tutorial 1 suggested solutions

Upload: chiew-jun-siew

Post on 01-Jun-2018

225 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/9/2019 Tutorial 1 Suggested Solutions

    1/6

    EC3351 Public Finance 2014/15 Semester 1

    1

    Tutorial 1 Suggested Solutions 

    Q1. A negative externality: Deal, tax or pay-to-reduce?

    The market demand for a good is given by the equation Q D = 120 – 2P, while the market

    supply is given by the equation Q S = 2P, where P is the market price in dollars per unit.

    Production of the good creates a negative externality to third parties, and the marginal

    external cost associated with the Q th unit of the good is given by the equation MEC = Q.

    A.  Find the efficient quantity, the market equilibrium quantity and price. Compute the

    value of the deadweight loss associated with the market outcome. Use a diagram to

    illustrate your answers.

    Refer to the diagram drawn on theleft. To find the deadweight loss,

    you need to find the coordinates of

    the shaded triangle ABC.

    Point A is the market equilibrium.

    To find its coordinates, equate

    quantity demanded with quantity

    supplied: 120 – 2PM = 2PM 

    PM = $30 and Q M = 60, where

    subscript M denotes ‘market’. The

    market quantity is thus 60 units.

    Point B is the social optimum. Find

    its coordinates by equating MSB

    with MSC. The MSB equation is simply the demand equation with price (= $ willingness to

    pay by consumers) as the subject1: MSB = 60 – ½Q. The MPC equation is simply the supply

    equation with price (= $ willingness to accept by producers) as the subject: MPC = ½Q. The

    MSC equation is given by MSC = MPC + MD = 3Q/2. Diagrammatically, the MSC curve isthe vertical summation of the MPC and MD curves.

    Equate MSB with MSC: 60 – ½ Q = 3Q/2 Q* = 30 and P* = $45. The optimal quantity is

    30 units.

    The MSC corresponding to Point C is given by 3(60)/2 = $90.

    Thus, the area of the shaded triangle is ½(60 – 30)($90 – $30) = ½ (30)($60) = $900.

    1 Since there is no positive externality, MSB = MPB, so I will use MSB throughout.

  • 8/9/2019 Tutorial 1 Suggested Solutions

    2/6

    EC3351 Public Finance 2014/15 Semester 1

    2

    B.  Assuming transaction costs are negligible, describe an agreement between consumers,

    producers, and those affected by the externality, that would result in the efficient

    quantity being produced.

    Refer to the diagram from part A. If production shrinks from 60 to 30, consumer and

    producer surplus will shrink by the area of triangle ABD = $450. But third parties would

    gain $1,350, the area of trapezium ADBC2.

    Third parties can offer to pay market participants an amount between $450 and $1,350 in

    return for reducing production to 30 units, and market participants would agree to the

    deal. This is a Pareto Improvement over the market outcome.

    C.  Suppose instead that the government imposes a $T-per-unit Pigouvian Tax on

    producers. What is the value of T that would lead the market to produce the efficient

    quantity? How is the Pigouvian solution different from the private solution in part B?

    Since the vertical gap BD

    between MSC and MPC at the

    optimal quantity of 30 units is

    $30, a $30/unit tax (placed on

    producers in the diagram drawn

    on the left) will shift the supply

    curve up sufficiently for the

    market to reach equilibrium

    with 30 units produced. Thus, T

    = 30.

    As in part B, third parties gain

    the area of trapezium ADBC =

    $1,350.

    The government gains tax

    revenue = area of rectangle

    DEFB = $30 x 30 = $900.

    Market participants will lose surplus = area of triangle ABD + rectangle DEFB = $1,350.

    Although gains outweigh losses by the same $900 as in part B, the result here is not a

    Pareto Improvement over the market outcome, since market participants are worse off.

    2 This trapezium is equal in size to the area under the MEC curve (not drawn) between Q = 30 and Q = 60.

  • 8/9/2019 Tutorial 1 Suggested Solutions

    3/6

    EC3351 Public Finance 2014/15 Semester 1

    3

    D.  Suppose instead that the government pays producers $S-per-unit to reduce their

    production. Is there a value of S that would lead the market to produce the efficient

    quantity? How does this solution compare to the Pigouvian Tax solution?

    A payment of $30 per unit to reduce production will effectively shift producers’ supply

    curve up in exactly the same way as the Pigouvian tax of part C, and will thus also result in

    30 units produced. This is because each unit produced now incurs an additional cost of

    $30 in foregone government payment.

    As before, third parties gain $1,350. Government loses 30 x $30 = $900 in subsidy

    payments. Market participants gain $450. Once again, gains outweigh losses by $900, but

    the distributional implications are very different.

    In practice, it is probably not advisable to pay producers to reduce production, since this

    may attract more producers to enter the market!

  • 8/9/2019 Tutorial 1 Suggested Solutions

    4/6

    EC3351 Public Finance 2014/15 Semester 1

    4

    Q2. Controlling Emissions in a cost-effective manner

    This is a modified version of Question 12 in Chapter 5 of the textbook.

    Suppose that two firms emit a certain pollutant. The marginal cost of reducing pollution for

    each firm is as follows: MC 1 = 300e1 and MC 2 = 100e2, where e1 and e2 are the amounts (in

    tons) of emissions reduced by the first and second firms, respectively. Assume that in the

    absence of government intervention, Firm 1 generates 100 tons of emissions and Firm 2

    generates 80 tons of emissions, and thus total emissions stands at 180 tons. Regulators aim

    to reduce emissions by 40 tons i.e. to 140 tons.

    A.  Show that an emissions fee of $3,000 achieves the target at minimal cost. How many

    tons of emissions will each firm reduce? How much would each firm pay in taxes?

    With a fee, marginal costs are equalized, which is necessary and sufficient for cost

    effectiveness.

    As depicted in the diagram below, with a fee of $3,000, firm 1 cuts 10 tons while firm 2

    cuts 30 tons. Firm 1’s abatement cost is ½ x $3,000 x 10 = $15,000 (triangle ABC), while

    Firm 2’s is ½ x $3,000 x 30 = $45,000 (triangle AGH), so total abatement cost is $60,000.

    Firm 1 pays a tax of 90 x $3,000 = $270,000 while Firm 2 pays 50 x $3,000 = $150,000. 

    B.  If regulators instead

    command each firm to reduceemissions by 20 tons, how large,

    if any, is the resulting

    deadweight loss?

    Compared to part A, firms gain

    by not having to pay tax, but

    government loses by the same

    amount. If each firm does 20

    tons of abatement, Firm 1incurs a total abatement cost of

    ½ x $6,000 x 20 = $60,000

    (triangle ADE), while Firm 2 incurs abatement cost of ½ x $2,000 x 20 = $20,000 (triangle

    AFE). Total abatement cost is thus $80,000, which is $20,000 more than in part A. This

    $20,000 is the deadweight loss of inefficient pollution reduction.3 

    3

     An equivalent way of explaining the issue is to see that by moving to 20 tons of reduction each, firm 1 incursadditional abatement cost of trapezium BCED, while firm 2 reduces its abatement cost by trapezium FEGH. The

    former is larger than the latter by $20,000.

  • 8/9/2019 Tutorial 1 Suggested Solutions

    5/6

    EC3351 Public Finance 2014/15 Semester 1

    5

    C.  Instead of an emissions fee, the regulatory agency introduces a tradable permit system

    and issues 140 permits, each allowing one ton of emissions. Each firm is given 70

    permits. Assume that the firms act as price-takers. Show that equilibrium permit price is

    $3,000, and that the two firms will reduce emissions by the same amount as in Part A.

    If both firms act as price-takers, each firm will reduce pollution until the marginal cost of

    reducing a ton of pollution equals the permit price of $3,000. Thus, Firm 1 will choose to

    cut emissions by 10 tons. Firm 2 will choose to cut emissions by 30 tons. This is identical to

    the result in Part A.

    The diagram to the right shows

    the market for permits, with

    individual firm demand curves

    and the market demand curve

    (which is the horizontal

    summation).

    Firm 1 will want to buy 20

    permits, since it will emit 90

    tons but it only has 70 permits.

    Firm 2 will want to sell 20

    permits, since it will emit 50

    tons of emissions but has 70permits. Since 20 = 20, the permit market will be in equilibrium! Thus, $3,000 is the

    equilibrium permit price.

    D.  Suppose the marginal damage of emissions is found to be constant at $2,000 per ton.

    How should the government alter the number of permits, if at all, to obtain the optimal

    quantity of emissions?

    The marginal damage of emissions is the marginal benefit of reducing one ton of

    emissions. The optimal amount of pollution is obtained when this is equal to the marginal

    abatement cost. Thus, Firm 1 should reduce emissions by 2000/300 = 6.67 tons, while firm

    2 should reduce emissions by 2000/100 = 20 tons. Total abatement should thus be 26.67

    tons. The government should issue enough permits to allow for 153.33 tons of emissions.

  • 8/9/2019 Tutorial 1 Suggested Solutions

    6/6

    EC3351 Public Finance 2014/15 Semester 1

    6

    Q3. Applying the theory of externalities

    Assess the following situations and answer the following questions: (1) Does an externality

    exist? (2) Does the Coase Theorem apply? (3) what (e.g. legislation, regulation, tax, quota,

    etc. or do nothing) is the appropriate government response?

    A.  Crying babies in a restaurant

    1.  Crying babies in a restaurant create a negative externality, because the noise disrupts

    the dinners of other patrons but the babies’ parents do not need to take this into

    account.

    2.  Rights on noise can be assigned, and negotiation costs may not be prohibitive given

    the small number of parents with babies in a restaurant, with other patrons being

    represented by the restaurant management, which has a strong stake in maintaining a

    good dining environment. The Coase Theorem may thus apply, and a viable solution is

    to grant the rights on noise to restaurant management. Restaurants are free to bancustomers with crying babies or to ask mothers to bring babies outside until they quiet

    down.

    3.  Government should not do any further intervention.

    B.  Smoking in indoor indoor public areas

    1.  Smoking indoors in communal areas affects others negatively because of a number of

    reasons such as damage to health form passive (second-hand) smoking, irritation from

    the smoke, and increased risk of fire. Because these effects are not taken into account

    by the smoker and are not transmitted by market prices, they qualify as externalities.2.  As there are too many smokers and non-smokers, it is probably too costly to use the

    Coase Theorem to allow for negotiations after assigning legal rights in public

    communal areas. Yet the damage to non-smokers is substantial.

    3.  Some options for government response:

    a.  A tax placed on cigarette purchases would harm smokers even if they smoke

    outdoors (where the external costs are much smaller).

    b.  A tax placed on smoking activity  indoors, operating akin to an emissions fee,

    would be more suitable, but it is extremely difficult to implement as it requires

    tracking the number of cigarettes each person smokes in all indoor public

    areas.

    c.  A third option is to do nothing (in effect giving non-negotiable rights to

    smokers). This places the burden of adjustment on non-smokers – they have to

    endure the smoke or walk away from it. Second hand smoking is extremely

    harmful to health, and the added risk of fire is not trivial.

    d.  A fourth option is to impose a ban on indoor smoking in public areas. This

    places the burden of adjustment on smokers, but it is not a heavy adjustment

    because they can still step outdoors for smoke breaks. This is likely to be the

    least costly option.