the 2008 us financial crisis

27
Philip Pledger Marcio Sierra

Upload: marcio-sierra

Post on 18-Feb-2017

197 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

Philip Pledger Marcio Sierra

Page 2: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

2

TABLE OF CONTENTS

Introduction ..........................................................................................................................3

Causes of the Credit Boom and the Housing Bubble ..........................................................3

The Deregulation and “laissez-faire” of the Financial Sector .................................3

Deregulation of the Financial Sector through Legislation ...........................4

The Credit Boom and the Housing Bubble ..............................................................5

Global Liquidity and Low Interest Rates .....................................................5

The Sub-Prime Mortgage Boom and Flawed Expectations .........................7

The Magnification of Systematic Risk through Financial Engineering in

the Capital Markets ....................................................................................11

The Burst of the Housing Bubble ......................................................................................14

The Market Freeze and its Effects on the Economy ..............................................14

TARP and other Governmental Responses ............................................................17

The General Effects in the Economy .....................................................................18

America Today .......................................................................................................19

The Federal Funds Rate .............................................................................20

Money Supply ............................................................................................21

Inflation ......................................................................................................22

Conclusion .........................................................................................................................23

References ..........................................................................................................................25

Page 3: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

3

INTRODUCTION

In this paper we will analyze the causes and effects of the 2008 United States financial

crisis that almost brought the global economy to a collapse. Due to the extent of literature

on the topic, we will focus our analysis on the causes of the credit boom and the housing

bubble and on the effects on the US financial sector. We will provide an overview on the

behavior that led to a burst in the housing bubble and give insight on the US

governmental response to the financial crisis.

CAUSES OF THE CREDIT BOOM AND THE HOUSING BUBBLE

After the Dot.com bubble burst in the early 2000’s, the US economy started to experience

a boom in its economy. Gross Domestic Product (GDP) was growing around a 3-4% per

year. The financial sector of the US was recording record breaking transactions and

compensations. Little did the population new that the high-risk business transactions

taken by the financial sector would lead to the deepest recession since the Great

Depression. “A financial crisis developed with remarkable speed starting in the late

2008, as mortgage-related securities that had spread through the U.S. and global financial

system suddenly collapsed in value” (Kotz 2009). The following sections give insight

into the several factors that contributed to the credit boom and housing bubble that

triggered the 2008 US Financial Crisis also known and referred to as the Great Recession.

The Deregulation and “laissez-faire” of the Financial Sector

Prior to the direct actions caused by the Shadow Banking System that led to the credit

boom and housing bubble burst, a framework for such possibilities had to be created.

This framework was created through the deregulation and lack of control of the Shadow

Banking System throughout the years leading to the Great Recession started in 2008.

Page 4: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

4

Deregulation of the Financial Sector through Legislation

The US commercial sector has been protected by legislators and government entities at

extreme levels since the Great Depression. As a response and in order to avoid another

stock market meltdown or securities crisis from affecting commercial banks, the Glass

Steagall Act was legislated in 1933. This brought the separation of commercial banking

from all other financial sectors like investment banking, securities and insurance banking.

In the Deregulation and bank supervision (1989), "it was felt that banks should be

insulated as much as possible from the risks of the stock and other securities market."

The Glass Steagall Act would separate commercial and shadow banking for almost 70

years until the Gramm-Leach-Billey Act of 1999 under Bill Clinton’s administration was

created. The new act in place deregulated banking, insurance, securities and the financial

service industry and overrode the separation of commercial and shadow banking from the

Steagall Act of 1933 as said by Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (2015). Coincidentally,

Citicorp had merged illegally with insurance company Travelers and turned into Citi

Group. Under the new Gramm-Leach-Billey Act, Citi’s merger would become legal and

it would mark the start of an interconnected financial system in which commercial and

shadow banking would be tied up together in multiple, complicated links and forms.

Furthermore, 106th Congress (2000) says a new set of deregulatory laws came into place

with the Commodity Future’s Modernization Act of 2000 were the regulation of

derivatives and other securities was banned. Furthermore, banks wanted to extend their

privileges and manage their operations with further liberty. “Investment banks added

leverage the old-fashioned way by persuading the SEC in August of 2004 to amend the

net capital rule of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934. This amendment allowed a

voluntary method of computing deductions to net capital for “large” brokers and dealers.

This alternative approach allowed the investment banks to use internal models to

calculate net capital requirements for market and derivatives-related credit risk. It

effectively allowed “big” investment banks to lever up as much as they wanted”

(Acharya, Philippon, Richardson, & Roubini, 2009). With this new framework, the

shadow banking system would financially engineer new ways to boost short-run

performances by exploiting the derivatives and securities market.

Page 5: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

5

Finally, economist found that there had been a weak federal regulation and supervision of

the shadow banking system, including lax oversight of the capital markets. “There were

several specific problems with regulation and oversight. These include the adequacy of:

(1) capital requirements for investment banks, CDS issuers, and the GSEs

(2) measures to ensure transparency

(3) oversight of rating agencies

(4) oversight and regulation of CDS markets and capital standards for CDS

protection writers

(5) assignment of liability for defects in loan originations

(6) underwriting standards

(7) oversight of compensation. (

The deregulation of the shadow banking system, weak federal regulation and supervision,

and lax oversight of the capital markets would set the framework necessary for a credit

boom and the creation of a housing bubble that would later lead to the Great US

Recession of 2008.

The Credit Boom and the Housing Bubble

Upon a change in regulations in favor of the Shadow Banking system, historically low

interest rates, a deterioration in loaning standards, and a high demand for short-term

profits and performance led to a credit boom, followed by a housing bubble during the

years before the Great Recession of 2008. The following subsections will analyze the

three main factors behind the credit boom and the housing bubble after the financial

sector was deregulated to a great extent during and before the decade of the 2000’s.

Global Liquidity and Low Interest Rates

According to economists, “the driving force behind the boom in nonprime lending was

the excess liquidity created in the 1990s by rapid growth in the United States and other

large economies, particularly China, Brazil, and India” (Belsky & Richardson, 2010).

This excess liquidity led to historically low interests in the United States that opened up

the possibility for an increase in lending, especially when it came to home mortgages.

Page 6: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

6

Figure #1: The Effective Federal Funds Rate

SOURCE: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System

As seen in Figure #1, historically low interest rates came in place after the Dot.com

bubble burst at the start of the millennium. As a result, a remarkable amount of cash

began to look for opportunities for high returns and “unrestrained competition put

pressure on each institution to constantly seek new, more profitable activities” (Gelain et

al., 2015). These benign macroeconomics conditions, like “Historically low real interest

rates helped foster increased leverage across a wide range of agents—notably financial

institutions and households—and markets” (Claessens, Kose, Laeven & Valencia, 2013).

The housing market became the target of financial institutions that were looking to boost

their short-term performances and profits. Their pressure led to a decrease in lending

standards. Easy credit prolonged and extended the boom, which would otherwise have

run out of steam due to affordability constraints. Furthermore, lower interest rates,

improved mortgaged terms and increased availability of mortgage finance. Those who

once were unable to lend, were now offered mortgages at low interest rates and low down

payment. Low interests and excess liquidity would pave the way to a boom in the Sub-

Prime Mortgage market.

Page 7: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

7

The Sub-Prime Mortgage Boom and Flawed Expectations

With historically low interest rates, and excess liquidity, financial institutions found in

the housing market a market from which they could easily profit with a couple of new

lending and securitization methods. “Increased competition among mortgage lenders has

led to an expansion of the range of mortgage products available to consumers and the

capacity to make demand effective in the market” (Kotz 2009). Financial institutions

believed that by lowering their lending standards, they would be able to reach an

untapped market. Thus, the sub-prime mortgage boom was born. The goal of lenders was

to create as much mortgages possible, with little or no importance at all for the

borrower’s ability to pay, and then sell the mortgages throughout the shadow banking

system. The system of compensation of bankers and agents within the financial system is

characterized by moral hazard in the form of “gambling for redemption”. Because a large

fraction of such compensation is in the form of cash bonuses tied to short-term profits,

managers/bankers/traders had a huge incentive to take larger risks than warranted by the

goal of shareholders’ long-run value maximization. “Much of the run-up in U.S. house

prices and credit during the boom years appears to be linked to an influx of

unsophisticated homebuyers. Given their inexperience, these buyers would be more likely

to employ simple backward-looking forecast rules for future house prices, income,

lending standards, etc. One can also make the case that many U.S. lenders behaved

similarly by approving subprime and exotic mortgage loans that could only be repaid if

housing values continued to trend upward.” (Gelain et al., 2015). Thus, the following

loan features became common in the housing market:

1) Low- or no-down payment loans (often in the form of piggyback loans that lifted

combined LTV to high levels).

2) Loans with balloon or negative amortization features.

3) Loans to borrowers with credit scores below 620.

4) Loans with little or no income verification or documentation, or payments

(Belsky & Richardson, 2010).

These new requirements for house mortgages became so popular because owning a house

was associated with the basis of the American Dream, as said by President George W.

Bush. Many Americans were willing to take these risks because they wanted to own a

Page 8: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

8

home, or wanted to speculate in real estate, or saw opportunities to buy a better home in a

more desirable location than if they limited themselves to more traditional products.

Figure #2: The Quality of New Debt Issuance

Figure #2 depicts the growth of of New Debt Issuance from 1993-2007. The Credit Boom

can be easily visualized in Figure #2. “Investors in search of higher yields kept increasing

their demand for private-label mortgage-backed securities (MBS), which also led to sharp

increases in the subprime share of the mortgage market (from around 8% in 2001 to 20%

in 2006) and in the securitized share of the subprime mortgage market (from 54% in 2001

to 75% in 2006)” (Demyanyk & Van Hemert, 2011), as seen in Figure #3. Sub-prime

mortgages and their securitization were fueled by each other. As the yield for

Collaterized Debt Obligations (CDOs) and MBS increased, so did the demand for sub-

prime mortgages and as the supply of sub-prime increased, the demand for their

securitization also increased. Figure #3 illustrates the increase in the sub-prime share of

the entire mortgage market and with it the increase in the percentage of mortgages that

became securitized simultaneous to the decrease in lending standards throughout the US

mortgage market.

Page 9: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

9

Figure #3: Subprime Mortgage Originations

Apart from easy credit, the expectation that home prices would keep increasing misled

many, including bankers, into the buying and selling of sub-prime mortgages without

little regard for the systematic risk these practices could cause. On the other hand, houses

in the US kept appreciating in value as seen in Figure #4 and Figure #5.

Figure #4: Real house price increases in selected OECD countries: 1995-2006

Page 10: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

10

Figure #5: All Transactions House Price Index for the United States

SOURCE: US Federal Housing Finance Agency

The credit boom and the housing bubble were going hand by hand in a vicious circle that

increased each other the more and more mortgages were given. In broad terms, house

prices are determined by demand and supply (Gelain et al., 2015). Changes in

demographics, especially the increases in household formation, income and the

availability, as well as terms of mortgage financing, are the most important factors on the

demand side. Also, increased competition among mortgage lenders has led to an

expansion of the range of mortgage products available to consumers and the capacity to

make demand effective in the market. Another key driver of the house price boom was

the expectations of house price increases. Both Wall Street and Main Street believed that

house prices would continue to appreciate for an indefinite time, leading to more and

more sub-prime loans. These flawed expectations and lending methods brought the

economy to the brink of collapse because of how mortgages were sold and resold within

the shadow banking system.

Page 11: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

11

The Magnification of Systematic Risk through Financial Engineering in the Capital

Markets

With a credit boom, and appreciating house prices, bankers and other financial

institutions financially engineered new ways to make profit through the securitization of

sub-prime mortgages. Investment banks, like Lehman Brothers, Goldman Sachs, and

Merrill Lynch would then buy these sub-prime mortgages and bundle them into

Collaterized Debt Obligations (CDOs). These CDOs were then insured, mainly by AIG.

Because the loans were risky, they were always backed by collateral, in this case the

appreciating prices of houses tied to each sub-prime mortgage. “Financial engineering on

the capital markets, for its part, resulted in large amounts of nonprime securities receiving

AAA ratings that increased demand for risky nonprime loans and kept credit flowing to

them” (Belsky & Richardson, 2010). Standard and Poor, Moody’s and Fitch would rate

give these CDOs a AAA rating, the highest possible rating. Then, other investors, like

pensioner funds would invest in these AAA backed CDO’s. At the same time, speculators

were able to bet on whether or not the CDO’s would default or not. Problems would arise

when the house prices started to decrease because the shadow banking operations and

mortgage performances were all supported by the expectation that house prices would

continue to appreciate. “On the back of buoyant housing and corporate financing markets,

favorable conditions spurred the emergence of large-scale derivative markets, such as

mortgage-backed securities and collateralized debt obligations with payoffs that

depended in complex ways on underlying asset prices. The corporate credit default swap

market also expanded dramatically due to favorable spreads and low volatility. The

pricing of these instruments was often based on a continuation of increasing or high asset

prices” (Claessens, Kose, Laeven & Valencia, 2013).

But the whole point of securitization is precisely that by transferring credit risk from

lenders to investors, the risks will be spread throughout the economy with minimal

systemic effect. Investors and holders of such securities believed that by selling them to

another entity, they would get rid of the effect of a CDO going default. “Although the

originate-to- distribute model in the U.S. seemed a good template for risk allocation, it

turned out to undermine incentives to properly assess risks and led to a buildup of tail

risks. The model also made it much more difficult to know the true value of assets as the

Page 12: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

12

crisis unraveled. This lack of understanding quickly turned a liquidity crisis into a

solvency crisis” (Claessens, Kose, Laeven & Valencia, 2013). In reality, the risks being

taken in the primary mortgage market were multiplied on the secondary market by

financial engineering and by leveraging the investments. In sum, the push to extend more

and more credit emanating from the capital markets—as well as what was done to the

credit when it was bundled and sold as securities on these markets—helped to magnify

risks and increase the exposure of the financial system to deterioration in mortgage loan

performance (Belsky & Richardson, 2010).

Furthermore, why were financial institutions taking the risk of managing, buying and

selling sub-prime mortgages turned into MBS and CDOs? “In the securitization food

chain for US mortgages, every intermediary in the chain was making a fee; eventually the

credit risk got transferred to a structure that was so opaque even the most sophisticated

investor had no real idea what he/she was holding. The mortgage broker, the home

appraiser, the bank originating the mortgages and repackaging them into MBSs, the

investment bank repackaging the MBSs into CDOs, CDOs of CDOs, and even CDOs

cubed, the credit rating agencies giving their AAA blessing to such instruments – each of

these intermediaries was earning income from charging fees for their step of the

intermediation process and transferring the credit risk down the line. The reduction in

quality of the loans and lack of transparency of the securitized structure added to the

fragility of the system.” (Acharya, Philippon, Richardson, & Roubini, 2009). Private

conduits (investment banks and other originators selling directly into private

securitizations) issued nearly all the securities backed by subprime loans, although both

Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac ended up purchasing significant amounts of the highly

rated tranches of those securities. As of 9/30/2009, they reported owning a total of $86

billion of subprime private label securities. Private conduits also issued most of the Alt-A

MBS, though Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac stepped up their issuances of securities

backed by Alt-A loans 2000-2007. As of August 30, 2009, they reported guarantees

outstanding on Alt-A loans in their credit books of business of $415 billion.

Some portfolio lenders also loaded up on nonprime debt. Lehman Brothers and other

investment banks increased their purchase of these CDOs in order to boost their short

Page 13: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

13

term performances. Little did they know that when house prices depreciated, their

mortgages would default and they would be left with billions of dollars worth of toxic

and illiquid assets.

Page 14: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

14

THE BURST OF THE HOUSING BUBBLE

As trillions of dollars in risky mortgage-related securities spread through the U.S.

financial system, and into much of the global financial system, in the mid 2000s, the

financial system became ever more vulnerable to a deflation of the housing bubble. Once

the housing bubble burst, the effects on the shadow banking system were devastating.

Unluckily, Main Street was also affected and thus, the Great Recession of 2008 started.

The following sections give insight to the freezing of the financial markets and its effects

on the economy. Furthermore, the policies and responses on behalf of the government are

analyzed and detailed.

The Market Freeze and its Effects on the Economy

Credit markets froze nearly solid in the fall of 2008, the stock market went into a freefall,

and job losses accelerated sharply. The interconnectedness of the global financial system

became apparent as problems emanating from residential debt in the United States and in

the derivatives used to hedge and trade mortgage risk prompted a global credit crisis.

After this market freeze, the next several months became a series of announcements

about subprime lenders going bankrupt, or massive write-down by financial institutions.

Figure #6: Magnitude of accounting write-downs per quarter during the 2007-08 crisis

Page 15: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

15

“By now, banks had stopped trusting each other as well and were hoarding significant

liquidity as a precautionary buffer; unsecured inter-bank lending at three-month maturity

had largely switched to secured overnight borrowing; the flow of liquidity through the

inter-bank markets had frozen; and lending to the real economy had begun to be

adversely affected” (Acharya, Philippon, Richardson, & Roubini, 2009). The erosion of

nonprime loan performance then reverberated through the global financial system for at

least four reasons:

1) the sheer size of the US mortgage market and the heavy amounts of foreign

capital invested in it, especially from nations with which the United States had

large trade deficits

2) the magnification of risk through the issuance of credit default swaps referencing

nonprime securities

3) the lack of transparency in the CDS market and the difficulty in assessing the

performance of the loans underpinning collateralized debt obligations

4) the amount of leverage financial institutions used to warehouse or purchase

nonprime securities with short-term liabilities, together with and the lack of

adequate reserves against the risk in the underlying subprime securities and the

CDS referencing them.

(Belsky & Richardson, 2010).

The burst of the housing bubble was felt in the US financial markets to a greater extent.

The effects of the burst in the housing bubble were felt throughout the major financial

institutions managing the housing mortgage market. With the depreciation in housing

prices, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac entered into governmental conservatorship because

they had a combined loss of $14.9 billion and market concerns about their ability to raise

capital and debt threatened to disrupt the US housing financial market. More detail of the

conservatorship will be given in the following section. “The two government-sponsored

enterprises had more than US$ 5 trillion in mortgage-backed securities (MBS) and debt;

the debt portion alone is $1.6 trillion” (Kopecki, 2008). The second phase of the shadow

banking system’s demise was the collapse of the entire system of Structured Investment

Vehicles (SIVs) and conduits that started when investors realized that they had invested

Page 16: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

16

in very risky and/or illiquid asset. These risky or illiquid assets were toxic CDOs based

on mortgages and other credit derivatives that had been profoundly affected by the burst

in the housing bubble. Following Fannie Mae and Freddy Mac came Lehman Brothers,

the fourth biggest investment bank in the US. On September 15, 2008, Lehman Brothers

filed a Chapter 11 bankruptcy petition in federal court. The market realized that there was

no company “too-big to-fail” and that it could become true for other major investment

bankers. “It resulted in a classic run on the other institutions, irrespective of the fact that

they were most likely more solvent than Lehman Brothers. This led to Merrill Lynch

selling itself to Bank of America” (Acharya, Philippon, Richardson, & Roubini, 2009).

Furthermore, Lehman’s bankruptcy caused inter-bank markets to truly freeze as no bank

trusted another’s solvency and the entire financial intermediation activity was at a risk of

a complete collapse. Lehman became an example of systemic risk that could have

actually materialized because Lehman hold considerable systemic risk and its bankruptcy

led to a near collapse of the financial system. Lehman’s systemic risk and domino effect

on other investment banks was halted thanks to the efforts of the Federal Reserve, which

will be discussed in the following sections. Either way, the crisis faced by the shadow

banking system translated into “a significant credit crunch that exacerbated the asset price

deflation and led to lower real spending on capital goods – consumer durable and

investment goods – which, in turn triggered an overall economic contraction” (Acharya,

Philippon, Richardson, & Roubini, 2009). The burst of the housing bubble led to a near

collapse of the US financial sector, its economy and the global economy. When the credit

and housing boom turned into a bust and banks deleveraged through contraction of credit,

the global economic meltdown occurred (Kalemli-Ozcan et al., 2012). The combined

efforts of the US Federal Reserve, and other US entities, as well as other governmental

intervention from around the world, were able to mitigate the losses and prevent a total

meltdown of the global economy.

Page 17: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

17

TARP and other Governmental Responses

The TARP (Troubled Asset Relief Program) initiative, authorized by Congress in

October 2008, was implemented by the US Treasury as a stabilization measure in

response to the 2008 financial crisis. Initially slated as a $700 billion initiative, the Dodd-

Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act cut this number down to $475

billion (“TARP Programs”). TARP funds were distributed among five program areas.

The bulk of TARP funds, at about $245 billion, went to programs stabilizing banking

institutions. These included the Asset Guarantee Program (AGP), the Supervisory Capital

Assessment Program (SCAP) and Capital Assistance Program (CAP), the Capital

Purchase Program (CPP), Community Development Capital Initiative (CDCI) and the

Targeted Investment Program (TIP). The AGP focused on purchasing risky assets from

financial institutions, the SCAP and CAP provided a market stress test, and the CPP,

CDCI and TIP simply provided capital to various banking institutions (“TARP

Programs”). The second largest recipient of TARP funding, at around $80 billion, was an

effort to stabilize the American automotive industry. About $68 billion went to

stabilizing AIG, an insurance provider deemed “too big to fail,” $46 billion to foreclosure

assistance for needy families and finally $27 billion to restart credit markets. The TARP

initiative contained programs and bailouts across a wide range of and institutions and

made up a large portion of the government’s efforts to repair the damage dealt to the

economy by the 2008 financial crisis. As with most proposals of its size and cost,

however, TARP has proven relatively divisive.

Perhaps due to TARP being a recent initiative, or perhaps due to its highly politicized

nature, opinion on the initiative’s effectiveness is largely split. The Treasury itself

defends TARP as being a complete success, both preventing a second Great Depression

and being “currently projected to cost approximately $37.2 billion” instead of the $475

billion allotted through the Dodd-Frank Act (“TARP Programs”). On the other hand, an

article published in an April 2013 issue of the Journal of International Financial

Markets, Institutions and Money noted a drop in operating efficiency for banks that

received TARP funding, attributing this trend to moral hazard stemming from the TARP

bailouts (Harris 85). The authors argued that bank managers who received TARP funding

Page 18: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

18

had “abated incentives…to adopt best practices that improve asset quality” (Harris 85).

The truth of TARP’s effectiveness is likely somewhere in between either depiction.

Indicators of economic health have been largely trending upwards since TARP was

instituted, although there are still indications of work yet to be done.

The General Effects in the Economy

The 2008 financial crisis heralded a significant drop in American economic output. The

damage done to output is most visible when comparing real GDP in 2008 Q3 (14,891.643

billion chained 2009 dollars) to real GDP in 2009 Q1 (14,375.018 billion chained 2009

dollars) (Real Gross Domestic Product, 3 Decimal [GDPC96]). This brief period alone

saw American real GDP drop by more than 3.469%, declining at a notably faster rate

than it had been growing before the financial crisis. Real GDP hit its lowest point for the

crisis in 2009 Q2, at 14,355.558 billion chained 2009 dollars. This was down from 2008

Q2, where real GDP was 14,963.357 billion chained 2009 dollars. However, since hitting

the floor in 2009 Q2, real GDP has been rising steadily. Real GDP for 2015 Q3 is

16,394.200 billion chained 2009 dollars as seen in Figure #7.

Figure #7: Real Gross Domestic Product (GDP), 3 Decimal

SOURCE: US Federal Housing Finance Agency

Page 19: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

19

The 2008 financial crisis came with an extremely visible impact on US civilian

unemployment. In December 2007, the civilian unemployment rate was at 5% (Civilian

Unemployment Rate [UNRATE]). Unemployment continued to rise sharply until about

May 2009, where it hit 9.4%. Civilian unemployment still continued to rise at a

somewhat diminished pace until its peak of 10% in October 2009. From there,

unemployment remained within the 9.8%-10% range until May 2010, where

unemployment dropped to 9.6%. After that, with some minor exceptions (November

2010, for example) the unemployment rate has been declining fairly steadily. The

downward slope of the unemployment level has grown increasingly smooth (as opposed

to an initial drop/plateau pattern), and unemployment for September 2015 was at 5.1%,

which is close to that before the 2008 recession. In summary, unemployment rose sharply

for the duration of the crisis, and has been falling at a relatively slower pace ever since as

seen in Figure #8.

Figure #8: Civilian Unemployment Rate 2000-2014

SOURCE: US Federal Housing Finance Agency

America Today

While effects of the 2008 financial crisis still linger, the US economy is no longer

experiencing the recession that followed in its wake. Many indicators of economic health

Page 20: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

20

are painting a fairly positive picture. Real GDP has been increasing steadily, and current

real GDP is higher than pre-crisis real GDP by a wider margin than pre-crisis real GDP

exceeded real GDP during the recession (Real Gross Domestic Product, 3 Decimal

[GDPC96]). Indeed, real GDP has been growing at a constant positive rate since it hit its

floor in Q2 of 2009. Additionally, the civilian unemployment rate for September of this

year (5.1%) is only slightly higher than the lowest rate of this past decade (4.4%, during

certain months in 2006 and 2007) (Civilian Unemployment Rate [UNRATE]).

The Federal Funds Rate

While the American economy is no longer in a period of recession, it is still strongly

affected by the 2008 financial crisis and the relief methods employed by the government.

The Effective Federal Funds Rate (interest rate) in particular has been extremely low ever

since the recession. As of October 2015, the Effective Federal Funds Rate is only 0.12%

(Effective Federal Funds Rate [FEDFUNDS]). This is opposed to 4.76% on October

2007, before the crisis, and is the same rate as October 2009 after the crisis. No month

between July 1954 (the earliest recorded in the FRED Figure) and the end of the 2008

financial crisis has had an Effective Federal Funds Rate as low as we have currently, as

seen in Figure #9.

Figure #9: Effective Federal Funds Rate 2000-2014

SOURCE: US Federal Housing Finance Agency

Page 21: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

21

US Money Supply

This is a result of a dramatic increase in the money supply. Supply of M1 currency in the

United States in 2014 was nearly double that of 2008, jumping from

$1,434,733,333,333.30 in 2008 to $2,806,208,333,333.30 in 2014 (M1 for the United

States [MANMM101USA189S]). With such a dramatic increase in money supply, it is

only natural that interest rates have dropped accordingly. The Federal Open Market

Committee (FOMC) set its interest rate target to these low levels in December 2008 in

order to encourage investment in capital goods, recapitalize the banking system and raise

asset prices (increasing household wealth and lowering the cost of business capital

purchases) (Kliesen). Both the extremely low federal funds rate and sharp upward trend

in money supply are current effects of the financial crisis on today’s economy, despite

other indicators being positive, as seen in Figure#10.

Figure #10: M1 for the United States 2000-2002

SOURCE: US Federal Housing Finance Agency

Page 22: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

22

Inflation

Interestingly enough, the US economy is not experiencing certain predicted effects from

its recession, namely high inflation rates. According to the Federal Reserve Bank of St.

Louis,

“During normal times, for each 1 percent increase in the growth of money,

inflation increases by 0.54 percent…money supply (MO) increased 40.29 percent

between December 2008 and December 2013, or about 8 percent per year on

average. Under this pace of annual growth, we would have seen inflation of 4.3

percent per year, or a price level increase of at least 40 percent in 2013 compared

with the price level in 2008” (Arias).

Figure #11: Inflation, consumer prices for the United States

SOURCE: US Federal Housing Finance Agency

The inflation rate in the United States, however, has behaving in a way that starkly

contradicts such forecasts. Despite M1 supply nearly doubling from 2008 to 2014, the

inflation rate actually dropped from 3.83910% in 2008 to 1.62222% in 2014 (Inflation,

consumer prices for the United States [FPCPITOTLZGUSA]). With the exception of

2011 (which had an inflation rate of about 3.16%), inflation after this dramatic surge in

M1 supply began has been at its lowest since 2003 (2.27% inflation). The Federal

Page 23: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

23

Reserve Bank of St. Louis argues that this curious pattern of low inflation despite sharp

money supply increases may be the result of a liquidity trap (Arias). Under normal

circumstances, an increase in the supply of money will lead to a decrease in its worth,

manifesting in higher inflation and higher price levels. In a liquidity trap, however,

demand for money is so great as to effectively “absorb” the increase. With the nominal

interest being held near zero, there is little opportunity cost to holding on to cash instead

of spending or investing it. This decrease in willingness to spend keeps prices from

rising. More money is entering the economy, certainly, but, in the event of a liquidity

trap, that money is not necessarily circulating in the economy. If a liquidity trap is

responsible for the US’s unusually low inflation, then inflation will not increase by much

until money demand decreases.

CONCLUSIONS

The US Financial Crisis of 2008 was the greatest recession since the Great Depression in

the 1930’s. We saw that an excess in global liquidity led to a credit boom that was fueled

by sub-prime mortgages and appreciating houses. This led to financial engineer within

the derivatives market. Once the home depreciation started, the financial sector lost

hundreds of billions in the derivatives market. This revealed the high level of systemic

risk spread through the trade of CDOs and MBS and many financial institutions

collapsed. Thanks to the effort of the Federal Reserve through TARP and their other

policies, the economy survived and refueled with an injection of capital through billions

in bailouts.

The crisis may have ended years ago but its ghost still haunts the fears of America. Still,

the idea that the US may be in a liquidity trap is certainly a worrying prospect. The

Federal Reserve is currently holding its interest rate target at around zero as a means of

encouraging spending and investment. However, in a liquidity trap, lowering interest

rates and increasing the money supply will have exactly the opposite effect. According to

the Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, “more monetary injections during a liquidity trap

can only reinforce the liquidity trap” (Arias). If the US is in a liquidity trap, the proper

Page 24: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

24

monetary policy would be to raise the nominal interest rate, rather than keeping it at near

zero levels. The Fed could sell financial assets in the marketplace to decrease money

supply, which would in turn raise the nominal interest rate. Should the Fed do so,

investors would have more of an incentive to hold interest-generating assets instead of

cash in their portfolios. If the US economy is experiencing a liquidity trap, a reversal of

the Fed’s current monetary policy may be enough to remedy the situation.

Page 25: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

25

REFERENCES

"TARP Programs." U.S. Department of the Treasury. U.S. Department of the Treasury,

10 Nov. 2015. Web. 23 Nov. 2015.

<https://www.treasury.gov/initiatives/financial-stability/TARP-

Programs/Pages/default.aspx#>.

Acharya, V., Philippon, T., Richardson, M., & Roubini, N. (2009). The financial crisis of

2007- 2009: Causes and remedies. Financial markets, institutions & instruments,

18(2), 89-137.

Arias, Maria A., and Yi Wen. "The Liquidity Trap: An Alternative Explanation for

Today's Low Inflation." Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis. Federal Reserve Bank

of St. Louis, Apr. 2014. Web. 23 Nov. 2015.

<https://www.stlouisfed.org/publications/regional-economist/april-2014/the-

liquidity-trap-an-alternative-explanation-for-todays-low-inflation>.

Arora, N., Gandhi, P., & Longstaff, F. A. (2012). Counterparty credit risk and the credit

default swap market. Journal of Financial Economics, 103(2), 280-293.

Belsky, E., & Richardson, N. (2010). Understanding the boom and bust in nonprime

mortgage lending. Joint Center for Housing Studies of Harvard University.

http://www. jchs. harvard. edu/sites/jchs. harvard. edu/files/ubb10-1. pdf, Figure,

1-3.

Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (US), Effective Federal Funds

Rate [FEDFUNDS], retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/FEDFUNDS/, November 23, 2015.

Claessens, S., Kose, M. A., Laeven, L., & Valencia, F. (2013). Understanding Financial

Crises: Causes, Consequences, and Policy Responses.

Demyanyk, Y., & Van Hemert, O. (2011). Understanding the subprime mortgage crisis.

Review of Financial Studies, 24(6), 1848-1880.

Deregulation and bank supervision. (1989). Money Affairs, 2(2), 73-85

Erkens, D. H., Hung, M., & Matos, P. (2012). Corporate governance in the 2007–2008

financial crisis: Evidence from financial institutions worldwide. Journal of

Corporate Finance, 18(2), 389-411.

Page 26: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

26

Gelain, P., Bank, N., Lansing, K. J., San Francisco, F. R. B., & Natvik, G. J. (2015).

Explaining the boom-bust cycle in the US housing market: a reverse-engineering

approach. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco Working Paper Series, 2.

Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act. (n.d.). Retrieved November 25, 2015, from

https://www.ftc.gov/tips-advice/business-center/privacy-and-security/gramm-

leach-bliley-act

H.R.5660 - 106th Congress (1999-2000): Commodity Futures Modernization Act of

2000. (n.d.). Retrieved November 25, 2015, from

https://www.congress.gov/bill/106th-congress/house-bill/5660

Harris, O., D. Huerta, and T. Ngo. "The Impact of TARP on Bank Efficiency." Journal of

International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money 24.1 (2013): 85-

104. SCOPUS. Web. 23 Nov. 2015.

Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem & Sorensen, Bent & Yesiltas, Sevcan, 2012. "Leverage across

firms, banks, and countries," Journal of International Economics, Elsevier, vol.

88(2), pages 284-298

Kim, K. H., & Renaud, B. (2009). The global house price boom and its unwinding: an

analysis and a commentary. Housing Studies, 24(1), 7-24.

Kliesen, Kevin L. "Low Interest Rates Have Benefits ...and Costs." Federal Reserve Bank

of St. Louis. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, Spring 2011. Web. 23 Nov. 2015.

<https://www.stlouisfed.org/publications/inside-the-vault/spring-2011/low-

interest-rates-have-benefits-and-costs>.

Kopecki, Dawn (2008-09-11). "U.S. Considers Bringing Fannie, Freddie on to Budget".

Bloomberg.

Kotz, D. M. (2009). The financial and economic crisis of 2008: A systemic crisis of

neoliberal capitalism. Review of Radical Political Economics.

Lehman Brothers Collection. (n.d.). Retrieved November 25, 2015, from

http://www.library.hbs.edu/hc/lehman/history.html

Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development, M1 for the United States©

[MANMM101USA189S], retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St.

Louis https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/MANMM101USA189S/,

November 23, 2015.

Page 27: The 2008 US Financial Crisis

27

US. Bureau of Economic Analysis, Real Gross Domestic Product, 3 Decimal [GDPC96],

retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/GDPC96/, November 23, 2015.

US. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Civilian Unemployment Rate [UNRATE], retrieved from

FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/UNRATE/, November 23, 2015.

World Bank, Inflation, consumer prices for the United States [FPCPITOTLZGUSA],

retrieved from FRED, Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis

https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/FPCPITOTLZGUSA/, November 23,

2015.