the long-term consequences of youth housing for...

14
Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858 Available online at www.sciencedirect.com ScienceDirect The long-term consequences of youth housing for childbearing and higher education Cecilia Enström Öst a , Mats Wilhelmsson b,a Institute for Housing and Urban Research (IBF), Uppsala University, Uppsala, Sweden b Department of Real Estate Economics, KTH, S-100 44, Stockholm, Sweden Received 3 December 2018; received in revised form 23 April 2019; accepted 28 May 2019 Available online 11 June 2019 Abstract The lack of housing in areas where young adults have greater opportunities to study and get work complicates young adults’ entry into the adulthood. Difficulties in accessing housing may therefore delay childbearing and may negatively have an effect on education opportunities. To increase housing accessibility, some municipalities have earmarked apartments for young adults. These “youth dwellings” are criticized for being small and not necessarily facilitating family formation and fertility, better suiting students’ needs. We have in this paper compared the long-term pattern of childbearing and education for young adults that entered their housing market through small cheap youth housing with those youngsters that received a rental apartment from the ordinary housing stock. To be able to draw the conclusion that differences in fertility and educational pattern between these two groups comes from the different housing situation and not from differences in in preferences when it comes to childbearing or individual prerequisites for higher education, we have used a geocoded data and information on the individual’s family background as well as a matching technique to create a comparison group that are similar to the treatment group in several aspects. The present results indicate that building affordable housing that is small and space efficient is sufficient and positive if the aim is to promote higher education. Affordable housing is on the other hand not enough to promote childbearing, instead, it seems to inhibit childbearing until there is a possibility of moving on in the housing career. Our result also indicates that the next step need not necessarily be homeownership, as earlier research has indicated. Entering the housing market via youth housing and then being able to move on to rental Corresponding author. E-mail address: [email protected] (M. Wilhelmsson). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2019.05.008 0161-8938/© 2019 The Author(s). Published by Elsevier Inc. on behalf of The Society for Policy Modeling. This is an open access article under the CC BY license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

Upload: others

Post on 18-Oct-2020

3 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

ScienceDirect

The long-term consequences of youth housing forchildbearing and higher education

Cecilia Enström Öst a, Mats Wilhelmsson b,∗a Institute for Housing and Urban Research (IBF), Uppsala University, Uppsala, Sweden

b Department of Real Estate Economics, KTH, S-100 44, Stockholm, Sweden

Received 3 December 2018; received in revised form 23 April 2019; accepted 28 May 2019Available online 11 June 2019

Abstract

The lack of housing in areas where young adults have greater opportunities to study and get workcomplicates young adults’ entry into the adulthood. Difficulties in accessing housing may therefore delaychildbearing and may negatively have an effect on education opportunities. To increase housing accessibility,some municipalities have earmarked apartments for young adults. These “youth dwellings” are criticizedfor being small and not necessarily facilitating family formation and fertility, better suiting students’ needs.We have in this paper compared the long-term pattern of childbearing and education for young adults thatentered their housing market through small cheap youth housing with those youngsters that received a rentalapartment from the ordinary housing stock. To be able to draw the conclusion that differences in fertilityand educational pattern between these two groups comes from the different housing situation and not fromdifferences in in preferences when it comes to childbearing or individual prerequisites for higher education,we have used a geocoded data and information on the individual’s family background as well as a matchingtechnique to create a comparison group that are similar to the treatment group in several aspects. The presentresults indicate that building affordable housing that is small and space efficient is sufficient and positiveif the aim is to promote higher education. Affordable housing is on the other hand not enough to promotechildbearing, instead, it seems to inhibit childbearing until there is a possibility of moving on in the housingcareer. Our result also indicates that the next step need not necessarily be homeownership, as earlier researchhas indicated. Entering the housing market via youth housing and then being able to move on to rental

∗ Corresponding author.E-mail address: [email protected] (M. Wilhelmsson).

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2019.05.0080161-8938/© 2019 The Author(s). Published by Elsevier Inc. on behalf of The Society for Policy Modeling. This is anopen access article under the CC BY license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

Page 2: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

846 C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858

accommodation in the ordinary housing market also seems to have a positive effect on overall childbearing,although moving to cooperative housing or owned housing has an even larger effect.© 2019 The Author(s). Published by Elsevier Inc. on behalf of The Society for Policy Modeling. This is anopen access article under the CC BY license (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/).

Keywords: Housing market; Youth housing; Childbearing; Higher education; Propensity score matching

JEL Classification: I21; J13; R21; R31

1. Introduction

The increase in adult children living with their parents has raised important questions regard-ing household formation. Furthermore, the lack of housing in areas where young adults havegreater opportunities to study and get work complicates young adults’ entry into the housingmarket. Earlier research has found that housing and childbearing are closely connected and diffi-culties accessing the housing market may possibly lead to delayed childbearing (see, e.g., Mulder,2006, 2013; Pinnelli, 1995; Castiglioni & Dalla Zuanna, 1994; Krishnan & Krotki, 1993; Clark,2012) and may negatively influence education opportunities (see, e.g., Cunningham, Harwood,& Hall, 2010; Dworsky, 2008; Garriss-Hardy & Vrooman, 2005; Crowley 2003; Conley, 2001;Rosenbaum, 1995). But is affordable housing sufficient to promote childbearing and education?

Leaving the parental home occurs for various reasons, the role of available housing likelydiffers for each reason. Young adults who want to leave home for education have little latitude forpostponement and are likely to move even if they have to accept substandard housing (Mulder,2006, p. 406). Those who want to leave the parental home for household formation have morelatitude to wait until they have found suitable or/and affordable housing. For example, it hasbeen demonstrated that higher housing costs are associated with lower probabilities of leavingthe parental home to live with a partner, an association not found for those leaving the parentalhome to live alone (Mulder & Clark, 2000).

Family formation has been demonstrated to be connected to homeownership tenure. Studieshave also found that the decisions to become a homeowner and have children are made simulta-neously (Malmberg, 2010, Enström Öst, 2012a, Kulu & Steele, 2013). Furthermore, it has beendemonstrated that the likelihood of having children is greater for homeowners and that the transi-tion to first-time homeownership often occurs in anticipation of parenthood (Mulder & Wagner,2001; Feijten & Mulder, 2002, Mulder, 2006, Kulu, 2008, Holland, 2012). However, having smallamounts of equity in ones home reduces the ability to realize a desired move (Ferreira, Gyourko,& Tracy, 2010). An affordable housing market may enable smooth entrance into the housingmarket, perhaps via a small cheap apartment, enabling later progress in the housing career tohigher-quality housing (Mulder, 2006, 2013). If young people succeed in leaving the parentalhome and enter the housing market in a small dwelling, this may positively affect childbearing ifsubsequent access to high-quality housing is easy. However, if such housing is scarce, prices arehigh, and/or mortgage providers are strict, young people might postpone childbearing until theyfind a house suitable for family formation, which may reduce the number of children born (cf.Chiuri & Jappelli, 2003). Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women whofeel more secure about their housing conditions are more likely to plan to have their first child.Simon and Tamura (2009) and Clark (2012) have explicitly investigated the effect of housing costs

Page 3: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858 847

on childbearing. Both studies show that first birth is significantly delayed in an expensive housingmarket. Liu and Clark (2016) demonstrates that an increase in the cost of renting is predicted todecrease the number of children born by renting households. However, the effect of higher houseprice is ambiguous and depends on the initial holdings of housing and the willingness to substitutebetween children and other goods.

The housing market in Sweden, especially in the capital Stockholm, is increasingly difficult foryoung adults to enter (Bokriskommittén, 2014; Swedish union of tenants, 2015). This market ischaracterized by increasing prices and housing costs and by housing construction that has laggedbehind population growth (The Swedish National Board of Housing, Building and Planning,2013). Queues to obtain rental apartments are growing and cooperative apartment prices are high.Studies indicate that a generation of young people may have little or no chance of accessing thehousing market unless they are rich, well paid, or/and have generous and wealthy parents (cf.Enström Öst, 2012b).

Fertility research commonly relates the relatively high Swedish fertility to the characteristicsof the Swedish welfare regime that, for example, may promote female labour-market attachmentby making it easier to combine work and family life (see, e.g. Andersson & Scott, 2007). However,along with indications of an inaccessible housing market for young people, the average age atwhich women bear their first child has increased in Sweden by approximately one year over afive-year period (cf. Andersson, 1999, 2000; Statistics Sweden, 2011). Recent years have also seenreports of students in higher education being forced out of larger cities, such as Stockholm, becauseof difficulties finding accommodation. To try to increase the accessibility of the housing market,housing projects targeting young adults have been started in Sweden. Several municipalitieshave earmarked small apartments for young adults to help them compete for an access to rentalapartments.

By examining a housing project for young adults in Stockholm, initiated as early as 1996, thisstudy advances our understanding of whether building small apartments for young adults maysolve problems related to housing shortage for young. This study will investigate the causal effectsof youth housing on higher education and parenthood. To our knowledge, no earlier studies havethis focus.

The dataset for this study contains information on young people who gained access to thehousing market in 1996 via a particular youth housing project in Stockholm. This study exploresthe development of their fertility pattern and education level during a time period of 14 years afterthey entered the housing market and compares them with the fertility and educational pattern ofa matched group of young people similar in several respects. Matching is used to evaluate theeffect of youth housing by comparing those young adults that moved into the youth house in 1996with those young adults that moved into an ordinary rental apartment the same time period. Thegoal of this matching procedure is, for every young adult that moved into the youth house, to findat least one young adult with similar observable characteristics against whom the effect of youthhousing can be assessed. With the data available for this project we can match on explanatoryvariables five years before the youth house was defined. By this matching procedure, it enables acomparison of outcomes among young adults moving into youth housing and young adults thatmoves into the ordinary rental housing stock to estimate the effect of youth housing reducing biasdue to confounding.

The present result indicates that having access to small youth housing reduces the probabilityof becoming a parent. However, if the rest of the housing market is mobile, i.e., enables youngadults to move on in their housing careers, the total effect on becoming parent is positive. Theeffect from living in youth house on completing higher education is positive and independent of

Page 4: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

848 C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858

the mobility of the rest of the housing market. This result confirms that the housing market hasrepercussions for both the fertility and the educational patterns.

The paper is organized as follows: The next section discusses the theory of household formationand the Swedish housing market during the study period and describes the studied youth housingcase. Section 3 presents the data and the empirical strategy and Section 4 presents the results. Thepaper ends by presenting the conclusions and discussing the policy implications of the presentfindings.

2. Background

2.1. Theory of housing and household formation

A large body of empirical work emphasizing the role of life course events on mobility, suchas leaving the parental home and get birth to a child (Clark & Dieleman, 1996). Transition tolife stages involving higher levels of commitment, such as parenthood, lead to requirements forlong-stay housing and to changing preferences over dwelling attributes. However, desires formobility may be prompted by a wide range of life events, but desires cannot always be realized.Income and wealth constraints, transactions costs that vary with tenure, social ties, the supply ofdwellings and the functioning of the housing and mortgage markets all affect whether a desiredmove will in fact be realized (Kiel, 1994; Linneman & Wachter, 1989; Stein, 1995; Venti & Wise,1984; Wheaton, 1990; Helderman et al. 2004; Belot & Ermisch, 2009; Ermisch & Washbrook,2012).

Mulder (2006) has explored the relationship between housing and household formation. Obvi-ously, to move from parental homes and form households, young people need somewhere to live.In a well-functioning housing market, housing demand equals housing supply and all householdscan access housing that meets their needs. However, housing prices, housing supply, and the abil-ity to obtain housing loans are limiting factors, especially for young adults who have had limitedtime to accumulate savings for home down payments. Some young adults may therefore postponehousehold formation if they cannot find suitable affordable housing. The degree to which theavailability of housing affects household formation, however, probably depends on the urgencywith which people want to form new households. Young adults who need to move, for example,for work or higher education, might have little latitude for postponement and may therefore moveeven though they must accept substandard housing. However, those moving to cohabit, marry,or have children may have more latitude to wait until they find suitable housing. Furthermore,young people who succeed in leaving parental homes, for example, to live in student housing orsmaller apartments, might still postpone childbearing if they think housing of a certain quality isa precondition (see, e.g., Ineichen, 1979, 1981; Ström, 2010). Lovenheim and Mumford (2013)also find a statistically significant positive relationship between house price changes and fertilityfor homeowners. However, no statistically significant negative relationship between house pricechanges and fertility was found for renters. Dettling and Kearney (2014) find that high housingprices have a negative effect on the fertility of renters but a positive effect for home owners.

2.2. The Swedish housing market

The Swedish housing market has three dominant tenure forms: single-family housing, cooper-ative multi-family housing, and multi-family rental housing. All rental housing units are subjectto rent control. In the case of cooperative housing, the property is owned by a cooperative asso-

Page 5: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858 849

ciation. Each resident owns a share of the cooperative and occupies an apartment with tenancyrights nearly as strong as those of full ownership. Cooperative housing is traded on an ordinaryfree housing market and in practice is regarded as a form of owner-occupied housing, althoughthis is not precisely correct from a judicial perspective. The standard of housing is generally highin Sweden, irrespective of tenure type.

The housing market in Sweden has undergone several gradual and substantial changes in recentdecades. The government housing policy of granting substantial subsidies to all new housingconstruction changed in the early 1990s, and subsidies were gradually phased out over a decadewithout being replaced with other investment incentives. This has resulted in the low productionof new housing of all types, and housing construction has lagged population growth since 1991,as well as very high house prices and housing costs.

Swedish house prices increased by over 200% in the 17 years from 1996 to 2013, a periodwhen general consumer prices increased by only 60%. Furthermore, the price level of houses inthe first quarter of 2015 was 12 percent higher than in the first quarter of 2014. However, this trendis even stronger in the market for cooperative apartments where the prices was 17 percent higherduring the first quarter of 2015 than in the corresponding quarter of 2014 (The Swedish NationalBoard of Housing, Building and Planning, 2015). After the 1991 tax system reform, which ledto sharply increased rents (Englund, Hendershott, & Turner, 1995), the vacancy rate in the rentalsector started to climb and was quite high by 1998. Since then, vacancy rates have decreased andtoday several counties in Sweden report a housing supply shortage (The Swedish National Boardof Housing, Building and Planning, 2015). In 2015, only 40 percent of Sweden’s young adultslived in a home of their own. This is the lowest percentage ever measured in Sweden (Swedishunion of tenants, 2015). Furthermore, in 2015, 20% of young adults who had children lived witha relative, in a rented room or in a student residence.

Stockholm is the largest and most dynamic regional housing submarket in Sweden; it isSweden’s most heterogeneous in terms of tenure forms, price variation, and neighbourhood struc-ture, though, from an international perspective, it is comparatively small, homogenous, and easyfor housing consumers to conceive of and analyse. The official recommendation to those whowant a rental apartment in inner Stockholm is to register as an applicant and stay on a waitinglist. Over the last two decades, in-migration to Stockholm has increased substantially. With pop-ulation growth substantially exceeding housing supply growth, the Stockholm housing marketis now suffering from a pronounced housing shortage (Andersson & Söderberg, 2012). About520,000 people were waiting for an apartment in Stockholm County in January 2016 and theaverage waiting time for a rental apartment in the region exceeds eight years. When it comes tostudent housing, approximately 80,000 students are waiting for only 12,000 student dwellings.1

2.3. “Youth house”

In 1995 a housing company in Stockholm decided to earmark an entire 150-apartment propertyin inner Stockholm for young adults aged 18–25 years. These apartments had formerly beenearmarked for nurses working at the nearby hospital. The apartments were all small, i.e., 30square metres in floor area comprising one room with a kitchenette, and were deemed fit foryouth by the housing company. Earmarking these apartments for young adults therefore requiredno major or costly renovations by the housing company.

1 Source: The Stockholm Housing Service.

Page 6: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

850 C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858

The property, located in inner Stockholm and built in the 1950s, has been subject to no default-enhancing renovations since completion. To obtain one of the units, which are all rental apartments,young adults must apply at the housing company or at the housing service that allocates vacantrental apartments in Stockholm. Applicants aged 18–25 years who register interest and wait thelongest will receive a vacant apartment.

The rents for these youth apartments could be considered quite low, especially relative to thecosts of the housing alternatives available to these young adults. Most rental apartments in thatsame area but in the ordinary housing stock, i.e., not earmarked apartments, have undergonedefault-enhancing renovations with the result that their rents have increased significantly. Thewaiting time for such apartments is over 15 years, indicating that this is an attractive area to whichyoung adults without the possibility of obtaining an earmarked apartment would normally havedifficulties gaining access, unless they can buy an apartment, which is very expensive. A oneroom rental apartment in the ordinary housing stock is also on average 10 square metres largerthan the apartments in this Youth House.

3. Data and empirical strategy

3.1. Data and sample

The dataset is extracted from a database provided by Statistics Sweden. This database containsinformation on all individuals who have resided in Sweden, including their demographic andsocioeconomic situation as well as geocoded data with coordinates and neighbourhood area codesfor where the individuals live. Using this database, it is possible to link records between individualsand generations, because the data include a household identity code and, for every individual bornafter 1932, a specific identity code for the individual’s mother and father.

The sample used in this study consists of young adults aged 18–25 years who moved into theproperty earmarked for young adults (“Youth House”) in Stockholm in 1996. These individualswere defined by identifying the geographic coordinates of the property, which is located near alarge hospital and is surrounded by a green area. No other residential properties are located imme-diately adjacent to the Youth House. Since we in our data also have the geographical coordinatesfor everyone, we have been able to define the young adults living a maximum of 30 m from theproperty geographical coordinates in 1996, i.e., those 112 young adults aged 18–25 years whomoved into Youth House in 1996.

This group of young adults will constitute the treatment group of this study. We will followthem in our data until they have a first child, complete their higher education, or fourteen yearshave elapsed (i.e., until 2010). Their childbearing and education patterns will be compared tothose of a matched group of young adults, i.e., a comparison group of young adults similar tomembers of the treatment group in several respects but who did not move into youth housing. Thematching procedure for defining the comparison group of young adults is explained in the nextsection.

3.2. Propensity score and matching

We are in this paper interested in comparing the long-term pattern of childbearing and educationfor young adults that entered their housing market through small cheap youth housing with thosewho did not and instead received a rental apartment from the ordinary housing stock. However,those individuals that choose to live in small cheap youth housing may differ from those that prefer

Page 7: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858 851

other rental apartments in terms of different attitudes towards education and family formation, forexample. A simple comparison of their education and childbearing pattern would then be biasedby these confounding variables. This confounding by indication is almost invariably present innon-randomised studies.

Rosenbaum and Rubin (1983) proposed the use of propensity scores as a method for allowingfor confounding by indication. Propensity may be defined as an individual’s probability of beingtreated with the intervention of, in this case, entering the housing market through youth housing,given the information available about that individual. The propensity score provides a singlemetric that summarises all the information from the explanatory variables. Individual subjectsmay have the same or similar propensity scores, yet some will start their housing career in youthhousing and others will not. An assumption of propensity score analysis is that a fair comparisonof treatment outcomes can be made between subjects with similar propensity scores who eitherdid or did not start their housing career in youth housing. The propensity score may be estimatedfor each subject from parametric regression in which the treatment is the dependent variable. Afeature of this approach is that explanatory variables are selected based on their ability to predictexposure to the intervention of interest.

Matching is a popular approach employed to include propensity scores in the analysis, andempirical examples can be found in very diverse fields of study. Matching requires that eachtreated individual is matched with one or several individuals having the same or similar propensityscore. By contrasting the outcomes between treated and untreated sets of individuals with similarpropensity for treatment, we can estimate the average treatment effect.

3.2.1. Strategy usedTo create a balanced (see, e.g., Rosenbaum and Rubin 1983) comparison group of young adults

in this study, we use the following strategy.First, we identify where the individuals who moved into the Youth House in 1996 grow up,

i.e. we identify the geographical coordinates for the individuals’ parental homes five years beforethey moved into the Youth House, i.e. in 1991. We then identify all young adults under 25 yearsold, with no children and with no higher education, who lives within 100 m of each individual inthe treatment group in 1991. The propensity scores, i.e. the probability of entering the housingmarket through Youth housing, are estimated for all these youngsters as well as for the treated.The propensity score has been estimated using a Probit model in which the dependent variable isthe probability of moving in to the Youth House in 1996.2 The covariates included in the modelare sex, age, and final primary school grade as well as family income, parental homeownershipstatus, and whether the parents live in single- or multifamily housing. All covariates refer to thesituation in year 1991, five years before the Youth House was defined.

After having estimated the propensity scores for all youngsters, we perform a 10 nearest-neighbor matching to identify those young adults under 25 years old with no children and nohigher education living close to each individual in the treatment group with a similar propensityscore and five years before the Youth House was created. Nearest-neighbour matching identifiesa control case with a propensity score closest to that of each treatment case (see, e.g., Gu &Rosenbaum, 1993). Here, we match with replacement, meaning that after a control case is usedas a match, it is put back into the sample, and can be used again to match other treated units aswell.

2 We also estimated a logit model to compute the propensity scores; this did not alter the results.

Page 8: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

852 C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858

Table 1Balance of the variables.

Variables Mean, treatmentgroup

Mean, comparisongroup

t-value

Sex [female = 1 and male = 2] 1.56 1.58 −0.19Age [year] 20.78 20.82 −0.14Final primary school grade [min = 1 and max = 5] 3.18 3.08 0.14Family income [tSEK/year] 711.54 727.49 −0.22Parental homeowner status [Owned housing or

cooperative = 1, rental = 0]0.38 0.37 0.06

Parents live in single-family house [Single-familyhouse = 1, multi-family house = 0]

0.30 0.29 0.17

N 112 985Rubin’s B = 5.7Rubin’s R = 1.01

After this matching procedure, we have tested whether the treated and control groups arebalanced with respect to the observed characteristics. The result is presented in Table 1.

Table 1 show the means of the variables for the treatment and matched control groups and ourbalancing test of the explanatory variables cannot reject equality of means between the treated andthe matched comparisons; the t-values indicate no significant differences between these groups,indicating the presence of assessed balance. With 112 individuals in the treatment group and 985in the comparison group, 170 of the comparisons appear more than once in the matched data. Fora sample to be considered sufficiently balanced, Rubin (2001) recommends that Rubin’s B, i.e.,the absolute standardized difference of the mean linear index, of the propensity score betweenthe treated and (matched) control groups, be less than 25 and that Rubin’s R, i.e., the ratio of thevariance of the propensity score index, between the treated and (matched) comparison groups,be 0.5–2.0. Both those recommendations are fulfilled, so the matching procedure is deemedsatisfactory.

3.3. Empirical strategy

A Cox proportional hazard model is used to estimate the transition to parenthood and comple-tion of higher education. A Cox regression model requires no assumption as to functional formand is not biased by right censoring. The dependent variable used in the empirical analysis is thehazard rate:

h (tX(t) = limΔt→0

P ((t, t + ΔtT ≥ t; X(t))

Δt, (1)

where T is the time (year) of the birth of a child or of completing higher education, t is any fixedpoint of time under risk, and p (t, t + Δt) is the probability of the event occurring in interval(t, t + Δt). X(t) is the vector of covariates. The variable of main interest is a treatment variableindicating whether the individual moved into Youth House in 1996, i.e., whether the individualbelongs to the treatment group, or whether they instead moved into the ordinary housing stock.

We will also include variables indicating when an individual moved from Youth House and towhich tenure type he or she moved, i.e., other rental apartment, cooperative apartment, or ownedhousing. 78 percent of the individuals in the treatment group moved from the Youth House duringthe observation period. About 40 percent of those moved to cooperative or owned housing.

Page 9: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858 853

Note that, after matching a sample, one can simply use the difference between the treatmentand control groups to estimate the average treatment effect. However, even if we have a matchedcomparison group, we still want to check whether other variables not included in the matchingprocedure may, over time, affect the childbearing decision or the decision to become educated,differently between the treated and the compared subjects. These variables are welfare benefits,income from work, and income from capital. However, including these covariates did not alterthe result for the treatment variable or the conclusions of this study.

Young adults who remain childless or do not complete higher education are censored at theend of the observation period, i.e., in 2010.

When modelling a Cox proportional hazard model, a key assumption is the proportional haz-ards. Accordingly, we will perform some diagnostic tests for non-proportionality and estimateparametric models, i.e., the exponential and Weibull models.

4. Analysis

4.1. Becoming parent

Here we report the results of the Cox proportional hazard models. The tables present the hazardrates rather than the coefficients themselves. A hazard rate above 1 indicates increased risk and ahazard rate less than 1 decreased risk. The variable of main interest in all tables is Youth House, adummy variable indicating whether the individual moved into Youth House in 1996, i.e., whetherthe individual belongs to the treatment group. Other variables of interest are, as earlier mentioned,a dummy variable indicating the time point when an individual first moved from Youth House(i.e., Youth House moved) as well as dummy variables indicating the type of tenure to which theindividual first moved (i.e., Youth House moved to rental = moved to another rental apartment,Youth House moved to coop = moved to a cooperative, and Youth House moved to own = movedto owned housing).

Table 2 presents the results of the model with becoming parent as the outcome variable. Models1 and 2 present the model results including a variable indicating the time the individuals movefrom Youth House. The results indicate that living in Youth House has a large significant andnegative effect on childbearing comparing to those that instead moved into the ordinary housingstock, a result that is stable even when including covariates in the model. The hazard of becomingparent while in Youth House is 0.12. However, moving from Youth House greatly increases thehazard (a hazard of about 17) of becoming a parent, indicating the importance of a mobile housingmarket. This result remains when controlling for the type of tenure to which subjects move whenthey leave the Youth House (Models 3 and 4). The hazard of becoming parent are, as expected,largest for ownership. However, it is also surprisingly higher for those that move to cooperativeapartments than for those that move into a rental apartment in the ordinary housing stock, a hazardof about 26 compared to 15 for rentals. The results are stable though the sample is quite smalland even when including covariates in the models.

4.2. Higher education

Table 3 presents the results of the education model, i.e., the outcome of completing highereducation. Here, unlike in the childbearing case, we observe a significantly increased risk ofcompleting higher education for the treatment group, i.e., a positive effect of Youth House onhigher education, corresponding to a hazard of approximately 2.6.

Page 10: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

854

C.

Enström

Öst,

M.

Wilhelm

sson /

Journal of

Policy M

odeling 41

(2019) 845–858

Table 2Cox proportional hazard model – outcome becoming parent.

Model 1 Model 2 with covariates Model 3 Model 4 with covariates

Youth House 0.125*** (0.073) 0.124*** (0.072) 0.124*** (0.072) 0.124*** (0.072)Youth House moved 17.455*** (10.408) 17.025*** (10.056) – –Youth House moved to rental – – 15.153*** (9.170) 14.833*** (8.880)Youth House moved to coop – – 25.580*** (16.847) 26.019*** (16.960)Youth House moved to own – – 29.143*** (21.457) 27.240*** (19.947)Covariates No Yes No YesNo. of spells 6066 6066 6066 6066

Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** Significant at the 0.01%, ** 1%, and * 5% levels.

Page 11: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858 855

Table 3Cox proportional hazard model – outcome higher education.

Model 15 Model 16 with covariates

Youth House 2.523* (1.130) 2.752* (1.224)Youth House* moved 0.306 (0.199) 0.332 (0.226)Covariates No YesNo. of spells 7685 7685

Robust standard errors in parentheses. *** Significant at the 0.01%, ** 1%, and * 5% levels.

However, the variable indicating a move from Youth House was not significant in this case,indicating that a mobile housing market seems unimportant to the promotion of higher education.This result remains when controlling for the type of tenure to which subjects move (not presentedhere). None of those variables were significant.

4.3. Sensitivity tests

All the models were also estimated using the exponential and Weibull models. The Weibullmodel is more general and flexible than is the exponential model and allows for hazard rates thatare non-constant but monotonic. The results of both these models were in line with those of theCox model presented in Sections 4.1 and 4.2.

As already mentioned, a key assumption when testing such models concerns the proportionalhazards. We accordingly performed the Schoenfeld residuals test, developed by Therneau andGrambsch (2000), to test the proportional hazard assumption. We found no evidence that themodels with higher education as the outcome violated the proportional hazard assumption, northat the models with the outcome childbearing that did not include the variable indicating amove from Youth House violated the same assumption. For the other models, the results of theSchoenfeld residual test indicated non-proportional hazards. One solution to this potential problemis to interact the variables displaying signs of non-proportional hazards with the natural log oftime (Box-Steffensmeier & Zorn, 2001, p. 978) to explicitly allow the effect of the variable tovary across time. We did this for all variables that displayed signs of non-proportional hazards;this, however, did not alter the results. All the variables of interest were still highly significant,with the same estimate size as with the Cox model.

5. Conclusions and policy implications

The point of departure of this study was to examine the effect of youth dwellings, i.e., apart-ments earmarked for young adults, on young adults’ childbearing and education patterns. Youthdwellings are often small and lack proper kitchen facilities, and therefore do not necessarilyfacilitate family formation. If access to higher-quality housing is difficult because of scarcity,high prices, and strict mortgage provision, young people might postpone childbearing if housingof a certain standard is desirable when forming a family. However, young adults who leave theparental home for education may have little latitude for postponement and may therefore obtainan education despite living in substandard housing.

We have in this paper compared the long-term pattern of childbearing and education for youngadults that entered their housing market through small cheap youth housing with those youngstersthat received a rental apartment from the ordinary housing stock. To be able to draw the conclusion

Page 12: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

856 C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858

that differences in fertility and educational pattern between these two groups comes from thedifferent housing situation and not from differences in preferences when it comes to childbearingor individual prerequisites for higher education, we have used a geocoded data and information onthe individual’s family background as well as a matching technique to create a comparison group.An assumption of propensity score analysis is that a fair comparison of treatment outcomes canthen be made between subjects with similar propensity scores who either did or did not start theirhousing career in youth housing.

The present results indicate that gaining access to a small, low-rent inner-city apartment ear-marked for young adults may promote higher education but negatively affect childbearing unlessthe rest of the housing market is mobile, i.e., enables young adults to advance in their housingcareers. However, the effect of such housing on higher education is independent of mobility inthe rest of the housing market.

So, what are the policy implications of our finding? The key policy implications of these resultsare that:

• Building affordable housing that is small and space efficient is sufficient and positive if the aimis to promote higher education.

• Affordable housing is on the other hand not enough to promote childbearing, instead, it seemsto inhibit childbearing until there is a possibility of moving on in the housing career.

• Our result indicates also that the next step need not necessarily be homeownership, as earlierresearch has indicated. Entering the housing market via youth housing and then being able tomove on to rental accommodation in the ordinary housing market also seems to have a positiveeffect on overall childbearing, although moving to cooperative housing or owned housing hasan even larger effect.

These results may lead to a deeper understanding how policy makers may promote childbearingand higher education through the housing market, something that seems to be a necessity to attractand retain younger residents. Small apartments for younger people in an area where most elderlyor families with children live may also create a good dynamic and a variety of people. It alsocreates a broader service and store range and a good basis for public transport.

However, the present results do not allow us to determine the driving force of the resultsachieved by youth housing. Is it that young adults do not find the general concept of youth housingcompatible with childbearing, or is it that the dwellings are small and lack proper kitchen facilities,i.e., the housing size and standard do not meet the quality norms required for childbearing? Ordoes the relatively low rent make alternative accommodations seem too expensive, creating alock-in effect that postpones childbearing? Answering these questions requires more data andfurther research into youth housing.

References

Andersson, R., & Söderberg, B. (2012). Elimination of rent control in the Swedish rental housing market: Why and how?Journal of Housing Research, 21(2), 159–181.

Andersson, G. (1999). Childbearing trends in Sweden 1961–1997. European Journal of Population, 15(1), 1–24.Andersson, G. (2000). The impact of labour-force participation on childbearing behaviour: Pro-cyclical fertility in Sweden

during the 1980s and the 1990s. European Journal of Population, 16(4), 293–333.Andersson, G., & Scott, K. (2007). Childbearing dynamics of couples in a universalistic welfare state: The role of labor

market status, country of origin, and gender. Demographic Research, 17(30), 897–938.

Page 13: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858 857

Belot, M., & Ermisch, J. (2009). Friendship ties and geographical mobility: Evidence from Great Britain. Journal of theRoyal Statistical Society Series A, 172, 427–442.

Bokriskommittén. (2014). Framtidens bostadsmarknad. Vision för bostadspolitiken. The Future of the Housing Market.A Vision for Housing Policy.

Box-Steffensmeier, J., & Zorn, C. (2001). Duration models and proportional hazards in political science. American Journalof Political Science, 45(4), 972–988.

Castiglioni, M., & Dalla Zuanna, G. (1994). Innovation and tradition: Reproductive and marital behavior in Italy in the1970s and 1980s. European Journal of Population, 10(2), 107–142.

Chiuri, M. C., & Jappelli, T. (2003). Financial market imperfections and home ownership: A comparative study. EuropeanEconomic Review, 47(5), 857–875.

Conley, D. (2001). A room with a view or a room of one’s own? Housing and social stratification. Sociological Forum,16(2), 263–280.

Clark, W. A. V., & Dieleman, F. M. (1996). Households and housing: Choice and outcomes in the housing market. NewJersey: CUPR Press, Rutgers University.

Clark, W. A. V. (2012). Do women delay family formation in expensive housing markets? Demographic Research, 27,1–24.

Crowley, S. (2003). The Affordable Housing Crisis: Residential Mobility of Poor Families and School Mobility of PoorChildren. The Journal of Negro Education, 72(1), 22–38.

Cunningham, M., Harwood, R., & Hall, S. (2010). Residential instability and the McKinney–Vento homeless children andeducation program: What we know, plus gaps in research. Washington, DC: The Urban Institute.

Dettling, L. J., & Kearney, M. S. (2014). House prices and birth rates: The impact of the real estate market on the decisionto have a baby. Journal of Public Economics, 110, 82–100.

Dworsky, A. (2008). Educating homeless children in Chicago: A case study of children in the family regeneration program.Chicago, IL: Chapin Hall at the University of Chicago.

Englund, P., Hendershott, P. H., & Turner, B. (1995). The tax reform and the housing market. Swedish Economic PolicyReview, 2, 319–356.

Enström Öst, C. (2012a). Housing and children: Simultaneous decisions? A cohort study of young adults’ housing andfamily formation decision. Journal of Population Economics, 25(1), 349–366.

Enström Öst, C. (2012b). Parental wealth and first-time homeownership: A cohort study of family background and youngadults’ housing situation. Urban Studies, 49(10), 2137–2152.

Ermisch, J., & Washbrook, E. (2012). Residential mobility: Wealth demographic and housing market effects. ScottishJournal of Political Economy, 59(5), 483–499.

Feijten, P., & Mulder, C. H. (2002). The timing of household events and housing events in the Netherlands: A longitudinalperspective. Housing Studies, 17(5), 773–792.

Ferreira, F., Gyourko, J., & Tracy, J. (2010). Housing busts and housing mobility. Journal of Urban Economics, 68, 34–45.Garriss-Hardy, B., & Vrooman, C. (2005). School stability and school performance. Greensboro, NC: National Center

for Homeless Education, SERVE Center, the University of North Carolina at Greensboro.Gu, X. S., & Rosenbaum, P. R. (1993). Comparison of multivariate matching methods: Structures, distances and algorithms.

Journal of Computational & Graphical Statistics, 2(4), 405–420.Holland, J. (2012). Home and where the heart is: Marriage timing and joint home purchase. European Journal of

Population, 28(1), 65–89.Ineichen, B. (1979). Housing factors in the timing of weddings and first pregnancies. In C. C. Harris (Ed.), The sociology

of the family: New directions for Britain (sociological review monograph 28) (pp. 127–140). Keele, UK: Universityof Keele.

Ineichen, B. (1981). The housing decisions of young people. The British Journal of Sociology, 32(2), 252–258.Kiel, K. A. (1994). The impact of housing price appreciation on housing mobility. Journal of Housing Economics, 3,

92–108.Krishnan, V., & Krotki, K. J. (1993). Life cycle effects on home-ownership in Canada. Housing Studies, 8(2), 120–127.Kulu, H. (2008). Fertility and spatial mobility in the life course: Evidence from Austria. Environmental and Planning A,

40(3), 632–652.Kulu, H., & Steele, F. (2013). Interrelationships between childbearing and housing transitions in the family life course.

Demography, 50, 1687–1714.Linneman, P., & Wachter, S. (1989). The impacts of borrowing constraints on homeownership. Journal of the American

Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 17, 389–402.Liu, M., & Clark, J. (2016). The effect of the price or rental cost of housing on family size: A theoretical analysis with

reference to New Zealand. New Zealand Economic Papers, http://dx.doi.org/10.1080/00779954.2016.1199591

Page 14: The long-term consequences of youth housing for ...uu.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1368705/FULLTEXT01.pdf · Similarly, Vignoli, Rinesi, and Mussino (2013) find that women who

858 C. Enström Öst, M. Wilhelmsson / Journal of Policy Modeling 41 (2019) 845–858

Lovenheim, M. F., & Mumford, K. J. (2013). Do family wealth shocks affect fertility choices? Evidence from the housingmarket. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 95, 464–475.

Malmberg, B. (2010). Low fertility and the housing market: Evidence from Swedish regional data. European Journal ofPopulation, 26, 229–244.

Mulder, C. H. (2013). Family dynamics and housing: Conceptual issues and empirical findings. Demographic Research,29(14), 355–378.

Mulder, C. H. (2006). Population and housing: A two-sided relationship. Demographic Research, 15(13), 401–412.Mulder, C. H., & Wagner, M. (2001). The connections between family formation and first-time home ownership in the

context of West Germany and the Netherlands. European Journal of Population, 17(2), 137–164.Mulder, C. H., & Clark, W. A. V. (2000). Leaving home and leaving the state: Evidence from the United States. International

Journal of Population Geography, 6(6), 423–437.Pinnelli, A. (1995). Women’s condition, low fertility, and emerging union patterns in Europe. In K. O. Mason, & A.-M.

Jensen (Eds.), Gender and family change in industrialized countries (pp. 82–101). Oxford, UK: Clarendon Press.Rosenbaum, J. E. (1995). Changing the geography of opportunity by expanding residential choice: Lessons from the

Gautreaux program. Housing Policy Debate, 6(1), 231–269.Rosenbaum, P. R., & Rubin, D. B. (1983). The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal

effects. Biometrika, 70(1), 41–55.Rubin, D. B. (2001). Using propensity scores to help design observational studies: Application to the tobacco litigation.

Health Services & Outcomes Research Methodology, 2(3–4), 169–188.Simon, C. J., & Tamura, R. (2009). Do higher rents discourage fertility? Evidence from U.S. cities, 1940-2000. Regional

Science and Urban Economics, 39, 33–42.Statistics Sweden. (2011). Olika generationers barnafödande. Childbearing patterns of different generations. pp. 3.

Demografiska rapporter.Stein, J. (1995). Prices and trading the volume in the housing market: A model with down-payment effects. The Quarterly

Journal of Economics, 110, 379–406.Ström, S. (2010). Housing and first birth in Sweden, 1972–2005. Housing Studies, 25(4), 509–526.Swedish union of tenants. (2015). Unga vuxnas boende. Young adult livin]. Stockholm: Hyresgästföreningen.The Swedish National Board of Housing, Building and Planning. (2015). Boverkets indikatorer. pp. 1. The swedish

national board of housing, building and planning’s indicators].The Swedish National Board of Housing, Building and Planning, (2013). Bostadsmarknaden 2013–2014: med slutsatser

från bostadsmarknadsenkäten 2013 [The housing market 2013–2014: conclusions from the housing market survey,2013]. Rapport 2013:19.

Therneau, T., & Grambsch, P. (2000). Modeling survival data: Extending the Cox model. New York: Springe–Verlag.Venti, S., & Wise, D. A. (1984). Moving and housing expenditure: Transaction costs and disequilibrium. Journal of Public

Economics, 23, 207–243.Vignoli, D., Rinesi, F., & Mussino, E. (2013). A home to plan the first child? Fertility intentions and housing conditions

in Italy. Population, Space and Place, 19, 60–71.Wheaton, W. (1990). Vacancy, search, and prices in a housing market matching model. The Journal of Political Economy,

98, 1270–1292.