stability of money demand function in nepal

84
STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION IN NEPAL A Thesis Submitted to the Central Department of Economics, Tribhuvan University, Kirtipur, Kathmandu, Nepal, in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements for the Degree of MASTER OF ARTS in ECONOMICS By SIDDHA RAJ BHATTA Central Department of Economics Tribhuvan University, Kirtipur Kathmandu, Nepal March 2011

Upload: siddha-raj-bhatta

Post on 02-Mar-2015

387 views

Category:

Documents


3 download

TRANSCRIPT

STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION IN NEPAL

A Thesis

Submitted to the Central Department of Economics,

Tribhuvan University, Kirtipur, Kathmandu, Nepal,

in Partial Fulfillment of the Requirements

for the Degree of

MASTER OF ARTS

in

ECONOMICS

By

SIDDHA RAJ BHATTA

Central Department of Economics

Tribhuvan University, Kirtipur

Kathmandu, Nepal

March 2011

LETTER OF RECOMMENDATION

This thesis entitled “STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION IN NEPAL”

has been prepared by Mr. Siddha Raj Bhatta under my supervision. I hereby

recommend this thesis for examination to the Thesis Committee as a partial

fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of MASTER OF ARTS in

ECONOMICS.

________________________

Mr. Ananta Kumar Mainaly

Associate Professor

Thesis Supervisor

Date : .............................

APPROVAL SHEET

We clarify that this thesis entitled "STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND

FUNCTION IN NEAPL" submitted by Mr. Siddha Raj Bhatta to the Central

Department of Economics, Faculty of Humanities and Social Sciences, Tribhuvan

University, in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the Degree of Masters of

Arts in Economics has been found satisfactory in scope and quality. Therefore, we

accept this thesis as a part of the said degree.

Thesis Committee

___________________________

Prof. Dr. Rudra Prasad Upadhyay

Head of Department

___________________________

Dr. Yuba Raj Khatiwada

Governor, Nepal Rastra Bank

External Examiner

________________________________

Associate Prof. Ananta Kumar Mainaly

Thesis Supervisor

Date : ............................

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

This thesis entitled "STABILITY OF MONEY DEMAND FUNCTION IN

NEPAL" has been prepared for partial fulfillment of the requirements for the

Degree of Masters of Arts in Economics.

I am pleased to take this opportunity to express my heartfelt gratitude to my

thesis supervisor Associate Prof. Ananta Kumar Mainaly, the Central

Department of Economics, University Campus, Kirtipur, Tribhuvan

University for his valuable guidance, encouragement and suggestions

throughout my work. Similarly, I am grateful to Prof. Dr. Rudra Prasad

Upadhyay, the Head of the Central Department of Economics for his

suggestions and guidance. I also feel privileged to express my gratitude to all

the teachers of Central Department of Economics for their gracious response

to my queries.

I would like to thank all the non-teaching members of Central Department of

Economics and all the staff members of Central library, T.U. Kirtipur, for the

help they extended to me during this study in very many ways.

I want to extend my indebtedness to Dr. Tap Prashad Koirala, Research

Division, Nepal Rastra Bank, and Mr. Dadhi Adhikari, lecturer of Central

Department of Economics for their help in data transformation. Similarly, my

heartfelt thanks goes to Mr. Naveen Adhikari, Mr. Resham Thapa and Mr.

Khagendra Katuwal, the lecturers of Central Department of Economics for

their invaluable guidelines.

I am heartily indebted to my friend Miss Sapana Singh who encouraged me all

the moment to complete this work in time.

I bear sole responsibility for any errors and discrepancies that might have

occurred in this research report.

Siddha Raj Bhatta

March, 2011

TABLE OF CONTENTS

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS iv

LIST OF TABLES viii

LIST OF FIGURES ix

LIST OF ACRONYMS x

CHAPTER I: INTRODUCTION 1-7

1.1 Background of the Study 1

1.2 Statement of the Problem 3

1.3 Objectives of the study 4

1.4 Significance of the study 5

1.5 Limitations of the study 6

1.6 Organization of the study 7

CHAPTER II : REVIEW OF LITERATURE 8-23

2.1 Introduction 8

2.2 Theoretical Review 8

2.2.1 Classical View 8

2.2.2 Neo-Classical View/Cambridge Cash Balance Approach 9

2.2.3 Keynesian Approach 10

2.2.4 The Inventory-Theoretic Approach 12

2.2.5 The Portfolio Balance Approach 13

2.2.6 Modern Approach 13

2.2.7 McKinnon Approach 14

2.2.8 Implication of the Theories for Nepal 15

2.3 Review of International Empirical Studies 15

2.4 Review of National Empirical Studies 20

2.5 Conclusion 23

CHAPTER III: DATA AND METHODOLOGY 25-43

3.1 Introduction 25

3.2 The General Model 25

3.3 Selection of Variables 25

3.3.1 Scale Variable 25

3.3.2 Opportunity Cost Variable 26

3.4 The Empirical Model 27

3.5 Estimation Methodology 29

3.5.1 Autoregressive Distributed Lag Model (ARDL) to Cointegration

Analysis 30

3.6 Hypothesis 31

3.7 Econometric Tools 32

3.7.1 Time Series Properties of the Variables 32

3.7.2 Cointegration 33

3.7.3 Error Correction Modeling 34

3.7.4 Diagnostic Tests and Other Test 35

3.8 The Data 42

CHAPTER IV : DATA ANALYSIS 44-60

4.1 Time Series Properties of the Variables 44

4.2 Estimation Results 47

4.3 Estimation Results 57

CHAPTER V: SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS

61-64

5.1 Summary of the Findings and Conclusions 61

5.2 Recommendations 63

APPENDIX 65

REFERENCES 76

LIST OF TABLES

Table 3.1 : Variable Details 28

Table 4.1 : ADF Test Results 46

Table 4.2 : F-statistics (Bound Test) 47

Table 4.3 : Full-information ARDL Estimate Results(M1 monetary

aggregate) 49

Table 4.4 : Estimated Long Run Coefficients using the ARDL

Approach(M1 Monetary Aggregate) 51

Table 4.5 : Error Correction Representation for the Selected ARDL

Model(M1 Monetary Aggregate) 53

Table 4.6 : Full-information ARDL Estimate Results(M2 monetary

aggregate) 54

Table 4.7 : Estimated Long Run Coefficients using the ARDL

Approach(M2 monetary aggregate) 55

Table 4.8 : Error Correction Representation for the Selected ARDL Model

(M2 monetary aggregate) 57

LIST OF FIGURES

Figure 1 : Time Series Plot of ln m1t, ln m2t and ln yt 45

Figure 2 : Time Series Plot of rsdt and rfdt 45

Figure 3 : Time Series Plot of rrsdt and rrfdt 45

Figure 4 : Plots of CUSUM Statistics (M1 Aggregate) 58

Figure 5 : Plots of CUSUMSQ Statistics (M1 Aggregate) 59

Figure 6 : Plots of CUSUM Statistics (M2 Aggregate) 59

Figure 7 : Plots of CUSUM Statistics (M1 Aggregate) 60

LIST OF ACRONYMS

AIC - Akaike Information Criterion

ARDL - Auto Regressive Distributed Lag Model

CBS - Central Bureau of Statistic

FY - Fiscal year

GDP - Gross Domestic Product

JB - Jarque Berra Test

LM - Lagrange Multiplier Test

IMF - International Monetary Fund

MOF - Ministry of Finance

OLS - Ordinary Least Squares

NRB - Nepal Rastra Bank

RESET - Regression Specification Test

SBC - Schwarz Bayesian Criterian

UK - United Kingdom

USA - United States of America

CHAPTER I

INTRODUCTION

1.1 Background of the Study

The demand for money is one of the key functions in all macroeconomic models of

the economy. A sound monetary policy formulation presupposes theoretically

coherent and empirically robust model of money demand. The stability of money

demand function is crucial for the effectiveness of monetary policy in offsetting the

fluctuations that may arise from the real sector of the economy. Given the importance

attached to money demand in the success or failure of an activist monetary policy, it is

not surprising that the demand for money is one of the most controversial and heavily

researched areas in macroeconomics (Bose and Rahman, 1996).

A good understanding of the determinants of the demand for real money

balances in the economy by investigating the behaviour of the money demand

function is crucial for the formulation and implementation of an effective

monetary policy. Moreover, the identification of a stable relationship between

the demand for money and its determinants provides empirical evidence that

the monetary targeting is an appropriate framework for economic stabilization

policy (Rutayisire, 2010). That is, if the demand for real balances has a

consistent or stable relationship with its determinants, the changes in money

stock has predictable effects on income and output and the required change in

the money stock to restore the equilibrium in the economy can be easily

worked out. This is what needed for the stability of the economy. In such a

case, the central bank can bring the desired changes in the economy by using

monetary aggregate as a target variable. Thus, if the central bank relies on

control of monetary aggregates as its policy instrument, it must believe in a

known and reliable connection between changes in that aggregate and changes

in the arguments of the money demand function in order for its policy to have

predictable effects on those arguments. If instead the central bank relies on

interest rates as targets and adjusts the monetary aggregate through daily

reserve management to whatever level is required to hit them, instability of

the demand for money could make the required reserve changes both large

and unpredictable. Disorderly financial markets might well result (Cameron

1979).

In the monetarists‟ type of transmission mechanism, stability of the demand

for money function has a decisive role for the effect of money supply on

income and prices. If the demand for money is stable, any change in money

supply has a direct effect on aggregate expenditure. Whether this change will

affect real income or price or both depends on whether the economy is at full

employment or less than full employment. If the demand for money is not

stable, (i.e. velocity of money circulation is fluctuating), any change in money

supply can just be offset by equal and opposite change in velocity (through

idle hoarding/dishoarding of cash balance) having no effect on income or

prices. So, to analyze the transmission mechanism of monetary policy, the

specification of the demand for money function, test of its stability and

estimation of its elasticities is highly essential (Laidler, 1971).

Thus, for any central bank, stability issue of the money demand function is

one of the most important guiding policy issues that helps to decide whether

to use the monetary targeting strategy or inflation targeting strategy in the

monetary policy in bringing the desired changes in the economy. This issue

has been triggered further by the abandonment of monetary targeting strategy

by many developed countries such as Canada, Newzeland, Brazil, Turkey,

Norway, Australia etc as they switched to inflation targeting strategy. Stability

of the demand for money function is, therefore, the focus point for any central

bank.

In this context, an assessment of the monetary policy of Nepal requires first to

test the stability of money demand function. The central bank of Nepal has

been using both the narrow money stock and broad money stock as the

intermediate targets of the monetary policy. Especially after the adoption of

financial liberalization in the 1980s, there may have been the forces that might

have caused the instability in money demand and rendered the monetary

policy ineffective. Thus, this study mainly focuses on the stability of money

demand function in Nepal.

1.2 Statement of the Problem

After the implementation of liberalization program in 1980s, the Nepalese

economy has gone through some significant structural and institutional

changes. These changes included the liberalization of the external trade and

payment systems, substantial degree of financial deepening and innovations in

the banking sector, the elimination of price and interest rate controls, changes

in monetary policy, and the emphasis on market determined indirect

instruments of monetary policy. It is conceivable that these developments may

have altered the relationship between money, income, prices, and other key

economic variables; and this may have caused the money demand function to

become structurally unstable. Consequently, determining whether the

financial reforms undertaken under the liberalization program have affected

the stability of the money demand relationship is important to the effective

formulation and implementation of monetary policy. Nepal started the

financial liberalization process with partial deregulation of the interest rate in

1984. Since then, various liberalization measures have been implemented in

phases, which include removal of entry barriers of banks and financial

institutions (1984), reforms in treasury bills issuance by introducing open

market bidding system (1988), introduction of prudential norms (1984), full

deregulation of interest rates (1989), establishment of Credit Information

Bureau for providing information on borrowers (1989), shift in monetary

policy stance from direct to indirect (1989), reform in capital markets through

the establishment of Security Exchange Company and introduction of floor

trading (1992), reduction in statutory reserve requirement (1993), and

enactment of Nepal Rastra Bank Act (2001) and Debt Recovery Act (2002).

The above measures were aimed at “widening” and “deepening” of the

financial sector in Nepal.

Due to the extensive liberalization process, the effects of monetary policy may

be transmitted to the real sector of the economy, because of relaxation of

direct control over the interest rate. So, money demand function might have

been unstable. The implications of this is the change in the relationship among

money, income, interest rate and hence the effectiveness of monetary policy.

Financial market development through reform measures may lead to new

financial assets with attractive yield. This may shift portfolio from the

monetary assets. Transaction costs often go down due to competition among

financial institutions and hence money demand may respond more rapidly to

interest rate changes. The holding of monetary aggregates may be affected by

the development of rural banking through shifting fund from informal sector

to the banking sector. Thus the financial reform have implications for the

stability of the money demand function and hence the conduct of monetary

policy (Khan and Wadud, 2003).

With the passage of time, the scope of monetary policy is getting wider. It

aims at price stability, economic growth, full employment etc. In Nepal also,

Nepal Rastra bank is being entrusted with a number of objectives since its

establishment in 1956. The intermediate target chosen for the conduct of

monetary policy in Nepal are the monetary aggregates M1 and M2. The first

and foremost condition for these intermediate targets to work in achieving

final goals is a stable money demand function. In such a context, the present

study is focused on answering the following questions:

Is there any significant long run equilibrium relationship among real

money balances, the scale variable (real GDP) and the opportunity cost

variable (interest rate) in Nepal?

Is the relationship between demand for real money balances with its

determinants stable in Nepal?

Are the monetary aggregates used as intermediate targets appropriate

for Nepal?

1.3 Objectives of the study

The general objective of this study is to analyze the money demand function

of Nepal for narrow and broad monetary aggregates and examine their

stability so as to provide some policy recommendations to the central

monetary authority for designing the monetary policy.

The specific objectives of this study are:

1. To examine whether there exists a long run cointegrating relationship

between the demand for real money balances and its determinants or

not.

2. To examine the long run money demand function and the short run

dynamics in the money demand function.

3. To examine whether the relationship between the demand for real

money balances and its determinants is stable or not in the long run

and

4. To provide suggestions to the central monetary authority about whether

to use monetary targeting strategy or inflation targeting strategy.

1.4 Significance of the study

A stable money demand function forms the core in the conduct of monetary

policy as it enables a policy-driven change in monetary aggregates to have

predictable influences on output, interest rate and ultimately price. Because of

its importance, many studies have been carried out worldwide in the last

several decades (Sriram, 1999).

Empirical research on the money demand function is of utmost interest

because the information on its structure is very useful for policy makers in

designing effective monetary policy. Due to this importance, many studies on

money demand function in both developed and developing countries have

been conducted in the past.

The study on stability of money demand function in Nepal is of utmost

interest for several reasons. Firstly, demand for money and its stability have

important implications for the selection of the monetary policy instruments

and for the conduct of monetary policy. According to Poole (1970) interest

rate should be selected as the monetary policy instrument when the LM curve

is unstable and money supply should be the instrument when IS curve is

unstable. If the choice of the monetary policy instrument is inappropriate, then

monetary policy will increase the costs of stabilization. Since instability in the

demand for money is a major factor contributing to instability in the LM, it is

important to test for the stability of the demand for money. Many developed

countries have switched to interest rate as the monetary policy instrument

when their money demand functions have become unstable following the

financial reforms from the second half of the 1980s. Secondly, there are

remarkable changes in both financial sector and economy as a whole after the

adoption of liberalization policies in the 1980s as a result of which the number

of financial institutions has been grown rapidly. According to Bordo and Jung

(2004), the development of financial institutions could be a stronger source of

instability of money demand function which can make monetary policy

ineffective. Researches on the stability of money demand in the face of

ongoing financial reform program are still lacking in Nepal. Thus, there is a

need to test the stability of money demand function. Thirdly, estimates of the

demand for money are useful to understand the limits to non-inflationary

seignorage revenue and for the formulation of monetary policy targets.

Fourthly, the unit roots and cointegration literature has made significant

impact on modeling dynamic economic relationships and especially on the

demand for money. Finally, it is widely known that, the currency substitution

phenomenon by the growing number of other financial assets may cause the

instability of money demand function. This affects the effectiveness of

monetary policy. Thus, there is a growing need to test the money demand

relationship in Nepal using the recently developed econometric tools of

cointegration and error correction modeling as it can determine the power of

predictability for the behavior of monetary policy. This study aims at fulfilling

this objective and providing information to the policy makers to the usefulness

of monetary aggregates as intermediate targets of monetary policy.

1.5 Limitations of the study

The study has the following limitations:

1. The study covers the time series data from FY 1974/75 to FY 2008/09

only.

2. It is based on annual data as there is no availability of quarterly data

figures on GDP in Nepal.

3. Current inflation has been used as a proxy for expected inflation.

1.6 Organization of the study

The present study is organized in five chapters. The first chapter is an

introductory part of the study covering the background of the study, statement

of the problem, objectives of the study, rationale and study limitations. The

second chapter covers the review of some of the theories concerning the

demand for money and review of empirical studies at national and

international level. The third chapter provides a glimpse of the methodology

used. The fourth chapter covers the analysis of data and finally, the fifth

chapter presents the summary, conclusions and recommendations.

CHAPTER II

REVIEW OF LITERATURE

2.1 Introduction

In literature, money demand function has been studied using both „velocity‟

and „conventional‟ formulation. In comparison to the relatively limited

literature on the velocity, „conventional‟ money demand function attracted a

large number of researchers, primarily because it is easy to understand the

formulation (Omer, 2010). Even if one starts with the Post Bretton Woods

Period, Goldfeld (1973), Boughton (1981), Arango and Nadiri (1981), Butter

and Fase (1981), Mehra (1991), etc are a few among the vast pool of the

authors who made a significant contribution in this field, banking on the

conventional models. The conventional models also have been analyzed by

using different methodologies. Among them are simple linear model, log

linear model, semi log linear model, partial adjustment model, autoregressive

distributed lag model, Almon polynomial lag model, Vector error correction

model etc. A recent technique is the cointegration analysis and use of error

correction modeling to time series modeling used in the money demand

function. This chapter presents a brief review of some of the theories

concerned with the demand for money in section 2.2. Section 2.3 presents the

review of the empirical studies on the money demand function at international

level; section 2.4 presents a brief review of the studies on money demand

function at national level and conclusion from the reviews has been discussed

in section 2.5.

2.2 Theoretical Review

Different economists have raised their different views regarding the demand

for money. The various views can be outlined as below:

2.2.1 Classical View

Classical economists were not explicitly concerned with the demand for

money but it can be derived from the quantity theory of money as proposed by

Fisher. The classical quantity theory can be written as:

MV=PT………………………………………………………………..... (2.1)

Where,

M=stock of money,

V=transaction velocity of money

P= general price level and

T=volume of transaction in the economy

Here V and T are assumed to be constant in the short run.

Though the equation MV=PT is an equation for determining the price level in

the economy as money supply changes. The variables used in this equation are

significant enough to derive the theory of the demand for money. For this, this

equation can be written as:

Md=

v

1PT…………………………………………………………..... ..(2.2)

Equation (2.2) implies that a constant fraction of the total volume of

transactions is demanded to keep in the form of money for transaction

purposes.

2.2.2 Neo-Classical View/Cambridge Cash Balance Approach

The Cambridge cash balance approach associated particularly with Marshall

and Pigou argues that other things remaining the same, the demand for money

of an individual depends upon his income .i.e.

Md=k(py)……………………………………………............................(2.3)

Where,

Py = nominal income,

k = proportion of money income that one likes to hold as cash balance and k

depends on institutional factors.

This implies that a constant fraction of money income is demanded as demand

for money. This equation seems quite similar to Fisher‟s equation except that

k=1/v. Thus, factors affecting the velocity of money are responsible to

determine k.

The main features of cash balance equation can be outlined as:

i) It makes the demand for money a function of money income and only

of it.

ii) The Cambridge economists did recognize that other variables such as

the rate of interest, wealth etc influence the value of k and thus the

money demand. But they were not able to incorporate these variables

systematically in their analysis.

iii) Md is a proportional function of money income and price,

iv) The income elasticity and price elasticity of money demand are unity

so that money demand is a homogeneous function of degree one in

price.

2.2.3 Keynesian Approach

In the Keynesian view, the desire for money is a demand for liquidity

preference. He presented three motives for holding money: transaction,

precautionary and speculative motives. The first motive arises because money

is needed to finance daily purchase of goods and services or money is required

to bridge the gap between the receipt of income and expenditure and to meet

the time interval between incurring business costs and receipts of sales. The

amount of money demanded for this purpose is expected to vary directly with

the level of income.

The precautionary motive arises to provide for future contingencies like

accident, sickness etc. The money balance for this purpose is also expected to

vary with the level of income.

Keynes has lumped together the transaction and precautionary demand on the

grounds that both are fairly stable functions of income which can be written

as:

M1 = f1(Y) ∂M1/∂Y>0…………………………………………………(2.4)

Where,

M1=amount of money demanded for transaction and precautionary purposes

and,

Y = level of income

The most significant contribution made by Keynes is his analysis of money

demand is the speculative demand for money. To him, people demand some

amount of money for speculation, i.e. for making profit due to rise/fall in the

rate of interest. Considering only two financial asset-world, he concluded that

in deciding whether to hold money or bonds, investors would take account of

the prospective capital gain or loss in holding bonds and interest rate as well

(Cuthberston:1988). If the investors feel that the interest is too low and they

expect it to rise, the value of the bond is expected to fall and the investors hold

cash to avoid capital losses. Similarly, if investors feel that interest rate is too

high so that it cannot rise further and the only expectation is a fall in the

interest rate, in such a case investors hold bonds because with the fall in the

interest rate, bond price will rise and accordingly there will be capital gains.

Thus, the speculative demand for money depends inversely on interest rate

which can be written as:

M2 =f2(r); ∂M2/∂r <0………………………………………………....... (2.5)

Where,

M2 =speculative balances

r = interest rate

Lumping equations (2.4) and (2.5) together,

M = M1+M2 = f1(Y) + f2(r)……………………………………………..(2.6)

Where,

∂M/∂Y>0, ∂M/∂r <0

M=total demand for money balances

Thus in Keynesian approach, the transaction demand follows Cambridge

tradition, but the demand for money in aggregate is determined by the

speculative behavior of individuals also.

2.2.4 The Inventory-Theoretic Approach

Baumol (1952) has argued that the cash held by people for transaction is like

an inventory or stock of capital and thus until otherwise needed, it can be

invested in short term bonds. Thus transaction demand for money is interest

rate sensitive but only at a higher rate of interest. The goal in holding money

balance is to minimize the total cost of holding money which comprises of

brokerage fee and interest cost. The money demand function as argued by

Baumol can be written as:

M/2 = i

bY

2;……………………………………………………….(2.7)

Where M/2 is the average demand for money balance for transaction purpose,

b = brokerage fee per conversion while converting bonds into cash

Y = total nominal income

i = market rate of interest

This demand function shows that:

i) Transaction demand for money is inversely related with the rate of

interest and is thus interest rate-sensitive but only at a higher interest

rate.

ii) Transaction demand is non-proportionately related to income as against

the proportional relationship established by earlier theories.

iii) Elasticity of money demand with respect to interest rate is less than

unity.

iv) Income elasticity of demand for money is less than unity. It shows that

a person with higher income holds less cash and there are economies of

scale in cash management.

2.2.5 The Portfolio Balance Approach

Tobin (1959) has analyzed the speculative demand for money incorporating

the uncertainty and risk and concluded that individuals hold a combination of

cash and bonds so as to optimize the return on bonds and minimize risk. With

this portfolio optimization theory, he reaches the conclusion that the risk

factors and uncertainty also play important role in speculative demand for

money. However, his theory produces similar results as the speculative

demand for money as Keynes.

2.2.6 Modern Approach

Milton Friedman (1959) the leader of monetarism, restated the classical

Quantity Theory of money. To him, money is one kind of asset in the whole

portfolio of assets, a capital good, and a source of productive services. He

attempted to clear the conceptual framework of the quantity theory with the

assertion that the demand for money does not become infinitely interest elastic

but it is relatively interest inelastic (Patinkin:1972).

His money demand function can be written as:

Md = f(Y, h, P, R, π, µ)………………………………………….. (2.8)

Where,

Md = money demand,

Y = permanent income,

h = ratio of human to non-human wealth,

P = price level,

R = vector of interest rates,

π = inflation and

µ = a variable incorporating tastes and preferences

The restrictions to this demand functions are:

fR <0, fh>0, fπ<0, and fy>0

To Friedman, the money demand function represented by equation (2.8) is

homogeneous of degree one in price showing the demand for real balance, i.e.

Md/p = f(Y/P, h, R, π, µ)……………………………...…………….... (2.9)

The major issue raised by Friedman is the stability of the money demand

function. To him, money demand function is highly stable which implies the

stability of the velocity of money.

2.2.7 McKinnon Approach

McKinnon (1973) has opined that due to the underdevelopment of capital and

financial markets and the poor performance in the underdeveloped countries,

the theories for the demand for money in developed countries do not fit the

scenario of underdeveloped countries. He thus has argued that due to

underdevelopment of capital market, there exists complementary relationship

between the demand for money and the demand for physical capital. In such a

case, the money demand function can be represented as:

(M/P)d = f(Y, I/Y, d-

*p )………………………………………………..(2.10)

Where,

fY

'

>0, fYI

'

/>0, and

*

' .d p

f

>0

(M/P) = real money demand,

Y = real income,

I/Y = investment income ratio,

d-

*p = real rate of return from money,

d = nominal rate of return from money,

*p = expected rate of inflation

2.2.8 Implication of the Theories for Nepal

If the financial market imperfections, political instability, risks and

uncertainties are kept in mind, it becomes clear that the demand for money in

Nepal may be less sensitive to interest rate. Since capital and money markets

are not well-developed, the security market, bond market etc are not well-

practiced; the speculative demand for money may be inoperative. Since the

elasticity of interest rate is low, Baumol‟s approach has less significance in

Nepal (Gaudel, 2003). Similar is the case with Tobin‟s and Friedman‟s

analysis. This leads us to the classical economic world. As argued by Prasad

and Sampath (1977), people in underdeveloped countries obtain cash for

transaction purpose first by borrowing it and withdrawing it from investment,

secondly by withholding it from cash receipts and thirdly by withdrawing and

withholding. Thus, interest elasticity of demand for money would become

almost zero. Johnson (1963) has recommended the possibility of keeping a

block of cash by an individual out of his remuneration, investing the rest in

assets thereby reducing the interest elasticity of money demand less than

unity.

This suggests that a simple model on quantity theory approach would perform

better than the Keynesian approach in the context of developing countries like

Nepal.

2.3 Review of International Empirical Studies

Reviews of some of the studies using different approaches at international

level are as follows:

Taylor (1993) has estimated the short run and long run demand for broad

money for United Kingdom using high quality data from 1871-1913 applying

recent econometric technique of Johansen‟s Maximum likelihood approach to

cointegration and has discovered a unique, statistically significant long-run

money demand function relating broad money, prices, real income and the

long-term interest rate, which displays price and income homogeneity and a

plausible long-run interest rate semi-elasticity. Cointegration estimates to

model short-run adjustment in money demand in which short-term interest

rates and the own rate of return on money were found to be important, and

which returned the long-run estimates as the steady-state solution. This short-

run demand function was found to be superior to previous estimates for this

period on statistical grounds. It fitted well with well-determined coefficients

and shows no sign of structural instability.

Lumas and Mehra (1997) have analyzed the stability of demand for money

in USA using annual data for the period 1900 to 1974 using the varying

parameter approach developed by Cooley and Prescott (1973). They found

that the demand for money equations which regress money (M1 or M2) on

income and interest rates but omit a lagged value of the dependent variable are

not stable. This result is consistent with the observation that there are lags in

the adjustment of actual to desired money stock and hence stability requires

the specification of the adjustment mechanism in the money demand function.

Hamori and Hamori (1999) have found the demand for money in Germany

unstable. They have also used cointegration analysis with the quarterly data

from 1969:Q1 to 1996:Q3. The included variables are real GDP, M1, M2, M3

and call rates. They have used chow test to test the stability of the money

demand function.

Bahmani-Oskooee (2001) has tested the stability of money demand in Japan using

ARDL modeling to cointegration analysis by using the quarterly data from 1964 to

1996 and found that demand for broad money is stable. The included variables are

M2, real income and interest rate. With the help of CUSUM and CUSUMSQ test, he

has found a stable relationship in the money demand function.

Bahmani-Oskooee and Chi Wing Ng (2002) have examined the long run demand

for money in Hong Kong using the ARDL cointegration procedure on the quarterly

data from the first quarter of 1985 to the fourth quarter of 1999. They have concluded

that M2 is cointegrated with its determinants real income, domestic interest rate,

foreign interest rate and foreign exchange rate and all the coefficients have been

found to be significant. The long run income elasticity and domestic interest rate

elasticity have been found to be 1.730 and .038 respectively. They have used the

CUSUM and CUSUMSQ test to confirm the stability of the money demand function

and found it stable. Their study has suggested that in addition to the conventional

scale and domestic interest rate variable, the foreign sector consideration do matter in

explaining the variation in the broad money aggregate for a highly open economy like

Hongkong. The coefficient of exchange rate has been found to be positive supporting

the result that currency depreciation would reduce the demand for domestic currency.

Bahmani-Oskooee and Hafez (2005) have also used the ARDL modeling for a

number of countries like Singapore, Malaysia, India, Indonesia, Pakistan, Philippines

and Thailand. The sample period used is 1972:Q1 to 2000:Q4. The included variables

are real M1, real M2, real GDP, inflation rate and exchange rate. Their study has

shown that demand for M1 is stable in India, Indonesia and Singapore while in other

countries M2 is stable.

Halicioglu and Ugur (2005) have empirically analyzed the narrow money

demand function in Turkey over the period 1950 to 2002. The variables

included are real narrow money stock per capita, real national income per

capita, interest rate on alternative assets and nominal exchange rate. The study

has shown that there is a long-run relationship between the narrow money

aggregate (M1) and its determinants: national income, interest rate and

exchange rates. The methodology used is the single equation cointegration

technique, ARDL as proposed by Pesaran et al. (2000). The long run income

elasticity and interest rate elasticity from ARDL (1,0,0,0) model have been

found to be 0.93 and -0.01 respectively. The CUSUM and CUSUMSQ

stability tests indicate that there exists a stable money demand function

implying that narrow money aggregate can be used as an intermediate target

variable of monetary policy in Turkey.

Akinlo (2006) has used the ARDL modeling to test the stability of the demand for

money in Nigeria by using the quarterly data from 1970:Q1 to 2002:Q4 and found

that the variables M2, real GDP, nominal exchange rate and interest rate are

cointegrated. The CUSUM and CUSUMSQ tests reveal that a stable relationship

exists between the variables.

Bahmani-Oskooee and Bahmani (2007) have examined the money demand

function for broad money balances in Iran in the post revolutionary period of

Islamic Revolution 1979 considering the data set from 1979 to 2007. They

also have applied the ARDL modeling approach to cointegration analysis

including the variables: real GDP, inflation, exchange rate and a volatility

measure of the real exchange rate. Their examination has concluded that the

variables included in the money demand function are strongly integrated.

Their conclusion is that the M2 money demand function of Iran in the study

period is stable as such the revolution has not led to the parameter instability

of the money demand function. The estimated long run income elasticity is

1.0086 and the coefficient of inflation -3.18. The long run coefficients of

exchange rate and exchange rate volatility index have been found to be -0.14

and -0.17 respectively. All the coefficients are significant. Thus, their study

has argued that in addition to Mundell‟s theory on exchange rate being an

important determinant of the demand for money, exchange rate volatility also

serves as another important variable that impacts demand for money and

should therefore be included in the money demand function. Further, the study

has revealed that indeed, exchange rate volatility has both short-run as well as

long-run effects on the demand for real M2 monetary aggregate in Iran during

the post revolutionary period of 1979 to 2007, and is therefore a very

important determinant of demand for money.

Ahmed and Islam (2007) have empirically explored the long run equilibrium money

demand relationship as well as the short run dynamics in the context of Bangladesh

for M2, M1 and M0 using the Johansen and Juselius multivariate cointegration

analysis using the quarterly data from 1990 to 2006. This study has revealed that there

exists a statistically significant long run equilibrium relationship among real money

balances of various types, real income and respective nominal interest rates. The long

run demand for broad money and narrow money depend positively on real income

and negatively on the respective interest rates. The demand for real balances in the

economy is strongly dominated by the transaction motive for holding money as shown

by the elasticity of real income.

Bahmani-Oskooee and Wang (2007) have studied the stability issue in Chinese

money demand function with ARDL modeling to cointegration and found that in

China; M1 money demand function is stable while M2 money demand function is not

during the study period 1983:Q1 to 2002:Q2. The included variables are real income,

domestic interest rate, foreign exchange rate and the nominal effective exchange rate.

The estimated income elasticities are 1.28 for narrow money demand and 1.69 for

broad money demand respectively. On the other hand, the domestic interest rate

elasticities are -4.52 for narrow money demand and -1.54 for broad money demand

respectively. They have recommended that Chinese central bank should use M1

monetary aggregate rather than M2 in implementing monetary policy. The stability

issue has been examined by applying CUSUM and CUSUMSQ tests to the residuals

of error correction model.

Samreth (2008) has also used the ARDL modeling to cointegration analysis in

Cambodia with the monthly data from 1994:12 to 2006:12. His study has found that

there exists cointegration among the variables included in the money demand function

which are real income, inflation, exchange rate and real narrow money balances (M1).

The estimated elasticity coefficients of real income and inflation are positive and

negative respectively as expected. The long run income elasticity has been found to be

1.75 while the coefficient of inflation has been found to be -19.91. The coefficient of

exchange rate is negative supporting the currency substitution phenomenon in

Cambodia. The estimated results have further shown that the political turmoil in

Cambodia has no impact on money demand function. The CUSUM and CUSUMSQ

tests have revealed reveal that estimated model is roughly stable.

Ashsani (2010) has compared the estimation results from vector error correction

modeling (VECM) and ARDL modeling to cointegration analysis to money demand

in Indonesia. The results suggest that there was a cointegrating relationship among

real broad money aggregate (M2), real income and interest rate in Indonesia during

the study period. The ARDL modeling was found better than VECM in terms of

stability of the model, significant error correction term and other indicators like R-

square and R-bar square. The ARDL model was stable while VECM was not stable.

The estimated long run income elasticity was 3.20 and interest rate elasticity was

0.0819. The applied stability tests are CUSUM and CUSUMSQ. The study has

covered the sample period from 1990:Q1 to 2008:Q3.

Omer (2010) by using the ARDL Model has found that in Pakistan the

velocities of M0 (reserve money) and M2 are independent of interest rate and

depend on income and business cycle fluctuations where as velocity of M1

significantly depends on interest rate. This implies that M0 and M2 (broad

money) can be used as nominal anchors for operational and the intermediate

targets, respectively. He has also found that there exists a stable and long run

relationship between money velocities and its determinants such as, per capita

real permanent income, and transitory income. His Study has covered the

annual data from 1975 to 2006.

2.4 Review of National Empirical Studies

Empirical studies at the national level using the latest techniques of cointegration and

error correction modeling are still lacking. The main problem behind this is lack of

sufficient data observations, lack of high frequency data etc. Some of the studies

relating to money demand function and test of its stability in Nepalese context are as

follows:

Poudel (1987) has estimated the money demand function of Nepal using the data

sample 1974/75 to 1986/87. He has concluded that:

i) The demand for narrow money in Nepal is highly stable.

ii) Aggregate real income is highly statistically significant determinant of

the demand for all types of money defined in real terms.

iii) The income elasticity of the demand for M1 is greater than unity lying

in the range of 2.31 to 2.47 implying that money is a luxurious

commodity.

iv) The nominal rate of interest is not the appropriate rate in explaining the

demand for real money balances in Nepal but the real rate of interest

turns out to be a significant variable.

v) The income elasticity of the demand for time deposits is 3.77.

vi) The broad money has also more than unitary income elasticity whose

magnitude is 2.72.

vii) The McKinnon hypothesis fits in Nepal.

However, this study has not tested the stability of the money demand

function.

Khatiwada (1997) has analyzed the money demand function in Nepal using the

annual data of 21 years from 1975/76 to 1995/96. He has concluded that demand for

real money balance in Nepal is a stable and predictable function of a few variables

(real income and interest rate). He has concluded that the financial reforms have not

significantly affected the money demand function. He has found the income elasticity

of broad money (1.45) higher than narrow money (1.25). The unit root test shows that

most of the time series in natural logarithmic form of the levels of the data used in the

money demand function are time trended or integrated of order zero or one. Only

GDP deflator is integrated of order three implying the higher degree of non-

stationarity in time series. The Engle-Granger (EG) cointegration test reveals that real

narrow money demand, real income and interest rate represented by 12-months fixed

deposit rate are cointegrated when the time trend variable is included in the

cointegration test. However, the EG test shows that the cointegrating relationship does

not seem significant for broad money definitions of real money balances.

Pandey (1998) by using an error correction dynamic specification found that demand

for narrow money (M1) is highly stable and this has been confirmed by all the

statistical tests that were employed. He also has found that the rate of interest on

savings deposits does not have a significant effect on the demand for M1 balances.

This study has also established the fact that money is a luxurious item for the

Nepalese people and the expected rate of inflation does not seem to have a significant

influence on the demand for M1 in Nepal. However, he has not tested the stability of

the demand for broad money.

Gaudel (2003) has used chow test to investigate the stability for the three alternative

definitions of money in the demand function using OLS estimation and found that a

stable relationship is maintained in all definitions of money. His study has covered

the data set from 1965 to 1994 only. He has estimated the money demand function

using the following various models:

1. Simple Linear Model

2. Simple Modified Model

3. Log Linear Model

4. Semi Log Linear model

5. Auto-regressive Distributed Lag Model

6. Partial Adjustment Model

7. Adaptive Expectations Model

8. The Almon Polynomial Lag Model

9. Simultaneous Equations System

His major findings are:

i) The demand for money in Nepal over the sample period is best

explained as a function of income as a scale variable and rate of

inflation and interest bearing assets as opportunity cost variables.

ii) From the result of the chow test, it is found that a stable relationship is

maintained in all the three definitions of money.

iii) The overall results of the linear models conclude that narrow definition of

money is superior to broad definition of money. It seems to indicate that

narrow definition of money is more appropriate than broad definition

providing the evidence of non-monetized economy.

iv) The income elasticity of the demand for money is positive and less than unity

in all log linear models implying that money is not a luxury asset in Nepal. It

also supports the view of Baumol and Tobin that there is a significant

economy of scale in holding money balances.

v) Money and physical assets in Nepal are more complementary rather than

substitutes.

vi) The long run demand function in comparison to the short run demand function

has performed better.

vii) The interest elasticities in log linear models are found to be low and

statistically insignificant.

2.5 Conclusion

The studies at international level reviewed in section 2.3 imply that most of

the studies in the money demand function in the international level have used

cointegration analysis. It is because the results from OLS estimation can

suffer from spurious regression phenomenon if the data are non-stationary.

When the standard assumption of stationarity breaks down, straightforward

application of regression technique no more remains valid. It therefore

becomes necessary to look for the presence of unit roots, prevalence of

cointegration and consequent application of error correction models (ECMs).

Further, they give support to the use of ARDL modeling over other methods

like Johansen multivariate cointegration technique, Phillips and Hansen

technique, etc in case of annual data and/or small number of observation. It is

because the validity of the result may be questioned in case of small size of

sample in latter methods. They also reveal the fact that the real GDP, interest

rate, inflation and exchange rate are the most common determinants of money

demand. The national literature on the money demand function makes a few

things clear: first, there has been a considerable lapse of time in the empirical

study of money demand function since Khatiwada (1997) and Pandey (1998);

secondly, the available literatures are based on OLS method of estimation

except Pandey (1998) which utilizes Engle-Granger Cointegration Method.

The reviews of studies at national level are relevant to compare the results of

the elasticities and other findings from the present study with the ones from

previous ones. Next, the studies by Poudel (1989), Khatiwada (1997) and

Pandey (1998) help to decide the appropriate scale variable and opportunity

cost variables in the money demand function. These studies prompt one to

apply the recently developed cointegration technique to the formulation of

money demand function to avoid the phenomenon of spurious correlation and

spurious regression. They also help to compare the efficiency and robustness

of the methodologies used in the formulation of money demand function till

now. Therefore, there has arisen the need to re-estimate the money demand

function extending the data set beyond 1997 and examine the stability issue.

This study, thus, aims to overcome these two shortcomings by extending the

data set from 1975 to 2009 and by adopting the ARDL modeling to

cointegration analysis proposed by Pesaran and Shin (1999) to get rid of the

spurious regression problem.

CHAPTER III

METHODOLOGY OF THE STUDY

3.1 Introduction

This chapter is a discussion of the methodology used in this study. Section 3.2

presents the general model used in the money demand function, section 3.3

provides a discussion on the selection of appropriate variables, section 3.4

presents the empirical model and variable details, section 3.5 discusses the

ARDL modeling to cointegration analysis, section 3.6 presents the hypothesis,

section 3.7 provides a discussion on the various econometric tools and tests

used in the study and finally section 3.8 discusses the data sources.

3.2 The General Model

In the literature of money demand function, the basic model of money demand

begins with the following relationship:

M/P = f(S, OC)

Where, the demand for real balances M/P is a function of the chosen scale

variable(S) to represent the economic activity and the opportunity cost of

holding money (OC). M stands for the selected monetary aggregates in

nominal term and P for the price (Sriram, 2000).

3.3 Selection of Variables

3.3.1 Scale Variable

There is a wide controversy among researchers on the selection of appropriate

scale variable. Studies in the developed countries have mostly used wealth

and permanent income as scale variables. The studies in US have been mostly

specified in terms of permanent income as the scale variable [Brunner and

Meltzer(1964), Chow(1966), Laidler (1966), Khan (1974), etc] while there are

some emphasizing the use of wealth as a scale variable [Meltzer(1963),

Hamberger (1966),etc] and some have used the measured income [Goldfeld

(1973), Arango and Nadiri (1981), etc]. However, in the context of developing

countries, measured income has been used in most empirical studies. Several

studies in India [Gujarati (1968), Bhattacharya (1974), Sampath & Husain

(1981), etc] have used current income as the scale variable. The reason for this

may be two-fold: first, the information on wealth is not available in the non-

monetized economy and secondly, permanent income series cannot be

meaningfully constructed because of very short time series national income

data.

In the context of Nepal, several studies [Poudel (1989), Khatiwada (1997),

Pandey (1998), Gaudel (2003) ] have used real GDP as the scale variable and

found significant and stable relationship between real GDP and the stock of

money holding. Thus, following the literature, this study has selected real

GDP as the scale variable.

3.3.2 Opportunity Cost Variable

Selection of opportunity cost variable also is not free of debate. There is the

ongoing controversy as which interest rate is the best indicator of the

opportunity cost of holding money. Some argue that the long-term bond rate is

better choice as it is more representative of the average rate of return on

capital. The Keynesian theory also supports the long term interest rate as it is

the interest rate that is linked with investment decision and hence the level of

income. Since the economic theory on the money demand function does not

provide any clear cut guideline on the choice of interest rate, researchers have

tried different interest rates in modeling the money demand function.

In case of US, Khan (1974) and Jacobs (1974) have used the long term rate of

interest whereas Heller (1965) and Laidler (1971) have used short term

interest rate. In case of India, Gupta (1970) and Bhattacharya (1974) have

used the short term interest variable in the money demand function.

In the context of Nepal, the use of T-bill rate or long term bond rate is

irrelevant as these instruments are not a significant part of asset portfolios.

Further data are not available for long term fixed deposit rate for the whole

study period. Thus, in this study, rate of interest on saving deposit has been

used as a proxy to interest rate on short term financial assets to model the

narrow money demand and the interest rate on one-year fixed deposit has

been used as a proxy for long term interest rate to model the broad money

demand function.

3.4 The Empirical Model

In this study, following Bahmani-Oskooee (2001), the following model has

been considered.

ln mt =a + b ln yt +c rt + et…………………………………………………………………… (3.1)

Where, mt is a monetary aggregate in real term, y the real GDP, r the interest

rate and e is a white noise error term. Based on the conventional economic

theory, the income elasticity coefficient, b, is expected to be positive; whereas

the interest elasticity parameter, r, is expected to be negative.

To model the money demand functions for both narrow and broad money

aggregates, equation (1) can be written in the form of two different models:

Model I for Narrow Money Demand Function and Model II for Broad Money

Demand Function.

Model I (Narrow Money Aggregate): ln m1t =a+b lnyt+c rsdt+et………….(3.2)

Model II (Broad Money Aggregate): ln m2t =a+b lnyt+c rfdt+et…(3.3)

The details of all the variables used in the formulation of equations (3.2), (3.3)

and used in this study have been presented in table 3.1.

Table 3.1

Variable Details

Variables Name Details

m1t Real Narrow Money Stock defined by the

narrow money stock divided by CPI(FY

2000/01=100)

m2t Real Broad money stock defined by the broad

money stock divided by CPI( FY 2000/01=100)

yt Real GDP defined by nominal GDP deflated by

the implicit GDP deflator(FY 2000/01=100)

ln m1t Natural logarithm of real narrow money stock

ln m2t Natural logarithm of real broad money stock

ln yt Natural logarithm of real GDP

rsdt Rate of interest on saving deposit

rfdt Rate of interest on one-year fixed deposit

Narrow money stock(M1) Currency held by public plus demand deposits of

the commercial banks(CC+DD)

Broad money stock(M2) Narrow money stock plus time

deposits(CC+DD+TD)

CPI Consumer price index (FY 2000/01=100)

INF Expected rate of inflation proxied by the actual

rate of inflation defined by ( CPIt -CPIt-1 )/CPIt-

1

rrsd Real rate of interest on saving deposit defined as

nominal interest rate on saving deposit minus

expected rate of inflation

rrfd Real rate of interest on 12-months fixed deposit

defined as nominal interest rate on such deposit

minus expected rate of inflation

3.5 Estimation Methodology

There are various techniques for conducting the cointegration analysis on

money demand function. The popular approaches are: the well-known

residual-based approach proposed by Engle and Granger (1987) and the

maximum likelihood-based approach proposed by Johansen and Julius (1990)

and Johansen (1991). When there are more than two I(1) variables in the

system, the maximum likelihood approach of Johansen and Julius has the

advantage over residual-based approach of Engle and Granger; however, both

of the approaches require that the variables have the same order of integration.

This requirement often causes difficulty to the researchers when the system

contains the variables with different orders of integration. To overcome this

problem, Pesaran et al. (1996, 2001) proposed a new approach known as

Autoregressive Distributed Lag (ARDL) to cointegration test that does not

require the classification of variables into I(0) or I(1). Therefore, adopting the

ARDL approach for cointegration test, there is no need to conduct the unit

root test, which is prerequisite for residual-based and maximum likelihood

based approach. For these advantages, ARDL approach has gained popularity

over recent years and its adoption for empirical analysis on money demand

can be found in many published works.

This study follows the Auto Regressive Distributed Lag Model (ARDL) as

proposed by Pesaran and Shin (1999). There are many advantages of this

approach. First, it can be applied on a time series data irrespective of whether

the variables are I(0) or I(1) (Pesaran and Pesaran, 1997). Second, it takes

sufficient numbers of lags to capture the data generating process in a general-

to-specific modeling framework (Laurenceson and Chai, 2003). Third, a

dynamic Error Correction Model (ECM) can be derived from ARDL through

a simple linear transformation (Banerjee et.al., 1993). The ECM integrates the

short-run dynamics with the long run equilibrium without losing long-run

information.

3.5.1 Autoregressive Distributed Lag Model (ARDL) to Cointegration

Analysis

The ARDL bounds testing approach to cointegration was developed by

Pesaran and Shin (1999) and Pesaran et al. (2001). Due to the low power and

other problems associated with other methods for cointegration test, the

ARDL approach to cointegration has become popular in recent years. The

ARDL cointegration approach has numerous advantages in comparison to

other cointegration methods such as Engle and Granger (1987), Johansen

(1988), and Johansen and Juselius (1990) procedures: (i) The ARDL

procedure can be applied whether the regressors are I(1) and/or I(0), while

Johansen cointegration techniques require that all the variables in the system

be of equal order of integration. This means that the ARDL can be applied

irrespective of whether underlying regressors are purely I(0), purely I(1) or

mutually cointegrated and thus no need for unit root pre-testing, (ii) While

the Johansen cointegration techniques require large data samples for validity,

the ARDL procedure is statistically more significant approach to determine

the cointegration relation in small samples, (iii) The ARDL procedure allows

that the variables may have different optimal lags, while it is impossible with

conventional cointegration procedures, (iv) The ARDL technique generally

provides unbiased estimates of the long-run model and validates the t-

statistics even when some of the regressors are endogenous, (v) The ARDL

procedure employs only a single reduced form equation, while the

conventional cointegration procedures estimate the long-run relationships

within a context of system equations.

Following the ARDL approach proposed by Pesaran and Shin (1999), the

existence of long run relationship could be tested using equation (3.4) below:

ln mt = a0 +

p

j 1

bj ln mt –j +

q

j 0

cj ln yt-j +

r

oj

dj rt-j +1 ln mt–1 + 2 ln

yt–1 + 3 rt-1 + t ……………………………………………………….(3.4)

Where, mt represents real narrow money balances for narrow money demand

model (model I) and real broad money balances for broad money demand

model(model II), r represents interest rate on saving deposit for model I and

interest rate on one-year fixed deposit for model II, similarly, γ1 ,γ2, γ3 are

the long run coefficients while, bj, cj, dj and ζt represents the short run

dynamics and random disturbance term respectively.

3.6 Hypothesis

To test whether the long run equilibrium relationship exists between demand

for real money balances, real GDP and interest rate, this study carries out

Bounds test (F-version) for cointegration as proposed by Pesaran and Shin

(1999). To test the long run level relationship between the variables, the

hypotheses are:

Null Hypothesis: γ1 =γ2 =γ3 =0 i.e. the long run relationship does not exist.

Alternative hypothesis: γ1 ≠ γ2 ≠ γ3 ≠ 0

This hypothesis is tested by means of the familiar F statistic. The distribution

of this F-statistics is non-standard irrespective of whether the variables in the

system are I(0) or I(1). The critical values of the F-statistics in this test are

available in Pesaran and Pesaran (1997) and Pesaran et al. (2001). They

provide two sets of critical values in which one set is computed with the

assumption that all the variables in the ARDL model are I(1), and another

with the assumption that they are I(0). For each application, the two sets

provide the bands covering all the possible classifications of the variables into

I(0) or I(1), or even fractionally integrated ones. If the computed F-statistics is

higher than the appropriate upper bound of the critical value, the null

hypothesis of no cointegration is rejected; if it is below the appropriate lower

bound, the null hypothesis cannot be rejected, and if it lies within the lower

and upper bounds, the result is inconclusive (Samreth, 2008).

Next step is the estimation of the long run relationship based on the

appropriate lag selection criterion such as adjusted R2, Schwarz Bayesian

Criterion (SBC), Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and Haann Quinn (HQ)

Criterion. Based on the long run coefficients, the estimation of dynamic error

correction will be carried out using formulation of equation (3.5). The

coefficients δ1i, δ2i, and δ3i show the short run dynamics of the model and δ4

indicates the divergence/convergence towards the long run equilibrium. A

positive coefficient indicates a divergence, while a negative coefficient

indicates convergence. The term ECM is derived as the error term from the

corresponding long run model whose coefficients are obtained by normalizing

the equation on m1t and m2t respectively for both money demand models.

ln mt = 0 +

p

j 1

𝛿1j ln mt –j +

q

j 0

𝛿2j ln yt-j +

r

oj

𝛿 3jrt-j + 4 ECMt-

1+t…… (3.5)

For the test of stability, CUSUM and CUSUMSQ tests as proposed by the

Brown et al. (1975) are carried out in this study. Besides these tests, a battery

of other tests are also carried out, such as Augmented Dicky-Fuller

Test(ADF) for testing the order of integration of the variables, Lagrange

Multiplier (LM) test for serial correlation, Ramsey Reset test for functional

form Misspecification, Jarque-Berra Test for normality and KB test for

heteroscedasticity.

3.7 Econometric Tools

3.7.1 Time Series Properties of the Variables

A time series is said to be stationary if its mean, variance and auto covariance

remain the same no matter at what point they are measured; i.e. they are time

invariant. Such a time series will tend to return to its mean and fluctuations

around this mean will have broadly constant amplitude. If a time series is not

stationary, it is called a non-stationary time series (Gujarati, 2007).

A stationary time series is also called a time series integrated of order zero or I

(0) process. If a time series is non-stationary at level but stationary at first

difference, it is said to be integrated of order one or I (1) process. In general, if

a non-stationary time series has to be differenced d times to get a stationary

series, it is said to be integrated of order d or an I(d) process.

Most economic time series are generally I(1); that is , they generally become

stationary only after taking their first differences (Granger,1986).

3.7.2 Cointegration

The regression analysis on time series has been much benefited from the

concept of cointegration by Granger (1981) and Engle and Granger (1987).

They showed that using OLS in case of I(1) variables could be dangerous

because a non-stationary series violates the basic assumptions of OLS and as

such one cannot get the best linear unbiased estimators (BLUE) and also there

may exist the spurious or non-sense correlation between non-stationary

variables. In the case where the variables are non-stationary at levels but are

difference stationary, cointegration methodology allows researchers to test for

the presence of long run equilibrium relationships between economic

variables. If the separate economic time series are stationary after differencing

or they are integrated of order one, but a linear combination of their levels is

stationary, then the series are said to be cointegrated. In other words, two or

more I (l) time series are said to be cointegrated if some linear combination of

them is stationary. Formally, given xt and yt are integrated of order one [I (1)]

or are difference stationary processes, they are said to be cointegrated if there

exists a parameter 𝛼 such that ut = yt-𝛼xt is a stationary process or is

integrated of order zero [I (0)].

Tests for cointegration seek to discern whether or not a stable long-run

relationship exists among such a set of variables. The existence of a common

trend among the variables means that in the long run the behavior of the

common trend will drive the behavior of the variables. Shocks that are unique

to one time series will die out as the variables adjust back to their common

trend.

3.7.3 Error Correction Modeling

Even if Yt and Xt variables are cointegrated, i.e. there is a long run equilibrium

relationship between them, there may be disequilibrium in the short run. Thus

the error term ut = Yt –𝛽1- 𝛽2Xt in the regression equation Yt = 𝛽1+ 𝛽2Xt+ ut is

called the equilibrium error. This error term can be used to tie the short run

behavior of Y to its long run value. The Error correction Models (ECM) first

used by Sargan (1984) and later popularized by Engle and Granger corrects

for disequilibrium. The Granger Representation Theorem says that if two

variables Yt and Xt are cointegrated, then the relationship between the two can

be expressed as Error Correction Modeling as:

𝛥Yt =𝛼0+𝛼1𝛥Xt+𝛼2ut-1+𝜺t………………….…………………........ (3.6)

Where,

𝛥= first difference operator,

𝜺t= a white noise error term,

ut-1= one period lagged value of the error term from the cointegrating

regression(ut-1=Yt-1-–𝛽1- 𝛽2Xt-1)

Equation (3.6) can be arrived through a simple manipulation of the

cointegrating regression Yt = 𝛽1+ 𝛽2Xt+ ut . Adding and subtracting Yt-1 on the

left hand side and adding and subtracting 𝛽2Xt-1 on the right hand side yields:

Yt –Yt-1 + Yt-1= 𝛽1+ 𝛽2Xt+ 𝛽2Xt-1 - 𝛽2Xt-1+ ut

Or, 𝛥Yt= 𝛽1+ 𝛽2𝛥Xt –(Yt-1 - 𝛽2Xt-1)+ ut

Or, 𝛥Yt= 𝛽1+ 𝛽2𝛥Xt –ECMt-1+ ut

The ECM in equation (3.6) states that 𝛥Yt depends on 𝛥Xt and on the

equilibrium error term. If the error term is non-zero, the model is out of

equilibrium. Here the value of 𝛼2 decides how quickly the equilibrium is

restored.

3.7.4 Diagnostic Tests and Other Tests

i) JB Test for Normality

Jarque Bera (JB) Test of Normality is an asymptotic large sample test based

on the OLS residuals. The test statistic is defined by

JB=n [6

2S+

24

)3( 2K]

Where n= sample size, S= skewness coefficient, K = kurtosis coefficient. For

a normally distributed variable, S= 0 and K = 3. Therefore, the JB test for

normality is a test of joint hypothesis that S and K are 0 and 3 respectively. In

that case, the value of the JB statistic is expected to be zero. Under the null

hypothesis that the residuals are normally distributed, Jarque and Bera showed

that asymptotically the JB statistic follows the chi-square distribution with 2

degree of freedom. If the computed p-value of the JB statistic is sufficiently

low or the value of the statistic itself is very different from zero, the null

hypothesis that the residuals are normally distributed is rejected. On the

contrary, if the p-value is reasonably high or the value of the statistic is close

to zero, the normality hypothesis is not rejected (Gujarati, 2007).

ii) LM Test for Serial Correlation

In the models which contain lagged values of the regressand, the Durbin-

Watson d-statistic is often around 2 implying that there is no first order

autocorrelation. Thus, there is a bias against discovering first order

autocorrelation in such models. This does not mean that autoregressive

models do not suffer from autocorrelation problem. To solve this problem,

Durbin has developed Durbin h-test but it is less powerful in statistical sense

than the Breusch-Godfrey test popularly known as the LM test for serial

correlation. The LM test allows for the lagged values of the regressand, higher

order autoregressive scheme and simple or higher order moving averages of

the white noise error term.

The null hypothesis under this test is:

H0: 𝜌1=𝜌2=𝜌3=……𝜌p=0 i.e. there is no serial correlation of any order.

Where ut follows the pth

order autoregressive, AR (p), scheme as follows:

ut = 𝜌1ut-1+ 𝜌2ut-2+………+ 𝜌put-p+𝜺t………………………………………(3.7)

Test statistic is given by

(n-p)R2 ∼𝜒

2

p

Where the R2 is calculated from the auxiliary regression equation given by

tu

=𝛼 0 +𝛼i Xti + 1

1

tu + 2

2

tu +………+ p

ptu

+𝜺t

Where Xti are explanatory variables

For large sample, this statistics follows the chi-square distribution with p df. If (n-

p)R2

exceeds the chi-square critical value at the chosen level of significance in which

case null hypothesis is rejected that is to say there is the presence of serial correlation

of some order.

iii) Koenker- Basset Heteroscedasticity Test

This test for Heteroscedasticity is based on the squared residuals, 2ˆtu but

instead of being regressand on one or more regressors, the squared residuals

are regressed on the squared estimated values of the regressand. Specifically if

the original model is

Yt = 𝛽1 + 𝛽2X2 + 𝛽3X3 + ………. + 𝛽kXk+ ut, …………….…………..(3.8)

Then, the following model is estimated,

2ˆtu =𝛼1 + 𝛼2(𝑌 𝑡)2 +vt

Where, 𝑌 𝑡=estimated Y value from the regression equation (3.8)

And 𝑢 = Yt -𝑌 t

Null hypothesis: 𝛼2=0

This hypothesis is tested by the usual t-test or the F-test. If the null hypothesis

is not rejected, the conclusion is that there is no heteroscedasticity.

iv) Ramsey’s RESET Test

This test is the regression specification error test (RESET). It is used to check

whether the specified functional form is correct or not.

The Procedure for F-Version is as follows:

Let the simple regression model is

Y = 𝛼1 + 𝛼2X + u ……………………………………………………..........(3.9)

From equation (3.9), 𝑌 is found and the following regression is run by adding 𝑌 in

some form as an additional regressors starting with 𝑌 2, e.g.

Y = 𝛽1+ 𝛽2X+ 𝛽3𝑌 2

+ 𝛽4𝑌 3+u………………………………… (3.10)

Let the R2 obtained from equation (3.9) is 2

oldR and that from Equation (3.10) is 2

newR

. Then, the following F statistics is constructed:

F =

(Rnew2 −Rold

2 )number of new regressors

(1−Rnew2 )

(n−numbers of parameters in the new model )

If the computed F value is found significant, say, at 5%, one can accept the hypothesis

that the model is mis-specified.

Alternative to F-version is the LM version where the calculated statistic nR2 follows

the chi-square distribution with df equal to the number of restrictions imposed for

large samples. If the calculated value exceeds the critical value of 𝜒2 at the chosen

level of significance, the null hypothesis is rejected and concluded that the model is

mis-specified.

v) Model Selection Criteria

Model selection criteria are used to choose a model from the alternative models.

Adjusted R2 criterion

It is calculated as:

𝑅 2 = 1-

𝑅𝑆𝑆 𝑛−𝑘

𝑇𝑆𝑆 𝑛−1

Where,

RSS= residual sum of square

TSS= Total sum of square

n = number of observations

k = number of parameters in the regression model

On the basis of this criterion, a model with highest 𝑅 2 is chosen.

Akaike Information criterion(AIC)

AIC is calculated as:

AIC = n

RSSe

nk

/2

Where, k= number of parameters,

It can also be writes as:

ln AIC = 2k/n + ln (RSS/n)

Where, ln = natural logarithm and 2k/n is the penalty factor.

AIC imposes harsher penalty than 𝑅 2 for adding more regressors. In comparing the

models, the lowest value of AIC is preferred.

Schwarz Bayesian Criterion (SBC)

SBC is calculated as:

SBC = n

k. ln n + ln(

n

RSS)

Here, n

k. ln n is the penalty factor. So SBC imposes a harsher penalty than AIC. Like

AIC, lower value of SBC is preferred.

vi) Recursive Residuals, CUSUM Test and CUSUMSQ Test

In recursive least squares, the equation is estimated repeatedly, using ever

larger subsets of the sample data. If there are k coefficients to be estimated in

the regression, then the first K observations are used to form the first estimate

of the parameters. The next observation is then added to the data set and k+1

observations are used to compute the second estimate of parameters. This

process is repeated until all the T sample points have been used, yielding T-

k+1 parameter estimates. At each step the last estimate of the parameters can

be used to predict the next value of the dependent variable. The one-step

ahead forecast error resulting from this prediction, suitably scaled, is defined

to be a recursive residual.

CUSUM Test

The CUSUM test (Brown, Durbin, and Evans, 1975) is based on the

cumulative sum of the recursive residuals. This option plots the cumulative

sum together with the 5% critical lines. The test finds parameter instability if

the cumulative sum goes outside the area between the two critical lines.

The CUSUM test is based on the statistic

Wt=1

t

r

r k s

w

For t=k+1,…….T , where Wt is the recursive residual and s is the standard

error of the regression fitted to all sample points T. If the vector of the

parameter remains constant from period to period, E (Wt) = 0, but if this

vector changes, Wt will tend to diverge from the zero mean value line. The

significance of any departure from the zero line is assessed by reference to a

pair of 5% significance lines, the distance between which increases with t.

The 5% significance lines are found by connecting the points

[k, ± -0.948(T-k)1/2

] and [T, ±3×0.948(T-k)1/2

]

Movement of outside the critical lines is suggestive of coefficient instability.

CUSUMSQ Test

The CUSUM of squares test (Brown, Durbin, and Evans, 1975) is based on

the test statistic

Wt =

2

1

2

1

t

rr k

T

rr k

w

w

The expected value of under the hypothesis of parameter constancy is E (St) =

t-k/T-k which goes from zero at to unity at. The significance of the departure

of from its expected value is assessed by reference to a pair of parallel straight

lines around the expected value. The CUSUM of squares test provides a plot

of against and the pair of 5 percent critical lines. As with the CUSUM test,

movement outside the critical lines is suggestive of parameter or variance

instability.

vi) Bounds Test (F-version)

The F-test can be used to test the hypothesis about one or more parameters of

the k-variable regression model:

Yi = 𝛽1 + 𝛽2X2i+ 𝛽3X3i+ 𝛽4X4i+………..+ 𝛽k Xki + ui…………………………… (11)

Let, the hypothesis to be tested is H0: 𝛽4= 𝛽5= 𝛽6= 𝛽7=0

Then, another regression by dropping the variables X4i, X5i, X6i and X7i is run

as

Yi = 𝛽1 + 𝛽2X2i+ 𝛽3X3i+ 𝛽8X8i+………..+ 𝛽k Xki + ui…………………………… (12)

and residual sum of squares is calculated from both models. Equation (11) is

called unrestricted regression and equation (12) is called restricted regression.

The F statistic is calculated by the formula:

F =

UR

UR

R(RSS RSS

m

RSS(n k)

;

Where,

RSSR =RSS of the restricted regression,

RSSUR = RSS of unrestricted regression,

m= number of restrictions,

k= number of parameters in unrestricted regression and

n=number of observations

According to Pesaran (1997), the bounds test (General F test) can be used test

the long run relationship in equation (3.4)

vii) Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF)Test

ADF test statistic is used to examine the stationarity of the time series

variable. The following regression is run in Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF)

test to check for unit root of the variables or to check the order of integration:

Δ xt = η+ γt + αxt-1+1

k

j t j

j

x

+ ε1t………….………………... (3.13)

Where xt is any variable used in this study, that is, ln m1t, ln m2t, ln yt,rsdt, and

rfdt, Δ indicates the first difference operator and k is the length of lag which

ensures residuals to have white noise empirically. The ADF statistic is simply

the t-value of the coefficient α in equation (13). The null hypothesis is that xt

has a unit root, that is, H0: α = 0 and is rejected if the calculated ADF statistic

is above the critical value implying that xt has no unit root or xt is stationary.

3.8 The Data

This study is based on the secondary data. The data sources are Quarterly

Economic Bulletin published by Nepal Rastra Bank (NRB), Economic Survey

published by Ministry of Finance(MOF) and the World Economic Outlook by

IMF. The GDP figures have been extracted from the World Economic

Outlook database of IMF available at econstats.com which contains the time

series data on the real GDP figures of Nepal calculated at the base year price

of FY 2000/01 adjusted to the base year price by data splicing chain weighted

method. The information pertaining to the money balances and interest rates

on saving and one-year fixed deposit have been extracted from Quarterly

Economic Bulletin (various issues). The data on the CPI (FY 2000/01=100)

have been extracted from the Economic Survey 2009/10.

CHAPTER IV

ANALYSIS OF DATA

This chapter presents the analysis of data with the estimated results. Section

4.1 presents the results from the ADF test to test the order of integration of the

variables, section 4.2 presents the results from the bounds test to test the long

run relationship between the variables, the estimated short run model, long run

model and the resulting error correction model for both money demand

models and section 4.3 presents the results of the CUSUM and CUSUMSQ

tests for both models.

4.1 Time Series Properties of the Variables

The underlying assumption of ARDL procedure that each variable in narrow

and broad money demand models is I (1) or I (0). Thus, there is no need to

check whether the variable is I (0) or I (1). However, if any variable is

integrated of higher than order one, then the procedure is not applicable

because if any variable is I(2) of of some higher order, the table values given

by Pesaran (1997) do not work. Thus, it is still necessary to perform unit root

tests to ensure that none of the variables in equations is I (2) or higher order.

Augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) unit-root test has been applied to test the

order of integration of the variables. Before conducting the ADF test, an

attempt is made on whether to include the trend as a variable in the ADF

regression or not. To confirm this, the time series plot of the variables has

been presented in Fig. 1 and Fig. 2 and Fig. 3.

The time series plot in Fig. 1 shows that ln m1t, ln m2t and ln yt are trended

variables. So, a trend is included in the ADF test for them. On the other hand,

rsdt and rfdt in Fig. 2 and rrsdt, rrfdt and INF in Fig. 3 have no trend as such

intercept only is included while testing their order of integration. From the

time series plot, it is obvious that the relevant ADF statistic for checking the

order of integration in case of ln m1t, ln m2t and ln yt is the ADF statistic from

the ADF regression including constant and trend whereas the relevant ADF

statistic for checking the order of integration in case of rsdt, rfdt, rrsdt, rrfdt and

INF is the ADF statistic from the ADF regression including constant but no

trend.

Fig. 1

Time Series Plot of ln m1t, ln m2t and ln yt

Fig. 2

Time Series Plot of rsd and rfd

Fig. 3

Time Series Plot of rrsdt, rrfdt and INF

2

4

6

8

10

12

1975 1984 1993 2002 2009

m1t m2t ln yt

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

1975 1984 1993 2002 2009

RFD RSD

Table 4.1 presents the results of the ADF test. Since the data is annual,

following Pesaran and Shin (1999), only one lag has been included (p=1).

Table 4.1

ADF Test Results (p=1)

Variables Constant Constant and trend

ln m1t -0.38 -

4.25

ln m2t -0.60 -

5.04

ln yt -0.98 -2.99

rsdt -1.48 -1.96

rfdt -1.80 -2.50

rrsdt -4.60 -4.58

rrfdt -4.38 -4.66

INF -3.51 -3.90

𝛥ln m1t -4.65* -4.42

𝛥ln m2t -5.65* -5.27

𝛥ln yt -4.95* -5.20

𝛥rsdt -4.06* -3.93

𝛥rfdt -3.79* -3.70

𝛥rrsdt -6.93* -6.73

-20

-10

0

10

20

30

1975 1984 1993 2002 2009

RRsd RRfd INF

𝛥rrfdt -7.12* -6.92

𝛥INF -6.46* -6.25

*represents the rejection of null hypothesis at 5% level of significance.

The critical values are -2.966 (constant but no trend) and -3.6008 (constant

and trend) at 5% level of significance. The critical values have been calculated

by stochastic simulation of 32 observations and 20000 replications.

From the results in table 4.1, it becomes clear that none of the variables are

integrated of higher than order one. All the variables are at most integrated of

order one. To confirm the order of integration of the variables besides ADF

test, the autocorrelation function for each variable has been examined which

leads to the conclusion that the variables ln m1t, ln m2t, ln yt, rsdt, rfdt, are

integrated of order one or are I (1) processes whereas the variables rrsdt, rrfdt

and INF are integrated of order zero or are I (0) processes (the graphs of

autocorrelation functions have been provided in Appendix E). If the auto

correlation coefficient starts with a high value and diminishes slowly, the

variables are non-stationary processes at level. Since, the variables are of

mixed order; the ARDL modeling is the most appropriate approach to model

the demand for money as suggested by Pesaran and Shin (1997).

4.2 Estimation Results

Since the main objective of the study is to check the long run cointegrating

relationship between the variables included in the money demand function

and check the stability of the money demand function, an attempt to check

such long run relationship is made first. As this study follows the Auto

Regressive Distributed Lag Modeling (ARDL) to the formulation of money

demand function popularized by Pesaran and Shin (1997), the bounds test (F-

statistics) has been applied to justify the existence of the cointegration or

long-run relationship among variables in the system. Table 4.2 provides the

results of the F-statistics according to various lag orders.

Table 4.2

F-statistics (Bound Test)

Lag order 0 1

F statistic M1 Aggregate 3.7513 4.5580*

M2 Aggregate 7.6529**

4.9437**

Note: The relevant critical value bounds are (with intercept and no trend;

number of regressors = 2) 3.793 – 4.855 at the 95% significance level and

3.182– 4.126 at the 90% significance level.

* denotes that the F-statistic falls above the 90% upper bound and ** denotes

above the 95% upper bound.

The results of Table 4.2 shows that most of the F-statistics are above the upper

bounds of the critical values (CV) of standard significance levels (5 % or

10%) provided by Pesaran and Pesaran (1997). But these critical values were

generated on the basis of 40,000 replications of a stochastic simulation for a

sample of 1,000 observations. So, they are less relevant for a small sample

size. Therefore, following the critical values by Narayan and Smyth (2004)

which are based on 40,000 replication of a stochastic simulation for a sample

of 40 observations with two regressors, the critical value bounds are 2.83 to

3.58 at 10 % and 3.43 to 4.26 for 5% level of significance. On the basis of

these critical values, the calculated F-statistics clearly rejects null hypothesis

of no cointegration at 5 % or 10% level of significance. These values Support

the existence of cointegration or long-run relationship between variables in

the equation. However, Bahmani-Oskooee and Bohl (2000) consider these

results as preliminary, precisely due to arbitrary choice of lag selection, and

rely more on the other stages of estimation for testing cointegration which are

more efficient.

In the second step, equation (3.4) is estimated and different model selection

criteria are used to justify the lag orders of each variable in the system. Only

an appropriate lag selection criterion will be able to identify the true dynamics

of the model. The maximum lag order is set to 2 following Pesaran and Shin

(1999) and Narayan (2004) as the data are annual and there are only 35

observations. With this maximum lag order, the adjusted sample period for

analysis becomes 1977 to 2009. This setting also helps save the degree of

freedom, as our available sample period for analysis is quite small. Using

Microfit 5.0, all the selection criteria have given the same results. Microfit

runs the (p+1)k

numbers of regressions and selects the best model, where p is

the maximum number of lags to be used and k is the number of variables in

the equation. Here then number of regressions to be run are (2+1)3 = 27. The

ARDL (1, 0, 0) model is selected on the basis of all criteria like Adjusted R2,

Schwarz Bayesian Criterion (SBC), Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) and

Haann Quinn criterion for both M1 aggregate and M2 aggregate models.

According to Pesaran (1997), AIC and SBC perform relatively well in small

samples, although the SBC is slightly superior to the AIC (Pesaran and Shin,

1999). Besides, SBC is parsimonious as it uses minimum acceptable lag while

selecting the lag length and avoid unnecessary loss of degrees of freedom.

Therefore, SBC criterion has been used, as a criterion for the optimal lag

selection, in all cointegration estimations.

After selecting the appropriate lag orders for each variable in the system,

equation (3.4) is re-estimated. The Results of such estimation along with the

short run diagnostic statistics are presented in table 4.3.

Table 4.3

Full-information ARDL Estimate Results (M1 monetary aggregate)

Autoregressive Distributed Lag Estimates

ARDL (1,0,0) selected based on Schwarz Bayesian Criterion

Dependent variable is ln m1t

33 observations used for estimation from 1977 to 2009

Regressors

𝛥 ln m1t(-1)

𝛥 yt

𝛥 rsdt

C

Coefficient

.51759*

.67440*

-.001907

-5.2578*

T-

Ratio[Prob]

4.4513[.000]

4.1057[.000]

-.26506[.793]

-3.9985[.000]

R-Squared .99482 R-Bar-Squared

.99428

S.E. of Regression .045336 F-Stat. F(3,29)

1855.9[.000]

Diagnostic Tests

Test Statistics LM Version F

Version

A:Serial Correlation CHSQ(1) = .33333[.564]

F(1,28)=.28571[.597]

B:Functional Form CHSQ(1) = 3.8703[.049] F(1,28) =

3.7202[.064]

C:Normality CHSQ(2) = 1.2077[.547] Not applicable

D:Heteroscedasticity CHSQ(1) = .007825[.930] F(1,31)

=.007353[.932]

A: Lagrange multiplier test of residual serial correlation

B: Ramsey‟s RESET test using the square of the fitted values

C: Based on a test of skewness and kurtosis of residuals

D: Based on the regression of squared residuals on squared fitted values

*denotes the significance of coefficient at 5% level

Table 4.3 indicates that the overall goodness of fit of the estimated ARDL

regression model is very high with the result of adjusted R2 = 0.9942. From

the diagnostic tests, it is clear that the model passes all of the tests. The critical

values of 𝝌2 for one and two degrees of freedom at 5% level of significance

are 3.84 and 5.99 respectively. Thus, null hypothesis of normality of residuals,

null hypothesis of no first order serial correlation and null hypothesis of no

heteroscedasticity are accepted. However, the null hypothesis of no

misspecification of functional form can be accepted at 1% level of

significance only. Since the LM version of misspecification test is a large

sample test, it is more appropriate to conclude on the basis of F-version of

RESET test. On the basis of F-version, the null hypothesis of no

misspecification can be easily accepted even at 5% level of significance. Not

much interpretation can be attached to the short run coefficients. These

coefficients will be interpreted in the error correction ARDL model in table

4.5.

The long-run model of the corresponding ARDL (1, 0, 0) for the demand for

narrow money balances can be written as follows:

ln m1t = -10.899 + 1.398ln yt - 0.00395 rsdt

The long run coefficients are the values of coefficients 𝛾1 to 𝛾3 of equation

(3.4) normalized on ln m1t by dividing the coefficients by the coefficient (-𝛾1).

The long run coefficients are reported in Table 4.4. As expected, the

coefficient of the real income (GDP) is positive and that of short term interest

rate is negative. Quantitatively, the income elasticity of narrow money

demand is 1.398, which is highly significant as reflected by a t-statistic of

27.40. This in turn shows that one percentage increase in real GDP leads to

increase in the real money balance holdings by 1.398 percentages. This shows

that money is a luxury asset in Nepal. This result is in conformity with many

studies done in underdeveloped countries e.g. Poudel (1989) and Khatiwada

(1997) for Nepal, Aghevli et.al.(1979) and Teseng and Corker (1991) for

Asian countries and Simmons (1992) for African Countries. It thus rejects the

conclusion of Gaudel (2003) that income elasticity of demand for money is

less than unitary in Nepal. The more than unity elasticity implies that an

increase in income leads to a higher increase in the demand for real money

balances and a reduction in the velocity of money (Rutayisire, 2010). This

result is attributed to the under-monetization of the economy where the

gradual absorption of the non-monetary sector by the monetary sector is

accompanied by an increase in cash in hand that is faster than income.

Table 4.4

Estimated Long Run Coefficients using the ARDL Approach

ARDL (1,0,0) selected based on Schwarz Bayesian Criterion

Dependent variable is ln m1t

33 observations used for estimation from 1977 to 2009

Regressors

ln yt

rsdt

C

Coefficient

1.3980*

-.0039530

-10.899*

T-Ratio[Prob]

27.4070[.000]

-

.26559[.792]

-

17.9565[.000]

*shows the significance of coefficients at 1% level of significance.

The interest rate despite bearing the correct negative sign is statistically

insignificant which implies that in the long run the demand for narrow money

balances remains independent of the interest rate. Thus, either the interest rate

is not a good proxy of the opportunity cost of holding money or interest rate

does not have a significant effect on the demand for narrow money balances

in Nepal. In an attempt to search for a suitable appropriate opportunity cost

variable in the narrow money demand function, the interest rate on one-year

fixed deposit was tried instead of interest rate on saving deposit but it also did

not appear to be fruitful. Also, the real rates of interest were tried, but none of

them carried significant t-ratio. Lastly, the inflation rate also did not turned

out to be a significant opportunity cost variable in money demand function

(Results are provided in the APPENDIX C and APPENDIX D). These results

strongly support the view of Johnson (1963) that in less developed country,

there is a possibility of keeping a block of cash by an individual out of his

remuneration, investing the rest in assets and thereby reducing the interest

elasticity of money demand to less than unity or even zero. The result that

inflation also is not a significant opportunity cost of holding narrow money

balances is in conformity with Pandey (1998) and in contradiction with

several other studies. This result points to two possibilities: either the actual

rate of inflation is not a good proxy of the expected rate of inflation or

inflation does not have a significant impact upon the demand for real money

balances in Nepal.

The estimates of the error correction representation of the ARDL (1, 0, 0)

model selected by the SBC criterion are presented in Table 4.5. The long run

coefficients are used to generate the error correction term .i.e. ecm = ln m1t-

1.398 ln yt + 0.00395rsdt+10.899. The computed F-statistic clearly rejects the

null hypothesis that all regressors have zero coefficients. The JB test for

normality shows that the residuals of the error correction modeling are

normally distributed. The KB test supports the homoscedasticity assumption.

Importantly, the error correction coefficient has the expected negative sign

and is highly significant as shown by the probability value being zero. This

helps to reinforce the existence of cointegration as provided by the F-test.

Specifically, the estimated value of ecm(−1) is - 0.482. The absolute value

of the coefficient of ecm (−1) is substantially high indicating the fast speed of

adjustment to equilibrium following short-run shocks; about 48% of the

disequilibrium, caused by previous period shocks, converges back to the long-

run equilibrium in one period. The short-run coefficients show the dynamic

adjustment of these variables. The coefficient of income and interest rate give

the short- run elasticities of income and interest rate respectively. The short

run income elasticity thus is 0.677 which is less than the long run elasticity

1.398. On the other hand, as in the long run, the short run elasticity of interest

rate is not statistically significant implying that demand for money even in the

short run remains independent of the interest rate. The adjusted R-square of

the error correction model is rather low but it does not significantly affect our

results [for example see Omer (2010), Samreth (2008), Bahmani-Oskooee and

Chi Wing Ng (2002)]. The low adjusted R square is due to the selection of a

restricted error correction model without a constant term following Pesaran

and Shin (1999).

Table 4.5

Error Correction Representation for the Selected ARDL Model

ARDL(1,0,0) selected based on Schwarz Bayesian Criterion

Dependent variable is 𝛥ln m1t

33 observations used for estimation from 1977 to 2009

Regressors

𝛥ln yt

𝛥 rsdt

ecm(-1)

Coefficient

.67440*

-.0019070

-.48241*

Standard Error

.16426

.0071946

.11628

T-Ratio[Prob]

4.1057[.000]

-.2651[.793]

-4.1488[.000]

R-Squared .37248 R-Bar-Squared

.30756

S.E. of Regression .045336 F-Stat. F(3,29)

5.7379[.003]

JB(Normality) 1.2076[0.5467]

F-stat. (For KB heteroscedasticity test) : 0.0953[0.759]

ecm = ln m1t -1.3980*ln yt + .0039530*rsdt + 10.8990*C

Note: R-Squared and R-Bar-Squared measures refer to the dependent variable

𝛥M1t and in cases where the error correction model is highly restricted, these

measures could become negative.

*shows the significance of coefficients at 1% level of significance.

Next, equation (3.4) is estimated for M2 monetary aggregates. Table 4.6

presents the estimated coefficients along with the diagnostic test statistics. It

indicates that the overall goodness of fit of the estimated ARDL regression

model is very high with the result of adjusted R2 = 0.9975.

Table 4.6

Full-information ARDL Estimate Results (M2 Monetary Aggregate)

ARDL(1,0,0) selected based on Schwarz Bayesian Criterion

Dependent variable is ln m2t

33 observations used for estimation from 1977 to 2009

Regressors

𝛥ln m2t(-1)

𝛥ln yt

𝛥rfdt

C

Coefficient

.59979*

.72642*

-.6579E-3

-5.7054*

Standard Error

.087851

.16415

.0048925

1.3393

T-Ratio[Prob]

6.8274[.000]

4.4253[.000]

-.1345[.894]

-4.2600[.000]

Diagnostic Tests

Test Statistics LM Version F Version

A:Serial Correlation CHSQ(1) = .065072[.799] F(1,28)

=.055322[.816]

B:Functional Form CHSQ(1) = 1.5144[.218] F(1,28) =

1.3467[.256]

C:Normality CHSQ(2) = .64742[.723] Not applicable

D:Heteroscedasticity CHSQ(1) = .0039343[.950] F(1,31) =

.00369[.952]

A:Lagrange multiplier test of residual serial correlation

B:Ramsey's RESET test using the square of the fitted values

C:Based on a test of skewness and kurtosis of residuals

D:Based on the regression of squared residuals on squared fitted values

*shows the significance of coefficients at 1% level of significance.

From the diagnostic tests in table 4.6, it is clear that the model passes all of

the tests. The critical values of 𝝌2 for one and two degrees of freedom at 5%

level of significance are 3.84 and 5.99 respectively. Thus, null hypothesis of

normality of residuals, null hypothesis of no first order serial correlation and

null hypothesis of no heteroscedasticity and null hypothesis of no

misspecification of functional form can be easily accepted at 5% level of

significance. Not much interpretation can be attached to the short run

coefficients. These coefficients will be interpreted in the error correction

ARDL model in table 4.9.

The long run coefficients are the values of coefficients 𝛾1 to 𝛾3 of equation

(3.4) normalized on ln m2t by dividing the coefficients by the coefficient (-𝛾1 )

The long-run model of the corresponding ARDL (1, 0, 0 ) for the demand for

money can be written as:

ln m2t=-14.255 + 1.815 ln y - 0.00164 rfdt

The long run coefficients are reported in Table 4.7:

Table 4.7

Estimated Long Run Coefficients using the ARDL Approach

ARDL(1,0,0) selected based on Schwarz Bayesian Criterion

Dependent variable is ln m2t

33 observations used for estimation from 1977 to 2009

Regressors

ln yt

rfdt

C

Coefficient

1.8151*

-.0016438

-14.2558*

Standard Error

.077302

.012221

.9079

T-Ratio[Prob]

23.4804[.000]

-.13450[.894]

-15.7019[.000]

Note: Figures in parentheses are the probabilities associated with the t-ratios

and the asterisk * shows that the coefficient is significant at 1% level of

significance.

In table 4.7, as expected, the coefficient of the real income (GDP) is positive

and that of one year fixed deposit interest rate is negative. Quantitatively, the

income elasticity of broad money demand is 1.815, which is highly significant

as reflected by a t-statistic of 23.48. This in turn shows that one percentage

increase in real GDP leads to increase in the real money balance holdings by

1.815 percentages. It also implies that the income elasticity for broad

definition of money is higher than narrow money. This result is again in

conformity with Poudel (1989) and Sharma (1997) for Nepal. The interest rate

despite bearing the correct negative sign is again statistically insignificant

which implies that in the long run, either, the demand for broad money

balances remains independent of the interest rate or the chosen interest rate rfdt

is not an appropriate opportunity cost variable. Here also, in search for an

appropriate opportunity cost variable, the real rate of interest was tried but the

coefficient of interest rate did not appear to be significant. This again is in

conformity with the view of Johnson (1963). Finally, the rate of inflation also

did not prove fruitful. As the intercept term is statistically significant, it

implies that unidentified variables including time trend have significant

bearings on real money demand and they have a negative impact on real

money demand (Sharma, 1997).

The error correction representation for broad money aggregate model has

been presented in table 4.8 which reconfirms the cointegrating relationship

between the variables included in the broad money demand function as

revealed by the expected negative sign with the error correction term with a

highly significant probability value of zero. The long run coefficients are used

to generate the error correction term .i.e. ecm = ln m2t- 1.8151*ln yt +

0.0016438*rfdt + 14.2558*C. The computed F-statistic clearly rejects the null

hypothesis that all regressors have zero coefficients. Specifically, the

estimated value of ecm (−1) is -0.40. The absolute value of the coefficient of

ecm (-1) is substantially high indicating the fast speed of adjustment to

equilibrium following short-run shocks; about 40% of the disequilibrium,

caused by previous period shocks, converges back to the long-run equilibrium

in one period. Since, the absolute value of the coefficient of ecm is lower in

case of broad money demand, there is a slower speed of adjustment of short

run disequilibrium to the long run equilibrium in case of broad money demand

function.

Table 4.8

Error Correction Representation for the Selected ARDL Model

ARDL(1,0,0) selected based on Schwarz Bayesian Criterion

Dependent variable is 𝛥ln m2t

33 observations used for estimation from 1977 to 2009

Regressors Coefficient Standard Error T-

Ratio[Prob]

𝛥ln yt .72642 .16415

4.4253[.000]

𝛥rfdt -.6579E-3 .0048925 -

.1344[.894]

ecm(-1) -.40021 0.087851 -

4.5556[.000]

R-Squared .41963 R-Bar-Squared

.35959

S.E. of Regression .038364 F-Stat. F(3,29)

6.9893[.001]

ecm = ln m2t - 1.8151*ln yt + .0016438*rfdt + 14.2558*C

JB(Normality) .6474[.723]

F-stat. (For KB heteroscedasticity test): 0.0238[0.878]

Note: R-Squared and R-Bar-Squared measures refer to the dependent variable

𝛥M1 and in cases where the error correction model is highly restricted, these

measures could become negative.

The coefficient showing the short run dynamics are not all significant: only

the short run income elasticity (0.7264) is significant where as the short run

interest rate elasticity is not significant though having a correct sign implying

that money demand in the short run also remains independent of the interest

rate. All these coefficients show the dynamic adjustment of these variables.

4.3 Stability Test

Finally, the stability of the long run coefficients together with the short run

dynamics is examined. In doing so, Pesaran and Pesaran (1997) have been

followed and the CUSUM and CUSUMSQ tests [proposed by Brown, Durbin,

and Evans (1975) have been applied. The tests are applied to the residuals of

the two models following Pesaran and Pesaran (1997). Specifically, the

CUSUM test makes use of the cumulative sum of recursive residuals based on

the first set of n observations and is updated recursively and plotted against

break points. If the plot of CUSUM statistics stays within the critical bounds

of 5% significance level represented by a pair of straight lines drawn at the

5% level of significance whose equations are given in Brown, Durbin, and

Evans (1975)], the null hypothesis that all coefficients in the error correction

model are stable cannot be rejected. If either of the lines is crossed, the null

hypothesis of coefficient constancy can be rejected at the 5% level of

significance. A similar procedure is used to carry out the CUSUMSQ test,

which is based on the squared recursive residuals. Figure 4 and figure 5,

figure 6 and figure 7 show the graphical representation of the CUSUM and

CUSUMSQ plots applied to the money demand models selected by the SBC

criterion. Neither CUSUM nor CUSUMSQ plots cross the critical bounds,

indicating no evidence of any significant structural instability. Similar results

have been obtained for the broad money demand model. Since all the graphs

of CUSUM and CUSUMSQ statistics stay comfortably well within the 5

percent band, it is safe to conclude that the estimated demand functions for

narrow and broad money balances are stable.

Figure 4

Plots of CUSUM Statistics (M1 Aggregate)

Figure 5

Plots of CUSUMSQ Statistics (M1 Aggregate)

Figure 6

Plots of CUSUM Statistics (M2 Aggregate)

Figure 7

Plots of CUSUMSQ Statistics (M2 Aggregate)

Thus, on the basis of all statistical tests applied, it can be concluded that a

statistically robust demand for money can be modeled for both narrow and

broad monetary aggregates using the ARDL model proposed by Pesaran and

Shin (19997). In case of both monetary aggregates, there exists the long run

cointegrating relationship between real money balances, real GDP and the

corresponding interest rate variable selected.

CHAPTER V

SUMMARY, CONCLUSIONS AND RECOMMENDATIONS

This study is focused on the estimation of money demand function in Nepal

and examination of the stability issue of it over the study period 1975-2009. It

has followed the recently developed ARDL modeling to cointegration and

error correction modeling approach developed and popularized by Pesaran

and Shin (1999) and Pesaran et.al. (2001) in analyzing the demand for both

narrow and broad money balances. It is expected that the results from this

study will provide valuable information to the monetary authority in

determining the intermediate targets of monetary policy. The main objectives

of the study are to examine the long run equilibrium relationship between the

variables included in the money demand function, to examine long run

coefficients and short run dynamics in the money demand function and to

examine the stability of the money demand function. This chapter is the

concluding chapter of the present study. The first part summarizes the

findings from the study and draws some conclusions. The second part lists

some recommendations that can be made from the conclusions of the study.

5.1 Summary of the Findings and Conclusions

The main purpose of this study has been to investigate the money demand

relationship in Nepal empirically and examine the stability of the money

demand function by using the recently developed tools of ARDL modeling to

cointegration and error correction modeling developed by Pesaran and Shin

(1999). It has included the variables that were found relevant by the previous

studies and analyzed the demand function for both narrow and broad money

aggregates over the time period 1975-2009.The major findings and

conclusions from this study are:

1. In both cases of money aggregates M1 and M2, demand for real money

balances has been found to have a long run equilibrium relationship with the

scale variable(real GDP) and corresponding opportunity cost variable( interest

rate on savings deposit in narrow money demand and interest rate on one year

fixed deposit in case of broad money demand). In other words, there exists

cointegrating relationship among the variables included in the money demand

function in case of both monetary aggregates.

2. The most significant determinant of money demand function in case of Nepal

is the scale variable or the real GDP as shown by the correct sign of long run

income elasticity which is highly significant in both cases.

3. The coefficient of interest rate in both cases though bears a correct sign is

statistically insignificant implying that demand for real money balances is

independent of interest rate in the long run in Nepal. Even if rate of interest in

savings deposits is replaced by the interest rate on one-year fixed deposit in

modeling the demand for narrow money, the coefficient is insignificant. This

finding is in conformity with Poudel (1989), and Pandey (1998). However, it

is in contrary to the Keynesian liquidity preference hypothesis which implies

that the chosen interest rate is either not an appropriate opportunity cost

variable or the money holders are sensitive to the return on other alternative

assets. According to Pandey (1998), the financial assets consists a negligible

part in the asset portfolio in Nepal because savings are mostly held in the form

of physical assets. Thus interest rate has a poor performance in modeling the

demand for money. Similarly this conclusion reinforces the findings of

Kaufman and Latta (1996) that interest rate would serve to be significant only

in those countries with well developed money markets. Next, this study has

tried to include the real rates of interest and inflation as opportunity cost

variable in modeling the money demand function but unfortunately they also

appeared insignificant. This conclusion does not support the earlier findings

by Poudel (1989) that real rate of interest is a significant variable in money

demand function where as nominal rate of interest is not. On the other hand,

inflation as an insignificant opportunity cost variable supports the findings of

Pandey (1998). This implies that either the actual rate of inflation is not a good

proxy of the expected rate of inflation or inflation is not a significant

opportunity cost variable in the demand for money function in Nepal.

4. The income elasticity in case of narrow money demand is 1.398 and in case of

broad money demand is 1.815. Since income elasticity is greater than unity in

both cases, money balances is still a luxury in Nepal. The more than unitary

income elasticity implies the under-monetization of the economy. In such a

situation, as the economy moves towards monetization, the demand for cash

increases more than the increases in income. Also, income elasticity in case of

broad money demand is found to be higher than the narrow money demand.

This finding also supports the findings by Poudel (1989) and Khatiwada

(1997).

5. The coefficient of error correction term in both cases has a negative sign

reinforcing the long run equilibrium relationship between the included

variables. Since the coefficient of ecm in case of broad money demand is

smaller in absolute value, disequilibrium errors created by the previous period

shocks are adjusted more slowly in case of broad money demand.

6. Money demand function in case of both monetary aggregates has been found

to remain stable during the time period under study as confirmed by the

CUSUM and CUSUMSQ tests. The financial liberalization process which has

led the economy to deregulation of interest rate, deregulation of financial

sector, deregulation of external sector and exchange rate depreciation has not

significantly resulted in the parameter instability as expected.

7. As the intercept term is statistically significant in both long run models, it

implies that unidentified variables including time trend have significant

bearings on real money demand. As the intercept term in both cases is

negative, it indicates that the unspecified variables including the time trend

have negative impact on real money demand.

5.2 Recommendations

From the conclusions of the study, the following recommendation can be

made:

1. Since the money demand functions in case of both monetary aggregates

are stable in their parameters, the central bank of Nepal can continue

the monetary targeting strategy as a policy in achieving the major

macroeconomic policy goals. NRB can use the narrow monetary

aggregate or broad monetary aggregate as an intermediate target in

conducting the monetary policy. Thus, any of the two definition of

money stock can be taken as an appropriate variable for estimation of

money demand in the policy formulation process.

2. In both models used in the study, none of the interest rates appeared to

be a significant variable in the long run money demand function. To

make the interest rate an effective opportunity cost variable, Nepal

should continue the financial liberalization process developing the

money and capital markets.

3. Since the intercept term is statistically significant in both long run models, it

implies that unidentified variables including time trend have significant

bearings on real money demand. As the coefficient is negative, it indicates that

the unspecified variables including the time trend have negative impact on real

money demand. Thus, further researches should be directed towards including

other determinant variables of money demand like expected inflation rate,

price level, exchange rate etc.

4. In both models, the income elasticity is greater than unity. This implies

the validity of the proposition that less developed countries where the

development of the financial markets is at the low web, money is more

important as a vehicle of saving. Thus, there is the need to develop the

financial market with attractive returns on the financial assets.

REFERENCES

Achsani, N.A. (2010). “Stability of Money Demand in an Emerging Market

Economy: An Error Correction and ARDL Model for Indonesia,”

Research Journal of International Studies, 13, March, 2010.

Aghevli, B.B., M.S. Khan, P.R. Narvekar, and B.K. Short (1979). “Monetary

Policy in Selected Asian Countries”. IMF Staff Papers, 26: 775–824.

Ahmed, S. and Md. Ezazul Islam (2007). “A Cointegrating Analysis of the

Demand for Money in Bangladesh,” Working Paper Series, Research

Division, Bangladesh Bank.

Akinlo, A.E. (2006). “The Stability of Money Demand in Nigeria: An

Autoregressive Distributed Lag Approach,” Journal of Policy

Modeling, 28: 445-452.

Arango, S. and M.I. Nadiri (1981). “Demand for Money in Open Economies,”

Journal of Monetary Economics, 7 (January 1981): 69-83.

Bahmani-Oskooee, M. (2001). “How Stable is M2 Money Demand Function

in Japan?” Japan and the World Economy, 13: 455-461.

_____and Sahar Bahmani (2007). “Exchange Rate Volatility and Demand for

Money in Iran?,” An Unpublished Paper, Department of Economics, The

University of Wisconsin-Milwaukee, Milwaukee, Wisconsin 53201

_____and Raymond Chi Wing Ng (2002). “Long run Demand for money in

Hongkong: An Application of the ARDL Model” International Journal

of Business and Economics, 1(2): 147-155.

_____ and H. Rehman (2005). “Stability of Money Demand Function in

Asian Developing Countries”, Applied Economics, 37: 773-792.

_____and Yongqing Wang (2007). “How Stable is the Demand for Money in

China?” Journal of Economic Development, 32(1) (Jan 2007)

Banerjee, A., J. Dolado, J.W. Galbraith and D.F. Hendry (1993). Co-

integration, Error Correction and the Econometric Analysis of Non-

stationary Data, Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Baumol, W.J. (1952). “The Transaction Demand for Cash: An Inventory

Theoretic Approach,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 66(Nov. 1952):

545-556.

Bhattacharya, B. B. (1974). “Demand and Supply of Money in a Developing

Economy: A Structural Analysis for India,” The Review of Economics

and Statistics, 56(4) (Nov. 1974): 502-510.

Bordo, M. D. and L. Jonung (2004). “Demand for Money: An Analysis of the

Long Run Behavior of the Velocity of Circulation,” Cambridge:

Cambridge University Press.

Bose, S. and H. Rahman (1996). “Demand for Money in Canada: A

Cointegration Analysis,” International Economic Journal, 10(4), 1996.

Boughton, J. M. (1981). “Recent Instability of the Demand for Money: An

International Perspective”, Southern Economic Journal, 47(Jan.1981):

579-597.

Brown, R., J. Durbin, and J. Evans (1975). “Techniques for Testing the

Constancy of Regression Relations Over Time,” Journal of the Royal

Statistical Society, Series B, 37: 149–63.

Brunner K. and A.H. Meltzer (1964). “Some Further Evidence on the Supply

and Demand Functions for Money,” Journal of Finance, 19, May,

1964.

Butter, F.A.G. Den, and M.M.G. Fase (1981). “The Demand for Money in

EEC Countries,” Journal of Monetary Economics, 8 (Sept. 1981): 201-

230.

Cameron N. (1979). “The Stability of Canadian Demand for Money Function

1954-75,” The Canadian Journal of Economics, vol. 12, no. 2 (May,

1979), pp. 258-281.

Chow, G.C. (1966). “On the Long Run and Short Run Demand for Money,”

Journal of Political Economy, April: 111-131.

Cooley, T. F. and E. C. Prescott (1973). "Systematic Variation Models

Varying Parameter Regression: A Theory and Some Applications,"

Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, 2(4) (1973a), 463-473.

Couthbertson, K. (1988). The Supply and Demand for Money, United

Kingdom: Basil and Blackwell Limited.

Engle, Robert F. and C. W. J. Granger. (1987). "Cointegration and Error

Correction Representation, Estimation, and Testing," Econometrica, 55

(March 1987): 251-76.

Friedman, M. (1959). “The Demand for Money: Some Theoretical and

Practical Results,” Journal of Political Economy, August 1959

Gaudel, Y.S. (2003). Monetary System of Nepal. New Delhi: Adroit

Publishers.

Goldfeld, S.M. (1973). “The Demand for Money Revisited,” Brookings

Papers on Economic Activity, 3: 577-646.

Granger, C.W.J. (1981). "Some Properties of Time Series Data and Their Use

in Econometric Model Specification,” Journal of Econometrics, 16:

121-130.

Granger, C.W.J. (1986). "Developments in the Study of Cointegrated

Economic Variables." Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 48

(August 1986): 213-228.

Gujarati, D. (1978). “The Demand for Money in India,” Journal of

Development Studies 5(1): 59-64

Gujarati, D.N. and Sangeetha (2007). Basic Econometrics, New Delhi: Tata

McGraw-Hill Publishing Company Limited.

Gupta, K.L. (1970). “The demand for Money in India: Further Evidence,”

Journal of Development studies, 6 (January 1970): 159-168.

Gupta, S.B. (1979), Monetary Planning for India, New Delhi: Oxford

University Press.

Halicioglu, F. and Mehmet Ugur (2005). “On Stability of Money Demand for

a Devoloping OECD Country,” Global Business and Economic

Review, 7(8).

Hamburger, M.J. (1966). “The Demand for Money by Households, Money

Substitutes, and Monetary Policy,” Journal of Political Economy, 74

(December 1996):600-623.

Hamori, N. and S. Hamori (1999). “Stability of Money Demand Function in

Germany,” Applied Economics Letters, 6: 329-332.

Heller, H.R. (1965). “The Demand for Money: The Evidence from the Short

Run Data,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 79 (June 1965): 291-303.

Jacobs, R.L. (1974). “Estimating the Long-Run Demand for Money from

Time Series Data,” Journal of political Economy, 82(6), Nov.-Dec., pp.

1221-1238.

Johansen, S. (1988). “Statistical Analysis of Cointegration Vectors,” Journal

of Economic Dynamics and Control, 12(2/3): 231-254.

Johansen, S. and Juselius, K. (1990). “Maximum Likelihood Estimation and

Inference on Cointegration: With Applications to the Demand for

Money,” Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics, 52(2):169-210.

Johnson, H.J. (1963). “Notes on the Theory of Transaction Demand for

Cash,” Indian Journal of Economics. 44(172) (July 1963):1-11.

Kaufman, G.G. and C.M. Latta (1966). “The Demand for Money: Preliminary

Evidence from Industrial Countries,” Journal of Financial and

Quantitative Analysis, 75-89

Khan, M.A. and Md Abdul Wadud, (2003). “Monetary Mechanism in

Bangladesh: A Cointegration and Error Correction Modeling

Appraoch,” A Paper presented at the 2nd European Integration and

Banking Efficiency Workshop held on October 30-31, 2003 at Lisbon,

Portugal.

Khan, M.S. (1974). “The Stability of the Demand for Money Functions in the

United States, 1901-1965,” Journal of Political Economy, 82(6) (Nov.-

Dec. 1974): 1205-1220

Khatiwada, Y.R. (1997). “Estimating the Money Demand in Nepal: Some

Empirical Issues,” Economic Review, Occasional Papers, NRB No.9.

Laidler, D.E.W. (1966), “Some Evidence on the Demand for Money,” Journal

of Political Economy 74(1) (Feb. 1966): 55-61.

Laidler, D.E.W. (1971), “The Influence of Money on Economic Activity: A

Survey of Some Current Problems,” in G. Clayton‟s et al (eds.),

Monetary Theory and Monetary Policy in the 1970s (Proceedings of

the 1970 Shetfield Money Seminar ), Oxford University Press.

Laurenceson, J. and J.C.H. Chai (2003). “Financial Reform and Economic

Development in China”, Cheltenham

Lumas, G.S. and Y.P. Mehra (1976). “The Stability of the Demand for Money

Function: The Evidence from Quarterly Data,” The Review of

Economics and Statistics, 58(4) ( Nov. 1976): 463-468.

McKinnon, R.I. (1973). Money and Capital in Economic Development,

Washington: The Brookings institution.

Mehra, Y.P. (1991). “An Error-Correction Model of U.S. M2 Demand,”

Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, Economic Review, 77(May/June):

3-12.

Meltzer, A.G. (1963). “Demand for Money: Evidence from the Time series,”

Journal of Political Economy, 219-246.

Narayan, P.K. and Russel Smyth (2004). “Temporal Causality and the

Dynamics of Exports, Human Capital and Real Income in China,”

International Journal of Applied Economics, 1: 24-35.

Omer, M. (2010). “Stability of Money Demand Function in Pakistan,” SPB

Working Paper Series, 36(Aug).

Pandey, R.P. (1998) “An Application of Cointegration and Error Correction

Modeling: Towards Demand for Money in Nepal,” Economic Review,

Occasional Papers, NRB No.10, 1998.

Patinkin, D. (1972). “Friedman on the Quantity Theory and Keynesian

Economics,” Journalof Political Economy, 80(5) (sept-oct. 1972):883-

905.

Pesaran, M. H., Y. Shin, and R. J. Smith (1996). “Bounds Testing Approaches

to the Analysis of Level Relationships,” DEA Working Paper 9622,

Department of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge.

Pesaran and B. Pesaran (1997). “Working with Microfit 4.0: Interactive

Econometric Analysis”, Oxford University Press.

Pesaran and Y. Shin (1999). “An Autoregressive Distributed Lag Modeling

Approach to Cointegration Analysis”, in S. Strom (ed.), Econometrics

and Economic Theory in the 20th Century, The Ragnar Frisch

Centennial Symposium, 1998, Cambridge University press,

Cambridge.

Pesaran, M. H., Y. Shin, and R. J. Smith (2001). “Bounds Testing Approaches

to the Analysis of Level Relationships,” Journal of Applied

Econometrics, 16: 289-326.

Poole, W. (1970). “The Optimal Choice of Monetary Policy Instruments in a

Simple Macro Model,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 192-216.

Poudyal, S.R. (1989). “The Demand for Money in Nepal,” Economic Review,

Occasional Papers, NRB No.3.

Prasad, K. and Sampath, R.K. (1977). “Transactions Demand for Cash: the

Indian Experience,” The Indian Economic Journal 24(4-5) (April-June

1977): 381-389.

Rutaysire, M. J. (2010). “Economic Liberalization, Monetary Policy and

Demand for Money in Rwanda: 1980-2005,” AERC Research Paper

193, African Research Consortium, Nairobi, January 2010.

Sampath, R.K. and Zakir Hussain (1981). “Demand for Money in India,” The

Indian Economic Journal, 29(1) (July-Sept. 1981): 17-36.

Samreth, S. (2008). “Estimating the Money Demand Function in Combodia:

ARDL Approach,” MRPA Paper No.16274, posted on July 2009.

Simmons, R. (1992). “An Error-correction Approach to Demand for Money in

Five African Developing Countries,” Journal of Economic Studies, 19:

29–47.

Sriram, S.S. (1999). “Demand for M2 in an Emerging-Market Economy: An

Error- Correction Model for Malaysia,” IMF Working paper

WP/99/173.

Sriram, S.S. (2000). “A Survey of Recent Empirical Money Demand Studies,”

IMF Staff Paper, 47(3): 334-365.

Taylor, M.P. (1993). “Modeling the Demand for UK Broad Money,” The

Review of Econimics and Statistics, 75 (1) ( Feb 1993): 112-117.

Tobin, J. (1956). “The Interest Elasticity of Transaction Demand for Money,”

Review of Economics and Statistics, August, 1956.

Tseng, W. and R. Corker. (1991). Financial Liberalization, Money Demand,

and Monetary Policy in Asian Countries. IMF Occasional Paper No.

84, International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C.