the irrational consumer why economics is dead wrong about how we make choices - business - the...

Upload: pedro-cepeda

Post on 03-Apr-2018

213 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 7/28/2019 The Irrational Consumer Why Economics is Dead Wrong About How We Make Choices - Business - The Atlantic

    1/4

    25/03/13 The Irrational Consumer: Why Economics Is Dead Wrong About How We Make Choices - Business - The Atlantic

    www.theatlantic.com/business/print/2013/01/the-irrational-consumer-why-economics-is-dead-wrong-about-how-we-make-choices/267255/ 1/4

    Print | Close

    SUBSCRIBE RENEW GIVE A GIFT DIGITAL EDITION

    The Irrational Consumer: WhyEconomics Is Dead WrongAbout How We Make ChoicesBy Derek Thompson

    A new paper reviews how psychology, biology, and neurology are ganging up on economics to prove

    that, when it comes to making decisions, people are anything but rational

    Reuters

    Daniel McFadden is an economist. But his new paper, "The New Science ofPleasure," shows the many

    ways economics fails to explain how we make decisions -- and what it can learn from psychology,

    anthropology, biology, and neurology.

    The old economic theory of consumers says that "people should relish choice." And we do. Shopping can

    be fun, democracy is better than its alternatives, and a diverse and fully stocked grocery store ice

    cream freezer is quite nearly the closest thing to heaven on earth. But other fields of science tell a more

    complicated story. First, making a choice is physically exhausting, literally, so that somebody forced to

    make a number of decisions in a row is likely to get lazy and dumb. (That's one reason why stores place

    candy near the check-out aisle: They suspect your brain is too zonked to resist.) Second, having too

    many choices can make us less likely to come to a conclusion. In a famous study of the so-called

    "paradox of choice", psychologists Mark Lepper and Sheena Iy engar found that customers presented

    with six jam varieties were more likely to buy one than customers offered a choice of 24.

    If you've read the work ofDan Arielyor Daniel Kahneman, you know exactly how far from perfectlyrational we are when faced with a decision. Many of our mistakes stem from a central "availability

    bias." Our brains are computers, and we like to access recently opened files, even though many

    decisions require a deep body of information that might require some searching. Cheap example: We

    http://www.theatlantic.com/business/print/2013/01/the-irrational-consumer-why-economics-is-dead-wrong-about-how-we-make-choices/267255/#http://www.theatlantic.com/business/print/2013/01/the-irrational-consumer-why-economics-is-dead-wrong-about-how-we-make-choices/267255/#https://secure.palmcoastd.com/pcd/eSv?iMagId=23301&i4Ky=IA2Shttp://itunes.apple.com/us/app/the-atlantic-magazine-digital/id397599894?mt=8http://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&cad=rja&ved=0CDIQFjAA&url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.amazon.com%2FThinking-Fast-Slow-Daniel-Kahneman%2Fdp%2F0374275637&ei=K_32UMH0FuXG0QGm04GwBQ&usg=AFQjCNHDq1W3923LRCnFNuoags7rmR-s_g&sig2=V6oZrpzjnAUD7psc3wot-A&bvm=bv.41018144,d.dmQhttp://www.google.com/url?sa=t&rct=j&q=&esrc=s&source=web&cd=1&cad=rja&ved=0CDUQFjAA&url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.amazon.com%2FPredictably-Irrational-Revised-Expanded-Edition%2Fdp%2F0061353248&ei=GP32UJjuEqrh0wG7v4GAAw&usg=AFQjCNEy4l8zfwMfeYuoVgtCUXkwk_4Qxg&sig2=g677kKRlWMmiSZJr_vQbOw&bvm=bv.41018144,d.dmQhttp://www.nber.org/papers/w18687.pdf?new_window=1http://itunes.apple.com/us/app/the-atlantic-magazine-digital/id397599894?mt=8https://secure.palmcoastd.com/pcd/eSv?iMagId=23301&i4Ky=IFGDhttps://secure.palmcoastd.com/pcd/eServ?iServ=MjMzMDE1ODgzNQ==https://secure.palmcoastd.com/pcd/eSv?iMagId=23301&i4Ky=IA1Shttps://secure.palmcoastd.com/pcd/eSv?iMagId=23301&i4Ky=IA2Shttp://www.theatlantic.com/business/print/2013/01/the-irrational-consumer-why-economics-is-dead-wrong-about-how-we-make-choices/267255/#http://www.theatlantic.com/business/print/2013/01/the-irrational-consumer-why-economics-is-dead-wrong-about-how-we-make-choices/267255/#
  • 7/28/2019 The Irrational Consumer Why Economics is Dead Wrong About How We Make Choices - Business - The Atlantic

    2/4

    25/03/13 The Irrational Consumer: Why Economics Is Dead Wrong About How We Make Choices - Business - The Atlantic

    www.theatlantic.com/business/print/2013/01/the-irrational-consumer-why-economics-is-dead-wrong-about-how-we-make-choices/267255/ 2/4

    remember the first, last, and peak moments of certain experiences. So when we make a choice about

    how to spend a certain amount of time -- say, by going to Six Flags -- we forget that most of the time at

    an amusement park is spent waiting around doing nothing. Instead, we remember the thrill of the roller

    coaster. (This has been previously used to explain why people sometimes go back to disappointing old

    romantic partners, but that might be for another article.)

    The third check against the theory of the rational consumer is the fact that we're social animals. We let

    our friends and family and tribes do our thinking for us. In a fascinating example, McFadden presents astudy that shows Korean peasant women within the same v illage tend to use the same contraception --

    even though there is "substantial, persistent diversity across villages." This pattern could not be

    explained by income, education, or price. Word-of-mouth explained practically all the difference.

    In another corner of the ivory tower (or, more likely, across campus in a glassy lab), neurologists are

    finding that many of the biases behavioral economists perceive in decision-making start in our brains.

    "Brain studies indicate that organisms seem to be on a hedonic treadmill, quickly habituating to

    homeostasis," McFadden writes. In other words, perhaps our preference for the status quo isn't just

    figuratively our heads, but also literally sculpted by the hand of evolution inside of our brains.

    A final example to show how other fields of science are ganging up on classical economics: The popular

    psychological theory of "hyperbolic discounting" say s people don't properly evaluate rewards over time.

    The theory seeks to explain why many groups -- nappers, procrastinators, Congress -- take rewards

    now and pain later, over and over again. But neurology suggests that it hardly makes sense to speak of

    "the brain," in the singular, because it's two very different parts of the brain that process choices for

    now and later. The choice to delay gratification is mostly processed in the frontal system. But studies

    show that the choice to do something immediately gratifying is processed in a different system, the

    limbic system, which is more viscerally connected to our behavior, our "reward pathways," and our

    feelings of pain and pleasure.

    And there's much more. To explain it, here's Daniel McFadden himself. The following transcript of our

    email conversation has been very lightly edited for clarity.

    Let me try to sum up your paper for readers, because it covers a lot of ground. Classical

    economists used to posit that, since consumers are rational, we make decisions to

    maximize our pleasure, end of story. But your paper reviews all the ways we know that

    consumers aren't in fact rational but prone to all sorts of biases and habits that pull us

    from any strictly rational view of the consumer. Is that alright?

    This is a good summary, but I think the final message is that neither the physiology of pleasure nor themethods we use to make choices are as simple or as single-minded as the classical economists thought.

    A lot of behavior is consistent with pursuit of self-interest, but in novel or ambiguous decision-making

    environments there is a good chance that our habits will fail us and inconsistencies in the way we

    process information will undo us.

    Choices are good. Trade is good. That's the view of neoclassical consumer theory. But it

    turns out that people don't really like making decisions. We have habits, we like

    thinking automatically. So sometimes we avoid making choices altogether because it

    stresses us out. Why is that? And how might, say, a company use that superior

    understanding of consumer theory to make consumers behave a certain way?

    Trade is a contest, with a chance of coming out on the short end. Animals in "fight or flee" situations

    often find it safer to flee. Similarly, people in situations where trade is possible, or even promising, may

  • 7/28/2019 The Irrational Consumer Why Economics is Dead Wrong About How We Make Choices - Business - The Atlantic

    3/4

    25/03/13 The Irrational Consumer: Why Economics Is Dead Wrong About How We Make Choices - Business - The Atlantic

    www.theatlantic.com/business/print/2013/01/the-irrational-consumer-why-economics-is-dead-wrong-about-how-we-make-choices/267255/ 3/4

    find it safer to turn away. It takes trust to trade. McDonald's is successful because it has created a

    brand people trust - they know what to expect. A "30-day free trial" or "satisfaction or your money

    back" or "bring us a better price and we will refund the difference" are offers by merchants intended to

    promote the idea that they can be trusted, and that the risk of an unsatisfactory trade is low.

    Real estate agents take advantage of people's discomfort with decision-making. Since buying a house is

    highly consequential and difficult to reverse, rational people should look at a great many options and

    think them through very carefully. A good agent will show you a few houses that are expensive and notvery nice, and then one at almost the same price and far nicer. Many buyers will respond by stopping

    their search and jumping on this bargain. Our susceptibility to "bargains" is one of the cognitive devices

    we use to simplify choice situations, and one that companies are conscious of when they position their

    products.

    One of the observations that most struck me was "economic choices can make us

    uncomfortable." That seems like a very powerful idea. How might I see it in my life?

    If two "rational" people meet and disagree on the probability of an event (e.g., the AFC team wins the

    super bowl, the price of Google stock goes up), then both can gain by wagering on the ev ent. In the real

    world, however, wagering is the exception, not the rule. On the one hand, you could say that getting

    someone to bet on an event, pay attention to the outcome, and finally make the payoff, is too much

    work. But actually, if you ask people why they don't bet often with their friends, they will simply say

    that it would make them uncomfortable to do so.

    I'm a big procrastinator. Why does that fall under the category of "hyperbolic

    discounting" rather than "rational way to spend a Sunday afternoon"?

    Procrastination is a way of avoiding uncomfortable choices. Hyperbolic discounting seems to be related

    to our subjective perception of time, and to the way the brain parses current and future pleasure-

    seeking - waiting for an hour right now is more painful than our perception of waiting for an hour in the

    future.

    Here is an example of how hyperbolic discounting works: You go to your car dealer seeking a model

    that has a sound system you want. He says it will take 3 days to get that exact model, but you can drive

    away right now with one that has a better sound system and costs $300 more. Most buyers will choose

    to pay a little more and take their new car now. However, if the dealer said that no car is available right

    now, and he can get the model you want in 33 days, but a model costing $300 more with a better sound

    system in 30 days, most buyers will choose to wait the 33 days and get the exact model they want. This

    is hyperbolic discounting at work. Rational consumers with consistent intertemporal evaluation shouldtreat the trade "$300 for an attractive but unneeded accessory versus 3 days" the same whether it is

    executed right now or executed in 30 days.

    I felt like this sentence at the end of your paper was really important -- "Specialized

    brain circuitry processes experience in ways that are not necessarily consistent with

    relentless maximization of hedonic experience" - but I didn't really understand what it

    meant.

    Our brains seem to operate like committees, assigning some tasks to the limbic system, others to the

    frontal system. The "switchboard" does not seem to achieve complete, consistent communicationbetween different parts of the brain. Pleasure and pain are experienced in the limbic system, but not on

    one fixed "utility" or "self-interest" scale. Pleasure and pain have distinct neural pathways, and these

    pathways adapt quickly to homeostasis, with sensation coming from changes rather than levels.

  • 7/28/2019 The Irrational Consumer Why Economics is Dead Wrong About How We Make Choices - Business - The Atlantic

    4/4

    25/03/13 The Irrational Consumer: Why Economics Is Dead Wrong About How We Make Choices - Business - The Atlantic

    www.theatlantic.com/business/print/2013/01/the-irrational-consumer-why-economics-is-dead-wrong-about-how-we-make-choices/267255/ 4/4

    Overall, presumably as a product of evolution, our brains are organized well enough to keep us alive,

    fed, reproducing, and responsive to but not overwhelmed by sensation, but they are not hedinometers.

    You make the case that humans are social animals more than economic machines,

    which sounds right to me. So do social network like Facebook and Twitter help us make

    better choices?

    This is complicated. Social networks are sources of information, on what products are available, what

    their features are, and how your friends like them. If the information is accurate, this should help you

    make better choices. On the other hand, it also makes it easier for you to follow the crowd rather than

    engaging in the due diligence of collecting and evaluating your own information and playing it against

    your own preferences. In net, the information provided by social networks probably improves choices.

    The down side is that it may make you a lazy decision-maker. There is also a problem that if social

    networks encourage herd behavior, then they increase the risk of panics and stampedes that lead to

    market bubbles and instability.

    This article available online at:

    http://www.theatlantic.com/business/archive/2013/01/the-irrational-consumer-why-economics-is-dead-wrong-about-how-we-make-choices/267255/

    Copyright 2013 by The Atlantic Monthly Group. All Rights Reserved.