the unthinkable policy option? key design issues under a

42
canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3, 421 - 62 421 The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a System of Full Consolidation Antony Ting* PRÉCIS En 2010, le ministère des Finances du Canada a lancé un processus de consultation visant à considérer l’établissement éventuel d’un régime officiel d’imposition des groupes de sociétés. La consultation s’est concentreé surtout sur le choix du meilleur type de régime pour le Canada. Les deux principales solutions adoptées dans d’autres pays sont le régime de transfert des pertes et le régime de consolidation intégrale. Il est difficile de faire un choix entre les deux régimes. Néanmoins, il est évident que l’intérêt provincial serait mieux servi par le système de consolidation intégrale, particulièrement en ce qui a trait à la question de la répartition interprovinciale du revenu. L’objet de cet article est de fournir une analyse comparative détaillée des régimes de consolidation adoptés dans huit pays : l’Australie, la France, l’Italie, le Japon, les Pays- Bas, la Nouvelle-Zélande, l’Espagne et les États-Unis. Ce sont les pays qui, dès la fin de 2009, avaient introduit des régimes de consolidation intégrale touchant à la fois la compensation des pertes à l’intérieur d’un groupe et les transferts d’actifs en franchise d’impôt. L’article fait une comparaison critique des options de politique alternatives en ce qui a trait aux paramètres de conception et aux principaux aspects structurels des huit régimes de consolidation choisis dans le but de trouver un système pouvant servir de modèle ou de base quant à l’élaboration d’un régime canadien. En réponse aux préoccupations touchant l’apparente complexité d’un régime de consolidation, l’article classe les huit régimes au moyen d’un indice de complexité. Cet exercice a pour but de souligner deux aspects de la question : premièrement, les huit régimes représentent un éventail des divers degrés de complexité, permettant de croire qu’un régime de consolidation n’a pas besoin d’être aussi complexe que les modèles australien et américain; et deuxièmement, la complexité d’un régime dépend en grande partie des choix de politique à l’égard des principaux aspects structurels. * Of the University of Sydney Business School (e-mail: [email protected]). I would like to thank Richard Vann for his continuous support and comments on earlier versions of this article. I am also indebted to Alan Macnaughton and Tim Edgar for their valuable suggestions and insightful comments, especially with respect to the issues surrounding the proposed introduction of a group taxation regime in Canada.

Upload: others

Post on 16-Oct-2021

10 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3, 421 - 62

421

The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a System of Full Consolidation

Antony Ting*

P R É C I S

En 2010, le ministère des Finances du Canada a lancé un processus de consultation visant à considérer l’établissement éventuel d’un régime officiel d’imposition des groupes de sociétés. La consultation s’est concentreé surtout sur le choix du meilleur type de régime pour le Canada. Les deux principales solutions adoptées dans d’autres pays sont le régime de transfert des pertes et le régime de consolidation intégrale. Il est difficile de faire un choix entre les deux régimes. Néanmoins, il est évident que l’intérêt provincial serait mieux servi par le système de consolidation intégrale, particulièrement en ce qui a trait à la question de la répartition interprovinciale du revenu.

L’objet de cet article est de fournir une analyse comparative détaillée des régimes de consolidation adoptés dans huit pays : l’Australie, la France, l’Italie, le Japon, les Pays-Bas, la Nouvelle-Zélande, l’Espagne et les États-Unis. Ce sont les pays qui, dès la fin de 2009, avaient introduit des régimes de consolidation intégrale touchant à la fois la compensation des pertes à l’intérieur d’un groupe et les transferts d’actifs en franchise d’impôt. L’article fait une comparaison critique des options de politique alternatives en ce qui a trait aux paramètres de conception et aux principaux aspects structurels des huit régimes de consolidation choisis dans le but de trouver un système pouvant servir de modèle ou de base quant à l’élaboration d’un régime canadien. En réponse aux préoccupations touchant l’apparente complexité d’un régime de consolidation, l’article classe les huit régimes au moyen d’un indice de complexité. Cet exercice a pour but de souligner deux aspects de la question : premièrement, les huit régimes représentent un éventail des divers degrés de complexité, permettant de croire qu’un régime de consolidation n’a pas besoin d’être aussi complexe que les modèles australien et américain; et deuxièmement, la complexité d’un régime dépend en grande partie des choix de politique à l’égard des principaux aspects structurels.

* OftheUniversityofSydneyBusinessSchool(e-mail:[email protected]).IwouldliketothankRichardVannforhiscontinuoussupportandcommentsonearlierversionsofthisarticle.IamalsoindebtedtoAlanMacnaughtonandTimEdgarfortheirvaluablesuggestionsandinsightfulcomments,especiallywithrespecttotheissuessurroundingtheproposedintroductionofagrouptaxationregimeinCanada.

Page 2: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

422 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

A B S T R A C T

In 2010, Canada’s Department of Finance initiated a consultation process to consider the possible introduction of a formal corporate group taxation system. A principal focus of the consultation process has been the type of group taxation system that would be best for Canada. The two most common alternatives that have been adopted in other countries are the loss transfer and full consolidation systems. The choice between these two systems is a difficult one. Nevertheless, provincial interest in a full consolidation regime is evident, especially as a means to address the interprovincial allocation issue.

The purpose of this article is to provide an in-depth comparative analysis of the consolidation regimes adopted in eight countries: Australia, France, Italy, Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Spain, and the United States. These are the countries that, by the end of 2009, had introduced full consolidation regimes providing for both intragroup loss offsets and tax-free asset transfers. The article critically compares the alternative policy options with respect to the design features and key structural elements of the eight selected consolidation regimes in an attempt to identify a model regime or template that might serve as a starting point for a Canadian system. In response to concern about the perceived complexity of a consolidation regime, the article ranks the eight consolidation regimes by applying a complexity index. This exercise is designed to highlight two aspects of the issue: first, the eight regimes represent a spectrum of varying degrees of complexity, indicating that a consolidation regime need not be as complex as the Australian and US models; and second, the complexity of a regime depends to a large extent on the policy choices with respect to the key structural elements.

KEYWORDS: COMPARATIVE ANALYSIS n CONSOLIDATION n CORPORATE TAXES n GROUP TAXATION n

LOSSES

C O N T E N T S

Introduction 423Overview of Group Taxation Regimes 427

Group Relief 429Group Contribution 430Group Pooling 430Organschaft 430

Design Features of Consolidation Regimes 432Application of the Single Entity Concept 432

Pooling 432Attribution 433Absorption 434

Definition of an Eligible Corporate Group and Mandatory Versus Elective Application of the Regime 434

Treatment of Preconsolidation Losses 441Quarantine 441Transfer to the Parent 442Cancellation 444

Treatment of Group Losses on Exit 445Treatment of Assets 445

On Entry 445

Page 3: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 423

INTRO DUC TIO N

TheCanadiangovernmentannouncedinits2010budgetthatitwillconsidertheintroduction of a “formal system of loss transfer or consolidated reporting”1(sometimesreferredtoas“corporategroupreporting”or“grouptaxation”).ThisannouncementwasfollowedbythereleaseofaconsultationpaperonthetaxationofcorporategroupsinNovember2010.2Sincethattime,aprincipalfocusoftheconsultationprocesshasbeenthetypeofgroupreportingsystemthatwouldbebestforCanada.Therearemanysystemsofgroupreportinginusearoundtheworld,butthetwomostcommonarethosereferredtoas“losstransfer”and“fullconsoli-dation”systems.Theformertermincludesthosesystemsthattreatthemembersofacorporategroupasseparatetaxpayersfilingseparatereturnsbutpermitlossestobetransferredfromonemembertoanother.Thelatterterm,asusedinthisarticle,referstoaregimeunderwhichagroupofresidentcompaniesis,ingeneral,treatedasasingletaxpayerandfilesasingleconsolidatedtaxreturn,allowingbothintra-grouplossoffsets3andtax-freeassettransfers.4

During Consolidation 449On Exit 450

Treatment of Intragroup Shareholdings 450On Entry 450During Consolidation 452On Exit 453

A Model Consolidation Regime? 454The Complexity Index—Comparison of the Eight Consolidation Regimes 459Conclusion 461

1 Canada,DepartmentofFinance,2010Budget,BudgetPlan,March4,2010,at386.Thegovernmentsuggested,ibid.,thattheproposalwasmadeinresponseto“variousconcernsfromthebusinesscommunityandfromtheprovincesregardingtheutilizationoftaxlosseswithincorporategroups,”andthatitwouldfocusinparticularonwhetherconsolidatedreportingcould“improvethecompetitivenessofthetaxsystemforCanadianbusinesses.”

2 Canada,DepartmentofFinance,The Taxation of Corporate Groups,ConsultationPaper(Ottawa:DepartmentofFinance,November2010)(hereinreferredtoas“theconsultationpaper”).

3 Lossoffsetsincludebothnon-capitalandcapitallosses.Fullconsolidationsystemsalsoextendconsolidatedreportingtoincludeothertaxattributes,suchastaxcredits.

4 Theterm“consolidation”maymeandifferenttypesofregimesindifferentcontexts.Itmaybeusedtoincludeothergrouptaxationregimes,suchasgrouplossreliefintheUnitedKingdomortheOrganschaftsysteminGermany:see,forexample,thebroaderdefinitionof“consolidation”inTonyStolarek,“TheTaxTreatmentofConsolidatedGroups:ManagingMajorTaxChange,”inChrisEvansandRichardKrever,eds.,Australian Business Tax Reform in Retrospect and Prospect(Sydney:ThomsonReuters,2009),201-22,atfootnote10.Theterm“consolidation”hasevenbeenusedtocovervirtuallyallformsofgrouptaxation:forexample,seeErnst&Young,Barometer of Tax Competitiveness for 2009: Comparative Analysis of Tax Systems Within the OECD(Paris:Ernst&Young,2009),at4.

Page 4: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

424 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

In1985,whenthenotionofaformalgrouptaxationsystemwaslastbroachedbytheCanadiangovernment,theDepartmentofFinancearticulatedaclearprefer-enceforagrouplosstransfersystem.5Thegovernment’scurrentpreferencewasnotdisclosed,however, in the2010consultationpaper,norhasanypreferencebeenindicatedinotherannouncements.

Theprivatesectorappearstofavouragrouplosstransfersystem.Forexample,theconsultationbriefssubmittedbytwolargeaccountingfirms,DeloitteandPrice-waterhouseCoopers,areclearinthisregard.Deloittestates:

Werecommendtheadoptionofagrouplosstransfersystem....Ontheotherhand,webelievethatafullconsolidationsystemwouldintroducealevelofcomplexityfarbeyondwhatisnecessarytoachievethebenefitssought.6

Similarly,PricewaterhouseCoopersendorsesalosstransfersystembecause

[it]wouldresultintheleastdisruptiontoCanada’staxsystemanditisthesystemtowhichtaxpayers,inparticular,smallandmedium-sizedcompanies,andthefederalandprovincialrevenueagenciescanmosteasilytransition.7

Incontrasttothefederalgovernment’sposition,thereappearstobemuteden-thusiasmfromtheprovincesforaformalsystemofgrouptaxationbecauseofitspotential impactonprovincial taxrevenues.Althoughmuchof thisdiscussion istakingplaceinprivate,anexpressionofthecurrentconcernsoftheprovinceswasprovidedinOntario’sfall2010economicupdate:

CanadahasasystemforsharingtheCorporateIncomeTaxbaseunderwhicheachprovinceisentitledtotaxtheeconomicactivitytakingplacewithinits jurisdiction.Anynewapproachtocorporategrouptaxationmustconsidertheimpactonprovincialrevenueswhenlossesaretransferredfromoneprovincetooffsetincomefromeco-nomicactivityinanotherprovince.Thetaxationofcorporategroupsmustnotdistorttheprinciplesofinterprovincialincomeallocationandshouldtreatlossesinafairandreasonablemanner.8

5 Canada,DepartmentofFinance,A Corporate Loss Transfer System for Canada(Ottawa:DepartmentofFinance,May1985).

6 LetteraccompanyingthebriefsubmittedbyDeloittetotheDepartmentofFinance,“TheTaxationofCorporateGroups—Deloitte’sComments,”April15,2011(www.deloitte.com/view/en_CA/ca/services/tax/eff59db12ad6f210VgnVCM1000001a56f00aRCRD.htm).

7 LetteraccompanyingthebriefsubmittedbyPricewaterhouseCooperstotheDepartmentofFinance,“TaxationofCorporateGroups:SubmissiontotheDepartmentofFinance,”April8,2011(www.pwc.com/ca/en/canadian-national-tax-service/publications/2011-04-taxation-corporate-groups-2011-04-en.pdf ),at6.

8 TheHonourableDwightDuncan,ministeroffinance,2010 Ontario Economic Outlook and Fiscal Review(Toronto:Queen’sPrinterforOntario,2010),at166.ConcernsabouttheeffectofsuchasystemonthedistributionofcorporatetaxrevenuesamongtheprovinceshavealsobeenexpressedinAlberta,MinistryofFinance,2011Budget,February24,2011,at147.

Page 5: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 425

Thisconcernaboutrevenueshiftingbetweenprovinceswasamajorreasonforthedemiseoftheconsultationprocessin1985.9Atthattime,itwassuggestedthataconsolidationregimemightbemoreacceptabletotheprovincesthanacorporatelosstransferregime.10Theinclusionofaconsolidationregimeasapolicyoptioninthe2010consultationpapermayhavebeenmotivatedbyprovincialinterestinsucharegime.Infact,suchinterestisevidentinarecentformalresponsetotheconsulta-tionpaperbytheOntarioMinistryofFinance,whichsignalsthatprovince’sclearpreferenceforasystemoffullconsolidationoveralosstransfersystemasameanstoaddresstheinterprovincialallocationissue:

Bytreatingacorporategroupasasingleeconomicunit,aconsolidationsystemwouldallow lossutilizationandminimize thedistortions toprovincial incomeallocationcreatedbyintra-grouptransactionsandtheallocationofthird-partyfinancingwithinthegroup....

However,alosstransfersystemgenerallydoesnottreatanentirecorporategroupasasingleeconomicentityandthereforemaynotadequatelyaddressprovincialcon-cernsaboutincomeallocation.11

Ontario’sresponsealsosuggeststhatthewidelytoutedsimplicityofalosstransfersystemmaybeoverstated,whilethecomplexityofasystemoffullconsolidationiscontingentonthetypeofsystemchosen—achoicethatcanbemadeinamannerthatminimizessuchconcerns.12

Atabroadconceptuallevel,thereappeartobetwopossibleapproachestofullcon-solidationintheCanadiancontext.Onepossibilityisapoolingsystem,underwhicheachconsolidatedsubsidiaryremainsasaseparateentityforincometaxpurposes.Eachconsolidatedcompanyisstillrequiredtofileastand-alonetaxcomputationwiththetaxauthorities,whilethetaxresultsofallgroupmembersareaggregatedatthegroupleveltoarriveattheconsolidatedgroup’staxableincomeorloss.Undersucha system, it ispossible for theprovinces to impose taxon individualgroupmembersbasedontheirstand-alonetaxreturnswhilethefederalgovernmentcouldimposetaxontheconsolidatedincomeofthegroup.Adisadvantageofthisapproachisadivergenceoffederalandprovincialtaxbases,whichincreasescomplianceandadministrativecosts.ThismaybeundesirableinCanada,giventhecurrent“highlyharmonized”taxsystematthefederalandprovinciallevels.13

9 NicholasLePan,“FederalandProvincialIssuesintheCorporateLossTransferProposal,”inReport of Proceedings of the Thirty-Seventh Tax Conference,1985ConferenceReport(Toronto:CanadianTaxFoundation,1986),13:1-11.

10 Ibid.,at13:9.

11 LetteraccompanyingthesubmissionbytheOntarioMinistryofFinancetotheDepartmentofFinance,“TaxationofCorporateGroups—ResponsetotheFederalConsultationPaperReleasedNovember23,2010,”April23,2011,at6.

12 Ibid.,at8.

13 Consultationpaper,supranote2,at5.

Page 6: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

426 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

Ifaconsistenttaxbaseisapriority,anobviousalternativeapproachistoadoptagroup’sconsolidatedtaxableincomeasthetaxbaseofthegroupforbothfederalandprovincialtaxpurposes.14Eachprovincecouldthenbeallocatedaportionofthattaxbaseaccordingtotheexistingformularyapportionmentrules.15Theadvan-tageofthisoptionisthatitmay(onthebasisofonthe1985experience)havesomepromiseasamethodofremovingtheopportunitiesforcorporategroupstoshiftincomebetweenprovinces.16

Inresponsetothefederalgovernment’sinterestinafullconsolidationregime,thesubmissionsbyDeloitteandPricewaterhouseCoopers,aswellasarecentpaperby Pantaleo and Johns,17 have provided some analysis of consolidation regimesaroundtheworld.ThesepapershavealsotriedtodeterminehowsucharegimecouldfitwithinexistingCanadiantaxlaw.Thepurposeofthepresentarticleistoprovideamorein-depthanalysisofeightspecificconsolidationregimesaroundtheworld:Australia,France,Italy,Japan,theNetherlands,NewZealand,Spain,andtheUnitedStates.18Thesearethecountriesthat,bytheendof2009,hadintro-ducedregimesprovidingforbothintragrouplossoffsetsandtax-freeassettransfers.Althoughitwouldbedesirabletoalsoconsidertheapplicationoftheseregimestothe Canadian context and recommend a specific structure to address provincialconcerns,analysisoftheeightregimesisasufficientlycomplexendeavourthattheirspecificapplicationtotheCanadiancontextisataskbestleftforfuturework.

Nonetheless,withthe idea thatsomeformof fullconsolidationsystemcouldmostreadilyaddressprovincialrevenueconcerns,thisarticlecomparesthedesignfeaturesoftheeightselectedconsolidationregimesinanattempttoidentifyamodel

14 SeeOntario,MinistryofFinance,supranote11,at7:“Thefederalgovernmentandtheprovincesgenerallyshareaharmonizedcorporatetaxbase,haveuniforminterprovincialallocationrules,andmanyprovinces,includingOntario,haveharmonizedcorporateincometaxcollection.ThesesignificantaccomplishmentscontributetotheefficiencyoftheCanadiantaxsystemandwereachievedthroughpartnershipbetweenthefederalandprovincialgovernments.”

15 AsimilarregimehasbeensuggestedbyAlexandreLaurin,Cleaning Up the Books: A Proposal for Revamping Corporate Group Taxation in Canada,C.D.HoweInstituteCommentaryno.284(Toronto:C.D.HoweInstitute,March2009).

16 Forabriefdiscussionoftheissue,seetheconsultationpaper,supranote2,at6;andOntario,MinistryofFinance,supranote11,at5-8.TheexperienceintheUnitedStatesalsosuggeststhatmorestateshaveadoptedcombinedreportinginrecentyearstodealwiththeinterstateincome-shiftingissue:consultationpaper,supranote2,at32.

17 NickPantaleoandJeffreyC.Johns,“TowardaNewSystemfortheTaxationofCorporateGroupsinCanada:HastheTime(Finally)Come?”inReport of Proceedings of the Sixty-Second Tax Conference,2010ConferenceReport(Toronto:CanadianTaxFoundation)35:1-38.

18 SouthKoreaintroducedaconsolidationregimein2010:seeInternationalBureauofFiscalDocumentation,Corporate Taxation Database(Amsterdam:IBFD)(www.ibfd.org),searchunder“CountryAnalysis”—“RepublicofKorea.”Sincelittleinformationisyetavailableonthedetailedrulesandactualimplementationoftheregime,itisnotanalyzedindetailinthisarticle.

Page 7: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 427

regimethatmightprovideatemplateasastartingpointfortheCanadiancontext.19Inanefforttoprovideabroadercontextforthemorelimitedcountrycomparison,thenextpartofthearticleprovidesabriefoverviewofgrouptaxationregimes,rang-ingfromlosstransfersystemstofullconsolidationsystems.Theoverviewisfollowedbyadiscussionofthekeystructuralelementsoftheconsolidationregimesoftheeightselectedcountries.Thisinturnisfollowedbyadiscussionofthepossibleele-mentsofamodelconsolidationregime,basedonanassessmentoftheeightregimes.Asaresponsetotheconcernregardingtheperceivedcomplexityofaconsolidationregime,theeightconsolidationregimesarethenrankedbyapplyingacomplexityindex.Thisexerciseisdesignedtohighlighttwoaspectsoftheissue:first,theeightregimesrepresentaspectrumofvaryingdegreesofcomplexity,indicatingthatcon-solidationregimesneednotbeascomplexastheAustralianandUSmodels;andsecond,thecomplexityofaregimedependstoalargeextentonthepolicychoiceswithrespecttothekeystructuralelements.

OV ERV IE W O F GRO UP TA X ATIO N REGIME S

Thegroup taxationregimes indifferentcountriesoftendiffer substantially, thuspresentingachallengetotheconstructionofasystematicanalysis.Ithasbeenob-servedthat it is“difficulttoestablishanexact ‘familytree’ofthegrouptaxationregimesaroundtheworld.Linesarehardtodraw.Exceptionsabound.”20Neverthe-less,thefollowingoverviewaimstoillustratethedifferentformsofgrouptaxationregimes.21Theregimesareclassifiedaccordingtotheextenttowhichasingleentityconceptisappliedinrespectoftwokeytaxattributesthatagrouptaxationregimenormallycovers:intragrouplossoffsetsandintragroupassettransfers.

Thegrouptaxationregimesclassifiedaccordingtothesetwotaxattributesaresummarizedinfigure1.

19 Althoughtheeightconsolidationregimeshavebeendescribedelsewhereinconsiderabledepth,verylittlecomparativeanalysishasbeendone.See,inthisrespect,AntonyTing,“PolicyandMembershipRequirementsforConsolidation:AComparisonBetweenAustralia,NewZealandandtheUS”[2005]no.3British Tax Review311-34.ForacomparisonoftheconsolidationregimesinAustraliaandtheUnitedStates,andthetreatmentofcorporatelossesinCanada,seeMaureenDonnellyandAllisterYoung,“PolicyOptionsforTaxLossTreatment:HowDoesCanadaCompare?”(2002)50:2Canadian Tax Journal429-88,at449-70.

20 YoshihiroMasui,“GeneralReport,”inInternationalFiscalAssociation(IFA),Group Taxation,Cahiersdedroitfiscalinternational,vol.89b(Amersfoort,theNetherlands:SduFiscale&FinanciëleUtigevers,2004),21-67,at29.

21 Theoverviewisnotintendedtobeexhaustiveanddoesnotcoverallgrouptaxationregimesineverycountry.ItisbasedprimarilyonMasui’sreport,ibid.,supplementedandupdatedbyinformationfromvarioussources,includinginparticulartheCorporate Taxation Database,supranote18,searchunder“CountryAnalysis.”AnotherIFAreportalsoprovidessomevaluableinformationonthetreatmentoflossesinacorporategroup:InternationalFiscalAssociation,Tax Treatment of Corporate Losses,Cahiersdedroitfiscalinternational,vol.83a(TheHague:KluwerLawInternational,1998).

Page 8: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

428 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

FIGURE 1 Group Taxation Regimes Allowing Intragroup Loss Offsets and/or Intragroup Asset Transfers

Only one regime for either loss offsets or asset transfers

Two separate regimes for loss offsets and asset transfers

One regime for both loss offsets and asset transfers

No regime for either tax attribute

Group contribution

Intragroup asset transfers

Group relief

Group pooling

Worldwide loss relief

Consolidation

Organschaft

Group contribution and asset transfers

Group relief and asset transfers

Australia, France, Italy,b Japan, the Netherlands, New Zealand, Spain, and the United States

Belgium, Canada, Hungary, South Africa, and Switzerland

India

Finland

Germany

Austria and Denmark

Norway and Sweden

United Kingdom

Malaysia, New Zealand, and Singapore

Italy,a Luxembourg, Mexico, Poland, and Portugal

Weaker

App

licat

ion

of th

e si

ngle

ent

ity c

once

pt

Stronger

a Since 2008.b Before 2008.

Sources: Yoshihiro Masui, “General Report,” in International Fiscal Association (IFA), Group Taxation, Cahiers de droit fiscal international, vol. 89b (Amersfoort, the Netherlands: Sdu Fiscale & Financiële Utigevers, 2004), 21-67, at 29; International Bureau of Fiscal Documentation, Corporate Taxation Database (Amsterdam: IBFD) (www.ibfd.org).

Page 9: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 429

Somecountries(Belgium,Canada,Hungary,SouthAfrica,andSwitzerland)donothaveaspecificregimeallowingeitherintragrouplossoffsetsorassettransfers.Corporategroupsinthesecountriesoftenhavetoresorttocomplicatedtax-planningstructurestoachievesimilartaxoutcomes;however,suchplanningisuncertaininpracticeandsubjecttochallengebytaxauthorities.22Forinstance,inCanada,de-spitethegenerallyaccommodatingattitudeofthetaxauthorities,thetaxstructurestoachieveintragrouplossoffsetsareoftennotonlycomplex,butalsouncertainintermsofoutcome.23

Manycountrieshaveatleastoneregimecateringforoneorbothofthesetaxattributes.Thegrouptaxationregimes,otherthanconsolidationregimes,thatallowintragrouplossoffsetsaredescribedbelow.

Group Relief

Malaysia,NewZealand,Singapore,andtheUnitedKingdom24haveagroupreliefregimeunderwhich,ingeneral,lossesmaybetransferredwithinagroupofresidentcompanies.25Forexample, intheUnitedKingdom,ifaparentcompanyownsatleast75percentofthesharesofasubsidiary,tradinglossescanbesurrenderedfromonecompanytotheother.26Eveniftheshareholdingislessthan100percent,thewholeamountofthelossescanbetransferred.27

22 Forageneraldiscussionofthecommonplanningtechniques,seeMasui,supranote20,at47-51.

23 Laurin,supranote15,at5-7.SeealsoMaureenDonnellyandAllisterW.Young,“GroupReliefforCanadianCorporateTaxpayers—AtLast?”(2011)59:2Canadian Tax Journal239-63.

24 TheUKgroupreliefregimewasintroducedin1967toreplacethe1953provisionsrelatingtosubventionpayments(underwhichanintragrouplossoffsetwaseffectivelyallowedbypermittingaprofit-makinggroupmembertomakeadeductiblepaymenttoanotherloss-makingmember).Thegroupreliefregimewasregarded“asaconcessiontothosewhowouldliketoseefullgrouping,withasinglegroupassessment....Itwasahalf-wayhouse,inwhichthegroupcompaniescouldmakeearlyuseofeachother’slosseswithout...needingtomakeactualpaymentstoeachother”:D.deM.Carey,“CompanyBran-Tub1967”( July-August1967)British Tax Review239-44,at239.

25 Since2006,thescopeoftheUKgroupreliefregimeingeneralhasbeenextendedtocovernon-residentsubsidiariesresidentintheEuropeanEconomicArea(EEA)undercertaincircumstances:Corporate Taxation Database,supranote18,searchunder“CountryAnalysis”—“UnitedKingdom,”atparagraph8.1.ForadiscussionoftheUKpositiononEEAlosses,seeJohnTiley,Revenue Law,6thed.(Oxford:HartPublishing,2008),at959.Incontrast,inAustralia,thescopeofgroupreliefhasbeensubstantiallyrestrictedsincetheintroductionofaconsolidationregimein2002.Inparticular,groupreliefisnowavailableonlyifoneofthepartiesinvolvedisanAustralianbranchofaforeignbank:IncomeTaxAssessmentAct1997(ITAA1997),subdivisions170-Aand170-B.

26 IncomeandCorporationTaxesAct1988(UK),1988,c.1,section402.Thesurrenderoftradinglossesisalsoallowedbetweentwo75percentsubsidiariesofaparentcompany.ForadetaileddiscussionoftheUKgrouplossreliefregime,see,forexample,Tiley,supranote25,section49.6.

27 HughJ.AultandBrianJ.Arnold,Comparative Income Taxation: A Structural Analysis,3ded.(AlphenaandenRijn,theNetherlands:KluwerLawInternational,2010),at400.

Page 10: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

430 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

Incontrast tothegeneralpolicyofrestrictingthegrouplossreliefregimetoresidentgroupsintheabovecountries,AustriaandDenmarkhaveextendedtheirgrouplossreliefregimestocoverlossesfromnon-residentsubsidiaries.

Group Contribution

Finland,Norway,andSwedenhaveagroupcontributionregime,underwhichaprofit-makinggroupmembercanmakeacontributiontoa loss-makingmemberwithinagroupofresidentcompanies.Thecontributionisdeductiblefortheformerandtaxabletothelatter,thuseffectivelyachievinganintragrouplossoffset.Thereisnorequirementtoeffectatransferofcashorproperty,andthecontributioncanbebookedasanintragrouploan.28

Group Pooling

CountrieswithagrouppoolingregimeincludeItaly(since2008),29Luxembourg,Mexico,30Poland,andPortugal.Underthisregime,agroupofresidentcompaniesisdefinedtobeataxableunitandcomputesitstaxableincomeorlossbyaggregatingindividualresultsofeachgroupmember.Anintragrouplossoffsetisthusachieved.Themajordifferencebetweenthisregimeandafullconsolidationsystemisthatgrouppoolingdoesnotallowtax-freeintragroupassettransfers.Thegrouppoolingregimeisthereforenotascomprehensiveasaconsolidationregime.

Organschaft

UnderGermany’sOrganschaft regime,31aparentcompanyand its subsidiarycanelecttohavethetaxableincomeorlossofthesubsidiarytransferredtotheparent

28 Masui,supranote20,at30;andDunjaEdvinsson,“NewRulesSeekToMakeGroupContributionRegimeEULawCompliant”(2010)50:7European Taxation329-32,at329.

29 Italyintroducedadomesticconsolidationregimein2004,allowingbothintragrouplossoffsetsandtax-freeassettransfers.However,intragroupassettransferswereabolishedin2008,thuschangingthesystemtoagrouppoolingregime.

30 InMexico,beginningin1991,non-residentsubsidiariescouldalsoparticipateingrouppooling:AageMichelsen,“GeneralReport,”inTax Treatment of Corporate Losses,supranote21,21-69,at57-58.However,few(ifany)taxpayerstookuptheoption,owingtoonerousrequirements,anditwassubsequentlyremoved:MarioCalderónDanel,“Mexico,”inTax Treatment of Corporate Losses,ibid.,629-51,at645-46.

31 ForabriefdiscussionoftheregimeinGermany,seeAultandArnold,supranote27,at401-2;andSimonPatrickLink,“Germany,”inGuglielmoMaisto,ed.,International and EC Tax Aspects of Groups of Companies,ECandInternationalTaxLawSeriesvol.4(Amsterdam:InternationalBureauofFiscalDocumentation,2008),301-25,at314-19.Before2005,AustriaalsohadanOrganschaftregime.Itwasreplacedbyanewgrouptaxationregime(Unternehmensgruppe)inresponsetocriticismsoftheOrganschaft—inparticular,theinabilitytooffsetcross-borderlosses:GeraldGahleitnerandStefanRatzinger,“Austria:InternationalGroupTaxation—AnOverviewofAustria’sNewTaxIncentive”(2005)45:11European Taxation509-14,at510.

Page 11: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 431

company,thusachievinganintragrouplossoffsetattheparentcompanylevel.Aprofit-and-losspoolingagreement,whichmusthaveaminimumtermoffiveyears,isrequiredbetweentheparentandthesubsidiary.Undertheregime,asubsidiaryremainsasaseparateentityfortaxpurposesandisrequiredtofileataxreturnre-portingataxableincomeofnil.Thetaxableincomeorlossofthesubsidiaryis,ingeneral,calculatedonaseparateentitybasisandintragrouptransactions(includingintragroupassettransfers)arenoteliminated.32

Organschaftappliestonotonlyincometax,butalsotradetaxandvalue-addedtax.33 Furthermore, it pools both taxable income and losses of subsidiaries. It isthereforeregardedasrepresentingastrongerapplicationofthesingleentitycon-ceptthanthegrouptaxationregimesdescribedabove.

Regimesallowingintragrouplossoffsetsaremorecommonthanthoseallowingintragroupassettransfers.Inthe2004CongressreportoftheInternationalFiscalAssociation(IFA),ofthe20countriesthatreportedatleastoneregimeforeitherofthetaxattributes,19hadanintragrouplossoffsetregimewhileonly12hadanintra-groupassettransferregime.34AsurveyofthecountriesinDecember2009revealsnomaterialchangeinthispattern.35Mostcountrieshavethesameregimesasin2004.Theexceptionsnotedinclude:

n Austria,whichhadanOrganschaftregimein2004,replaceditwithanUnter-nehmensgrupperegimein2005,allowingcross-borderlossoffsets;

n Poland, which was not included in the 2004 report, has a group poolingregime;

n Malaysia,whichwasnotincludedinthe2004report,hasagroupreliefre-gime;and

n South Korea, which had no regime for either of the two tax attributes in2004,introducedaconsolidationregimein2010.

Infigure1,11countriesallowbothintragrouplossoffsetsandtax-freeintragroupassettransfers.Eightofthem—Australia,France,Italy,36Japan,theNetherlands,NewZealand,Spain,andtheUnitedStates—implementaconsolidationregimetodealcomprehensivelywithbothtaxattributes.Thesearethecountriesselectedforcomparisoninthisarticle.Onlythreecountries—Norway,Sweden,andtheUnitedKingdom—haveseparateregimescateringforthetwotaxattributes.

32 AnunusualfeatureoftheOrganschaftregimeisthatpre-groupinglossesofasubsidiaryaresuspended.Theyarenotavailabletotheparentcompany,butcanbeusedbythesubsidiaryafteritleavestheregime:Link,supranote31,at317.

33 Corporate Taxation Database,supranote18,searchunder“CountryAnalysis”—“Germany,”atparagraph8.1.

34 Masui,supranote20,at33-34.

35 ThesurveywasdoneonDecember10,2009ontheIBFDdatabases:seenote21fordetails.

36 Seesupranote29.

Page 12: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

432 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

DE SIGN FE AT URE S O F CO NSO LIDATIO N REGIME S

Asaparticularformofgrouptaxationregime,consolidationregimesrequirethearticulationofthefollowingkeystructuralelements:

n applicationofthesingleentityconcept;n definitionofaneligiblecorporategroupandmandatoryversuselectiveap-

plicationoftheregime;n treatmentofpreconsolidationlosses;n treatmentofgrouplossesonexit;n treatmentofassetsonentry,duringconsolidation,andonexit;andn treatmentofintragroupshareholdingsonentry,duringconsolidation,and

onexit.

Thesestructuralelementsarediscussedinturnbelowwithreferencetotheirpres-enceintheconsolidationregimesoftheeightcountries.

Application of the Single Entity Concept

Theconsolidationregimesoftheeightselectedcountriesgenerallytreatcorporategroupsasonesingleentity.However,theydemonstratesomevariationintheextenttowhichthissingleentityconceptisapplied.Inparticular,thereappeartobethreedifferentapplicationsoftheconcept:(1)pooling,(2)attribution,and(3)absorption.

PoolingThepoolingsystemisthepredominantapplicationofthesingleentityconceptintheeightcountries;indeed,sixofthem—allexceptAustraliaandtheNetherlands—applythissystem.37Theparentcompanyanditssubsidiariesinaconsolidatedgrouparetreated,toalargeextent,asseparateentitiesforincometaxpurposes,withthetaxable incomeor lossof eachgroupmemberbeing computedon an individualbasis.Theseparateentityresultsarethenaggregatedatthegrouplevel—oftenad-justedforintragrouptransactions—toarriveatconsolidatedtaxableincomeorloss.

Themajoradvantageofthisapproachisitssimplicity.Mostoftheexistingtaxrulesforcompaniesarefoundedonthetraditionalseparateentitydoctrine,accord-ingtowhicheachcompanyistreatedasaseparatetaxpayer.Therulescanthereforebe applied comfortably to consolidated group members under a pooling systemthat,forthemostpart,preservesthisseparateentitytreatment.Theinteractionsbetweentheconsolidationregimeandotherincometaxregimesarealsosimpler,

37 GeneralTaxCode(GTC),France,articles223Aand223B;IncomeTaxCode(ITC),Italy,articles118and121;CorporationTaxAct(CTA),Japan,article4-2;IncomeTaxAct2007(ITA2007),NewZealand,sectionsFM3(1)and(2);CorporateIncomeTaxLaw(CITL),Spain,section65(1);andInternalRevenueCode(IRC),UnitedStates,IRCReg.sections1.1502-11(a)and1.1502-13.

Page 13: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 433

sincetheformerembracestoalargeextenttheseparateentitydoctrinethatisthefundamentalunderlyingprincipleofthelatter.

Arelatedpolicyissuewithrespecttothepoolingsystemiswhethertheindivid-ual tax computations of a consolidated group member should be prepared on astand-aloneoragroupbasis.Forexample,anexpenditureofasubsidiarymayberegardedascapitalinnatureonastand-alonebasisandthusnotdeductible.How-ever, iftheitemisexaminedonagroupbasis,sothatfactsandcircumstancesofothergroupmembersaretakenintoconsideration,theexpendituremaybejudgedtohavearevenuecharacterandthusbecurrentlydeductible.

Fiveofthesixcountrieswithapoolingsystem(allexceptNewZealand)adoptthe stand-alonebasis.That is,eachsubsidiaryprepares its taxcomputationonastand-alonebasisbeforeaggregationatthegrouplevel.Taxabilityanddeductibilityofvarious itemsaregenerallydeterminedas if thesubsidiarywereastand-aloneunconsolidatedcompany.Thereareexceptionstothegeneralrule,butthestand-alonebasisisthepredominantapproach.

Incontrast,inNewZealand,eachcompanyinthegrouppreparesitstaxcompu-tationonagroupbasis.38Whencalculatingthetaxableincomeofagroupmemberfor consolidation purposes, measures are in place to ensure that a consolidatedgroupisgenerallyliabletoincometaxasifitwereasinglecompany.Thus,incomederivedbyagroupmember—whichwouldbenon-taxableonastand-alonebasis—istreatedastaxableiftheincomewouldbetaxabletotheconsolidatedgroupifthegroupwereacompany.Similarrulesapplytoexpenditures.

Inpractice,thestand-alonebasisimplieslowercompliancecoststhanthegroupbasis.Theindividualtaxcomputationofaconsolidatedcompanycanbepreparedasifthecompanyhadnotconsolidated.Ordinarytaxrulesforcompaniescanbeapplied,avoidingreassessmentof the taxabilityanddeductibilityofeach incomeandexpenseitemofaconsolidatedmemberinlightofthefactsandcircumstancesofothergroupmembers.

AttributionTheNetherlandsistheonlycountrythathasadoptedtheattributionoptionreferredtoas“fiscalunity.”39Assets,liabilities,andactivitiesofconsolidatedsubsidiariesareattributedtotheparentcompany.Inotherwords,incomeandexpensesofthesubsidi-ariesaredeemedtobethoseoftheparentcompany,thusachievingtheaggregationoftaxableincomeandlossesofthegroupmembers.Oneimportantfeatureofthisoptionisthatthesubsidiariescontinuetobetreatedasseparateentitiesforincometaxpurposes,anapproachthathasprovedtobeespeciallyimportantintheapplica-tionoftaxtreaties.40

38 ITA2007sectionsFM9,11,and12.

39 CorporateIncomeTaxLawof1969(CITL1969),article15(1).

40 RudolfJ.deVries,“Netherlands,”inGroup Taxation,supranote20,461-84,at467.Before2003,theNetherlandsadoptedanabsorptionmodelunderwhichaconsolidatedsubsidiarywas

Page 14: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

434 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

AbsorptionAustraliaiscurrentlytheonlycountrythatappliestheabsorptionoption.41Underthissingleentityconcept,knownasthe“singleentityrule”(SER),consolidatedsub-sidiariesaredeemedtohavebecomedivisionsoftheparentcompanyandtohaveceasedtoexistasindividualcompaniesforincometaxpurposes.42Assetsofsubsidi-ariesaredeemedtobehelddirectlybytheparentcompany.Asaresult,unlikethetreatmentinmostotherconsolidationregimes,intragroupassettransferswithinaconsolidatedgrouparecompletelyignored.Thetransfersnotonlyhavenoimmedi-atetaximplications,butalsodonotrequirethepartiestotraceassetmovements,keeparecordofanydeferredgainorloss,orrecapturethegainorlosswheneitherthetransferororthetransfereeleavesthegroup.Moreover,preconsolidationlossesofajoiningsubsidiaryaretransferredtoandcanbeusedbytheparentcompany,with-outtheneedtocomputethesubsidiary’sstand-alonetaxableincomeeveryyear.43

Asdescribedbelow,thepricetopayfortheseapparentadvantagesishigh.Prob-lematicandhighlycomplexrules,knownasthe“tax-cost-setting”(TCS)rules,arerequiredtoadjustthecostbasesofassetsandsharesinajoiningsubsidiary.44Therulesonpreconsolidationlossesarealsocomplexandproblematic.45AnotherproblemassociatedwiththeSERisthedifficultinteractionsitcreatesbetweentheconsolida-tionregimeandotherpartsoftheincometaxsystembasedontheseparateentitydoctrine.TheAustralianexperiencesuggeststhatapplicationoftheSERrenderstheapplicationofothertaxregimestoconsolidatedgroupsmoredifficult.

Definition of an Eligible Corporate Group and Mandatory Versus Elective Application of the Regime

Consolidationregimestendtoberestrictedtoresidentcompaniesundercommoncontrol.Therestrictiontoresidentcompaniesreflectsthepoliticalrealitythatex-tendinggeneralresidencetaxingrightstonon-residentcompaniesisproblematic.Extending consolidation to non-resident entities also raises revenue and anti-avoidanceconcerns.Therefore,alloftheeightconsolidationregimesconsidered

treatedashavingbeen“absorbed”intotheparentcompany.However,theexactmeaningof“absorption”wascontroversial,especiallywithrespecttowhetherthesubsidiarywasstilleligiblefortreatybenefits.Thetaxlawwasamendedin2003toreplacetheabsorptionmodelwiththecurrentattributionmodel,inordertoremovethetreatyissue.

41 ThediscussionofAustralia’sconsolidationregimeinthisarticleisbasedonthemoredetailedanalysisinAntonyTing,“Australia’sConsolidationRegime:ARoadofNoReturn?”[2010]no.2British Tax Review162-93.

42 ITAA1997section701.1.

43 Theuserateofthetransferredlossesissubjecttothe“availablefraction”rules,whicharediscussedbelowundertheheading“TreatmentofPreconsolidationLosses.”

44 Seethediscussionbelowundertheheadings“TreatmentofAssets—OnEntry”and“TreatmentofIntragroupShareholdings—OnExit,”respectively.

45 Seethediscussionoftheserulesbelowundertheheading“TreatmentofPreconsolidationLosses.”

Page 15: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 435

hereare, ingeneral, restricted toresidentcompanygroupsundercommoncon-trol.46Unincorporatedentitiesare, ingeneral,excludedfromconsolidation.TheAustralianregimeisanexceptiontothisgeneralrule;itallowstrustsandpartner-shipstobeincludedasmembersofaconsolidatedgroup.47Aswell,allofthefourEUcountriesextendthescopeofconsolidationtocoverpermanentestablishmentsof non-resident companies.48 This policy represents a response to the EU non-discriminationrulesandtocertaindecisionsoftheEuropeanCourtofJusticeontheapplicationofthoserules.49

Mostcountriesspecificallyexcludecertainentitiesfromconsolidation.Besidesnon-residents,themostcommonexclusionisforcompaniesthatarenotsubjecttothenormalcorporateincometaxrates—forexample,thosesubjecttoareducedtaxrateorexemptfromtax.50Companiesinbankruptcyandliquidationarealsooftenexcludedfromaconsolidatedgroup.51BothNewZealandandtheUnitedStateshavespecificrestrictionsoncompanies thatare taxedasflowthroughentities. Inparticular,NewZealandonlyallowssuchcompanies(knownas“qualifyingcom-panies”)toformaconsolidatedgroupwitheachother.52FlowthroughentitiesintheUnitedStates(forexample,Scorporations)arenoteligibletojoinanyconsolidatedgroup.53

46 Exceptionstothisresidencerequirementarerareingrouptaxationregimes.Forinstance,FranceandItalypermitworldwidegrouppooling,butithasverylimiteduseinpractice.Forabriefdiscussion,seeCorporate Taxation Database,supranote18,searchunder“CountryAnalysis”—“France”and“Italy.”

47 ITAA1997sections703.15(2),tableitem2,and719.10(1)(b).Somecountriesdoallowconsolidationofcertainunincorporatedentitiesthataretaxedascorporations—forexample,limitedpartnershipsinItaly,NewZealand,andSpain(aswellasAustralia).Ananalysisoftheissuesrelatingtotheinclusionofunincorporatedentitiesinaconsolidatedgroupisbeyondthescopeofthisarticle.Forfurtherdiscussion,seeTing,supranote19,at324-25.

48 ForabriefsurveyoftheEUcountriesthatallowpermanentestablishmentsintheirgroupingregimes,seeMarcoAdda,“CanaPermanentEstablishmentBea‘LegitimateHeir’inaDomesticConsolidatedTaxRegime?”(2008)48:5European Taxation238-44,at239-40.SeealsoMasui,supranote20,at53-55and58-62.

49 Forexample,since2003,theNetherlandshasallowedapermanentestablishmentofanon-residentcompanytobeeithertheheadentityorasubsidiarymemberofaconsolidatedgroup:CITL1969article15(4).AlsoseedeVries,supranote40,at475.

50 CountriesthathavethisexclusionincludeAustralia(ITAA1997section703.15(2)),Italy(ITCarticle126(1)),Japan(CTAarticle4-2),NewZealand(ITA2007sectionFM31(1)(c)),Spain(CITLsection67(4)),andtheUnitedStates(IRCsections1504(b)(1)and(2)).Theexclusioncoverscompaniesthataresubjecttospecifictaxregimes,suchasinsurancecompaniesandspecialinvestmententities.

51 CountriesthatexcludethesecompaniesincludeItaly(ITCarticle126(2)),Japan(CTAarticle4-2),andSpain(CITLsection67(4)(b)).

52 ITA2007sectionFM31(2)(a).Miningcompaniesaresubjecttosimilarrestrictions:ITA2007sectionFM31(2)(b).TheUnitedStateshassimilarrulesforinsurancecompanies:IRCsection1504(c).

53 IRCsection1504(b)(8).

Page 16: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

436 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

Inpractice,itisnoteasytoprovideasimpleandeffectivedefinitionofcommoncontrol.Abright-linedefinition—forexample, specificationof aminimumper-centageofvotingrights—maybesimple,butmaynotbeeffective.Controlcanbeestablishedbyvariousmeans, suchasoptions andconvertible securities, controloverthecompositionoftheboardofdirectorsorkeyexecutives,orspecialshare-holders’agreements.54Amoregeneraldefinition—forexample,defactocontrol—may be more effective in capturing a control relationship, but is not easy toadminister, being “too uncertain and unpredictable.”55 Most countries adopt abright-lineoptionbasedonshareownership,butprotectitfromabusewithsupple-mentarytestsoranti-avoidanceprovisions.

Withrespecttotheownershipthreshold,thecomparativeanalysisoftheeightcountries reveals two different specifications: (1) substantially 100 percent and(2) substantially less than 100 percent. Five of the eight countries—Australia,France,Japan,theNetherlands,andNewZealand—useasubstantially100percentownershipstandard.56Specifically,FranceandtheNetherlandshavea95percentthreshold;theotherthreecountries,100percent.ThethresholdintheNetherlandswas100percentbefore2003.The95percentthresholdisintendedtoaccommo-dateemployeeshareschemesorsmallshareholdingsthattheparentcompanyfailstopurchaseinanacquisition.

Ahighownershipthresholdcanbejustifiedonanumberofbases.Perhapsmostimportantly,asubsidiaryunderthecontrolofaparentcompanyshouldbetreatedina similarmannerasabranchof theparent.Realizationof thisconsistencyoftreatmentrequiresthataparentcompanymustwhollyownthesubsidiary,withnoallowanceforminorityinterests.Inotherwords,thethresholdshouldbe100per-cent.57Moreover,sincelossoffsetamonggroupmembersislikelytohaveanadverseimpactonrevenue,governmentsmaytrytominimizetheimpactbyrestrictingaccesstotheregimethroughtheapplicationofahigherthreshold.Forexample,theDutchgovernmenthasbeenreluctanttolowerthe95percentthresholdbecauseofrevenueconcerns.58Furthermore,thepresenceofaminorityinterestintroducescomplexityintoconsolidationregimes.Forthisreason,duringthedesignphaseoftheAustralian

54 Foradetailedanalysisofthedefinitionofcontrolindifferentregimes,seeAntonyTing,“Definitionof‘Control’UndertheConsolidationandControlledForeignCompanyRegimes:AComparisonBetweenAustralia,NewZealandandtheUnitedStates”(2006)12:1New Zealand Journal of Taxation Law and Policy37-60.

55 BrianJ.Arnold,The Taxation of Controlled Foreign Corporations: An International Comparison,CanadianTaxPaperno.78(Toronto:CanadianTaxFoundation,1986),at417.

56 ITAA1997section703.15(2)(Australia),GTCarticle223A(France),CTAarticle4-2( Japan),CITL1969article15(1)(theNetherlands),andITA2007sectionFM35(1)(NewZealand).

57 Manycountriesallowasmallpercentagetobeownedbyemployeesthroughemployeeshareschemes.Thispolicyispragmaticandreasonable,sincethiskindofholdingingeneralwouldnotsignificantlyaffectthecontroloftheparentcompanyoverthesubsidiary.

58 DeVries,supranote40,at471.

Page 17: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 437

consolidationregime,USofficialsspecificallywarnedtheirAustraliancounterpartsnottoallowminorityinterestsinsubsidiariesastheUnitedStatesdoes.59

Interestingly,itseemsthatcorporategroupsinpracticedonothavemajorobjec-tionstotheuseofahighownershipthresholdtodetermineeligibilityforconsolidatedtreatment.Giventhesignificantbenefitoflossoffsetsandtax-freeassettransfers,itisreasonabletoexpectastrictownershiprequirementtoscreenforeligiblegroupmembers. Furthermore, in practice, most subsidiaries of corporate groups arewhollyownedforcommercialreasons.60Ahighthresholdthereforedoesnotposeasignificantobstacletoconsolidation.

Nonetheless,threeoftheeightcountriesuseanownershipthresholdsubstan-tiallylowerthan100percent:Italy,50percent;Spain,75percent;andtheUnitedStates,80percent.61TheunusuallylowthresholdinItalymaybeduetohistoricalreasons.62Beforetheconsolidationregimewasintroduced,Italyhadan“implicit”grouptaxationregime,knownasthe“excessimputationcreditsurrender”regime.Inbroadterms,theregimeallowedintragrouplossutilizationbysurrenderingex-cesstaxcreditofalosscompanytoprofitablerelatedcompanies.Theownershipthresholdunderthisregimewas50percent,possibly(atleastinpart)accountingfortheuseofthesamelowthresholdintheconsolidationregime.

InSpain, theownership thresholdhasfluctuated.63 Initially set at 50percentwhentheconsolidationregimewasintroducedin1977,thethresholdwassubse-quentlyincreasedto90percentin1982,andthenreducedto75percentin2002.TheownershipthresholdundertheUSconsolidationregimehasalsofluctuated.64Whentheregimewasfirstintroducedin1917,itrequiredthattheparentcompanyown “substantially all” of the shares of another company.65 The threshold was

59 GeoffreyLehmann,“AnAssessmentofAustralia’sTaxConsolidationRegime,”inGeoffreyLehmann,ed.,Business Tax Reform: Meet the Critics,AustralianTaxResearchFoundationConferenceSeriesno.24(Sydney:AustralianTaxResearchFoundation,2007),at277.

60 StatisticsoncorporategroupsinCanadashowthatbetween2005and2008,onaverageabout85percentofthecorporategroupscontainedcorporationswith100percentownership:consultationpaper,supranote2,at27.Similarly,inAustralia,itwasfoundthatover90percentofsubsidiariesinlistedcorporategroupswerewhollyownedsubsidiaries:IanM.RamsayandG.P.Stapledon,“CorporateGroupsinAustralia”(2001)29:1Australian Business Law Review7-32.

61 ITCarticles117and120(Italy),CITLsection67(2)(b)(Spain),andIRCsection1504(a)(1)(B)(ii)(UnitedStates).

62 MassimoGiaconia,“Italy,”inGroup Taxation,supranote20,369-91,at375-76.

63 MaríaAmparoGrauRuiz,“Spain,”inGroup Taxation,ibid.,609-32,at615;andJoséIgnacioGarciaMuniozguren,“Spain:NewCorporateTaxMeasuresfor2002”(2002)42:3European Taxation138-40,at139.

64 ForadetaileddiscussionofthehistoricaldevelopmentoftheownershiprequirementintheUnitedStates,seeKevinM.Hennessey,RichardYates,JamesBanks,andPatriciaPellervo,The Consolidated Tax Return: Principles, Practice, Planning,6thed.(NewYork:RIA)(looseleaf ),chapter1.

65 The1917regimewasmandatoryandbasicallyananti-avoidancemeasure.Consequently,“substantiallyall”didnotmeanafixedpercentage;instead,ownershipwasdeterminedonthebasisofthefactsineachparticularcase:ibid.,atparagraph1.04[2][a].

Page 18: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

438 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

changedto95percentofvotingstockin1924,andwasagainamendedin1942torequireownershipof95percentof thevotingpowerofall classesof sharesand95percentofnon-votingshares.Thethresholdwasthenreducedto80percentin1954asameanstoallowmorecompaniestoconsolidate.Themajorproblemwiththislowerthresholdisthepresenceofminorityinterestsinsubsidiaries(asdiscussedabove).TheUSexperiencestronglysuggeststhatthepresenceofasignificantmin-orityinterestshouldbeavoided.66

Theownershipthresholdundereachoftheeightconsolidationregimesisappliedonthebasisofsomespecificationofshareownership.Atoneextreme,AustraliaandSpainadoptaformalisticapproachandapplythespecifiedthresholdprimarilyonthebasisoflegalownership.Theabsenceofconstructiveownershiprulesthataccountforthird-partyarrangementsaffectingvotingrightsandeconomicexposureother-wiseassociatedwithshareownershipprovidessubstantialpotentialforabuse.67

Incontrast,othercountrieshavemorerobustownershiprequirements in thesensethatarrangementsaffectingeconomicownershipofsharesandtheabilitytoexercisevotingrightsarerelevant.France’sownershipthresholdrequires95percentholdingsinbothsharecapitalandvotingrightsinthesubsidiary.68TheNetherlands’ownershipthresholdrequires95percentownershipinbothsharecapitaland“rightstoprofits,”69whileItaly’s50percentownershiprequirementappliestoallthreefac-torsofsharecapital,votingrights,andrightstoprofits.70Japanprotectsitssharecapitalthresholdbyaspecificanti-avoidanceprovisiontargetingabuseofitscon-solidationregime.71

Thevotingrightfactorisdesignedtodefineacontrolrelationshipbetweentheparentcompanyanditssubsidiaries.InadditiontoFranceandItaly,NewZealand72

66 Lehmann,supranote59,at277.

67 Forexample,inAustralia,awhollyownedsubsidiarymayescapeconsolidationtreatmentifathirdpartyholdssomeofitsnon-votingpreferenceshares,eventhoughthesubsidiaryisfullycontrolledbytheparentcompany.Thisviolatesthe“all-in”principleoftheAustralianconsolidationregime.Alternatively,evenifaparentcompanyholdsallthesharesinasubsidiary,thelattermaybeeffectivelycontrolledbyathirdpartythatholdsoptionsoverallthesharesinthesubsidiary.Inthatcase,theparentcompanymaystillconsolidatewiththesubsidiary,eventhoughthelatterisinsubstancecontrolledbyanotherparty.Incontrast,bothNewZealandandtheUnitedStateshavespecialprovisionstodealwithoptionsandotherfinancialinstrumentsintheirconsolidationregimes.

68 GTCarticle223A.SeealsoNicolasMessage,“France,”inInternational and EC Tax Aspects of Groups of Companies,supranote31,277-99,at283.

69 CITL1969article15(1).SeealsodeVries,supranote40,at469;andJohannMüller,The Netherlands in International Tax Planning(Amsterdam:InternationalBureauofFiscalDocumentation,2005),at248.

70 ITCarticles117and120;ItalianCivilCode,articles2346and2359.

71 CTAarticle132-3.

72 ITA2007sectionIC4.

Page 19: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 439

and the United States73 also adopt this factor in their ownership requirements.WhileFranceandItalyadoptthevotingrightfactorinconjunctionwiththesharecapitalfactor,NewZealandandtheUnitedStatesdonotstipulatesharecapitalintheirownershiprequirements.Instead,theybasetheirownershiptestsprimarilyonvotingrights,supplementedbysharevalueasananti-avoidancemeasure.

Alloftheeightselectedcountriesallowcorporategroupstoelecttoconsolidate;infact,noneoftheseconsolidationregimesismandatory.However,theeightcoun-triesaredividedontheissueofwhethertheelectiontoconsolidateisrevocable.Threecountries—theNetherlands,74NewZealand,75andSpain76—allowagrouptorevoketheelection.Fourcountries—France,Italy,Japan,andtheUnitedStates—donot,ingeneral,allowrevocation.77TheelectiontoconsolidateinJapanandtheUnitedStatesisforanindefiniteterm.Incontrast,therelativelyshorttermofanelectioninFrance(fiveyears)andinItaly(threeyears)representsalessrigorousanti-avoidancepolicyobjective.Theremainingcountry,Australia,doesnothaveaconsistentpolicyonthisissue.Anelectiontoconsolidateisirrevocablefordomes-ticallyownedgroups78buteffectivelyrevocableforforeign-ownedgroups.79Thedivergentpoliciesamongtheeightcountriesonthiskeystructuralelementillus-tratethedifficultcompromisesthatgovernmentshavetomakebetweencompetingpolicyobjectives.Thepolicychoicebetweenrevocableand irrevocableelectionsdependsonthetradeoffbetweenanti-avoidance(whichwouldsuggestanirrevo-cableelection)andflexibility(whichwouldsuggestthattheelectionberevocable).

Giventheassociatedbenefits,mosteligiblecorporategroupselectconsolidatedtreatment.Anotableexceptionissmallandmedium-sizedenterprises,whichseemtohaveatendencynottoelectconsolidatedtreatmentbecauseofperceivedcompliancecosts.80Theavailabilityofconsolidatedtreatmentonanelectivebasisforeligible

73 IRCsection1504(a)(1)(B)(ii). 74 CITL1969article15(6).Ananti-avoidanceprovisionpreventsasubsidiaryfromjoiningand

leavingaconsolidatedgroupinthesameyear:CITL1969article15(7). 75 ITA2007sectionFM37.NewZealand’srulesofelectiontoconsolidateareveryflexible.They

notonlyallowagrouptoelecttoconsolidate,butalsoallowagroupmembertoelecttoleaveaconsolidatedgroup.Therefore,itisunnecessaryforthelawtostipulatewhetherthechoicetoconsolidateisrevocableornot.

76 CITLsection70(5). 77 GTCarticle223A(France),ITCarticle117(3)(Italy),CTAarticle4-5(3)( Japan),andIRC

Reg.section1.1502-75(a)(2)(UnitedStates). 78 ITAA1997section703.50. 79 ITAA1997sections719.60and719.80. 80 Forexample,inAustralia,morethan90percentoflargecorporategroups(thatis,havinga

groupturnoverofmorethanA$1billion)haveelectedtoconsolidate,whilelessthan30percentofsmallcorporategroups(havingagroupturnoveroflessthanA$10million)haveformedaconsolidatedgroup:Australia,TheBoardofTaxation,Post-Implementation Review into Certain Aspects of the Consolidation Regime,DiscussionPaper(Canberra:CommonwealthofAustralia,2009)(www.taxboard.gov.au/content/reviews_and_consultations/aspects_of_the_consolidation_regime/discussion_paper/consolidation_regime_discussion_paper.pdf ),at54.

Page 20: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

440 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

corporategroupsiscontrarytotheapparentpreferenceamongCanada’sprovincestohavesucharegimeapplyonamandatorybasis.Itappearsthatthereasonforthispreferenceistoensurethatcorporategroupsthatmeettherequirementsforconsoli-datedtreatmentcannotescapeapplicationoftheregimeandengageininterprovincialincomeshifting.81

Themorecommon issueofelectivityunder theconsolidationregimesof theeightselectedcountriesconcernstheinclusionofalloronlysomeoftheotherwiseeligiblemembersinaconsolidatedgroup.Indeed,inclusionofotherwiseeligiblecompanieswithinaconsolidatedgroupmaybeelectiveormandatory.Thecompara-tiveanalysisoftheeightcountriesrevealsnopredominantpolicyonthisstructuralelement.Fourcountries—France,82Italy,83theNetherlands,84andNewZealand85—allowcherry-pickingofsubsidiaries.Threecountries—Japan,Spain,andtheUnitedStates—imposetheall-inrule.86Australiadoesnothaveaconsistentpolicyinthisrespect.Itimposestheall-inrulefordomesticallyownedconsolidatedgroups,butallowscherry-pickingofsubgroupsownedbyforeignparentcompanies.87

Itisdifficulttodeterminewhichapproachisbetter.Thediversepolicychoicesamongtheeightcountriesagainreflectthedifficultcompromisesthatgovernmentshavetomakebetweencompetingpolicyobjectives.Ontheonehand,theall-inruleservesananti-avoidanceobjectivebyinsistingthat,wheretheelectiontoconsoli-dateismade,alleligiblemembersofthecorporategroupmustjointheconsolidatedgroup.Ontheotherhand,allowingcherry-pickingprovidesflexibilityoftreatment.

81 See,forexample,Ontario,MinistryofFinance,supranote11,at7.

82 FrankLeMentec,“FrenchTaxGroupRegimes,”inThe European Union and Group Relief: How Will the Marks & Spencer Case Impact?BNAInternationalSpecialReport(London:BNAInternational,2006),at3.Thisflexiblepolicyhasbeeninplacesincetheconsolidationregimewasintroducedin1988:PierreKnoepflerandJackAnderson,“France:TowardsaRealGroupTaxHarmonization”(1988)28:6European Taxation171-77,at172.

83 Giaconia,supranote62,at379.

84 ThebasicbuildingblockofaconsolidatedgroupintheNetherlandsisdefinedtobebetweentwocompanies,aparentanditssubsidiary:CITL1969article15.

85 Anytwo or moreeligiblecompaniesofawhollyownedgroupmayelecttoformaconsolidatedgroup:ITA2007sectionFM35(1).

86 CTAarticle4-2( Japan),CITLsection67(1)(Spain),andIRCReg.sections1.1502-75(a)and(e)(UnitedStates).

87 Australia’sall-inpolicyfordomesticallyownedgroupsisachievedquiteindirectlybythecombinationofseveralprovisions.ITAA1997section703.10definesa“consolidatablegroup”asconsistingoftheheadcompanyandallthesubsidiarymembersofthegroup.Section703.5(1)(a)inturndefinesa“consolidatedgroup”ascomingintoexistenceupontheelectionbytheheadcompanytoconsolidatetheconsolidatablegroup.Newsubsidiarymembersacquiredbyanexistingconsolidatedgroupmustalsobeincludedintheconsolidationpursuanttosection703.5(3).Thecontrastingpolicyforforeign-ownedgroups,knownas“MEC”(multipleentryconsolidated)groups,iscontainedinsection719.5.

Page 21: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 441

Treatment of Preconsolidation Losses

Onentryofacompanyintoaconsolidatedgroup,thetreatmentofpreconsolidationlosses incurredbythecompanymustbedetermined.88Thecomparativeanalysisrevealsthreealternativetreatmentsofsuchlosses:(1)quarantine,(2)transfertotheparent,and(3)cancellation.89

QuarantineUnderthequarantineapproach,preconsolidationlossesincurredbyajoiningsub-sidiaryarequarantinedandareavailableforoffsetonlyagainstprofitsgeneratedbythatsubsidiary.Thepolicyrationaleforquarantineisthatsincethepreconsolida-tion losseswere incurredwhenthesubsidiarywas treatedasaseparate taxpayer,thoselossesshouldremainwiththesubsidiaryandbeavailableonlyforoffsetagainstitsfuturetaxableincome.Aprerequisiteforthispolicyisthatthesubsidiarymain-tainsitsseparateidentityforincometaxpurposesduringconsolidation.Insixoftheeightcountries—allexceptAustraliaandJapan—preconsolidationlossesofajoiningsubsidiaryarequarantined.90AllofthesesixcountriesexcepttheNetherlandsadoptthepoolingsystem,whichisalogicalcompanionofthequarantinepolicy.

Arelatedissueiswhetherthepreconsolidationlossesshouldbeappliedbeforeor after aggregation of the group members’ taxable income and losses. The sixcountries that adopt the quarantine approach are divided between two differentversionsof itsapplication:offsetbeforeaggregationandoffsetafteraggregation.Threecountries—France,Italy,andNewZealand—adopttheoffsetbeforeaggre-gationoption.Underthisoption,preconsolidationlossesofasubsidiaryareappliedfirsttooffsettaxableincomeofthecompany.Remainingtaxableincome(ifany)isthenpooledwiththeresultsofothergroupmemberstoarriveatthegroup’scon-solidatedtaxableincomeorloss.

Theadvantageofthispolicyoptionisitssimplicity:thepreconsolidationlossesaredeterminedandcarriedforwardonthebasisofthegeneralrulesapplicableto

88 Theamountinvolvedisoftensubstantial.InCanada,thebalancesofunutilizednon-capitallossesandcapitallossesin2008were$206billionand$78billion,respectively:consultationpaper,supranote2,at23.Similarly,theAustraliangovernmentestimatedthattheamountofcarryforwardlossesinentitiesbeforetheintroductionoftheconsolidationregimewasintheorderofA$66billion:ReviewofBusinessTaxation,A Platform for Consultation: Building on a Strong Foundation(Canberra:CommonwealthofAustralia,1999),vol.2,at561.

89 Theoretically,anotheralternativepolicyistosuspendpreconsolidationlossesofasubsidiaryduringconsolidation,andrevertthembacktothecompanywhenitleavestheconsolidatedgroup.However,inpractice,noneoftheeightcountriesadoptthispolicy,perhapsbecauseoftheundesirabledeferraloflossutilization,andthepossibilityofeitherlossexpiry(unlesslossescanbecarriedforwardindefinitelyinacountry)orunusablelossesifthesubsidiaryneverleavesthegroup.Germanyisarareexceptionamonggrouptaxationregimesinadoptingthesuspensionpolicy:Link,supranote31,at317.

90 GTCarticle223I(France),ITCarticle118(2)(Italy),CITL1969articles15ae(1)(a)and15ah(theNetherlands),ITA2007sectionsID2(2)and3(NewZealand),CITLsection74(2)(Spain),andIRCReg.1.1502-21(c)(1)(i)(UnitedStates).

Page 22: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

442 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

companylosses.Thisoptionmayalsohaveimplicationsincountriesthatimposeatimelimitonthecarryoveroflosses.Ascomparedwiththealternativeapproach,offsetbeforeaggregationprovidesa fasterrateofuseofpreconsolidation losses,thusreducingtheriskoflossexpiry—thoughthismaynotbeasignificantissueifthelosscarryforwardperiodislong.

TheNetherlands,Spain,andtheUnitedStatesadoptthereverseorderunderanoffset-after-aggregationapproach.Preconsolidationlossesofasubsidiaryareavail-able for offset only after the taxable income of the company is aggregated withothergroupmembers’results.Thisapproachisrelativelycomplex.Experienceofthethreecountriessuggeststhattheapportionmentrulesallocatingthegroup’snettaxableincometoaparticularsubsidiarytendtobecomplicated.91Anotherpoten-tialproblemistheriskoflossexpiry.Preconsolidationlossescanbeusedonlyifthegroupasawholehasnettaxableincome.Allthreeofthecountriesadoptingthispolicyoptionhavelosscarryforwardtimelimits;however,thecarryforwardperiodisrelativelylong.92Itthusappearsthattheriskoflossexpiryisnotamajorconcerntopolicymakersinthesecountries.

Transfer to the ParentUnderthesecondofthethreealternativetreatments,preconsolidationlossesofasubsidiaryaretransferredtotheparentcompanyuponconsolidation.Thepolicyispremisedonastrongsingleentityconcept,underwhichsubsidiariesaredeemedtohaveceasedtoexistasseparateentitiesforincometaxpurposes.Whentheirpre-consolidationlossesaretransferredtotheparentcompany,theyareavailableforoffsetagainsttheconsolidatedgroup’staxableincome.

Australiaistheonlycountrythathasadoptedthisapproach.Underitsstrongsingleentityrule(SER),subsidiariesaredeemedtohaveceasedtoexistduringcon-solidation.Thisdeemed“disappearance”ofsubsidiariesmeansthatthequarantineapproachisnotanoption,sinceittypicallyrestrictsthelossutilizationratebyal-lowingoffsetofpreconsolidationlossesonlyagainsttaxableincomegeneratedbythesamesubsidiary.Moreover,theSERassumesthatthedeemeddisappearanceofsubsidiariesduringconsolidationmeansthatitisimpossibletocalculateasubsidi-ary’staxableincomeonastand-alonebasis.93

91 Forinstance,intheNetherlandstheallocationofthegroupprofitattributabletoaparticularsubsidiaryissubjecttoasetofcomplexprofit-splitrules.Foradetaileddiscussionoftherules,seeMüller,supranote69,at263-68.IntheUnitedStates,theallocationissubjecttothehighlycomplex“separatereturnlimitationyear”rules.Foradetaileddiscussionoftherules,see,forexample,Hennesseyetal.,supranote64,section8.05.

92 Thetimelimitsare9yearsintheNetherlands,15yearsinSpain,and20yearsintheUnitedStates.

93 A Platform for Consultation,supranote88,at563.Itisdoubtfulthatthisassumptioniscorrect.Experienceinothercountriesthatadoptthequarantinepolicystronglysuggeststhatinpracticeitisstillpossibletocomputeasubsidiary’sprofitandlossonastand-alonebasisduringconsolidation.

Page 23: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 443

Australianpolicymakersnonethelessfacedanimportantconstraintinthedesignoftherulesonpreconsolidationlosses.Beforetheconsolidationregimewasintro-ducedin2002,Australiahadagrouplossregime,which,inbroadterms,allowedintragrouplosstransfersamongwhollyownedresidentcompanies.94Thisplacedconsiderablepressureonpolicymakerstocomeupwithamodelthatwouldbeatleastasattractiveastheexistingregime.Thepressurewasintensifiedbythefactthatmostcompanieswouldbedeniedaccesstotheformergrouplossreliefregimeaftertheintroductionoftheconsolidationregime.95Australia’ssolutionwastoallowthetransferofpreconsolidationlossesofsubsidiariestotheparentcompanyuponconsolidation,96andtoprovidethatthetransferisnotreversedwhenthesubsidiaryleavesthegroup.

Thepolicyoftransferringpreconsolidationlossestoaparentcompanypresentedaseriousproblemtothegovernment:unrestrictedutilizationofsuchtransferredlosseswouldhaveasignificantrevenueimpact.97Theresponsewastoadoptanin-ventedconcept,theavailablefraction(AF).98Inbroadterms,preconsolidationlossesofajoiningsubsidiaryareassignedanAFthatiscalculatedastheratioofthemarketvalueofthesubsidiarytothatoftheconsolidatedgrouponentry.Themaximumamountofthelossesthattheparentcompanymayuseinayearisequaltotheprod-uctoftheAFandthegroup’sconsolidatedprofitsforthatyear.

TheAustraliangovernmentclaimsthattheobjectiveoftheAFrulesistoreflectthelossuseratethatwouldapplyifthesubsidiaryhadnotjoinedtheconsolidatedgroup.However,thequestionableuseofmarketvalueasaproxyfortheactualtaxpositionsofacompany,andthefailuretoadjustthemarketvaluationsonaregularbasis,maketheAFaveryroughproxy.Nevertheless,ifoneacceptsthatthemostim-portantobjectiveoftheAFrulesistorestricttheuserateofpreconsolidationlosses,theirmechanicaloperationarguablyservesthatpurposewell.ThisisespeciallysogiventhattheAFsofagroupcanneverbeadjustedupwardunderadjustmentevents.99

94 ITAA1997division170.Upontheintroductionoftheconsolidationregime,thescopeofthegrouplossreliefregimewassubstantiallycurtailed;currently,itisapplicableonlytoforeignbankgroupswithAustralianbranchesandsubsidiaries.

95 NewZealandfacedasimilarconstraintinthedesignofitsconsolidationregimebutcameupwithamoreflexibleandtaxpayer-friendlyapproach,inwhichconsolidationandgrouplossreliefregimescoexist.

96 ITAA1997section707.120.Thetransferissubjecttoamodifiedcontinuity-of-ownershiptestandasamebusinesstest.Adetaileddiscussionofthesetestsisbeyondthescopeofthisarticle.

97 Atthetime,itwasestimatedthattherewasa“largestoreofpastlossesinentities...approximately$44.6billionrevenuelossesand$21.7billioncapitallosses”:A Platform for Consultation,supranote88,at561.Toputthenumbersintoperspective,theaggregatetaxableincomeofcompaniesinthe1999-2000incomeyearwas$129billion:AustralianTaxOffice,Tax Statistics 1999-2000(Canberra:CommonwealthofAustralia,2002).

98 ITAA1997division707.

99 Thisisclearlythegovernment’sintention:Australia,TreasuryDepartment,New Business Tax System (Consolidation) and Other Measures Bill (No. 1) 2002: Explanatory Memorandum(Canberra:CommonwealthofAustralia,2002),atparagraph8.5.

Page 24: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

444 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

ItmaybemoreaccuratetodescribetheAFrulesassimplyaroughandarbitrarymeasuretoallocateagroup’staxableincometoindividualgroupmembersforthepurposeofcontrollingtheuseratesofpreconsolidationlosses.

Ironically,anotheradvantageoftheAFrulesisaresultofthearbitrarynatureoftheAF.Incontrasttocountriesthathaveadoptedaquarantinepolicy,specificanti-avoidance provisions are not required in Australia to prevent abuses of the lossoffsetrules.ItalyandtheNetherlands,forexample,havefounditnecessarytoenactprovisionstopreventaccelerationoftheuseofpreconsolidationlossesbyanintra-grouptransferofassetswithhiddenreserves.100ThiskindofprovisionisunnecessaryundertheAFmodelsincetheutilizationrateisnotdependentonasubsidiary’sin-dividualtaxableincome.

Evenso,itisdoubtfulwhetherthisadvantageissufficienttojustifytheproblem-aticAFrules,theoutcomeofwhichisdetachedfromtheactualcircumstancesofacompany.Asnotedabove,theAFofpreconsolidationlossesofasubsidiaryisdeter-minedonentry,onthebasisoftheprevailingmarketvaluesofthecompanyandthegroup.ThevalueoftheAFdeterminedatthatpointintimeisnotsubjecttoregularrevaluation,even though themarketvaluesof thecompanyand thegroupmostlikelywouldchangeovertime.Evenifthesubsidiarysuccessfullyturnsaroundandmakesasubstantialprofitduringconsolidation,thetransferredlossesarestillsub-ject to theoldAF limitfixedat the joining time.Theoutcome is thereforeverydifferent from that under the more common quarantine policy. The method ofcalculatingtheAFalsoimpliesthattheoutcomewouldbeverydifferentifthesub-sidiaryhadnotjoinedaconsolidatedcorporategroup.Finally,theheavyrelianceonmarketvaluationsofsubsidiariesandthegroupimplieshighcompliancecostsfortaxpayersandmonitoringcostsfortheAustralianTaxationOffice(ATO).

CancellationInJapan,generallypreconsolidationlossesofasubsidiaryarecancelleduponentryintoaconsolidatedgroup.101Thisharshpolicyisdrivenprimarilybytax-avoidanceconcerns.Infact,thegovernmentdidnotappeartobetooenthusiasticaboutintro-ducingaconsolidationregime.Thisreluctanceisimplicitinotheraspectsoftheregime,includingthedeemeddisposalofcertainassetsatmarketvalueatjoiningtime,anda2percentconsolidationsurchargeinadditiontothenormalcorporatetaxrate(imposedforthefirsttwoyearsfollowingtheintroductionoftheregime).

The cancellation approach is simple, avoiding the need for complex rules tocontroltheuserateofpreconsolidationlosses.However,thetaxoutcomeforanunconsolidatedcompanywithunusedlossesisverydifferentonceitjoinsaconsoli-datedgroup.Toavoidsuchdiscontinuityintaxtreatment,theothercountriesallowtheoffset of preconsolidation lossesof a subsidiary at a rate approximating thatwhichwouldapplyifthecompanyhadnotconsolidated.

100 ITCarticle123(2)(Italy),andCITL1969article15ae(2)(theNetherlands).

101 CTAarticle81-9(1).

Page 25: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 445

Thecancellationofpreconsolidation lossesof joining subsidiarieshasbeen amajordisincentivetoconsolidationforcorporategroupsinJapanthatwouldqualifytoelectconsolidatedtreatment.ItisthereforenotsurprisingthattheJapanesegov-ernmenthasrecentlyrelaxedtherulesunderits2010taxreform.EffectiveApril1,2010,preconsolidationlossesofajoiningsubsidiaryarenotcancelledbutaresub-jecttoquarantineprovidedthat,amongotherthings,thesubsidiaryhasbeenwhollyownedbytheparentcompanyforfiveyearsbeforethejoiningtime.102

Treatment of Group Losses on Exit

Themostsignificantadvantageofconsolidationistheabilitytooffsettaxablein-comeandlossesamongconsolidatedgroupmembers.Allof theeightcountriesallowintragroupoffsetoflossesincurredbygroupmembersduringconsolidation.However,thetreatmentofgrouplossesonexit(thatis,whenasubsidiaryleavesaconsolidatedgroup)ismorevaried.Therearetwomainpolicyapproachestothisdesignissue:(1)staywiththegroupand(2)apportionment.

Under the stay-with-the-group approach, group losses stay with the consoli-datedgroupevenifaleavingsubsidiaryhascontributedtothoselosses.Thisoptionissimpletooperatesincethereisnoneedforcomplexallocationrulestoapportiontheconsolidatedgrouplossestoaleavingsubsidiary.Fivecountrieshaveadoptedthisoption—Australia,France,Italy,theNetherlands,andNewZealand.103How-ever,ItalyandtheNetherlandsprovideanoptiontoapplyforapportionmentofthegroup’sconsolidatedlossestoaleavingsubsidiary.Thisapportionmentoptionincreasesthecomplexityoftheregime.

InJapan,Spain,andtheUnitedStates,agroup’sconsolidatedlossesareallocatedtoaleavingsubsidiary.104Thisoptionrequirescomplexallocationrulestoapportiontheconsolidatedgroup’slossestotheleavingsubsidiary.

Treatment of Assets

On EntryThetax-freetransferofassetsamongconsolidatedgroupmembersisanothersig-nificantadvantageofconsolidation.Taxpolicymakersmustdecide,however,asaseparateissue,howtotreattheassetsofacompanyonentryintoaconsolidatedgroup.Thecomparativeanalysisof theeight selectedcountries reveals,broadly,three alternative approaches to the treatment of assets (other than intragroup

102 Corporate Taxation Database,supranote18,searchunder“CountryAnalysis”—“Japan”—“CorporateTaxation,”atparagraph8.2;andErnst&Young,“Japan”(May2010)APAC Tax Matters14-15,at15.

103 ITAA1997section707.410(Australia),GTCarticle223E(France),ITCarticle118(1)(Italy),CITL1969articles15af(1)(b)and(2)(theNetherlands),andITA2007sectionID1(1)(NewZealand).

104 CTAarticle57(6)( Japan),CITLsection81(1)(b)(Spain),andIRCReg.section1.1502-21(b)(2)(i)(UnitedStates).

Page 26: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

446 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

shares)105onentry:(1)rollovertreatment,(2)mark-to-markettreatment,and(3)costbasereset.

Rollover Treatment

Undertherolloverapproach,preconsolidationtaxattributesarerolledovertotheconsolidatedgroup,andassetsofajoiningsubsidiaryaretreatedasownedbythecon-solidatedgroupat theoriginalcostbases.Thewholeamountofgainor lossondisposal—includingtheamountattributabletothepreconsolidationperiod—isat-tributedtothegroup.Sixoftheeightcountries(excludingAustraliaandJapan)haveadoptedthisapproach,withnoimmediatetaxconsequencesforassetsofsubsidi-ariesonentrytoaconsolidatedcorporategroup.106

Mark-to-Market Treatment

Underthemark-to-marketapproach,assetsaredeemedtohavebeenpassedtotheconsolidatedgroupattheirrespectivemarketvalues.Unrealizedgainsorlossesonassets owned by a subsidiary before entry are recognized immediately on entry.Presumablybecauseofvaluationissues,andtheeffectofimmediatetaxationontheattractivenessofaconsolidationregime,Japanistheonlycountrythathasadoptedthemark-to-marketapproachapplicabletofixedassets,land,securitiesheldascap-ital assets, andmonetary assetsheldby a joining subsidiary.107TheNetherlandsadopts a general policy of rollover except for intragroup shares and receivables,whicharemarkedtomarketonentry.108

Cost Base Reset

Australia is the only country that has adopted an “asset-based” approach to thetreatmentoftheassetsofajoiningsubsidiary.Adoptionofthisapproachwasdrivenprimarilybyadeterminationtodealwiththedualcostbaseissue—thatis,therec-ognitionofthesameeconomicgainorlossmorethanonceinacorporategroupbecauseofmultiplelevelsofownership.109Becausethisapproachisnewandun-usual,andpossiblyunfamiliartomostreaders,itisanalyzedinmoredetailhere.

105 Treatmentofintragroupsharesisdiscussedseparatelybelow.

106 Therolloverpolicyonassetsinsubsidiariesisoftentheconsequenceofapoolingsystem,underwhichthesubsidiariesremain,toalargeextent,separateentitiesforincometaxpurposes.Theirassetsthusattractnoimmediatetaxconsequencesuponconsolidation.TheNetherlandsprovidesforanexceptiontothisgeneralrule:seethediscussionbelowunder“Mark-to-MarketTreatment.”

107 CTAarticle61-11.Thedeemedsaleruleissubjecttoanumberofexceptions,includingassetsoftheparentcompanyandofsubsidiariesownedbytheparentcompanyformorethanfiveyears.

108 CITL1969articles15ab(1)and(6).Thisexceptionisprimarilyanti-avoidanceinnature:Müller,supranote69,at253.

109 ITAA1997division705.Thegovernment’sdeterminationtousetheconsolidationregimetodealwiththedualcostbaseissuewasevidentinthelegislationdesignprocess:seeA Platform for Consultation,supranote88,atparagraphs25.5and25.6.SeealsoGraemeS.Cooper,“AFew

Page 27: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 447

UnlikemostEuropeancountries,Australiadoesnothaveacomprehensivedo-mesticparticipationexemption (PEX)regimeforcorporateequity.Thedualcostbase issue therefore represents a serious challenge to the tax system, includingdoubletaxationofthesameeconomicgain,doubledeductionofthesameeconomicloss,andvalueshiftingamonggroupmembers.Thegovernmentbelievedthattheintroductionofaconsolidationregimeprovidedavaluableopportunitytodealwiththeseproblemsby adopting the SER andeffectively collapsingmultiple levelsofownershipinacorporategroupintoonesinglelevel.Inparticular,allsubsidiariesaredeemedtohavebecomedivisionsoftheparentcompany,andtheirassetsaredeemedtobeowneddirectlybytheparent.Becausemultiplelevelsofownershiparecollapsedintoone,thedualcostbaseissuebecomesanon-issuewithinacon-solidatedgroup.110

TheadoptionoftheSER,however,raisesanimportantissue:Whatshouldbethecostbasesofsubsidiaries’assetsthatarenowdeemedtobeowneddirectlybythepar-entcompany?Asnotedearlier,sinceintragroupassettransfersareignoredcompletelyforincometaxpurposes,thereisnoneedtotraceintragroupassetmovementsdur-ingconsolidation,tokeeptrackofanydeferredgainorlossonthosetransfers,ortorecapturethegainor losswheneitherthetransferororthetransfereeleavesthegroup.Thegovernmentapparentlybelievedthatthemorecommonrolloverpolicywasincompatiblewithitsdeterminationtocollapsemultiplelevelsofownershipinaconsolidatedgroupintoone.

Thisdeterminationtodealwiththedualcostbaseissuecomesatahighcompli-anceandadministrativeprice.Amongotherthings,thepreconsolidationcostbasesofsharesinasubsidiarybecomeirrelevant,sincethecompanymaycarryverydifferentassetswhenitlaterleavesthegroup.Thecostbaseofsharesofaleavingsubsidiarythereforehastobereconstructed.Thegovernmentconsideredtwopolicyoptionsto reconstruct the cost bases of shares in a leaving subsidiary: the entity-basedmodel111andtheasset-basedmodel.112Under the latter,uponconsolidation, thecostbaseofsharesinasubsidiaryispusheddowntotheunderlyingassets.Precon-solidationcostbasesofassetsingeneralareerasedandpermanentlyreplacedbytheresetcostbases.Onexit fromthegroup, thesharecostbase isreconstructedbypushingupthecostbasesofassetsthatthecompanytakesawayfromthegroup.

ObservationsonManagingtheTaxationofCorporateGroups—TheAustralianExperience”(2011)59:2Canadian Tax Journal265-94.

110 However,consolidationcandealwiththedualcostbaseissueonlyinrelationtocorporategroupsthatelecttoconsolidate.Thetaxlawstillrequiresotherspecificprovisionstodealwiththeissuefornon-consolidatedgroups.Incontrast,acomprehensiveparticipationexemptionwouldbeamorecomprehensivesolutionforallcorporategroups.

111 ThisisbasicallythemodelintheUSconsolidationregime.Seethediscussionbelowundertheheading“TreatmentofIntragroupShareholdings—OnExit.”

112 A Platform for Consultation,supranote88,at572-78.

Page 28: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

448 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

AsomewhatbitterironyisthatAustraliachoseitsasset-basedapproachinordertoavoidthecomplianceandadministrativecostsoftracingintragroupassettrans-fersunderanentity-basedapproachsuchas that in theUnitedStates,describedbelow.113Infact,asnotedearlier,thedecisiontoadopttheasset-basedapproachwasinfluencedbytheUSexperiencewiththeentity-basedapproach;inparticular,UStaxofficialsapparentlywarnedtheirAustraliancounterpartsthattheentity-basedap-proachrequirescomplexandongoingequitytaxbasisadjustmentsforintragroupassettransfersduringconsolidation.114However,theAustralianapproachishardlyaclearimprovementintermsofsimplicity.Theasset-basedmodelincludesacom-plexsetofrules—theTCS,ortax-cost-setting,rules—thataredesignedtoachievethepushdownofsharecostbasestotheunderlyingassets.UndertheTCSrules,asubsidiary’sliabilities(identifiedandmeasuredunderaccountingrules)areaddedtothecostbasesofsharesinthecompany,andadjustmentsaremadeforcertainprofitsand losses of the company, to arrive at an amount known as the “allocable costamount”(ACA).115TheACAisthengenerallyallocatedtotheassetsinthesubsidiaryaccording to their respectivemarket valuesonentry.116 Inotherwords, thecostbasesofmany assets are “reset”on entry,with the reset costbase replacing the“real”costbaseandremainingpermanentlywiththeasset,evenifthesubsidiarysubsequentlyleavesthegroup.117

Theresetcostbaseofanassetmaybehigherorlowerthantheoriginalcostbase.Inpractice,thecreativityoftaxpayersandtheiradvisersismorelikelytoproducea

113 ReviewofBusinessTaxation,A Tax System Redesigned: More Certain, Equitable and Durable,Report:Overview,Recommendations,EstimatedImpacts(Canberra:CommonwealthofAustralia,1999),at528.ForabriefdescriptionoftheUSentity-basedmodel,seeYarivBrauner,“UnitedStates”inInternational and EC Tax Aspects of Groups of Companies,supranote31,503-34,at524-25.

114 Lehmann,supranote59,at277.

115 ITAA1997section705.60.

116 ITAA1997section705.35(1)(c).Certainassets(suchasAustraliancurrencyandreceivables)—knownas“retainedcostbaseassets”—retaintheircostbases:ITAA1997section705.25.ThetotalamountoftheseretainedcostbasesissubtractedfromtheACAbeforethebalanceisallocatedtotheremainingassets(knownas“resetcostbaseassets”):ITAA1997section705.35(1)(b).

117 AdetaileddiscussionofthehighlytechnicalandcomplexTCScalculationsisbeyondthescopeofthisarticle.Nevertheless,theproblemsbecomeobviousifonelooksattheendproduct—thatis,theresetcostbaseofanasset.Ironically,theATO’sConsolidation Reference Manual—whichisintendedtohelptaxpayerstounderstandhowtheconsolidationregimeworks—providesatellingexampleillustratingtheproblemswiththeTCSrules:AustralianTaxationOffice,Consolidation Reference Manual: Taxing Wholly-Owned Corporate Groups as Single Entities(Canberra:CommonwealthofAustralia,2008),exampleinsectionC2-2-110.Intheexample,asubsidiaryhadapieceoflandwhosecostbaseandmarketvaluebothwereandremained$100.Atthejoiningtime,after16pagesofTCScalculations,thecostbaseofthelandwasresetto$74.Theimplicationisthatiftheconsolidatedgroupsoldthelandforitsmarketvalueof$100(whichisequaltoitsoriginalcostbase),thegroupwouldbetaxedonanartificialgainof$26.

Page 29: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 449

stepped-up,insteadofastepped-down,resetcostbase.TheTCSrulesthusprovidefertilegroundfortaxpayers’ingenuity.

Thepolicyofallowingastepped-upcostbaseisuniqueamongtheeightcoun-tries.Infact,theresultofthispolicyundertheTCSrulesissurprisinglygenerous.Theruleseffectivelypermitconversionofpartofshareacquisitioncostsintodepre-ciable cost bases, with the extent of the conversion depending on the relativeamountofdepreciableassetsof thesubsidiary involved, theirmarketvalues,andalsotheaggressivenessoftaxpayerstakingadvantageoftherules.Thestepped-upbasiscanalsoreducegainonfuturedisposalofcapitalassets.

Finally,asinthecaseoftheAFrulesdiscussedabove,theheavyrelianceonmarketvaluationofassetsatthejoiningtimealsoimplieshighcompliancecostsfortaxpay-ersandpolicingcostsfortaxauthorities.

During ConsolidationUnderthesingleentityconcept,anintragroupassettransferduringconsolidationshouldhavenoimmediatetaxconsequencesforthegroup.Thatis,thetransfershouldbetreatedasifitwereatransferbetweendivisionsofacompany.Amongtheeightcountries,threeapproachesareusedtoaddressthisstructuralelement:(1)rollovertreatment,(2)non-recognitionofatransfer,and(3)realizationtreatment.

Therolloverapproachisthepredominantchoiceamongtheeightcountries;sixofthem(excludingAustraliaandItaly)haveadoptedthisoption.118Undertherolloverapproach,anygainorlossonintragroupassettransfersisdeferred,andthedeferredgainorlossis,ingeneral,recapturedwheneitherthetransferororthetransfereeleavestheconsolidatedgroup.

Asdiscussedearlier,theSERadoptedinAustraliadictatesthatallassetsofsubsidi-ariesbeconsideredassetsoftheparentcompanyduringconsolidation.Intragroupassettransfersarethereforecompletelyignored.Theadvantagesofthistreatmentovertherolloverapproachhavebeendescribedabove:thereisnoneedtotracethemovementofassetswithinaconsolidatedgroup,tokeeparecordofanydeferredgainorloss,ortorecapturethegainorlosswheneitherthetransferororthetrans-fereeleavesthegroup.However,thebenefitcomesatahighpriceintermsofthecomplexandproblematicTCSrules.

Italyoriginally allowed rollover treatmentwhen its consolidation regimewasintroducedin2004.However,becauseofavoidanceconcerns,thepolicywasabol-ishedin2008,andintragroupassettransferswithinaconsolidatedgrouparenowsubjecttorealizationtreatment.119

118 GTCarticle223F(France),CTAarticle81-10( Japan),ITA2007sectionsFM8and10(NewZealand),CITLsection72(Spain),andIRCReg.section1.1502-13(a)(2)(UnitedStates).

119 ITCarticle121.SeealsoFabrizioBendotti,“Italy,”inInternational and EC Tax Aspects of Groups of Companies,supranote31,327-62,atfootnote7.

Page 30: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

450 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

On ExitOntheexitofacompanyfromaconsolidatedgroup,policymakersmustdecidehowtotreattheassetsandassociatedtaxattributesthatgowiththeleavingsubsidiary.Thetaxattributesmaybeamixtureofpreconsolidationtaxattributes(forexample,gainsaccruedduringthepreconsolidationperiod)andtaxattributesgenerateddur-ingconsolidation(forexample,gainsaccruedduringconsolidation).Tosomeextent,theapproachtothetreatmentofassetsonexitisdictatedbythetreatmentofintra-groupassettransfersduringconsolidation.Thecomparativeanalysisoftheeightcountriesrevealsthreeapproachestothisstructuralelement:(1)recapturetreat-ment,(2)inheritanceofresetcostbases,and(3)non-recognitiontreatment.

Whereacountryadoptsrollover treatment for intragroupasset transfers, thedeferredgainis,ingeneral,recapturedwheneitherthetransferororthetransfereeleavestheconsolidatedgroup.Sixoftheeightselectedcountries(excludingAus-traliaandItaly)haveadoptedthisrealizationapproach.120However,therearesomesubtle differences. In three of the six countries (France, Spain, and the UnitedStates),recaptureistriggeredifeitherthetransferororthetransfereeoftheprevi-ousassettransferleavestheconsolidatedgroup.IntheNetherlands,recaptureistriggeredbytheexitofthetransferororthetransfereeonlyifthepreviousintra-group asset transfer is regarded as tax-driven.121 Recapture is triggered in NewZealandwhenthetransfereeleavesthegroup,whileonlythedepartureofthetrans-ferortriggersrecaptureinJapan.Triggeringofrealizationtreatmentontheexitofthetransferorappearstobebasedonthepremisethat,intheabsenceoftherollover,thedeferredgainorlosswouldhavebeentaxedtothetransferor.Alternatively,acountrymayrecapturedeferredgainorlossuponthedepartureofthetransfereesoastopreventthetransfereefromtakinganassetwithhiddenreservesawayfromthegrouptax-free.

Undertheuniqueasset-basedmodelinAustralia,aleavingsubsidiaryinheritsthecostbasesofassets—includingtheresetcostbasescreatedundertheTCSrules—thatittakesawayfromtheconsolidatedgroup.122Noimmediatetaxationarisesonexit.

InItaly,sinceintragroupassettransfersduringconsolidationaresubjecttorealiza-tiontreatment,therearenoadditionaltaxconsequencesforassetsthatasubsidiarytakeswithitonleavingthegroup.

Treatment of Intragroup Shareholdings

On EntryIntragroupshareholdingsgiverisetothedualcostbase issuenotedabove.Mostmoderncorporatetaxsystemsaddress,invaryingdegrees,thedoublerecognition

120 GTCarticle223F(France),CTAarticle61-13( Japan),CITL1969article15ai(1)(theNetherlands),ITA2007sectionFM21(2)(NewZealand),CITLsection73(2)(Spain),andIRCReg.section1.1502-13(a)(5)(UnitedStates).

121 Forabriefdiscussionoftherules,seeMüller,supranote69,at270and274-77.

122 Thisisoneoftheimplicationsofthe“exithistory”rule:ITAA1997section701.40.

Page 31: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 451

ofgainorlossassociatedwithsuchshareholdings.123OnecomprehensiveapproachisthePEX(participationexemption)regimeusedbymanyEuropeancountries.Byexemptingdividendsandgainsderivedfromsharesinasubsidiary,aswellasdeny-ingtherecognitionoflosses,sucharegimeeffectivelyremovesoneofthetwolevelsoftaxationassociatedwithintragroupshareholdings.Inotherwords,itdealsdirectlywiththeprimarycauseoftheissueandcomprehensivelyresolvesit.124CountrieswithoutageneralPEXregimehavechosentoadoptother,andoftenmorecompli-cated,policiestodealwiththedualcostbaseissueinthecontextoftheirconsolidationregimes.Asdescribedabove,Australiacollapsesmultiplelevelsofownershipinacorporate group. The United States adopts an entity-based model under whichadjustmentstothecostbaseofsharesaremadecontinuouslyduringconsolidationtoremoveduplicationofincomeorlosses.

Onentryintoacorporategroup,thecomparativeanalysisrevealsthreealterna-tiveapproachestothetreatmentofintragroupshareholdings:(1)rollovertreatment,(2)mark-to-markettreatment,and(3)deemedelimination.Thepreferredoptiontendstobeafunctionofacountry’sgeneralapproachtothedualcostbaseissue.

Sixoftheeightcountries—France,Italy,Japan,Spain,NewZealand,andtheUnitedStates—haveadoptedrollovertreatmentforintragroupsharesonentryintoaconsolidatedgroup,consistentwithrollovertreatmentoftheassetsofajoiningsubsidiary.125TheNetherlandsistheonlycountrythatdoesnotextenditsgeneralrolloverpolicyforassetstointragroupshares;instead,suchsharesaremarkedtomarketonentry.126Thisapproachwasapparentlyadoptedtopreventanotherwisetaxablegainonthesharesfromescapingtaxationthroughconsolidation.127

UnderAustralia’sasset-basedmodel, shares insubsidiariesheldby theparentcompanyaredeemedtohaveceasedtoexist.Ontheexitofacompany,thecostbaseofthesharesintheleavingsubsidiarymustbereconstitutedundertheTCSrules.128

123 See,forexample,AultandArnold,supranote27,at358-62.Attemptstodealwiththeissueinthecontextofunrealizedgainsorlossesinassetshaveprovedtobeparticularlycomplex.Forexample,seeITAA1997subdivisions165-CCand165-CDfortheAustralianrulesdealingwiththemultiplicationoflosses.

124 AnotheradvantageofthePEXregimeisthatitisgenerallyapplicabletobothconsolidatedandunconsolidatedgroups.Itisalsoapplicableequallytoresidentandnon-residentshareholders.Inotherwords,itprovidesageneralandneutralsolutiontointracorporateshareholdings.Incontrast,othersolutions,suchastheasset-basedmodelinAustralia,donotapplyoutsideconsolidationregimes.Ofcourse,thePEXregimehasitsdrawbacks.Thegeneralexemptionpolicytendstoattracttaxavoidance.Specificanti-avoidanceprovisionsareoftennecessarytoprotecttheregimefromabuse.

125 Rollovertreatmentisagainalogicalconsequenceofthepoolingsystem,underwhichthetaxattributesofsharesinasubsidiaryaremaintainedatthejoiningtime.

126 CITL1969article15ab(1).

127 Müller,supranote69,at253.

128 Seethediscussionbelowundertheheading“OnExit.”

Page 32: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

452 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

During ConsolidationUnderastrongapplicationofthesingleentityconcept,intragroupsharetransfersshould have no tax implications, consistent with the treatment of divisions of asinglecompany.Thispolicyis,infact,followedbyamajorityoftheeightcountries,thoughsomecountriesadoptadifferentapproach,primarilytodealwiththedualcostbaseissue.Nonetheless,inalleightcountries,thereisnoimmediatetaxationofintragroupsharetransfersduringconsolidation.

Four countries—France, Japan, Spain, and the United States—have adoptedrollovertreatment.129Whileeachgroupmemberaccountsforthegainorlossontheintragrouptransferinitsowntaxcomputation,thetransferisneutralizedatthegrouplevelwhentheparentcompanypreparestheconsolidatedtaxcomputation.Thisisthesameapproachthatappliestoanintragrouptransferofnon-shareassetsduringconsolidation.InallofthesefourcountriesexceptJapan,thedeferredgainorlossisrecapturedwheneitherthetransferororthetransfereeleavestheconsoli-dated group. In France and Spain, the recaptured gain or loss may qualify forexemptionunderthePEXregime.InJapan,recaptureistriggeredonlybythede-partureofthetransferor.

ItalyandtheNetherlandsrelyontheirgeneralPEXregimestoexemptintragroupsharetransfers.Inbothcountries,thePEXregimeappliestocompaniesingeneral,whetherornottheyaremembersofaconsolidatedgroup.130Inmostcases,intra-groupsharetransferwillbeeligibleforexemptionsincetheownershipthresholdrequirementsunderconsolidationareoftenstricterthanthoseunderthePEXre-gime.Anadvantageofthisapproachisitssimplicity,sinceadditionalprovisionsarenotrequiredintheconsolidationregimetodealwithintragroupsharetransfers.ThePEXregimealsoappliesconsistentlythroughouttheconsolidationcycle,coveringentry,theconsolidationperiod,andexit.Apossibledrawbackofapplyingtheregimetointragroupsharetransfersisthatitmaybelessbeneficialthannon-recognitiontreatment(forexample,inFranceandSpain).ThisissoifthePEXregimeexemptsonly,say,95percentofthegain,thusleavingtheremaining5percenttobetaxedatthetransfertime.

InAustralia,asdiscussedabove,intragroupsharesinsubsidiariesaredeemedtohaveceasedtoexistduringconsolidation.Thisfictiondictatesthattherebenotaximplicationsforintragroupsharetransfers,sincetheyaredeemednottohaveoc-curred.Butagain,thisapproachrequiresapplicationoftheTCSrulestoreconstructthecostbaseofsharesinaleavingsubsidiary.

TheabsenceofageneraltaxoncapitalgainsinNewZealandmeansa“notaxa-tion”outcomefor intragroupsharetransfers.Intherarecaseswhereshares inasubsidiaryareheldasrevenueassets(receivables),anintragrouptransferofthese

129 GTCarticle223F(France),CTAarticle61-13( Japan),CITLsection72(Spain),andIRCReg.section1.1502-13(a)(2)(UnitedStates).

130 ITCarticle87(Italy)andCITL1969article13(theNetherlands).

Page 33: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 453

assetsissubjecttorollovertreatmentconsistentwiththetreatmentofintragroupassettransfers.131

On ExitOntheexitofacompanyfromaconsolidatedgroup,taxattributesthathavebeendeferredduringconsolidationhavetobeaddressed,withintragroupshareholdingspresentingthetroublesomedualcostbaseissue.Theapproachesoftheeightcoun-triestothisstructuralelementoftheirconsolidationregimesarediverse,especiallyamongthecountriesthatdonothaveacomprehensivePEXregimefordomesticcorporate groups. In particular, the comparative analysis reveals two broad ap-proaches:(1)applicationofthePEXregimeand(2)realizationtreatment.

AllofthefourEuropeancountriesenjoythebenefitofanexistingPEXregime,withgainorlossonadisposalofsharesinaleavingsubsidiarygenerallybeingeli-gibleforexemption.132NewZealandagainenjoystheluxuryofthegeneralpolicyofnottaxingcapitalgains.Disposalofsharesinaleavingsubsidiarythereforedoesnothaveanytaximplications,unlessthesharesareheldasrevenueassets.Inthatcase,NewZealandrecapturesanydeferredgainorlossontheshares.133Thereisnospecificprovisiontoadjustthecostbasesoftheshares,probablybecauseitisrareforsharesinaconsolidatedsubsidiarytobeheldasrevenueassets.

Australia,Japan,andtheUnitedStates,lackingthebenefitofageneralPEXre-gimefordomesticcorporategroups,allimposetaxationonthedisposalofsharesina leavingsubsidiary.However,eachof the threecountriesadoptsadifferentap-proach to the determination of the cost bases of the shares in the subsidiary—thoughwiththesameobjectiveofdealingwiththedualcostbaseissue.

InAustralia,thesharesinaleavingsubsidiary,whicharedeemedtohavedisap-pearedduringconsolidation,springbacktolifeandareassignedacostbasethatisreconstitutedfromthecostbases—includingresetcostbasescreatedundertheTCSrulesonentry—of theunderlyingassets that the subsidiary takesaway fromtheconsolidated group.134 As discussed earlier, the disadvantages of this asset-basedmodelarethecomplexandproblematicTCSrulesandthefailureofthemodeltoprovideacomprehensivesolutiontothedualcostbaseissue.Inparticular,doubletaxationisstillpossibleifasubsidiaryleavesaconsolidatedgroupandtakeswithitassetswithhiddenreserves.OwingtothearbitrarinessoftheTCSrules,artificialgainorlosscanbecreatedandevenduplicatedatleavingtime,sincethecostbasesof shares in a leaving subsidiary are reconstitutedon thebasisof the reset costbasesofassetsinthesubsidiary.Theheavyrelianceonmarketvaluationofassets

131 ITAsectionFM15.

132 GTCarticle219(France),ITCarticle87(Italy),CITC1969article13(theNetherlands),andCITCsection30(Spain).

133 ITAarticleFM15.

134 ITAA1997division711.

Page 34: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

454 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

undertheTCSrules implieshighcompliancecosts fortaxpayersandmonitoringcostsforthetaxauthorities,andcreatesavoidanceopportunities.

IntheUnitedStates,undertheentity-basedmodel,thecostbasesofintragroupshares are adjusted continuously during consolidation. The model provides for“investmentadjustments”underwhichthecostbasesofsharesinasubsidiaryareadjustedforvariousitems,includingdistributions,profits,andlossesofthesub-sidiary.135Forexample,assumethataparentcompany(P)acquiresasubsidiary(S)for$100andthenformsaconsolidatedgroup.136IfShastaxableincomeof$10,thatamountisincludedinthegroup’sconsolidatedtaxableincomeandissubjecttotaxatthegrouplevel.TheinvestmentadjustmentrulesadjustthecostbaseofS’ssharesto$110.IfPsubsequentlysellsS,the$10oftaxableincomeisnottaxedagain.Therulesarecomplexandimposehighcompliancecosts.Theyrequirecon-tinuousadjustmentsthroughoutconsolidation,137andtheruleshavetobeappliedon a bottom-up approach if multiple levels of shareholdings are involved.138Furthermore,ifacompanyhasmorethanoneclassofshares,theadjustmentrulesareevenmorecomplicated.139

InJapan,thecostbasesofsharesinaleavingsubsidiaryareadjustedattheleav-ingtime,reflectingingeneralthenetchangeinretainedprofitsofthecompany.140Althougharguablylessprecise,theJapaneseapproachismuchsimplerthantheap-proachesinAustraliaandtheUnitedStates.

A MO DEL CO NSO LIDATIO N REGIME?

Thedifferentapproachestothemajorstructuralelementsofconsolidationregimesintheeightcountriesaresummarizedintable1,withthecountriesarrangedfromlefttorightaccordingtotheextentoftheapplicationofthesingleentityconcept(weakesttostrongest).

Theprecedingdiscussionhasindicatedthat,amongtheeightcountries,Australiastandsoutashavingadoptedthestrongestversionofthesingleentityconcept,andthisisborneoutbyitspositionatthefarrightofthetable.UndertheAustralian

135 Theinvestmentadjustmentrules,containedinIRCReg.section1.1502-32,arecomplex,andadetaileddiscussionoftheirapplicationisbeyondthescopeofthisarticle.Formoreinformationabouttherules,see,forexample,Hennesseyetal.,supranote64,chapter13.

136 ThescenariodescribedhereisbasedontheexampleprovidedinIRCReg.section1.1502-32(a)(1).

137 Inparticular,theadjustmentshavetobemade“asofthecloseofeachconsolidatedreturnyear,andasofanyothertime...ifadeterminationatthattimeisnecessarytodetermineataxliabilityofanyperson”:IRCReg.section1.1502-32(b)(1).

138 IRCReg.section1.1502-32(a)(3)(iii).

139 IRCReg.section1.1502-32(c).

140 SeeFumihiroKomamiya,“Japan,”inGroup Taxation,supranote20,393-405,at397;andJapan,MinistryofFinanceTaxBureau,Comprehensive Handbook of Japanese Taxes 2006(Tokyo:MinistryofFinance,2006),at82;andYujiGomiandTasukuHonjo,eds.,2007 Corporation Tax Act of Japan(Tokyo:SozeiShiroyokan,2007),at457-58.

Page 35: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 455

TAB

LE 1

M

ajor

Str

uctu

ral E

lem

ents

of C

onso

lida

tion

Reg

imes

in th

e Ei

ght C

ount

ries

Des

ign

feat

ure

Ital

yFr

ance

Japa

nU

nite

dSt

ates

Spai

nN

ew

Zea

land

Net

herl

ands

Aus

tral

iaM

odel

re

gim

e

Sing

lee

ntity

con

cept

Poo

ling

Poo

ling

Poo

ling

Poo

ling

Poo

ling

Poo

ling

Att

ribu

tion

Abs

orpt

ion

Poo

ling

Ow

ners

hip

requ

irem

ent

Thr

esho

ld<<

100%

≈10

0%≈

100%

<<10

0%<<

100%

≈10

0%≈

100%

≈10

0%≈

100%

Fact

ors

SC+

VR

+

PR

SC+

VR

SCa

VR

+

Val

ueSC

VR

bSC

+P

RSC

VR

and

/or

SCw

ith

prot

ectio

ns

Ele

ctio

nto

con

solid

ate:

re

voca

ble?

No

(3-y

ear

term

)N

o(5

-yea

rte

rm)

No

No

Yes

Yes

Yes

Yes/

No

Inde

cisi

ve

All-

inr

ule

No

No

Yes

Yes

Yes

No

No

Yes/

No

Inde

cisi

ve

Pre

cons

olid

atio

nlo

sses

Qua

rant

ine

Qua

rant

ine

Can

celc

Qua

rant

ine

Qua

rant

ine

Qua

rant

ine

Qua

rant

ine

Tra

nsfe

rQ

uara

ntin

e

Gro

uplo

sses

(on

exit)

Stay

+

optio

nto

al

loca

te

Stay

Allo

cate

Allo

cate

Allo

cate

Stay

Stay

+

optio

nto

al

loca

te

Stay

Inde

cisi

ve

Ass

ets

(exc

epts

hare

s)

On

entr

yR

ollo

ver

Rol

love

rM

ark-

to-

mar

ket

Rol

love

rR

ollo

ver

Rol

love

rR

ollo

ver

Cos

tbas

ere

set

Rol

love

r

Intr

agro

uptr

ansf

erIm

med

iate

ta

xatio

nR

ollo

ver

Rol

love

rR

ollo

ver

Rol

love

rna

(rol

love

rif

taxa

ble

asse

t)

Rol

love

rD

eem

edn

otr

ansf

erR

ollo

ver

(Tab

le1

isc

oncl

uded

on

the

next

pag

e.)

Page 36: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

456 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3TA

BLE

1

Conc

lude

d

Des

ign

feat

ure

Ital

yFr

ance

Japa

nU

nite

dSt

ates

Spai

nN

ew

Zea

land

Net

herl

ands

Aus

tral

iaM

odel

re

gim

e

Ass

ets

(exc

epts

hare

s)(c

ontin

ued)

On

exit

naR

ecap

ture

Rec

aptu

reR

ecap

ture

Rec

aptu

rena

(r

ecap

ture

if

taxa

ble

asse

t)

Rol

love

rdIn

heri

tre

setc

ost

base

Rec

aptu

re

Intr

agro

ups

hare

s

On

entr

yR

ollo

ver

Rol

love

rM

ark-

to-

mar

ket

Rol

love

rR

ollo

ver

Rol

love

rM

ark-

to-

mar

ket

Dee

med

ce

ased

to

exis

t

Rol

love

r

Intr

agro

uptr

ansf

erP

EX

Rol

love

rR

ollo

ver

Rol

love

rR

ollo

ver

na(r

ollo

ver

ifre

venu

eas

set)

PE

XN

ota

xim

plic

atio

nIn

deci

sive

On

exit

PE

XP

EX

Taxa

ble:

ba

sed

on

adju

sted

co

stb

ase

Taxa

ble:

ba

sed

on

adju

sted

co

stb

ase

PE

Xna

(r

ecap

ture

if

reve

nue

asse

t)

PE

XTa

xabl

e:

base

don

re

cons

ti-tu

ted

cost

ba

se

Inde

cisi

ve

<<10

0%=

Sub

stan

tially

less

than

100

%.

≈10

0%=

Sub

stan

tially

100

%.

SC=

Sha

rec

apita

l.V

R=

Vot

ing

righ

ts.

PR

=P

rofit

rig

hts.

PE

X=

Par

ticip

atio

nex

empt

ion.

a P

rote

cted

by

anti-

avoi

danc

epr

ovis

ion.

b P

rote

cted

by

valu

efa

ctor

inc

erta

inc

ircu

mst

ance

s.c

Eff

ectiv

eO

ctob

er1

,201

0,q

uara

ntin

eif

the

join

ing

subs

idia

rys

atis

fies

cert

ain

rest

rict

ive

cond

ition

s.d

Rec

aptu

reif

pre

viou

str

ansf

eris

reg

arde

das

tax-

driv

en.

Page 37: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 457

regime,subsidiariesarenotonlydeemedtohavebecomedivisionsoftheparentcompany,butalsodeemedtohaveceasedtoexistforincometaxpurposes.Multiplelevelsofownership in a corporategroup are collapsed intoone, and intragroupshareholdingsaredeemedtohavevanishedduringconsolidation.Theimplicationsofthesepropositionsaresignificant.Theoriginalcostbasesofunderlyingassetsandsharesinthesubsidiariesareerasedandlostforeveronenteringconsolidation.

TheNetherlandscomessecondwithitsattributionconcept,underwhichassets,liabilities,andactivitiesofsubsidiariesareattributedtotheparentcompany,butthesubsidiaries are still regarded as existing separate entities during consolidation.Amongthesixremainingcountries,allofwhichadoptthepoolingsystem,NewZealandstandsoutwithitsgeneralpolicyofdeterminingthetaxabilityanddeduct-ibilityofvariousitemsforeachindividualgroupmemberonagroupbasis.

Amongtheremainingfivecountries,FranceandItalyallowcherry-pickingofsubsidiariestojoinconsolidation,whicharguablyiscontrarytotheprinciplethatacorporategroupshouldbetreatedasasingleentity.Theythereforerepresentaweakerapplicationoftheconceptthanthatintheotherthreecountries.Italydevi-atessignificantlyfromthesingleentityconceptbyimposingimmediatetaxationonintragroupassettransfersduringconsolidation,andisthereforeregardedashavingtheweakestapplicationoftheconceptamongtheeightcountries.

Theremainingthreecountries—Japan,Spain,andtheUnitedStates—aremoredifficult to rank since theydonotexhibit significantdifferences in theextentoftheirapplicationofthesingleentityconcept.Theirpositionsinthetabletakethefollowingfeaturesintoconsideration:

n Japanhasadoptedtheuniqueapproachofcancellingpreconsolidationlossesofacompanyonentryintoaconsolidatedcorporategroup,whicharguablyisnotsupportedbythesingleentityconcept.

n ForSpainandtheUnitedStates,theonlymajordifferencelieswiththetreat-mentofintragroupshareholdings.SpainreliesonitsgeneralPEXregimetoaddressthedualcostbase issue,whiletheUnitedStatesapplies itsuniqueentity-basedmodel,underwhichthecostbasesofsharesinasubsidiaryareadjustedcontinuouslyduringconsolidation.

Isitpossibletoidentifyamodelconsolidationregimefromtheapproachesofthe eight selected countries?Thediscussion so far suggests that a consolidationregimeisoftentheproductofcompromisesbetweencompetingpolicyobjectivesandconstraints.Nevertheless,itisworthwhiletoattempttoidentifyamodelregimerepresentingthebestpracticeina“cleanslate”scenario.Infact,comparativeanaly-sisoftheeightcountriesrevealsconvergencearoundthebestpracticewithrespecttomanystructuralelements.Apoolingsystemispreferredtootherversionsofthesingleentityconceptintermsofsimplicity.Interactionbetweentheconsolidationregimeandotherpartsoftheincometaxsystemiseasiersincethepoolingsystempreserves,toalargeextent,theseparateidentityofasubsidiary,andthusoperatesundera similar conceptual frameworkas the separateentitydoctrine.Australia’s

Page 38: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

458 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

experiencewithitsasset-basedmodeldemonstratesthatastrongsingleentitycon-ceptcanbeverycomplexandproblematictooperateinpractice.

Thecomparativeanalysisoftheownershiprequirementssuggeststhattheowner-shipthresholdshouldbesubstantially100percent,therebyavoidingthecomplicatingpresenceofminorityinterests.Inrespectofthefactorsintheownershipthreshold,theconceptofcommoncontrolsuggeststhatvotingrightsshouldbeonefactor.Ashareholding requirement without some form of constructive ownership rule issimpletoapplyinpractice,butpronetoabuse.

Withrespecttothetreatmentofpreconsolidationlosses,thequarantineapproachistheapparentpreference.Theirreversibletransferofthelossestotheparentcom-panyinAustraliaprovestobeveryproblematic.ThepotentialrevenueimpactissosubstantialthattheAustraliangovernmenthashadtoadoptanarbitraryregimetolimittheuserateofthetransferredlosses.Theheavyrelianceonmarketvaluationofsubsidiariesandtheconsolidatedgroupnotonlyimplieshighcompliancecostsfortaxpayersandmonitoringcostsfortaxauthorities,butalsoprovidesavoidanceopportunities.Japan’scancellationapproachisharshandhasseverelydiminishedtheattractivenessofitsconsolidationregime.

Therolloverandrecapturepolicy—beingthemostcommonapproachtodealwiththeassetsofajoiningsubsidiary—isthepreferredapproach,presumablybecauseofitssimplicity.Australia’sasset-basedmodelprovidesatax-friendlyenvironmentforcorporategroupsduringconsolidation.However,theproblemsandcomplexityatthetransitiontimes(onentryandonexitofacompany)areahighpricetopay.Italy’seliminationofrollovertreatmentin2008,justfouryearsaftertheintroductionofits consolidationregime, illustrates thedifficultcompromisebetweencompetingobjectives.

Thecomparativeanalysisoftheotherstructuralelementsfailstorevealclearlypreferredapproaches.Theall-inruleisaclassicexampleofthedifficultcompromisebetweencompetingpolicyobjectives.Ontheonehand,theruleshouldbeimple-mentedasananti-avoidancemeasure.Ontheotherhand,somecountriesbelievethatanall-inrulewouldrendertheirconsolidationregimelessattractive.Thede-cisiononwhetherornottoadopttheall-inruledependsontherelativeweightthatpolicymakersplaceontheseobjectives.Thediversetreatmentofgrouplossesonexitillustratesasimilarproblem.

Theapproachtointragroupshareholdingsisperhapsthemostdifficultstruc-turalelement.Theassociateddualcostbaseissuehastroubledpolicymakersfordecades.ThesolutiondependstoalargeextentonwhetheracomprehensivePEXregimeexistsfordomesticcorporategroups.Ifso,theanswerisstraightforward.NewZealand achieves anoutcome similar toparticipation exemption treatmentowingtotheabsenceofageneraltaxationregimeforcapitalgains.OthercountrieswithoutacomprehensivePEXregimedonothavethisluxury.Australia,Japan,andtheUnitedStateshavetoincorporateoftencomplexrulesintotheirconsolidatedregimestodealwiththedualcostbaseissue.Thefactthateachofthethreecoun-trieshasadoptedadifferentapproachtothisissueistelling.

Page 39: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 459

THE COMPLE X IT Y INDE X—COMPA RISO N O F THE EIGHT CO NSO LIDATIO N REGIME S

OneofthemajorconcernsregardingtheintroductionofafullconsolidationregimeinCanadaistheperceivedcomplexityofsucharegime.AustraliaandtheUnitedStatesarethetwoexamplescommonlycitedtosubstantiatethisconcern.However,thecomparativestudyoftheeightcountriessetoutabovesuggeststhataconsolida-tionregimeneednotnecessarilybeascomplexasthoseregimes.Infact,theothersix regimes appear tobemuch simpler than theAustralianand USmodels.Thestudyfurthersuggeststhatthecomplexityofaconsolidationregimedependstoalarge extent on the policy choices that a country makes with respect to the keystructuralelementsoftheregime.

Toillustratetherelativecomplexityoftheeightconsolidationregimes,acom-plexity indexcanbeconstructed,withacomplexityscorebeingassignedtoeachregime.Therankingoftheeightregimesispresentedintable2.Somecriticsmayarguethatthescoreassignedtoaregimeisarbitraryandperhapssubjective.How-ever,itisimportanttobearinmindthattheindexservesprimarilytohighlighttherelativecomplexityoftheeightregimes.Therelativemagnitudeofascoredoesnotimplyaproportionallevelofcomplexity.Forexample,ifaregimehasacomplexityscoreof40,thisdoesnotnecessarilymeanthatitistwiceascomplexasaregimewithascoreof20.Instead,thesetwoscoressimplyindicatethatthefirstregimeismorecomplexthanthesecond.

Thecomplexityscoreofaconsolidationregimeis theoutcomeofa two-stepprocedure.Thefirststepistoidentifythekeystructuralelementsinthedesignofaregimethatsignificantlyaffectitscomplexity.Theseelementsinclude

1. applicationofthesingleentityconcept, 2. thetreatmentofpreconsolidationlosses, 3. thetreatmentofgrouplossesonexit, 4. thetreatmentofassets,and 5. thetreatmentofintragroupshares.

Thesecondstepistoassignascoretoeachofthealternativepolicyoptionsforeachdesign featureorstructuralelement.Themostcomplexpolicyoptionreceivesascoreof10andthesimplestoptionascoreof0.Theoptionwithcomplexity inbetweenthetwoextremeshasascoreof5.Forexample,withrespecttotheapplica-tionofthesingleentityconcept,Australia’sabsorptionmodelhasascoreof10sinceit is the most complex policy option, especially with respect to the complicatedinteractionsbetweentheconsolidationregimeandtheotherpartsofthetaxsystem.Thepoolingsystemadoptedinsixoftheothercountriesisrelativelythesimplestoptionandgetsascoreof0.TheNetherlands’attributionsystemscores5since,intermsofcomplexity,itfallsbetweenthesetwoextremes.

Theresultofthisexerciseispresentedintable2,withtheeightcountriesrankedaccordingtotheiraggregatedcomplexityscores.

Page 40: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

460 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3TA

BLE

2

Com

plex

ity

of C

onso

lida

tion

Reg

imes

in th

e Ei

ght C

ount

ries

Des

ign

feat

ure

New

Zea

land

Fran

ceIt

aly

Japa

nN

ethe

rlan

dsSp

ain

Uni

ted

Stat

esA

ustr

alia

Sing

lee

ntity

co

ncep

t0

00

05

(att

ribu

tion)

00

10(a

bsor

ptio

n)

Pre

cons

olid

atio

nlo

sses

00

00

5(q

uara

ntin

e+

of

fset

aft

er

aggr

egat

ion)

5(q

uara

ntin

e+

of

fset

aft

er

aggr

egat

ion)

5(q

uara

ntin

e+

of

fset

aft

er

aggr

egat

ion)

10(t

rans

fer

to

pare

nt)

Gro

uplo

sses

on

exi

t0

05

(sta

y+

opt

ion

toa

lloca

te)

10(a

lloca

te)

5(s

tay+

opt

ion

toa

lloca

te)

10(a

lloca

te)

10(a

lloca

te)

0

Ass

ets

05

(rol

love

ran

dre

capt

ure)

5(r

ollo

ver

and

reca

ptur

e)

5(r

ollo

ver

and

reca

ptur

e)

05

(rol

love

ran

dre

capt

ure)

5(r

ollo

ver

and

reca

ptur

e)

10(r

eset

cos

tba

ses)

Intr

agro

ups

hare

s0

00

00

010

(ent

ity-b

ased

m

odel

)

10(r

econ

stitu

ted

cost

bas

es)

Com

plex

ityin

dex

05

1015

1520

3040

Page 41: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

key design issues under a full consolidation system n 461

Thetableshowsthatonthebasisoftherespectivescores,theAustralianandUSregimes are the most complex. This is consistent with the common perception.NewZealandscoresaperfect0,suggestingthatitisthesimplestregimeamongtheeightcountries.However,oneimportantqualification,notedpreviously,isthatNewZealandenjoystherareluxuryoftheabsenceofageneraltaxoncapitalgains.Thisparticularfeatureofitstaxsystemremovesmostofthepressureonitspolicieswithrespecttothetreatmentofassetsandintragroupshares.

CO NCLUSIO N

Thechoicebetweenasystemoffullconsolidationandagrouplossreliefregimeisadifficultone.Itoftenrepresentsatradeoffbetweenconflictingpolicyobjectivesaswellasconstraintsimposedbytheexistingtaxsystem.Nevertheless,Canadashouldconsideraconsolidationregimeforthefollowingreasons:

n First,aconsolidationregimeismorecomprehensivethanothergrouptaxationregimes,allowingbothintragrouplossoffsetsandintragroupassettransfers.

n Second, intragrouptransactionsotherthanassettransfersaregenerally ig-noredwithinaconsolidatedgroup,afeaturethatcanconstraininterprovincialincome-shiftingopportunitiesbetweenconsolidatedgroupmembers.

n Third,althoughaconsolidationregimetendstobemorecomplexthanothergrouptaxationregimes,thefactthatanincreasingnumberofcountrieshaveadoptedconsolidationinrecentyearssuggeststhatmanygovernmentspreferthistypeofregimeoverothergrouptaxationregimes,andthattheybelievethatthecomplexityinvolvedisjustified.

n Fourth,somecountriesthatalreadyhadothergrouptaxationregimeshavedecidedtointroduceaconsolidationregime.

n Finally,asystemoffullconsolidationmayprovideanelegantsolutiontothetroublesomeissueofinterprovincialallocationofthecorporategrouptaxbase.

Thecomparativeanalysissuggeststhatastrongerapplicationofthesingleentityconcept inaconsolidationregimedoesnotnecessarily implyabetterregimeonpolicy grounds. Australia has adopted the world’s first asset-based model, whichrepresentsthestrongestapplicationofthesingleentityconceptamongtheeightcountries.Itssingleentityruledictatesthefictionthat,afterconsolidation,onlyonecompany remains—the parent company. Australia’s consolidation regime offerssomedistinctattractions,includingtheabilitytocompletelyignoreintragroupassettransferswithinaconsolidatedgroup.However,thepricetopayfortheadvantagesishigh,especiallyatthetransitionpointswhenacompanyentersorexitsthecon-solidatedgroup.TheTCSrulesarecomplexandcangenerateartificialgainorloss,whichcanevenbeduplicatedatthetimeacompanyleavesthegroup.Therulesonpreconsolidationlossescanalsoproducearbitraryandanomalousresults.Bothsetsofrulesrelyheavilyonmarketvaluationsofassetsandcompanies,implyinghighcomplianceandpolicingcosts,andcreatingavoidanceopportunities.Anotherproblem

Page 42: The Unthinkable Policy Option? Key Design Issues Under a

462 n canadian tax journal / revue fiscale canadienne (2011) 59:3

withthestrongapplicationofthesingleentityconceptisthedifficultinteractionbetweentheconsolidationregimeandotherpartsoftheincometaxsystem.Mostregimesinthetaxlawaredesignedtooperateunderthetraditionalseparateentitydoctrine,whichbydefinitioncontradictsthesingleentityconcept.Experiencesug-geststhatthestrongertheapplicationofthesingleentityconcept,themoredifficulttheinteractionstendtobe.

Foramajorityofthekeystructuralelementsofaconsolidationregime,thecom-parativeanalysispointsquiteclearlytoapredominantpolicyoptionintheeightcountries.ThepoolingsystemisadoptedinalloftheeightcountriesexceptAustraliaand the Netherlands. Preconsolidation losses are quarantined in all of the eightcountriesexceptAustraliaandJapan.AlloftheeightcountriesexceptAustraliaandItalyadopttherolloverandrecapturepolicyforassetsonentryandexit,andforintragroupasset transfers.Thecomparativeanalysis suggests that theownershipthresholdshouldbesubstantially100percentinordertoavoidminorityinterestproblems.

Fortheotherkeystructuralelements,theeightcountriesexhibitconsiderablevariationsandrevealnoclearpreferreddesignchoice.Theall-inruleandthetreat-mentofgrouplossesonexitareexamplesofthedifficultcompromisesthatpolicymakers have to make. The approach to intragroup shareholdings is perhaps themostdifficultchoice.Itdepends,toalargeextent,onthepresence(orabsence)ofageneralPEXregimedealingwiththedualcostbaseissue.

Experiencesuggeststhatonceaconsolidationregimeisintroduced,majorstruc-turalchangesareunlikely.Businessesenjoythebenefitsofintragrouplossoffsetsandtax-freeassettransfersundertheconsolidationregime.Repealoftheregimeisthereforelikelytobepoliticallyunacceptable.Fine-tuningisoftentheonlyfeasibleapproachinpractice.Therefore,itisimportantforCanada,ifitdecidestointro-duceaconsolidationregime,togetthelegislationrightwhenitisfirstintroduced.Thecomparativeanalysisoftheeightconsolidationregimespresentedinthisarticleattemptstoshedsomelightonthestructuraldesignchoices.