thesis zivile kazlaus kaite

Upload: jude-agnello-alex

Post on 05-Apr-2018

232 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    1/90

    MSc in International Economic Consulting

    Aarhus School of Business, University of Aarhus

    A New Nuclear Power Plant in Lithuania:

    Cost-Benefit Analysis

    Author:

    Zivile Kazlauskaite

    Academic Supervisor:

    Jan Brsen Bentzen

    Department of Economics

    June 2010

    http://www.asb.dk/staff.aspx?pid=11463http://www.asb.dk/staff.aspx?pid=11463
  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    2/90

    Abstract

    Currently Lithuania faces significant changes in its electricity generation sector

    caused by the closure of the old nuclear reactors. The main challenge is the

    overdependence on single-source gas imports and as a result diminished security of

    supply. In addition, Lithuania will face problems with meeting its electricity demand

    growth in the medium run and confront issues related to the retirement of electricity

    generating plants. The government has already established the plans to attract the

    private investor and build a new nuclear plant in order to cope with the existent

    challenges.

    Inspired by the situation in Lithuanian energy sector, this thesis performs a social

    cost-benefit analysis of a likely new nuclear power plant build in Lithuania relative to

    the situation where the investments would divert to the gas-fired electricity

    generation.

    The results show that nuclear power plant project would not be cost-effective relative

    to the counter-factual and result in a nuclear cost penalty in the base case. Security of

    supply benefits are relatively small and would not justify the nuclear case. However,it is concluded that expanding nuclear power would result in huge environmental

    benefits, which would offset the nuclear cost penalty. Therefore, following the net

    present value criterion, the nuclear project is justified under the base case

    assumptions.

    However, it is emphasized that the project justification particularly depends on the

    shadow price of carbon dioxide, future gas prices and nuclear construction costs. The

    government should also take into consideration such aspects as the disadvantage oftechnological lock-in in the case of nuclear plant, the drawback of accident risk,

    sustainability and intergenerational issues, moral hazard problems, declare the

    employment benefits with caution.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    3/90

    Contents

    1. Introduction .................................................................................................................. 1

    1.1 Lithuanian energy sector and government policy ................................................... 2

    1.2 Problem statement and delimitations ..................................................................... 4

    1.3 Choice of methodology ......................................................................................... 5

    1.4 Structure of the thesis ............................................................................................ 5

    2. Theoretical foundations ................................................................................................ 7

    2.1 Key theoretical aspects of CBA ............................................................................. 7

    2.1.1 Partial and general equilibrium approaches in CBA ....................................... 7

    2.1.2 Price dynamics .............................................................................................. 9

    2.1.3 Social Discount Rate ....................................................................................10

    2.1.4 Investment criterion......................................................................................15

    2.2 Energy economics ................................................................................................15

    2.2.1 Cost and performance characteristics of electricity generating technologies ..15

    2.2.2 Levelised-cost methodology .........................................................................18

    3. Analysis ......................................................................................................................21

    3.1 Project description and alternatives ......................................................................21

    3.2 Scope and Standing ..............................................................................................283.3 Identification, quantification and monetization of costs and benefits .....................29

    3.3.1 Cost Penalty/Advantage ...............................................................................31

    3.3.2 Accident Costs .............................................................................................47

    3.3.3 Environmental Benefits ................................................................................49

    3.3.4 Security of Supply ........................................................................................54

    3.3.5 Employment benefits ....................................................................................56

    3.4 Discounting procedure and NPV calculation ........................................................57

    3.5 Sensitivity Analysis .............................................................................................58

    3.6 Recommendation .................................................................................................61

    4. Conclusions .................................................................................................................63

    Bibliography .......................................................................................................................66

    Appendices .........................................................................................................................71

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    4/90

    List of Figures

    Figure 1. Electricity generation in Lithuania by fuel type.................................................. 3

    Figure 2. Analytical structure of conducting CBA ............................................................ 5

    Figure 3. Key cost variables of power plants ...................................................................16

    Figure 4. Projections of electricity demand in Lithuania ..................................................22

    Figure 5. Assumed timeline of the new nuclear build project ...........................................26

    Figure 6. Estimates of nuclear reactor overnight costs .....................................................33

    Figure 7. Structure of electricity generation cost in the base case .....................................46

    Figure 8. Break-even CO2 shadow prices in various sets of alternatives (LTL/tCO2) ........60

    List of Tables

    Table 1. Deriving SDR for Lithuania .............................................................................14

    Table 2. Representative proportions of electricity generating costs, % ............................20

    Table 3. Nuclear technologies under consideration .........................................................24

    Table 4. Identified costs and benefits of a new NPP build ..............................................30

    Table 5. Recent evidence on III generation nuclear reactor construction cost ..................34

    Table 6. IDC calculations for the base case ....................................................................37

    Table 7. Total construction costs for nuclear and CCGT plants in the base case ..............38

    Table 8. Cost to get 1 kg of uranium as UO2 reactor fuel ................................................40

    Table 9. Decommissioning costs ofIgnalina NPP ..........................................................43

    Table 10. Average nuclear and gas-fired plant levelised-cost for the base case .................46

    Table 11. GHG emissions (kg CO2 equivalent/MWh) from nuclear fission and CCGT .....50

    Table 12. Net annual lifecycle CO2 equivalent and carbon emissions reduction ................51

    Table 13. Welfare balance of a new NPP in the base case ................................................58

    Table 14. Welfare balances of a new NPP project under different gas price, nuclearconstruction cost and CO2 shadow price (in million Litas) ..................................................59

    Table 15. Welfare balances of a new NPP project under different SDR and cost of capitalcombinations (in million Litas) ............................................................................................60

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    5/90

    List of Acronyms and Abbreviations

    BWR Boiling Water Reactor

    CBA Cost-Benefit Analysis

    CCGT Combined Cycle Gas Turbine

    CO2 Carbon Dioxide (a Greenhouse gas)

    EGC Average Lifetime Levelised Electricity Generation Cost

    EPC EngineeringProcurement - Construction

    GHG Greenhouse Gas

    GWe Gigawatt electrical (power)

    IAEA International Atomic Energy Agency

    IDC Interest During Construction

    IEA International Energy Agency

    LCOE Levelised Cost of Energy

    LTL Lithuanian Litas

    NEA Nuclear Energy Agency

    NPP Nuclear Power Plant

    O&M Operating and Maintenance cost

    PHWR Pressurized Heavy Water Reactor

    PWR Pressurized Water Reactor

    SDR Social Discount Rate

    STPR Social Time Preference Rate

    TWh Terawatt hours

    UNIDO United Nations Industrial Development Organization

    WNA World Nuclear Association

    WTP Willingness-to-pay

    WWER Water-Water Energetic Reactor

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    6/90

    Section

    :Introduction

    1

    1.IntroductionWorldwide there are 437 nuclear reactors currently in operation with a total net

    installed capacity of 371 GWe (IAEA, 2010). World Nuclear Association (WNA,

    2010) estimates, that they supply approximately 15% of the worlds electricity.

    Although the volume of nuclear electricity production has been stable during the last

    decade, the share of the total nuclear production has been slightly falling1.

    Nonetheless, recently there has been an increasing interest in nuclear power across

    countries and IAEA (2010) states that there are 55 nuclear power reactors under

    construction, which will contribute to 50.9 GWe. WNA (2010) emphasizes the

    growth in international cooperation and commerce in the field of nuclear science and

    technology. The organization forecasts that the nuclear capacity will at least triple

    until 2060. Plenty of academic literature also shows an increasing attention to a

    potential renaissance of nuclear power and discusses whether we will indeed see

    the revival of nuclear energy in the 21st century.

    At the moment nuclear energy is back on the policy agendas and the advocates

    emphasize its advantages and opportunities. Firstly, worldwide electricityconsumption is expected to double in the next two decades as a result of increasing

    population, industrial development and improvement in living standards. This is of a

    particular importance in such countries as China and India. In addition, Western

    world is facing a need to renew its generating stock. Nuclear energy offers superior

    possibilities to meet this booming electricity demand. Lately there also has been paid

    a lot of attention on climate change and the necessity for greenhouse gas reductions.

    Nuclear power generation could be an option as it is known for its relatively very low

    carbon emissions. Moreover, in some circumstances the use of uranium is more

    advantageous than fossil fuels. The supply of uranium is considered a more secure

    option as compared to delivery of gas or oil. In the case of deregulated markets, the

    use of uranium could mean higher stability of electricity price as a contrast to fossil

    fuels characterized with relatively intense price fluctuations. Finally, if oil and gas

    prices kept increasing and credit markets strengthen after the financial crisis, this

    1 See Appendix 1

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    7/90

    Section

    :Introduction

    2

    would lead to an increase of a relative competitiveness of nuclear energy (Lester and

    Rosner, 2009; WNA, 2010)

    However, despite the advantages the nuclear power generation faces a vast number ofobstacles. Problems arise already in the primary state of the projects. For example,

    long licensing proceedings as well as high initial investments with occasional and

    significant budget overruns. There also exist high concerns about accident risk,

    vulnerability to terrorism and health impacts from radiation. Intergenerational

    problems arise because nuclear waste remains radioactive for ages and are left for our

    descendants. Besides that, nuclear plants also need to be decommissioned, which also

    may last for a considerably long time after the end of its operation (SustainableDevelopment Commission, 2006; Lester and Rosner, 2009).

    The motivation for nuclear power expansion depends on particular national

    circumstances. The way, how the obstacles of this development are overcome, is a

    subject of a particular national case as well. Therefore, this thesis seeks to investigate

    the case of Lithuania, where nuclear expansion is at the center of attention at the

    moment.

    1.1 Lithuanian energy sector and government policyOn December 31, 2009 Lithuania shut down the second reactor ofIgnalina Nuclear

    Power Plant (NPP), which was inherited from the former Soviet Union. After

    regaining the independence in the 90s, with the help of Western countries Lithuania

    improved the safety standards at this plant. Nevertheless, the experts concluded that

    NPPs with RBMK (rus. Reaktor Bolshoy Moshchnosti Kanalniy; eng. High Power

    Channel-type Reactor) could not reach necessary safety standards in a long-term

    operation. The closure of the plant became Lithuanias obligation and condition to

    obtain the EU membership in 2004 (Juozaitis and Baauskas, 2007). Currently the

    plant is at the decommissioning stage though the process is followed by corruption

    scandals and large scale waste of EU funds.

    After the closure ofIgnalina NPP Lithuanian economy confronts a major challenge

    because of significant changes in its energy generation (see Figure 1).

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    8/90

    Section

    :Introduction

    3

    Figure 1. Electricity generation in Lithuania by fuel type

    2004before Unit 1 closure 2007before Unit 2 closure

    Data source: Directorate-General for Energy and Transport (2010)

    According to the EU Directorate-general for Energy and Transport (2010) data, in

    2004 Lithuania produced 19.3 TWh of electricity and net exports amounted for 28%.

    The old nuclear plant was generating 78% in 2004. After the closure of the firstnuclear reactor, the production reached 14 TWh and decreased by 27.3% in 2007.

    Lithuania was constrained to rely more on electricity imports and increase production

    by other generating technologies in order to meet its energy demand.

    The final shutdown in 2009 means that Lithuanian economy lost the diversity of fuels

    used in energy production and became over dependent on gas, which is imported

    from Russia through a pipeline. The other import options such as supply of liquefied

    natural gas (LNG) are only considered but the necessary storages are only depicted inthe plans and not in the reality. After the closure, Lithuania became a net importer of

    electricity as well. To import electricity is physically possible only through a grid

    with Russia and Belarus as the only connection with the rest of EUs electricity grid

    (Estlink-1) is of a limited capacity. The lost capacity is also compensated by more

    intensive use of the older and less efficient, more expensive and pollutant plants,

    which are causing the increase in electricity price (Visaginas Nuclear Power Plant

    Ltd., 2010).

    Oil

    2%

    Gas

    14%

    Nuclear

    78%

    Renewab

    les6%

    Oil

    3%

    Gas

    17%

    Nuclear

    70%

    Renewab

    les10%

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    9/90

    Section

    :Introduction

    4

    Although the electricity demand will be met, the situation shows that Lithuanian

    economy is highly dependent on one dominant source of energy. Such reliance

    extremely diminishes security of supply and carries obvious risks in a long-term.National Energy Strategy specifies that natural gas supplied for energy production

    from one source should not exceed 30% of the total fuel balance. Therefore, national

    energy priority is to replace the old plant with alternative sources of power supply

    which guarantees a positive balance of electricity production and increases energy

    security and supply reliability. In National Energy Strategy 2007 Lithuanian

    government announced the necessity to continue a further development of safe

    nuclear energy. Despite an active public debate, the government proceeds with the

    preparatory work and plans to start the construction of a new NPP as soon as possible

    (Visaginas Nuclear Power Plant Ltd., 2010).

    1.2 Problem statement and delimitationsInspired by the current situation in the Lithuanian energy sector this thesis attempts to

    conduct a socio-economic evaluation of investment into a new NPP in Lithuania. The

    purpose is to find out whether the allocation of resources into expansion of nuclear

    energy production would result in a net economic gain or loss for the Lithuaniansociety as a whole, relative to an alternative situation, where investment would divert

    to gas-fired generation technology. Kennedy emphasizes that such analysis is

    economic rather than financial, and as such, cannot be used as a basis for determining

    likely commercial appetite for bringing forward nuclear projects (Kennedy, 2007, p.

    3701).

    In order to achieve the purpose, it will be necessary to determine and catalogue social

    costs and benefits caused by the project. In addition, it will be pursued to monetizethese impacts. If it is not possible to do so, the qualitative description will not be

    dismissed. Moreover, the analysis will also require making numerous assumptions

    about these impacts and their development over a relatively very long time horizon.

    Therefore, the assessment of how these assumptions contribute to the conclusions will

    be necessary to evaluate.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    10/90

    Section

    :Introduction

    5

    1.3 Choice of methodologyA cost-benefit methodology will be applied in order to answer the main question of

    the analysis. The purpose of CBA is to assist social decision making. Morespecifically, CBA is a tool used to determine whether a project2 contribute to the

    economic welfare, i.e. could they potentially be Pareto improving3. After quantifying

    in monetary terms all impacts of a policy and using the net benefits criterion, it can be

    learnt, if making some people better off does not make anyone else worse off.

    Positive net benefits mean that theoretically the resources are available and could be

    used to compensate those who bear costs. The comparison of projects net benefits

    with a counter-factual is necessary in order to rank the policies. Due to this necessity,the elements of cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) will be incorporated into the

    analysis (Boardman et al., 2006; European Commission, 2008).

    1.4 Structure of the thesisThe thesis is organized into three major sections. Section 2 describes theoretical

    foundations of CBA and emphasizes some important aspects of energy economics.

    The CBA analysis of the Lithuanian case takes place in Section 3. Because

    conducting CBA is a complex process, Boardman and others (2006) suggest making

    it more manageable by breaking it down into nine basic steps. Some steps were

    merged in order to make the analytical section more concentrated.

    Figure 2. Analytical structure of conducting CBA

    Source: Own elaboration based on Boardman et al. (2006), p.8

    2The terms project, policy andprogram are used as synonyms in this paper

    3 This is known as Kaldor-Hicks decision criterion

    1 Defining alternative projects

    2 Defining scope and standing

    3

    Identifying, quantifying and monetizing costs and benefits

    4 Discounting and calculating NPV

    5 Performing sensitivity analysis

    6 Deriving recommendations

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    11/90

    Section

    :Introduction

    6

    Therefore, the analytical section is divided into steps, depicted in Figure 2. Finally,

    the conclusion is provided in Section 4.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    12/90

    Section

    :Theoreticalfoundations

    7

    2.Theoretical foundationsThe following part of the thesis intends to highlight the most important aspects of the

    chosen CBA methodology and to draw attention on some details regarding energy

    economics.

    2.1Key theoretical aspects of CBAHere the different approaches of performing CBA will be shortly discussed by

    highlighting such famous concepts as consumer and producer surplus as well as the

    importance of using shadow prices. Secondly, important characteristics of price

    dynamics will be explained. Moreover, the social discount rate will be introduced byshedding the light on its difference from the financial discount rate. As a result, a set

    of alternative social discount rates for the Lithuanian case is going to be derived.

    Finally, the investment criterion is introduced.

    2.1.1 Partial and general equilibrium approaches in CBACBA originated in the 19th century from the French engineer Jules Dupuit, who had

    proposed to use the concept that currently is known as consumers surplus. Later,

    Alfred Marshall and Cecil Pigou contributed the idea by adding the producers

    surplus and developed the social surplus concept (European Commission, 2008b).

    Today the basic conceptual foundations of CBA are provided by microeconomic

    theory (Boardman et al., 2006).

    Partial equilibrium approach, which is comprehensively discussed in Boardmanet al.

    (2006), suggests estimating the effects of the governmental policy on different

    members of the society and summing them in order to arrive at the net social benefits.

    If the demand and supply curves of a particular market were known in the reality, it

    would be straightforward to measure how governmental project affects the consumer

    surplus4, producer surplus5 and government revenues and therefore get the results on

    the social welfare associated with one particular good. However, in order to get the

    full picture, there is a necessity to account for complementarities and substitution

    4The surplus of consumers willingness-to-pay (WTP) for the good over price of that good (EuropeanCommission, 2008b).5 The revenue from selling the good minus the opportunity cost given up in order to produce that good

    (Boardman et al., 2006).

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    13/90

    Section

    :Theoreticalfoundations

    8

    effects, positive and negative externalities, i.e. to include the welfare effects in the

    secondary markets and the effects on the third parties, which are not related to the

    consumption or production of the good. In addition, there are even more estimationproblems in such cases as informational asymmetry between producers and

    consumers, income effects etc. (Boardman et al., 2006; European Commission,

    2008b).

    Another CBA framework, based on the shadow prices (or differently named as

    accounting prices), was suggested by some researchers from OECD, UNIDO and

    World Bank in the 1970s in order to facilitate the application of CBA by avoiding

    difficulties of distorted market analysis with partial equilibrium approach. Shadowprices are derived artificially and used to correct the market prices to better reflect the

    real social value (European Commission, 2008b).

    Market prices are conceptually correct measures to evaluate the net benefits of the

    project if the markets are competitive and undistorted by various regulations and

    taxes. As a result, in such situations market prices reflect the opportunity costs of all

    project inputs (Campbell and Brown, 2003). The inputs in CBA should be valued in

    terms of opportunity costs because once the resources are dedicated to one purpose, itis not available for the other usage. Opportunity costs are equal to the forgone value

    of the goods or services that would have been produced in the best alternative way

    (Boardman et al., 2006). Therefore, if the markets were perfect, the market prices

    would accuratelly determine the social costs and benefits as all the limited resources

    would be allocated to its highest value use and the economy would be efficient

    (Campbell and Brown, 2003).

    However, we live in the world where markets are distorted and are sociallyinefficient. The best examples of such situations are: monopolies and oligopolies who

    set the price of the good or service above its marginal cost; trade barries, which

    obliges the consumers to pay a higher price than they could otherwise do etc.

    (European Commission, 2008b). Moreover, sometimes the problem why the costs and

    benefits cannot be measured by using market prices is that the market simply does not

    exist for that good (Boardman et al., 2006). The most popular example is

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    14/90

    Section

    :Theoreticalfoundations

    9

    environmental costs or benefits for which there is no market price (HM Treasury,

    2003).

    Therefore, the suggested use of shadow prices allows calculating the shadow socialprofits of projects and as a result to find out whether the project is socially feasible.

    Shadow profits, or economic profits, are general equilibrium measures that are

    defined in such a way as to include all the direct and indirect effects, so thatif you

    know them you do not need to sum welfare effects in each market and for each

    agent (European Commission, 2008b, p. 48).

    Nevertheless, although various shadow pricing techniques exist, Boardman et al.

    (2006) emphasizes that usually in practice analysts use market prices. The reasons todo so might be various. Firstly, due to the subtlety of the difference between the

    market price and conceptually correct measure, this might be overlooked without an

    intention. Secondly, data constraints exist in order to derive the appropriate shadow

    price and due to the time or resource constraints it is impossible to do much about it.

    Lastly, sometimes it is thought that the difference between the actual and the

    conceptually correct measures are adequately little and as a result the results of the

    appraisal is not significantly affected (Boardman et al., 2006).

    2.1.2 Price dynamicsOne of the many questions that arise while doing a CBA is how to deal with the

    inflation. According to Boardman et al. (2006) the analyst may choose to estimate the

    costs and benefits either in real or nominal terms. However, the authors note that it is

    more natural to work in nominal terms in the private sector appraisals, while in

    practice public policy projects are usually assessed in real terms. According to

    Campbell and Brown (2003), the main reason for this is that public projects spreads

    out for relatively long periods of time in the future and the forecasts of inflation for

    such long periods are impossible. The governmental bodies project the change in

    price levels only for a very short perspective. Because the inflation is an increase in

    general price level, it can be assumed that it will affect all costs and benefits

    uniformly and as a result will not have an effect on the relative returns on different

    projects in real sense (Campbell and Brown, 2003). Therefore, estimation of costs and

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    15/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    10

    benefits in the public sector appraisal should be expressed in real terms (HM

    Treasury, 2003).

    There must be a clear distinction between project evaluation when we are lookingback and project appraisal when we are looking into the future (Campbell and Brown,

    2003). As the costs and benefits in the forthcoming nuclear power plant project

    appraisal must be expressed in this years 2010 price level, some of the historical data

    will be a subject to inflation, i.e. the figures from the earlier years needs to be inflated

    to the chosen 2010 price level. This will be done by using the historical change in

    construction prices in Lithuania (see Appendix 5) exceptionally for the construction

    costs6

    and GDP deflator (see Appendix 6) for the rest of the costs and benefits.Because this is a national CBA, therefore the costs and benefits need to be expressed

    in national currency. The exchange rates of 2.9897 LTL/USD and LTL 3.4921

    LTL/EUR are going to be used to convert some data into the national currency (see

    Appendix 4 for the derivation).

    However, after having converted all the costs and benefits to the same years price

    level and the same currency, there is a necessity to project how these impacts escalate

    over time. It is worth emphasizing that although escalation also refers to the increase

    in prices, it is independent and exclusive of inflation. Real escalation measures the

    change of the prices over or above the general inflation and may result, for example,

    due to the scarcity and depletion of resources, increase or decrease of the competition

    in the market, the origin of economies of scale in the market etc. (IAEA, 2010; HM

    Treasury, 2003). Due to the importance of this aspect, this will be taken into account

    in the further analitical part.

    2.1.3 Social Discount RateIt is extremely well known that money at hand today is not worth the same the next

    year. As a result, the costs and benefits that occur later in the future needs to be

    discounted in order to arrive at present values. For this reason, appraisals, which

    evaluate the attractiveness of investment opportunities, are highly dependent on the

    6 The construction input price change is used in order to better reflect the inflation in national

    construction sector, while the GDP deflator reflects the general change in prices.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    16/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    11

    choice of discount rate. In general, low discount rates favor the projects with the

    highest total benefits regardless the time they occur. However, in the case of

    increasing the discount rate, there will be smaller weights applied to the costs andbenefits that occur far in the future and as a result this will weaken the projects that

    are back-end loaded (Boardman et al., 2006).

    A proper social discount rate (SDR), which reflects the social point of view on how

    individuals are willing to give up consumption today in exchange for additional

    consumption in the future, must be chosen when evaluating government policies or

    projects. Due to the failures in financial markets the SDR may differ from the

    financial rate of return (Campbell and Brown, 2003; European Commission, 2008b).There are two main approaches available and widely discussed in the literature on

    how to derive the appropriate SDR:

    1) Derive SDR from the rates observable in the market (four alternatives):o Marginal rate of return on private investments;o Social marginal rate of time preference (MRTP);o Governments real borrowing rate;o Weighted average rate of the oncoming rates.

    2) Use social time preference rate (STPR) approach.Firstly, a traditional argument for using a marginal rate of return on private

    investments states that public investment should be competitive with private

    investments, i.e. public project should be at least as good as the private one (European

    commission, 2008b). Secondly, using a MRTP as SDR is based on the principle that

    individuals are willing to delay consumption today in order to receive additional

    consumption in the future. Thirdly, many economists suggest using long-term

    governments borrowing rate as SDR as it is the rate that reflects real cost of

    financing (Boardman et al., 2006). As there is no official guideline existing in

    Lithuania which suggests the consistent use of SDR for social project evaluation,

    Kuodis (2009) also suggest to use governments eurobond interest rate in the

    Lithuanian case. The last alternative of deriving SDR from the market is simply to

    use the weighted average of the previously proposed rates (Boardman et al., 2006).

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    17/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    12

    Finally, the other option is to obtain the SDR from forecasted long-term growth in the

    economy, i.e. use the so called social time preference (STPR) approach, which has an

    increasing consensus among the social planners. There are some instances ofEuropean countries that set SDR on the basis of STPR (European Commission,

    2008b). For example, France use 4% SDR, Germany 3% and UK 3.5% (Evans,

    2006). European Commission (2008b) suggests using 3.5% SDR for mature European

    countries and 5.5% for Cohesion countries whose economies are expected to grow at

    a faster phase than the old members. The formula for deriving SDR from the growth

    rate is the following:

    r = eg + p

    rReal social discount rate;

    gGrowth rate of per capita consumption;

    eElasticity of marginal utility of consumption;

    pPure time preference.

    Source: European Commission (2008b)

    STPR consist of two major components: utilitarian preference (eg) and pure time

    preference (p). The utilitarian part estimates the utility decrease of a marginal moneyunit resulted by the increases in real income. This means that if per capita

    consumption is expected to increase over time, the future consumption will be

    abundant relative to today and as a result will have a lower marginal utility (HM

    Treasury, 2003). Individuals from a developing country will require a higher

    compensation for postponing current consumption than individuals from a developed

    country because the future consumption will be more plentiful relative to current

    levels (European Commission, 2008b). The other component (p) representsconsumers impatience, i.e. at what rate the individuals discount future consumption

    over present consumption if there is no change in per capita consumption (HM

    Treasury, 2003).

    All the parameters in the above formula is specific to the individual country, in

    particular the growth in per capita consumption (g). Here it is intended to review the

    possible ranges of these parameters and derive the SDR for the Lithuanian case.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    18/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    13

    Pure time preference (p) is affected by the life expectancy and other individual

    features (European Commission, 2008b). Evans (2006) takes into account all the

    different views on estimating this parameter and summarizes that an appropriaterange should lie between 0%-2%. However, the author concludes that the safest

    option is to use 1% as the evidence on annual death-rate statistics provides the basis

    for this figure in most EU countries.

    In order to estimate real annual per capita growth rate in Lithuania, here it has been

    chosen to retrieve historical real consumption per capita and GDP per capita growth

    from the national statistics. The annual change in these parameters from 1992-2009 is

    attached in Appendix 2. The results show that on average consumption per capitagrew by 5.4% and GDP per capita increased by 3.2%

    The elasticity of marginal utility of consumption (e) measures how quick the social

    marginal utility of consumption falls as the per capita consumption increases. Ife is

    equal to zero, this means that consumption units received today is treated by society

    the same as the consumption units received in the future, i.e. there is no concern on

    intergenerational inequality. In the situation where e is equal to one, this means that

    the relative weight on societys consumption in each time period equals the inverse ofits relative per capita consumption (Boardman et al., 2006). This component is

    affected by the social and individual preferences therefore the estimation of this

    parameter is not that obvious (European Commission, 2008b). Evans (2006) states

    that estimating e with behavioural approaches causes empirical problems and as a

    result bases the estimate ofe on tax data and foreign aid contributions. The author

    concludes that e close to unity should be applied. HM Treasury (2003) also uses

    marginal utility equal to 1 and concludes that an additional consumption unit to ageneration that has twice the consumption of the current generation will decrease the

    utility by half.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    19/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    14

    Table 1. Deriving SDR for LithuaniaCase p e g SDR

    Optimistic 0% 1 3.2% 3.2%Base 1% 1 4.3% 5.3%

    Pessimistic 2% 1 5.4% 7.4%

    Data sources: estimates on p, e and g based on Evans (2006), Lithuanian Statistical Department

    (2010), HM Treasury (2003).

    The derived SDR rates from Table 1 will be used in the appraisal of a new NPP for

    the base, optimistic and pessimistic cases. In the base case the SDR estimate of 5.3%

    is close to the European Commission (2008b) suggestion and supports the argument

    that SDR for a Cohesion country should be higher relative to the developed EU

    countries.

    However, there is one more issue that should be addressed here, i.e. intergenerational

    equity. Due to the fact that nuclear power project would disperse the costs and

    benefits through a considerably long period of time, it might be inferred that

    individuals not yet born may be affected by the project and individuals that bear some

    of the costs may not be alive to reap the benefits. For example, using a constant SDR

    implies that it is not efficient for the society to allocate even a small amount of

    resources today in order to avoid very costly effects in the far future. This raises an

    ethical dilemma and gives the basis for taking into account sustainability and

    intergenerational equity issues by applying a time-declining SDR. Another argument

    for time-declining SDR is uncertainty. The wider the future perspective, the more

    uncertainty there is concerning the growth rate and other aspects of the economy

    (Boardman et al., 2006).

    HM Treasury (2003) also recommends to use the approach of decreasing SDR rates

    depending on the project duration in order to give more weight to the costs and

    benefits of the project that occur far in the future. Starting from the time span of 31-

    75 years, HM Treasury (2003) decreases the SDR by 0.5%. The same procedure will

    be followed in the CBA appraisal of a new NPP.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    20/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    15

    2.1.4 Investment criterionThe most widely applied investment criterion in practice is the net present value

    (NPV) principle. As mentioned above, the main reason for discounting future socialcosts and benefits is to convert them into present values, which takes into account

    societys impatience to consume today instead of tomorrow and allows the

    comparability between the project alternatives (Boardman et al., 2006). The formula

    for NPV calculation is:

    = C0 + (Bt Ct)1 + SDRt

    =1

    Net social benefits at time t equals to the difference between social benefits (Bt) and

    costs (Ct) occurring at that time. After the discounting procedure, net benefits in

    different time periods are converted to present values and summed (also taking into

    account the possible cost (Co) occurring in the beginning of the project). NPV

    investment criterion means that one should recommend to allocate the resources to

    the project if NPV of that project is positive (NPV>0). On the contrary, if NPV is

    negative (NPV

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    21/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    16

    to arrive at certain estimates and assumptions. Therefore, the data must be gathered

    consistently so that it is actually comparable and can facilitate the comparative

    analysis between different electricity generating technologies (DEA, 2005).According to Cooper (2009), some of the variability in the cost estimates is a result

    of comparing apples to oranges (p.17). Therefore, for the sake of clarity, it is of great

    importance to identify the common aspects of electricity generating technologies. The

    main variables of electricity generating costs are structured in Figure 3.

    Figure 3. Key cost variables of power plants

    Overnight construction cost sometimes is called as instant costs, which are

    dedicated to construction of the plant. It comprises of Engineering-Procurement-

    Construction (EPC) and owners cost. EPCmeans bare plant costs, for example, in acase of nuclear power plant, these costs would be dedicated to purchase turbine and

    steam generators, reactor vessel and other necessary materials, compensating for

    construction workers etc. Whereas, owners costdepends on whether the project is a

    Greenfield investment or replaces the old plant. Therefore, it might comprise of

    buying a land and cooling infrastructure, administrating site works and constructing

    associated buildings, managing the project, acquiring licenses etc. (Cooper, 2009;

    WNA, 2010).

    Construction Cost is "all-in" or installed costs, which sums overnight construction

    cost and interest during construction (IDC). IDC is largely dependent on country

    specific economic context, the form of financing the project, construction cost and

    time. Due to the inclusion of financing cost, total construction costs are very sensitive

    to the building delays (Thomas, 2005).

    Non-fueloperating and maintenance costs (O&M) are dedicated to controlling and

    running the utility, repairing it. In the case of nuclear power plant, O&M costs are

    Busbar/Levelized-cost

    Construction cost

    Overnight

    EPCOwner's cost

    IDC

    Operating costs

    O&M Fuel Cycle cost

    Front-End Back-End

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    22/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    17

    mostly fixed, i.e. independent of the plant capacity factor and contain of labor cost,

    expenditure on outside support services, moderator and coolant makeup, nuclear

    liability insurance etc. (IAEA, 1984).Fuel cycle cost is buying all materials and services associated with fuel. Cost analysis

    of gas, oil or coal fuel cycle is less complicated than that of uranium, because

    conventional fuels are consumed instantaneously whereas nuclear fuel is used in a

    reactor for several years (IAEA, 1984). Nuclear fuel cycle includes steps from

    uranium acquisition to waste disposal and is divided into the front-end and back-end.

    Front-End costs is uranium supply cost, which includes mining of natural uranium

    ore, conversion, enrichment and delivering already fabricated fuel to the reactor. Asthese costs are mostly associated with services of processing uranium, the volatility of

    the price is much smaller than that of commodity prices (NEA et al., 2005).Back-

    End costs are relevant to all power plants that use fuel, but in practice are of great

    importance only for nuclear power plants (Sustainable Development Commission,

    2006). In the case of nuclear power, back-end costs are dedicated to waste disposal

    and plant decommissioning.

    Decommissioning cost is inquired while dismantling plants. It also can be entitled asa scrap or horizon value. These costs arise very far in the future, when operational

    period is complete. Therefore, they have little effect on the overall economics after

    discounting procedure. Usually the owner of the plant is required to collect the

    decommissioning fund and collecting schemes are provided to ensure that the money

    is available after the plant is finished its operation (Thomas, 2005).

    As seen in Figure 3, busbar or levelised cost involves all-in, O&M and fuel cycle

    costs. Using cost of capital as a discount rate, the price of producing electricity isderived. According to Koomey and Hultman (2007) these costs are defined as total

    discounted cost of conveying electricity from a production unit to the point of

    interconnection with electricity grid. Therefore, these costs represent cost of

    producing electricity and addition of transmission and distribution costs results in a

    price, which consumers pay for the electricity7 (Cooper, 2009).

    7 More on this levelised-cost estimation methodology is discussed in section 2.2.2.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    23/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    18

    It is also important to mention one more parameter in energy economics, i.e. plant

    load factor, also called capacity factor in the US. This parameter is very important

    because it measures the operating performance and reliability of energy generatingunit. Thomas (2005) defines it as output in a given period of time expressed as a

    percentage of the output that would have been produced if the unit had operated

    uninterrupted at its full-design output level throughout the period concerned

    (Thomas, 2005, p.20). IAEA (1984) provides the following formula:

    % = ()8 ()

    This difference between the actual and theoretical maximum arises because ofplanned maintenance, forced outages, other circumstances when a plant lacks of load

    or the nuclear power is more expensive than other energy (Kaplan, 2008). The factor

    can be denominated on annual or lifetime basis. Plant operators are especially

    concerned about this variable, because the higher output produced means the lower

    generating cost per unit, i.e. capital costs are divided over more units (Sustainable

    Development Commission, 2006).

    2.2.2 Levelised-cost methodologyOne of the major parts in the forthcoming analytical section is going to be numerous

    cost estimations of a new nuclear power plant and a comparison with the other

    electricity generating alternative. This will require application of levelised-cost

    methodology, which is standardized, conventionally accepted and widely used in a

    range of literature.

    The rationale of levelised-cost approach is to quantify various costs of different

    electricity generation options throughout their economic lifetime and estimate busbar

    cost of generating electricity. This is done by dividing these lifetime expenses from

    expected outputs and applying discounting procedure (NEA et al., 2005). The

    following formula, provided by NEA et al. (2005), will be applied in further

    calculations:

    8Important distinction between capacity and energy terms. Capacity measured in watts and meansa potential output of a unit, while energy is denominated in watt-hours and measures the actual amount

    of electricity generated during a time period (Kaplan, 2008).

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    24/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    19

    = I0 + It + Mt + Ft1 + rt /

    =1

    Et1 + rt

    =1

    EGCaverage lifetime levelised electricity generation cost;

    ItCapital investment in year t;

    MtOperating and maintenance cost in the year t;

    FtFuel cycle cost in the year t;

    EtElectricity output in year t (Et= 87609*Plant Capacity*Load Factor);

    rCost of capital (post tax real WACC);

    nEconomic life of a plant.

    The methodology to be applied is applied by electricity generating utilities,

    governmental agencies and international organizations in order to provide economic

    assessments of alternative generation options (NEA, 2008). However, the levelised

    costs excludes environmental or other social costs and indicate the average price that

    consumers will have to pay for the plant operators and investors in order to offset the

    expenditure they incur and to repay a proper amount of return (NEA et al. 2005). This

    cost will be quoted in terms of LTL/MWh

    10

    .In order to picture separate contributions of cost variables to the EGC, UKs

    Sustainable Development Commission (2006) provides typical cost proportions for

    the most popular electricity generating alternatives, assuming 10% real cost of capita l

    (see Table 2).

    9 There are 8760 hours per year (365*24=8670)10 LTL is an abbreviation forLitasthe national currency of Lithuania.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    25/90

    Se

    ction:Theoreticalfoundations

    20

    Table 2. Representative proportions of electricity generating costs, %Variable Nuclear CCGT11

    Renewable

    (wind)

    Construction or capital (including IDC) 60-75 30-40 85-90

    Fuel 5-10 50-60 0

    O&M 8-15 5-10 5-15

    Back-End * 0 0

    Source: Sustainable Development Commission (2006), p.7

    Generally, it is seen that nuclear and wind power generation is highly capital

    intensive process relative to gas-fired plants. On the other hand, for CCGTs it istypical to have relatively high expenditures on fuel. As mentioned before, back-end

    fuel costs are only relevant in the case of nuclear, but they are highly uncertain. In the

    paper of Sustainable Development Commission (2006) it is explained that this is so,

    primarily because the cost depends on the waste management decisions, i.e. whether

    reprocessing of spent fuel is made. Secondly, there is little commercial experience

    concerning decommissioning and waste management. Nevertheless, as these costs

    can stretch over hundreds of years, the paper concludes that these costs are expectedto be only a small proportion of average lifetime levelised electricity generation cost.

    Of course, these proportions is just a generalization and separate variables depend,

    firstly, on the type of a plant and, moreover, on the country specific context

    (Sustainable Development Commission, 2006).

    11Combined Cycle Gas Turbine plant

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    26/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    21

    3.AnalysisThe analytical part of the thesis begins with a description of the project and, as

    mentioned in the introduction, later follows six major steps12. The steps followed are

    described in detail when they are applied.

    3.1Project description and alternativesAfter the shutdown ofIgnalina NPP, the government declared that the major task in

    the energy sector is to ensure reliable and secure supply of electricity in Lithuania.

    One of the options to reach this goal is to construct a new NPP. Therefore, the subject

    of this analysis is to conduct an economic assessment of investment into a new NPP inLithuania.

    This alternative has been considered already for a while. In the late 2006 a summary of

    a nuclear build feasibility study was provided to the public, picturing nuclear power

    expansion in a good light. A number of actions were also taken in order to make a

    project become a reality. The collaboration acts were signed with the neighboring EU

    countries, Environmental Impact Assessment of the site was completed, the Parliament

    approved a construction of a new NPP in the Lithuanian Republic and the law ofNuclear power station was issued. Today Lithuania is at the milestone of negotiating

    the proposals received from the potential investors and signing the partnership

    agreement (Visaginas Nuclear Power Plant Ltd., 2010).

    Despite this considerable effort, there has not been many decisions made concerning

    the details of the project. Lithuanias Ministry of Energy (2010) claims that, after the

    selection of strategic investor in 2010, the final decisions on the number of reactors

    and optimal capacity, the type and design of reactor will be done. However, the

    specifications of a project are vital in this analysis. Because the construction of a new

    NPP can vary in many aspects and create numerous potential alternatives, the set of

    scenarios will be created taking into account the proposed features of the project. The

    CBA appraisal will be based on the base case scenario and some of the most important

    12 See Figure 2 in the introduction section

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    27/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    22

    assumptions of pesimistic and optimistic scenarios will be tested in the sensitivity

    analysis.

    Site of a project

    A new NPP is planned to be built near the borders with Latvia and Belarus, on the

    south bank ofDrkiai Lake, where the old Ignalina NPP is situated13. The plant is

    called under the name of adjacent town Visaginas (Visaginas Nuclear Power Plant

    Ltd., 2010). This particular site is chosen because of the obvious benefits of existing

    infrastructure. As this is not a Greenfield investment, it will have considerable effect

    on the upfront investment size.

    Capacity demanded

    The operator of Lithuanian transmission system claims that current Lithuanian

    generating capacities will be sufficient to meet the national demand until 2013. A new

    NPP should replace the old reactors in Ignalina, which had a capacity of 1300 MWe

    each, and add capacity of maximum 3400 MWe. (Lietuvos Energija, 2007). This

    number would translate into approximatelly 27 TWh of electricity output per year.

    Whereas, according to Lithuanian Statistical Department (2010) Lithuania consumed

    around 9 TWh in 2008. In addition, Figure 4 depicts possible scenarios of electricity

    demand growth in Lithuania.

    Figure 4. Projections of electricity demand in Lithuania

    Data Source: International Atomic Energy Agency (2007), p.111

    13 See Appendix 3 for the map

    6

    8

    10

    12

    14

    16

    18

    2010 2015 2020 2025

    Electricityde

    mand,TWh

    Year

    Slow economic growth

    scenario

    Basic Scenario

    Fast economic growth

    scenario

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    28/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    23

    As seen from Figure 4, the electricity output of 27 TWh would exceed the demand

    even in the scenario of fast economic growth. Therefore, as Wenisch and Mraz (2008)

    claim this would be more than a simple replacement of the old reactors. It has to beemphasized that a new capacity should be added only in two cases, i.e. replacing the

    existing capacity due to retirement and meeting demand growth. Otherwise, a new

    investment would result in excessive cost, displace other investments and would be

    economically unjustified (Kennedy, 2007). It can be concluded that, from a national

    perspective, there is a capacity only for 800-1600MWe14 plant, which would produce

    approximately 6.312.6 TWh of electricity. This conclusion can be also supported by

    Lithuanian experts opinion, which states that to satisfy current national demand it is

    enough capacity of around 1000MWe (Visaginas Nuclear Power Plant Ltd., 2010).

    Hereby, in the base case scenario it is assumed a 1000MWe capacity, pessimistic

    scenario800MWe and optimistic1600MWe.

    Reactor type

    There also has not been much discussion about the type of a reactor expected to be

    built in Lithuania although according to Thomas (2005) it is clear that the most

    relevant designs for the future orders will be advanced reactors - Generation III orGeneration III+ designs. Juozaitis (2006) provides information on the nuclear

    technologies under consideration in Lithuania. The following Table 3 lists a wide

    range of technical alternatives, i.e. boiling water (BWR), pressurized water (PWR) and

    pressurized heavy water (PHWR) reactors.

    14 These figures were considered in the primary plan and stated in the summary of a feasibility study,

    provided by Lietuvos Energija (2006)

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    29/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    24

    Table 3. Nuclear technologies under considerationTechnologies Type Size, MWe Supplier

    V-392 WWER (PWR) 1006 AtomStroyExportV-448 WWER (PWR) 1500 AtomStroyExport

    ABWR BWR 1300 Hitachi (General Electric)

    ESBWR BWR 1535 General Electric

    SWR-1000 BWR 1254 AREVA Nuclear Power

    ACR-1000 PHWR 1085 Atomic Energy of Canada Limited

    EC-6 PHWR 700 Atomic Energy of Canada Limited

    APWR PWR 1700 Mitsubishi Heavy Industries

    AP-1000 PWR 1000 Westinghouse

    AP-600 PWR 600 Westinghouse

    EPR PWR 1600 AREVA Nuclear Power

    Source: Juozaitis (2006), slide 18; WNA (2010)

    Using information provided in the British Sustainable Development Commissions

    (2006) report, the assumption on the reactor likely to be built in Lithuania can be

    arrived at. According to the report, WWER is a type of Russian PWR design similar to

    Chernobyl, which is currently ordered by China and India. Here it can be assumed thatLithuania would align with Western Europe practice, where only a little possibility

    exist that Russian designs would be attempted to license. A Japanese ABWR and

    APWR are also unlikely to be built in Lithuania, because so far these suppliers have

    not ever tried to export these designs to the West and it is not likely to change

    (Thomas, 2005). The other BWRs tend to produce higher operator doses than other

    reactor types (Sustainable Development Commission, 2006, p.10). Therefore, it is

    assumed that the other technologies are superior relative to BWRs. The Canadian

    PHWRs could be an alternative, but the British report stresses out that the licensing

    process is significantly longer then for PWRs (Sustainable Development Commission,

    2006). Finally, the options of PWRs are left. Therefore, for the purpose of this

    appraisal it is assumed that it is likely that the PWRs supplied by Westinghouse or

    AREVA will be ordered in Lithuania.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    30/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    25

    Operating performance

    Having assumed that a likely reactor is an advanced one, the operating performance

    can be discussed. Thomas (2005) summarizes that historically the assumptions on loadfactor provided by vendors and other technology promoters were somewhat

    misleading. While the load factors of nuclear plants were projected to reach 85-90%,

    the reality showed that worldwide average load factor was only around 60%. The

    importance of this inaccuracy can be illustrated by a simple example. If the load factor

    is assumed 90% and fixed costs represent two-thirds of the overall nuclear generation

    cost, 60% load factor would mean the overall cost to increase by a one-third. In 2005,

    only 7 out of 414 reactors showed a lifetime load factor higher than 90% and only 100plants more than 80% (Thomas, 2005).

    While a number of sources provide higher effectiveness of new generation plants

    relative to the ones already in operation, there is little confidence about the operating

    effectiveness and reliability based on the historical evidence. AREVA, the supplier of

    European Pressurized Reactors (EPRs) which are likely to be built in Lithuania, claims

    the average load factor of 93% over the entire service life of the plant (AREVA,

    2010). However, European Commission (2008a) assumes the EPRs load factor only of85%.

    Thomas (2005) also provides and argument about the teething problems, which

    mean that the performance of the advanced plant during the first years of operation

    might be poorer than expected. In addition, the decline in performance during the

    operating life is expected to decline as the equipment and machines tends to wear out

    and needs to be replaced. Nonetheless, this decline may be of a lesser importance

    relative to the teething problems because the replacements would take place furtherin the future and discounting procedure would assign smaller weight (Thomas, 2005).

    Taking the discussed details this into account, the load factor of the nuclear alternative

    is assumed to be 85% in the first 5 years of operation and afterwards increase to 90%.

    Timeframe of the project

    AREVA and Westinghouse assure to be able to build a nuclear reactor in 3 years

    (CitiGroup, 2009). However, the most recent examples of Finish Olkiluoto and French

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    31/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    26

    Flamanville EPRs show that a new nuclear construction is a subject of significant

    construction delays. International Energy Agency (2007) projects the construction

    time to equal 60 months. European Commission (2008) suggests assuming a 6-yearconstruction period, while Lietuvos Energija (2006) assumes the same. This is not

    overoptimistic and is considered to be reasonable. Therefore, this will be assumed in

    the analysis.

    The implementation company of Visaginas project declares that the expected

    generation starting date is 2019-2020 (Visaginas Nuclear Power Plant Ltd., 2010).

    Having in mind that the preparations for construction is not finished yet though

    initiated, a construction starting date is assumed to be the beginning of 2014.

    Another important aspect in the analysis is the economic lifetime of a plant. The 3rd

    generation plants are considered to have a longer accounting life relative to their

    predecessors (Thomas, 2005). According to AREVA (2010), their reactors are

    designed for 60 years life service. Again to avoid optimism bias, here it is assumed the

    operational life of 40 years as suggested by International Energy Agency (2007) and

    European Commission (2008). The assumed timeframe of the project is summarized in

    the Figure 5.

    Figure 5. Assumed timeline of the new nuclear build project

    Although the decision to build a nuclear plant was made in 2006, the analysis will take

    into account impacts of a project from 2010 as costs already occurred are considered

    as sunk costs and should not be a subject in the analysis. Regarding the cost and

    benefit occurrence over the course of a year, Boardman et al. (2006) suggest to treat

    these impacts as if they are experienced in the middle of a year. However, this would

    complicate the calculations and would not improve the analysis greatly. Therefore, it is

    assumed that benefits and costs of the project are accumulated immediately in the

    beginning of the project (t=0) and later at the end of the year (t=1,2,,n).

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    32/90

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    33/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    28

    Hereby, it is assumed that a possibly diverted project would have a construcion period

    of 3 years. This assumption is consistent with the information provided by other

    organizations such as NEA, IEA and OECD. They estimated that gas-fired powerplants are built rapidly and the expense schedules reported show that in most cases

    expenditures are spread over two to three years (NEA et al., 2005, p.12).

    The exploitation period of a gas-fired plant is also shorter as compared to a nuclear

    plant. The expected operational life varies between 25-35 years according to various

    sources. Lietuvos Elektrin (2009) projects the operating life of not less than 30 years.

    Hence, this figure will be used in the following calculations. Concerning the operating

    performance of the CCGT Lithuanian Plant expects to reach the load factor of 90%and thermal efficiency of 58.4% (Lietuvos Elektrin, 2009).

    3.2 Scope and StandingThe second step in the CBA appraisal is to define whose costs and benefits should be

    included. More precisely, one should define whose welfare counts in the aggregation

    of the net benefits (European Commission, 2008b, p.31). The analysis can be

    approached from various perspectives, i.e. local, provincial, national, regional or even

    global (Boardman et al., 2006; Jensen and Bakker, 2006).

    There has been chosen to limit the analysis to the national standpoint. This is so

    because Lithuanian government firstly seeks to implement its individual national

    energy policy, i.e. to secure the supply of electricity to Lithuanian inhabitants.

    However, adding a nuclear power plant could have an impact on the whole Baltic

    region and actors from Poland, Latvia, Estonia and Russia could be affected as well.

    This is so because the plant is an integrated part of the whole Baltic energy system and

    it might significantly affect the market supply which in turn might result in changes of

    the electricity market price (European Commission, 2008b; Campbel and Brown,

    2003). Besides this possible effect, adding a NPP into the system and displacing

    investment into a gas-fired plant would also capture significant effects on climate

    change, which fundamentally is of global concern (European Commission, 2008b).

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    34/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    29

    3.3 Identification, quantification and monetization of costs and benefitsThe next step is ultimate in this appraisal as it covers the identification of costs and

    benefits to be estimated, specifies the measurement indicators, forecasts thedevelopment of costs and benefits over the life of the project and puts the money value

    to them if it is possible to do so.

    Boardman and others (2006) stress out that while listing the impacts caused by the

    policy it is very important to take into account only those which affect the utility of

    individuals and leave out those which have no value to the human beings. The impact

    identification requires defining the cause-and-effect relationship between the outcome

    of the policy and the utility of individuals. This is often forgotten by politicians, whotend to generalize the impacts (Boardman et al., 2006). For example, Lithuanian

    government states that an economic stimulus from a new Visaginas NPP is expected to

    be large; the use of local supply chain will benefit the Lithuanian economy etc.

    (Visaginas Nuclear Power Plant Ltd., 2010). Thus, from the first sight a

    straightforward task can become a complex one.

    Using the examples of Kennedy (2007), Jensen and Bakker (2006), information from

    British Sustainable Development Commission (2006) and many other articles onelectricity generation cost, there has been identified the impacts to be discussed and

    evaluated in this CBA appraisal (see Table 4).

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    35/90

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    36/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    31

    benefits of nuclear expansion are compared in regard with that of gas-fired electricity

    generation.

    Together with identification of costs and benefits it is necessary to specify themeasurement indicators, which is mostly straightforward (Boardman et al., 2006).

    There are numerous electricity generation costs to be evaluated and they mostly

    depend on the capacity of the plant (MW) or the electricity output produced (MWh).

    Consequently, most of the costs will be expressed as Litas per MW (LTL/MW) or

    Litas per MWh (LTL/MWh). The benefit of greenhouse gas reduction is measured as

    Litas saved by reducing a ton of CO2 annually (LTL/t CO2 eq.) and the security of

    supply benefit is expressed as expenditures saved from renting a gas storage andbuying additional gas (LTL/m3).

    The extensive explanation of the details on identified costs and benefits is given in the

    following part and discussed individually.

    3.3.1 Cost Penalty/AdvantageThe choice of electricity generation technology mainly depends on its cost. The

    following approach used by Kennedy (2007) has been chosen to be employed in the

    appraisal. The costs of generating electricity with nuclear and gas-fired plants will be

    estimated and necessary assumptions will be made to reflect the situation in the

    Lithuanian market as close as possible. In order to allow the comparability of cost

    magnitudes between these options, levelised costs of each alternative will be estimated

    (using private investment cost of capital). Subsequently, nuclear levelised-cost will be

    deducted from gas-fired levelised-cost and there will be arrived at levelised-cost

    differences, which will be located within the assumed operational life of the nuclear

    power plant and multiplied by the assumed annual electricity output. This will lead to

    nuclear cost penalty or cost advantagesocial cost or benefit. According to Kennedy

    (2007), this procedure will allow to evaluate the opportunity cost of capital and take

    into account a commercial view of risks associated with electricity generation

    investments.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    37/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    32

    Pre-development costs of nuclear and gas-fired plants

    Pre-development costs will not be included in the appraisal partly due to the fact that

    the preparation of building a NPP in Lithuania already began and some money hasalready been spent. Various pre-development related stages are completed:

    environmental impact analysis is prepared, other consultancy services are used, and

    geological research on the site is performed etc. Decisions about these costs cannot be

    made anymore and they should be considered as sunk cost; therefore, they should not

    be a subject in the analysis. Pre-development costs still expected to be incurred are

    uncertain and are considered relatively small. It is assumed that not involving these

    costs for nuclear and gas-fired electricity generation technologies will not distortresults significantly.Nuclear investment cost

    The major variable in the economics of nuclear power plants is investment cost, which

    receives the most attention in the appraisals. This is so, primarily because it usually

    accounts for approximately 60-70 percent of nuclear generation costs, i.e. costs that

    will be inquired whether or not the plant starts its operation (Thomas, 2005; Linares

    and Conchado, 2009). The magnitude of the initial investment critically diminishes the

    competiveness of nuclear power as compared to the other forms of power generation.

    Conversely, the other forms of electricity generation such as gas-fired plants contains

    of significantly greater operational costs related to the purchase of expensive fuel

    (Sustainable Development Commission, 2006).

    The fact that investment costs of nuclear power plants are very uncertain is well

    known and widely disputed in the literature. The main reasons, why construction costs

    are difficult to forecast, could be summarized in two points. Firstly, the controversy

    occurs as a result of a necessity to estimate costs based on the past data, which might

    be unreliable (Cooper, 2009). On the other hand, the difficulty arises due to the nature

    of the project (Thomas, 2005).

    Thomas (2005) argues that cost estimates provided by bodies with a concern in the

    technology should be treated with skepticism. A large pool of such actors can be

    mentioned, i.e. promotional bodies, plant vendors, nuclear utilities, international

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    38/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    33

    agencies and governments. The last eight years overnight cost estimates15, collected

    from various studies and summarized by Copper (2009), supports the argument.

    Figure 6. Estimates of nuclear reactor overnight costs

    Data source: LietuvosEnergija (2006), Cooper (2009), p. 23

    Cooper (2009) states, that low cost estimates during 2001-2005 was provided by

    technology vendors and academics based on earlier bandwagon market in the 1970s.

    Followed by favorable governments support, this led to formation of nuclear

    renaissance. Starting with 2007, nuclear utilities already provided almost doubled

    overnight construction figures. However, this was only the lower part of the range and

    independent energy analysts estimated the construction costs even higher (Cooper,

    2009). Therefore, the evidence suggests that evaluation of nuclear construction costs

    should be treated with high level of cautiousness.

    As mentioned before, the other reason why it is difficult to forecast nuclear

    construction costs is the nature of the project. Thomas (2005) explains that such large

    scale projects as building a nuclear power plant demands a large amount of on-site

    engineering and this causes difficulties to manage and control costs. The third

    generation nuclear reactors are expected to have lower construction costs as compared

    to ancestors due to learning, economies of scale and new technology. However, today

    this is not the case and recent constructions experience significant time delays and

    15 Original data is provided in Appendix 7

    2,000

    4,000

    6,000

    8,000

    10,000

    12,000

    14,000

    16,000

    18,000

    20,000

    2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010

    OvernightConstructioncost,Lt/kW

    (in2010prices)

    Date of Estimate

    Lithuanian estimate

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    39/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    34

    result in enormous cost overruns. These construction costs cannot be locked-in

    because nuclear power plants are not sold on turnkey terms, i.e. vendor cannot

    assure a fixed construction price due to the complexity of the project (Thomas, 2005).Recent cases provide evidence that actual nuclear construction costs are likely to

    overrun their primary estimates (see Table 5).

    Table 5. Recent evidence on III generation nuclear reactor construction cost

    Plant Technology

    Overnight Construction Cost, LTL/kW

    (in 2010 prices)

    Primary estimate Updated estimate/Actual

    Olkiluoto (Finland) EPR 8,065 14,150Flamanville (France) EPR 10,054

    San Men (China) AP-1000 2,957 8,600

    Bellefonte (USA) AP-1000 12,430

    (Georgia) 17,005*

    Visaginas (Lithuania) 7,915

    *IDC included

    Data source: Lietuvos Energija (2006) and own elaboration based on CitiGroup (2009)

    CitiGroup (2009) summarizes that the developers and builders, such as AREVA and

    Westinghouse, assure to be able to build a nuclear reactor in 3 years. Nevertheless,

    Finland, France, China and the US had to update the targeted estimates due to

    construction delays and planning problems. Georgia already sets cost estimate to the

    highest level. One of the most famous examples of cost overruns is Finish Olkiluoto

    EPR plant, which is already 3 years behind the schedule and the construction cost

    estimate had to be increased by around 60% (CitiGroup, 2009). This recent data shows

    fragility and uncertainty of time schedules and costs of new build, but BritishEnvironmental Audit Committee (2006) concludes that this does not necessarily

    indicate that new nuclear power plants cannot be built as scheduled and within the

    budget. It means that private investors may require higher rate of return for

    experiencing higher risks.

    Lithuanian electricity transmittor Lietuvos Energija provided overnight cost estimate

    for a new nuclear built in 2006. As seen in Table 5, this estimate converted to 2010

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    40/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    35

    prices equals 7915 LTL/kW. In the context of other studies (see Figure 6), the estimate

    takes place in a lower range of the interval. Here it can be argued that this estimate is

    overoptimistic because it is likely that the expansion of nuclear power in Lithuania isattempted to be pictured in a good light. The comparative analysis have shown that

    this figure is one of the lowest, therefore might be a subject to optimism bias. HM

    Treasury (2003) emphasizes that this is a worldwide phenomena for the appraisers to

    underestimate the costs and to overestimate the benefits. British CBA guidline

    suggests to make empirically based adjustments in order to overcome the appraisal

    optimism and to complement the calculations with spesific risk adjustments. This can

    be done by referring to the historical data and other similar examples in the other

    countries.

    As a result, here it has been chosen to adjust the Lithuanian estimate by comparing it

    to the most recent and technologically similar examples in Europe, i.e. Olkiluoto

    (Finland) and Flamanville (France). As seen in Table 5, current estimates for

    overnight construction costs of these plants are 14,150 LTL/kW and 10,054 LTL/kW,

    which were corrected recently due to various construction problems, delays and even

    significant design changes (CitiGroup, 2009). In addition, European Commission

    (2008a) suggests using a base case assumption of 9,249 LTL/kW16 on overnight

    construction costs for nuclear fission (optimistic case6,798 LTL/kW; pesimistic

    11,664 LTL/kW). It can be argued that overnight construction costs for the Lithuanian

    NPP is likely to be around 10,000 LTL/kW. Historical data shows that the lower

    estimates of 6,798 and 7915 LTL/kW are likely to be overoptimistic because nuclear

    construction process is subject to various construction problems. However, the higher

    estimates of 11,664 and 14,150 LTL/kW might be too high for the Lithuanian NPP

    due to couple of reasons. Firstly, Lithuania is a country in Eastern Europe, which is

    known for lower costs (especially labor costs) relative to Scandinavia or Western

    Europe. Moreover, building a NPP in Lithuania is not a Greenfield investment because

    the site of the old plant is planned to be used. As discussed earlier, this might cause the

    owners costs to be significantly lower because there is no need for high investments

    into a new infrastructure. In addition, as first-of-its-kind EPR plants in Finland and

    16 Converted to 2010 prices by using annual average rates of change in construction input prices

    provided in Appendix 5

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    41/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    36

    France are almost completed, the argument of learning by doing can be applied. It is

    likely that vendors will be more experienced by the time a 3rd Generation reactor is

    ordered in Lithuania.Therefore, for the base case here it is assumed that NPP overnight construction costs

    are 10,000 LTL/kW. As this is a major cost component in the economics of nuclear

    power and is a subject to high uncertainties, for the forthcoming sensitivity analysis it

    is assumed that in an optimistic case the estimate is 7915 LTL/kW (provided by

    Lietuvos Energija in 2006) and for the pesimistic case 14,150 LTL/kW (CitiGroup,

    2009).

    Regarding the volume of costs spent in each year, NEA et al. (2005) notes that around90% of the construction costs are incured within the first 5 years or even less.

    Therefore, to account for different amounts of costs incurred in different years of

    construction, the fractions of expenditures were assumed (see Table 6).

    As mentioned before, total construction cost comprises not only of overnight

    construction cost but of interest during construction (IDC) as well. In order to evaluate

    IDC, it is assumed here that commercial banks charges 6% interest rate. The interest

    rate is derived from the comparison of overnight construction cost and total

    construction cost, which were provided by Lietuvos Energija (2006) in the summary of

    a potential NNP feasibility study.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    42/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    37

    Table 6. IDC calculations for the base caseOvernight construction cost: 10,000,000 LTL/MW

    Interest rate: 6.00%

    Year Fraction spent during

    the year (1)

    [(1+n)n -1]* (1) Interest amount,

    LTL/MW

    2014 10% 0.041852 418,519

    2015 20% 0.067645 676,451

    2016 30% 0.078743 787,431

    2017 20% 0.038203 382,032

    2018 10% 0.01236 123,600

    2019 10% 0.006 60,000

    Total 100% 0.244803 2,448,033

    nnumber of years between the time the resources are borrowed and the time the money is started to

    be paid back (start of operation).

    Source: The calculations are based on the approach suggested by IAEA (1984), p.551-552

    It can be concluded that total construction costs of a new NPP in a base case will

    amount for around 12.448 billion LTL or 12,448,033 LTL/MW (see Table 6).

    Investment costs of a gas-fired plant

    According to Thomas (2005) current generation CCGT are produced in factories,

    which are controlled by the vendors, and requires little on-site work, therefore they are

    available to be bought under trunkey terms. Concequently, there is almost no risk that

    the construction costs will increase.

    Concerning the gas-fired plant investments, here it has been chosen to base the

    assumptions on a recent project in Lithuania. Currently a modern combined cycle gas

    turbine (CCGT) is being built to replace the old and retired plant blocks in Lithuanian

    power-station. Staniulis and Adomaitien (2009) notes that a new block of 455MW

    electrical capacity will cost 384.3 million Euros (2009 price level) including interest

    during construction. Converted to current price level it amounts for 1,322 million Litas

    and translates to 2,905.49 LTL/kW. Therefore, it is assumed that similar blocks are

    displaced if investments flow to nuclear electricity generation.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    43/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    38

    For the forthcoming sensitivity analysis the estimate of similar CCGT investment in

    neighboring Latvia is selected. EBRD (2010) publishes project description document,

    where it is stated that 400MWe CCGT plant will cost 400 million Euros (2009 pricelevel). The construction cost is equal to 1,381.654 million Litas or 3,454 LTL/kW. The

    cost per kilowatt in the Latvian case is 26% higher than the Lithuanian estimate,

    consequently it is going to be used for the pesimistic case scenario. For the optimistic

    case, Staniulis and Adomaitien (2009) provide an estimate of 310 million Euros

    (2,352.367 LTL/kW).

    According to NEA et al. (2005) gas-fired plants are built rapidly and the majority of

    expenditures are incurred during the first 2-3 years of the construction. Here it isassumed that during the first and second year of construction there will be spent 40%

    of total expenditures each year and during the last year of the construction the

    remaining 20%. The results of total construction cost computation for nuclear and

    CCGT plants are summarized in the following table.

    Table 7. Total construction costs for nuclear and CCGT plants in the base case

    Year

    NUCLEAR CCGT

    IDC,

    LTL2010/MW

    Overnight

    construction

    cost,

    LTL2010/MW

    Total

    construction

    cost, LTL2010

    Construction

    cost,

    LTL2010/MW

    Total

    Construction

    cost, LTL2010

    2014 418,519 1,000,000 1,418,519,112 1,162,196 1,162,196,000

    2015 676,451 2,000,000 2,676,451,155 1,162,196 1,162,196,000

    2016 787,431 3,000,000 3,787,430,880 581,098 581,098,000

    2017 382,032 2,000,000 2,382,032,000

    2018 123,600 1,000,000 1,123,600,000

    2019 60,000 1,000,000 1,060,000,000

    Total 2,448,033 10,000,000 12,448,033,147 2,905,490 2,905,490,000

    The results show that to add 1000 MWe to the system by nuclear plant is around 4.3

    times more expensive than do it with a CCGT.

  • 8/2/2019 Thesis Zivile Kazlaus Kaite

    44/90

    Section

    :Analysis

    39

    Nuclear and gas-fired plant O&M costs

    Non-fuel O&M costs are mostly fixed and as a result does not depend on the

    electricity output (Thomas, 2005). Because these costs account for only 5-15% of thetotal cost of electricity17, there are fewer discussions in the literature on these

    variables. NEA et al. (2005) concludes that O&M costs may vary considerably across

    countries due to differences in wages and equipment prices.

    As there has not been found any relevant domestic data on O&M related to

    technologies representing new generation plants, it has been chosen to use data on the

    European level. According to European Commission (2008a) research, annualized

    O&M for nuclear fission technology amounts for 90 EUR2005/kW (398.853 LTL/kWin 2010 prices18) and CCGT annualized O&M costs amount for 25 EUR2005/kW (109.4

    LTL/kW18), which is assumed for the base case. For the pessimistic and optimistic

    scenarios, the data from the same European source is used. Annual nuclear O&M

    range from 323.834 LTL/kW to 468.248 LTL/kW and annual CCGT O&M vary

    between 83.148LTL/kW to 113.78 LTL/kW (European Commission, 2008a).

    It is expected that both nuclear and gas-fired plants, also related equipment and

    machines will depreciate over time. However, depreciation is a subject of financial

    accounting and should not be considered in CBA appraisal. Nevertheless, this is an

    argument for maintenance costs to increase over time as the plants getting old might

    require more repairs and other improvements (IAEA, 1984). The research of NEA et

    al. (2005) summarizes that the majority of CCTG and nuclear plants have a modest

    O&M cost escalation over the operational phase. The majority of the countries that

    participated in the research declare O&M cost escalation of 0.5-1%. Du and Parsons

    (2009) projects real non-fuel O&M costs to rise at 1% for nuclear plants. As a result,here it is also assumed 1% growth in costs for nuclear and CCGT plants. The results

    on O&M costs for both alternatives are at