telecom sector reform for essential facilitates in west africa a case study of the cable consortium...

Upload: kolubahzizi-howard

Post on 08-Oct-2015

72 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

DESCRIPTION

A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OF THE REQUIREMENTS FOR LLM (INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS LAW) BY DISTANCE LEARNING

TRANSCRIPT

  • UNIVERSITY OF SOUTHAMPTON, 2014

    LAW SCHOOL

    TELECOM SECTOR REFORM FOR ESSENTIAL FACILITATES IN WEST AFRICA: A

    CASE STUDY OF THE CABLE CONSORTIUM OF LIBERIA (CCL)

    CANDIDATE NUMBER

    25268961

    A DISSERTATION SUBMITTED IN PARTIAL FULFILMENT OFTHE

    REQUIREMENTS FOR LLM (INFORMATION TECHNOLOGY AND

    TELECOMMUNIATIONS LAW) BY DISTANCE LEARNING

    WORD COUNT

    14,659

    THIS DISSERTATION IS ALL MY OWN WORK.

    REFERENCE TO, QUOTATION FROM, AND

    DISCUSSION OF THE WORK OF ANY OTHER PERSON

    HAS BEEN CORRECTLY ACKNOWLEDGED WITHIN THE WORK

  • 1

    Declaration of Authors Rights

    The copyright of this dissertation belongs to the author under the terms of the United

    Kingdom Copyright Act as qualified by University of Southampton Regulations. Due

    acknowledgment must always be made of the use of any materials contained in, or derived

    from, this dissertation.

  • 2

    Acknowledgments

    And unto man he said, Behold, the fear of the Lord, that is wisdom; and to depart from

    evil is understanding. Job 28:28

    Sincere thanks and appreciation are due Madam Angelique Weeks, Chairperson of the

    Liberia Telecommunications Authority (LTA) and the Board of Commissioners of the LTA

    for the scholarship provided to earn this degree. I am indeed grateful!

    Special thanks also go to Professor Ian J. Lloyd, Program Director and Project Supervisor,

    Professor David Mellor, Lecturer, and all the other Faculty members of the Department with

    whom I interacted and provided guidance along this academic voyage. Your collective

    patience, wisdom and efforts were appreciated and have been worthwhile.

    This work is dedicated to my late parents, Moses and Nora Howard, who taught me that, to

    whom much is given much, is expected!

  • 3

    Table of Contents

    Acknowledgments ................................................................................................................................... 2

    Chapter 1: Purpose and Progress of Telecom Sector Reform ................................................................. 5

    1.0 Introduction ................................................................................................................................... 5

    1.1 Purpose of Telecommunications Sector Reform ................................................................................. 7

    Chapter 2: Literature Review ................................................................................................................ 12

    2.0 Introduction ................................................................................................................................. 12

    2.1 The Role of Telecommunications Sector Reform ............................................................................. 14

    2.2 The Doctrine of Essential Facilities .................................................................................................. 20

    2.3 Counter Essential Facilities Arguments ........................................................................................ 24

    Chapter 3: Telecommunications Sector Reform in West Africa........................................................... 28

    3.0 Introduction ....................................................................................................................................... 28

    3.1 Regional Telecommunications Development ................................................................................... 29

    3.2 Telecom Sector Reform within ECOWAS ....................................................................................... 32

    3.2.1 World Bank Support ............................................................................................................ 33

    3.2.2 ITU Support ......................................................................................................................... 36

    4.0 Case Study of the Cable Consortium of Liberia (CCL) .................................................................. 41

    4.1 Introduction ....................................................................................................................................... 41

    4.2 Liberias Telecom Sector Reform ..................................................................................................... 43

    4.3 The Cable Consortium of Liberia (CCL) .......................................................................................... 50

    4.4 Remedies for CCLs Dominance ...................................................................................................... 53

    4.5 Analysis ............................................................................................................................................. 55

    5.0 Chapter 5: Conclusion ..................................................................................................................... 57

    5.1 Summary ........................................................................................................................................... 57

    5.2 Recommendations ............................................................................................................................. 58

    Table of Figures

    Figure 1: 2013 Regional Internet penetration rates ................................................................................. 6

    Figure 2: Growth in mobile-cellular subscriptions ................................................................................. 7

    Figure 3: Regulating Fixed-lines........................................................................................................... 19

    Figure 4: Incentive regulation and growth in mobile services .............................................................. 19

    Figure 5: Concept of Essential Facilities .............................................................................................. 21

    Figure 6: Economic Community of West African States...................................................................... 28

    Figure 7: West Africa's Undersea Cables ............................................................................................. 32

    Figure 8: Map of Liberia ....................................................................................................................... 41

    Figure 9: Liberia's fixed and mobile growth rates ................................................................................ 43

    Figure 10: Decline in Liberia's fixed-line infrastructure ....................................................................... 45

    Figure 11: Market Analysis process...................................................................................................... 52

    List of Tables

    Table 1: Privatization revenues per sector .............................................................................................. 6

  • 4

    Table 2: . Privatization revenues by sector, 1990-98 ............................................................................ 10

    Table 3: Regional Integration and Membership Arrangements in West Africa ................................... 29

    Table 4: Telecom performance indicators for ECOWAS & Mauritania .............................................. 31

    Table 5: Status of ECOWAS Regulatory Instruments 2002/2003 ........................................................ 36

    Table 6: Demographic and economic indicators for Liberia ................................................................ 42

    Table 7: World Bank telecom technical assistance program to the NTGL ........................................... 44

    Table 8: Liberia's GSM networks ......................................................................................................... 47

    Table 9: LTA 2008 Interconnection price caps .................................................................................... 48

    Table 10: Value-chain of related markets relevant to the CCL ............................................................ 53

    Table 11: Proposed remedies for CCLs dominance ............................................................................ 54 Table 12: Equivalent price per E1 per month (US$) based on capacity commitment .......................... 54

    Table 13: WARCIP Liberia Project M&E Results ............................................................................... 56

  • 5

    Chapter 1: Purpose and Progress of Telecom Sector Reform

    1.0 Introduction

    The growth in the telecommunications/ICT sector over the last decade has been phenomenal,

    with amazing statistics for 2014:

    Almost 7 billion mobile-cellular subscriptions world-wide with 3/4 of all

    subscriptions from the developing world;

    96% global mobile-cellular penetration rates expected - 90% from developing

    countries and 69% for Africa;

    2.3 billion mobile-broadband subscriptions with 55% from developing countries;

    32% global mobile-broadband penetration expected, double the penetration rate of

    2011 and four times as high as 2009;

    3 billion people, almost 40% of the worlds population, using the Internet with 2/3 of

    users from the developing world;

    20% of Africas population online by end of 2014, up from 10% in 2010; and,

    44% of global households with Internet access and 31% of households in developing

    countries connected.1

    In 2014 the volume of international traffic reflecting Internet, voice, and data in Liberia grew

    to 2.93 Kb/s per person, Internet penetration rate is 3.72%, and access to telephone service,

    both fixed and cellular, 58.83%.2 Developing countries that implemented

    ICT/telecommunications sector reforms between 1990 and 2001 attracted more investments

    in telecommunications than in any other sector; totaling $331 billion of private investment.3

  • 6

    Table 1: Privatization revenues per sector

    Figure 1: 2013 Regional Internet penetration rates

    Source: ITU

    In 2005, global penetration for fixed mobile-cellular subscriptions was 33.9%, penetration for

    active mobile-broadband subscriptions were unavailable, global fixed (wired)-broadband

    subscriptions were 3%, households with Internet access 18.4% and only 15.8% of individuals

    globally used the Internet.4 In 2001, Liberias fixed-line penetration was 0.1%, mobile-

    cellular subscriptions 5%, with no fixed or mobile-broadband subscriptions and no household

    Internet access.5

  • 7

    Figure 2: Growth in mobile-cellular subscriptions

    The remarkably success of ICTs in Africa over the past decade has been driven by sector

    reform; especially in the mobile market segment, resulting in improved availability, quality

    and reduced cost of connectivity. Continent wide policy changes triggered reforms in the

    telecommunications sector and how investments are financed; making telecommunications

    unique among infrastructure sectors in Africa. The shift from politically driven decision-

    making to rules-based technocratic methods has increased investor confidence and allowed

    the development of competition, greatly increasing the performance of Africas ICT sector.6

    1.1 Purpose of Telecommunications Sector Reform

    Globally, telecommunications has transformed from a public utility industry immersed in

    natural monopoly rights to a strategic investment required for competitive advantages at the

    national, regional and firm levels.7 Recognition of information as an economic commodity

    needed as a factor of production has been a key factor driving this transformation.

    Information is increasingly an economic commodity combined with the globalization of

  • 8

    capital flows and trade. Resulting economic activities have generated greater consumer

    demand for diverse, higher quality and cheaper communications and information services.8

    Rapid advances in telecommunications technology have changed cost structures of the sector

    and related industries by reducing the cost of information transmission and processing;

    making the provision of a wider range of communications facilities and services possible at

    greatly reduced costs.9

    Telecommunications services are widely consumed and regarded as essential public social

    requirements for the effective performance of the economy. They constitute a significant

    percentage of the gross domestic product (GDP), are critical intermediary inputs for other

    economic sectors, and are major determinants of the production cost and competiveness of

    national economies. Accordingly, the presence of limited utility operators raises immediate

    concerns about monopoly inefficiencies, abuse of market power and restrictions of freedom

    of choice.10

    The transformation of the telecommunications, computer and audio-visual industries by

    digital technology heightened global concerns and created the information society. The

    ability of nations to access, process and produce information efficiently became a necessity

    for remaining competitive.11

    Access to global markets and customers became a vital

    requirement to remain at the forefront of the global information society and open network

    access a prerequisite for successful development and continued competiveness.12

    Economic stimulation and the need to attract investment in telecommunications infrastructure

    catalysed governments to pursue telecommunications liberalization.13

    Monopolistic and

    monolithic telecom markets required transformation to introduce and safeguard some

  • 9

    measure of competition. The entrenched competitive positions of incumbent monopolies

    necessitated urgent steps to prevent the perpetuation of public monopolies in the private

    sector.14

    The following issues required attention:

    Identifying services/facilities, for economic or political reasons, to remain monopoly

    based;

    Determining rules governing competitive interactions between monopoly providers

    and private operators;

    Developing institutional arrangements to:

    Monitor and enforce rules;

    Resolve disputes amongst parties; and,

    Review and amend rules and dispute resolution mechanisms as necessary?15

    Liberalization and telecommunications sector reform formed part of a broader economic

    reform process initiated in the 1980s, influenced by the recognition of the importance of

    pervasive access to telecommunications in promoting social and economic development.

    While the goals of liberalization differ nationally, they are broadly classified as follows:

    Interpretation of neoliberal ideology among decision making elites as a justification

    for less state intervention;

    1980s debt crisis and global recession justified scaling down the public sector burden

    on the state, raising revenues through sale of state-owned operators and licensing new

    operators;

    The growing multilateral trading system and inclusion of basic telecommunications in

    the WTOs General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) committing countries to

    telecom sector liberalization;

  • 10

    Integration into the global economy required advanced telecommunications

    infrastructure for attracting investment and maintaining national competitiveness;

    The underperformance of the sector; and,

    Rethinking economies of scale in telecommunications.16

    These factors, combined with a revolution in telecommunications technology, resulted in a

    global pursuit of telecommunications privatization, liberalization and regulatory reform in the

    1990s unparalleled to any technological led reform since the beginning of the century.17

    Table 2: . Privatization revenues by sector, 1990-98

    This dissertation shall examine telecommunications sector reform with an emphasis on the

    liberalization of access to essential facilities and how the reforms have been applied within

    the West African context, using Liberia as a case study. Chapter 2 will examine the literature

    on telecommunications sector reform and liberalization with an emphasis on interconnection

    and access to essential facilities. Chapter 3 will examine the process of telecommunications

    sector reform and access to essential facilities within the Economic Community of West

    African States (ECOWAS). Chapter 4 will present the Liberian case study of Cable

  • 11

    Consortium of Liberia (CCL) and the legal framework for assess to the Cable Landing

    Station as an essential facilities. Chapter 5 will present a summary, conclusions and

    recommendations.

  • Chapter 2: Literature Review

    2.0 Introduction

    In May 2001 the United Nations conducted an appraisal of the effectiveness of the Paris

    Programme of Action (PPoA) adopted by the Second United Nations (UN) Conference on

    Least Developed Countries (LDCs) in 1990. The appraisal revealed that the goals and

    objectives of the PPoA had not been achieved. LDCs were being circumvented by the process

    of globalization; further exacerbating their marginalization. The PPoA sought to implement

    economic reforms in LDCs by substantially reducing tariffs and trade barriers, liberalizing

    currency regimes, privatizing public enterprises, establishing and strengthening

    institutional/regulatory frameworks and adopting liberal investment policies. The outcomes

    of reform efforts fell below expectations and LDCs faced declining financial resources,

    unsustainable and heavy debt burdens, complex trade barriers, and supply-side constraints.

    To address these challenges, the Brussels Programme of Action (BPoA) was adopted by the

    UN Conference in 2001. The BPoA was based on seven Commitments:

    1. Fostering a people-centered policy framework;

    2. Good governance at national and international levels;

    3. Building human and institutional capacities;

    4. Building capacity for globalization within LDCs;

    5. Enhancing the development role of trade;

    6. Protecting the environment; and,

    7. Mobilizing financial resources.18

    Commitment 4 sought to increase telephone density to five main lines per 100 inhabitants and

    Internet connections to ten users per 100 inhabitants by 2010. The International

  • 13

    Telecommunications Unions (ITU) Special Programme for LDCs was formulated to meet

    these goals by prioritizing universal access, emergency telecommunications and concentrated

    assistance to LDCs. Through Official Development Assistance (ODA) the ITUs Special

    Programme has undertaken diverse activities and provided assistance to LDCs focused on:

    Promoting universal access;

    Bridging the urban/rural access gap and introducing new technologies;

    Human resource development;

    Rural communication development;

    Spectrum management; and,

    Developing appropriate ICT strategies based on sound policies, and appropriate

    regulatory and legal frameworks.19

    The role of the ICT sector in nurturing economic and social development is well documented.

    Telecommunications investments influence economic development by reducing production

    costs and increasing revenues and employment through direct and indirect effects. Unlike

    other infrastructure investments, the benefits of increased telecommunications access result

    from increases in information and knowledge.20

    The potential for transferring information

    provided by the telecommunications sector significantly impacts trade and economic growth

    in a global economy.21

    Major improvements in ICTs in Africa from 2001 2005, compared

    with 1991 1995, added one percentage point to the continents per capita growth rate and

    accounted for over half of improved growth performance observed between the two periods.

    Every Ten-percentage-point increase in telephone penetration and Internet services increases

    economic growth one percentage point.22

  • 14

    2.1 The Role of Telecommunications Sector Reform

    ICTs offer major transformational opportunities and enhance productivity, competitiveness,

    wealth creation and poverty reduction by facilitating knowledge based economies and

    participation in the global economy. However, these opportunities can only be realized to the

    extent that regulatory frameworks create an enabling environment supportive of cultivating

    investment in, and widespread diffusion of, ICTs.23

    This envisages a framework of market

    access for service suppliers clearly intended to foster competition and participation of foreign

    firms through a legal and regulatory environment conductive to market entry and elimination

    of restrictions.24

    Causality between telecommunications investments and economic growth does not

    automatically translate investments into growth. Economic growth is not promoted by

    telecommunications investments in and of itself. The economic impacts of new investments

    are strongest where telecommunications facilities are either absent or inadequate to the extent

    that they serve as bottlenecks to private economic activities. The key is not the correlation

    between telecommunications and growth, but the institutional mechanisms that determine

    how and when investments are made.25

    Lack of regulatory stability and clarity is a

    disincentive for private investment; conversely, stable regulatory environments can increase

    private sector investment by 25% and reduce the cost of owning and using a mobile phone by

    Ten%.26

    Private investment is therefore contingent on an enabling regulatory environment.

    Environments supportive of sustainable investment require NRA independence in decision

    making that is transparent, non-discriminatory, objective and free of political influence.27

  • 15

    By 2010, 80% of International Development Association (IDA) countries had introduced

    competition in the Internet and mobile markets and more than 85 % had established separate

    NRAs. These achievements have deepen reforms and improved sector performance28

    leading

    to more liberalized fixed-line markets and international gateways, fully liberalized mobile

    markets and liberalized provision of Internet services.29

    These regulatory and institutional

    accomplishments have translated into increased foreign direct investment in the

    telecommunication infrastructure, especially in SSA. ICT policy harmonization projects such

    as the West African Common Market Project has led to increased financial investments in

    SSA from China, India and the Gulf States equivalent to the ODA provided by the

    Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OCED) with commitments

    totaling $2.16 billion.30

    The harmonization of multilateral and regional commitments into

    local laws by many countries were major accomplishments which served to accelerate

    regulatory reforms, facilitate international best practice, and provide investors with regulatory

    certainty and predictability.31

    The opening of telecommunications markets to new infrastructure investments required

    migration from government intervention, to development of coherent competition

    frameworks. Frameworks grounded on efficient and practical laws guaranteeing private

    sector rights and remedies and providing protection from anticompetitive behavior and abuse

    of market dominance.32

    Recognition of property rights and enforcements is positively

    correlated with network expansion and efficiency.33

    In historically developed monopoly markets with massive telecommunications infrastructure

    built by public funding, general competition law principles are required to guarantee access to

    scarce, limited or essential facilities dominated by incumbents. Liberalized

  • 16

    telecommunications markets necessitate the interconnection of rival networks through

    regulatory intervention requiring that incumbents provide network access to new entrants to

    enhance network externalities. Access to new entrants establishes competition by avoiding

    unnecessary duplication of costly network components.34

    Interconnection, in this context,

    refers to the commercial and technical arrangements by which service providers connect their

    equipment, networks and services to grant their customers access to the customers, services

    and networks of other service providers.35

    The goals of access policy are therefore to:

    Ensure infrastructure owners operate efficiently and access terms do not distort the

    process by which prices are adapted to consumer preferences and demand for

    services; and,

    Safeguard competitive parity through transparent non-discriminatory access and

    charges that reflect the economic costs of performing the supply function.36

    Telecommunications liberalization led to massive investments in alternative infrastructure;

    however, the local loop remains the primary method of obtaining connectivity to the public

    telecommunications network. The dominance of local access by incumbents has remained a

    source of regulatory concern due to the propensity of incumbents to use their control over

    essential facilities to obtain unfair competitive advantages over competitors in

    complementary downstream markets.37

    Interconnection, therefore, remains a major stumbling

    block to the development of competition and liberalized telecommunications services.38

    The most contentious interconnection issues are centered on prices and terms for

    interconnection and access for interconnection. Prices are controversial because they affect

    profitability and the development of competition. Terms of interconnection and access remain

    controversial because they define what competitors receive and when, how and where they

  • 17

    obtain interconnection access.39

    Therefore, the bottleneck owner must be required to charge

    itself the same interconnection charges it levies on its competitors, minus the marginal costs

    of providing that service. Also, the price charged for the final product must recover both the

    access charge and the incremental cost of the suppliers own retail operations.40 To ensure the

    benefits of liberalization are actualized, true competition must be supported by a regulatory

    environment that clarifies the terms of interconnection and access between operators,

    establishes the rules for interconnection, defines the guidelines for sharing infrastructure, and

    institutes interoperability provisions.41

    The General Agreement on Trade in Services (GATS) recognizes that access to and use of

    public telecommunications infrastructure is indispensible for the competitive provision of

    effective services covered by GATS. World Trade Organization (WTO) members are

    therefore required to provide suppliers of scheduled services access to the public

    telecommunications transport network and services on reasonable and non-discriminatory

    terms. The WTOs Reference Paper telecommunications reform checklist of success is

    based on six necessary principles to remove regulatory barriers to market access and prevent

    anticompetitive practices. They are:

    Competitive safeguards: Members must establish safeguards preventing major

    suppliers from engaging in anticompetitive conduct;

    Interconnection: Major suppliers of Members capable of materially affecting terms of

    market price and supply by control over essential facilities or position in the market

    must provide interconnection upon request, on non-discriminatory terms and

    conditions, and at transparent, feasible cost-orientated rates;

  • 18

    Universal service: Members may impose universal service obligations that are

    transparent, non-discriminatory, competitively neutral and do not create unnecessary

    burdens on service suppliers;

    Public availability of licensing criteria: Members should make publicly available the

    licensing criteria, the decision-making timeframe, and the terms and conditions of

    individual licenses;

    Independent regulators: Members should ensure that NRAs are separate from and not

    accountable to any telecommunications supplier and that decisions are impartial and

    based on equal, transparent and objective treatment of all market operators; and,

    Allocation of scarce resources: Allocation and use of scarce resources should be

    carried out in an objective, timely, transparent and non-discriminatory manner and

    made publicly available.42

    Telecommunications sector reform in SSA has improved tremendously over the last decade.

    Regulatory mandates and requirements have driven network expansion and introduction of

    new services in the fixed-line market segments. Requirements for unbundling the local loop,

    publication of reference interconnection offers and the setting of minimum quality of service

    standards have improved competition in fixed-line markets and protected consumers.

    However, growth has been slower relative to mobile markets which received a liberal

    regulatory approach, less regulatory intervention and the creation of opportunities for mobile

    market development.43

  • 19

    Figure 3: Regulating Fixed-lines

    Source: ITU

    Market liberalization involves the grant of licenses to ISPs and broadband service providers,

    setting technical standards, defining price regulations, and designing interconnection

    principles and dispute resolution mechanisms. It also requires the identification of key

    bottlenecks to sector development and the formulation of appropriate regulatory actions to

    address them. Liberalization must also go beyond the provision of mobile services.44

    Figure 4: Incentive regulation and growth in mobile services

    Source: ITU

  • 20

    Licensing restrictions in some SSA countries on terrestrial backbone networks, international

    gateways and submarine cables limiting the size of operators networks, obstacles in

    obtaining rights of way, and outright monopolies continue to hinder private investments.45

    2.2 The Doctrine of Essential Facilities

    The threat of market entry in contestable competitive markets is an important constraint on

    firms already in markets. This constraint prevents them from anti-competitive pricing because

    potential entrants would respond to the opportunity for profit by entering and reducing

    prices.46

    Markets are contestable where there are no barriers to entry and exit.47

    In

    telecommunications markets, barriers to entry may be due to legal restrictions, economies of

    scale and scope, high fixed or sunk costs and essential facilities.48

    As such, the three criteria

    test for regulatory intervention applies where:

    1. There are high and non-transitory entry barriers;

    2. Market structure does not tend towards effective competition within a relevant time

    frame; and,

    3. Application of competition law is insufficient to address market failure.49

    The essential facilities doctrine was developed by Professor A.D. Neale in his treatise of

    United States (US) Supreme Court and lower-court rulings dealing with the refusal by a

    vertically-integrated dominant undertaking to deal with a competitor. The standard elements

    of essential facilities were established by the 1983 US Court of Appeals decision in MCI

    Communications Corp. v. AT&T. The four-part test is the standard for imposing antitrust

    liability for failure to deal with a competitor and applies where:

    1. A monopolist controls access to an essential facility;

  • 21

    2. The facility cannot feasibly be replicated;

    3. Access to the competitor is denied by the monopolists; and,

    4. Granting access is possible and there is no valid justification for refusal to deal.50

    Essential facilities are critical inputs to retail production at the wholesale level of the

    production chain and are essential inputs in the supply of retail products or services.51

    Monopoly control of essential facilities can create incentives for anti-competitive behavior to

    repress competition and create artificial hurdles for rivals in the market for the final products

    sold to consumers.52

    Liberalization of the telecommunications sector resulted in the

    emergence of two types of markets: provision of services to end users market and provision

    of access to facilities market necessary to provide service to end users. Service providers

    require access to one or more upstream, or downstream, facilities to provide services to

    customers. NRAs must therefore ensure that the prospective access markets develop and

    dominant incumbents do no use their control over access facilities to stifle development of

    competition and new services.53

    Figure 5: Concept of Essential Facilities

    Source: ITU

  • 22

    Access, within the telecommunications industry, remains an important aspect of regulations

    and antitrust.54

    Effective competition requires that new entrants have access to facilities with

    natural monopoly characteristics;55

    this precludes incumbent operators from using ownership

    of bottleneck facilities to control market developments.56

    Essential facilities include

    interconnection inputs provided to facilitate the logical linking of competing networks and

    the exchange of traffic.57

    Regulation of access terms and conditions to essential inputs by

    competing firms remains the single biggest regulatory issue; competition and the success of

    liberalization depend on the terms and conditions chosen.58

    Particular attention is required when dominant undertakings own and use an essential facility

    required by competitors to provide services to their customers; especially when access is

    denied rivals without justification; or on terms less favorable than granted to their own

    services.59

    Within the context of the European Union (EU), Articles 85 and 86 of the Treaty

    of Rome (March 25, 1957) specifically prohibit agreements that have as their purpose or

    result, the prevention, restriction or distortion of competition within the EU; or conduct

    which constitutes an abuse of a dominant position.60

    This is consistent with the probability

    that incumbent undertakings may continue to remain dominant for some time, both in the

    provision of access and services,61

    and necessitate regulatory intervention over the long term.

    The doctrine of essential facilities attempts to provide the legal certainty and predictability

    for access to bottleneck facilities required to facilitate investments in new infrastructure and

    services.62

    This promotes consumer welfare by eliminating exclusionary, anticompetitive

    behavior. The applications of the doctrine of essential facilities and antitrust law have

    developed differently in the US and the EU. In the US, the focus of antitrust law is

    prohibiting transaction intended to maintain or create monopoly power; in the EU the purpose

  • 23

    is to prevent abuse of a dominant position. In the US therefore, essential facilities cases are

    considered exceptions to the general Colgate defense principle that undertakings are under

    no obligation to deal where there are legitimate competitive reasons for refusal. In the EU the

    essential facilities doctrine is a specification of a general duty of dominant firms to deal.63

    The principle of obligating dominant monopolies in network infrastructure to contract is

    premised on the fact that competition in downstream markets depend on the pricing and

    conditions of access in upstream network services. An objective of increasing competition in

    downstream markets is to facilitate higher value services than local infrastructure. This has

    significance where the refusal of access renders provision of a new service impossible or

    limits the development of different new markets, products or services for which there is

    consumer demand64

    not satisfied by existing products or services.65

    In determining whether a dominant firm controlling an essential facility should be obliged to

    grant access, the following conditions should be present:

    a. Access is essential for competition on the relevant market and refusal of access makes

    competition impossible;

    b. Sufficient available capacity to provide access;

    c. The owner does not satisfy demand, blocks new products or services or impedes

    competition on existing or potential services or product markets;

    d. The access seeker is prepared to pay a reasonable non-discriminatory price on non-

    discriminatory terms and conditions; and,

    e. There is no objective justification for refusal of access.66

    Important considerations are:

    1. Does access achieve or facilitate competition in downstream or upstream markets?

  • 24

    2. General public interest significance of access to the economy and impact on national

    competitiveness of effective competition in the relevant market; and,

    3. The legitimate interest of the facility owner.67

    Essential facility cases are all linked by infrastructure owners also participating in a market

    dependent on access to that infrastructure, constituting a conflict of interest. They also

    involve vertically-integrated dominant firms in one market using their dominance in a manner

    to strengthen their position and eliminate competition in a related market.68

    2.3 Counter Essential Facilities Arguments

    There are concerns that the enforcement of access conditions on owners of essential facilities

    amounts to re-allocating monopoly rents accruing from the facilities amongst competitors

    with little impact on consumers. Notably, antitrust law does not prohibit monopolies that are

    earned;69

    therefore it has been cautioned that:

    The rights to choose trading partners and dispose freely of ones property are

    generally recognized principles of law, therefore violations require careful

    justification;

    Using competition policy to interfere with a dominant undertakings freedom to

    contract requires careful balancing of conflicting considerations. Easy accesses to

    production, purchasing or distribution facilities reduce incentives to develop

    competing facilities and competition in the long term. The mere fact that retaining a

    facility for its own use gives a dominant undertaking competitive advantage cannot

    justify requiring access to it;

  • 25

    The primary purpose of antitrust and competition law is to prevent distortion of

    competition and safeguard the interests of consumers; not to protect the interests of

    particular competitors; and,

    The essential facilities doctrine is only justified when there is a genuine stranglehold

    on the related market.70

    Areedas six limiting principles cautions against imposing liability based on the essential

    facilities doctrine; rather, he urges the allowance of defenses based on legitimate business

    justifications, because:

    1. Compulsory access should be very exceptional since there is no general duty to share;

    2. A single firms facility is essential only where it is critical to the access requestors

    competitive vitality, and the requestor is essential for market competition;

    3. Firms should only be forced to deal where dealing substantially increases competition

    by reducing prices or increasing output and innovation;

    4. Denial of access is never unlawful per se and legitimate business purpose is a valid

    defense;

    5. Discernment of intent should seek to establish if the dominant firm sought to

    exclude competition by improper means or merely to limit competition and increase

    profits; and,

    6. The duty to deal should not be imposed by a court that it cannot explain or adequately

    and reasonably supervise.71

    While the roots of the essential facilities doctrine are said to originate in the US from the

    1912 Terminal Railroad decision, the Supreme Court in Trinko (2004) denied the existence

    of such a doctrine. The Court ruled that essential facility claims are not relevant where there

  • 26

    is effective power to compel sharing and regulate its scope and terms.72

    Critics argue that

    courts conclude too quickly that refusal to deal harms consumers and it remains unclear that

    refusal of a monopolist to supply a downstream competitor is contrary to public interest. A

    refusal to supply which eliminates a competitor, may not produce a significant reduction of

    competition or have a significant anticompetitive effect on the market.73

    The essential

    facilities doctrine is also considered an assault on property rights of successful firms;

    inappropriate application risks damaging incentives for economic efficiency which underpins

    economic and technical progress. This is significant where intellectual property (IP) rights are

    misrepresented as monopoly rights in a misuse of essential facilities arguments. Imposing

    an obligation to supply on a facilities owner without specifying the details of that obligation

    compounds the situation.74

    The obligation to grant access to essential facilities creates a tension between static

    competition and dynamic competition. Static competition increases where access is granted to

    facilities essential for downstream markets, reducing more important dynamic competition.

    Intervention also reduces incentives to invest in essential facilities, and the incentives for

    possible third party duplication.75

    Additionally, competition rules may be used, not to enable

    expansion of efficient firms, but to protect smaller and medium sized firms at the expense of

    efficient or larger firms. This subordinates the interests of consumers and the economy to the

    interests of smaller traders.76

    Calls therefore remain for the retention of high burden of proof

    in essential facilities cases, with access granted only where each of the following questions is

    answered affirmatively:

    1. Was the monopoly earned and are there compelling external social or economic

    reasons beyond monopoly exploitation for forcing access?

  • 27

    2. There is a mechanism in place for monitoring and regulating the price and terms of

    access?

    3. Is it inconceivable to circumvent the use of the facility?

    4. Is it impossible in the foreseeable future for new technologies to substitute for the

    essential facility?77

  • 28

    Chapter 3: Telecommunications Sector Reform in West Africa

    3.0 Introduction

    The Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS) was created on May 28, 1975

    by the Treaty of Lagos. It forged an economic union amongst 15 West African Member

    States: Benin, Cte d'Ivoire, The Gambia, Ghana, Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, Liberia, Mali,

    Mauritania, Niger, Nigeria, Senegal, Sierra Leone, Togo, and Burkina Faso. Cape Verde

    joined in 197778

    and Mauritania withdrew in 1999 due to disagreements over the ECOWAS

    Protocol for Conflict Resolution.79

    ECOWASs objectives are economic trade, national

    cooperation and monetary integration for the growth and development of West Africa80

    through effective economic cooperation and integration.81

    Figure 6: Economic Community of West African States

    Source: The World Bank

    Other sub-regional integration arrangements include the Communaute des Etats de lAfrique

    de lOuest (CEAO), the Mano River Union (MRU), the West African Economic and

    Monetary Union (UEMOA) and the West African Telecommunications Regulatory Assembly

    (WATRA).

  • 29

    WATRA was established in November 2004 by ECOWAS Member States and Mauritania.

    Its membership includes 15 independent NRAs and departments for regulation of

    telecommunications services. WATRAs formation was to address sub-regional

    telecommunications industry challenges, develop a harmonized regulatory identity to increase

    investors confidence and sector investments, and contribute to industry human resource and

    capacity building efforts.82

    Table 3: Regional Integration and Membership Arrangements in West Africa

    Source: The World Bank

    3.1 Regional Telecommunications Development

    Regional Economic Communities (RECs) are important in enabling regional integration of

    ICTs and trade.83

    However, the small-scale economies of ECOWAS Member States inhibit

    this role. Eight Member States have populations below 10 million, 11 Member States have a

    GDP of less than $5 billion, while three Member States are landlocked and rely on

    neighboring infrastructure to access critical markets. This prevents economies of scale in

    infrastructure development and makes it difficult for governments to pay the high fixed costs

    of infrastructure development.84

    ECOWAS incumbent operators are also impeded by bad

  • 30

    management and poor underdeveloped infrastructure.85

    In 2011 ECOWAS penetrations rates

    were 2.41% for fixed-line, 61.65% for mobile-cellular and 3.43% for fixed-broadband.86

    However, compared with other RECs, ECOWAS provides better access to ICTs, though at

    higher prices. ECOWAS international bandwidth indicators of 16 bits per capita and mobile

    subscriptions of 25 per 100 inhabitants are the second-highest in Sub-Saharan Africa after the

    Southern African Development Community (SADC). ECOWAS broadband access rates and

    Internet subscriptions are lower compared with SADC, possibly due to the late arrival of

    international broadband capacity which may account for the relatively higher tariffs. The

    monthly-averaged prepaid mobile basket cost of $14 is higher than in any other region except

    the Central African Economic and Monetary Community (CEMAC), and monthly Internet

    access price of $80 is exceeded only by East African Community (EAC). The prices of

    international telephone calls and fixed-line telephone service, however, are relatively low.87

    WATRAs proactive regulatory intervention and large regional mobile operators has led to

    relatively advanced regional mobile roaming arrangements. WATRA has been particularly

    active in promoting regulatory ICT harmonization and the ECOWAS Department of

    Transport and Telecommunications promotes key objectives of a single liberalized market,

    harmonized laws and regulations, coordinating/integrating regional infrastructure projects,

    and enhancing regional GSM service. ECOWAS Member States have embraced telecom

    sector reform and are very open to foreign investment in mobile telecommunications, with

    most countries having two or three foreign operators.88

  • 31

    Table 4: Telecom performance indicators for ECOWAS & Mauritania

    Source: The World Bank

    ECOWAS has international broadband connectivity from several submarine cables including:

    1. South Atlantic 3 (SAT-3)/WASC: 14,350 km from South Africa, up West Africa to

    Portugal and Spain, connecting 36 countries with 120 Gbps;

    2. Atlantis-2: 8,500 km connecting South America, Cape Verde, Senegal, Portugal, and

    Spain with 10 Gbps @ $370 million;

    3. Glo-1: 9,800-kilometer connecting 17 African countries to the United Kingdom with

    318.4 Gbps @ $170 million;

    4. Africa Coast to Europe (ACE): 14,000 km from France to South Africa connecting 24

    countries with 1.92 Tbps @ $650 million; and,

    5. West African Cable System (WACS): 17,200 km from South Africa, along West

    Africa to the United Kingdom connecting 15 countries with 3.84 Tbps, @ $650

    million.89

  • 32

    Figure 7: West Africa's Undersea Cables

    Source: Manypossibilities.net

    3.2 Telecom Sector Reform within ECOWAS

    ECOWAS has commenced several infrastructure projects and activities in cooperation with

    the New Partnership for Africa's Development (NEPAD), the EU, the World Bank, USAID

    and other donors.90

    From 2002 up to 2013 the following sector reform milestones have been

    achieved:

    February 2002: World Bank launched regional telecommunications harmonization

    study;

    2004: ITU launched regional project to establish an integrated West Africa ICT

    Market;

    September 2005: Common Market Best Practice Guidelines adopted by the 3rd

    Ordinary General Assembly of WATRA;

    May 2006: ECOWAS ICT Ministers validate legislative and regulatory texts for the

    establishment of a Common ICT Market;

  • 33

    January 2007: validated legislative and regulatory texts adopted by ECOWAS Heads

    of States and Government as Supplementary Acts;91

    November 2009: WATRA identifies access to submarine cables as most pressing

    priority;

    December 2010 and March 2011: draft submarine cable assessment report, guidelines

    and regulation validated at WATRA and ECOWAS consultative and National ICT

    Experts meeting respectively;

    June 2011: Access to Submarine Cables Guidelines adopted at the 9th WATRA

    Annual General Assembly;

    October 2011: Regulation on Access to Submarine Cables in West Africa adopted at

    the 11th Meeting of ECOWAS ICT Ministers; and,

    2013: Access to Submarine Cables Assessment Report issued.92

    3.2.1 World Bank Support

    In the 1990s the Bank shifted its ICT strategy from support to large infrastructure projects to

    smaller lending interventions of technical assistance (TA). The TAs focused on building

    enabling sector environments to mobilize private investments, using competition as the

    primary policy tool to promote efficiency and innovation while facilitating regulatory

    capacity development. Within ECOWAS, the Bank has been involved in market

    liberalization through privatization and licensing in Burkina Faso, Ghana, Mail, Niger, and

    Nigeria.93

    The Bank and Public Private Infrastructure Advisory Facility (PPIAF) provided support to

    ECOWAS to develop a common framework to harmonize national telecommunications

  • 34

    sector policies amongst Member States and establish a common telecommunications market.

    This was based on perceptions that NRAs within ECOWAS were not autonomous and lacked

    the authority to make and enforce regulations.94

    A telecommunications harmonization study

    was launched in February 2002 and subsequently endorsed at validation meetings in Abuja,

    Accra, and Lom.95

    The study concluded that:

    There was sufficient completed work to create the regional legal framework;

    Some Member States had adopted laws and regulations in line with international best

    practice;

    The ECOWAS Treaty and Protocols provided the legal framework to achieve

    harmonization in line with the centralized harmonization model;

    Previous failures to implement expressed ideas and principles of the ECOWAS legal

    framework were a disappointing track record in advancing Treaty initiatives;

    Resources were insufficient to perform enforcement and other regulatory functions;

    and,

    Different legal traditions of Member States, different levels of liberalization, and

    trade-offs affecting the relative gains of individual countries, posed additional

    challenges.96

    Recommendations were that ECOWAS adopt a centralized harmonization model based on

    the existing legal framework for implementation at both the national and treaty levels. An

    implementation schedule and draft Protocol were also proposed.97

    ECOWAS connectivity gaps prevented Member States from deriving the full benefits of a

    highly functional and effective ICT sector. This was due to higher communication costs and

    capacity bottlenecks limiting the availability of end-to-end high-capacity bandwidth at

    competitive pricing. A regional approach to bridging this connectivity gap was necessary to

  • 35

    facilitate better access to international infrastructure. Regional cross-border connectivity was

    also impeded by costly routing of traffic through non-regional third-party countries, straining

    regional economic and social development. Civil wars in Guinea, Liberia and Sierra Leone

    destroyed critical transmission infrastructure, leaving no functional cross-border links

    between the countries. There are also no cross-border links connecting Guinea northward to

    Mali, eastward to Cote dIvoire and southward to Liberia. This required a new approach to

    create regional connectivity, provide redundancy to costly existing routes, rapidly reduce the

    missing gaps between the countries, and reduce the fragmentation of existing member

    systems.98

    In this context, the Bank developed a $300 million99

    West Africa Regional Communications

    Infrastructure Program (WARCIP) to expand the geographical reach of broadband networks

    and reduce communications costs within the region. In WARCIPs first phase, funding was

    provided to Liberia and Sierra Leone in the amounts of $25.6 million100

    and $31 million101

    respectively. In the second phase WARCIP provided similar support to The Gambia, Guinea

    and Burkina Faso.102

    The WARCIP funding support has three components:

    1. Supporting connectivity:

    a. International connectivity - facilitating membership to the Africa Coast-to-

    Europe (ACE) Cable Consortium;

    b. Regional/national connectivity leveraging alternative infrastructure;

    2. Creating an enabling environment for connectivity; and,

    3. Project implementation support.103

  • 36

    3.2.2 ITU Support

    By 2003 regulatory reforms within ECOWAS contributed to accelerated sector progress and

    increases in penetration rates for mobile communications. The ITU directly assisted

    governments, conducted studies, provided training tools, organized workshops and forums,

    and sponsored regional and sub-regional organizations. Interventions were based on

    implementation of the ITUs Telecommunications Development Bureaus (BDT) operational

    plan and focused on accelerating creation of an environment to facilitate rapid extension of

    access to ICTs. The ITU contributed to improvements in frequency and numbering

    management and interconnection, which was a source of conflict amongst operators.104

    Table 5: Status of ECOWAS Regulatory Instruments 2002/2003

    Source: Evora-Sagna

    Between 2004 and 2007, the ITU collaborating with the EU, implemented the West African

    Common Market Project to harmonize policies governing ICT markets within ECOWAS.

    This was as a pilot project to develop and promote harmonization of policies and guidelines

    based on best practices within ECOWAS and develop a harmonized regulatory framework

    for the ICT sector and build human and institutional capacity in the field of ICT.105

    The

  • 37

    project built on the recommendations and conclusions of the Banks Harmonization of

    Telecommunications Policies in ECOWAS study leading to the development and adoption

    of:

    Harmonized regional ICT policy for:

    a. National ICT Policy and Law;

    b. Interconnection;

    c. Licensing;

    d. Numbering;

    e. Radio Spectrum Management; and,

    f. Universal Access and Universal Service.

    Harmonized regional ICT legislation; and,

    Harmonized regional regulatory guidelines.106

    The regulatory guidelines were adopted by the 3rd WATRA Annual General Meeting (AGM)

    of September 9, 2005 held in Dakar, Senegal.107

    The harmonized regional ICT policies and

    ICT legislation led to the development and adoption of ECOWAS Supplementary Acts by the

    Thirty-First Session of the Authority of Heads of State and Government held in

    Ouagadougou, Burkina Faso on January 19th

    , 2007. The adopted Acts were:

    Supplementary Act A/Sa.1/01/07 On The Harmonization Of Policies And Of The

    Regulatory Framework For The Information And Communication Technology (ICT)

    Sector;

    Supplementary Act A/Sa.2/01/07 On Access And Interconnection In Respect Of ICT

    Sector Networks And Services;

    Supplementary Act A/Sa.3/01/07 On The Legal Regime Applicable To Network

    Operators And Service Providers;

  • 38

    Supplementary Act A/Sa.4/01/07 On Numbering Plan Management;

    Supplementary Act A/Sa.5/01/07 On The Management Of The Radio-Frequency

    Spectrum; and,

    Supplementary Act A/Sa.6/01/07 On Universal Access/Service.108

    Subsequent instruments adopted include the Supplementary Act A/Sa.21d1/1d On Electronic

    Transactions Within ECOWAS, Supplementary Act A/Sa.1f01/10 On Personal Data

    Protection Within ECOWAS adopted by the 37th Session of Authority of Heads of State and

    Government in Abuja, Nigeria on February 16th, 2010 and Directive C/Dir. 1/08/11 On

    Fighting Cyber Crime Within ECOWAS adopted by the 66th Ordinary Session of the

    Council of Ministers in Abuja, Nigeria on August 19th, 2011.109

    In 2009 WATRA identified access to submarine cables as a pressing priority of its members

    and requested the assistance of the ITU in developing guidelines and regulations for access to

    submarine cables. The ITU funded the preparation of draft guidelines and regulation by

    consultants guided by the ECOWAS Commission and the WATRA Secretariat. The draft

    documents were reviewed, discussed and validated during a WATRA workshop in Monrovia,

    Liberia in December 2010 and at the ECOWAS National ICT Experts consultative meeting

    in Lom, Togo in March 2011. The WATRA Guidelines on access to submarine cables were

    adopted at the 9th WATRA Annual General Assembly in Accra, Ghana in June 2011. The

    ECOWAS Regulation on Condition for Access to Submarine Cables Landing Stations was

    adopted at the 11th Meeting of ECOWAS Ministers of Telecommunication and ICTs in

    Yamoussoukro, Cte dIvoire on 14 October 2011.110

    The Regulations seek to ensure:

  • 39

    The grant of licenses to new cable landing stations (CLS);

    Amendment of the existing licenses of CLS operators to conform to open access,

    nondiscrimination and prohibition of anti-competitive practices on the international

    capacity access market;

    Withdrawal of restrictions on access to international capacities in licenses or

    authorizations previously issued;

    Fair and effective access to available capacity on all cable systems operated by an

    SMP Operator are provided eligible operators upon request;

    Provision by CLS operators of co-location and backhaul services to eligible operators;

    Maintenance of a reasonable balance between the need to encourage competition and

    preserve a reasonable return on the investments made for the co-location;

    Publication by CLS operators of terms and conditions of all services in a Reference

    Interconnect Offer;

    Transparent charges for all services, operation and maintenance, in accordance with

    the cost calculation framework set by the NRA;

    Provision by SMP-CLS Operators of Service Level Guarantees consistent with best

    practices and equivalent to those applied to their own services or to their

    subsidiaries/partners; and,

    Availability of equitable dispute resolution mechanisms.111

    The design of terms and conditions of access to bottleneck facilities by competing

    operators remains one of the most vexing regulatory tasks of NRAs within ECOWAS. 112

    The

    terms, conditions and pricing for access continue to be root causes of interconnection disputes

    in the Region. Examples are disputes between Comium and Gamtel in The Gambia113

    ;

  • 40

    Areeba and Ghana Telecom114

    and Ghana Telecom and Spacefon in Ghana115

    ; NITEL and

    other GSM operators in Nigeria,116

    and between Lonestar/MTN and Cellcom in Liberia.117

  • 41

    4.0 Case Study of the Cable Consortium of Liberia (CCL)

    4.1 Introduction

    Liberia is situated in West Africa and borders Cte dIvoir, Guinea, and Sierra Leone.

    Liberias 14 year civil war engulfed the country, led to substantial loss of human lives,

    massive displacement population, widespread destruction of economic and social

    infrastructure and the disruption of productive and commercial activities.118

    Figure 8: Map of Liberia

    Source: Nations Online Project

    Liberias land mass is 43,000 square miles, its population 4,092,310 with a growth rate

    of 2.52%. GDP per capita is $700; growth rate is 8.1% and inflation 5.2%.119

    Liberias Internet penetration rate is 3.72% and access to both fixed and cellular telephone

    service 58.83%.120

  • 42

    Table 6: Demographic and economic indicators for Liberia

    Source: United Nations

    The Liberia Telecommunications Corporation (LTC) has historically provided

    telecommunications facilities and services in Liberia. The Corporation was created by the

    LTC Act 1973 granting it the monopoly to provide telecommunications facilities and services

    nationally. The LTC Amendment Act 1976 established LTC as a public corporation under the

    supervision of a Board of Directors. The 1978 Ministry of Posts and Telecommunications

    Executive Law transformed the Ministry of Postal Affairs to the Ministry and Posts and

    Telecommunications (MP&T). It transferred all policy and regulatory functions from the

    LTC to the Ministry.121

    Liberias civil war destroyed the telecommunications sector, resulting in a fixed teledensity of

    0.06%. Mobile communications kept Liberia connected internationally during the war and post-

    war communications are almost exclusively via mobile technology. Liberias mobile sector

    was liberalized in 1998 and became competitive in 2003 with the introduction of two

    additional mobile operators. Mobile density increased from 0.06% in 2003 to approximately

    to 5% in mid-2005, well above SSA average. However, in 2003 mobile service was still a

    luxury commodity for many Liberians. Internet access was also limited as 85% of users were

    large multinational businesses or international organizations with VSAT-based Internet

    services.122

  • 43

    Figure 9: Liberia's fixed and mobile growth rates

    Source: ITU

    4.2 Liberias Telecom Sector Reform

    Liberia, like Benin, The Gambia and Sierra Leone, issued licenses for competition in the

    mobile sector without the enabling legal framework.123

    In 1998 the MP&T licensed I-COM

    Communications (I-COM) and OMEGA Communications to offer mobile services via TDMA

    and GSM technology respectively. LibNet Inc. and Data Technology were also licensed as ISPs

    while UN Agencies, NGOs and banks were licensed to install and operate VASAT terminals for

    their humanitarian and corporate uses. In 1999, I-COM ceased operations and Atlantic

    Wireless Inc. (AWI), was licensed as a mobile operator using the AMPS standard. OMEGAs

    license was withdrawn due to license performance conditions and Lonestar Communications

    (Lonestar) granted the exclusive license to provide GSM service. By November 2001

    Lonestars subscribers exceeded the number of LTCs customers, making Lonestar the largest

    provider of telecommunications services in Liberia.124

    The ITU prioritized assistance to Liberia, Sierra Leone and The Gambia; the three countries

    without a formal regulatory body.125

    The ITU conducted the first workshop on Telecom

    Reform Policy in Liberia from April 11th

    15th, 2000. The focus was developing an affective

    telecommunications policy for a competitive environment, and formulation of both a

    Telecommunications Improvement Policy for Liberia and Posts and Telecommunications

  • 44

    Policy Statement.126

    Although funds were allocated in 2003 to complete the sector reform

    assistance covering legal framework, spectrum monitoring and interconnection, the assistance

    was cancelled due to security concerns.127

    President Charles Taylor resigned on August 11, 2003 and the Accra Comprehensive Peace

    Agreement of August 18, 2003 created the National Transitional Government of Liberia

    (NTGL) to replace the Government of Liberia.128

    The Bank approved Liberias Country

    Reengagement Note (CRN) in 2004 and provided $0.85 million to the NTGL to create an

    interim regulatory framework comprising of a National Telecom Policy & Strategy and

    interim LTA (ILTA) legislation.129

    The National Telecom Policy & Strategy presented the

    NTGLs vision of sector liberalization to improve and increase telecommunications services

    and develop an open, competitive market regulated by an independent NRA that reported to

    the Head of State.130

    Table 7: World Bank telecom technical assistance program to the NTGL

    Source: World Bank

    The Interim Liberia Telecommunications Authority (ILTA) was created by enactment of Bill

    18 by the National Transitional Legislative Assembly (NTLA) on September 5, 2005. Bill 18

    amended the Public Authorities Law creating the LTC, the Executive Law creating the

    MP&T, and established an interim regulatory framework for telecommunications. The

  • 45

    purpose was to prepare a new telecommunications law and establish a longer-term regulatory

    framework to recommend to the elected Government. It also established and clarified the

    framework for regulation of the telecommunications sector prior to the assumption of powers

    by the regulatory authority to be created under the new telecommunications law.131

    In September 2007 the Telecommunications Act of 2007 (Telecoms Act 2007) was enacted

    into law repealing Act No.18. The new Act established the legislative framework for policy

    making, regulation and development of the Liberian telecommunications sector. The Act

    defined the responsibility of the MP&T to develop policies for the telecommunications sector

    in consultation with the LTA and support the establishment of a regulatory environment for

    growth of the sector.132

    The Telecom Act 2007 established the LTA as an independent

    Commission of five Commissioners, nominated by the President and confirmed by the

    Liberian Senate. One Commissioner is designated Chairman of the Commission and all

    Commissioners are appointed to a four year term which may be renewed for another four

    year term.133

    Figure 10: Decline in Liberia's fixed-line infrastructure

    Source: UN Data

    Between August and October 2003 the MP&T issued 15 GSM licenses, in many cases, with

    overlapping frequencies. A Presidential Telecommunications Committee was established by

  • 46

    the NTGL to review the issuance of licenses and revise the spectrum plan.134

    The Banks

    PPIAF provided support to Liberias elected government commencing 2007 to develop a

    telecommunications fee and taxation policy, promote competition and improve access to ICT

    services. A PPIAF-funded telecommunications sector fiscal-study subsequently led to Bank

    support for:

    Finalization of rationalized spectrum allocation;

    Formulation of sustainable sector taxation;

    Formulation of a methodology and license fee schedule for mobile operators;

    Standardization of the licenses granted to existing mobile operators; and,

    Issuance of GSM licenses.135

    On April 24, 2009 four GSM licenses were issued operators for US$65 million in license fees

    for 15-year licenses with payments schedule in installments until 2019.136

    Licenses of the

    three new operators (Libercell, Comium and Cellcom) are alleged to have been hurried,

    opaque and without public tender or public assessment of capacity to perform; leading to

    accusations of bias and corruption.137

    Other support outcomes were finalization of:

    Licensing and Authorization Regulations LTA-REG-001, September 2010;

    Interconnection Regulations 2009 LTA-REG-003, September 2010;

    Regulations for the Treatment of Confidentiality, Dispute Resolution, Compliance,

    and Enforcement 2009 LTA REG-0002, March 1, 2010;

    Resettlement Policy Framework for the Liberia ACE Cable Landing Project,

    November 2010; and,

    Environmental and Social Management Framework for the Liberia ACE Cable

    Landing Project, November 2010.138

  • 47

    Table 8: Liberia's GSM networks Operator License Service MHz Owners

    Lonestar Cell 2000 2001 907-

    915

    PLC Investments (60%), originally Investcom Global

    (BVI) now MTN Group (40%)

    Libercell 2004 2004 890-

    895

    Atlantic Wireless International (45%) and HiTS

    Telecom (55%)

    Comium 2004 2004 902-

    902

    Comium Group (Lebanon) apparently owned by

    Dalloul family

    Cellcom 2004 2004 895-

    902

    Cellcom Telecommunications Limited (BVI) in turn

    owned by Emerging Capital Partners (Washington,

    DC), Cellcom (USA) LLC (Washington, DC) and

    Dialogue Limited (Larnaca, Cyprus). Source: Southerland

    The LTA also issued the:

    Tariff Moratorium Order LTA-TMO-003: placing a moratorium on tariff increases for

    all services offered by GSM operators and Internet Service Providers (ISPs);139

    Interconnection Tariff Order, LTAITO002A: mandating all licensed operators,

    upon request from another licensed operator, to enter into agreements to establish and

    maintain interconnection between networks and provide all other technically and

    economically feasible related facilities necessary at established interconnection price

    caps, pending the issuance of Interconnection Regulations by the LTA;140

    LTA EXEMPTION ORDER-0004/EXO-01/09-16-11: exempts LTC (branded as

    Libtelco in 2006) from requirements to pay license fees and defines its rights and

    responsibilities as the National Operator;141 and,

    Regulations on International Traffic, LTA-REG-0005: instituted policies and systems

    to minimize fraud/grey routing and discourage unfair market practices by regulating

    international call traffic to ensure revenues therefrom are appropriately accounted

    for.142

  • 48

    Table 9: LTA 2008 Interconnection price caps

    NO. SERVICE TYPES FLOOR PRICE CEILING PRICE

    1 Mobile to Mobile $0.06 $0.10

    2 Fixed Line to Fixed Line $0.02 $0.04

    3 Mobile to Fixed Line $0.06 $0.10

    4 Fixed Line to Mobile $0.04 $0.06

    Price Caps: Floor is the lowest price to charge and the Ceiling is the highest price to charge Source: LTA

    With the assistance of WARCIP Liberia Project funded consultants, the LTA in 2012

    undertook a review of Licensing and Authorization Regulations, LTA-REG-001, and drafting

    of a revised licensing and authorization regime. The purposes was to transition from a

    technology-specific to a technology-neutral licensing framework, considering new market

    realities introduced by the ACE cable system, and ensure conformity with the ECOWAS

    Supplementary Acts.143

    Draft Licensing Fees Regulations were also prepared to clarify and

    confirm the obligations of licensees to pay licensing fees determined by the LTA pursuant to

    the Telecom Act 2007.144

    Draft Quality of Service identifying minimum Quality of Service

    Standards to be met by service providers through periodic performance measurement reports.

    For the full benefit of international broadband connectivity provided by ACE to be realized

    an open and non-discriminatory access regime, consistent with loan contractual

    obligations145

    , had to be implemented. The Telecom Act 2007 requires the LTA to determine

    dominant operators in different telecom markets and if they, or may in future, abuse that

    position by preventing competition in relevant markets. In considering the relevant market for

    the CCL, it became apparent that changes to the Interconnection Regulations 2009 were

    required to give effect to a finding of dominance and the principle of open access.146

    Amendments were also required to ensure consistency and compliance with the ECOWAS

  • 49

    Supplementary Act A/SA.2/01/07 and give effect to applicable remedies for dominant

    licensed providers in markets relevant to interconnection.147

    Amended Interconnection Regulations were prepared to incorporate interconnection,

    facilities-leasing and access; consistent with the definition of interconnection in both the

    Act and Interconnection Regulations which refer to facilities leasing and granting access.

    The amended regulations also highlight obligations of dominant operators to provide

    interconnection upon request and provide access in terms of facilities-leasing and/or co-

    location. The inclusion of co-location in the access obligations confirms the extent of

    access anticipated under the Act.148

    Despite its importance, although drafted in 2012, the draft Regulations have not been

    consulted on, finalized, or adopted by the LTA. This undermines the authority of the LTA

    and supports perceptions that the LTA is unable to provide the leadership and environment

    for the resolution of interconnection disputes and deliver on its regulatory responsibilities.149

    The LTA in 2010 implemented a new National Numbering Plan (NNP) consistent with the

    ITUs recommendation E.164. The NNP was implemented without the accompanying

    Numbering Regulations. Therefore, in 2012 a draft Numbering Regulation was prepared to

    validate the NNP, promote investment, facilitate competition and protect customers.150

    The

    LTA also prepared draft Siting Regulations on Telecommunications Infrastructure

    Deployment to provide general conditions and guidelines on the deployment of telecoms

    infrastructure.151

    In 2013 the draft Regulations on Penalties, LTA-REG-0006, issued for

  • 50

    consultations, identified specific offences and penalties, fines and sanctions imposable on

    licensees for violations of license conditions, regulations, rules and orders of the LTA.152

    These draft regulations have been pending for two years or more and in that period, the LTA

    has been unable to conduct required consultations to finalize the instruments designed to

    improve sector interactions and governance. This strengthens sector perception of the LTA as

    weak and ineffective153

    although, the LTA has determined to finalize and adopt these

    regulations by June 2014.154

    4.3 The Cable Consortium of Liberia (CCL)

    Under the WARCIP Liberia Project, Liberia joined the ACE Consortium and the Cable

    Consortium of Liberia (CCL) was incorporated as a public-private partnership (PPP)

    comprising Lonestar (10%), Cellcom (10%), Libtelco (20%) and the Government of Liberia

    (60%). The CCL signed the ACE Construction & Maintenance Agreement on June 5, 2010

    and formalized Liberias membership to ACE.155 The ACE submarine cable landed in

    Monrovia on November 3, 2010156

    and the ACE cable system was inaugurated on December

    19, 2012 providing Liberia with its first international broadband connectivity.157

    To implement WARCIP Liberia Project, the Bank and the Government of Liberia (GoL) on

    February 8th

    , 2010 signed the Financing Agreement for the WARCIP Liberia Project. The

    Agreement provided for a 40-year low interest loan of $25.6 million at a service charge of

    of 1% annually to implement the Project.

  • 51

    In the design of the Project, the Bank identified implementation capacity and sustainability as

    key project risks, due to the limited perceived capacity of policy makers and the inexperience

    of the LTA with open access regimes.158

    $3.32 million was allocated by the Project to support

    the development of an enabling environment for the ACE cable landing to mitigate this risk.

    This included building the capacity of the MP&T to develop and implement sectorial

    policies, and support to strengthen the LTAs capability to regulate the sector.159

    In 2011 under Project funding, the LTA conducted a market study and determined that the

    relevant market for the CCL was the market for wholesale capacity and access to

    international fibre-optic submarine cables. The CCL is the only licensed cable landing station

    operator and no other technically feasible alternative is available. Considering the relevant

    market, the LTA considered that:

    High, non-transitory barriers to entry existed due to difficulty in securing investment

    funding for a second landing point;

    The lack of effective competition behind the barriers to entry with no credible

    competitor for international cables; and,

    Insufficiency of Liberias telecommunications/Competition law to resolve possible

    market failures because application of the LTAs ex post powers to resolve abuses of

    dominance would result in substantial damage to downstream retail markets before

    the abuse was rectified.160

  • 52

    Figure 11: Market Analysis process

    Source: Incyte Consulting

    CCLs perceived market share of 100% exceeded the threshold for a presumption of

    dominance and control of an essential facility within the relevant market combined with

    anticipated pricing behavior strongly supported the hypothesis of dominance. Additionally,

    six out of 11 other relevant factors* considered were significant indicators of dominance. The

    LTA therefore concluded that CCL was dominant in the market for wholesale capacity and

    access to international fibre-optic submarine cables and subject to remedies for dominance.161

    The Telecom Act 2007162

    and the Interconnection Regulations 2009163

    both define a

    dominant service provider as a service provider designated to have significant market power

    in one or more telecommunications service markets. The ECOWAS Regulations on Access to

    Submarine Cables164

    adopt the definition of Supplementary Act A/SA.2/01/07 that a

  • 53

    company, either on its own or with other companies, holds a dominant position when it has

    the capacity to act independent of its competitors, customers and consumers.165

    Table 10: Value-chain of related markets relevant to the CCL

    Source: Incyte Consulting

    4.4 Remedies for CCLs Dominance

    The Telecommunications Act 2007 provides that dominant undertakings must publish a

    Reference Interconnection Offer (RIO), which should be cost-based and comply with all

    regulations, rules and orders of the LTA.166

    Dominant providers must also provide access to

    network elements, physical infrastructure, ducts and masts, and network software systems.167

    Their tariffs, in their markets of dominance, must be approved by the LTA and they may be

    required to participate in market studies to develop tariff methods.168

    In this regard, the following remedies in Table 10 were considered appropriate:

  • 54

    Table 11: Proposed remedies for CCLs dominance

    Source: Incyte Consulting

    On October 1, 2012 following appropriate consultations, the LTA declared the CCL to be

    dominant in the market for wholesale capacity on, and access to, international fibre-optic

    submarine cables. The decision requires CCL to set prices for wholesale capacity on the basis

    of actual or predicted costs for the first three years using a methodology developed by LTA.

    The first review of the caps will occur six months after CCLs RFCS and annually

    subsequently. The price caps are as follows:169

    Table 12: Equivalent price per E1 per month (US$) based on capacity commitment Wholesale

    capacity ordered

    Year after Ready for Commercial Service Date

    1 2 3

    STM1 2,030 1,347 1,006

    E3 3,552 2,358 1,761

    E1 8,524 5,659 4,227 Source: LTA

  • 55

    4.5 Analysis

    The LTAs interconnection regulations require dominant service providers to grant access to

    infrastructure and network elements. However, specific regulations may be required for

    access to infrastructure required for distribution of CCLs capacity on cost-based prices. This

    includes LTCs Monrovia fibre-ring duct system, to avoid inhibiting Internet access and

    diffusion of ICTs. LTA guidelines specifying the circumstances for infrastructure sharing and

    imposition of penalties for non-compliance would also be helpful.170

    The LTA is criticized because since it established the obligation on CCL to publish a RIO on

    its website, the CCL has not published a public offer to date. The CCL has also not been

    licensed, although it commenced operations in January 2013. Also, international connectivity

    prices on the Liberian market for business data packages are substantially lower than the

    price caps imposed by the LTA and continue to decline driven by competition from

    Novafone, which recently bought. 5% share in the CCL. However, prices for retail data

    packages have not declined substantially. The LTA also needs to address the monopoly

    position of the LTC on the fiber backhaul for which it charges substantially more than the

    cost for supply of fiber backhaul services. ISPs and other smaller operators are not supplied

    capacity directly but are supplied capacity through CCL shareholders because CCL does not

    have a de-multiplexer to supply capacity below a STM1.171

    This was addressed during a

    Banks Mission to Liberia in January 2014 when the Bank approved a request from the CCL

    to purchase a de-multiplexer to supply E1 and lower capacity to ISPs.172

  • 56

    Table 13: WARCIP Liberia Project M&E Results

    Source: WARCIP Liberia Project

    It is argued that CCL market share is 0% on the wholesale capacity and access to

    international fibre-optic submarine cables markets because only its shareholders have been

    active in that market, negating the value of the price caps. Reduction of wholesale prices for

    capacity far below the LTA price caps set indicates reasonable competition in this market.

    The LTA should consider the potential of CCLs shareholders being jointly dominant in this

    market and the necessity for price caps on the retail markets. Remedies for LTCs

    monopolistic position on the Monrovia fibre-ring providing backhaul services and the market

    for leased lines should also be considered. Further market analysis of all telecommunications

    market segments must be conducted to identify other access bottlenecks, introduce more

    transparency and ensure effective competition.173

  • 57

    5.0 Chapter 5: Conclusion

    5.1 Summary

    Over the last decade the ICT/telecommunications sector has achieved tremendous outcomes

    and grown phenomenally, driven by a revolution in telecommunications technology

    combined with liberalization and telecommunications sector reform. The transformational

    opportunities of ICT can only be realized to the extent that regulatory frameworks create an

    enabling environment supportive of cultivating investment in, and widespread diffusion of,

    ICTs. Liberalized telecommunications markets necessitate the interconnection of rival

    networks through regulatory interventions mandating that incumbents provide network access

    to new entrants to enhance network externalities.

    Essential facilities are critical inputs to retail production at the wholesale level of the

    production chain and are essential inputs in the supply of retail products or services.

    Monopoly control of such facilities can create incentives for anti-competitive behavior to

    repress competition and create artificial barriers for rivals in the market for the final products

    sold to consumers. Telecommunications sector liberalization has led to two types of markets:

    provision of services to end users market and provision of access to facilities market to

    provide service to consumers. NRAs must therefore ensure that the respective access markets

    develop and dominant incumbents are prevented from using their control over access

    facilities to stifle development of competition and new services. However, the essential

    facilities doctrine is only justified when there is a genuine stranglehold on the related

    market.

  • 58

    ECOWAS has commenced several infrastructure projects and activities in cooperation with

    the NEPAD, EU, the Bank, USAID and other donors. Sector reform milestones achieved

    include regional telecommunications policy and regulatory harmonization, establishment of a

    Common ICT Market and Supplementary Acts and Regulation on Access to Submarine

    Cables.

    The Bank, ITU and other donors have assisted Liberia implement major telecom sector

    reforms and develop an enabling regulatory environment largely compliant with the

    ECOWAS framework. This assistance has been critical in successfully implementing

    Liberias participation in the ACE cable consortium and creating the open, transparent and

    non-discriminatory environment for the success of the CCL. However, the LTA must take

    urgent steps to reassert its sector leadership fulfillment of its regulatory responsibilities. This

    is crucial with reference to interconnection and access to essential facilities.

    5.2 Recommendations