tilburg university the return of the dutch disease?

33
Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE? Bachelor Thesis Economics Student: W.J.A. van Benthem Supervisor: prof. dr. J.A. Smulders Date: 06/06/2011 Word Count: 7892

Upload: others

Post on 03-Feb-2022

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

Tilburg University

THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

Bachelor Thesis Economics

Student: W.J.A. van Benthem Supervisor: prof. dr. J.A. Smulders

Date: 06/06/2011 Word Count: 7892

Page 2: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

Table of Contents

Introduction ...........................................................................................................................1

What is the Dutch Disease? ..................................................................................................3

Models Explaining the Dutch Disease ......................................................................4

Empirical Work on the Dutch Disease ......................................................................8

Methodology and Data ..........................................................................................................10

Methodology .............................................................................................................10

Data ...........................................................................................................................11

Results ...................................................................................................................................15

Potential Problems and Pitfalls .................................................................................18

Conclusion ............................................................................................................................24

Appendix 1 Description of Variables and their Sources .......................................................25

Appendix 2 Countries Used in the Dataset ...........................................................................26

Appendix 3 Correlation Matrices..........................................................................................27

Reference List .......................................................................................................................29

Page 3: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

1

Introduction

The striking observation that many countries abundant with natural resources have

experienced little or no economic growth in the last century has been studied extensively in

the last decades. This phenomenon is generally referred to as the resource curse. The study of

the resource curse is relevant because many of the world’s poorest countries possess huge

amounts of natural resources. With this in mind it is especially disturbing that resource

abundance, in most cases, does not seem to translate directly into economic growth.

There is a variety of possible causes studied in the literature. Recently there is a big

emphasis on the role of institutions in explaining the resource curse. For example Mehlum et

al. (2006) introduce the concept of grabber friendly institutions, which in combination with

resource abundance should lead to low growth, and producer friendly institutions, which

should help turning abundance of natural resources into a blessing. They find empirical

evidence for their hypothesis that ‘institutions determine whether countries avoid the resource

curse or not’. Boschini et al. (2007) confirm the finding that institutions play a vital role in

determining whether resource abundance is a curse or a blessing, and in addition show

evidence that the type of resource is a decisive factor as well.

In addition, van der Ploeg and Poelhekke (2009) find that the most important cause of

the resource curse comes from macroeconomic volatility. The volatility that comes with

natural resources prices creates volatility in the output per capita in the countries that depend

heavily on their natural resources.

Earlier studies of the resource curse date back from the late 1970s and early 1980s.

Contrary to the contemporary views, in these days there was much focus on the so-called

Dutch disease explanation of the resource curse. In short this theory states that due to a

windfall of natural resources there is an appreciation of the real exchange rate which leads to

de-industrialization and a decrease in the sector for traded goods (Corden and Neary, 1982).

Stijns (2003) made an empirical investigation on the Dutch disease hypothesis using a gravity

model of trade. He found negative relationships between a net energy exporting country’s net

energy exports and manufacturing exports, and between energy world prices and

manufacturing exports. Further, Harding and Venables (2010) have written an article about

the effects of changes in net resource exports on non-resource exports, non-resource imports,

and net non-resource exports which is the difference between the former and the latter. One

Page 4: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

2

important result they find is a fall of 65 cents in net non-resource exports for a dollar increase

in natural resource exports.

The relationship I am trying to study for my thesis tries to integrate the effects of

institutions in explaining the Dutch disease. The main research question is: Does the Dutch

disease really exist and what is the role of a country’s institutional quality on the impact of

the disease. To investigate the existence of the Dutch disease, and to shed light upon the role

of institutions on the Dutch disease, I use empirical data to carry out regression analysis. The

remainder of the thesis is constructed as follows: section two describes the theoretical

framework and some empirical studies, section three elaborates on the methodology and data

used for the research, section four discusses the results, and section five concludes.

The results show that most of the times a negative relationship occurs between a

windfall in natural resource wealth and manufacturing exports, albeit it that there could be

significant omitted variables bias. Furthermore, in some cases the relationship turns out to be

insignificant. Additionally, the role of institutions turns out to be insignificant as well.

Page 5: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

3

What is the Dutch Disease?

In an article published as early as 1977 in the Economist, the bad macroeconomic

situation in the Netherlands compared to other European countries, was given the name the

Dutch disease. The article argues that part of the bad performance can be explained by the

post OPEC-recession that occurred at that time. This recession caused other countries to

perform badly as well. However the reason behind the fact that the Netherlands was having

more problems than the other European countries is being linked to the amounts of gas

reserves the country was exploiting during that period. The article argues that the cause of the

Dutch disease consisted out of three parts.

First of all, the currency at the time was too strong. When the gas was discovered in

1959, the Dutch government chose for quick exploitation of the gas, because at that time oil

was cheap and nuclear energy was expected to be abundant within twenty years. The quick

implementation took the form of low prices for domestic use of the gas, and long term export

contracts. By means of this way the current account improved accordingly, with an average

of $2 billion in the period 1972-1976. However, on the other hand the improving capital

account was partially offset by capital outflows. In the period 1967-1971 the country was a

recipient of foreign investment, whereas in the period 1972-1976 it became a net investor

abroad. This capital outflows even helped to prevent, to a certain degree, the Dutch industry

from losing its attractiveness to importers from abroad. Although these outflows have slowed

it down, they could not prevent an increase in the value of the Guilder.

Second, there was a significant increase in industrial costs which was caused by three

main reasons. Minimum wage legislation imposed upward pressure on all wages in the

economy. In addition, the social security payments were substantial and risen significantly

compared to earlier years. And in that period, in the Netherlands the regulations for

environmental and employment standards where tightened.

Finally, the proceeds from the gas reserves were not used in a sound way. It seems

most appropriate to invest the revenues from an asset which is diminishing, in capital1.

However the Dutch government chose to use it for government spending. The majority of this

spending took the form of transfer payments. For example: pensions and unemployment

benefits.

1 Generally known as Hartwick’s rule.

Page 6: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

4

Models Explaining the Dutch Disease

Corden and Neary (1982) provide a clear and understandable analysis of the Dutch

disease. Their framework is a small open economy which produces three goods. Two of them

are traded goods, called energy and manufacturing (XE and XM respectively). The prices of XE

and XM are exogenously determined at the world markets. And the other good is non-traded,

called services (XS). The price of XS is determined by domestic supply and demand. Two

important assumptions are made. First, the models presented are in real terms so that

monetary considerations play no role, and national output is always equal to expenditure.

Second, the markets for the factors of production, in this case labor and capital are perfect.

This means that the real wages are perfectly flexible and that full employment is maintained

at all times. It is further important to know that the real exchange rate in this article is defined

as the relative price of non-traded to traded goods.

An important distinction this article makes is between the resource movement effect

and the spending effect. The resource movement effect is defined as a reallocation of mobile

factors of production, caused by an increase in the marginal products of those factors in the

sector experiencing a boom. On the other hand the spending effect is the increase in spending

on XS caused by the higher real income resulting from the windfall in natural resources. This

effect raises the price of services and thus a real appreciation which leads to further

adjustments in the structure of the economy.

The models put forward in the article are distinguished from each other by different

assumptions about the economy. The assumptions concern the mobility of the different

factors of production between the three sectors. For example, one model assumes that labor is

the only mobile factor of production in the economy, while another one assumes that next to

the mobility of labor, capital is mobile between the manufacturing and services sectors, and

that the energy sector uses its own specific factor of production. Other important factors

influencing the effects of the boom are the relative intensities of the factors of production.

Due to the different situations presented in the article the outcomes differ from each other.

To give a basic understanding of the dynamics, the simplest of the models is

presented. To begin with it is assumed that labor is the only mobile factor between the three

different sectors (XE, XM, XS) in the economy, and that each sector has its own specific capital

factor. The total labor supply of the economy is shown by the distance OSOT in figure 1.

Labor input into services is measured by the distance from OS, and likewise the distance from

OT measures the total labor supply into the traded goods sector. Further, the labor demand

Page 7: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

5

schedules for the services sector (LS), the manufacturing sector (LM), and the total traded

sector (LT) are shown.

Figure 1

The effect of the boom can be analyzed by looking at the resource movement effect

and the spending effect separately. Through the resource movement effect the labor demand

schedule of the energy sector shifts upwards and thus the total traded labor demand schedule

shifts upwards as well. The new labor demand schedule for traded goods is shown by the

dashed LT’ curve in the figure. The position of the LT’ curve causes a new equilibrium to

form at point B, and labor is drawn out of the manufacturing sector (m � m’). The new

equilibrium thus gives rise to direct de-industrialization. In addition, the resource movement

effect leads to an excess demand for services. In order to restore equilibrium between the

traded goods and services markets, shown in figure 2, there must be an appreciation of the

real exchange rate (the price of non-traded goods relative to traded goods increases). As a

result of the higher prices in the services sector, the labor demand schedule for services shifts

upward. This in turn causes a final equilibrium to form a point G.

Next the effects of the boom are analyzed by looking at the spending effect. The

boom increases the production possibilities of the economy, shown by the new curve T’S in

figure 2. The point b corresponds to the highest possible indifference curve which can now be

reached. The curve ON shows the demand for services at the initial exchange rate, it is

OS m m’ m’’

LM

B

G

A

Wage

OT

LS

LS’

LT’ LT

w2

w1

w0

Labor

Page 8: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

6

assumed that demand for services rises with income. This curve intersects the T’S to the right

of point b. Hence, there is again an excess demand for services and an appreciation of the real

exchange rate must take place to restore equilibrium. To summarize, the resource movement

effect causes a decrease in the output of services, and the spending effect leads to an

increased demand for services. Both effects lead to a real appreciation of the exchange rate,

and in turn to indirect de-industrialization.

According to van Wijnbergen (1984) the Dutch disease cannot simply be ignored,

since the structure of the economy has a big influence on the performance of the economy.

For example, after the Second World War most of the economies that experienced rapid

growth benefited from strong traded sectors. Furthermore, in the economic literature it is a

stylized fact that technological progress is much faster in the traded sector.

In his article Van Wijnbergen sets out a model for the Dutch disease which

incorporates learning by doing. The reason for this is that one of the factors affecting

technological progress is accumulated experience. Further, the article assumes that learning

by doing mostly occurs at the traded sector, so that in the model learning by doing effects

only affect the traded sector. The learning by doing implies that production in the second

period depends positively on the production in the first period.

The economy modeled is a two period model with a traded and a non-traded sector. A

subsidy is introduced which induces firms in the traded sector to produce at the social optimal

S

a

b

n T

T’

O

Services

Traded

Goods

Figure 2

Page 9: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

7

level. Without the subsidy this would not occur since the return on experience is assumed to

be industry specific. For this reason firms cannot appropriate all the returns on experience.

Therefore the optimal level for the firm and the socially optimal level are not the same, and

government intervention is needed. The effects of a temporary increase in oil revenues are

analyzed in two situations: one with an exogenous current account, and another with the

possibility to accumulate assets or borrow from abroad.

In the model with the assumption that the current account is exogenous, the results are

unambiguous. The temporary increase in oil revenues in the first period is at least partially

spent on non-traded goods. This means that a real appreciation of the price of non-traded

good in terms of traded goods has to occur, for the demand for non-traded goods increases.

This real appreciation causes resources to shift out of the traded sector into the non-traded

sector. Because learning by doing takes place only in the traded sector, the shift means that

production in the second period will be lower. Therefore a higher subsidy in the first period is

needed to ensure that firms produce at the social optimal level. Due to the higher subsidy

more traded goods are produced in the first period and as a result in the second period as

well. The excess supply of traded goods pushes up the second period real exchange rate. To

conclude, without the subsidy the second period welfare will decline because of the loss of

learning by doing, induced by lower production of traded goods in the first period.

The second model introduces foreign borrowing and foreign asset accumulation. This

allows income in one period to be distributed over the two periods. The outcome of this

model is however ambiguous unfortunately. Again, the higher oil revenues will lead to a real

appreciation exactly similar to the previous model, and thus to less learning by doing in

period one and lower output in period two2. On the other hand, the real exchange rate which

appreciates in the first period will gradually depreciate over time. This causes a higher cost of

borrowing in the first period, and therefore there will be a shift of expenditure from the first

to the second period. The effect of the shift in expenditure is an upward pressure on the real

exchange rate of tomorrow3. In addition, the learning by doing effect increases the first period

optimal production subsidy, and the cost of borrowing effect decreases the subsidy. So the

question is: which of these effects really dominates.

2 Learning by doing effect. 3 Cost of borrowing effect.

Page 10: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

8

Empirical Work on the Dutch Disease

Stijns (2003) investigates the phenomenon of the Dutch disease by using a gravity

model of trade. This model helps to take out the other macroeconomic effects faced by the

home economy. For example, an energy boom that takes the form of an increase in the world

price of energy tends to accompanied by economic recessions.

In the paper, four different testable hypotheses are being identified; an appreciation of the

real exchange rate; an increase in non-traded output; a decrease in manufacturing sector

production; and a decrease in manufacturing exports. The last hypothesis is being tested,

because for the second and third hypotheses there is not enough data, and the first hypothesis

is already being tested by Chen and Rogoff (2003).

Three approaches are being used. First, only the world price of energy is used as the

independent variable. Second, net energy exports is being used for this purpose. And third,

net energy exports and the world price of energy are used together to capture the benefits of

both approaches. In his investigation Stijns makes use of the world price of energy because

he is of the belief that it is safe to assume that the world price of energy is exogenous to

manufacturing trade, whereas net energy exports has the potential to be endogenous to

manufacturing trade.

The results Stijns finds are very interesting. In all the three approaches mentioned

above, there seems to be significant evidence which supports the Dutch disease theory: the

world price of energy and net energy exports both have a negative effect on manufacturing

exports. According to the results of the article: ‘a one percent increase in the price of energy

will, ceteris paribus, decrease a net energy exporter’s real manufacturing exports by half a

percent.’ In addition, ‘a one percent increase in net energy exports will, ceteris paribus,

decrease a net energy exporter’s real manufacturing exports by one eight of a percent.’

As mentioned before, Chen and Rogoff (2003) have tested the relationship between

natural resource booms and the real exchange rate. In their article they test the relationship

between the real exchange rates and world commodity prices. The relationship is tested for

three OECD countries: Canada, Australia, and New Zealand. The focus is on these three

countries in particular because they have a large share of commodity exports in their total

exports, and because of their relatively small size, which disables them to influence the world

price of commodities. The results of the study show a significant positive relationship

between the real exchange rate and world commodity prices for Australia and New Zealand.

However, the relationship is not significant for Canada after the trend of declining world

commodity prices is being removed out of the relationship. This investigation confirms the

Page 11: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

9

Dutch disease, for a positive relationship is found between the commodity price shock and

the value of the real exchange rate. However, the data is compiled only out of three

developed countries. For this reason it may not be very useful for policy-makers in the

developing world, which have to deal with the resource curse the most.

More recently, Harding and Venables (2010) have studied the effects of foreign

exchange windfalls on the balance of payments of a country. The balance of payments

accounts studied are non-resource exports, total imports, and the net accumulation of foreign

assets. This accumulation takes the form of ‘government accumulation of a sovereign wealth

fund’, and ‘foreign debt reduction’. Two different forms of the foreign exchange windfalls

are studied; net resource exports, defined as the net exports of fuels, metals, and ores; and

foreign aid, defined as inflows of aid. For their investigation they use a data set consisting of

133 countries, over the period 1960 to 2000.

The results of their study lead to the conclusion that roughly per dollar of resource

exports, there is a 50 cent decline in non-resource exports, a 15 cent increase in imports, and

35 cents are saved. The effect of one dollar of foreign aid is an increase imports by 40 cents,

while exports decline only slightly.

What this study shows for my own research is that an increase in resource exports

tends to decrease non-resource exports. The latter could lead to a symptom of the Dutch

disease, namely a decrease in outputs of the non-resource tradable sector.

Page 12: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

10

Methodology and Data

Methodology

In order to lay bare the relationship between manufacturing exports4 and natural

resource wealth. I will make use of regression analysis. The regression analysis is based on

panel data. Because panel data varies over two dimensions, in this case time and individual

countries, it is often more accurate than single time series or cross-sectional data (Verbeek,

2008). The data is described in the section below this section.

The model studied is constructed as shown by equation 1. This model is a fixed

effects model, based on the first-differencing technique. An advantage of this technique is

that it eliminates the time invariant effects from the model. First-differencing suits my dataset

well, for I have two time periods available, as will be explained in the section below. This

makes it easy to subtract the values for the two periods for each variable.

∆��� � ∆�������� ∆��������� ∆������������� ∆����� ∆��� (eq. 1)

∆Yit is the dependent variable which represents the difference in total manufacturing

exports per capita of country i at period t compared to period t-1. ∆NatCapit is the variable

representing the difference in the World Bank’s (1997, 2006) natural resource wealth per

capita estimate of country i at the same periods, whereas ∆InstQit represents the difference in

institutional quality of a country i at these periods. To discover the combined effect of

institutional quality and natural resource wealth, I have included an interaction term as well

in the model. ∆Xit is a vector of the differences in control variables. These controls are

constructed following Gourdon (2009), however not all variables are the same because I

could not collect precisely the same data. In his article Gourdon investigates the determinants

of trade. The variables are made up out of produced capital per capita, intangible (or human)

capital per capita, openness to trade, total factor productivity growth5 , GDP per capita,

population, weighted growth rates of trading partners per country, number of patent

applications, total kilometers of road network, and number of internet users per 100 people.

∆uit is the error term capturing the random components.

4 For reasons of simplicity I use the term manufacturing goods to denote non-natural resource traded goods, similar to section two. 5 I use total factor productivity growth instead of total factor productivity. The reason for this is that I was not able to find data on total factor productivity for the countries used in my dataset.

Page 13: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

11

The variables for the endowments are not constructed in the same way as Gourdon

(2009). Gourdon uses the ratio of a country’s per capita endowment of a factor to the world

per capita endowment of that factor. This is because the relative advantage compared to other

countries is used as an explanatory variable in Gourdon’s model. I am interested in

explaining the relationship between a country’s natural resource endowments and

manufacturing exports. Because the theory described in section two does not directly take

into consideration a country’s comparative advantage in factor endowments I have chosen to

take the per capita values of the factor endowments. By this way I can test whether windfalls

in other factors have an effect on manufacturing exports as well. For a full description of the

control variables and their sources I refer to appendix 1.

When the Dutch disease would really exist I expect the estimate of β1 to be negative,

for a windfall in natural resource endowments would cause a decrease in manufacturing

exports. Next, the estimate of β2 could be either positive because generally better institutional

quality would lead to better economic conditions, and therefore better export performance, or

negative, because of the possibility that the richer a country becomes, the more it will

specialize in services rather than manufactured goods. β3 is a very interesting term in the

model. This is the interaction term composed of institutional quality and natural resource

wealth. The estimate of the coefficient for this interaction term provides information about

the role of institutions in the Dutch disease. It tests whether the relationship between natural

resource abundance and manufacturing exports is different for different levels of institutional

quality. One would maybe expect that there would be an influence of institutions on the

Dutch disease. On the other hand however, the Netherlands and the UK, two countries with

good institutional quality, have experienced Dutch disease symptoms in the past.

Data

The mechanisms discussed in section two have to be translated into models consisting

of measurable variables. The effects highlighted in the theories of van Wijnbergen (1984) and

Corden and Neary (1982) suggest several variables, and as mentioned before Stijns (2003)

identifies four different hypotheses. First of all, what is observed is an increase in the real

exchange rate. In both articles this is defined as the price of non-traded goods in terms of

traded goods in a country. To construct a variable for the real exchange rate, one could use a

price index of non-traded goods in a country divided by the price index of traded-goods in a

country. Chen and Rogoff (2003) use the nominal exchange rates of countries expressed in

terms of a basket composed of foreign currencies. Their results are described in section two.

Page 14: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

12

Second, non-traded output per country could be chosen as the dependent variable.

According to the theory this variable should increase with a natural resource boom. However,

the question is whether data is widely available for many countries. Especially it will be hard

to collect data on this for the developing countries, and for these countries data is particularly

useful since most of the countries that are endowed with large amounts of natural resources

are developing countries.

Third, output in the manufacturing sector could be taken as the dependent variable.

An accurate measure for this would be a variable which measures tradable goods output. For

instance it could be created by aggregating output in the sectors not falling under the

classification of natural resources or non-tradables.

Nevertheless, most studies use non-resource exports as the dependent variable

(Harding and Venables, 2010), (Stijns, 2003), because of data-availability. Using exports as

the dependent variable could lead to a misinterpretation of the results. An increase in exports

should lead to an increase in output, but a decrease in exports should not necessarily lead to a

decrease in output, for the demand at home could have risen more than the decline in exports.

However (Stijns, 2003) finds that manufacturing exports are too much affected by the

resource boom, for the latter to be plausible. For data-availability reasons I follow Stijns’

(2003) approach by taking manufacturing exports as the dependent variable. The data on

manufacturing exports for each country is extracted from the dataset compiled by Feenstra et

al. (2005). This database covers international trade for almost all of the world’s countries.

Further, the database disaggregates all trade according to the Standard International Trade

Classification (SITC) Revision 2 (UN, 1975). Table 1 lists the SITC categories I have

selected to represent manufacturing exports. I have divided the manufacturing exports levels

by the total number of the population in a country, for the natural capital wealth estimates are

also measured per capita.

Table 1

SITC Section Code Section Heading

5 Chemicals and Related Products, N.E.S.

6 Manufactured Goods

7 Machinery and Transport Equipment

8 Miscellaneous Manufactured Articles

Page 15: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

13

Next, we turn to the explanatory variables. As mentioned in Stijns (2003), Corden

(1984) describes three possible forms a natural resource boom can take: ‘a once–and-for-all

exogenous technical improvement, a windfall discovery of new resources, or an exogenous

rise in the world price of the natural resource, relative to import price.’ The technological

improvement would be hard to measure, because one would have to gather data on

technological improvements in a specific sector of the economy. This would be quite difficult

to do, as gathering data on the state of the technology in the overall economy is difficult

already. For the latter sometimes a proxy is taken in the form of resource and development

expenditures. Because this data is hard to find for many countries, I would expect that

resource and development expenditures data for the manufactured sector is even harder to

find.

As mentioned above Stijns (2003) uses the world price of energy and net energy

exports. This data is easier to collect. Furthermore, windfall discoveries of new resources are

interesting to use, for developing countries regularly find new amounts of natural resources.

For example, in Ghana (2007 and 2009) and Uganda (2009) huge amounts of oil were found.

Most studies use the share of natural resource exports in total exports or GDP, to quantify

resource abundance, for example Arezki and van der Ploeg (2010), Sachs and Warner (1997),

and Boschini et al (2007).

Nonetheless, other studies, for example, Fum and Hodler (2010), Brunnschweiler and

Bulte (2009), and Bond and Malik (2009) use the value of natural capital calculated by the

World Bank (1997, 2006). This measure is based on agricultural lands; pasture lands; forests;

protected areas, metals and minerals; and coal, oil, and natural gas. The advantage of these

estimates is that they are more accurate than the share of natural resource exports, since the

latter are amounts traded and not the endowment of a country. The disadvantage of the

natural capital estimates of the World Bank compared to natural resource exports is that the

data is estimated for only two years. Nevertheless, I will use these natural capital estimates to

test the existence of the Dutch disease, because to my knowledge this data is never been used

before to explore the empirical relationship between manufacturing exports and natural

resource abundance. Further, any possible relationship found can be compared, to some

degree at least, with the results of Stijns (2003) who made use of natural resource exports.

Because natural resource abundance is one of the most important explanatory variables, I

have chosen to base the countries and time periods in the dataset on those used for these

estimates, as reported by the World Bank (1997, 2006). A full list of the countries used in the

dataset can be found in appendix 2.

Page 16: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

14

In addition, data on institutional quality is gathered from Kaufmann et al. (2009). This

database contains country-level information about six different indicators of institutional

quality. These indicators are: voice and accountability, political stability and absence of

violence/terrorism, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of

corruption. All six indicators are measured on a scale of -2.5 to 2.5, where the higher the

value the better the quality is. I have chosen to take the average of these six indicators to

construct a single index number for institutional quality in a country. Unfortunately, this

database covers the period 1996-2008. For this reason I have chosen to take the 1996 average

value as a proxy for the 1994 average value, under the assumption that in two years time

institutional quality in a country does not change significantly.

Page 17: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

15

Results

In this section the results of the regression analysis are described. The regression

analysis is conducted according to section three. Before the results of this analysis are

presented, a scatter plot is made to illustrate the relationship graphically. In figure 3 the y-

axis represents the change in manufacturing exports per capita, and the x-axis the change in

natural capital per capita. This scatter plot suggests that the relationship between natural

resource windfalls and manufacturing exports is negative, and thus that the Dutch disease

does exist. To investigate the relationship further we turn to regression analysis.

Figure 2

The results of the regression analysis are shown in table 2. The analysis is conducted

in five steps, according to the correlations between the different explanatory variables in the

model. This correlation matrix can be found in appendix three. I have chosen to completely

exclude the changes in patent applications, internet users per 100 people, and total roads

network, from the model. The reason for this is that the data on these three variables has

Page 18: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

16

many missing values, and high correlations with other variables which I assume are more

important for the determination of manufacturing exports.

The first regression includes the changes in a country’s factor endowments,

population, trade openness, weighted average growth of a country’s trading partners, and the

growth of total factor productivity. Further, the model omits the change in GDP of a country

because this variable has a significant correlation with the change in intangible capital and the

change in openness. Because of missing observations the total number of observations used

in the model is 62. From the table can be read that the model explains 44.5% of the variation

in the data. Furthermore, the only significant explanatory variable in the model is ∆open. This

result is easy to understand, for an improvement in a country’s openness to trade will increase

its exports. Especially because this variable is measured as the sum of a country’s exports and

imports divided by the country’s GDP. The estimator for ∆nat has a negative sign but is not

significant at a 10% significance level. However, the smallest significance level where the

variable is significant is equal to 11%.

Regression two incorporates institutional quality into the model to see if this brings

more significance to the model. Unfortunately R2 is decreased, as well as the t-value of ∆nat.

Although, the estimator for ∆nat still has a negative sign, this means that incorporating ∆iq in

the first model is not going to help us any further in proving the existence of the Dutch

disease.

Regression three starts from another viewpoint. This model includes, amongst others,

∆gdp to control for change in the domestic market size. According to the correlation matrix,

∆gdp is significantly correlated to ∆open and ∆int. For this reason these two variables are

omitted in this model. When looking at the results, the first thing that strikes is that after

introducing the new variable, the estimator for the change in natural capital is significant,

even at the 5% significance level. Further, the estimators for ∆pro and ∆gdp are significant at

the 5% significance level as well. This result confirms the Dutch disease, albeit that there is

not a radical effect on manufacturing exports. An increase of $1 in a country’s natural wealth

estimate per capita decreases a country’s manufacturing exports per capita with 6.4 cents. In

addition, the model now explains 61.4% of the variation in the data.

Page 19: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

17

Table 2

**,* significant at 5% and 10% respectively, the number within brackets denotes the value of the t-

statistic

To test again for the influence of institutional quality on the Dutch disease, regression

four builds on regression three by including ∆iq, similar to regression two. Unfortunately,

again institutional quality is not significant in explaining the Dutch disease. This

insignificance may be caused by the fact that there is correlation between institutional quality

and GDP. Nevertheless, the significance of the estimators for ∆nat and ∆pro, as well as the

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

∆nat -0.048

(-1.627)

-0.40

(-1.321)

-0.064**

(-2.641)

-0.070**

(-2.764)

-0.067**

(-2.610)

∆int 0.002

(1.226)

∆pro 0.014

1.068

0.011

(0.879)

0.026**

(2.393)

0.028**

(2.501)

0.026**

(2.279)

∆gdp 0.434**

(8.726)

0.446**

(8.594)

0.458**

(8.424)

∆pop -6.742E-06

(-0.620)

-7.669E-06

(-0.704)

-5.121E-06

(-0.577)

-5.831E-06

(-0.653)

-6.195E-06

(-0.690)

∆open 69.388**

(5.312)

72.563**

(5.688)

∆iq 830.565

(0.878)

-692.608

(-0.856)

-539.390

(-0.644)

∆tfp 0.115

(0.319)

0.003

(0.007)

0.168

(0.565)

0.238

(0.770)

0.229

(0.739)

∆gtp -2.315

(-1.182)

-2.075

(-1.061)

-1.331

(-0.848)

-1.317

(0.837)

-1.401

(-0.884)

∆pat

∆trn

∆inu

∆natiq 0.102

(0.747)

R2 0.445 0.438 0.614 0.619 0.623

observations 62 62 62 62 62

Page 20: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

18

significance of the entire model is increased slightly, and the significance of ∆gdp is

decreased slightly. A $1 increase in natural resource abundance per capita now leads to a

decrease of 7 cents in manufacturing exports per capita.

Regression five includes the interaction term between natural capital wealth and

institutional quality as described in section three, ∆natiq, to test whether the influence of a

change in natural capital is different for different levels of institutional quality. The inclusion

of this interaction term slightly increases the R2 of the model to 0.623. Nonetheless this

interaction term is not significant in the model. The significance of the estimators for ∆nat,

∆pro, and ∆gdp are all decreased slightly but they remain significant at the 5% significance

level. A $1 windfall in natural resource wealth per capita leads to a decrease of 6.7 cents in

manufacturing exports per capita.

Potential Problems and Pitfalls

One of the big issues arising from using regression analysis to empirically test

economic relationships is the omitted variable problem. The estimators may be biased

because important variables are left out of the model. For instance, variables can be left out of

the model because of collinearity or simply because the data is not available. The problem

described can be an important issue for my research. For instance, due to the significant

correlation between institutional quality and GDP, it is better not to use both variables in the

same regressions. Probably the change in institutional quality is endogenous to the change in

GDP. When one of the variables is left out of the model, its effects on the model are

incorporated in the error term ∆uit. When one of the explanatory variables is correlated to the

error term, omitted variable bias can arise (Hill, Griffiths, and Lim, 2008).

In order to solve this problem one could make use of an instrumental variable to replace

the problematic variable. Instrumental variables must satisfy the following conditions:

1. The variable does not have an effect on the dependent variable

2. The variable is not correlated with the error term in the model

3. The variable must be strongly correlated with the variable that it replaces

Some of the empirical literature on the resource curse makes use of an instrumental

variable for institutional quality (Boschini et al. 2007), (Arezki and van der Ploeg, 2010).

This literature follows Acemoglu et al. (2001), by using the log of the European settler

mortality risk. However, using this variable as an instrument for institutional quality in my

Page 21: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

19

research is not possible since I am using the first-differencing technique. The fact that this

technique makes use of the change in a variable over time means that the single value for

settler mortality risk cannot be used. On the other hand however, the advantage of using first-

differencing is that it removes omitted variable bias arising from time invariant variables, for

the simple reason that they do not change over time. For example geographical variables do

not change over time6.

To test for any misspecification I will use the RESET test (REgression Specification

Error Test) as described in Hill, Griffiths, and Judge (2001). This test uses the predicted

values of the model. The predicted values are the ∆y����s that can be computed by plugging in

the explanatory variables in the regression equations found by running the regressions. With

these predicted values the following model can be constructed:

∆��� � ∆���� � ������

� �������∆��� (eq. 2)

In this model ∆Yit is again the change in a country’s manufacturing exports, and ∆X’it

is a vector containing all the explanatory variables used in the regressions. The procedure of

the RESET test is to test the hypothesis H0:γ1= γ2=0 against H1: γ1≠0 or γ2≠0. For this testing

procedure an F-test7 is required. Rejection of H0 means that the original model may not be

correctly specified and can be improved. A failure to reject H0 means that the test was not

able to detect any misspecification. The results of the RESET test conducted on the five

models are shown in table 3.

As can be read from the table, all five models may be subject to model

misspecification and can be improved. The fact that the coefficients of the predicted values

do not appear to be zero according to these tests, means that the effects of omitted variables

may be picked up by these variables.

Since institutional quality is one of the main explanatory variables of my research, I

have chosen to adopt an alternative strategy to be able to test for its effects on the Dutch

disease. The approach is simple. The dataset is made up out of a wide range of countries, both

from the developed and developing world. Assuming that institutions are one of the main

6 At least not in the period used for the research. 7 The F-test is conducted according to the follow five steps:

1. Test H0:γ1= γ2=0 against H1: γ1≠0 or γ2≠0

2. Test statistic: �!""#$%""#&'/!)%*'

""#&/!+%!),�''

3. Reject H0 if - . /;)%*;+%!),�'

4. Calculate value of F 5. Draw conclusion

Page 22: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

20

driving forces behind GDP growth, one could say that the developing countries have worse

institutions compared to the developed countries. Following this reasoning I have classified

the countries in the dataset according to the classification by income developed by the World

Bank. I have chosen to use the low income countries8 and lower middle income countries.

Although this shrinks the dataset to 41 countries, now inferences can be made on the Dutch

disease for developing countries. These countries are shown in bold in appendix two; the

correlation between the variables can be found in the second table of appendix three.

Table 3

(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)

SSEr 1,035E+08 1,049E+08 7,203E+07 7,108E+07 7,036E+07

SSEc 1,863E+07 1,881E+07 1,329E+07 1,312E+07 1,149E+07

K 9 9 8 9 10

G 7 7 6 7 8

N 62 62 62 62 62

Α 0,05 0,05 0,05 0,05 0,05

FINV 3,175 3,175 3,172 3,175 3,179

VAL 118,444 118,997 117,126 114,860 130,651

Conclusion Reject H0 Reject H0 Reject H0 Reject H0 Reject H0

α denotes the significance level of the test, k and g denote the number of explanatory variables with

and without the predicted values respectively

The results of the regressions based on the dataset compiled of low income and lower

middle income countries can be found in table 4. I have chosen the variables for the different

regressions according to their mutual correlations. The sixth regression starts with including

∆nat, alongside ∆int, ∆open, and ∆pop. In the model ∆pro is omitted because of a significant

correlation with ∆int. A model that includes intangible capital instead of produced capital

proves to be more significant. With this regression 37.3% of the variation in the data is

explained. The sign of the estimator for ∆nat is now positive, albeit that the estimator is not

significant at a 0.05 or 0.10 significance level. The only significant variable is ∆int, with a

negative sign for the estimator.

8 This classification is based on 2009 GNI per capita. Low income countries are countries with a GNI per capita of $995 or less, lower middle income countries have GNI per capita of $996 - $3,945.

Page 23: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

21

Regression seven includes ∆tfp in the analysis, controlling for the effect of more

efficient use of inputs. This decreases the amount of observations to 27 because of missing

values. The sign of the estimator for ∆nat is still positive and its significance is increased,

though the estimator is still not significant. In addition, the significance of the model is

increased from 0.373 to 0.567.

Adding the change in a country’s GDP per capita decreases the significance of the

model to 0.494, as shown in regression eight. In this model ∆pop is omitted because of

significant correlation with ∆gdp. The influence of the change in a country’s natural capital

per capita is about the same in this regression compared to the previous one.

Table 4

(6) (7) (8) (9)

∆nat 0.001

(0.280)

0.004

(0.696)

0.004

(0.707)

-0.001

(-0.030)

∆int -0.003**

(-3.535)

-0.003**

(-3.539)

-0.003**

(-3.010)

-0.003*

(-1.854)

∆pro

∆gdp 0.027

(0.652)

∆pop 1.241E-7

(0.879)

8.582E-8

(0.112)

1.891E-7

(0.165)

∆open 0.694

(0.155)

0.409

(0.249)

0.469

(0.289)

1.157

(0.335)

∆tfp -0.531

(-0.161)

-0.487

(-0.149)

0.032

(0.313)

∆gtp

∆oil 0.024

(0.539)

R2 0.373 0.567 0.494 0.546

observations 41 27 27 16

**, * significant at 0.05 and 0.10 significance level respectively

As a final step in my research I have chosen to include a variable measuring the

change in a country’s proven reserves of oil, ∆oil. Different types of natural resources may

have different effects on the economy. For instance, Bond and Malik (2009) find a positive

Page 24: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

22

relationship between fossil fuel exports and investment, and Boschini et al. (2007) show that

the type of resources a country possesses are important in determining whether natural

resource abundance is beneficial for economic development. The data for oil reserves per

country are gathered from the U.S. Energy Information Administration. I have chosen to

include the variable ∆oil into the model with the highest significance (for developing

countries). Including this variable, changes the sign of the estimator for ∆nat, but its

significance is decreased dramatically. In addition, the proportion of variance explained by

the model decreases to 54.6%.

What is remarkable is that the only significant variable in the models, ∆int, remains

negative. This result indicates that an increase in the amount of intangible capital per capita

will have a negative effect on manufacturing exports. Possibly this result shows the

possibility that the more educated a country becomes, the more it specializes in services

rather than manufactured goods.

The RESET test is being conducted as well for the last four regressions, in the same

way as described above. The results of this test are shown in table 4.4. For these four

regressions, the test fails to detect any misspecification.

Table 5

(6) (7) (8) (9)

SSEr 3,428E+05 182642,088 179278,582 1.549E+05

SSEc 3,211E+05 160209,481 144773,463 1.403E+05

K 6 7 7 8

G 4 5 5 6

N 41 27 27 16

Α 0,05 0,05 0,05 0.05

FINV 3,276 3,522 3,522 4.737

VAL 1,146 1,330 2,264 0.365

Conclusion Don't reject H0 Don't reject H0 Don't reject H0 Don't reject H0

α denotes the significance level of the test, FINV denotes the rejection value, VAL denotes the value

of the test statistic

To summarize, filtering out the richer countries to test for the effects of less

institutional quality does not yield significant estimators for ∆nat. Nonetheless, what is

interesting to see is that for regressions six, seven and eight the sign of ∆nat is positive. If the

Page 25: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

23

estimators were significant this would mean that developing countries experience less of the

symptoms of the Dutch disease than richer countries do.

Page 26: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

24

Conclusion

My research tried to investigate one of the earlier explanations of the resource curse

by testing the Dutch disease hypothesis. What distinguishes this research from other research

is that the differences in the variables in two moments in time are used to detect the effects of

a change. Although my research finds mostly negative relationships between a windfall in

natural resource wealth and manufacturing exports, the usability of the results is limited due

to some of the problems described above. Furthermore, the effects of institutions on the

Dutch disease could not be shown to exist. To further understand the mechanics of the Dutch

disease additional research has to be done.

Further research could include the natural capital estimates used in this paper in a

gravity model of trade, similar to the one used by Stijns (2003). Consequently, the effects of a

windfall in natural resource wealth estimates can be compared with a windfall in net energy

exports and world energy prices, to see if the Dutch disease still persists.

Another strategy would be to disaggregate the total measure of natural resource

wealth into different types of resources in the same fashion as Boschini et al. (2007), and use

these different types of resources to test for the Dutch disease rather than differences in GDP

growth.

In addition, an econometric model could be used which is not based on differences in

two points in time. By this way, it will be possible to include the instrument for institutional

quality as proposed by Acemoglu et al. (2001). The omitted variable problem can be

decreased by this method.

Additionally, even if a significant and persisting Dutch disease relationship is laid

bare, this does not necessarily mean that an economy suffers from it. For example, the fact

that a country’s manufacturing exports decrease does not necessarily imply a decrease in the

growth rate of the economy, for the increase in natural resource exports can more than offset

the aforementioned decrease, or the country can specialize in other sectors. After a Dutch

disease relationship is found, one should think of a way to test the relationship between the

Dutch disease and the growth of a country’s economy, and possibly include also the role of

the institutions.

Page 27: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

25

Appendix 1 Description of Variables and their Sources

Table 6

variable description source

Mxp Manufacturing exports composed of goods categorized under the headings 5, 6, 7 and 8 by SITC

Feenstra et al. (2005)

Nat Natural capital estimates by World Bank World Bank (1997, 2006)

Int Intangible (or human) capital estimates by World Bank

World Bank (2006) and Kunte et al. (1998)

Pro Produced capital estimates by World Bank World Bank (2006) and Kunte et al. (1998)

Gdp Real GDP per capita (constant prices, chain series) Pen World Table Version 6.3 by Heston et al. (2009)

Opn Openness of a country for trade. Measured by exports plus imports divided by real GDP

Pen World Table Version 6.3 by Heston et al. (2009)

Pop Population of a country Pen World Table Version 6.3 by Heston et al. (2009)

Iq Institutional quality. Measured by the unweighted average of the indices of voice and accountability, political stability and absence of violence/terrorism, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of corruption

Kaufmann, Kraay, and Mastruzzi (2009)

Tfp Percentage growth of total factor productivity. The Conference Board Total Economy Database (2011)

gtp9 Weighted growth rates of trading partners of a country

Calculated by author by using Feenstra et al. (2005)

Pat Number of patent applications World Development Indicators World Bank (2011)

Trn Total kilometers of road network World Development Indicators World Bank (2011)

Inu Number of internet users per 100 people World Development Indicators World Bank (2011)

Oil Proven oil reserves, billions of barrels U.S. Energy Information Administration (2011)

All monetary measures are converted to the 2005 dollar value using the U.S. Bureau of

Economic Analysis GDP deflator.

9 This value was calculated by the following procedure. First, all of a country’s exports to a specific country were aggregated. Second, this value was divided by a country’s total exports. Third, the previously calculated ratio was multiplied by the importing country’s GDP growth. And finally, the calculated values were aggregated to yield the weighted growth of trading partners.

Page 28: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

26

Appendix 2 Countries Used in the Dataset

Table 7

Countries Used in the Dataset

Argentina Greece Niger

Australia Guatemala Norway

Austria Guinea-Bissau Pakistan

Bangladesh Haiti Panama

Belgium Honduras Paraguay

Benin India Peru

Brazil Indonesia Philippines

Burkina Faso Ireland Portugal

Burundi Italy Rwanda

Cameroon Jamaica Senegal

Canada Japan South Africa

Chad Jordan Spain

Chile Kenya Sri Lanka

China Korea, Rep. Of Sweden

Congo, Rep. Of Madagascar Switzerland

Costa Rica Malawi Thailand

Cote d'Ivoire Malaysia Trinidad and Tobago

Denmark Mali Tunisia

Dominican Rep. Mauritania Turkey

Ecuador Mauritius United Kingdom

Egypt, Arab Rep. Of Mexico United States

El Salvador Morocco Uruguay

Finland Mozambique Venezuela

France Nepal Zambia

Gambia, The Netherlands, The Zimbabwe

Germany New Zealand

Ghana Nicaragua

Page 29: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

27

Appendix 3 Correlation Matrices

Table 8 Correlation Matrix for all Countries

∆nat ∆int ∆pro ∆gdp ∆pop ∆open ∆iq ∆tfp ∆gtp ∆pat ∆trn ∆inu

∆nat 1

∆int 0.015 1

∆pro 0.095 -0.104 1

∆gdp 0.074 0.553** -0.203 1

∆pop -0.016 -0.123 0.080 -0.101 1

∆open -0.068 0.197 -0.051 0.354** -0.023 1

∆iq -0.173 0.239* 0.002 0.272* -0.032 0.151 1

∆tfp 0.084 -0.090 0.023 -0.102 -0.019 -0.096 0.212 1

∆gtp -0.075 0.132 0.012 0.006 -0.007 0.206 0.092 0.037 1

∆pat -0.007 0.077 0.539** 0.094 0.071 -0.004 0.127 0.027 -0.239 1

∆trn -0.013 -0.044 0.071 -0.058 0.933** 0.023 -0.011 -0.059 0.032 -0.003 1

∆inu -0.188 0.634** -0.177 0.619** -0.224 0.259 0.361* -0.104 -0.010 0.320* -0.192 1

**,* correlation is significant at 0.01 and 0.05 level respectively

Page 30: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

28

Table 9 Correlation Matrix for Low and Lower Middle Income Countries

∆nat ∆int ∆pro ∆gdp ∆pop ∆open ∆tfp ∆gtp ∆oil

∆nat 1

∆int -0,012 1

∆pro -0,178 0.621** 1

∆gdp 0,232 -0,237 -0,183 1

∆pop 0,005 -0,067 0,069 0,391* 1

∆open -0,146 -0,110 0,001 -0,003 0,030 1

∆tfp 0,066 0,067 0,104 -0,061 -0,090 -0,297 1

∆gtp -0,320* -0,052 -0,019 0,154 0,000 0,187 -0,004 1

∆oil 0.164 -0.035 0.497* -0.311 -0.185 0.378 0.057 -0.340 1

**,* correlation is significant at 0.01 and 0.05 level respectively

Page 31: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

29

Reference List

Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. and Robinson J.A. (2001), The Colonial Origins of Comparative

Development: an Empirical Investigation. The American Economic Review, 95 (5), 1369-

1401.

Arezki, R. and Ploeg, van der, F. (2010), Trade policies, institutions and the natural resource

curse. Applied Economic Letters, 17, 1443-1451.

Bond, S.R. and Malik, A. (2009), Natural resources, exports structure, and investment.

Oxford Economic Papers, 61, 675-702.

Boschini, A.D., Petterson, J. and Roine, J. (2007), Resource Curse or Not: A Question of

Appropriability. Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 109 (3), 593-617.

Brunnschweiler, C.N. and Bulte, E.H. (2009), Natural resources and violent conflict: resource

abundance, dependence, and the onset of civil wars. Oxford Economic Papers, 61, 651-674.

Chen, Y. and Rogoff, K. (2003), Commodity Currencies. Journal of International

Economics, 60, 133-160.

Conference Board, The. (2011), Total Economy Database. http://www.conference-

board.org/data/economydatabase/

Corden, W.M. and Neary, J.P. (1982), Booming Sector and De-Industrialization in a Small

Open Economy. The Economic Journal, 92 (368), 826-841.

Corden, W.M. (1984), Booming Sector and Dutch Disease Economics: Survey and

Consolidation. Oxford Economic Papers, New Series, 36 (3), 360.

Economist, the. 1977, November 26th, The Dutch Disease. 82-83.

Page 32: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

30

Feenstra, R.C., Lipsey, R.E., Deng, H., Ma, A.C. and Mo, H. (2005), World Trade Flows:

1962-2000. Working Paper, 11040. Natural Bureau of Economic Research, 1050

Massachusetts Avenue, Cambridge.

Fum, R.M. and Hodler, R. (2010), Natural resources and income inequality: The role of

ethnic divisions. Economic Letters, 107, 360-363.

Gourdon, J. (2009), Explaining Trade Flows: Traditional and New Determinants of Trade

Patterns. Journal of Economic Integration, 24 (1), 53-86.

Harding, T. and Venables, A.J. (2010), Foreign Exchange Windfalls, Imports and Exports.

Working Paper, University of Oxford, Department of Economics.

Heston, A., Summers, R. and Aten, B. (2009), Penn World Table Version 6.3, Center for

International Comparisons of Production, Income and Prices at the University of

Pennsylvania.

Hill, R.C., Griffiths, W.E., Judge, G.G. (2001), Undergraduate Econometrics, Second

Edition. John Wiley & Sons Inc., 605 Third Avenue, New York, NY, United States

Hill, R.C., Griffiths, W.E., Lim, G.C. (2008), Principles of Econometrics, Third Edition. John

Wiley & Sons Inc., 111 River Street, Hoboken, NJ, United States

Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A. and Mastruzzi, M. (2009), Aggregate and Individual Governance

Indicators 1996-2008. The World Bank Development Research Group, Macroeconomics and

Growth Team.

Kunte, A., Hamilton, K., Dixon, J. and Clemens, M. (1998), Estimating National Wealth,

Indicators and Environmental Valuation. The World Bank.

Mehlum, H., Moene, K. and Torvik, R. (2006), Intstitutions and the Resource Curse. The

Economic Journal, 116, 1-20.

Page 33: Tilburg University THE RETURN OF THE DUTCH DISEASE?

31

Ploeg, van der, F. and Poelhekke, S. (2009), Volatility and the Natural Resource Curse.

Oxford Economic Papers, 61, 727-760.

Sachs, J.D. and Warner, A.M. (1997), Natural Resource Abundance and Economic Growth. Working Paper, Center for International Development and Harvard Institute for International Development.

Stijns, J. (2003), An Empirical Test of the Dutch Disease Hypothesis Using a Gravity Model

of Trade. Working Paper, University of California, Berkeley, Department of Economics.

U.S. Energy Information Administration. (2011), data on proven oil reserves per country.

Accessed via Datastream.

United Nations. (1975), Standard International Trade Classification Revision 2. Statistical

Papers Series M No. 34. Department of Economic and Social Affairs, Statistical Office.

Verbeek, M. (2008), A guide to modern Econometrics, Third Edition. John Wiley and Sons

Ltd, The Atrium, Southern Gate, Chichester, West Sussex, England

Wijnbergen, van, S. (1984), The ‘Dutch Disease’: A Disease After All? The Economic

Journal, 94 (373), 43-53.

World Bank. (1997), Expanding the Measures of Wealth, Indicators of Environmentally

Sustainable Development. Washington D.C.

World Bank. (2006), Where is the Wealth of Nations, Measuring Capital for the 21st Century.

Washington D.C.

World Bank. (2011) World Development Indicators. http://databank.worldbank.org/ ddp/

home.do