trentmann - political culture and political economy - interest, ideology and free trade.pdf

Upload: bejmanjin

Post on 02-Jun-2018

221 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    1/36

    Political Culture and Political Economy: Interest, Ideology and Free TradeAuthor(s): Frank TrentmannReviewed work(s):Source: Review of International Political Economy, Vol. 5, No. 2 (Summer, 1998), pp. 217-251Published by: Taylor & Francis, Ltd.Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/4177265.

    Accessed: 27/12/2011 17:17

    Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at.http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp

    JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of

    content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms

    of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact [email protected].

    Taylor & Francis, Ltd.is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access toReview of

    International Political Economy.

    http://www.jstor.org

    http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=taylorfrancishttp://www.jstor.org/stable/4177265?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsphttp://www.jstor.org/stable/4177265?origin=JSTOR-pdfhttp://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=taylorfrancis
  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    2/36

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    3/36

    ARTICLES

    and

    transnational

    flows of

    capital,

    technology

    and

    knowledge.

    On

    the

    other, revisionists have

    exposed

    the normative

    binary

    structures

    of

    gender,

    progress

    and

    underdevelopment.

    This article

    is

    designed

    to

    con-

    tribute to this ongoing debate by adding a historical perspective on the

    cultural foundations

    of a

    subject

    central to

    political

    economy:

    free

    trade.

    Free trade

    occupies

    a

    privileged

    position

    in

    liberal

    schools

    of

    political

    economy.

    For economists

    it is a

    theory

    of welfare

    optimization:

    societies

    specialize

    where

    they

    are

    most efficient

    according

    to

    comparative advan-

    tage.

    For realist scholars

    it

    plays

    a

    central

    role

    in international

    relations,

    expressed

    in

    concepts

    of

    hegemony. For

    public

    choice

    analysts,

    it

    informs

    both the

    methodological application of economics

    to

    politics

    and

    the

    political programme for eliminating the wasteful 'rent-seeking' activities

    of

    producer interests.

    Inevitably,

    discussion of

    present

    models

    and

    future

    policy

    has

    tumed

    to 'lessons of the

    past'.

    This

    has not

    been

    an

    unprob-

    lematic

    exercise, for free trade

    appears

    simultaneously

    as

    both

    historical

    subject

    and

    analytical

    method.

    The

    aim of this

    article is

    to enter the

    debate about

    method

    from a

    historical

    inquiry

    into

    the

    relationship

    between

    political

    economy

    and

    political culture

    in

    free trade Britain.

    Free trade had

    been

    the

    pillar

    of

    British

    political

    economy since

    the

    repeal of the

    Com

    Laws in

    1846 and

    withstood the international drift towards neo-mercantilism in the late

    nineteenth

    century.

    Joseph

    Chamberlain's tariff

    reform

    crusade

    in

    1903

    put the

    future of

    free trade once

    again at

    the centre of

    British

    politics.

    The

    ensuing 'fiscal

    controversy'

    culminated in the

    1906 election,

    at which

    the

    protectionist

    programme of

    imperial

    preference and

    a small duty on

    foreign corn

    (2 shillings per

    cwt)

    and

    manufactures (10

    per cent) was

    decisively defeated and

    the survival

    of

    free

    trade secured.

    This article

    takes the fiscal

    controversy as its

    starting

    point, using it in

    Section I to

    problematize economistic arguments that explain trade regimes exoge-

    nously, that

    is, by the

    location of trades or

    sectors

    in the world

    economy.

    This

    general

    critique is

    illustrated

    through a

    discussion

    of the historical

    and

    conceptual

    limits of a recent

    sectoral

    analysis of

    the 1906

    election.

    The

    discussion

    highlights two

    equally

    problematic

    dichotomies

    under-

    lying

    conventional

    approaches to

    free

    trade: between

    state and

    market,

    and

    between

    ideas and

    interests. In

    contrast to

    the universalist

    method-

    ology

    of

    individualist

    rational

    agents or

    emphasis on

    cosmopolitan

    interests,

    Section II outlines

    an

    alternative

    historical

    perspective, focusing

    on the collective and ideological dimension in political economy. Section

    III

    explores

    the

    political ideas,

    values and

    discourse that

    shaped group

    interests and

    identities in the

    British

    debate about

    free

    trade. This

    involves two

    related shifts in

    analysis:

    one from an

    exogenous to an

    endogenous

    plane,

    the other from

    questions of

    cui bonoto

    those of

    cultural

    significance.

    The

    power of free

    trade, it is

    argued,

    depended on

    the

    ideological construction

    of 'the

    consumer', on

    national identity, and

    218

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    4/36

    POLITICAL

    CULTURE

    AND POLITICAL

    ECONOMY

    on

    moral and civic

    virtues,

    not

    on

    individual

    self-interestor the

    logic

    of

    the free

    market.The article concludes

    in

    SectionIV with a

    discussion

    of the

    place

    of

    ideas

    and

    political

    culture

    in the

    study

    of

    political

    economy. Politics and economy, far from separate, emerge from this

    interpretationas

    overlapping spheres

    held

    together by

    webs

    of

    cultural

    meanings

    and

    practices,

    a

    perspective

    that, admittedly,

    lacks the

    parsi-

    mony

    of

    economistic

    models

    but

    may

    shed

    new

    light

    on the

    changing

    historical place of

    economic

    ideas

    in

    political

    life.

    I HISTORICAL AND

    CONCEPTUAL

    DEFICITS OF

    SECTORAL

    ANALYSIS

    Victorian Britain

    was the

    only society to

    embrace a

    pure,

    unilateral

    system

    of free trade after the

    repeal

    of the Corn Laws

    (1846).

    That Britain

    did

    so

    naturally

    because of

    the prominence

    of

    export

    industries

    and

    the

    City

    has

    long been

    a

    common notion.3

    J.

    S. Mill

    maintained

    n

    1868

    that

    'it would have been

    long

    before the

    Corn

    Laws would have been

    abol-

    ished

    ... if

    those laws had not been

    contrary

    to the

    private interests of

    nearly the

    whole of the

    manufacturing

    and

    mercantile classes'.4

    Argu-

    ments have

    come

    in

    stronger

    and

    weaker

    forms,invoking

    the

    power

    of

    entire sectors or of smaller interest groups, trades and firms. In

    hegemony arguments,

    for

    instance,

    the

    influence of the

    City has

    been

    invoked to

    explain why Britain did not

    revise

    its

    internationalism

    n

    response to relative decline

    after the 1880s.5

    Publicchoice theorists

    have

    presented the Anti-Corn

    Law

    League

    as a

    vehicle of the cotton

    industry,

    seeking to abolish duties on

    its

    raw

    material

    and

    oppose

    factoryreform.6

    These different

    analyses share basic

    methodological

    problems. First,

    the

    mode of

    argument often

    employs post

    hoc

    propter

    hoc reasoning:

    because internationallyoriented sectors benefit from free trade, a free

    trade

    system reflects the power

    of these sectors. How

    economic inter-

    ests translate

    nto

    politicalpower and

    popular

    movements is left vague.

    Second, they cannot

    explain

    the

    specificity of

    policies,

    whether bilateral

    and

    moderate free

    trade, as

    in

    the United States after

    the Second

    World

    War,

    or

    unilateral and

    dogmatic 'Free

    Trade'

    in

    Victorian and Edwar-

    dian

    Britain.

    The

    relationshipbetween national

    economic structure

    and

    tariff

    levels is left

    unspecified;Britain

    rejecteda smaller

    dose of protec-

    tion

    than

    that in

    force

    in

    more export-oriented

    countries like

    Denmark

    or Switzerland.7Today, the only genuine free tradecountry n the world

    is

    land-lockedMongolia.8

    This

    indeterminacy, inally, is mirroredat

    the

    microeconomic

    level.

    The universalist

    assumptions

    of neo-classical

    economics can

    tell us as

    little

    about the

    varied strategic behaviour

    of

    firms and

    trades as about

    that of the

    varieties of capitalism, which

    are

    conditioned

    by culture and institutions.9

    References o a

    trade'sgeneral

    interest do

    not explain the strategy chosen

    to attain it. If

    free tradedoes

    219

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    5/36

    ARTICLES

    not serve their

    goals, export

    trades can turn to

    reciprocity,

    cartelization

    or other forms of

    trade

    regulation.10

    These

    problems

    are rooted

    in

    the

    methodological

    basis

    of

    economistic

    argument. A strong illustration is offered by Douglas Irwin's recent

    sectoral

    analysis

    of the

    1906

    election,

    'The

    political

    economy

    of

    free

    trade'.11 Irwin's

    model

    is

    predicated on

    methodological

    individualism.

    Electoral behaviour

    is determined

    by self-seeking

    material

    interest alone.

    It

    expresses

    an individual's

    sectoral position

    rather than

    ideology, social

    position

    or

    cultural

    identity.

    In

    line

    with

    recent

    'industry

    approaches',

    this model

    presumes imperfect factor

    mobility, especially

    of

    labour.

    In

    contrast to the

    classic

    Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson

    model,

    which

    assumed mobile factors of production, the decisive variable is a sector's

    international

    location, not the

    relative abundance of

    capital

    or

    labour.

    Irwin

    concludes that the

    election

    confirms

    the

    general thesis that

    'all

    factors employed

    in

    a

    given sector see their fate tied to the

    economic

    fortunes of that sector.

    Consequently,

    voters would favour

    any policy

    that

    increases the relative

    price of the

    output produced

    by

    the

    sector

    in

    which

    they

    are

    employed.'12

    To bring

    into

    focus the limits of the

    sectoral model for

    political econ-

    omy,

    we will

    first examine

    historically its principal

    assumptions: sectoral

    unity, economic knowledge and the deduction of political choice from

    sectoral

    interest.

    Sectoral analysis

    hinges

    on two

    basic propositions:

    united sectoral

    behaviour and

    labour

    support

    for

    protection

    in

    import-

    competing sectors

    (and

    for

    free trade

    in

    export-oriented

    ones).

    Yet

    'sectors'

    have

    proved

    a

    problematic

    category

    for

    understanding protectionism

    in

    Imperial

    Germany

    and the inter-war

    United States.13In

    the British

    case,

    the units

    used by

    Irwin, such

    as 'chemicals'

    or 'iron and

    steel', covered

    such a

    variety of processes with

    different markets and

    import/export

    ratios that any aggregate use is

    questionable.14

    Few trades shared the

    sectoral

    coherence of

    the cotton

    trade, which imported

    its

    raw

    material but

    exported

    its

    manufacture, and

    overwhelmingly opposed tariffs.

    In

    many

    industries

    the product of

    one trade is the

    input of

    another, and here

    firms

    and

    their

    workers

    occupy different,

    often

    conflicting positions in

    inter-

    national trade.

    Nor is the

    assumption of

    imperfect

    labour

    mobility

    unproblematic. Seasonal

    labour

    and multiple

    occupations

    continued to be

    widespread

    at the turn

    of the century. In

    Monmouthshire, for

    example,

    three-quarters of field

    workers still

    worked also

    in

    the wood and

    mining

    industries.15

    These

    complexities

    are obscured in

    aggregate

    net export figures

    which,

    according to sectoral

    reasoning, explain Liberal

    support

    from the iron

    and

    steel,

    coal

    mining, engineering,

    shipbuilding,

    chemicals and

    woollen

    trades.16

    Yet

    in

    three of these

    -

    iron

    and steel,

    engineering and

    wool

    -

    owners,

    unlike

    their

    workers,

    had joined the

    growing

    chorus for fiscal

    reform at

    the turn of

    the century.17

    How shall we

    explain

    these opposite

    220

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    6/36

    POLITICAL CULTURE AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

    trends

    among capital

    and

    labour?

    Did businessmen

    fail to

    understand

    their sectors' 'real' interests?

    The turn from unilateral free trade to reciprocity

    in

    sections

    of the

    busi-

    ness community illuminates the danger of inferring a politico-economic

    position from

    an

    export/import

    ratio.

    Rather,

    the

    crucial

    variable

    was

    businessmen's

    perception

    of a

    changing

    international

    position

    and of

    the

    best strategy to preserve competitiveness. Surrounded by

    new

    mercan-

    tilist barriers and deprived of the lever of

    tariff

    bargaining,

    the woollen

    trades

    -

    still exporting three times more than imports

    -

    called for retali-

    ation to halt the closure of foreign

    markets.18 Other

    trades were

    deeply

    divided about the nature of their interest. The tinplate

    industry

    was

    split

    on

    how

    to

    respond

    to the

    loss

    of their

    principal

    US

    market

    after

    the

    McKinley tariff. Steel-tinplate makers favoured

    tariffs. Smaller

    makers,

    however, believed free trade guaranteed their autonomy by

    preserving

    a

    range of alternative supplies of cheap steel.19 The absence of

    a united

    trade

    profile extended to Chamberlain's

    Tariff

    Commission.20

    Even in

    the City of London, the heart of Britain's cosmopolitan

    power,

    a

    neo-

    mercantilist mood was rising. The City had been divided

    during

    the

    earlier

    movement to free trade. Now

    in

    1903,

    the

    leading

    stockbroker

    Faithfull

    Begg warned that

    [j]ust

    in

    proportion as

    Great Britain built

    up

    the

    prosperity

    of

    foreign

    nations under

    a

    system

    which

    gave equal advantages

    in

    her markets, so she was creating a race of commercial

    rivals, who,

    when the

    time came, would be attacking her

    with

    their ships

    and

    destroying her commerce.21

    Fiscal

    reform would benefit capital interests where

    unilateralism

    had

    failed,

    a

    conclusion which commanded a majority in the London

    Chamber of Commerce in a poll in 1907. These divisions undermine not

    only

    notions of

    sectoral unity but also the picture of a united

    capital-

    labour

    alliance for free trade in capital- and

    labour-abundant economies

    (like Victorian Britain) painted in studies based on

    the Stolper-

    Samuelson

    theorem.22

    Labour's place in the political economy of trade conflicts with the

    second

    sectoral

    assumption: the correlation between import competition

    and

    protectionism. The Labour Party and trade unions

    rejected protec-

    tion

    outright

    in

    1903,

    in

    spite of cyclical depression and

    unemployment.

    Can two million workers be 'wrong'? Opposition rallied together export

    trades, like cotton and shipping, with those facing import

    competition,

    like

    fine

    chemicals and the heavy sections of the iron and steel industry.

    Support

    for

    protection was limited to a few marginal trades, like flint

    glass making.23 Labour did not support tariffs in a single

    major trade

    until

    the

    late 1920s; then, interestingly, support came first from the

    woollen industry, which was still exporting four times

    the amount it

    221

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    7/36

    ARTICLES

    imported.24 Even in

    agriculture,

    protection

    failed to

    win

    over

    workers.

    In

    fact, the Liberal

    triumph

    in

    1906

    was most

    pronounced

    in

    pre-

    eminently arable,

    import-competing

    rural

    areas like the

    south-east.25

    The divisions within trades highlight the sociological deficit in the

    sectoral

    approach.

    The

    hypothesis

    that

    capital

    and

    labour

    equate

    their

    interests

    with

    their sector's does not

    take

    into

    account the

    asymmetry

    underlying capitalist

    society.

    Modem

    industry

    is

    not

    an

    association

    of

    free

    producers. The exchange of

    wage

    for labour

    places

    workers

    and

    entrepreneurs

    in

    unequal positions.

    This makes for different

    associa-

    tional practices.26

    It

    also

    provides

    social

    groups

    with uneven

    knowledge

    for collective action.

    It

    is a long way from the world market

    to

    the local

    polling booth.

    Vertical

    and

    horizontal

    divisions

    of labour

    deprive

    actors of the knowl-

    edge necessary

    to

    make

    a

    uniform assessment

    of trade

    policy

    and

    its

    effects

    on their

    work,

    firm

    or sector.

    They

    are

    separated

    not

    merely from

    the

    end product of

    their labour,

    but

    also from information about

    origin

    of

    input,

    destination

    of output, profit

    and

    productivity.

    Workers

    re-

    rolling steel do not necessarily know

    whether

    the firm's

    ingots come

    from South Wales

    or Westphalia, or

    whether their labour ends up

    in a

    bridge across the

    Thames or the Hudson. All

    this, of course, raises

    general questions about exogenous perspectives, which presume indi-

    viduals' knowledge of

    the complex

    present and future state of markets

    and its

    automatic

    translation

    into

    personal interests and political strat-

    egies. Capitalism

    might

    be said to be

    no more prone to generate sectoral

    unity

    than

    class

    unity.

    In

    the

    absence of transparency,

    protectionist

    entre-

    preneurs tried to shape their

    workers' economic

    knowledge through

    educational

    campaigns

    or

    later, more crudely, by

    exhibiting

    foreign

    articles on the

    shopfloor.27

    The conceptual and empirical problems involved in a sectoral expla-

    nation

    of free trade are connected

    to a deductive

    treatment of politics.

    To test

    the sectoral

    model, Irwin

    reconstructs the election into 'a

    case

    of

    direct

    democratic

    voting on trade

    policy'.28 Political realities,

    however,

    were more complex.

    Divisions

    among Conservatives between

    protec-

    tionists,

    reciprocitarians and free

    traders, the number of

    contests

    between

    Liberals, Labour and

    socialists, and the

    combination of free

    trade with

    other significant

    issues, make it

    impossible to read the

    election

    as

    a

    simple

    contest

    between Conservative protectionism

    and

    Lib-Lab Free Trade.29 Arguably, it was the very combination of free

    trade with

    other issues, such as

    education reform,

    Taff Vale and 'Chinese

    slavery',

    that

    proved significant

    among key voting

    groups like Noncon-

    formists and

    organized labour.30To reduce voting

    to an

    individualist

    act of

    assessing the

    sectoral costs

    and benefits of trade policy

    brackets

    the

    collective

    dimension of politics: party allegiance,

    mobilization,

    social

    solidarity

    and

    discursive practices.31

    On a

    fundamental statistical level,

    222

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    8/36

    POLITICAL CULTURE AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

    there is

    an

    "ecological fallacy"

    here: constituencies are not sectors.

    Conclusions

    about the

    political

    outlook of an

    occupational group

    cannot

    be drawn from the electoral

    returns

    and

    occupational

    structures of

    constituencies.32

    Finally, the analysis

    is

    complicated by

    the introduction

    of a non-

    sectoral variable: consumption.

    Two-thirds of all

    employees worked in

    non-traded goods sectors and spent nearly

    half

    the

    family budget

    on

    food. Surely, their interest

    in

    cheap

    food

    made them natural free traders.

    The problem with this reasoning

    is that it

    explains

    not too little

    but too

    much.

    The

    only

    votes

    for

    protection

    should

    have come

    from

    the

    small

    group of import-competing

    interests. Yet

    Liberals

    received

    less than

    50

    per cent of the vote.33 In any modern society consumers far outweigh

    workers in import-competing trades.34

    In

    a democratic vote, free

    trade

    would be a natural

    winner

    emerging spontaneously

    from the

    ubiquity

    of consumer preferences.

    Yet 'the consumer

    interest' is

    no more

    a natural

    given than 'the producer interest'. It represents no unambiguous,

    separate, group,

    but

    an

    interest

    in

    conflict

    with and

    part

    of other

    social

    roles. 'Everyone

    and at

    the same

    time no one is

    a

    "consumer"',

    as Offe

    has succinctly put

    it.35

    Two dimensions therefore need

    to be

    sharply distinguished

    in

    political

    economy. An economistic analysis models

    individual

    preferences as if

    atomistic, fixed

    and

    universal.36 The

    collective

    meaning of 'the consumer'

    and

    the changing social

    and

    political significance

    of untaxed food are

    not,

    however,

    a

    simple aggregation of

    individual

    preferences. Its formation

    is a problem of

    a

    quite different dimension concerning collective values

    and the

    discursive construction of

    'the

    public interest'.

    What

    needs

    explaining

    is how

    free

    trade was

    of

    such

    significance

    to

    Britons that

    any

    departure

    from

    it

    became a

    central subject

    of

    politics.

    What

    made it

    possible for the diffuse public interest to defy the logic of collective action,

    overcome

    the free-rider

    problem,

    and

    avoid

    the

    vicious cycle of rent seek-

    ing predicted by public choice theory?37How to account for free trade's

    special historical significance

    in a

    society which enjoyed the highest

    standard of

    living

    and had

    overcome

    systemic food shortages long before

    its neighbours? The inquiry, then, must look beyond material interests to

    the collective meanings

    and

    discursive practices that helped translate

    individual

    interests into

    a

    broader conception of political economy and

    assigned

    free

    trade

    an

    iconic position.

    In

    short, it is necessary to shift the

    inquiry from economic function to cultural significance.

    II

    IDEOLOGY

    AND

    INTEREST

    This

    shift

    opens up three dimensions for political economy: economic

    knowledge;

    the

    ideological

    nature

    of interest; and the constitutive role of

    political languages.

    The

    interpretative framework

    of

    past actors is easily

    223

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    9/36

    ARTICLES

    lost in

    reconstructions

    of interests

    through

    the

    lens

    of

    present

    neo-

    classical

    theory.

    Recent social

    history

    has

    produced

    well-documented

    doubts

    about

    the triumph

    of

    a

    differentiated market

    society

    and

    its

    social

    reach in nineteenth-century Europe.38The economy, like society or poli-

    tics, is not a

    separate, self-explanatory

    universe that

    comes

    with an

    unam-

    biguous

    interpretation

    attached.

    Rather than

    beginning

    with

    notions of

    market

    rationale

    and

    social

    totality,

    economistic

    approaches

    would have

    to show how historical actors came

    to know of the

    economic world and

    of the material

    consequences

    of fiscal

    policy

    - and

    how

    groups

    could fail

    to

    recognize their

    'real'

    interest.

    Some

    in

    the

    City perceived

    economic

    trends as

    supporting

    fiscal reform.

    Organized

    labour

    understood

    the

    fiscal

    controversy

    in a

    national

    sociopolitical

    context as a

    battle

    between

    democracy

    and

    reaction,

    between classes not

    trades,

    a

    battle over

    the dis-

    tributive

    politics

    of taxation not sectoral interests.

    Tariff

    reform was

    not

    dismissed

    only

    as

    a

    bad

    bargain

    for

    export

    trades. It

    was viewed as

    a

    con-

    spiracy

    by capitalists

    and

    old elites to

    suppress

    social

    democracy

    and rob

    the

    working people

    of their

    fair

    share of the national

    income.39

    In

    theory, it is

    possible

    to

    weigh

    a

    tariff's direct

    impact

    on

    prices

    against

    its

    more indirect influence on

    wages.

    Even

    if

    employers kept

    all

    additional

    profits,

    a tariff

    might

    increase real

    wages

    through

    an

    increase

    in demand for labour in the protected sector. Such reasoning, however,

    never

    played

    a

    major

    historical role. Labour

    focused instead on

    the loss

    to national welfare from tariff

    wars,

    declining competitiveness

    abroad,

    and

    lower

    purchasing power

    at home.

    History,

    not

    trade

    theory,

    provided the framework of

    analysis.

    The Trades Union

    Congress rejected

    protection

    in

    one

    voice

    as

    nothing better than a

    delusive

    and

    plausible

    fallacy; neither

    history,

    observation,

    nor

    experience justifies

    it.

    The

    history

    of

    every

    country

    proves beyond a doubt that just in proportion as protective tariffs are

    heavy, wages are low, and

    where they

    are light, wages are high.40

    The

    universal-historical association

    between

    protection and low wages

    illustrates

    how

    far

    popular

    knowledge transcended

    strict

    economic

    reasoning.

    Contemporaries would have been

    astonished to hear that

    trade

    policy played

    only

    a

    marginal role

    in

    their

    economic lives and in

    national

    development

    or

    to see

    it

    reduced to

    a

    'secondary power

    struc-

    ture'.41 Even

    at

    the

    height

    of

    the

    Great Depression

    and even in

    import-

    competing trades, a belief in the collective benefits of free trade retarded

    the

    advance of

    protectionism.

    Popular

    pamphlets offered

    historical read-

    ings of the

    economy. Joseph Arch, the

    leader of the

    National Agricultural

    Labourers'

    Union,

    emphasized

    in

    1884 that

    '[t]he

    natural

    effect of

    Protection

    is

    to

    restrict

    trade,

    and

    restriction

    means less

    of everything for

    the

    working

    classes.

    This is

    proved by actual

    experience. The darkest

    days

    in

    our

    history were

    those of

    Protection'42. Historical

    memory

    proved

    224

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    10/36

    POLITICAL

    CULTURE

    AND

    POLITICAL

    ECONOMY

    stronger

    than

    an individualist

    weighing

    of short-term costs and

    benefits.

    By the

    late

    nineteenth

    century,

    the

    long story

    of

    popular

    opposition

    to

    liberal trade

    -

    from

    eighteenth-century

    food riots to

    early

    Victorian

    Chartism - had fallen victim to a lapse in collective memory. Historical

    and

    theoretical

    counter-examples

    alike vanished from the

    new

    'progres-

    sive'

    story

    of free trade. The

    complex

    relationship

    between tariffs

    and

    wages,

    as in the

    high-wage

    high-tariff

    USA,

    was

    easily ignored.

    So

    too

    were the

    more immediate reasons for the

    sharp

    drop

    in

    food

    prices,

    which

    had less to do with

    fiscal

    policy

    than with

    the

    growth

    of Midwestern

    and

    Russian farms and the

    revolution

    in

    intemational

    transport.

    Such

    ideological readings of the

    economy

    raise

    fundamental method-

    ological issues. Conventional

    political economy, though interested

    in

    the interaction

    between

    politics

    and

    economy,

    is

    founded

    on

    their

    conceptual separation

    into

    distinct,

    indeed

    opposed, systems

    of

    state

    and

    market.43

    This

    presupposes

    an

    economic

    sphere

    governed

    by

    instru-

    mental

    rationality,

    naturalistic and

    free of

    ideology,

    a

    view that can be

    traced back to

    Enlightenment notions of the

    market

    taming

    the

    passions

    and

    that,

    subsequently, neo-classical economics

    developed

    into

    a

    scien-

    tific

    paradigm.

    It

    has

    supported

    a liberal

    metanarrative

    separating

    free

    trade,

    the

    pure

    agent

    of

    economic truth,

    rationality

    and

    progress,

    from

    the many guises of protection: fallacy, ideology and reaction. Ideology

    is

    reduced to

    a

    protectionist tool for

    capturing votes or

    deceiving

    governments.44

    Sound

    theory

    and

    cool-headed

    analysis, however, are

    able

    to

    bring 'reality' into focus.

    'Broad

    economic principles

    always

    in

    the end

    defeat the

    sharp devices of

    expediency',

    the young Winston

    Churchill reassured

    the

    Free

    Trade

    League.45 Free

    trade,

    in

    this

    confi-

    dent

    liberal

    view, is already

    rational: it

    is non-ideological.

    The

    view

    of

    separate

    systems has been a

    pleasant

    illusion. It has

    allowed the reconstruction of interest from economic reality and their

    clean

    separation

    from

    political

    culture,

    bracketed as

    epiphenomena. This

    has made

    it

    difficult

    to interpret the

    changing location and

    meaning of

    economic ideas

    like free

    trade, because

    it

    has tended to close

    an analyt-

    ical

    space for the

    relatively autonomous

    role of

    ideas and discourse. The

    economist

    framework

    leaves

    little room for

    exploring the

    formative role

    of

    ideas

    in

    shaping interest, because it

    envisions an

    atomistic, fixed indi-

    vidual,

    not

    a

    living member

    of a community,

    political

    culture or

    preinformed world.

    With sufficient

    information,

    rational interest is the

    direct expression of an objective economic position. Like functionalist

    explanations

    in

    general,

    this

    approach looks to

    needs as

    the causal

    motive

    for want satisfaction.

    As

    Luhmann has observed, the

    equation

    between need and

    motive produces an

    equation between

    imagined effect

    and

    its cause.

    It

    tends

    towards

    tautology. Moreover, the

    economy is not

    immune

    to

    how it

    is

    observed and understood

    -

    in

    the past or

    present.46

    We

    cannot

    reconstruct an

    economic reality

    separate

    from its past

    225

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    11/36

    ARTICLES

    interpreters. Rational choice

    becomes a troublesome

    tool, at a time

    when assumptions

    of

    social

    totality

    and

    correspondence

    theories

    of

    reality have become questionable. Ideology

    and

    language, then,

    far

    from

    being instrumental or epiphenomenal, are essential cognitive tools: they

    turn an overwhelming, contingent

    world

    into

    controllable, meaningful

    reality.47 In short, they help to constitute political economy.

    The formation of

    interest s not

    an unmediated

    process by

    which

    the

    economy imprints

    itself

    on the mental

    landscape

    of the

    individual.

    Rationality stands for

    what

    social actors

    find

    plausible

    and

    meaningful

    at

    a

    historical moment

    rather than for

    what

    might

    be

    theoretically

    'true'.

    Interest comes from

    inter-esse to be between.

    Interest has

    had

    evolving

    meanings and functions, from compensation

    in

    Roman

    law,

    a

    euphemism

    for

    usury

    in

    the Middle

    Ages,

    to

    foreign policy

    interest

    of states in

    the

    early

    modern

    period,

    when the

    concept

    came to

    embrace

    competing

    economic

    and

    ideological groups

    as well as individual rational

    behaviour.

    There

    was yet

    no inherent discursive conflict

    between ideas

    and

    interests.

    For much of the

    modern period

    the

    concept remained ambiguous,

    still

    referring

    to the interest

    of

    humanity

    in

    general

    as

    well as to

    particular

    material

    interests

    or Sonderinteressen.

    n

    nineteenth-century politics,

    the

    language

    of

    'interest' functioned to

    maintain a

    conservative relation

    between property and rights. A new language of 'organized interest

    politics' only emerged

    in

    the

    early twentieth century, accompanied by

    the

    growing importance

    of

    corporate organizations

    in

    defining

    as

    well as

    mediating

    the

    'interests' of their members.48

    In

    Britain,

    this

    development

    was retarded; the Federation of British Industries was not founded until

    1916. Present narrow categories of interest may obscure the historicity of

    'interests'

    and

    past systems of political economy.

    The market

    speaks

    in

    many tongues. Economy and politics can be

    viewed as interdependent, interpenetrative spheres, linked through

    culture.

    The cultural foundations of economic theories have received

    generous attention.49

    In

    popular knowledge, too, different perceptions

    have structured and

    read

    the

    economy

    in

    different ways. Free trade

    was no

    exception, though its ideological power in legitimating itself as

    common

    sense

    and a

    scientific fact as indisputable as gravity has helped

    to

    dehistoricize it. The

    argument here is not that there may not be good

    reasons

    in

    economics for liberal trade. But this view of political economy

    is itself so

    clouded

    by

    the

    normative lens of economic liberalism that it is

    bound to produce a distorted historical picture, blind to the changing

    functions

    and

    meanings

    of

    free trade, from statism among Physiocrats

    and

    the ideal

    of

    an

    agrarian republic in revolutionary France, to the divine

    design

    of

    a

    'stationary, self-acting,

    and

    unprogressive model' held up by

    early

    Victorian

    Evangelicals,50

    all

    the way to a modernizing engine of

    growth, globalization and progress, more familiar from economic text-

    books since.

    226

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    12/36

    POLITICAL

    CULTURE

    AND POLITICAL

    ECONOMY

    Liberal political

    economy

    in

    Victorian

    and Edwardian Britain

    ulti-

    mately rested not on economic interest or

    theory

    but

    on

    a

    moral-political

    conception

    of free trade.

    It is not

    possible

    to derive the historical

    signif-

    icance of 'free food' from the size of the food bill. As a collective identity

    and

    social movement,

    free

    trade

    culture,

    after

    all,

    was

    unique

    to

    Britain,

    and not shared

    by societies

    then,

    before

    or

    since

    in

    which

    people spent

    more than

    half

    their income on food.

    That

    it

    was

    unwise

    to

    rely

    on

    the

    consumer as

    a natural

    champion

    of free trade was not lost on

    Cobden-

    ites at the turn of the

    century.

    They

    feared that

    when bad

    times

    come,

    the more

    ignorant

    classes

    will

    listen to

    any

    quack who

    professes

    to have

    a

    remedy

    for the

    troubles

    they

    are

    feeling.

    Moreover,

    as each

    year

    passes

    the

    number

    of those who

    can

    personally

    remember the

    pinch

    of Protection

    grows

    rapidly

    less.

    Therefore it is

    necessary that

    some agency should be

    constantly on

    the watch

    to combat

    every

    [protectionist] attempt.51

    Liberal

    'enlightenment' did

    more

    than

    just overcome costs of

    infor-

    mation for the

    'ignorant classes'

    by

    communicating

    economic

    data.

    After

    a

    summer of ministerial debate and

    resignations

    in

    1903,

    the

    question

    of free trade was thrown open to the public. Its survival now became

    dependent on

    popular support.

    The

    fiscal

    controversy

    developed

    an

    ideological

    momentum of its

    own that

    transcended the concrete

    economic issues at stake.

    Informed

    foreign

    observers

    deplored

    the

    public

    debate's lack of

    'rational', 'scientific'

    analysis.52

    Why was this?

    Liberals

    then,

    and

    historians

    since, were quick to

    expose the

    distortions

    and

    contradictions

    in

    Chamberlain's

    picture

    of

    fiscal reform as

    a

    panacea

    for

    national

    decline. Yet the lack of

    'rationality'

    was not all in one

    corner.

    The

    battle

    was not one

    between 'Fact

    versus Fiction', as the

    Cobden

    Club

    labelled it.

    Both sides worked with

    ambiguous

    statistics

    and

    prob-

    lematic

    economic

    categories.53

    Liberal language

    provided

    ideological

    bonds

    for

    public

    mobilization, set the

    parameters

    of

    the public

    debate

    over

    political economy,

    and

    relegitimated free

    trade as

    the only

    rational,

    indeed

    natural, system.

    Two

    discursive achievements

    need to be

    emphasized. For one,

    liberal

    ideology quickly

    eliminated the

    space for rival

    policies, most

    impor-

    tantly reciprocity, which

    Liberals

    attacked as

    protectionism in

    disguise.

    Trade diplomacy was denounced in general declarations that any depar-

    ture

    from

    unilateralism would

    end

    in tariff

    wars, a

    food tax

    and an

    omnipotent

    executive.

    This

    was part of a

    larger ideological

    momentum

    that

    polarized

    discourse between

    pure free

    trade and alternative

    regimes.

    Complex

    relations

    of

    political

    economy were

    reduced

    to

    a

    stark choice

    between

    two

    exclusive

    world-historical systems.

    Campbell

    Bannerman,

    the

    leader

    of the

    Liberal

    Party,

    proclaimed in 1904:

    227

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    13/36

    ARTICLES

    [w]e

    stand to-day

    at the

    parting of the ways. One road ...

    leads

    to

    Protection,

    to

    conscription,

    to the

    reducing

    of

    free

    institutions

    to

    a

    mere

    name....

    And the other road leads to the

    consolidation

    of liberty and the development of equity at home, and to treaties

    of arbitration

    and

    amity

    ... and

    the lightening of

    taxation, which

    presses

    upon

    our trade and

    grinds

    the faces of

    the

    poor.54

    The discursive construction

    of free

    trade into the sheet anchor

    of

    liberal

    civilization

    deflected

    both

    from

    the

    (historically)

    limited influence

    of

    free

    trade on life and from alternative

    orders of

    democracy,

    such as

    pluralist

    corporatism.

    Liberal

    bodies and radical movements

    like the

    Free

    Trade

    Union,

    the

    Cobden Club, the Free Food League and the two million-strong Coop-

    erative

    movement

    provided

    the

    public

    with the

    interpretative

    frame

    for

    political economy through

    leaflets and rallies.

    It

    is more

    useful to

    view

    these

    groups

    in

    terms

    of

    a

    social movement

    than

    interest-pressure

    groups.

    They were popular

    and self-financing,

    with a

    diverse

    member-

    ship

    that included

    women.

    Their

    roots

    in

    civil

    society

    and their

    defence

    of

    universal free trade contrast

    with the

    more

    limited,

    recent

    'anti-protec-

    tion' campaigns led by narrow

    interest groups against

    trade-specific

    restrictions; the Free Trade Union focused on 'the public interest' and,

    significantly, only

    had one

    researcher preparing

    material

    on

    specific

    trade

    interests.55 They helped to construct the public

    significance

    of

    free

    trade

    by providing associations between the

    national

    economic interest

    and

    political legitimacy.

    A

    liberal

    song

    rallied audiences

    against Cham-

    berlain's

    campaign to 'Tax, Britannia ':

    Tax, Britannia,

    if

    British

    commerce dies,

    At

    least

    the

    prices

    that we pay shall rise

    But, if you think protection made

    For dupes who

    cannot think or see,

    Be this the charter

    of your trade,

    The world

    our market and our

    people free

    Then, rule

    Britannia, Britannia rule the waves,

    Britons

    never,

    never,

    never shall

    be

    slaves 56

    Free

    trade was central to the 'structure of political

    discourse', to borrow

    Peter Hall' s

    apt concept.57 However, in contrast to

    later economic theory,

    like Keynesianism, free trade with its popular, ideological body played

    a

    more

    constitutive,

    self-generating role in creating the very structure

    and

    dynamic of political

    discourse. Rather than

    being differentiated as

    'rational'

    economic discourse, public argument

    and political action

    concerning trade were

    embedded

    in a

    cultural web

    of associations and

    narratives that tied free trade

    to national liberty,

    social justice and inter-

    national

    peace.

    228

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    14/36

    POLITICAL

    CULTURE

    AND POLITICAL

    ECONOMY

    III COLLECTIVE REPRESENTATIONS

    OF FREE

    TRADE

    'The

    consumer' was at

    the centre of

    this web. The defence of free

    trade

    depended on the defence of the consumer

    as the

    imagined guardian

    of the

    public interest. The

    political

    nation was defined as

    a

    nation

    of

    consumers, represented

    in

    Parliament. The state's function

    -

    represented

    in

    the Treasury

    doctrine

    of

    taxation for revenue

    only

    -

    was

    to

    defend

    the

    freedom of

    all consumers

    alike.

    A

    healthy body

    politic,

    in

    this

    vision,

    depended on free

    consumers rather than the

    preservation, say,

    of

    'national

    productive interests', classes or communities like

    farming.

    In

    a

    period of limited

    democratic

    and

    socioeconomic

    rights,

    free trade served

    as an

    alternative form

    of

    public

    inclusion,

    accountability

    and

    social

    jus-

    tice, as radical and women's groups reminded voters and politicians.58 As

    a

    language of

    indirect, passive

    inclusion it

    bridged

    the

    gulf

    between

    the

    restricted

    equation

    of citizenship

    with

    property

    in

    the

    nineteenth

    century

    and the

    more

    universal

    democratization of

    active political and

    social

    rights

    in

    the

    twentieth, the

    Scylla and

    Charybdis of liberalism.

    Fiscal

    equity

    and

    political

    legitimacy

    were

    interlocking:

    parliamentary

    sover-

    eignty

    was

    believed to

    depend

    on

    free trade. Was a tariff

    not

    'the

    mother

    of

    trusts',

    giving

    birth

    to

    a new

    absolutism of

    vested

    interest,

    favouritism

    and an overweight executive? Free trade was linked to a public ideal of

    the

    'purity

    of

    politics',59

    which it

    insulated from the

    economy

    and

    private

    interests. Politics

    and

    commerce, in Lloyd

    George's

    characteristic warn-

    ing

    to

    businessmen,

    were

    'like two

    chemicals

    ...

    all

    very well

    if

    kept

    apart,

    but if

    mixed,

    there

    was

    an

    explosion'.60

    By

    invoking

    the

    autonomy

    of the

    market and

    by equating public and

    consumer, then, free trade

    spoke

    directly

    to the

    liberal

    political

    elite,

    seeking

    to

    preserve

    the

    autono-

    my

    of

    the political from

    the

    claims of

    socioeconomic

    groups and out-

    siders.

    Liberals

    opposed even

    anti-monopolistic

    measures, such as

    the

    countervailing

    of

    bounties under

    the

    Brussels

    sugar

    convention

    of

    1902,

    for fear

    of

    subjecting Parliament and

    consumer to a

    foreign tribunal.61

    The

    unifying influence of

    consumption made free

    trade an

    agent of inter-

    national

    peace.

    'It

    is through

    consumption', Hobson

    argued,

    'that the

    co-operative nature and

    value

    of

    commerce is realized.

    Production

    divides, consumption

    unites.'62

    'The consumer'

    here

    was a cultural con-

    struct,

    signifying

    an

    inclusive

    'public interest'

    rather than an

    atomistic

    individual

    with

    given

    economic

    preferences

    -

    not to be

    confused

    with the

    materialist, conformist 'consumerism' discussed today.

    By

    transcending

    the language of

    economic

    utility, these

    associations

    were

    flexible

    enough to

    connect with

    several strands

    in liberal

    political

    culture.

    On

    one

    extreme

    was the

    individualist

    libertarian

    linkage

    between

    economic and

    political

    freedom. An

    old liberal

    steelmaster, for

    instance, condemned

    protection, because 'I

    shall be

    called upon to give

    up my right to

    buy where

    I

    please

    and compelled to

    buy

    where the

    229

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    15/36

    ARTICLES

    Governmentwills'.63On the other,liberal reformerswere able to

    present

    free

    trade

    as

    the natural

    complement

    of social

    legislation,

    a view

    well

    captured

    in

    posters showing Asquith

    as a free trade

    John Bull,

    with

    one

    hand giving cheap sugar to a little girl, and with the other giving old

    age pensions

    to an

    aged couple.64

    The

    popular connection

    between

    political

    freedom

    and

    consumer

    freedom

    was

    no instant,

    automatic

    product.

    The Gladstonian

    marriage

    between popular liberalism

    and radicalism65 ushed

    aside earlier asso-

    ciations between freer

    trade and attacks

    by

    the

    rich on the

    rights

    of

    'the

    people'.

    The demand for

    the

    'Free BreakfastTable' was an article

    of

    faith to the National

    Agricultural

    Labourers' Union and

    helped to

    preserve Liberalsupportin rural areasafter the suffragereformof 1884.

    Edwardian free trade was able

    to draw on the radical

    milieu

    to recon-

    struct the

    moral-political

    discourse

    against

    tariffs.

    The past, however, provided more

    than

    just

    a

    direct ine of

    political

    tra-

    dition. The free

    trade defence also involved

    the

    dynamic

    reconstruction

    of historical

    memory.

    While

    protectionists

    were

    prophesying decline,

    free

    traderswere

    legitimating

    their cause

    by refashioning

    he

    past.

    The

    repeal

    of

    the Corn Laws here

    represented

    the

    crucial

    turning point

    in

    the

    story

    of

    liberty

    and

    progress.

    It

    provided

    an

    essential

    movement narrative

    by

    fusing individual memorieswith the larger public interest.Repealhad

    given

    the

    labourer

    'a

    more generally-recognizedposition

    in

    the State',66

    in

    the

    recollection of

    Holyoake,

    the old Cooperative eader.

    The

    rewrit-

    ing of history reached its most

    ambitious

    stage

    with

    the invention of the

    'hungry

    forties'.

    In

    1904, upon

    the initiative of Cobden

    Unwin,

    a

    collec-

    tion

    of

    select

    labourers'memories

    of the

    'hungry

    forties'

    was published.

    A

    'people's

    edition' was issued

    in

    1905.

    By

    1912a

    penny edition

    had

    sold

    110,000 copies,

    a

    bound

    copy another 100,000.

    Personal

    memories of

    material misery under protection were interwoven with associations

    between free

    trade, political liberty and social stability. The ambivalent

    experience

    of

    the 1840s was crystallized into a simpler image of the

    protectionist past to appeal to the present needs of liberal memory.

    Edwardianfree traders concluded for their readers that 1846 had deliv-

    ered

    the

    English nation from

    'an

    Egyptianbondage'; tariffs threateneda

    return to

    social disintegrationand civil war.67

    The

    free tradebig loaf and the protectionist ittle loaf

    -

    symbols already

    employed by Cobden

    and

    prominent

    n

    the HungryForties ollection and

    Edwardianposters and propaganda- need to be read in the context of

    these cultural

    associations.The 'cheap oaf' was an icon of national iberty

    and

    progress. Fiscalpolicy here appearedcentral o the course of national

    history,

    in

    contrast to

    economic historians' reassessmentsmore recently

    that it

    played

    at

    best

    a

    marginal role. Immediate material concerns fail

    to

    explain this discrepancy,because on their own they do not turn indi-

    vidual

    grievances into collective ideals or action. Whether,and to what

    230

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    16/36

    POLITICAL

    CULTURE AND

    POLITICAL

    ECONOMY

    degree,

    a

    small

    2

    shilling duty

    on corn

    would

    increase the cost of

    living

    was hotly debated

    at

    the

    time

    -

    the

    price

    of bread

    in

    most towns

    had

    remained

    unaffectedby the

    short-lived corn

    duty (3d.)

    of

    1902-3.68

    The free trade vision was sustained by a contrast between British

    progress

    and civilization and

    foreign

    reactionand

    backwardness.

    mper-

    ial

    Germany

    served

    as the

    principal

    other',

    a

    stereotypical

    counter-image

    that

    is more

    revealing

    about British iberal

    culture than about

    contempo-

    rary

    politico-economic

    realities;

    Germany

    was

    a

    low-tariff,

    autocratic

    constitutional

    monarchy,

    Franceand the

    US

    high-tariff

    epublics.

    The

    free

    trade

    campaign

    amplified horror

    stories of

    starving

    and

    disempowered

    Germansdependenton

    blackbread and

    dog

    meat

    -

    even as

    Germany

    was

    becoming

    a

    relatively

    more egalitarian

    society.69

    Germany

    exhibited the

    symptoms

    of

    the lethal

    'poison'of

    protection

    hat

    would

    inevitably

    spread

    throughout he

    body politic.

    'If

    this

    country

    wanted German

    ariffs',

    Lloyd

    George

    warned

    audiences

    in

    1905,

    'it

    must

    have German

    wages...

    German

    militarism,

    and

    German

    ausages....

    They

    could

    not have British

    freedomand

    British

    wages

    along with

    German

    Protection.'70

    his

    view

    of

    Germany, ike the

    absolute

    rejection

    of

    reciprocity,

    reflected

    the

    dogma-

    tism

    of

    the liberal

    Weltanschauung,nable

    to

    appreciate

    eitherthe

    relative

    autonomyof the

    state or the

    possibility of

    integratingcorporate

    associa-

    tionsintomoderndemocracy:twas fearedthateven a small tariffortrade

    regulationwould

    unleash a

    vicious

    circle of

    uncontrollablevested

    inter-

    ests,

    ungovernability

    and

    autocracy.

    The

    'cheap

    loaf',

    then,

    symbolized

    a

    pillar

    of liberal

    society.

    It

    stood

    for

    the

    'development

    of

    civilization'

    and

    the spread

    of

    'enlightenmentof

    the

    masses',

    manifestationsof

    free

    trade's

    contribution

    o human

    progress under

    Britain's

    providential

    leadership.

    Juxtaposed

    accounts of the

    Germanpoor

    throwing

    themselves

    on horse

    carcasses sent a

    sure

    warning

    to

    Britons

    of the

    uncivilizing

    process

    unleashed by food taxes.71In the close connection between national

    identity and

    free

    trade,

    political

    economy

    moulded

    collective

    conscious-

    ness through

    a

    diametric

    opposition

    between

    idealized

    British

    virtues

    and

    traditions

    and

    'false' and

    degenerateforeign

    cultures.This

    can be

    seen as

    a

    continuation

    of

    an

    important

    dynamic n

    English

    nationalism,

    which

    had

    been

    rooted in the

    constructionof

    the

    Dutchand

    French

    as alien

    'other'

    n

    seventeenth-and

    eighteenth-century

    opular

    political

    economy.72

    The

    discourse

    of

    free

    trade

    provided the

    frames

    of

    meaning

    necessary

    for

    a

    public

    movement.

    Some

    like

    Schuster

    n

    the City or

    Pigou,the

    econ-

    omist, might have relied on economic concepts concerningthe market,

    comparative

    advantage and

    intemational

    differentiation

    familiar

    from

    today's

    discussion.As

    noted

    earlier,

    however, farfrom

    being a

    separate

    economic

    matter,

    this

    was

    embedded

    in

    liberal

    concerns

    about

    political

    ethics.

    Neo-classical

    economists,as

    Supple has

    stressed,

    recognized

    theor-

    etical

    justifications or

    state

    intervention

    but

    refrained

    rom

    concretepro-

    posals

    out of

    political

    considerations.73

    ormany

    entrepreneurs,

    upport

    231

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    17/36

    ARTICLES

    for free trade

    did

    not reflect

    support

    for

    the free market as

    a

    social

    model.

    The steelmaster

    Hugh Bell,

    typically,

    rejected protectionism

    partly

    as

    an

    agent of

    a

    more

    materialistic,

    selfish

    and

    degenerate society,

    associated

    with US millionaires and trusts.74 For the mid-Victorian period Boyd

    Hilton has shown how

    middle-class

    support

    for free trade

    was

    inspired

    by

    a

    concern less

    for 'enrichissez-vousand

    social

    progress'

    than for

    'leav-

    ing

    providence to

    its

    own

    devices'.75

    It

    would be

    wrong

    to

    assume

    that

    the retreat

    of this evangelical vision of

    a

    moral

    economy

    in

    the

    second

    half of the

    nineteenth

    century

    marked the

    triumph

    of a

    secular

    vision

    of

    a

    market

    society.

    There is

    no historical reason

    to

    presume

    that

    popular

    support

    for free

    trade then has to be at one with

    the

    understanding

    of liberal

    trade

    theory

    now. Radicals saw

    no problem

    in

    linking

    it to

    land

    reform

    and

    the return

    of an

    independent

    peasantry

    to the

    land,

    a

    combination

    that

    indicated

    how

    limited

    their vision of international

    comparative

    advantage

    was.

    Free trade was often

    associated

    with

    community

    and

    cooperation

    rather

    than

    market or

    competition.

    This

    took

    a

    number of

    forms,

    from

    Christian

    ethics and visions

    of

    a

    cooperative society,

    all

    the

    way

    to

    'new liberal'

    ideas of

    welfare. One

    manual worker, for

    instance, concluded his

    memories of 'the

    hungry

    forties' with

    a

    denunciation of

    tariffs as

    'an

    immoral policy because it substitutes "Do unto others as they do unto

    you," for the

    Golden Rule, "Do

    unto others

    as

    ye

    would

    they SHOULD

    do unto

    you." The former

    policy

    embodies the

    spirit

    of

    irritation and

    revenge.

    The latter breathes

    of

    conciliation and good-will

    to all

    men'.76

    At a

    national

    level,

    as

    McKibbin has

    stressed,

    free trade

    'permitted

    the

    relative

    autonomy

    and

    propriety of working-class

    politics'.77

    To the

    powerful

    cooperative movement the 'Free

    Breakfast Table'

    represented

    an

    inalienable right of

    democratic society as

    much as

    cheap bread.

    Free

    trade

    meant free

    exchange, not the economics of the free market, liable

    to generate

    greed,

    poverty and

    hatred. As

    such, it stood for

    a

    wider

    vision of

    'self-dependence',

    cooperative

    internationalism and

    the auton-

    omy

    of

    civil

    society from

    colonization by the

    state. It

    embodied a

    strong

    contemporary belief

    in

    societal

    self-development and

    in

    civil

    society

    as

    an

    important terrain

    of

    active citizenship.78

    Most

    interesting,

    perhaps, was the

    evolving social and civic

    meaning

    linked

    to free

    trade

    in

    the

    course of the

    debate. A

    leading voice of

    the

    'new

    liberalism' was J. A.

    Hobson,

    an economic

    heretic who

    held as few

    illusions about the pacific nature of cosmopolitan interests as about the

    soundness of liberal

    economics. Free trade

    retained

    its

    anti-imperialist

    appeal.

    But

    his

    discovery of

    'underconsumption'

    shifted

    emphasis from

    the

    economic

    function of

    free trade

    to an organic

    notion of

    its social

    function.

    Rather than

    promoting an

    ever advancing

    industrial

    division

    of

    labour,

    free trade

    plus

    social reform

    would

    overcome the growing

    distance

    between

    production

    and

    consumption,

    seen to erode the

    232

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    18/36

    POLITICAL CULTURE AND POLITICAL

    ECONOMY

    cohesion

    and freedom of civil

    society.

    In this vision a

    special place

    was

    accorded

    to

    the

    'citizen-consumer',

    whose

    economic actions would

    no

    longer

    pursue selfish

    market-oriented interests

    but

    bring

    into

    harmony

    the collective ends of society by promoting civic culture, democratic

    spirit,

    taste

    and

    creativity.

    Consumption

    would become

    a

    cultural

    agency

    for uplifting

    the

    social, political

    and economic

    ethics of

    the

    indi-

    vidual. Individual and social

    interests

    would

    be reconciled while

    promoting

    a

    virtuous,

    participatory

    civil

    society.

    This

    organic

    vision did

    not look towards

    a

    market

    society

    or

    modernization,

    individual ration-

    ality or bureaucratic

    organization,

    but

    to

    a

    community

    of creative

    and

    individuated yet mutually

    dependent

    citizens

    who would

    develop

    their

    productive talents

    alongside

    their tastes as consumers.

    All

    this

    was

    in

    contrast to the individualistic vision

    of the invisible

    hand

    of the market

    coordinating

    atomistic self-interests for

    maximum wealth. Not

    surpris-

    ingly, Hobson demonized classical free

    trade

    economists

    as

    intellectual

    spokesmen

    of

    Manchesterism,

    confederates

    of

    mercantile

    and

    producer

    interests whose obsession

    with

    commercial

    gain

    blinded them to

    the

    social

    utility

    of

    consumption.79

    Whatever

    the different

    type

    of

    reforms

    advocated,

    for a

    growing

    num-

    ber of

    liberals

    support

    of

    free

    trade

    went

    hand in hand

    with

    the

    rejection

    of a natural equilibrium model and assumptions of a convergence

    between individual and

    collective interests.80 Rather than

    beginning

    and

    ending

    with

    'the

    market' or economic

    self-interest, popular free trade

    was embedded

    in

    ideas

    of

    political

    legitimacy,

    national

    history

    and

    civil

    society.

    IV

    IDEOLOGY

    AND POLITICAL

    ECONOMY

    This article has discussed free trade's sources of strength in late Victorian

    and Edwardian

    Britain. The

    economistic account of

    the survival of free

    trade as a

    natural

    alliance of

    internationally

    oriented trades or sectors

    has

    been

    found

    empirically and

    methodologically

    unconvincing. Instead

    of

    viewing

    interests as

    determined

    exogenously by

    location

    in

    the world

    economy,

    the

    historical explanation here has

    argued that the power of

    free trade was an

    endogenous construction shaped

    by political culture.

    I

    would

    like to conclude by

    discussing some implications for the study

    of

    the role of

    ideology

    in

    political

    economy.

    The renewed attention to 'ideas' by some political scientists has been

    a

    welcome

    move away from

    functionalism, but has

    been constrained by

    its

    principal focus on official

    policy. This has

    distracted from the broader

    discursive

    role of

    political economy. In Goldstein

    and Keohane's impor-

    tant

    approach, ideas function

    as 'roadmaps'

    selected by policy makers

    to

    chart their

    way through

    problems.81

    While this approach goes

    beyond

    rational

    choice,

    it

    continues to

    separate ideas from

    interests. Ideas might

    233

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    19/36

    ARTICLES

    influence administrations

    by

    institutionalizing

    routines,

    but

    they

    remain

    a

    secondary

    phenomenon, creating

    the occasional

    'lag'

    behind the

    'real'

    primary forces of history rather

    than

    inherently shaping

    these

    forces.82

    Yet interests are not pre-social but are embedded in society and culture.

    Human

    beings

    enter

    a

    bounded,

    pre-interpreted

    world that

    their actions

    and

    frames

    of

    meaning

    continuously

    reconstitute. Historical

    actors,

    to

    paraphrase

    Giddens,

    are

    their own

    politico-economic

    theorists.83

    As

    reflexive

    agents, they interpret

    and

    help

    to create their

    political

    economy.

    To emphasize

    culture as

    a

    constitutive aspect

    of

    political

    economy,

    however,

    should not mean

    giving

    primacy

    to

    'economic culture'

    as

    a

    subject and method

    of

    explanation

    in

    the

    way

    recently suggested by

    Rohrlich.84

    Rohrlich

    is

    right

    in

    stressing

    the limits

    of behaviouralist

    and

    realist analyses and the need for more

    cognitive

    approaches.

    But he is

    less persuasive

    in

    presuming

    that

    a

    shared

    market 'economic culture'

    was the

    key

    factor

    in

    the mid-Victorian

    adoption

    of free trade

    policy.

    To

    conceptualize

    it as a Kuhnian

    paradigm

    raises well-known

    problems.

    How useful is a

    model

    of a

    closed, internally

    unified

    system

    for under-

    standing historical

    change?

    Human

    agents

    interact

    differently

    with

    the

    economy,

    a

    social

    system,

    than

    with

    the natural

    world.85

    Furthermore,

    it is

    problematic to start out with notions

    of

    a

    shared,

    stable

    under-

    standing of the economy or to presume popular convergence around

    theoretical models. Far

    from

    supporting

    the idea that

    the

    early

    nine-

    teenth

    century

    saw

    the rise

    of an

    optimistic

    belief

    system

    about the

    free

    equilibrating

    market and

    growth through

    comparative

    advantage,

    historical

    research

    has found a wide

    spectrum

    of ideas about

    the

    economy among

    states and

    publics.

    Advocates

    of

    liberal trade

    often

    understood

    the

    economy

    as

    stationary

    or

    were concerned

    with

    balanced

    growth rather than

    differentiation.

    In

    nineteenth-century

    Europe, the

    middle classes envisaged a variety of social systems, of which a differ-

    entiated

    market

    society

    was

    only one

    among many.86

    The

    temptation to

    look for market ideas

    in

    the

    past has been part of

    the

    wider

    'modern'

    framework of interpretation

    which tells the story of

    modernity

    as a

    battle between

    the rise of the

    market and state

    regula-

    tion.

    Polanyi's

    Great

    Transformation

    s, perhaps, its

    most

    popular and

    ideal-typical narration.87Free

    trade is

    presumed to have a fixed

    meaning

    and

    becomes

    one

    chapter

    in

    the

    grand

    narrative

    of the rise of the

    market.

    The

    public

    significance

    of

    free trade

    in

    our

    period,

    however, lay in its

    moral-political conception, not in a shared economic culture. This was

    important, this article

    has

    argued, because it

    could bring

    together

    competing

    social

    and

    political

    groups.

    The

    liberal

    appeal to

    'free food'

    as a

    collective

    good was

    echoed

    in

    the

    trades union

    manifesto in 1903

    thanking

    'God

    that Englishmen who

    toil have a

    vote, without which

    no

    capitalist can

    enter the

    House of Commons to

    commit

    the sin of

    inc:reasing

    the

    cost of living'.88

    Similarly, it was the civil and

    political

    234

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    20/36

    POLITICAL CULTURE

    AND POLITICAL ECONOMY

    ethics

    of free trade rather

    than

    any agreement

    on

    laissez-faire

    economics

    that held together the alliance

    between old and new liberals. For

    Conser-

    vative free traders, too, opposition to

    tariff reform was

    inspired

    not

    by

    a belief in the free market, but by the double fear of social anarchy

    following

    a food tax

    and

    of the

    displacement

    of

    public

    virtue

    and

    parlia-

    mentary liberty, guarded by

    'disinterested,

    moderate

    independent men',

    by the politics of class,

    interests

    and

    demagoguery.89

    Labour leaders

    like Hardie and Snowden, on the other

    hand,

    were

    sceptical

    about

    inter-

    national economic integration

    and Britain's

    dependence

    on

    foreign

    markets. Their economic

    thought

    shared socialist

    expectations

    that

    capi-

    talist trade would lead to

    a

    global overproductionist

    crisis.

    At

    the same

    time as attacking competitive

    exchange, however, they

    remained

    sympa-

    thetic

    to radical views of the 'Free Breakfast Table'

    and

    free

    exchange

    as a pacific, civilizing force.

    Traders,

    caricatured as

    non-productive

    middlemen at home, underwent

    a

    metamorphosis

    in

    international

    waters into 'great missionaries of a

    brighter day

    ...

    majestically coming

    and

    going

    with their

    freights

    of

    barter, teaching

    the

    nations the much-

    needed lesson of their

    mutual

    dependence one upon the other'.90

    It

    was

    the strength of such shared ideas

    that

    kept

    free trade

    at

    the centre of

    public politics.

    Consensus but not conformity. Rather than in terms of hegemonic

    economic

    culture,

    the

    survival of free trade can

    be

    conceptualized

    as

    a

    convergence

    of ideas about liberal

    politics

    and

    society

    sufficient to

    generate

    collective

    allegiance

    and

    action. Free trade was tied to social

    movements, like the Cooperatives, interested

    in

    sheltering civil society

    as a

    democratizing

    terrain from colonization

    by

    the state. The

    relative

    autonomy

    of civil

    society

    from state and

    market has

    recently

    been redis-

    covered.91Putting this dimension back into the

    analysis

    makes it

    possible

    to step beyond the grand narrative of 'modernization'. Between the para-

    digms

    of realist and

    economistic models

    that

    reduce

    socio-political

    relations to either state or economic

    structures,

    this

    opens

    a

    space for

    examining

    social

    groups

    as reflexive

    agents participating

    in

    the

    dynamic

    process

    of

    debate

    and

    the construction of political economy.

    Britain's position

    in

    the world

    economy was deteriorating from the

    1880s. Yet, significantly, it was not until

    'decline' became linked to a more

    fundamental disillusionment with

    liberal views of

    political economy

    that

    free trade lost its impregnable position. In

    early twentieth-century Britain,

    a period marked by increasing socioeconomic regulation, industrial

    concentration and

    structural

    unemployment,

    the

    nineteenth-century

    trin-

    ity

    of

    freedom, cheapness

    and

    individual initiative finally lost its cultural

    authority.

    What

    emerged

    was a

    new discourse of

    regulation, reorganiza-

    tion and

    productivity. As labour and

    capital turned their attention to

    production

    and

    internal

    rationalization, the cultural authority of con-

    sumption

    and

    international

    exchange

    diminished

    accordingly.

    The

    view

    235

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    21/36

    ARTICLES

    that free

    trade

    guaranteed

    'the

    purity

    of

    politics'

    and social

    justice

    faded

    as devaluation

    and industrial decline were blamed on

    the

    power

    of

    the City.

    Internationalists, too,

    moved

    away

    from the older ideal of

    self-

    regulating commerce towards institutional sources of international inte-

    gration.92

    Freedom

    of trade lost its

    paradigmatic

    function as

    a

    source

    of

    collective

    identity

    and

    social

    mobilization once

    socioeconomic

    demands

    became articulated

    as

    proactive

    rights (employment,

    welfare)

    and

    class-

    based

    organizations competed

    for

    control

    over the

    state and

    its

    regulatory

    powers.

    This

    period

    marked a break

    in

    the

    meaning

    and

    function

    of

    the idea,

    in

    which

    the economic one

    lived

    on,

    detached

    from the

    larger

    cultural one. The introduction

    of

    a

    general

    tariff

    in

    1931-2

    completed

    free

    trade's

    marginalization.

    It

    may

    be

    interesting

    at

    this

    stage

    to look

    far

    ahead and

    briefly

    compare

    basic features

    of

    British

    free trade culture

    with

    the

    resurgence

    of

    trade

    in

    recent western

    politics,

    in

    the

    discussions about trade liber-

    alization and

    globalization.

    At

    the level of

    cultural associations

    and

    sociopolitical

    constituencies,

    free

    trade's

    position

    has been reversed.

    Instead of

    its

    earlier

    association

    with

    democratic

    rights,

    communitarian

    ethics,

    social

    justice

    and

    national

    identity

    in

    British radical and

    progres-

    sive

    politics,

    free trade

    today

    is denounced

    by

    a

    range

    of

    radical

    and

    social movements as an international corporate attack on participatory

    democracy,

    hard-won

    social

    rights, consumer,

    labour

    and

    environmental

    standards,

    and

    regional

    and

    national

    culture. Opposition to NAFTA

    and

    GATT has extended from

    organized labour, social democrats and

    consumer

    advocates

    to

    women's

    groups

    and

    ecological

    and cultural

    movements.93

    Neither the

    popular

    disenchantment with free trade

    as

    such,

    nor the

    more

    general and frequently

    alarmist fixation on trade and globalization,

    can be explained as a mere reaction to autonomous economic develop-

    ments

    without reference to the

    formative influence of ideological and

    political

    factors. As

    several

    critical economists and

    sociologists have

    pointed

    out,

    it

    is difficult to

    correlate the present

    obsession with trade

    with

    secular

    economic trends.94 While the world

    economy has become

    more

    integrated

    in

    the last half-century, it is far

    from clear that it is

    creating

    a

    unitary global system or

    that

    changes

    in

    trade

    are

    a

    signifi-

    cant

    factor

    in

    national income and employment.

    In the advanced

    economies of

    the

    European Union, Japan and North

    America trade is a

    mere 12 per cent of GDP. For the USA it has been argued that the

    economic lives of

    citizens are

    determined by technological changes

    rather than changes in trade, for

    Germany that trade

    has been a positive,

    not a

    negative, source of growth

    and employment.95

    The share of foreign

    direct

    investment and of the

    operations of

    multinational corporations

    that

    reaches

    beyond the privileged north is too

    small to justify the

    images of

    doom painted by

    the prophets of globalization. It would be

    236

  • 8/10/2019 Trentmann - Political Culture and Political Economy - Interest, Ideology and Free Trade.pdf

    22/36

    POLITICAL CULTURE

    AND POLITICAL

    ECONOMY

    too simple, however,

    to

    explain discrepancies

    between economic

    trends

    and public perception

    as the

    result of the

    fallacious

    reasoning

    and

    poor

    statistical knowledge

    of certain

    commentators.96

    Attention should

    be

    given, instead, to the discursive construction of 'globalization'. Part of

    its appeal,