandevelopment[2,4]

Scenariosoncitiesfuturespatialexpansion[6,8]

ExampleofascenarioforParismetropolitanareaexpansionbetween2010and2100[8]

• Economic-basedurbanexpansionmodelscaninformdecisionmaking,andderiveprospectivescenariosaboutcitiesfutureexpansion/structuremodification

• Suchmodelscanbecoupledwithenvironmentalmodules(flooding-pronezones,urbanmicro-climate,airpollutionemissionanddispersion…)

• Themodelwehavedeveloped,NEDUM2D,isabletodynamicallyassessvariationsinrealestatepricesassociatedwithpublicinvestmentsorchangesofurbanplanningregulations.

• Thismodelisrelativelyeasytocalibrate,andisbasedonrobustandverifiableassumptions :itallowstheusertoeasilyunderstandthemechanismsinvolvedandtounderstandclearlytheuncertaintyandthevalidityoftheresultsobtained.

Acknowledgements :Thesestudiesreceivedfinancialsupport fromtheAgence Nationale delaRercherchethrough theprojectsVITE(ANR-14-CE22-0013-03)andDRAGON(ANR-14-ORAR-0005).ThisworkwasalsosupportedbytheWorldBankandtheFrenchministryofenvironment.FormermembersoftheteamincludeStéphaneHallegatteandPaoloAvner.Muchofthisworkwasdonethankstothem.

MaincitiesstudiedusingNEDUM-2Dmodel

Thespatialstructureofcitiesplaysakeyroleontheirenergyconsumptionlevelsandontheirvulnerabilitiestoenvironmentalhazards.Thetypeofurbangrowththatcitieswillexperienceinthenextdecadeswillthereforehavemajorimplicationsforclimatechangemitigationandadaptation.

ObjectiveInourwork,westudyandmodelthemechanismsdrivingtheurbanexpansionofcities.Weanalyzeeconomic,environmentalandsocialconsequencesofpoliciesaimingatimpactingurbansprawl.

ApproachUrbanshapeistheresultof2forces:• Statedecisions:Land-useconstraints,zoning,urbanismpolicies...• Aggregationofmultipleindividualdecisionstakenbytheinhabitants,andoften

reflectedinalandmarket(thesedecisionscanbeinfluencedbypolicies,e.g.transportpolicies).

Thesecondforce(themarket)canbeanalyzedthrougheconomicmodels.Weusesuchamodeltosimulateprospectivescenariosofcitygrowthandtoassesstheconsequencesofvariouspolicies.

1.Contextandmainideas

Usingonlythemostfundamentaleconomicprinciplesfromurbaneconomicsliterature,NEDUM-2Dmodelenablestomodeltheseinteractionsandtobuildscenariosoncityconceivablefutureevolutions.Itusesasinputsscenariosonthecity’sfuturedemography,transportsystemandlanduseconstraints.Thismodelisbynatureanidealizationofreality,butimplementationsonseveralcitiesondifferentcontinentshaveshownthatitreproducesfaithfullymaincharacteristicsofinhabitantsresidentialchoices,buildingsconstructionandrealestatepricesacrossanurbanarea.

Transport

Land pricesLandplanning

Transport,landplanningpoliciesandrealestatepriceseachinteractwiteachother.Eachofthemimpactsresidentiallocationchoicesofcityinhabitants,whichthemselvesactonlandprices,andontransportdemand.

Implicationsofcitygrowthscenariosintermsofgreenhousegasesemissions,airpollutionandnaturalhazardsvulnerability[5,6,7]

Example:simulationofairtemperaturechangeincaseofheatwave,inasimulatedscenarioinwhichParisregionbecomeslesscompact[5]

Example:simulationofpotentialimpactsonpopulationdensityofanovelconstructiontaxinParisregion.

1.Viguié,V.&Hallegatte,S.Trade-offsandsynergiesinurbanclimatepolicies.Nat.Clim.Change2,334–337(2012).2.Avner,P.,Viguié,V.&Hallegatte,S.Modélisation del’effet d’une taxe sur laconstruction.Rev.OFCEN° 128,341–364(2013).3.Avner,P.,Rentschler,J.E.&Hallegatte,S.Carbonpriceefficiency:lock-inandpathdependenceinurbanformsandtransportinfrastructure.WorldBankPolicyRes.Work.Pap.(2014).4.Avner,P.,Mehndiratta,S.R.,Viguie,V.&Hallegatte,S.Buses,housesorcash ?socio-economic,spatialandenvironmentalconsequencesofreformingpublictransportsubsidiesinBuenosAires.1–54(TheWorldBank,2017).5.Lemonsu,A.,Viguié,V.,Daniel,M.&Masson,V.Vulnerabilitytoheatwaves:Impactofurbanexpansionscenariosonurbanheatisland andheatstressinParis(France).UrbanClim.14,586–605(2015).6.Houet,T.etal.Combiningnarrativesandmodelling approachestosimulatefinescaleandlong-termurbangrowthscenariosforclimateadaptation.Environ.Model.Softw.86,1–13(2016).7.Masson,V.etal.Adaptingcitiestoclimatechange:Asystemicmodellingapproach.UrbanClim.10,407–429(2014).8.Viguié,V.,Hallegatte,S.&Rozenberg,J.Downscalinglongtermsocio-economicscenariosatcityscale:AcasestudyonParis.Technol.Forecast.Soc.Change87,305–324(2014).9.Viguie,V.&Hallegatte,S.Urbaninfrastructureinvestmentandrent-capturepotentials.WorldBankPolicyRes.Work.Pap.(2014).

Analysisoftheconsequencesofdelaysintheimplementationofemissionreductionatcityscale[3]

Relativeimpactsofcarbontaxesoncommuting-

relatedemissionlevelsinParisregionin2020for

scenarioswithandwithoutpublictransport [3]

Analysisofthetrade-offsandsynergiesbetweenmitigationandadaptationpoliciesatcityscale[1]

ExampleofanalysisinParismetropolitanarea[1]

NATURE CLIMATE CHANGE DOI: 10.1038/NCLIMATE1434 LETTERS

Adaptation and natural risk reduction

Natural area and biodiversity protectionPolicy neutrality

Housing affordability

Do-nothing scenario

Greenbelt policy

Public-transport subsidy

Zoning policy to reduce the riskof flooding

Climate change mitigation

Figure 2 | Consequences of a greenbelt policy, a public-transport subsidyand a zoning policy to reduce the risk of flooding compared with thedo-nothing scenario. Axes orientation is such that directions towards theexterior of the radar plot represent positive outcomes. Preferred outcomesare a decrease in average distance travelled by car, in the population livingin flood-prone areas, in total urbanized area, in spatial Gini index, and anincrease in average dwelling size.

Figure 2 presents graphically the positive and negative impactsof the three policies. The impact of each policy on each indicatorhas been assigned a score and is located along one of the five axesof the figure. The �100% score is in the middle of the figure;the +100% score is at the extremity of each axis. All scores aremeasured relative to the do-nothing scenario, which is assigneda 0% score. The +100% score goes to the preferred outcomeamong all considered policies. Each policy is thus ranked bestwhen the corresponding coloured area is biggest. For instance,Fig. 2 shows that a public-transport subsidy improves the situationcompared with the do-nothing scenario for three policy goals(climate change mitigation, housing affordability, and adaptationand disaster risk reduction), and makes it worse with respectto two policy goals (natural area and biodiversity protectionand policy neutrality).

As Fig. 2 shows, each policy causes both positive and negativeoutcomeswith respect to different policy goals when comparedwiththe do-nothing scenario. Each policy thus seems to be undesirablebecause it has negative consequences with respect to at least onepolicy goal. This result can explain, for instance, why it is sodifficult to implement efficient flood-zoning or greenbelt policieson a local scale, even when it is required by national law14. Indeed,negative side effects on housing availability and on developmentopportunities understandably create political resistance.

However, as Fig. 3 shows, a mix that includes the three policiescan mitigate the adverse consequences of each individual policy.For instance, public-transport subsidies decrease the real-estatepressures caused by a greenbelt or a flood-zoning policy. Floodzoning also prevents the greenbelt from increasing the populationat risk of floods. When all three policies are applied together,the situation is improved as measured along all policy goalscompared with the do-nothing scenario. In particular, theseresults indicate that flood-zoning and greenbelt policies need tobe combined with transportation policies to gain real politicalmomentum and effectiveness.

Note that in a policy mix, the consequences of each policyare not simply additive. For instance, when all three policies areimplemented, the decrease in population in flood-prone areas

Adaptation and natural risk reduction

Public-transport subsidy, greenbelt policy and zoning to reducethe risk of flooding

Natural area and biodiversity protectionPolicy neutrality

Housing affordability

Do-nothing scenario

Climate change mitigation

Figure 3 | Consequences of a policy mix including all three policies. Axesorientation is such that directions towards the exterior of the radar plotrepresent positive outcomes.

is smaller than the sum of the variation caused by each policytaken separately. This nonlinearity and the complexity of policyinteractions explainwhy it is useful to analyse various urban policiestogether, in a consistent framework.

Our analysis shows that building win–win solutions by combin-ing policies is possible and leads to more efficient outcomes thana set of policies developed independently. Climate goals can thusbe reached more efficiently and with higher social acceptability,if they are implemented through taking into account existingstrategic urban planning, rather than by creating new independentclimate-specific plans. Such mainstreaming of climate objectiveswith other policy goals is found to help design better policies in ourmodel, confirming previous findings in other domains15–17.

Obviously, it does not mean that win–win strategies are alwaysavailable. In some cases, trade-offs will remain unavoidable andurban decision makers will need to make tough choices. Thiscan be done by associating different weights to our indicators—through a process of stakeholder engagement—and by maximizingthe resulting weighted sum of indicators. But our analysis showsthat a mainstreamed approach can allow for the design ofpolicies that are robust to differences in the weights of differentindicators, as they improve all indicators. Such policies areparticularly easy to implement, because they aremore likely to seemdesirable to all stakeholders, in spite of their different priorities,objectives and world views.

MethodsWe use the NEDUM-2D model to simulate the evolution of the Paris urban areabetween 2010 and 2030. This model is an extension of that described in previouspapers18,19, which is based on classical economic theory20–22. This theory explainsthe spatial distribution of land and real-estate values, dwelling sizes, populationdensity, and building height and density.

Our approach aims to bridge the gap between high-complexityland-use–transport interaction models23 and theoretical urban-economicsmodels. To do so, we propose a model that is fully based on microeconomicfoundations describing economic agent behaviours (like theoretical models), butthat can be calibrated on realistic transportation networks and include preciseland-use regulations and natural land characteristics (for example, rivers andother natural areas).

Two main mechanisms drive the model. First, households choose wherethey live and the size of their accommodation by assessing the trade-off betweenproximity to the city centre and housing costs. Living close to the city centrereduces transportation costs, but housing costs (per unit of area) are higher there.Theoretical extensions to account for decentralized production have been proposed,but are not included in this analysis24–26. Second, we assume that landownerscombine land with capital to produce housing: they choose to build more orless housing (that is, larger or smaller buildings) at a specific location dependingon local real-estate prices and construction costs. We assume that households

NATURE CLIMATE CHANGE | ADVANCE ONLINE PUBLICATION | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange 3

NATURE CLIMATE CHANGE DOI: 10.1038/NCLIMATE1434 LETTERS

Adaptation and natural risk reduction

Natural area and biodiversity protectionPolicy neutrality

Housing affordability

Do-nothing scenario

Greenbelt policy

Public-transport subsidy

Zoning policy to reduce the riskof flooding

Climate change mitigation

Figure 2 | Consequences of a greenbelt policy, a public-transport subsidyand a zoning policy to reduce the risk of flooding compared with thedo-nothing scenario. Axes orientation is such that directions towards theexterior of the radar plot represent positive outcomes. Preferred outcomesare a decrease in average distance travelled by car, in the population livingin flood-prone areas, in total urbanized area, in spatial Gini index, and anincrease in average dwelling size.

Figure 2 presents graphically the positive and negative impactsof the three policies. The impact of each policy on each indicatorhas been assigned a score and is located along one of the five axesof the figure. The �100% score is in the middle of the figure;the +100% score is at the extremity of each axis. All scores aremeasured relative to the do-nothing scenario, which is assigneda 0% score. The +100% score goes to the preferred outcomeamong all considered policies. Each policy is thus ranked bestwhen the corresponding coloured area is biggest. For instance,Fig. 2 shows that a public-transport subsidy improves the situationcompared with the do-nothing scenario for three policy goals(climate change mitigation, housing affordability, and adaptationand disaster risk reduction), and makes it worse with respectto two policy goals (natural area and biodiversity protectionand policy neutrality).

As Fig. 2 shows, each policy causes both positive and negativeoutcomeswith respect to different policy goals when comparedwiththe do-nothing scenario. Each policy thus seems to be undesirablebecause it has negative consequences with respect to at least onepolicy goal. This result can explain, for instance, why it is sodifficult to implement efficient flood-zoning or greenbelt policieson a local scale, even when it is required by national law14. Indeed,negative side effects on housing availability and on developmentopportunities understandably create political resistance.

However, as Fig. 3 shows, a mix that includes the three policiescan mitigate the adverse consequences of each individual policy.For instance, public-transport subsidies decrease the real-estatepressures caused by a greenbelt or a flood-zoning policy. Floodzoning also prevents the greenbelt from increasing the populationat risk of floods. When all three policies are applied together,the situation is improved as measured along all policy goalscompared with the do-nothing scenario. In particular, theseresults indicate that flood-zoning and greenbelt policies need tobe combined with transportation policies to gain real politicalmomentum and effectiveness.

Note that in a policy mix, the consequences of each policyare not simply additive. For instance, when all three policies areimplemented, the decrease in population in flood-prone areas

Adaptation and natural risk reduction

Public-transport subsidy, greenbelt policy and zoning to reducethe risk of flooding

Natural area and biodiversity protectionPolicy neutrality

Housing affordability

Do-nothing scenario

Climate change mitigation

Figure 3 | Consequences of a policy mix including all three policies. Axesorientation is such that directions towards the exterior of the radar plotrepresent positive outcomes.

is smaller than the sum of the variation caused by each policytaken separately. This nonlinearity and the complexity of policyinteractions explainwhy it is useful to analyse various urban policiestogether, in a consistent framework.

Our analysis shows that building win–win solutions by combin-ing policies is possible and leads to more efficient outcomes thana set of policies developed independently. Climate goals can thusbe reached more efficiently and with higher social acceptability,if they are implemented through taking into account existingstrategic urban planning, rather than by creating new independentclimate-specific plans. Such mainstreaming of climate objectiveswith other policy goals is found to help design better policies in ourmodel, confirming previous findings in other domains15–17.

Obviously, it does not mean that win–win strategies are alwaysavailable. In some cases, trade-offs will remain unavoidable andurban decision makers will need to make tough choices. Thiscan be done by associating different weights to our indicators—through a process of stakeholder engagement—and by maximizingthe resulting weighted sum of indicators. But our analysis showsthat a mainstreamed approach can allow for the design ofpolicies that are robust to differences in the weights of differentindicators, as they improve all indicators. Such policies areparticularly easy to implement, because they aremore likely to seemdesirable to all stakeholders, in spite of their different priorities,objectives and world views.

MethodsWe use the NEDUM-2D model to simulate the evolution of the Paris urban areabetween 2010 and 2030. This model is an extension of that described in previouspapers18,19, which is based on classical economic theory20–22. This theory explainsthe spatial distribution of land and real-estate values, dwelling sizes, populationdensity, and building height and density.

Our approach aims to bridge the gap between high-complexityland-use–transport interaction models23 and theoretical urban-economicsmodels. To do so, we propose a model that is fully based on microeconomicfoundations describing economic agent behaviours (like theoretical models), butthat can be calibrated on realistic transportation networks and include preciseland-use regulations and natural land characteristics (for example, rivers andother natural areas).

Two main mechanisms drive the model. First, households choose wherethey live and the size of their accommodation by assessing the trade-off betweenproximity to the city centre and housing costs. Living close to the city centrereduces transportation costs, but housing costs (per unit of area) are higher there.Theoretical extensions to account for decentralized production have been proposed,but are not included in this analysis24–26. Second, we assume that landownerscombine land with capital to produce housing: they choose to build more orless housing (that is, larger or smaller buildings) at a specific location dependingon local real-estate prices and construction costs. We assume that households

NATURE CLIMATE CHANGE | ADVANCE ONLINE PUBLICATION | www.nature.com/natureclimatechange 3