social costs of innovative electricity generation ... · social costs of innovative electricity...

22
Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich and Volker Klotz Institute of Energy Economics and the Rational Use of Energy (IER) Department of Technology Assessment and Environment (TFU) Universität Stuttgart Tel.: +49(0)711 - 685-878 35, Fax.: +49(0)711 - 685-878 73, [email protected] 1 Abstract A consistent assessment of electricity generating technologies and a comparison of such technologies has to take into account not only the generation costs (private costs), but also the external effects associated with the generation, e.g. risks to human health, ecosystem damages, reduction of crop yields, material deteriora- tion, change in energy supply security, the effects of global warming and other effects. This paper provides new estimates on social costs of different electricity generation technologies operating in Germany, and in addition PV and concentrated solar power (CSP) in the Mediterranean area. Social costs are obtained by summing up external costs (i.e., monetary value of impacts on human health, crops, building materials, bio- diversity and costs due to climate change) and private costs, i.e. internal electricity generation costs. External costs are calculated applying the ExternE methodology (European Commission, 2005). This in- cludes the Impact Pathway Approach (IPA), which is a site specific bottom-up approach. First, the impacts and risks of an activity, here of generating electricity, are estimated. Therefore, life cycle inventory (LCI) data are applied, i.e. not only the operation phase of the technology but also up- and downstream processes like fuel supply, etc. are taken into account. Then, to make the different impacts comparable with each other and with private costs, these impacts are converted into a common unit by using a method derived from wel- fare economics, i.e. by measuring the willingness to pay to avoid a risk or impact. The derived damages, expressed as external costs, can be added and compared with other costs and other advantages and disadvan- tages. The list of investigated technologies includes nuclear and fossil fired power plants, renewable (PV, Solar Thermal (CSP), Wave & Tidal and Off-Shore Wind) and bio-fuel technologies. Results are provided for new (current state-of-the-art) technologies at present and for technologies that assumingly become available in 2025 and 2050. The data was derived within the integrated European project NEEDS (European Commis- sion, 2008b). Chapter 2 provides an overview of the methodology adopted for external costs calculation. Chapter 3 describes the methodology adopted for private costs calculations. Chapter 4 summarises the results of external and internal costs to social costs. Finally, in Chapter 5 some conclusions are drawn. Keywords: External Costs, Impact Pathway Approach, ExternE, Social Costs, Life Cycle Impact Assessment 2 External Cost Calculation External effects arise from the direct impacts of the economic activities of an economic agent A (e.g. enter- prises, private and public budgets) on the production or consumption options of other economic agents B, if that impact is not fully accounted for by the agent A. If these effects are negative they can be expressed as external costs. The calculation of external costs was performed with the online tool EcoSenseWeb (Preiss and Klotz, 2008). 1

Upload: others

Post on 24-Apr-2020

6 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich and Volker Klotz Institute of Energy Economics and the Rational Use of Energy (IER) Department of Technology Assessment and Environment (TFU) Universität Stuttgart Tel.: +49(0)711 - 685-878 35, Fax.: +49(0)711 - 685-878 73, [email protected]

1 Abstract A consistent assessment of electricity generating technologies and a comparison of such technologies has to take into account not only the generation costs (private costs), but also the external effects associated with the generation, e.g. risks to human health, ecosystem damages, reduction of crop yields, material deteriora-tion, change in energy supply security, the effects of global warming and other effects. This paper provides new estimates on social costs of different electricity generation technologies operating in Germany, and in addition PV and concentrated solar power (CSP) in the Mediterranean area. Social costs are obtained by summing up external costs (i.e., monetary value of impacts on human health, crops, building materials, bio-diversity and costs due to climate change) and private costs, i.e. internal electricity generation costs. External costs are calculated applying the ExternE methodology (European Commission, 2005). This in-cludes the Impact Pathway Approach (IPA), which is a site specific bottom-up approach. First, the impacts and risks of an activity, here of generating electricity, are estimated. Therefore, life cycle inventory (LCI) data are applied, i.e. not only the operation phase of the technology but also up- and downstream processes like fuel supply, etc. are taken into account. Then, to make the different impacts comparable with each other and with private costs, these impacts are converted into a common unit by using a method derived from wel-fare economics, i.e. by measuring the willingness to pay to avoid a risk or impact. The derived damages, expressed as external costs, can be added and compared with other costs and other advantages and disadvan-tages. The list of investigated technologies includes nuclear and fossil fired power plants, renewable (PV, Solar Thermal (CSP), Wave & Tidal and Off-Shore Wind) and bio-fuel technologies. Results are provided for new (current state-of-the-art) technologies at present and for technologies that assumingly become available in 2025 and 2050. The data was derived within the integrated European project NEEDS (European Commis-sion, 2008b). Chapter 2 provides an overview of the methodology adopted for external costs calculation. Chapter 3 describes the methodology adopted for private costs calculations. Chapter 4 summarises the results of external and internal costs to social costs. Finally, in Chapter 5 some conclusions are drawn. Keywords: External Costs, Impact Pathway Approach, ExternE, Social Costs, Life Cycle Impact Assessment

2 External Cost Calculation External effects arise from the direct impacts of the economic activities of an economic agent A (e.g. enter-

prises, private and public budgets) on the production or consumption options of other economic agents B, if

that impact is not fully accounted for by the agent A. If these effects are negative they can be expressed as

external costs. The calculation of external costs was performed with the online tool EcoSenseWeb (Preiss

and Klotz, 2008).

1

Page 2: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

2.1 ExternE Methodology

The ExternE methodology (External costs of Energy (European Commission, 2005) and (ExternE Home-

page)) provides a framework for transforming impacts that are expressed in different units (e.g. global warm-

ing potential [CO2eq], human health impacts [DALY] or damage to the biodiversity due to acidification [loss

of biodiversity]) into a common unit, namely monetary values.

It has the following principal stages:

1) Definition of the activity to be assessed and the background scenario where the activity is embedded;

definition of the important impact categories and externalities.

2) Estimation of the impacts or effects of the activity (in physical units). The impacts are the difference

between the impacts of the scenarios with and without the activity. This is important in order to calculate

marginal impacts if non-linear effects are taken into account. Dispersion modelling is necessary in order to

allocate impacts to certain sources of emission.

3) Monetisation of the impacts, leading to external costs.

4) Assessment of uncertainties and sensitivity analysis.

5) Analysis of the results and drawing of conclusions.

2.2 The Impact Pathway Approach

The impact pathway approach (IPA) is used to quantify environmental impacts as defined above. The princi-

pal steps are illustrated in Figure 1.

2

Page 3: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

⇒ impact(e.g., cases of asthma due to ambient

concentration of particulates)

DOSE-RESPONSE FUNCTION(or concentration-response function)

⇒ cost(e.g., cost of asthma)

MONETARY VALUATION

DISPERSION(e.g. atmospheric dispersion model)

⇒ emission(e.g., kg/yr of particulates)

⇒ increase in concentrationat receptor sites

(e.g., µg/m3 of particulatesin all affected regions)

SOURCE(specification of site and technology)

DOSE

Dose-ResponseFunction

- Emission: specification of the relevant technolo-

gies and pollutants, e.g. kg of oxides of nitrogen

(NOx) per kWhel emitted by a power plant at a spe-

cific site

- Dispersion: calculation of increased primary and

secondary pollutant concentrations in all affected

regions

- Impact: calculation of the cumulated exposure

from the increased concentration, followed by calcu-

lation of impacts (damage in physical units) due to

this exposure using concentration-response func-

tions, e.g. cases of asthma due to increase in O3

- Cost: valuation of impacts in monetary terms, e.g.

multiplication by the monetary value of a case of

asthma.

Figure 1: The principal steps of an impact pathway analysis, for the example of air pollution

2.3 Technology Description

The NEEDS LCI data for the considered reference power plants are taken from (Krewitt, 2009) and

(Frischknecht, 2008). The technologies investigated within the NEEDS project are described in more detail

in the corresponding reports (listed in Table 1) of the different NEEDS partners.

Table 1: List ofreports on technical data, costs and LCI for each technology

Technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of advanced fossil fuels (Dones et al., 2008)

Technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of fuel cell power plants (Gerboni et al., 2008)

Technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of offshore wind farms (DONG Energy, 2008)

Technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of PV applications (Frankl et al., 2008)

Technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of solar thermal power plants (Viebahn et al., 2008)

Technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of biomass power plants (Gärtner, 2008)

Technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of nuclear power plants (Lecointe et al., 2007) Technical specification of reference technologies wave and tidal power plant (Sørensen and Naef, 2008)

In the calculation of the LCI data, the supply of materials and energy carriers, as well as the electricity mix

and transport services were considered for average European conditions.

3

Page 4: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

In case of CHP power plant there are two main products generated in the power plants: heat and electricity.

The emissions and resource use of the production process was allocated to these co-products based according

to their exergy.

2.4 Life Cycle Inventory (LCI)

The Life Cycle Inventory (LCI) is one phase of the Life Cycle Assessment (LCA) methodology, which is

standardised in the ISO norm series 14040 et seq. The norm ISO 14041 specifies the conduction of LCI cal-

culation. For each electricity generation technology a LCA analysis was performed. Figure 2 gives an over-

view of these processes and life cycle stages contributing to the life cycle of electricity generation.

The process of electricity generation is divided

into four sub-processes representing the life cycle

phases. The process fuel supply is relevant for

electricity generation technologies that are based

on hard coal, lignite, oil, natural gas, biomass and

nuclear energy.

Figure 2: Generic Structure of the LCI calculation on electricity generation

Detailed process chain analysis (including all direct and indirect emissions), the material and energy demand

as well as the waste and the release of emissions were identified and quantified. These results for the indi-

vidual processes are referred to the functional unit of one kilowatt hour (1 kWhel) of generated net electricity

(i.e. electricity, which is supplied to the grid) and summed up along the process chain. Within NEEDS sev-

eral different scenarios have been defined in order to provide LCI data for different technology developments

and configurations. These technology development scenarios are called Pessimistic (PE), Realis-

tic/Optimistic (RO), and Very Optimistic (VO).

The general assumptions valid for all datasets are the following:

Pessimistic (PE)

“Socio-economic framing conditions do not stimulate market uptake and technical innovations.”

- it is assumed that there is no technological development (i.e. the datasets are left unchanged) except for

transports (due to legal requirements) and electricity mixes

- the business as usual (BAU) electricity mix scenario is applied on European electricity supply.

4

Page 5: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

Realistic/Optimistic (RO)

“Strong socio-economic drivers support dynamic market uptake and continuous technology development. It

is very likely that the respective technology gains relevance on the global electricity market.”

- the pathway of technology development is as far as possible according to predictions and goals of the in-

dustry that seem reasonable to be achieved

- a “440 ppm CO2 electricity mix” scenario is applied on European electricity supply

Very Optimistic (VO)

“A technological breakthrough makes the respective technology on the long term a leading global electricity

supply technology.”

- improvements according to the optimistic-realistic scenario are introduced earlier

- a switch to cleaner energy generating technologies (e.g. oil to gas) is more common or more pronounced

- the enhanced renewable electricity mix scenario (Renew.) is applied on European electricity supply.

The different scenarios result in different LCI data because of e.g., different underlying energy mix and dif-

ferent assumptions regarding the possible development of technologies.

The LCI data are based on the climate change ‘440 ppm COeq stabilisation scenario’, as it basically repre-

sents current European policy targets.

Substances considered for external cost calculation:

NH3, As, Cd, CO2, Cr-IV, N2O, Dioxins, Formaldehyde, Pb, Hg, CH4, Ni, NOx, NMVOC, primary particu-

late matter (PPMcoarse and PPM2.5), SO2, radioactive noble gases, aerosols, C-14, Cs-137, H-3, Iodines, Kryp-

ton-85, Pb-210, Radon-222, Th-230, Uranium-238.

2.5 Physical Impacts

Impact with regard to human health, ecosystem damages, reduction of crop yields, material deterioration and

effects of global warming have been quantified.

According to the IPA the physical impact to the receptors can be calculated by multiplying the concentration

or deposition in each grid cell with a) the number of receptors, e.g. population or natural soil surface, and b)

by a factor (concentration response function) per unit of concentration or deposition. The impact over the

whole area of Europe is than summed up. Since the impact to human health due to the main primary air pol-

5

Page 6: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

lutants (NH3, NOx, SO2, NMVOC, PPMco and PPM2.5) and their corresponding secondary pollutants nitrates,

sulfates (SIA = secondary inorganic aerosols) and ozone contribute most to the external costs this category is

explained in more detail in the paragraph below. Impacts due to radio nuclides, heavy metals, and to ecosys-

tems, crop yields, and material are described in detail in (European Commission, 2005), (Ott et al., 2006) and

(Preiss et al., 2008).

2.6 Concentration-Response Functions (CRF) and Monetary Values for

Human Health Impacts

In Table 2 an overview over the different health endpoints and the corresponding CRF for particulate matter

(PM) and ozone is given. These are the most important and most reliable CRF provided by (Torfs et al.,

2007). Furthermore, the monetary values per health endpoints are shown. The risk and age group fractions

are already included and the CRF can be applied to total population. The reduced life time expectancy

[YOLL] (Years of Lost Lifetime) is the most important endpoint with regard to the share of external costs.

Table 2: Overview of the CRF for particulate matter (PM) and ozone and corresponding monetary values

Pollutant and corresponding endpoint

Physical impact per person per µg per m3 [1/(µg/m3)] unit

Monetary Value per case or per YOLL [Euro]

External costs per person per µg per m3 [1/(µg/m3)]

primary PM & SIA < 2.5µm Life expectancy reduction - YOLLchronic 6.51E-04 YOLL 40,000 2.60E+01net Restricted activity days 9.59E-03 days 130 1.25E+00Work loss days 1.39E-02 days 295 4.10E+00Minor restricted activity days 3.69E-02 days 38 1.40E+00

primary and SIA < 10µm Increased mortality risk (infants) 6.84E-08 cases 3,000,000 2.05E-01New cases of chronic bronchitis 1.86E-05 cases 200,000 3.71E+00Respiratory hospital admissions 7.03E-06 cases 2,000 1.41E-02Cardiac hospital admissions 4.34E-06 cases 2,000 8.68E-03Medication use / bronchodilator use (adult) 4.03E-04 cases 1 4.03E-04Medication use / bronchodilator use (child) 3.27E-03 cases 1 3.27E-03Lower respiratory symptoms (adult) 3.24E-02 days 38 1.23E+00Lower respiratory symptoms (child) 2.08E-02 days 38 7.92E-01

Ozone - as SOMO35 (sum of ozone means 35 over ppb) Increased mortality risk 2.23E-06 YOLL 60,000 1.34E-01Respiratory hospital admissions 1.98E-06 cases 2,000 3.95E-03

6

Page 7: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

Pollutant and corresponding endpoint

Physical impact per person per µg per m3 [1/(µg/m3)] unit

Monetary Value per case or per YOLL [Euro]

External costs per person per µg per m3 [1/(µg/m3)]

Minor restricted activity days (MRAD) 7.36E-03 days 38 2.80E-01Medication use / bronchodilator use 2.62E-03 cases 1 2.62E-03Lower respiratory symptoms excluding cough 1.79E-03 days 38 6.81E-02Cough days 1.04E-02 days 38 3.96E-01

Values are taken from (Preiss et al., 2008), derived from (Torfs et al., 2007), (Desaigues et al., 2007) and (European Commission, 2005). YOLL = Years of Life Lost.

Example:

Due to operation of a coal fired power plant in Germany SO2 is emitted. Due to dispersion and chemical

transformation with background NH3 into ammonium sulphate this leads to a concentration increment of

secondary particulate matter with aerodynamic diameter smaller than 2.5 µm (PM2.5), in all regions of Eu-

rope - for example, also in Austria. In a certain EMEP grid cell (ca. 50 km x 50 km) in Austria a population

of 250,000 people is living. The yearly average concentration increment due to the emission in Germany is

0.031 ng/m3 PM2.5 per tonne of SO2 emitted. We can calculate the years of lifetime lost (YOLL) and the ex-

ternal costs as follows:

YOLL per tonne SO2_Ger = 0.031 ng/m3 * 6.51E-04 YOLL/µg/m3/person * 250,000 people = 0.005 YOLL.

If we multiply the number of YOLL with the corresponding monetary value we get the external costs, i.e.

0.005 YOLL * 40,000 Euro per YOLL = 200 Euro per tonne of SO2 emitted in Germany - just for this one

grid cell in Austria.

However, this procedure is carried out for each grid cell in the whole of Europe and regarding all quantifi-

able impacts. This leads to an average cost of ca. 9,500 Euro per tonne of SO2 emitted in Germany. For other

countries and other substance also external cost values have been calculated.

2.7 Evaluation of Climate Change due to Greenhouse Gases (GHG)

The evaluation of greenhouse gas emissions is a crucial and highly controversial task. Within the NEEDS

project (European Commission, 2008b) a considerable share of resources has been used to drive a recom-

mendation for reasonable range of values based on most recent insights and scientific results.

The optimal point of greenhouse gas emissions is the one where the real marginal damage costs are equal to

the real marginal avoidance costs. However, these costs are not known and can only be estimated by differ-

7

Page 8: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

ent models. If the calculation of marginal damage costs is based on observable preferences of the society, i.e.

certain value choices regarding discounting and equity weighting the results are relatively small (Anthoff,

2007). However, the application of alternative value choices leads to a very large range of results. Moreover,

large uncertainties and possible gaps exist in the damage assessment. Therefore, and in order to account for

the precautionary principle the values in Table 3 have been recommended, which are based on marginal

avoidance costs based on certain agreed aims.

Scenario I reflects the ambitious policy targets for reaching a maximum of 2°C temperature increase, i.e.

reduction of ca. 20% CO2 in 2020 (compared to 1990) in the EU.

Scenario II is assumed to be more realistic and is directly inspired by the post-Kyoto scenario.

Both scenarios reflect marginal avoidance costs. It has to be emphasised that avoidance costs estimates re-

garding GHG have also wide ranges depending on future developments, emission targets and evaluation

settings and therefore, also have large uncertainties (Kuik et al., 2008).

Table 3: Recommended marginal external costs of GHG [Euro2005 per tonne emission CO2eq ] within

NEEDS

Year 2010 2025 2050

Scen I 23.5 51 198

Scen II 23.5 32 77

2.8 Uncertainties

External cost estimates are notorious for their uncertainties and many people have questioned the usefulness

of external costs. The first reply to this critique is that even an uncertainty by roughly a factor of three is

better than infinite uncertainty. However, a considerable share of uncertainties is not of a scientific nature

(data and model uncertainty) but results from ethical, so called value choices (e.g. valuation of lost life years

in different regions of the world, i.e. equity weighting) and uncertainty about the future. One approach to

reduce the range of results arising from different assumptions on discount rates, valuation of mortality, etc. is

to reach agreement on (ranges of) key values.

The uncertainties have been discussed and quantified for example in (Spadaro and Rabl, 2007) and (Spadaro

and Rabl, 2008). As a rule of thumb the range of possible results (67% confidence interval) is estimated as to

be ca. one third and up to three times the average values of external costs for main air pollutants. Regarding

the estimates for heavy metals or impacts due to climate change this factor is ca. 4-5.

8

Page 9: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

In order to show the influence of this uncertainty a factor of 2.5 and 0.4 will be applied to the external costs

except of the GHG and the influence on the ranking of technologies with regard to the social costs will be

shown.

The ExternE methodology aims to cover all relevant (i.e. not negligible) external effects. However, in the

current state of knowledge, there are still gaps and uncertainties. The purpose of ongoing research is to cover

more effects and thus reduce gaps and in addition refine the methodology to reduce uncertainties. The latest

developments have been achieved in the EU-projects NEEDS (European Commission, 2008b) and CASES

(European Commission, 2008a).

2.9 External Costs per kWhel

External cost per kWh electricity have been calculated multiplying the LCI data with generalised damage

factors “Euro per unit of emission” in a certain region or country, derived with the software tool EcoSen-

seWeb (Preiss and Klotz, 2008). For emissions due to operation damage factors for Germany have been ap-

plied. For all other life cycle stations average European (EU27) damage factors have been applied. In case

of solar thermal, i.e. concentrated solar power (CSP) the facility is assumed to be located in South Spain or

Algeria, because such a plant can not be sited in Germany as the direct solar radiation would not be suffi-

cient.

It has to be emphasised that the LCI data per kWh will vary for the technologies depending on the actual

location due to several factors, such as fuel supply chains but also efficiency of thermal power plants due to

different ambient temperatures. Moreover, it has to be noted that the efficiency of wind and photovoltaic

technologies significantly depend on the location where they operate because the availability of solar radia-

tion or advantageous average wind speeds influences directly the life time electricity output and therefore,

the emissions and also the private costs per kWh. For example, the solar radiation [kWh/m2] in Southern

Italy can be up to factor 2 larger than in Northern Europe.

2.9.1 Which External Costs have been considered?

Considered are releases of substances or energy (noise, radiation) into environmental media (air, indoor air,

soil, water), that cause - after transport and transformation - considerable (not negligible) harm to ecosys-

9

Page 10: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

tems, humans, crops or materials. Regarding climate change impacts damage costs and avoidance cost ap-

proach is taken into account.

Regarding accidents public and partly occupational risks caused by accidents have been considered by use of

expectation value (i.e. risk = potential outcome * probability).

Regarding insecurity of energy supply unexpected changes in availability and prices of energy carriers leads

according to (European Commission, 2008a) to small externalities.

Nuclear fuel cycle waste disposal and nuclear reactor accident

The assessments done by (European Commission, 1995) indicated the external costs (mEcu = 0.001 Ecu) of

waste disposal from waste disposal facilities. Low level waste (LLW) and high level waste (HLW) lead to

ca. 0.0302 mEcu/kWh with a 0% discount rate (DR) and 0.00000853 mEcu/kWh for a 3% DR. Regarding

nuclear reactor accident a range of 0.00235 - 0.104 mEcu/kWh for different reactor accidents was reported

(risk aversion is not included).

External Costs of Transport of Oil and Gas and Transmission of Electricity

The external costs of transport of oil and gas have been investigated within the NEEDS project (research

stream Rs1c) and results have been reported in (FEEM and NTUA, 2007).

The external costs of Transmission of Electricity has been investigated and described in (Vito, 2007).

Overall, the studies indicates that the externalities of transport of oil and gas, and the transmission of electric-

ity are likely to be small compared to those of power generation if they are expressed per kWhel consumed

for a whole country. Nonetheless, local effects can be quite significant to the concerned population.

2.9.2 Which Effects Are Not Included ?

As they are not considered as externalities:

- Effects on Employment

- Depletion of non-renewable resources (oil, gas, silicon, copper, etc.)

- Research and development (sunk costs)

- Income and damage distribution

- Local, site specific ecosystem damage (however, they are addressed and at least partly compensated

within the Environmental Impact Assessment).

10

Page 11: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

As they are considered as externalities but agreed methods or reliable information are not available,

though impacts on the result may be large:

- Assessment of risk aversion (so called Damocles risks, i.e. low probability- high damage risks) –

agreed method not available

- Risk of terrorism or proliferation – information not publicly available

- Visual Intrusion or annoyance (large variability, thus benefit transfer difficult)

- Risk analysis of carbon storage – no quantitative information yet available

- Security of supply for natural gas - methodology not available.

In general not included are unknown or unquantifiable impacts. However, as far as possible, critical issues

are at least mentioned and will be included in future research.

The external cost values for technologies in present and future years are costs in the corresponding year but

expressed in Euro2000 prices.

3 Private Costs Calculation Private costs are all costs per kWhel borne by the electricity producer, but without taxes (VAT) and subsidies.

They include investment, operation and maintenance, fuel, supplies and services, dismantling, waste dis-

posal, and in case of the necessity of provision of reserve capacity also back-up costs. The estimation and

projection of costs have been made for current plants, plants built 2025 and some educated guesses have

been made for 2050 by Markus Blesl and Steffen Wissel. Private costs have been also reported in (Blesl et

al., 2008) and in the NEEDS reports listed in Table 1. The current state and long-term development of gener-

ating costs is based on present best predictions about the evolution of the considered technologies and energy

price assumption up to 2050.

The lower end of the range of private costs represents values from the NEEDS (Table 1) realistic-optimistic

scenario. The upper bound uses

- for renewables: a realistic but less optimistic estimation

- for natural gas: 70% higher prices

- for CCS: a doubling of estimated costs for carbon transport and storage

- for nuclear: 20% (2025) respectively 80% (2050) higher investment costs.

11

Page 12: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

It has to be born in mind that all values, but especially the once for year 2050 are highly uncertain due to

long time span in the future.

Costs of building, maintaining and running different types of generating systems are included. To quantify

the full generating costs the Average Levelised Lifetime Generating Costs (ALLGC`s) are calculated for each

considered technology. The methodology calculates the generation costs on the basis of net power supplied

to the station busbar, where electricity is fed to the grid. The cost estimation methodology discounts the time

series of expenditures to their present values in a specified base year by applying a discount rate. A discount

rate takes into account that the time value of money does not have the same value as the same sum earned or

spent today. The levelised lifetime cost per kWh of electricity generated is the ratio of total lifetime expenses

versus total expected outputs, expressed in terms of present value equivalent. This cost is equivalent to the

average price that would have to be paid by consumers to repay exactly the investor/operator for the capital,

fuel expenses and Operation and Maintenance (O&M) expenses, inclusive the rate of return equal to discount

rate. The date selected as base year for the following calculations is Euro in year 2000. Hence, the normal

inflation is excluded from the calculations. However escalation of fuel prices and increased O&M costs, e.g.

due to higher staff and materials costs, are considered. The results taken for this paper are based on 5% dis-

counting. The introduction of the intermittent renewable energies, like wind or solar power, affects the elec-

tricity generating system. The inflexibility, variability, and relative unpredictability of intermittent energy

sources are the most obvious barriers to an easy integration and widespread application of wind and solar

power. Due to the fluctuation by producing energy with wind and solar plants a back-up technology is neces-

sary for compensating this. The back-up cost of not assured generating power of solar and wind plants can be

calculated with equations derived from (Friedrich et al., 1989).

What is important for strategic decisions about research and development is the possible development of

costs in the future, i.e. until 2050. The methodology used here is a combination of learning curves, i.e. a

trend projection of the past cost reduction into the future, and a technical analysis of improvements discussed

for each technology.

12

Page 13: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

4 Social Cost Calculation Social costs are private cost plus external costs. In Figure 3 the external cost of present new technology are

displayed. The category “HH_others” includes impacts due to heavy metals, radionuclide, formaldehyde and

dioxins, and is (due to the small amounts emitted), mostly negligible. The category “Land Use” evaluates the

potential loss of biodiversity due to land transformation. The category “CropsMaterialBioDiversity” displays

the impacts due emissions of SO2, NOx and NH3 which leads to acid deposition, eutrophication due to N

deposition and to ozone. “Human Health class” includes all effects due to main air pollutants towards human

health, as described in Table 2.

0 1 2

Lignite

Hard Coal

Gas CC

Nuclear

Bio fuelled ''typical' current

Fuel Cell' 'typical' current

Solar Thermal

PV tilted roof, sc-Si, retrofit

Wind offshore park 160MW

3[Euro-Cent2000 per kWh]

Greenhouse Gas

Human Health class

CropsMaterialBioDiversity

Land Use

HH_others

Figure 3: External cost of new technologies at the present (risk aversion, terrorism and visual intru-sion not included)

13

Page 14: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

In Figure 4 the ranking according to the social costs of these technologies is displayed. The different contri-

butions to the private costs and to the external costs of each technology add up to the total social costs.

Please note the different scale of the x-axes [Euro-Cent2000 per kWh]. The external costs are distinguished in

GHG costs and all other external costs are sub summarised in the category “other Ext Cost”. The uncertainty

range indicates the uncertainty of these external costs.

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55

Nuclear

Lignite

Gas Comb. Cycle

Wind Offshore

Biomass

Solar Thermal

Nat. Gas Fuel Cell

PV Roof, Retrofit

[Euro-Cent per kWh]

Invest Costs

Fuel Costs

O&M Costs

Back Up

GHG Costs

other Ext Costs

with uncertaintyrange

Figure 4: Ranking according to social costs of electricity generation technologies in the year 2010 (risk aversion, terrorism and visual intrusion not included)

In the following Figures the external costs and the social costs of typical average technologies in 2025 and

2050 are presented in diagrams.

The external costs are shown in Figure 5 and Figure 8. The external costs are based on LCI data correspond-

ing to the “440ppm” and Realistic / Optimistic scenario (RO).

The technologies are ranked according to the total external costs based on the greenhouse gas evaluation

“Scenario II”, i.e. the lower, more realistic external costs regarding greenhouse gas emissions. However, the

difference to the external costs if “Scenario I” values are used is added on top of the columns. It becomes

quite obvious that the external costs of fossil fuelled technologies are dominated by the costs of greenhouse

gases (mainly CO2). However, it is also shown that the combustion technology regarding biomass has very

14

Page 15: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

high external costs due to main air pollutants, i.e. the impact on human health. The external costs of solar

thermal, PV, wave and tidal, wind off-shore and nuclear power are all very small.

0

1

2

3

4

5

6

Biomas

s

Coal_C

ond.

Lignit

e_Con

d.

Lignit

e_IG

CC

Coal_I

GCC

Lignit

e_IG

CC_CCS

Coal_I

GCC_CCS

FuelCell

Gas

Gas C

CGT

FuelC

ell B

iogas

Gas C

CGT CCS

PV roof

Centra

l

PV Ope

n Cen

tral

Solar th

ermal

PV Ope

n Sou

th

Wav

e&Tida

l

Nuclea

r PW

R

Wind

off-s

hore

[Eur

o-C

ent 2

000 p

er k

Wh]

GHG_highGHGLand UseHuman Health otherCrops Material BioDiversityHuman Health main air pollut

Figure 5: External costs in 2025 (RO), operation in Germany (except of Solar thermal and PV South) (risk aversion, terrorism and visual intrusion not included)

In Figure 6 and Figure 7 the social costs for the year 2025 are displayed. In Figure 9 and Figure 10 the social

costs for the year 2050 are displayed

Columns show quantifiable social costs for technologies with the first year of operation in the year 2025 and

2050. However, both, private costs and external costs span a range of uncertainty. The external costs include

impacts to human health due to main air pollutants, greenhouse gases (GHG) and other quantifiable external-

ities. The external costs of GHG are based on certain values for 2025 and 2050, as shown in Table 3. The

blue bars exemplify the range of social costs based on the “best guess” of external costs plus the lower and

the upper range of private costs. The red lines indicate the uncertainty range of external costs of non-

greenhouse gases. This influence of the uncertainty of the non-GHG is demonstrated by the application of

factor of 2.5 for the upper and 0.4 for the lower value. The range of private costs is especially large for the

PV technologies.

15

Page 16: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

FuelCell

Gas

PV roof

Centra

l

FuelC

ell B

iogas

Biomas

s

PV Ope

n Cen

tral

Solar th

ermal

PV Ope

n Sou

th

Coal_C

ond.

Gas C

C CCS

Coal_I

GCC

Lignit

e_IG

CC

Coal_I

GCC_CCS

Lignit

e_IG

CC_CCS

Lignit

e_Con

d.

Wind

off-s

hore

Gas C

C

Wav

e&Tida

l

Nuclea

r PWR

[Eur

o-C

ent 2

000 p

er k

Wh]

upper range due to uncertainty of non-GHG external costs

range of social costs due to range of private costs

lower range due to uncertainty of non-GHG external costs

Figure 6: Social costs of electricity generation technologies in the year 2025 - operation in Germany - (except of Solar thermal and PV South) (risk aversion, terrorism and visual intrusion not included) based on GHG evaluation according to scenario II, i.e. lower, more realistic external costs regarding greenhouse gas emissions

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

35

FuelC

ell G

as

PV roof

Centra

l

FuelC

ell B

iogas

Biomas

s

PV Ope

n Cen

tral

Coal_C

ond.

Solar th

ermal

Lignit

e_IG

CC

PV Ope

n Sou

th

Coal_I

GCC

Lignit

e_Con

d.

Gas C

C CCS

Coal_I

GCC_CCS

Gas C

C

Lignit

e_IG

CC_CCS

Wind

off-s

hore

Wav

e&Tida

l

Nuclea

r PWR

[Eur

o-C

ent 2

000 p

er k

Wh]

upper range due to uncertainty of non-GHG external costs

range of social costs due to range of private costs

lower range due to uncertainty of non-GHG external costs

Figure 7: Social costs of electricity generation technologies in the year 2025 - operation in Germany - (except of Solar thermal and PV South) (risk aversion, terrorism and visual intrusion not included) based on GHG evaluation according to scenario I, i.e. lower, more realistic external costs regarding greenhouse gas emissions

16

Page 17: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

In 2050 the LCI data of the different technologies is in general lower than in 2025. However, the monetary

value of impacts to human health and to biodiversity is increasing with increasing willingness to pay (WTP)

to avoid these impacts. It is assumed that the WTP increases proportional (corrected by a factor of 0.85 for

the income elasticity) with the rate of economic growth (which is assumed to be ca. 2% per year till 2030 and

after 1% per year till 2050).

0

2

4

6

8

10

12

14

16

Lignit

e_IG

CC

Coal_I

GCC

Biomas

s

FuelC

ell G

as

Gas C

CGT

Lignit

e_IG

CC_CCS

Coal_I

GCC_CCS

FuelC

ell B

iogas

Gas C

CGT CCS

Solar th

ermal

PV roof

Centra

l

PV Ope

n Cen

tral

Wav

e&Tida

l

PV Ope

n Sou

th

Wind

off-s

hore

Nuclea

r Gen

IV

[Eur

o-C

ent 2

000 p

er k

Wh]

GHG_highGHGLand UseHuman Health otherCrops Material BioDiversityHuman Health main air pollut

Figure 8: External costs in 2050 (RO), operation in Germany (except of Solar thermal and PV South) (risk aversion, terrorism and visual intrusion not included)

The technologies in Figure 8 are again ranked according to the total external costs based on the Scenario II,

i.e. the lower, more realistic external costs regarding greenhouse gas emissions. In future the external costs

of fossil fuelled plants are even more dominated by GHG emission. Even the technologies including CCS

cause considerable external costs due to emission of GHG. In Figure 9 and Figure 10 the social costs are

displayed.

17

Page 18: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

PV roof

Centra

l

FuelC

ell G

as

Biomas

s

PV Ope

n Cen

tral

Lignit

e_IG

CC

Coal_I

GCC

FuelC

ell B

iogas

Gas C

CGT

Gas C

CGT CCS

PV Ope

n Sou

th

Coal_I

GCC_CCS

Lignit

e_IG

CC_CCS

Solar th

ermal

Wind

off-s

hore

Wav

e&Tida

l

Nuclea

r Gen

IV

[Eur

o-C

ent 2

000 p

er k

Wh]

upper range due to uncertainty of non-GHG external costs

range of social costs due to range of private costs

lower range due to uncertainty of non-GHG external costs

Figure 9: Social costs of electricity generation technologies in the year 2050 - operation in Germany - (except of Solar thermal and PV South) (risk aversion, terrorism and visual intrusion not included) based on GHG evaluation according to scenario II, i.e. lower, more realistic external costs regarding greenhouse gas emissions

0

5

10

15

20

25

30

Lignit

e_IG

CC

Coal_I

GCC

FuelC

ell G

as

PV roof

Centra

l

Gas C

CGT

Biomas

s

PV Ope

n Cen

tral

Gas C

CGT CCS

FuelC

ell Biog

as

Coal_I

GCC_CCS

Lignit

e_IG

CC_CCS

PV Ope

n Sou

th

Solar th

ermal

Wind

off-s

hore

Wav

e&Tida

l

Nuclea

r Gen

IV

[Eur

o-C

ent 2

000 p

er k

Wh]

upper range due to uncertainty of non-GHG external costs

range of social costs due to range of private costs

lower range due to uncertainty of non-GHG external costs

Figure 10: Social costs of electricity generation technologies in the year 2050 operation in Germany - (except of Solar thermal and PV South) (risk aversion, terrorism and visual intrusion not included)

18

Page 19: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

based on GHG evaluation according to scenario I, i.e. lower, more realistic external costs regarding greenhouse gas emissions

5 Conclusions In the following the conclusions based on these results are listed:

- The ranking of technologies according to the external costs is very different from the ranking according to

private costs only. However, the assumptions regarding private costs are crucial.

- Social costs differ from private costs and thus, the external costs influence the ranking of electricity gener-

ating technologies.

- The comparison of different technologies cannot only be based on comparison of direct pressures, i.e. emis-

sions at the site of the power plant operation because the different up- and downstream processes can con-

tribute to a considerable share to the total life cycle impact.

- The majority of the external costs are caused by emission of main air pollutants and greenhouse gases. The

external costs caused by emission of main air pollutants are mainly caused by impacts to human health. With

regard to the fossil fuelled technologies (natural gas, lignite and hard coal) SO2 and NOx are main contribu-

tors and less impacts are caused due emissions of primary particulate matter and NMVOC.

- The results provide important input for the comparison, discussion and integration of the different options

for electricity generation technologies. However, other aspects have also to be taken into account, such as

potential, net stability, resource consumption and availability, security of supply, public acceptance, etc.

- Nuclear, wind, run-off water, wave and tidal energy are electricity generating options with low external and

social costs. However, especially run-off water has nearly reached its potential.

- Fluctuating technologies need back-up capacity, e.g. coal or gas or alternative renewable.

- For nuclear (EPR now, Generation IV after 2030) and on-shore wind in some countries problems with the

acceptance might occur.

- Lignite, where available and coal will continue to play a major role, especially with CCS (if CCS turns out

to have low environmental and technical risks) unless the costs for transport and storage are higher than an-

ticipated and the level of ambition for climate protection is not too high.

19

Page 20: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

- At least until 2025 electricity production with solar plants continues to have the highest quantifiable social

costs.

- In the 2050 future solar thermal systems in Mediterranean countries could be the next best option with high

potential – especially, if the climate protection goals are very ambitious and CCS is not working efficiently

or has a limited potential.

- Natural gas will only play a role replacing coal, if the price for gas (and oil) is expected to stay moderate,

however, without CCS.

- Bio-fuel has relatively high external and social costs. But still, the use of residual biomass in large plants

might be a favourable option.

The resulting social costs data provide a basis for the recommendation to use the potential of nuclear, wind

and hydropower as far as possible, however the potential of these technologies is limited. The analysis

shows, that the remaining electricity demand in the near future still should be met by using lignite and coal.

Depending on the stringency of the climate change aims these plants would be equipped with CCS (carbon

capture and storage) or not. The environmental advantages of PV are too small to compensate the very high

investment costs in Germany. With ambitious climate change aims and if CCS turns out to be less economi-

cally or technically feasible the import of electricity generated by a solar thermal systems in Mediterranean

countries will become an option.

4 References Anthoff, D. (2007), "Report on marginal external costs inventory of greenhouse gas emissions", NEEDS Deliverable D5.4, RS1b - Project no: 502687.

Blesl, M., Wissel, S. and Mayer-Spohn, O. (2008), "Private costs of electricity and heat generation", CASES deliverable D.4.1, CASES project, WP4, Institut für Energiewirtschaft und Rationelle Energieanwendung, (IER), Universitaet Stuttgart.

Desaigues, B., Ami, D., Hutchison, M., Rabl, A., Chilton, S., Metcalf, H., Hunt, A., Ortiz, R., Navrud, S., Kaderjak, P., Szántó, R., Nielsen, J. S., Pellegrini, C. J. e. S., Kohlová, M. B., Scasny, M., Máca, V., Urban, J., Stoeckel, M.-E., Bartczak, A., Markiewicz, O., Riera, P. and Farreras, V. (2007), "Final Report on the monetary valuation of mortality and morbidity risks from air pollution", NEEDS project, FP6, Rs1b_D6.7.

Dones, R., Bauer, C., Heck, T., Mayer-Spohn, O. and Blesl, M. (2008), "Final report on technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of advanced fossil fuels", NEEDS Rs1a_WP7_D07.2 - Project no: 502687.

20

Page 21: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

DONG Energy (2008), "Final report on technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of offshore wind farms", NEEDS Rs1a_WP1_D10.2 - Project no: 502687.

European Commission (1995), "ExternE, Externalities of Energy, Vol. 5", prepared by, M. DREICER, V. TORT and P. MANEN, Centre d’etude sur l’evaluation de la protection dans le domaine nucleaire (CEPN).

European Commission (2005). "ExternE - Externalities of Energy: Methodology 2005 update", Edited by Peter Bickel and Rainer Friedrich, Institut für Energiewirtschaft und Rationelle Energieanwendung (IER), Universität Stuttgart, Germany. EUR 21951.

European Commission (2008a), "CASES “Cost Assessment of Sustainable Energy Systems” Project No 518294 SES6, http://www.feem-project.net/cases/ ".

European Commission (2008b), "Integrated project NEEDS – New Energy Externalities Devel-opments for Sustainability, Project no: 502687, Research Stream 1b: “Development and improvement of a methodology to estimate external costs of energy” - http://www.needs-project.org/. "

ExternE Homepage. "Externalities of Energy. A Research Project of the European Commision", from http://www.externe.info/.

FEEM and NTUA (2007), "Burdens from Oil Transportation Phase of Oil by Pipeline and by Tanker Route", NEEDS project, FP6, Rs1c_D1.5 - Project no: 502687, FEEM, NTUA.

Frankl, P., Menichetti, E. and Raugei, M. (2008), "Final report on technical data, costs and life cycle invento-ries of PV applications", NEEDS Rs1a_WP1_D11.2 - Project no: 502687.

Friedrich, R., Kallenbach, U., Thöne, E., Voß, A., Rogner, H. and Karl, H. (1989), "Externe Kosten der Stromerzeugung. Schlussbetrachtung zum Projekt im Auftrag vom VDEW, VWEW Energieverlag", Frank-furt (Main).

Frischknecht, R. (2008), "LCA database content, LCI data V1.1 (13.01.2009) - with 440ppm-mix", NEEDS project, Rs1a_D5.2 - Project no: 502687, ESU-services.

Gärtner, S. (2008), "Final report on technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of biomass power plants", NEEDS project, FP6, Rs1a_D13.2 - Project no: 502687, IFEU, IER.

Gerboni, R., Pehnt, M. and Viehbahn, P. (2008), "Final report on technical data, costs and life cycle invento-ries of fuel cell power plants", NEEDS Rs1a_WP9_D9.2 - Project no: 502687.

Krewitt, W. (2009), "NEEDS, Rs1a European average technology LCI data for the scenario "Optimistic Re-alistic" for present, 2025 and 2050 - Project no: 502687", Stuttgart.Personal Communication to P. Preiss,

Kuik, O., Brander, L., Nikitina, N., Navrud, S., Magnussen, K. and Fall, E. H. (2008), "Report on the mone-tary valuation of energy related impacts on land use changes, acidification, eutrophication, visual intrusion and climate change", CASES project, WP3.

Lecointe, C., Lecarpentier, D., Maupu, V., Le Boulch, D. and Richard, R. (2007), "Final report on technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of nuclear power plants", NEEDS project, FP6, Rs1a_D14.2 - Project no: 502687.

Ott, W., Frischknecht, R., Baur, M., Kaufmann, Y. and Steiner, R. (2006), "Assessment of biodiversity losses", NEEDS Deliverable D4.2, RS1b, WP4 - Project no: 502687.

Preiss, P., Friedrich, R. and Klotz, V. (2008), "Report on the procedure and data to generate aver-aged/aggregated data, including ExternalCosts_per_unit_emission_080821.xls." NEEDS project, FP6, Rs3a_D1.1 - Project no: 502687, Institut für Energiewirtschaft und Rationelle Energieanwendung (IER), Universität Stuttgart, Stuttgart.

21

Page 22: Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation ... · Social Costs of Innovative Electricity Generation Technologies in the Present and till 2050 Philipp Preiss, Rainer Friedrich

22

Preiss, P. and Klotz, V. (2008), "Revised Description of the Updated and Extended Tool EcoSenseWeb for the Detailed Site-dependent Assessment of External Costs (http://EcoSenseWeb.ier.uni-stuttgart.de/)", NEEDS project, FP6, Rs1b_D7.1 - Project no: 502687, Institut für Energiewirtschaft und Rationelle Ener-gieanwendung (IER), Universitaet Stuttgart, Stuttgart.

Sørensen, H. C. and Naef, S. (2008), "Final report on technical specification of reference technologies (wave and tidal power plant)", NEEDS project, FP6, Rs1a_D16.1 - Project no: 502687, SPOK.

Spadaro, J. and Rabl, A. (2007), "Report on the methodology for the consideration of uncertainties", NEEDS project, FP6, Rs1b_D7.2 - Project no: 502687, ARMINES/Ecole des Mines, 60 boul. St.-Michel, 75272 Paris 06, Joseph V. Spadaro, [email protected] and Ari Rabl, [email protected].

Spadaro, J. V. and Rabl, A. (2008), "Final report on the Uncertainty of the Transfer/Generalization of Ex-ternE Results", NEEDS project, FP6, Rs3a_D3.2 - Project no: 502687, ARMINES/Ecole des Mines, 60 boul. St.-Michel, 75272 Paris 06, Joseph V. Spadaro, [email protected] and Ari Rabl, [email protected].

Torfs, R., Hurley, F., Miller, B. and Rabl, A. (2007), "A set of concentration-response functions", NEEDS project, FP6, Rs1b_D3.7 - Project no: 502687.

Viebahn, P., Lechon, Y., Kronshage, S. and Trieb, F. (2008), "Final report on technical data, costs and life cycle inventories of solar thermal power plants", NEEDS Rs1a_WP12_D12.2 - Project no: 502687, DLR, CIEMAT.

Vito (2007), "Accounting framework to assess the external costs of electricity transmission", NEEDS pro-ject, FP6, Rs1c_WP3 D3.1-4 - Project no: 502687 - not publicly available, Vito, E-CO, NTUA, FEEM and OME.