the triumph of monetarism

13
The Triumph of Monetarism?  J. Bradford De Long T he story of 20th century macroeconomics begins with Irving Fisher. In his books Appreciation and Interest (1896), The Rate of Interest (1907), and The Purchasing Power of Money (1911), Fisher fueled the intellectual re that became known as monetarism. To understand the determination of prices and interest rates and the course of the business cycle, monetarism holds, look rst (and often last) at the stock of money—at the quantities in the economy of those assets that constitute readily spendable purchasing power. Twentieth century macroeconomics ends with the community of macroecono- mists split across two groups, pursuing two research programs. The New Classical research program walks in the footprints of Joseph Schumpeter’s Business Cycles (1939), holding that the key to the business cycle is the stochastic character of economic growth. It argues that the “cycle” should be analyzed with the same models used to understand the “trend” (Kydland and Prescott, 1982; McCallum, 1989; Campbell, 1994). The compet ing New Ke yne sian research program is harder to summar ize quickly. But surely its key ideas include the following ve propositions: 1) The frictions that prevent rapid and instantaneous price adjustment to nominal shocks are the key cause of business cycle uctuations in employment and output. 2) Under normal circumstances, monetary policy is a more potent and useful tool for stabilization than is scal policy. y  J. Bradford De Long is Professor of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, Califor- nia, and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massa- chu setts. His e- mai l add res s is [email protected]  and hi s we b- page is  http:// econ161.berkeley.edu/ .  Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 14, Number 1—Winter 2000—Pages 83–94 

Upload: daniel-lipara

Post on 07-Apr-2018

220 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 1/12

The Triumph of Monetarism?

 J. Bradford De Long

The story of 20th century macroeconomics begins with Irving Fisher. In his

books Appreciation and Interest  (1896), The Rate of Interest  (1907), and The 

Purchasing Power of Money  (1911), Fisher fueled the intellectual fire that 

became known as monetarism. To understand the determination of prices and

interest rates and the course of the business cycle, monetarism holds, look first (and

often last) at the stock of money—at the quantities in the economy of those assetsthat constitute readily spendable purchasing power.

Twentieth century macroeconomics ends with the community of macroecono-

mists split across two groups, pursuing two research programs. The New Classical

research program walks in the footprints of Joseph Schumpeter’s Business Cycles 

(1939), holding that the key to the business cycle is the stochastic character of 

economic growth. It argues that the “cycle” should be analyzed with the same

models used to understand the “trend” (Kydland and Prescott, 1982; McCallum,

1989; Campbell, 1994).

The competing New Keynesian research program is harder to summarize

quickly. But surely its key ideas include the following five propositions:1) The frictions that prevent rapid and instantaneous price adjustment to

nominal shocks are the key cause of business cycle fluctuations in employment and

output.

2) Under normal circumstances, monetary policy is a more potent and useful

tool for stabilization than is fiscal policy.

y  J. Bradford De Long is Professor of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, Califor- 

nia, and Research Associate, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massa- 

chusetts. His e-mail address is [email protected] 

and his web-page is 

http:// econ161.berkeley.edu/ .

  Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 14, Number 1—Winter 2000—Pages 83–94 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 2/12

3) Business cycle fluctuations in production are best analyzed from a starting

point that sees them as fluctuations around the sustainable long-run trend (rather

than as declines below some level of potential output).

4) The right way to analyze macroeconomic policy is to consider the implica-tions for the economy of a policy  rule , not to analyze each one- or two-year episode

in isolation as requiring a unique and idiosyncratic policy response.

5) Any sound approach to stabilization policy must recognize the limits of 

stabilization policy, including the long lags and low multipliers associated with fiscal

policy and the long and variable lags and uncertain magnitude of the effects of 

monetary policy.

Many of today’s New Keynesian economists will dissent from at least one of 

these five planks. (I, for example, still cling to the belief—albeit without much

supporting empirical evidence—that policy is as much gap-closing as stabilizationpolicy.) But few will deny that these five planks structure how the New Keynesian

 wing of macroeconomics thinks about important macroeconomic issues. Moreover,

few will deny that today the New Classical and New Keynesian research programs

dominate the available space.

But what has happened to monetarism at the end of the 20th century?

Monetarism achieved its moment of apogee with both intellectual and policy 

triumph in the late 1970s. Its intellectual triumph came as the NAIRU grew very 

large and the multiplier grew very small in both journals and textbooks. Its policy 

triumph came as both the Bank of England and the Federal Reserve declared in the

late 1970s that henceforth monetary policy would be made not by targeting interest rates but by targeting quantitative measures of the aggregate money stock.1 But 

today monetarism seems reduced from a broad current to a few eddies.

 What has happened to the ideas and the current of thought that developed out 

of the original insights of Irving Fisher and his peers?

The short answer is that much of this current of thought is still there, but its

insights pass under another name. All five of the planks of the New Keynesian

research program listed above had much of their development inside the 20th

century monetarist tradition, and all are associated with the name of Milton

Friedman. It is hard to find prominent Keynesian analysts in the 1950s, 1960s, or

early 1970s who gave these five planks as much prominence in their work as MiltonFriedman did in his.

For example, the importance of analyzing policy in an explicit, stochastic

context and the limits on stabilization policy that result comes from Friedman

(1953a). The importance of thinking not just about what policy would be best in

response to this particular shock but what policy rule would be best in general—and

  would be robust to economists’ errors in understanding the structure of the

1 For the process by which monetarism achieved political influence in Britain, see Peter Hall (1986). For

the process by which the Federal Reserve decided (temporarily) to target the money stock, see Volckerand Gyohten (1992).

84 Journal of Economic Perspectives 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 3/12

economy and policymakers’ errors in implementing policy—comes from Friedman

(1960). The proposition that the most policy can aim for is stabilization rather than

gap-closing was the principal message of Friedman (1968). We recognize the power

of monetary policy as a result of the lines of research that developed from Friedmanand Schwartz (1963) and Friedman and Meiselman (1963). Finally, a large chunk

of the way that New Keynesians think about aggregate supply saw its development 

in Friedman’s discussions of the “missing equation” in Gordon (1974).

Thus a look back at the intellectual battle lines between “Keynesians” and

“monetarists” in the 1960s cannot help but be followed by the recognition that 

perhaps New Keynesian economics is misnamed. We may not all be Keynesians

now, but the influence of monetarism on how we all think about macroeconomics

today has been deep, pervasive, and subtle.

 Why then do we today talk much more about the “New Keynesian” economiststhan about the “New Monetarist” economists? I believe that to answer this question

 we need to look at the history of monetarism over the 20th century. One fruitful

 way to look at the history of monetarism is to distinguish between four different 

 variants or subspecies of monetarism that emerged and for a time flourished in the

century just past: First Monetarism, Old Chicago Monetarism, High Monetarism,

and Political Monetarism.

First Monetarism

The First Monetarism is Irving Fisher’s monetarism. The ideas of Fisher, hispeers, and their pupils make up the first subspecies. It is true that the ideas that we

see as necessarily producing the quantity theory of money go back to David Hume,

if not before. But the equation-of-exchange and the transformation of the quantity 

theory of money into a tool for making quantitative analyses and predictions of the

price level, inflation, and interest rates was the creation of Irving Fisher.

This first subspecies of monetarism, however, fell down on the question of 

understanding business cycle fluctuations in employment and output. The business

cycle analysis of some of the practitioners of this first subspecies of monetarism was

subtle and sophisticated. Irving Fisher’s (1933) “The Debt-Deflation Theory 

of Great Depressions” can still be read with profit. But the business cycle theory  of 

this first subspecies of monetarism was by and large not as subtle, and not as

sophisticated.

Other economists became exasperated with monetarist analyses of events

made by their colleagues in the immediate aftermath of World War I. This exas-

peration led one of the very best of this first subspecies of monetarists—John

Maynard Keynes, Mark I—to declare in his Tract on Monetary Reform (1923) that the

standard quantity-theoretic analyses were completely useless:

Now ‘in the long run’ this [way of summarizing the quantity theory: that adoubling of the money stock doubles the price level] is probably true. . . . But 

  J. Bradford De Long 85 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 4/12

this long run is a misleading guide to current affairs. In the long run we are all 

dead. Economists set themselves too easy, too useless a task if in tempestuous

seasons they can only tell us that when the storm is long past the ocean is flat 

again.

Indeed, John Maynard Keynes’s exasperation with the way that the First Monetar-

ism was used by economists in works like, say, Lionel Robbins’s (1934) The Great 

 Depression led him on the intellectual journey that ended with the non-monetarist 

  John Maynard Keynes, Mark II, and The General Theory of Employment, Interest and 

Money.

Most economists would agree with Keynes’s evaluation of First Monetarism.

Milton Friedman certainly does. In his 1956 “The Quantity Theory of Money—A 

Restatement,” Friedman sets out that one of his principal goals is to rescuemonetarism from the “atrophied and rigid caricature” of an economic theory that 

it had become in the interwar period at the hands of economists such as Robbins

and Joseph Schumpeter (1934), who argued that monetary and fiscal policies were

bound to be ineffective—counterproductive in fact—in fighting recessions and

depressions because they could not create true prosperity, but only a false pros-

perity that would contain the seeds of a still longer and deeper future depression.

 According to Friedman, the inadequacies of this framework opened the way 

for the original Keynesian Revolution. The atrophied and rigid caricature of the

quantity theory painted a “dismal picture.” By contrast, “Keynes’s interpretation of 

the depression and of the right policy to cure it must have come like a flash of light on a dark night” (Friedman, 1972). Keynes’s General Theory  may not have had a

correct theory of business cycle fluctuations in employment and output, but it least 

it had a theory, and a theory that did not dismiss all macroeconomic policies as

pointless in seeking to affect business cycles.

Old Chicago Monetarism

Slightly later but somewhat alongside this first subspecies of First Monetarism

came what Friedman always called the Chicago School oral tradition: the OldChicago Monetarism of Viner, Simons, and Knight. In economic theory, this school

stressed the variability of velocity and its potential correlation with the rate of 

inflation. In economic policy, they blamed monetary forces that caused deflation as

the source of depression. It was monetary and fiscal policies that, as Viner (1933)

 wrote, had “permitt[ed] banks to fail and the quantity of deposits to decline” that 

 were at the root of America’s macroeconomic policies in the Great Depression. To

cure the depression they called for massive stimulative monetary expansion and

large government deficits, or at least for policies to make sure that any deflation

that took place was balanced.The debate over whether Old Chicago Monetarism was properly a theory  has

86 Journal of Economic Perspectives 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 5/12

gone on intermittently for 30 years. Don Patinkin (1969, 1972) and Harry Johnson

(1971) denied that this Chicago School oral tradition existed. They saw a set of 

macroeconomic policies advocated by Simons, Knight, Viner, and company that 

made sense, but that were ad hoc, free-floating, and at best tenuously connected with their underlying monetary theory . In Patinkin and Johnson’s view, Old Chicago

Monetarism was a retrospective construction by Milton Friedman (1956). In their

 view, Friedman used “Keynesian” tools and insights to provide a retrospective post 

hoc theoretical justification for policy recommendations that had little explicit 

theoretical base at the time, and to construct for himself some intellectual

antecedents.

 You can side with Patinkin and Johnson and dismiss Old Chicago Monetarism

as too amorphous and vague to be called a theory or a school. Alternatively, you can

side with Friedman and supporters like Tavlas (1997), and call Old ChicagoMonetarism a theory—even if only an implicit theory, a theory never written down

anywhere, an “oral tradition.” You can then go on to say, with Friedman (1972),

that it was this oral tradition that made possible the kind of macroeconomic analysis

found in Viner (1933): a “subtle and relevant version . . . of the quantity theory . . .

a flexible and sensitive tool for interpreting movements in aggregate economic

activity and for developing relevant policy prescriptions.”

 You can note that Friedman does not disagree with Patinkin that Old Chicago

Monetarism needed further development. Friedman did write that: “after all, I am

not unwilling to accept some credit for the theoretical analysis” found in “The

Quantity Theory—A Restatement” and used by all the others who contributed tothe landmark Studies in the Quantity Theory of Money. Or you can recognize that it 

all depends on what you mean by a “theory” or a “tradition,” and what you

understand to be the dividing line between theoretically-based and ad hoc policy 

recommendations.

In my view there is nothing of substance at stake in such debates.

But it is important to note, as George Tavlas (1997) points out, that Old

Chicago Monetarism did not believe that the velocity of money was stable and did

not believe that control of the money supply was straightforward and easy. It did not 

believe that the velocity of money was stable because inflation lowered and defla-

tion raised the opportunity cost of holding real balances. The phase of the businesscycle and the concomitant general price level movements powerfully affected

incentives: economic actors had strong incentives to economize on money holdings

during times of boom and inflation, and to hoard money balances during times of 

recession and deflation. These swings in velocity amplified the effects of monetary 

shocks on total nominal spending.2 It did not believe that controlling the money 

supply was easy because fractional-reserve banking in the absence of deposit 

insurance created the instability-generating possibility of bank runs. The fear by 

2

Friedman (1974, section 8) spends much time trying to capture this insight in a simple monetary theory of nominal income. Yet communication with his critics is not achieved.

The Triumph of Monetarism? 87 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 6/12

banks that they might be caught illiquid could cause substantial swings in the ratio

of deposits to reserves. The fear by deposit holders that their bank might be caught 

illiquid could cause substantial swings in the deposit-currency ratio. Together, these

two ratios determined the money multiplier.Thus, the overall level of the money supply was determined as much by these

two unstable ratios as by the stock of high-powered money itself. And the stock of 

high-powered money was the only thing that the central bank could quickly and

reliably control.3

Classic Monetarism

Monetarism subspecies three, Classic Monetarism, either emerged as a naturalevolution of Old Chicago Monetarism or sprung full-grown like Athena from the

brains of the Chicago School after World War II. Classic Monetarism as laid out in

Friedman’s classic Essays in Positive Economics  (1953b), Studies in the Quantity Theory 

of Money (1956), A Program for Monetary Stability (1960), and “The Role of Monetary 

Policy” (1968), as well as in works by many others like Brunner (1968), or Brunner

and Meltzer (1972), contained strands of thought that have proven remarkably 

durable.

Classic Monetarism contained empirical demonstrations of many points: that 

money demand functions could retain remarkable amounts of stability under the

most extreme hyperinflationary conditions (as in Cagan, 1956); analyses of thelimits imposed on stabilization policy by the uncertain strength and lags of policy 

instruments (Friedman, 1953a); a stress on the importance of policy rules and of 

rules that would be robust (Friedman, 1960); the belief that the natural rate of 

unemployment is inevitably close to the average rate of unemployment (Friedman,

1968); the potency of monetary policy over time (Friedman and Schwartz, 1963);

and demonstrations of the short-run power of monetary policy (Brunner and

Meltzer, 1963; Anderson and Jordan, 1970; Goodhart, 1970). Classic monetarism

 was also the start of the process that has cut the multiplier down from the value of 

four or five that it possessed in economists’ minds in 1947 to the value of maybe one

that it possesses in economists’ minds today (Friedman, 1957).These elements and conclusions of the Classic Monetarist research program

have endured. They make up much of what the New Keynesian wing of macroeco-

nomics believes today.

But these strands of Classic Monetarism were not the whole. There were two

other strands as well.

The first such strand has not fared very well. It is best seen as an attempt to

3 Indeed, in Friedman and Schwartz (1963) and Cagan (1965), it is clear that changes in the money 

stock are as often driven by changes in the deposit-currency and deposit-reserve ratios as by changes inthe monetary base.

88 Journal of Economic Perspectives 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 7/12

eliminate the sources of macroeconomic instability identified by Old ChicagoMonetarism. The worry that control of the monetary base was insufficient to control

the money stock was to be dealt with, in Friedman’s (1960) Program for Monetary 

Stability, by reforming the banking system to eliminate every possibility of fluctua-

tions in the money multiplier. Shifts in the deposit-reserve and deposit-currency 

ratios would be eliminated by requiring 100 percent reserve banking. Shifts in the

deposit-reserve ratio then become illegal. Banks can never be caught illiquid. In the

absence of any possibility that banks will be caught illiquid, there is no reason for

there to be any shifts in the deposit-currency ratio either.

In addition, shifts in the velocity of money in response to cyclical bursts of 

inflation and deflation that amplified fluctuations in the rate of growth of themoney stock would be eliminated by a rule requiring a constant rate of growth for

the nominal money stock. Without cyclical fluctuations in the money stock and in

inflation, there would be no cause of cyclical fluctuations in the velocity of money.

Thus, reform of the banking system and Federal Reserve practices would eliminate

the monetary causes of the business cycle.

This component of Classic Monetarism—the program for monetary stability—

has not flourished over the past half century. The tide, instead, has flowed in the

direction of the deregulation of the financial sector, not in the more intensive

regulation that would be required to enforce 100 percent reserve banking and astrict separation between investments and transactions deposits. The sharp swings

 Figure 1

 Velocity of Money (M1)

  J. Bradford De Long 89 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 8/12

in the velocity of money in the 1980s, as shown in Figure 1, led not to a renewed

commitment to stable inflation and money growth to eliminate such swings, but 

instead to a distrust by central bankers of monetary aggregates as indicators. There

are few live remnants of the program to control the sources of monetary instability 

identified by Old Chicago Monetarism.

The second additional strand of Classic Monetarism has fared better within the

intellectual ecology. At some point in the first post-World War II generation, the

Chicago School developed a strong fear and distaste for the state.4 The monetarist 

policy recommendations of a stable growth rate for nominal money and a con-

strained, automatic central bank were then seen as having an added bonus: they 

 were tools to advance the libertarian goal of the shrinkage of the state. After all, a

central bank not constrained by the constant nominal money growth rate rule can

get itself into all kinds of mischief. It could use the inflation tax to gain commandover goods and services. It could try to stimulate aggregate demand and manipulate

the business cycle in order to create a favorable economic climate at election time.

From the viewpoint of Classic Monetarism, there were two reasons to fear

unconstrained policy formulated by politically chosen central bankers: it could fail,

or it could succeed. It could fail in the sense that central bankers appointed by 

politicians without concern for their competence could advance destructive eco-

nomic policies. It could succeed in the sense that it could pursue policies that were

in interests of the government, or the bureaucrats, or of a political party—but not 

in the public interest. A large chunk of this strand of monetarism shapes macro-economists’ thoughts today, mostly as transmitted through Kydland and Prescott 

(1977).

Classic Monetarism, shorn of its program for monetary stability, became intel-

lectually very powerful in the 1970s. Increased awareness of the difficulties of 

passing fiscal policy legislation in the United States and the leakages that dimin-

ished the multiplier shifted the balance of opinion in the direction of attributing

relatively greater force to monetary policy. The Volcker disinflation left few in

doubt that central banks had and could rapidly use their powerful levers to control

nominal spending. Finally, Classic Monetarism rose to its peak of intellectual

influence as Milton Friedman’s and Edward Phelps’s prediction that the stable

short-run Phillips curve would break down was made just in time to be proven

spectacularly correct by the economic history of the 1970s.

4 The Chicago school did not always possess this distaste for the state. For the midwestern-populist founding generation of the Chicago School, the government was a tool to help control private

monopoly power. To see how rapidly and completely libertarian ideas took hold and grew, see Kitch(1983).

90 Journal of Economic Perspectives 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 9/12

Political Monetarism

The multi-stranded complex of doctrines and ideas that was Classic Monetar-

ism—with its institutional reform side, its analytical side, and its political economy 

side—was not the monetarism that became a powerful political doctrine in the

1970s. Political Monetarism was something different.

Political Monetarism argued not that velocity could be made stable if 

monetary shocks were avoided, but that velocity  was  stable. Thus, the money 

stock became a sufficient statistic for forecasting nominal demand, and central

bankers could close their eyes to all economic statistics save monetary aggre-

gates alone. Political Monetarism argued not that institutional reforms were

needed to give the central bank the power to control the money supply tightly,

but that the central bank already did control shifts in the money supply. Thecentral bank was the source of all monetary forces, either in its actions or in its

failure to neutralize private actions. Everything that went wrong in the macro-

economy had a single, simple cause: the central bank had failed to make the

money supply grow at the appropriate rate.

Political Monetarism expresses skepticism about the potential for non-

monetary shocks to spending to affect output significantly: the major effect of 

a fiscal stimulus is “to make interest rates higher than they would otherwise be,”

not to boost nominal demand—unless the fiscal stimulus is “financed by print-

ing money.” Political Monetarism is at least somewhat skeptical of the depen-

dence of the velocity of money on interest rates: lower interest rates “make it lessexpensive for people to hold cash. Hence, some of the funds . . . may be added

to idle cash balances rather than spent or loaned” (Friedman, 1974, pp. 139-40).

Political Monetarism concludes that any policy that does not affect “the quantity 

of money and its rate of growth” simply cannot “have a significant impact on the

economy.”

 When theories and doctrines become political and policy weapons, they are

typically stripped down to a core that includes substantial proportions of mis-

representation and overstatement. From today’s perspective, it is clear that the

stripping-down that created Political Monetarism was unfortunate. For what 

many economists now believe to be truly valuable about the work done by theClassic Monetarist tradition was deemphasized, while the elements that were

emphasized—the sufficiency of money growth as an indicator of demand, the

stability of velocity, the assumption that it was easy and straightforward for the

central bank to find and control the most relevant measure of the money 

stock—are the elements that turned out to be empirically false in the 1980s and

1990s. Perhaps they would have proven true had the Classic Monetarist program

for monetary stability been implemented. But that world of no slippage between

the monetary base and nominal income—no slippage between the monetary 

base and the money stock, and no slippage in velocity—was not the world that  we turned out to live in.

The Triumph of Monetarism? 91

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 10/12

Hence, Political Monetarism crashed and burned in the 1980s. The elision of 

the difficulties in controlling the money stock from the monetary base created a

great hostage to fortune. Charles Goodhart’s law made itself felt: whatever mone-

tary aggregate was being targeted by a central bank turned out to be the one withthe lowest correlation with nominal income. Controlling the particular money 

supply that was relevant for total spending turned out to be very difficult indeed.

The claim that only policies that affected the money stock could affect nominal

demand proved even more unfortunate, for the velocity of money turned unstable

in the 1980s, but not in any manner simply correlated with the rate of money 

growth.

But even as monetarism subspecies four was failing its empirical test, large

elements of monetarism subspecies three—Classic Monetarism—were achieving

their intellectual hegemony. For under normal circumstances, monetary policy is infact a more potent and useful tool for stabilization than is fiscal policy. The frictions

that give slope to the expectational aggregate supply curve are in fact key causes of 

business cycle fluctuations. The natural rate of unemployment hypothesis has

strong empirical support in U.S. data, and does mean that fluctuations are best 

analyzed as being about trend rather than being beneath potential. It is better, in

fact, to analyze macroeconomic policy by considering the long-run implications of 

rules. Finally, any sound view of stabilization policy must recognize how limited are

its possibilities for success.

These insights survive, albeit under a different name than “monetarism.”

Perhaps the extent to which they are simply part of the air that modern macro-economists today believe is a good index of their intellectual hegemony.

y I would like to thank the National Science Foundation for financial support, and Robert 

Barsky, Alan Krueger, Paul Krugman, Timothy Taylor, David Romer, and Robert Wald- 

mann for helpful comments and discussions.

References

  Anderson, Leonall and Jerry Jordan. 1970.“Monetary and Fiscal Actions: A Test of Their

Relative Importance in Economic Stabilization.”  Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Monthly Review.

 April, 52:4, pp. 7-25.Brunner, Karl. 1968. “The Role of Money and

Monetary Policy.” Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Monthly Review . July, 50:7, pp. 8-24.

Brunner, Karl and Alan Meltzer. 1963. “Pre-dicting Velocity.” Journal of Finance. May, pp.

319-34.Brunner, Karl and Alan Meltzer. 1972. “Fried-

man’s Monetary Theory.” Journal of Political Econ- 

omy . Reprinted in Robert J. Gordon, ed., 1974.

Milton Friedman’s Monetary Framework: A Debate with His Critics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

92 Journal of Economic Perspectives 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 11/12

Cagan, Philip. 1956. “The Monetary Dynamicsof Hyperinflation,” in Studies in the Quantity The- 

ory of Money . Friedman, Milton, ed. Chicago: Uni- versity of Chicago Press.

Cagan, Philip. 1965. Determinants and Effects of  

Changes in the Stock of Money, 1875-1960. New York: Columbia University Press.

Campbell, John. 1994. “Inspecting the Mech-anism: An Analytical Approach to the StochasticGrowth Model.” Journal of Monetary Economics. 33,pp. 463-506.

Fisher, Irving. 1896. Appreciation and Interest.

New York: Macmillan.

Fisher, Irving. 1907. The Rate of Interest. New York: Macmillan.

Fisher, Irving. 1911. The Purchasing Power of   

Money. New York: Macmillan.Fisher, Irving. 1933. “The Debt-Deflation The-

ory of Great Depressions.” Econometrica, 1.Friedman, Milton. 1948. “A Monetary and

Fiscal Framework for Economic Stability.”American Economic Review. June, 38:2, pp. 245-64. Reprinted in Essays on Positive Economics.

Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 1953,pp. 133-56.

Friedman, Milton. 1953a. “The Effects of aFull-Employment Policy on Economic Stability:

 A Formal Analysis,” in Essays on Positive Econom- 

ics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press: 1953,pp. 117-32.Friedman, Milton. 1953b, Essays on Positive Eco- 

nomics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Friedman, Milton. 1956. “The Quantity The-

ory of Money—A Restatement,” in Studies in the 

Quantity Theory of Money. Chicago: University of Chicago Press:, pp. 3-21.

Friedman, Milton. 1957. A Theory of the Con- 

sumption Function. Princeton: Princeton Univer-sity Press.

Friedman, Milton. 1960. A Program for Mon- 

etary Stability. New York: Fordham University 

Press.Friedman, Milton. 1968. “The Role of Mone-

tary Policy.” American Economic Review. March,58:1, pp. 1-17.

Friedman, Milton. 1970. “A TheoreticalFramework for Monetary Analysis.” Journal of Po- 

litical Economy. April, 78:2, pp. 193-238.Friedman, Milton. 1971a. “A Monetary Theory 

of Nominal Income.” Journal of Political Economy.

 April, 79:2, pp. 323-37.Friedman, Milton. 1971b. A Theoretical Frame- 

work for Monetary Analysis, New York: NBER Oc-

casional Paper 112. Reprinted in Robert J. Gor-don, ed., 1974. Milton Friedman’s Monetary 

 Framework: A Debate with His Critics. Chicago: Uni-

 versity of Chicago Press, pp. 1-61.

Friedman, Milton. 1972. “Comments on the

Critics.” Journal of Political Economy . Reprinted in

Robert J. Gordon, ed., 1974. Milton Friedman’s 

Monetary Framework: A Debate with His Critics. Chi-

cago: University of Chicago Press.

Friedman, Milton and David Meiselman. 1963.

“The Relative Stability of Monetary Velocity and

the Investment Multiplier in the United States,

1897-1958,” in Stabilization Policies. Englewood

Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.

Friedman, Milton and Anna J. Schwartz. 1963.

A Monetary History of the United States. Princeton:

Princeton University Press.

Goodhart, Charles. 1970. “The Importance of 

Money.” Quarterly Bulletin of the Bank of England.

 June, pp. 159-98.

Gordon, Robert J., ed. 1974. Milton Friedman’s 

Monetary Framework: A Debate with His Critics. Chi-

cago: University of Chicago Press.

Hall, Peter. 1986. Governing the Economy . Cam-

bridge: Harvard University Press.

 Johnson, Harry. 1971. “The Keynesian Revo-

lution and the Monetarist Counterrevolution.”

American Economic Review. May, 61, pp. 1-14.

Keynes, John Maynard. 1923. A Tract on Mon- 

etary Reform. London: Macmillan.

Keynes, John Maynard. 1936. The General The- ory of Employment, Interest, and Money. London:

Macmillan.

Kitch, Edmund W. ed. 1983. “The Fire of 

Truth: A Remembrance of Law and Economics

at Chicago, 1932-1970.” Journal of Law and Eco- 

nomic s.

Kydland, Finn and Edward Prescott. 1977.

“Rules Rather Than Discretion: The Inconsis-

tency of Optimal Plans” Journal of Political Econ- 

omy. June, 87:3, pp. 473-92.

Kydland, Finn and Edward Prescott. 1982.

“Time to Build and Aggregate Fluctuations.” Econometrica. November, 50, pp. 1345-1370.

McCallum, Bennett. 1989. “Real Business Cy-

cle Models,” in Modern Business Cycle Theory .

Barro, Robert, ed. Cambridge: Harvard Univer-

sity Press, pp. 16-50.

Patinkin, Don. 1969. “The Chicago Tradition,

the Quantity Theory, and Friedman.” Journal of  

Money, Credit, and Banking. February, 1:1, pp.

46-70.

Patinkin, Don. 1972. “Friedman on the Quan-

tity Theory and Keynesian Economics.” Journal of  

Political Economy . Reprinted in Robert J. Gordon,ed., 1974. Milton Friedman’s Monetary Framework: 

  J. Bradford De Long 93 

8/3/2019 The Triumph of Monetarism

http://slidepdf.com/reader/full/the-triumph-of-monetarism 12/12

A Debate with His Critics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

Robbins, Lionel. 1934. The Great Depression.

London: Macmillan.Schumpeter, Joseph. 1939. Business Cycles.

New York: McGraw-Hill.Schumpeter, Joseph. 1934. “Depressions,” in

  Economics of the Recovery Program . Brown, Doug-lass, et al. New York: McGraw-Hill.

Tavlas, George. 1998. “Retrospectives: Wasthe Monetarist Tradition Invented?” Journal of   

  Economic Perspectives. Fall, 12:4, pp. 211-22.

Tobin, James. 1972. “Friedman’s TheoreticalFramework.” Journal of Political Economy . Re-printed in Robert J. Gordon, ed., 1974. Milton 

 Friedman’s Monetary Framework: A Debate with His 

Critics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.  Viner, Jacob. 1933. Balanced Deflation, Infla- 

tion, or More Depression. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.

 Volcker, Paul and Toyoo Gyohten, with Law-

rence Malkin, ed. 1992. Changing Fortunes: The 

World’s Money and the Threat to American Leader- 

ship. New York: Random House.

94 Journal of Economic Perspectives