the new tax bill -- winners and losers 06-30-2018auerbach/the new tax bill -- winners and... ·...

28
The New Tax Bill – Winners and Losers Alan J. Auerbach University of California, Berkeley Laurence J. Kotlikoff Boston University and Darryl Koehler The Fiscal Analysis Center June 29, 2018 We thank The Goodman Institute, The Sloan Foundation, The Burch Center for Tax Policy and Public Finance, The Fiscal Analysis Center, Boston University, and Economic Security Planning, Inc. for research support. We thank Jane Gravelle for very helpful comments. All opinions are strictly those of the authors.

Upload: others

Post on 25-Jun-2020

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

TheNewTaxBill–WinnersandLosers

AlanJ.Auerbach

UniversityofCalifornia,Berkeley

LaurenceJ.Kotlikoff

BostonUniversity

and

DarrylKoehler

TheFiscalAnalysisCenter

June29,2018WethankTheGoodmanInstitute,TheSloanFoundation,TheBurchCenterforTaxPolicyandPublicFinance,TheFiscalAnalysisCenter,BostonUniversity,andEconomicSecurityPlanning,Inc.forresearchsupport.WethankJaneGravelleforveryhelpfulcomments.Allopinionsarestrictlythoseoftheauthors.

Page 2: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

Abstract

TheTaxCutandJobsActof2017(TCJA)representsthemostsignificantchangeinU.S.taxationsince1986.Thebill’sfairnessandwelfareimpactshavebeenstudiedandwidelydebated.Butprior distributional analyses suffer from three shortcomings. First, they examine changes incurrentgross,notremaininglifetimenettaxes.Second,theylumptogethertheyoungandtheold,leadingtomisleadingcomparisons.Third,theyignorethereform’spotentialimpactonthedistributionofpre-taxincome.ThispaperrespondstotheselimitationsinidentifyingwinnersandlosersundertheTCJA.ItusesThe Fiscal Analyzer (TFA) – a program developed to understand fiscal progressivity, workdisincentives and spending inequality. TFA is a detailed life-cycle consumption-smoothingprogramthatincorporatesborrowingconstraints,lifespanuncertaintyandallmajorfederalandstate tax and transfer programs. TFA calculates for different resource groupswithin specificcohortsremaininglifetimenettaxesandremaininglifetimenetspending.Itscalculationscan,inturn,beusedtoa)formresource-andcohort-specificaverageandmarginalremaininglifetimenettaxrates,b)measureabsolutechangesinremaininglifetimespendingforparticularresourcegroupswithin particular cohorts and c) assess changes, within-cohort, in remaining lifetime-spendinginequality.Thepaper’smeasurementsresultfromrunningtheFederalReserve’s2016SurveyofConsumerFinancesthroughTFAbasedonbotholdtaxlawaswellastheTCJA.Insodoing,weconsidertwoalternativeassumptionsaboutthenewtaxlaw’simpactonrealwages.Thefirstiszeroimpact,whichletsusconsidertheimpactofthetaxreformonitsown.Thesecondisa5.5percentincreaseinrealwages–afiguresuggestedbyanalysisinBenzell,KotlikoffandLagarda(2017b).Wefind,forallresource(humanplusnon-humanwealth)groupswithinallcohorts,verymodestreductionsinaverageremaininglifetimenettaxrates(remaininglifetimenettaxesofaresourcequintiledividedbyremaininglifetimeresourcesofthatresourcequintile)regardlessofresourcelevel.Wealsofindverylittlewithin-cohortchangeinfiscalprogressivitywhetheronemeasuresfiscalprogressivityby the shareof totalnet taxespaidby the richest1percent, the shareofspendingdonebythetop1percent,thepercentageincreaseinaveragespendingbythetop1percentcomparedtootherresourcegroups,orthedegreetowhichaverageremaininglifetimenettaxratesrisewithresources.Thissaid,theabsoluteaveragenettaxreductionsthattherichwillenjoyaredramaticallylargerthanthoseprovidedtothepoor.Buttaxcuts,evenprogressiveones,canproducesucharesultsincetherichpaydramaticallymoretaxesperhouseholdthandothepoor.TCJAimpactsthedistributionofresources,albeitmodestly,amongsimilarlyplacedhouseholds– households within the same cohort and resource quintile. Consider, for example, middlequintile, 40-49 year olds. Leaving aside potential wage increases, TCJA produces less thana1.0percentriseinlifetimespendingfor9.9percentofhouseholdsinthecohortandalargerthan3.0percentriseinlifetimespendingfor4.3percent.

Page 3: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

1

1. IntroductionTheTaxCutandJobsActof2017(TCJA)representsthemostsignificantchangeinU.S.taxationsince1986.Thebill’sfairnesshasbeenstudiedanddebated,withresultsgenerallysuggestingthereformisregressive.AnexampleisTaxPolicyCenter(2017),whichreports“higherincomehouseholdsreceivelargeraveragetaxcutsasapercentageofafter-taxincome,withthelargestcuts as a share of income going to taxpayers in the 95th to 99th percentiles of the incomedistribution.” The Congressional Budget Office (2017) and the Joint Committee on Taxation(2017a)reachsimilarconclusions.Butthemethodologyunderlyingthesestudiessuffersfromthreemajorshortcomings.First, itexaminescurrent,notremaininglifetimetaxes,foreachhousehold.Second,itlumpstogethertheyoungandtheold,mixinghouseholds inverydifferentpositions relative to their lifetimeincomes.Third,itignoresthereform’spotentialimpactonwagesand,viathischannel,welfareandprogressivity.This paper rectifies these problems in assessing TCJA. It measures the reform’s impact onremaininglifetimenettaxesofhouseholdswithdifferentlevelsofremaininglifetimeresources.Itperformsthisanalysisseparatelyfordifferentagecohorts.Itconsidersbothzeropercentand5.5percentreal-wagechanges,thelatterfiguresuggestedbysimulationsoftheGlobalGaidarModel(seeBenzell,KotlikoffandLagarda,2017aand2017b).1Anditshows,foreachcohort,howtheTCJAaltersinequalityinremaininghouseholdlifetimespending.Thepaper’smeasurementsresultfromrunningtheFederalReserve’s2016SurveyofConsumerFinancesthroughTheFiscalAnalyzer(TFA)developedinAuerbach,KotlikoffandKoehler(2015).TFA is a detailed life-cycle consumption-smoothing program that incorporates borrowingconstraints,lifespanuncertaintyaswellasallmajorfederalandstatetaxandtransferprograms,includingcorporateincometaxes.Consideringazerochangeinwagesletsusisolatetheimpactofthetaxreformfromitspossibledynamic economic feedback effects. It also accommodates other views, (e.g., Gravelle and 1 Benzell, Kotlikoff and Lagarda’s (2017b) simulation of theUnited Framework produces very similar simulationresultsasthosefortheTCJAsinceitscorporatetaxchangesareessentiallyidentical.Theassumptionofzerowageimpact treats theU.S. economy as effectively closedwhen it comes to changes in effectivemarginal corporateincometaxrates.Thisaccordswith theassessmentofGravelleandSmetters (2001).TheBenzell,et.al. (2017b)modelsuggests,ontheotherhand,thattheU.S.isbettermodeledasasmallopeneconomysincelargechangesintheU.S.effectivemarginalcorporatetaxrateintheirmodelhavesignificantU.S.wageimpacts,butverylittleeffectontheworldinterestrate.TheCongressionalBudgetOfficetakesamiddlegroundposition,assumingthatthreequartersoftheincidenceoftheU.S.corporateincometaxfallsonU.S.ownersofcapitalwiththeremainingonequarterfallingonU.S.workers.RatherthanfollowtheCBOapproachofassumingaparticularincidenceoutcome,wepresentresultsthatassumethatwagesbeareithernoneofthecorporatetaxincidenceorcloseto100percent.WehandlethelattercasebyrunningtheTFAwitha5.5percentchangeinrealwages,butnochangeintherateofreturn(theworldinterestrate)receivedbyhouseholds.

Page 4: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

2

Smetters,2001,thePennWhartonBudgetModel,2017,andtheJointCommitteeonTaxation,2017b)ofTCJA’spotentialdynamiceffects,someofwhichsuggestamuchsmallerimpactthanBenzell,et.al.(2017a,2017b).Wefindverymodestandgenerallysimilarreductionsforallcohortsinaverageremaininglifetimenettaxrates(remaininglifetimenettaxesdividedbyremaininglifetimeresources)regardlessofresourcelevel(non-humanwealthplusthepresentvalueoffuturewagesandsalaries).Regardingthemagnitudeofchanges,consider,forexample,themiddle-resourcequintile.Assumingazeropercentwageincrease,thereductionsare15.8percentto14.2percentfor40-49yearolds,26.4percentto24.5percentfor20yearolds,and-58.0percentto-59.2percentfor60yearolds.2Witha5.5percentwageincrease,therespectivechangesare15.8percentto15.3percentfor40yearolds,26.4percentto25.2percentfor20yearoldsand-58.0percentto-57.9percentfor60yearolds.TCJAhasvery little impactonfiscalprogressivitybasedonaverageremaining lifetimenettaxrates.Inthecaseof40-yearolds,assumingnochangeinbefore-taxwages,theaverageremaininglifetimenettaxrateforthetop1percentfallsfrom34.1percentto33.1percent.Forthebottom20percent,theaveragenettaxratefallsfrom-41.6percentto-42.6percent.Witha5.5percentwageincrease,theaveragenettaxrateofthetop1percentfallsverylittle--from34.1percentto33.7percent.Forthepoorest20percent,theaveragenetraterisesfrom-41.6percentto-37.9 percent. Clearly, the reform’s feedback effects matter for fiscal progressivity as wageincreasespushhouseholdsintohighermarginalnettaxbrackets,particularlyatthelowerendoftheresourcedistribution.Still,thesearerelativelysmallchanges.Analternativeindicatoroffiscalprogressivityistheshareofremaininglifetimegrosstaxespaidbytherichest1percent.Thisindicatoralsoshowsverylittlechangeduetothereform.Inthecaseof40-49yearolds,theshareis16.6percentundertheoldtaxsystem.Underthereform,it’s16.9percentwithnowageincreaseand16.7percentifwagesriseby5.5percent.Yes,thetop1percentexperiencesasmalldeclineintheiraveragenettaxrate.Butthecorrespondingdeclineissomewhatlargerforotherpercentilegroups,whichexplainswhythetaxshareofthetop1percentactuallyrisesslightly.Hence,bythismeasure,thetaxreformisslightlyprogressive.Thetaxshareofthemiddlequintileof40-49yearoldsis11.8percentunderoldlaw,11.7percentunder the TCJAassumingnowage increases, and12.0percent assuming a 5.5percentwageincrease. For the bottomquintile of 40-49 year olds, the three respective tax shares are 2.6percent,2.6percentand2.7percent.TCJA-inducedchangesinremaininglifetimespendinginequalityisarguablythebestmeasureofthereform’sfiscalprogressivity.Thereformproducesverylittlechangeinthespendingsharesofdifferentpercentilegroupsregardlessofthecohort’sage.Take40-49yearolds,onceagain.

2Note that average remaining lifetimenet tax rates declinewith age since taxes are front loaded and transferpaymentsarebackloadedoverthelifecycle.

Page 5: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

3

Thepre-reformspendingshareofthetop1percentis12.9percent.Itremainsconstantat12.9percentunderthereformwithfixedwagesanddecreasesto12.7percentwhenwagesrise.Thesesharesare,bytheway,farlowerthanthetop1percent’s30.3percentshareofnetwealth.Thedifferencereflects,ofcourse,thefactthathumanwealthandremaininglifetimenettaxesarefarmoreprogressivelydistributedthanisnetwealth.Forthemiddlequintileof40-49yearolds,thespendingshareis14.1percentunderboththeoldlawandnewlawassumingwagesremainfixed.The5.5percentriseinwagesraisesthisfigureslightly--to14.2percent.Thesefiguresmaybecomparedwithanetwealthshareof5.6percent.Asforthepoorestquintileinthe40-49yearoldcohort,theirspendingshareis6.5percentpre-reform.Itdropsslightlyto6.4percentunderthereform,assumingnowageincrease.Witha5.5percentwageincrease,it’sagainslightlysmaller–6.4percent.Hereagain,theTCJAhasonlyasmallimpactoninequality.Thecorrespondingnetwealthshareforthepoorest20percentof40yearoldsis1.0percent.YetanotherwaytomeasureofTCJA’sprogressivityTCJA is toconsider theshareof thetotaladditionalspending(ignoringanyassociatedwageincrease)affordedbythereformthatgoestothetop1percent.Inthecaseof40-49yearolds,thisshareis9.7percent,whichislessthanthetop1percent’sinitial12.9percentshareoftotalcohortspendingunderoldlaw.Theshareofadditionalspendinggoingtothelowestquintileis2.3percent.Thistooislessthantheiroverallinitial spending share, which is 6.5 percent. Consequently, for 40-49 year olds, neither thesuperrichnortheverypoorbenefitdisproportionatelyfromthereform.Thismeasureisdifferentfordifferentcohorts.Forexample,thetop1percentof20-29yearoldsgarner7.0percentoftheir cohort’s total spending increase.Among70-79yearolds, the top1percentgarner28.5percentofthetotalcohort’sspendinggain.Buttheshareofthetotal,within-cohortincreaseinspending enjoyed by the top 1 percent is not enough to materially alter the share of totalspendingofthetop1percentinanycohort.What about changes in average spending levels among 40-49 year olds? Ignoring any wageincreases,thetop1percentexperience,onaverage,a$320,624riseinspending.Thoseinthemiddlequintileaveragea$23,159spendingincrease.Forthoseinthebottomquintile,averagespendingrisesby$3,960.Consequently,thegaintothesuperrichis81timesthatofthepoor.Fromthisperspective,whichisoneoftentakeninpolicydiscussions,thereformappearsgrosslyunfair. But by other standard measures of progressivity and inequality, which focus not onchangesinabsolutenettaxpaymentsorabsolutespendinglevelsbutonaveragetaxratesaswell as tax and spending shares, the TCJA appears to be roughly distributionally neutral. Ofcourse, if it causeswages to rise, these reformswill also improve theeconomyandworkers’welfare.TheTCJA’sgreatest impactonthedistributionofresources,albeitmodest, isamongsimilarlyplacedhouseholds – householdswithin the same cohort and resourcequintile. Consider, forexample,middlequintile,40-49yearolds.Leavingasidepotentialwageincreases,TCJAproduces

Page 6: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

4

lessthana1.0percentriseinlifetimespendingfor9.9percentofhouseholdsinthecohortandalargerthan3.0percentriseinlifetimespendingfor4.3percent.ThepaperproceedsinSection2bybrieflydescribingtheTCJA.Section3presentsourmethodofcalculatingremaininglifetimenettaxes,remaininglifetimenettaxrates,andremaininglifetimespending. Section 4 describes the 2016 Survey of Consumer Finances (SCF) data, ourbenchmarkingoftheSCFtonationalaggregates,andthelimitationsoftheSCFwhenitcomestoincorporating pass-through business tax provisions. Section 5 presents results and section 6concludes.2. TheTaxCutsandJobsActof2017(TCJA)TheTCJAwas theculminationofayearandahalfof fiscal reformdebateamongHouseandSenate Republicans, beginning with The Better Way Plan released in June 2016. That planenvisioned replacing the corporate income taxwith a 20 percent destination-based businesscash-flow tax, reducing taxation of pass-through businesses, streamlining personal-incometaxation by eliminating the Alternative Minimum Tax (AMT), unifying the tax treatment ofpersonalasset income(taxinghalfofpersonalasset income),eliminatingexemptionsandthedeductibilityofstateincomeandpropertytaxes,raisingthestandarddeduction,raisingthechild-taxcredit,reducingthenumberofincome-taxbracketsfromseventothree(withthetopratelowered from 39.6 percent to 33.0 percent), using a chain CPI to index tax brackets, andeliminatingtheestatetax.TheUnifiedFrameworkwasthereform’ssecondincarnation,differingfromTheBetterWayPlanprimarilyinitscorporatetaxreform.Specifically,iteliminatedbordertaxadjustment,eliminatedexpensingoflong-livedinvestments,andpermittednetinterestdeductionsuptoalimit.TheTCJAretainedmostofTheUnifiedFramework’sbusinessprovisions.Butitseta21percentcorporate tax rate and introduced a variety of international tax provisions aimed at limitingcorporate taxavoidance. It alsoplaced restrictionson thenatureandextentofpass-throughincomethatcanreceivefavorabletaxtreatment.Onthepersonalside,theTCJAretains7taxbrackets,withatoprateof37percent.Themortgageinterestdeductiononoldmortgagesupto$1millionwasgrandfathered.Fornewmortgages,thelimitwasreducedto$750,000.Stateandlocaltaxandpropertytaxdeductionswererestored,butonlyuptoacombinedtotalof$10,000.Thetopmarginalratewassetat37percent.TheindividualAMTwasretainedinmodifiedform.Therewerealsosomeminorchangestocapitalgainstaxbrackets.Finally, theestatetaxwasretained, but the exemption level was doubled. The Fiscal Analyzer incorporates all theaforementionedelementsoftheTCJAand,asdescribedinAuerbachet.al.(2016)andAuerbachet.al.(2017),allelementsofpriortaxlaw.

Page 7: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

5

Many of TCJA’s tax provisions become less favorable over the course of the 10-year budgetperiod.Inaddition,manyofitsindividualtaxcutprovisionsaresettoexpirebytheendofthedecade.Thesefeaturesappeartohavebeenincludedsimplytomeetarbitrarybudgettargetswithinthebudgetperiodandtolimitthegrowthinprojecteddeficitsbeyondthebudgetperiod.MeetingthebudgettargetsandlimitingfutureprojecteddeficitswereneededtopermitpassageofthebillwithasimplemajorityintheSenate.However,therewasnocoherentpolicyreasonofferedforsuchtemporaryprovisions,norareweawareofany.Consequently,inthisanalysisweassumeTCJA’sprovisionsarepermanent.ThisassumptionisimportanttokeepinmindwheninterpretingourresultsandcomparingthemwiththoseofotherstudiesthatadherestrictlytotheletterofTCJA’slaw.

3. Methodology

TomeasuretheeffectsoftheTCJAonrevenue,inequality,progressivity,andworkincentives,weranallhouseholdssampled in theFederalReserve’s2016SurveyofConsumerFinances (SCF)throughTheFiscalAnalyzer(TFA).TFAisadetailedlife-cycleconsumption-smoothingprogramthatincorporatesbothborrowingconstraintsandlifespanuncertaintyaswellasallmajorfederalandstatetaxandtransferprograms.3Inthecourseofdoingitsconsumptionsmoothing,TFAdetermineseachhousehold’sexpectedpresent valueof remaining lifetime spending,where the termexpected references averagingover different longevity outcomes and spending encompasses all expenditures, includingterminalbequestsnetofestatetaxes.Theimpetusforfocusingonremaininglifetimes,ratherthanjustthecurrentyear,comesfromstandardlifecycleeconomictheory.Thelifetimebudgetconstraintfacingeachhouseholdisgivenby

(1) S=R–T,whereSreferencesthepresentexpectedvalueofahousehold’sremaininglifetimespending,Rstandsforremaininglifetimeresources(thepresentexpectedvalueofremaininglifetimelaborearningsplusitscurrentnetworth)andTstandsforthepresentexpectedvalueofremaininglifetimetaxesnetoftransferpaymentsreceived.Theaveragenettaxrate,t,isdefinedby

(2) t= 𝑇/𝑅.Thus, if theexpectedpresent valueof ahousehold’s spending is, for example, 65percentofremaininglifetimeresources,itsaveragenettaxrate,t,equals35percent.Averageremaininglifetimenettaxratestellusnotonlythenetshareoftheirresourcesthathouseholdssurrender 3See Auerbach, Kotlikoff, and Koehler (2016).

Page 8: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

6

tothegovernment.Theyalsotellusabouttheprogressivityofthefiscalsystem.Ifaveragenettaxratesrisewiththelevelofresources,thefiscalsystemisprogressive.Iftheyfall,thesystemisregressive.Iftheyareindependentofthelevelofresources,thesystemisproportional.This paper, like our prior studies using TFA (Auerbach et. al., 2016, Auerbach et. al., 2017),calculates inequality and the progressivity of the fiscal system on a cohort-specific basis.Specifically,weconsiderinequalitybylookingwithin10-yearagecohortsattheshareoftotalremaining lifetime spending attributable to households falling within different within-cohortpercentiles of remaining lifetime resources, R. To measure within-cohort progressivity, weconsiderhowaverageremaininglifetimenettaxratesvarywithresources.Weusecohort-specificanalysistoconsiderinequalityandprogressivitybecausefailingtodosoamounts to comparing apples with oranges. Ranked by remaining lifetime spending, oldercohortswould lookpoorer than younger cohorts simplybecause theyhad shorter remaininglifespans.AndremaininglifetimenettaxratesofoldercohortswouldappearlowerthanthoseofyoungercohortssimplybecausetheelderlywouldreceivenocreditfornettaxespaidinthepastandappeartobesubsidizedbecausetheyarecollectingorwillstarttocollectMedicare,Medicaid,andSocialSecuritybenefitssoonerthanyoungercohorts.Evenifwewereconsideringjustone-year’sincomeandtaxesforeachcohort,comparingindividualsfromdifferentcohortswouldleadtomisleadingresults.Consider,forexample,thecaseinwhichallhouseholdsearnthe same amount over their life cycles regardless of their year of birth. Hence, there is noinequalityinlifetimewelfareeitheracrossorwithingenerations.Butifsuchaneconomyfeaturedasocialsecuritysystemthattaxedtheworking(andearning)youngtopaybenefitstotheretired(andnon-earning)old,policywouldlookhighlyprogressive(thosewithhighincomespaytaxes,thosewithlowincomereceivebenefits),contrarytoreality.4. The2016SCF

The Federal Reserve’s Survey of Consumer Finances is primarily a cross-section survey thatcollects data from some 6,500 American households. The survey includes data on assets,liabilities, income,demographicsandahostofothersocio-economicvariables.Unfortunately,thesurveydoesn’tlinktopastearningsrecords.Consequently,toestimatefutureSocialSecuritybenefitsaswellasfuturelaborearnings,weused,asdescribedinAuerbach,KotlikoffandKohler(2016),datafromthepastCurrentPopulationSurveystobackcastandforecastlaborincome.IntheSCFdata,household-weightedtotalsofvariouseconomicandfiscalaggregatesmaynothavedirectcounterpartsintheNationalIncomeandProduceAccount(NIPA)orFederalReserveFinancialAccounts(FA).Thus,wedecidedtofollowtheapproachoutlinedinAppendixAandBinDettling,etal.(2015),namelybenchmarkingthe2016SCFbasedon“conceptuallyequivalent”values. Specifically, we set SCF benchmark factors to ensure that SCF-weighted aggregatescoincidewithconceptuallycomparableNIPAandFAaggregates.Forwagesandself-employmentincome(reportedfor2015inthe2016SCF)weuse2015NIPAaggregates.Forassets,weuseFA-2016Q3aggregates.

Page 9: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

7

Table 1a details the overall values, their sources, and our benchmark adjustments. First,weinflate all SCF-reported wage income by 12.3 percent to match the NIPA 2015 measure ofemployeecompensation.Second,wedeflateallSCF-reportedself-employmentincomeby29.3percenttomatchtheNIPA2015proprietorshipandpartnershipincometotal.Thefactthatweneedtoinflatewageincomeandsignificantlydeflateself-employmentincometomatchnationalaggregatesmayreflect,inpart,atendencyofSCFrespondentstoreportwageearningsasself-employmentincome.Third,weinflateallwageandself-employmentincomeamountsreportedinthe2016SCFbynominalaveragewagegrowththrough2017.4Benchmarking assets andnetworth reported in the SCF requires several adjustments to theFinancialAccountsvalues.UsingtheapproachoutlinedinAppendixBofDettling,et.al.(2015),we first created a net worth breakdown as detailed in Table 1b. We then adjusted thecorrespondingTFAcomponentstoalignwiththeparticularFAaggregateproducingthetable1c’sreportednetworth.ThedifferenceinnetworthisalmostentirelyduetodifferencesinLiabilities.Ourliabilitiesare17.2percentlowerthanintheFA.Wechosenottobenchmarkourliabilitiesasweweren’t clearhowtodosoonacomponentbycomponentbasis,e.g.,whether toadjustmortgagedebtbythesamepercentageasstudentloans.Furthermore,TFAdoesn’tusedliabilityvaluesperse.Itusesrepaymentvalues,suchasmonthlymortgagepayments,initscalculations.Webelievethatrespondentshavefarmoreaccurateknowledgeofwhattheyneedtorepayeverymonthwith respect to theirmortgages, car loans, student loans, etc. than of the remainingbalanceontheseliabilities.OurfirstassetadjustmentwastoreduceSCF-reportedhomemarketvalueby11.6percenttomatchthe2016Q3FederalReserveFinancialAccountsmeasure.Second,wereducetheSCF-reported equity in non-corporate businesses by 38.0 percent tomatch the 2016Q3 FederalReserveFinancialAccountsestimate.Fourth,weincreasedreportedretirementaccountassetsby 4.4 percent tomatch the total reported for 2016Q3 Federal Reserve Financial Accounts.Finally,weinflateallfinancialandnon-financialassetsbythegrowthrateimpliedbythechangeintotalassetsbetween2016and2017intheFinancialAccounts5.Ourbaselinecorporatetaxrateisderivedrelativetoallcapitalincome,basedonthetraditionalHarbergeranalysisthatattributestheincidenceofcorporatetaxestoallcapitalincome,whethercorporateornon-corporate.Tomakethiscalculationweuse2017nationalincomelessindirectbusiness taxes as reported in the 2017 NIPA. We then calculate the ratio of employeecompensationtonetnationalincomelessproprietorshipincometofindtheportionofnational

4https://www.ssa.gov/oact/cola/AWI.html#Series reports Social Security’s average wage index series through 2016. We assume the same growth rate for 2017 as that reported for 2016. 5FederalReserveZ.1-FinancialAccounts,B.101,Line1,2016-2017

Page 10: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

8

income attributed to capital. Finally, we divide total corporate taxes less taxes on FederalReserveprofitsbycapitalincomegivinganoverallcorporatetaxrateof9.3percent6.InmodelingtheTCJA,wereducedourcorporatetaxrate,by12.4percent.Thisistheaverage,over the next five years, due to TCJA, in the Joint Committee on Taxation’s static projectedcorporatetaxrevenuelossdividedbythe2017NIPAestimateofcorporatetaxrevenue.7OneusefulcheckofourbenchmarkingprocedureistocompareourresultstothoseoftheJointCommitteeonTaxation,whicharebasedontaxreturndata.Table2showsaveragecurrent-yeartaxratesunderoldlaw,undertheTCJA,andthechangebetweenthetwo,fromJCT(2017a)andaccording to our calculations, where we adhere as closely as possible to JCT’s incomeclassificationandincomeandtaxdefinitions.8Asthetableshows,ourmeasuresarerelativelyclosetoJCT’s.Indeed,thecorrelationcoefficientbetweenourstaticTCJAaverageratesandtheJCT’s across the income categories in table 2 is 96.0 percent.Moreover, like JCT,we find anincrease in percentage tax cuts as income increases, although this upward trend is lesspronouncedinouranalysis.ThefactthatweareabletocomereasonablyclosetotheJCT’sanalysisofprogressivitywiththeSCFdata,butthat,asshownbelow,ourpreferredmethodofassessingprogressivityproducesadifferentpicturebasedonthesesamedataindicatesthatourfindingsarenotdrivenprimarilybydifferencesindata,butthatdifferencesinmethodologyplayanimportantrole.

5. FindingsRemainingLifetimeSpendingInequality

Tables3-5considerourcentralmeasureofinequality,namelywithin-cohort,lifetimespendingshares of different resource-percentile groups. Specifically, the tables show, by cohort, thelifetime spending shares for the top 1 percent, middle 20 percent and poorest 20 percent,respectively,underoldlaw,TCJAwithnowageincreaseandunderTCJAwitha5.5percentwageincrease.Top,middle,andpoorestrefertotheresourcerankingofhouseholdswithincohorts. 6AllvaluesusedtoderiveourcorporatetaxratearefromNIPA2017.NetNationalIncome(NNI)equalsTable1.7.5Line16minusLine18.CapitalIncome(CI)equals(1minusTable2.1Line2dividedby(NNIminusTable2.1Line9))timesNNI.CorporateTaxRateequals(Table3.1Line5minusTable3.2Line8)dividedbyCI.7https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func=startdown&id=50538 We are unable to include certain components of JCT’s expanded income measure, including worker’scompensation,alternateminimumtaxpreferenceitems,individualshareofbusinesstaxes,andexcludedincomeofU.S.citizenslivingabroad.TheJCTisalsousing2013IRSdata,whichisthelatestsuchdataavailable,whereasourSCFdatareferenceeither2015or2016.OurapproachandtheJCT’s(atleastwithrespecttotable2)bothassumethattheincidenceofthecorporateincometaxfalls100percentonownersofcapital.TheJCTalsoassumesthatnearly10percentofcorporateincomeaccruestoforeignowners,whoseburdenisexcludedfromtheircalculation(JCT,2013).Wemakenoadjustmentinouranalysisforforeignownership.

Page 11: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

9

Aquickglanceacross the rows in the three tables shows that thedistributionof spending isessentiallyunchangedundertheTCJAregardlessofwhetherwagesremainfixedorriseby5.5percent.Withnowageincrease,thespendingshareofthetop1percentisunchangedforfiveofthe six age-cohorts, and it falls slightly for one. With the wage increase, the top-1 percentspendingshareremainsfixedforthreecohorts,fallsslightlyforoneandrisesslightlyfortwo.Amongmiddle-quintilehouseholds,spendingshares, in theno-wage increase,are identical infiveofsixcases,andslightlylowerintheotherone.Withthewageincrease,thesharesarethesameinjustonecase,slightlyhigherinoneandslightlylowerinfour.Finally,amongthebottomquintilewithnowageincrease,spendingsharesarethesameforonecohortandslightlylowerforfivecohorts.Withwageincreases,spendingsharesareslightlyloweracrossallsixcohorts.Thisreflectsthesmallershareofresourcesamongthebottomquintilethanamongotherquintilesthat’srepresentedbyhumanwealth.SharesofRemainingLifetimeTaxes

Tables 6-8 repeat tables 3-5, but consider remaining lifetime taxes, not remaining lifetimespending. Here, again, we see very small changes from TCJA. The top 1 percent with oneexception–70yearolds--payaslightlyhighershareofremaininglifetimetaxesthantheydowithoutthereformandthisholdsregardlessofthesizeofthewageincrease.Thesameholdsforthemiddleandbottomquintileswithinthedifferentcohorts.There iscertainlynosystematicshiftingofthetaxburdenawayfromthericharisingfromTCJA.ImpactonAverageSpendingLevelswithinCohort,forTop1%andMiddleandBottomQuintiles

Thenextsetoftables,9-11,reportaverageremainingspendinglevelsfortheoldtaxregimeaswellasunderTCJAwithandwithoutwageincreases,withpercentageincreasesinparentheses.Asabove,theanalysisisbycohortforthetop1percent,middleandbottomquintiles.Ignoringwageincreases,theaveragespendingincreasesrangefrom0.0percentforthepoorest70-79yearoldsto2.6percentforthemiddlequintileof20-29yearolds.Withwageincreases,theaveragespendingincreasesrangefrom0.1percentforthepoorest70-79yearoldsto7.0percentforthemiddlequintileof20-29yearolds.Thebottomquintileclearlyexperiencesthesmallestincreaseinspendingwhetherornotwagesrise.Butthedifferentialislargeriftheydorise.Thisisexpectedgiventhatthepoorpayrelativelylittleintaxesandrelytoamuchlargerextentontransferpaymentstofinancetheirspending.Depending on the age cohort, the superrich enjoy larger or smaller percentage spendingincreasesthanthemiddleclassdependingtosomedegreeonwhetherornotwagesrise.AverageChangesinSpendingandShareofTotalWithin-CohortSpendingChanges

Page 12: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

10

AnotherperspectiveonwinnersandlosersfromTCJAisthesizeanddistributionofchangesinlifetimespending.Consider,inthisregard,tables12-14.Table12focuseson40-49yearoldsforthecaseofnowageincrease.Itshowsthattheaverageabsoluteincreaseinremaininglifetimespendingforthetop1%is$320,624.Thisis81.0timestheaveragespendinggaininthelowestquintile.Ifonejudgesfairnessbasedonabsolutespending,TCJAisclearlyhighlyunfair.Butifoneconsiderstheshareofthespendingincreaseenjoyedbythetop1percent,it’s9.7percent.Thisfigure is smaller than this group’s 12.9 percent of total cohort spending (see Table 3).Consequently,therichest1percentendupwithaslightlysmallershareoftotalcohortspendingunderTCJAthanbeforeitwasenacted.Thisissupportedbythemiddlecolumnoftable12,whichshowsthattheaveragepercentageincreaseinspendingofthetop1percentof40-49yearoldsislowerthanthatofotherresourcepercentilegroupswiththeexceptionofthatofthebottomquintile.Table13,whichshowresultsfor20-29yearolds,tellsaverysimilarstory,althoughtheaverageabsolutespendinggainofthetop1percentis27.0,not81.0,timesthatofthebottomquintile.Thetop1percentaccountfor7.0percentofthecohort’stotalspendinggain.Thiscompareswiththeirpre-reform12.5percentshareofcohortspending.Themiddlecolumnof this tablealsoshows that the top 1 percent experience, on average, the smallest percentage increase inspendingofanyresourcepercentilegroupinthiscohort.Thestoryfor70-70yearolds,providedbytable14,issomewhatdifferent.Forthiscohort,theaveragespendingincreaseofthetop1percentisthehighestamongthethreeagecohorts,at$389,887.Forthelowestquintile,theaveragespendinggainisonly$84.That’saratioof4,641to1!Forthemiddlequintile,theaveragegainisjust$4,080.Moreover,thetop1%of70-79yearoldsgarner28.5percentoftheircohort’stotalspendinggains,whichexceedstheir21.7percentshareofspendingundertheoldtaxlaw.Theiraveragepercentageincreaseinspendingishigherthanforotherresourcegroups.Still,atthelevelofprecisionmeasuredintable3,thespendingshareofthetop1percentisonlyslightlyhigher(0.1percent)intheno-wage-increasecasethanprereform.AverageRemainingLifetimeNetTaxRatesAnothermeansofexaminingprogressivityistoconsiderchangesinaverageremaininglifetimenettaxratesarisingfromthereform.Figures1-3dothisfortheage40-49cohort.Figure1showsrates pre-reform. Figures 2 and 3 show rates post reformwithout andwithwage increases,respectively. Comparison of figures 1 and 2 shows small cuts in net tax rates (ignoring anyeconomy-widewageincrease),whetheronecalculatestaxratesbasedonalifetimeorcurrent-yearbasis.9Moreover,thesecutsinnettaxratesaresimilarinsizeforallresourcegroups.Forexample,ournet lifetime tax rates fallby, respectively,1.0,1.5,1.6,1.6,and1.5percentagepointsforthefivequintilesandby1.4and1.0percentagepointsforthetop5percentandtop1

9Current-yearnettaxratesare2018nettaxesdividedbycurrent-yearincome.

Page 13: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

11

percentoftheresourcedistribution.Thechanges(again,betweenfigures1and2) inaveragecurrent-year net tax rates are alsoquiteuniformacrossour resource groups, falling in the7percentilegroupsby1.2,1.3,1.3,1.3,1.4,1.4,and0.9percentagepoints,respectively.Tosummarize,partitioningbyagegroup,aseconomicreasoningsuggests,andalsofocusingonnet,notgrosstaxratesleavesTCJAveryslightlyregressive.Andthisistruewhetherweconsiderremaininglifetimenettaxratesorcurrentyearnettaxrates.Table 3 shows the impact on net tax rates of higherwages. This pushes certain households,particularly those in the lowest quintile, into higher brackets, raising their net tax ratessomewhat.WithinCohortandResourcePercentileDifferencesinTreatment

AfinalimportantfeatureofTCJAisitsredistributionacrosshouseholdswithinthesamecohortand, indeed,within thesameresourcepercentile rangewithingivencohorts.Figures4and5show, for the age40-49 cohort, scatterplots of before andafter remaining lifetime spendinglevelswithoutandwithwageincreases.Withnowageincreases,mostpointslieabovethe45-degree line,butnot farabove.Thisaccordswiththesmallnettax-ratereductions impliedbyfigures1and2.Withthewageincrease,thepointsliefarthernorthofthe45-degreeline.Somepoints are farther out than others. Figures 6 and 7 explore this. They show histograms ofpercentagechanges in lifetimespendingforthe40-49year-oldcohortbothwithoutandwithwageincreases.Bothfiguresindicatesignificantdifferencesacrosshouseholdsintheextentoftheirwelfaregainfromthetaxreform.Thespreadbetweenmaximumandminimumvaluesintables12-14showthatdifferencesintreatmentundertheTCJAoccurnotjustacrosshouseholdswithdifferentresources,butalsoacrosshouseholdswithsimilarlevelsofresources.6. Conclusion

TheTaxCutandJobsActof2017madesignificantchangestothestructureofbothcorporateandpersonalfederaltaxes.ThisstudyusedTheFiscalAnalyzerinconjunctionwiththeFederalReserve’s2016ConsumerExpenditureSurveytostudytheTCJA’sprogressivityanditseffectonspendinginequality.Ourresultscompareoutcomeswithincohortsandarebasedonremaininglifetimenettaxationandspending.Analyzingfiscalprogressivityonaremaininglifetime,ratherthancurrent-yearbasis,doingsowithinagecohort,andconsideringnetratherthangrosstaxburdensare,webelieve,threeimportantandlongoverdueimprovementstoconventionalfiscaldistributionalanalysis.AsacomparisonoftheJCT’saveragetaxratesunderTCJAintable2and,forexample,theTFAaverageremaininglifetimenettaxratesportrayedinfigure1indicates,theassessmentofprogressivityisverydifferentunderthetwomethodologies.Thisisparticularlythecasewhenitcomestoconsideringthefiscalburdenonthepoor.Ourapproachalsofocusesonthebottom line,namelyhowthewithin-cohortdistributionand levelsofspendingchangebyresourcegroup.

Page 14: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

12

We find that the TCJA did notmaterially alter the fiscal system’swithin-cohort progressivitywhetheronemeasuresprogressivityintermsoftheshareofspendingdonebytherichortheshareoftaxespaidbytherich.Ifthereformsucceedsinraisingwages,itwill,onaverage,produceasmall,butmeaningfulincreaseinremaininglifetimespending,i.e.,ineconomicwelfare.Asonewouldexpectfromamajorreform,therearewinnersandlosers,relativetoabenchmarkofequalreductions in net tax rates or equal percentage increases in consumption. But much of thedispersioniswithincohortmemberswithroughlythesamelevelofresources.Theseresultsarefullyconsistentwithourownestimates,andthoseofothers,thattheabsolutegainsofthoseatthetoparefargreaterthanthosewhoarelowerintheincomedistribution.Onemay,ofcourse,viewsuchadistributionofabsolutegainsasunfair,indeedextremelyunfairevenif they are consistent with maintaining the existing degree of inequality as conventionallymeasured. Also,we stress again that our results assume that the new tax provisions do notchangeovertime,eventhoughthelawformallystipulatesmanytaxincreasesthatmightaffectprogressivitybytheendoftheten-yearbudgetperiod.Finally,ouranalysisdoesn’taddresstheimportantissueoffiscalsustainabilityandrequisitemajorfuturetaxincreasesandgovernmentspendingcuts,whichwillhavetheirown,verysignificantdistributionaleffects.

Page 15: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

13

References

Auerbach, Alan J., Laurence J. Kotlikoff, and Darryl Koehler. 2016. “U.S. Inequality, FiscalProgressivity,andWorkDisincentives.”NBERworkingpaperno.22032.Auerbach, Alan J., Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Darryl Koehler and Manni Yu. 2017. “Is Uncle SamInducingtheElderlytoRetire?”inTaxPolicyandtheEconomy.NBERvol.31,no1,pp.1-42.Benzell,SethG.,LaurenceJ.Kotlikoff,GuillermoLagarda.2017a.“SimulatingBusinessCashFlowTaxation:AnIllustrationBasedonthe“BetterWay”U.S.CorporateTaxReform.”NBERworkingpaper23675.December.https://www.kotlikoff.net/sites/default/files/Simulating%20the%20Better%20Way%20Tax%20Reform%20Plan.pdfBenzell, Seth G., Laurence J. Kotlikoff, Guillermo Lagarda. 2017b. “Simulating the UnifiedFrameworkTaxReform.”October.https://www.kotlikoff.net/sites/default/files/Simulating%20the%20Better%20Way%20Tax%20Reform%20Plan.pdfCongressional Budget Office. 2017. “Distributional Effects of Changes in Taxes and SpendingUndertheConferenceAgreementforH.R.1.”December.https://www.cbo.gov/system/files/115th-congress-2017-2018/reports/53429-distributionhr1.pdf.Dettling,LisaJ.,SebastianJ.Devlin-Foltz,JacobKrimmel,SarahJ.Pack,andJeffreyP.Thompson(2015). “ComparingMicro andMacro Sources for Household Accounts in the United States:EvidencefromtheSurveyofConsumerFinances,”FinanceandEconomicsDiscussionSeries2015-086. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,http://dx.doi.org/10.17016/FEDS.2015.086.Fullerton,Don,andDianeLimRogers.1993.WhoBearstheLifetimeTaxBurden?.Washington,DC:BrookingsInstitution.Gravelle, Jane,andKentSmetters. “WhoBears theBurdenof theCorporateTax in theOpenEconomy?.”No.w8280.NationalBureauofEconomicResearch,2001.JointCommitteeonTaxation.2013.JointCommitteeonTaxation.2017a.“DistributionalEffectsof theConferenceAgreement forH.R.1“TheTaxCutsandJobsAct.”December18.https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func=startdown&id=5054.

Page 16: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

14

JointCommitteeonTaxation.2017b.“MacroeconomicAnalysisoftheTaxCutsandJobsAct.”November30.https://www.jct.gov/publications.html?func%3Dstartdown%26id%3D5045PennWhartonBudgetModel.2017.“TheSenateTaxCutsandJobsAct:DynamicEffectsontheBudgetandtheEconomy.”November15.http://budgetmodel.wharton.upenn.edu/issues/2017/11/21/the-senate-tax-cuts-and-jobs-act-amended-111517-dynamic-effects-on-the-budget-and-the-economyPoterba,J.M.,1989.Lifetimeincidenceandthedistributionalburdenofexcisetaxes.NBERworkingpaperno.2833.TaxPolicyCenter.2017.“DistributionalAnalysisoftheConferenceAgreementfortheTaxCutsandJobsAct.”TheTaxPolicyCenter,Washington,D.C.December18.http://www.taxpolicycenter.org/sites/default/files/publication/150816/2001641_distributional_analysis_of_the_conference_agreement_for_the_tax_cuts_and_jobs_act_0.pdf

Page 17: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

15

Table1aBenchmarkingTFA

Line Variable Data(Billions)BenchmarkedTFAEstimateValue(Billions)

BenchmarkFactor DataSource

1 Wages 7,858.9 7,858.8 1.1227

NIPAdata-Table2.1.PersonalIncomeandItsDisposition-Line2–2015

2 Self-employmentIncome

1,318.8 1,318.7 0.7067

NIPAdata-Table2.1.PersonalIncomeandItsDisposition-Line9–2015

3HomeMarketValue,owner-occupied 22,588.8 22,589.1 0.8836

FinancialAccounts–Z.1,B.101,Line4

4EquityinNon-

corporatebusiness 11,156.5 11,156.0 0.6202FinancialAccounts–Z.1,B.101,Line28

5 RegularAssets 32,506.7 32,505.1 0.9936

ConceptuallyEquivalentFinancialAssetsFA(Table1b)minusRetirementAccounts(Table1aLine6)

6 RetirementAccounts 14,407.8 14.408.5 1.0444FinancialAccounts–Z.1,L.117,Line26&27

Sources:NationalIncomeandProduceAccount(NIPA)2015;FinancialAccountsoftheUnitedStates–Z.1,March,2017Release

Page 18: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

16

Table1bFAValuesthatAreConceptuallyEquivalenttoSCFAggregates($Billions) PublishedNetWorthFA 90,762.1 SourcePublishedNonfinancialAssetsFA 31,827.2 B.101-Line2 (-) IdentifiableNonprofitNetWorth RealEstate 3,382.4 B.101-Line5 Equipment 336.6 B.101-Line6 IntellectualProperty 145.2 B.101-Line7

(-) ConsumerDurableGoods 5,374.1 B.101-Line8 (+) EquityinNon-corporate Business 11,156.5 B.101-Line28ConceptuallyEquivalent(toSCF) FANonfinancialAssets 33,745.4 PublishedFinancialAssetsFA 73,889.5 B.101-Line9 (-) IdentifiableNonprofitNetWorth OpenMarketPaper ConsumerCredit(StudentLoans) 39.9 B.101-Line22

(-) LifeInsuranceReserves 1,356.6 B.101-Line26 (-) Misc.Assets 983.8 B.101-Line29 (-) OtherloansandAdvances 862.3 B.101-Line20 (-) Mortgages 112.9 B.101-Line21 (-) PensionEntitlements 22,078.2 B.101-Line27 (-) EquityinNon-CorporateBusiness 11,156.5 B.101-Line28 (+) PensionEntitlements DCPensions 6,640.8 L.117-Line26 AnnuitiesinIRAsatLifeInsCo. 2,974.4 L.227-Line2ConceptuallyEquivalent(toSCF) FAFinancialAssets 46,914.5 PublishedLiabilitiesFA 14,954.6 B.101-Line40 (-) IdentifiableNonprofitNetWorth MunicipalSecurities 219.6 B.101-Line31 CommercialLoansandAdvances 238.5 B.101-Line37 TradePayables 314.2 B.101-Line38 (-) DepositoryInstitutionloansn.e.c. 319.2 B.101-Line35 (-) OtherloansandAdvances 448.0 B.101-Line36 (-) DeferredandUnpaidLife InsurancePremiums 32.7 B.101-Line39ConceptuallyEquivalent(toSCF) FALiabilities 13,382.4 ConceptuallyEquivalent(toSCF) FANetWorth 67,277.5

Page 19: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

17

Table1cBenchmarkingTFANetWorthtoFinancialAccounts

(Billions)FAConceptuallyEquivalentValue

BenchmarkedTFAEstimateusingSCF

Non-financialAssets: 33,745.4 33,746.3FinancialAssets: 46,914.5 46,913.6Liabilities: 13,382.4 11,084.3NetWorth: 67,277.5 69,575.5

Table2.DistributionalEffectsoftheTCJA,2019

TFAEstimates JCT(2017a)Estimates

IncomeCategory

Avg.TaxRateUnder

PresentLaw

Avg.TaxRateUnder

TJCA Change

Avg.TaxRateUnder

PresentLaw

Avg.TaxRateUnder

TJCA ChangeLessthan10,000 7.25% 6.46% -0.79% 9.10% 8.60% -0.50%10,000to20,000 4.04% 3.25% -0.79% -0.70% -1.20% -0.50%20,000to30,000 3.05% 1.93% -1.12% 3.90% 3.40% -0.50%30,000to40,000 7.14% 5.80% -1.34% 7.90% 7.00% -0.90%40,000to50,000 9.58% 8.27% -1.30% 10.90% 9.90% -1.00%50,000to75,000 11.43% 10.01% -1.43% 14.80% 13.50% -1.30%75,000to100,000 13.87% 12.33% -1.53% 17.00% 15.60% -1.40%100,000to200,000 18.48% 16.68% -1.80% 20.90% 19.40% -1.50%200,000to500,000 25.34% 23.17% -2.17% 26.40% 23.90% -2.50%500,000to1,000,000 33.78% 31.23% -2.55% 30.90% 27.80% -3.10%1,000,000andover 38.30% 36.92% -1.38% 32.50% 30.20% -2.30%

Page 20: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

18

Table3ShareofRemainingLifetimeSpendingofTop1%,byCohort

CohortAgeRange OldLaw TCJAAssumingNoWageIncrease

TCJAAssuminga5.5%WageIncrease

20-29 12.5% 12.3% 12.3%

30-39 10.7% 10.7% 10.6%

40-49 12.9% 12.9% 12.8%

50-59 18.3% 18.3% 18.2%

60-69 19.7% 19.7% 19.7%

70-79 21.7% 21.8% 21.8%

Table4ShareofRemainingLifetimeSpendingof3rdQuintle,byCohort

CohortAgeRange OldLaw TCJAAssumingNoWageIncrease

TCJAAssuminga5.5%WageIncrease

20-29 14.9% 14.9% 15.0%

30-39 15.6% 15.5% 15.6%

40-49 14.1% 14.1% 14.1%

50-59 10.1% 10.1% 10.1%

60-69 10.3% 10.3% 10.3%

70-79 10.2% 10.2% 10.2%

Table5ShareofRemainingLifetimeSpendingofBottomQuintle,byCohort

CohortAgeRange OldLaw TCJAAssumingNoWageIncrease

TCJAAssuminga5.5%WageIncrease

20-29 7.4% 7.3% 7.2%

30-39 7.3% 7.2% 7.1%

40-49 6.5% 6.4% 6.3%

50-59 5.3% 5.3% 5.2%

60-69 5.3% 5.3% 5.2%

70-79 5.6% 5.6% 5.6%

Page 21: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

19

Table6ShareofRemainingLifetimeTaxesPaidByTop1%,byCohort

CohortAgeRange OldLaw TCJAAssumingNoWageIncrease

TCJAAssuminga5.5%WageIncrease

20-29 13.9% 14.2% 14.1%

30-39 15.5% 15.8% 15.7%

40-49 16.6% 16.9% 16.8%

50-59 24.1% 24.6% 24.4%

60-69 25.5% 25.8% 25.6%

70-79 26.4% 26.3% 26.3%

Table7ShareofRemainingLifetimeTaxesof3rdQuintile,byCohort

CohortAgeRange OldLaw TCJAAssumingNoWageIncrease

TCJAAssuminga5.5%WageIncrease

20-29 13.2% 13.1% 13.1%

30-39 12.5% 12.4% 12.5%

40-49 11.8% 11.7% 11.9%

50-59 7.8% 7.7% 7.8%

60-69 6.6% 6.6% 6.7%

70-79 6.4% 6.4% 6.4%

Table8ShareofRemainingLifetimeNetTaxesofBottomQuintile,byCohort

CohortAgeRange OldLaw TCJAAssumingNoWageIncrease

TCJAAssuminga5.5%WageIncrease

20-29 3.3% 3.2% 3.3%

30-39 3.0% 3.0% 3.1%

40-49 2.6% 2.6% 2.7%

50-59 1.7% 1.8% 1.8%

60-69 2.0% 2.1% 2.1%

70-79 2.7% 2.8% 2.8%

Page 22: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

20

Table9AverageRemainingLifetimeSpendingandPercentageIncreasesRelativetoNoReform,Top1%,byCohort

CohortAgeRange OldLaw TCJAAssumingNoWageIncrease

TCJAAssuminga5.5%WageIncrease

20-29 $13,409,166 $13,581,823(1.3%) $14,115,969(5.3%)

30-39 $15,496,134 $15,841,922(2.2%) $16,351,594(5.5%)

40-49 $21,758,600 $22,079,223(1.5%) $22,594,045(3.8%)

50-59 $35,965,838 $36,425,132(1.3%) $36,937,566(2.7%)

60-69 $33,996,632 $34,444,460(1.3%) $34,576,286(1.7%)

70-79 $33,309,785 $33,699,673(1.2%) $33,745,728(1.3%)

Table10AverageRemainingLifetimeSpending(PercentageIncreases)

RelativetoNoReform,ThirdQuintile,byCohort

CohortAgeRange OldLaw TCJAAssumingNoWageIncrease

TCJAAssuminga5.5%WageIncrease

20-29 $957,345 $981,921(2.6%) $1,024,094(7.0%)

30-39 $1,139,022 $1,164,084(2.2%) $1,208,715(6.1%)

40-49 $1,213,620 $1,236,779(1.9%) $1,276,088(5.1%)

50-59 $994,140 $1,007,751(1.4%) $1,030,398(3.6%)

60-69 $932,663 $939,748(0.8%) $945,040(1.3%)

70-79 $819,781 $823,861(0.5%) $824,352(0.6%)

Table11AverageRemainingLifetimeSpendingandPercentageIncreases

RelativetoNoReform,BottomQuintile,byCohort

CohortAgeRange OldLaw TCJAAssumingNoWageIncrease

TCJAAssuminga5.5%WageIncrease

20-29 $473,679 $480,083(1.4%) $489,659(3.4%)

30-39 $539,698 $545,650(1.1%) $553,349(2.5%)

40-49 $558,498 $562,458(0.7%) $569,748(2.0%)

50-59 $522,383 $524,027(0.3%) $525,095(0.5%)

60-69 $481,259 $481,570(0.1%) $481,922(0.1%)

70-79 $451,966 $452,051(0.0%) $452,198(0.1%)

Page 23: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

21

Table12AverageChangesandShareofTotalChangesinRemainingLifetimeSpending,Ages40-49,AssumingNoWageIncrease

Quintile

AverageChangeinRemainingLifetimeSpending

ShareofTotalChangesinRemainingLifetimeSpending

PercentageChangeinAverageSpending

MinimumPercentageChangeinSpending

MaximumPercentageChangeinSpending

Lowest $3,960 2.34% 0.75% -5.539% 2.77%

Second $13,957 8.32% 1.66% -1.209% 3.09%

Third $23,159 13.71% 1.94% -0.477% 3.44%

Fourth $34,966 20.74% 2.05% -0.053% 4.09%

Highest $92,315 54.89% 1.97% -2.063% 5.88%

Top5% $183,803 27.39% 1.79% -2.063% 5.48%

Top1% $320,624 9.74% 1.36% -2.063% 4.08%

Table13AverageChangesandShareofTotalChangesinRemainingLifetimeSpending,Ages20-29,AssumingNoWageIncrease

Quintile

AverageChangeinRemainingLifetimeSpending

ShareofTotalChangesinRemainingLifetimeSpending

PercentageChangeinAverageSpending

MinimumPercentageChangeinSpending

MaximumPercentageChangeinSpending

Lowest $6,404 4.33% 1.31% -0.300% 3.14%

Second $14,127 9.59% 2.10% 0.273% 4.06%

Third $24,576 16.56% 2.61% 1.513% 3.67%

Fourth $38,021 25.58% 2.71% 0.220% 4.16%

Highest $65,287 43.95% 2.44% -0.973% 5.25%

Top5% $110,070 18.60% 2.16% -0.973% 5.25%

Top1% $172,658 6.96% 0.85% -0.973% 5.25%

Page 24: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

22

Table14AverageChangesandShareofTotalChangesinRemainingLifetimeSpending,Ages70-79,AssumingNoWageIncrease

Quintile

AverageChangeinRemainingLifetimeSpending

ShareofTotalChangesinRemainingLifetimeSpending

PercentageChangeinAverageSpending

MinimumPercentageChangeinSpending

MaximumPercentageChangeinSpending

Lowest $84 0.12% 0.02% -0.074% 0.22%

Second $1,490 2.06% 0.26% -0.090% 1.72%

Third $4,080 5.72% 0.48% -0.229% 1.85%

Fourth $12,888 17.99% 0.95% -0.046% 2.48%

Highest $52,911 74.12% 1.07% -0.935% 4.09%

Top5% $139,286 49.15% 1.17% -0.935% 4.09%

Top1% $389,887 28.52% 1.27% -0.935% 4.09%

Figure1OldTaxLaw–AverageRemainingLifetimeandCurrent-Year

NetTaxRates,byPercentileRange,Ages40-49

-41.6%

9.1% 15.8%

20.8% 29.8% 32.3% 34.1%

-12.1%

21.7% 25.0% 28.2% 33.2% 35.3% 37.8%

Lowest Second Third Fourth Highest Top5% Top1%AverageLifetimeNetTaxRate AverageCurrentYearNetTaxRate

Page 25: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

23

Figure2TCJA–AverageRemainingLifetimeandCurrent-YearNetTaxRates,byPercentileRange,Ages40-49,AssumingNoRiseinWages

Figure3TCJA–AverageRemainingLifetimeandCurrent-YearNetTaxRates,byPercentileRange,Ages40-49,Assuming5.5%RiseinWages

-42.6%

7.7% 14.2%

19.2% 28.3% 30.9% 33.1%

-13.3%

20.4% 23.8% 27.0% 31.8% 33.8% 37.0%

Lowest Second Third Fourth Highest Top5% Top1%AverageLifetimeNetTaxRate AverageCurrentYearNetTaxRate

-37.9%

9.0% 15.3%

20.0% 28.9% 31.5% 33.7%

-11.0%

21.4% 24.5% 27.6% 32.2% 34.3% 37.3%

Lowest Second Third Fourth Highest Top5% Top1%AverageLifetimeNetTaxRate AverageCurrentYearNetTaxRate

Page 26: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

24

Figure4ComparingPre-andPost-ReformLifetimeSpending,Ages40-49,Assuming0%RiseinRealWages

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

8,000

9,000

10,000

0 2,000 4,000 6,000 8,000 10,000

Remaining

Lifetim

eSp

ending

Und

erTCJA

Thou

sand

s

RemainingLifetimeSpendingUnderOldTaxSystem

Thousands

Page 27: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

25

Figure5ComparingPre-andPost-ReformLifetimeSpending,Ages40-49,Assuming5.5%RiseinRealWages

0

1,000

2,000

3,000

4,000

5,000

6,000

7,000

8,000

9,000

10,000

0 2,000 4,000 6,000 8,000 10,000

Remaining

Lifetim

eSp

ending

Und

erTCJA

Thou

sand

s

RemainingLifetimeSpendingUnderOldTaxSystem

Thousands

Page 28: The New Tax Bill -- Winners and Losers 06-30-2018auerbach/The New Tax Bill -- Winners and... · This paper responds to these limitations in identifying winners and losers under the

26

Figure6Shareof40-49CohortbyPercentChangeinRemainingLifetimeSpending,Assuming0%RiseinRealWages

Figure7Shareof40-49CohortbyPercentChangeinRemainingLifetimeSpending,Assuming5.5%RiseinRealWages

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

3.0%

3.5%

-1.00%

-0.62%

-0.23%

0.16

%

0.54

%

0.93

%

1.31

%

1.70

%

2.08

%

2.47

%

2.85

%

3.24

%

3.62

%

4.01

%

4.39

%

4.78

%

5.16

%

5.55

%

5.93

%

6.32

%

6.70

%

7.09

%

7.47

%

7.86

%

8.24

%

8.63

%

9.01

%

9.40

%

9.78

%

Share

PercentChangeinRemainingLifetimeSpending

0.0%

0.5%

1.0%

1.5%

2.0%

2.5%

-1.00%

-0.62%

-0.23%

0.16

%

0.54

%

0.93

%

1.31

%

1.70

%

2.08

%

2.47

%

2.85

%

3.24

%

3.62

%

4.01

%

4.39

%

4.78

%

5.16

%

5.55

%

5.93

%

6.32

%

6.70

%

7.09

%

7.47

%

7.86

%

8.24

%

8.63

%

9.01

%

9.40

%

9.78

%

Share

PercentChangeinRemainingLifetimeSpending