social cohesion paper

Upload: max-berre

Post on 07-Apr-2018

227 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    1/27

    Evaluating welfare states in Europeon social cohesion

    Maastricht University

    Faculty of Economics and Business Administration

    Maastricht, 1 June 2007

    NGotho, Philip (i428442)

    Groenestijn, Martin-Hugo, van (i179388)

    1039M Social Europe(s)

    Tutor: Dr. T. van Veen

    Paper

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    2/27

    Social Europe(s) 2

    Table of Content

    Table of Content ______________________________________________________2

    1.INTRODUCTION_____________________________________________________3

    2.METHODOLOGY_____________________________________________________42.1 Weighting sub-indicators ______________________________________________ 5

    2.2 Quantifiying sub-indicators_____________________________________________ 52.2.1SOCIAL INCLUSION_________________________________________________________5 2.2.2INEQUALITY______________________________________________________________6 2.2.3POVERTY ________________________________________________________________7

    2.3 Aggregating towards Social Cohesion ____________________________________ 7

    3.DATA DESCRIPTION__________________________________________________8

    4.EMPIRICALANALYSIS________________________________________________9

    4.1 Indicator outcome_____________________________________________________ 94.2 Social Cohesion with respect to Public Social Expenditures _________________ 11

    4.3 Equity and Efficiency_________________________________________________ 13

    5.CONCLUSION______________________________________________________15

    REFERENCES: _______________________________________________________16

    APPENDIXA_________________________________________________________17

    APPENDIXB_________________________________________________________19

    APPENDIXC_________________________________________________________24

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    3/27

    Social Europe(s) 3

    1.INTRODUCTION

    The European welfare state is under attack. Opponents suggest causality

    between Europes modest economic performance compared to the US and the size of

    transfer programs (Atkinson, 1999). Supporters of the welfare state claim that the

    European welfare system can be regarded as the jewel on the crown. (Giddens,

    2007, p. 1).

    When arguing against the welfare state, authors often come up with poor or

    even wrong arguments see De Neubourg and Castonguay (2006). Even the concept

    of welfare state is often misused, when is argued against the Europes welfare state in

    general. It is a misconception that there is just one European Social Model.

    Sapir (2005) argues that there are four types of welfare states; the Nordic,

    Continental, Mediterranean and the Anglo-Saxon. This paper will develop an

    indicator which can be used to identify these four systems and compare the

    performance of the different types of welfare states. The created indicator will reflect

    social cohesion. The welfare state is created to achieve broad social cohesion and is

    therefore the most important evaluator of success. We quantify social cohesion (our

    indicator) by data on social inclusion, inequality and poverty.

    The subsequent step to take, is investigating whether social spending has a

    (positive) influence on social cohesion. This is done on a cross-section basis within

    Europe. This relation is indeed positive (more social spending is associated with

    higher social cohesion).

    The last opportunity for opponents of the welfare state left, is the so-called

    equity-efficiency trade-off. This is often mentioned as an endogenous welfare state

    characteristic: generating equity can only be achieved at the cost of efficiency. We

    investigate the change in real GDP per capita as a proxy for efficiency along with theGini-coefficient as estimator for equity. If there exists a positive relation, then that

    suggests that an equity-efficiency trade-off exists. We cannot provide any convincing

    evidence in favour or against the trade-off.

    This paper continues with a section on the methodology. Section III gives a

    short overview of the data we collected; section IV presents the empirical findings.

    The paper is concluded with section V where we summarise our findings and

    formulate our view on the welfare state. This view is accompanied by

    recommendations for future policy.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    4/27

    Social Europe(s) 4

    2.METHODOLOGY

    We follow the methodology as proposed by Efferink, Kool and Van Veen

    (2003) for their analysis of country risk. Their starting point is the development of

    data categories and grouping the corresponding data. A weighting scheme gives one

    indicator per category. The category indicators (sub-indicators) are also given a

    certain weight to finally arrive at the final indicator. According to Efferink et. al., it is

    important to [n]ote that this formula or weighting scheme is not derived from a set of

    equations. Nor is there any prescription about how to construct such a scheme. (...)

    [T]his highly subjective view on the relevance of various variables (...) is the secret.

    (Efferink, Kool & Van Veen, 2003, p.45).

    This methodology is applied as following. The data categories relevant for this

    paper are social inclusion, inequality and poverty. The weights given to each of these

    sub-indicators are 40%, 20% and 40%, respectively.

    Subsequently, these three categories need to be quantified this is done by

    using the following variables. For social inclusion, we use (very) long-term

    unemployment rate, suicide rate and self-perceived health. Inequality is measured by

    the Gini-coefficient and the gender pay gap. The last category (poverty) is using data

    on (persistent) at risk of poverty rate. This methodology is summarised in table 1.

    Parameter Value Weight Sub-indicator Weight Indicator

    1.1 Long-Termunemployment 15%1.2 Very Long-Termunemployment 35%

    1.3 Suicide rate 30%1.4 Self-perceived health(bad) 10%

    1. SocialInclusion

    1.5 Self-perceived health(very bad) 10%

    40%

    2.1 Gini coefficient 70%2Inequality 2.2 Gender pay gap 30%

    20%

    3.1 At-risk of poverty rate 30%3 Poverty 3.2 Persistent at-risk of

    poverty rate 70%

    40%

    Table 1

    As mentioned by Efferink et al., the weights on each sub-indicator and their

    underlying variables are rather subjective. Therefore, unfortunately, the justificationof our (sub-)indicator weights is not extremely robust, nor analytically invulnerable.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    5/27

    Social Europe(s) 5

    Practically, the scheme has been created by logical reasoning. Besides, it

    represents our view on the relative importance of the different components of social

    inclusion.

    2.1 Weighing sub-indicators

    As poverty and social inclusion are highly related (poverty can result in a lack

    of social inclusion), these variables should be given equal weight1 to reflect the

    relative importance of these variables. Inequality is a phenomenon that is, outside

    Europe, often observed in societies with lower income per capita. This is a

    correlation, not a causality and therefore it only sideways contributes to a lack of

    social cohesion. Another reason to give inequality a lower importance than the other

    two sub-indicators is the fact that inequality deviates less between European countries

    than other data (e.g. income per capita). This roughly evenly distributed variable

    carries therefore less information in it than a very scattered variable would do (see for

    example Bertola (2006), figure 2). These two types of arguments (analytical and

    empirical) give enough support to assign only half the importance to inequality as

    compared to social inclusion and poverty.

    2.2 Quantifying sub-indicators

    The following subsection section elaborates on the construction of the sub-

    indicators on social inclusion, inequality and poverty. Prior to producing these sub-

    indicators it is essential to provide a definition of these concepts, as it enlarges our

    understanding of these social conditions. This in turn enables us to select the most

    appropriate variables which can capture the development of the social conditions over

    time and can allow cross-section analysis. For the underlying variables, the general

    rule long-term/persistence is worse than short-term applies. This is applicable for

    unemployment and poverty rates.

    2.2.1SOCIAL INCLUSION

    Several definitions are offered for social and economic inclusion and

    exclusion (see The Roeher Institute p.43 (2003)). We intend to use the definition as

    1This is a good example of the subjectiveness; one could argue that poverty facilitates social exclusion

    and should therefore have a higher (relative) importance [1:1.5 instead of 1:1]

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    6/27

    Social Europe(s) 6

    suggested by Guildford (2002), where he defines social inclusion as being

    accepted and able to participate fully within our families, our communities and our

    society. Those who are excluded (...) do not have the opportunity for full participation

    in the economic and social benefits of society. For measurement purposes it is

    important to find indicators which capture the development of the social conditions

    over time.

    Bearing in mind the definition for social inclusion, we believe that long-term

    unemployment, suicide rate and self-perceived health are the most suitable indicators

    for the level of social inclusion. The weighing scheme gives the highest weight (50%)

    to long-term unemployment as it is considered to be the highest risk factor of social

    exclusion (European Commission DJR, 2001).

    Suicide rate, used as a proxy for societys physiological exclusion (social

    attachment), is given the second highest weight (30%). Suicide may be a surprising

    choice, but it is the second most common cause of death among young men

    (Rahman et al., 2000). Rahman et al. provide evidence about the connection between

    suicide and socio-economic conditions. This is enough for enclosure of this variable.

    Amongst others, OHara (2006) discusses the link between social inclusion

    and health status. He observes that social inclusion has been widely recognized as a

    key social determinant of health. Obviously, this is the reverse relation as we use it,

    but the correlation still holds. The reason for equal importance of bad and very bad

    self-perceived health is due to subjective measurement of this data; self-reporting

    makes an objective distinction between bad and very bad difficult.

    2.2.2INEQUALITY

    The second sub-indicator to be quantified is inequality. The two variables to

    quantify inequality are the Gini-coefficient and the gender pay gap. The Gini-

    coefficient measures the inequality of distribution of income. The value lies between 0

    and 1, where 0 corresponds to perfect income equality and 1 to perfect income

    inequality. The gender pay gap measures the difference between mens and womens

    average gross hourly earnings as a percentage of mens average gross hourly earnings.

    These two variables are given weights of 70% (societal income inequality) and

    30% (gender inequality) respectively. This weighting scheme does in principle just

    represent a matter of taste we think inequality is best described by income inequality

    across the entire population; though, much gender inequality is certainly undesirable.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    7/27

    Social Europe(s) 7

    It must be recognised that changing this relative importance has only moderate

    aggregate effects (inequality as sub-indicator only contributes to one-fifth of the total

    indicator).

    2.2.3POVERTY

    The final sub-indicator is poverty. We follow the definition proposed by

    Hansen (1994, cited in Golding 1995, p.213), which states that people are in poverty

    when their resources are so limited as to exclude them from the minimum acceptable

    way of life in the state in which they live.

    Persistent poverty is worse than short-term poverty (general rule). The

    relative importance is set at 70% and 30% respectively and is justified by mentioning

    that this proposal reflects our view that long term poverty and is much worse than

    short term poverty.

    2.3 Aggregating towards Social Cohesion

    In the literature many different definitions of social cohesion are used; some

    authors emphasise shared values and sense of belonging as being critical, other base

    their definition on the ability to work together. We propose to use the definition

    employed by the European Committee for Social Cohesion, which defines social

    cohesion as:

    Societys ability to secure the long-term well-being of all its members,

    including equitable access to available resources, respect for human dignity

    with due regard for diversity, personal and collective autonomy and

    responsible participation.

    According to the committee this definition presupposes social commitment to

    reduce disparities to a minimum and avoid polarisation (Council of Europe, 2005,

    p.23). Using this description one can group social inclusion, inequality and poverty to

    the broader definition of social cohesion. Our indicator will thus aim to measure the

    degree of social cohesion within a country, where a lower indicator corresponds to a

    higher degree of social cohesion.

    .

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    8/27

    Social Europe(s) 8

    3.DATA DESCRIPTION

    Our research on the indicators is for the largest part based on data provided by

    Eurostat. This database is an institution from the European Union to enhance public

    access to information about [European Union] initiatives and European Union policies

    in general (http://ec.europa.eu). Some caution about objectivity is therefore

    demanded, but severe concerns about this issue are highly unlikely to be realistic.

    We have created a panel of yearly data ranging in the time-dimension mostly

    from 1995 to 2005. This enables both a cross-section analysis to discuss differences

    within the European Union as well as an analysis over time of certain countries.

    Appendix A shortly summarises time-span for the data and how the data is measured

    for each variable.

    Regarding the analysis on equity-efficiency trade-off we consulted three

    datasets from the OECD; economic outlook, national accounts and the social

    expenditure database. Data on real GDP, output gap and public social expenditure was

    retrieved from these datasets. Locating information on the gini-coefficient proved to

    be a greater challenge, as there was no one single source available with a data

    collection covering a long time span. Through the World Institute for Development

    Economics Research (WIDER) we retrieved a dataset on the Gini-coefficient,

    composed from a range of sources. The main disadvantage such a dataset has, is the

    fact that the sources also employ different methodologies, making it hard to compare

    data. Although we have taken the greatest care in ensuring that the final data is as

    reliable and comparable as possible one has to remain cautious on the results.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    9/27

    Social Europe(s) 9

    4.EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

    4.1 Indicator outcome

    After gathering all necessary data from the sources as described in the

    previous section, the methodology can be carried out. The results of this are presented

    in Table 2 (appendix B presents the detailed tables per country and for the EU-15 as a

    whole).

    Sub-indicators

    System

    (final indicator

    average)

    Country Social Inclusion Inequality Poverty

    Final

    indicator

    Denmark 5.33 19.78 7.34 9.02Finland 8.58 22.18 7.14 10.73

    Nordic

    (9.40)Sweden

    25.16 20.89 5.50 8.44

    Austria 7.02 23.74 8.69 11.03

    Belgium 8.49 22.55 9.53 11.72

    France 7.42 23.44 10.41 11.82

    Germany 7.48 24.55 8.44 11.27

    Luxemburg 5.62 23.85 9.47 10.81

    Continental

    (11.02)

    NL 3.92 25.20 7.23 9.50

    Ireland 4.96 27.36 14.63 13.31Anglo-Saxon

    (12.94) UK 3.86 30.03 12.58 12.58

    Greece 3.80 27.88 15.46 13.28

    Italy 5.69 23.83 14.01 12.65

    Portugal 5.37 28.23 16.33 14.32

    Mediterranean

    (13.31)

    Spain 5.51 27.41 13.26 12.99

    EU-15 6.05 25.55 11.02 11.94

    Table 2

    The first observation to be made is that the Nordic system (the average of

    Denmark, Finland and Sweden) has the best final indicator. The second-best

    performer is the Continental model (also when Luxemburg is excluded), followed by

    the Anglo-Saxon model and the worst performance comes from the Mediterranean

    model.

    2We had to estimate the variables on self-perceived health and persistent at-risk of poverty rate for

    every period, since this data was missing. It is estimated between Danish and Finnish values for thefirst variable and about about half of the at-risk of poverty rate for the second variable (see Appendix B

    for data).

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    10/27

    Social Europe(s) 10

    These observations are in line with the expectations: a very equitable North

    and a less equitable South. It is worth paying attention to important factors that

    contribute to this indicator.

    The sub-indicator on social inclusion is the best for Greece (3.80) and worst

    for Finland (8.58). This is quite surprising, as the overall indicator has the reverse

    order. The value for social inclusion means that amongst European citizens, the

    Finnish feel most excluded from society. The suicide rate causes the high value on

    social inclusion for Finland it has the highest suicide rate within the EU-15.

    The distribution of social inclusion across different countries is mixed. Some

    Continental countries, for example, perform well on social inclusion, whilst others

    perform even worse than every single Mediterranean country. Apparently, the distinct

    ranking of the four systems comes from the indicator on inequality or poverty, or

    both.

    Inequality shows a picture that is more in line with the final indicator. The

    Nordic countries experience the lowest inequality; least inequality is experienced by

    Denmark, then Sweden and Finland. The Anglo-Saxon model does worst as a group.

    For poverty, the performance is exactly as the final indicator; the Scandinavian

    countries perform best, where the Mediterranean experience most poverty. A division

    can be made into two groups here; Nordic-Continental (average value of poverty-

    indicator: 7.8) and Anglo-Saxon-Mediterranean (14.2), since those rates lie relatively

    close to each other.

    Where social inclusion is rather spread across the sample, inequality and

    poverty both contribute to a pretty robust distinction between the models. Poverty

    distinguishes the Nordic and Continental countries from the Anglo-Saxon and

    Mediterranean ones. Inequality emphasises the difference between the Nordic and

    Continental system. The cause for Mediterranean underperformance compared to the

    Anglo-Saxon model is ascribed to worse performance on both social inclusion and

    poverty. It does better on inequality; assigning different weights to inequality could

    therefore change the picture. This investigative part is summarised in table 3.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    11/27

    Social Europe(s) 11

    Averages on sub-indicators

    SystemSocial inclusion Inequality Poverty

    Average onfinal indicator

    Nordic 6.36 20.95 6.66 9.40

    Continental 6.66 23.89 8.96 11.02

    Anglo-Saxon 4.41 28.69 13.60 12.94

    Mediterranean 5.09 26.83 14.76 13.31

    Table 3

    Not only does this analysis give evidence that social cohesion is rather diverse

    within the European Union, it also provides convincing evidence that it is plausible to

    divide Europe (in this respect) into four regions. The region where the Netherlands

    should be placed, is a controversial issue, as it scores satisfactory on social cohesion

    (

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    12/27

    Social Europe(s) 12

    y = -0,315x + 19,244

    R2 = 0,5374

    6,0

    7,0

    8,0

    9,0

    10,0

    11,0

    12,0

    13,014,0

    15,0

    15,0 20,0 25,0 30,0 35,0X

    Y

    Public social exp. vs. Social cohesion

    FIN

    SW

    A

    B F

    L

    NL

    IRL EL

    IT

    PT

    ES

    DK

    D

    UK

    6,0

    7,0

    8,0

    9,0

    10,0

    11,0

    12,0

    13,0

    14,0

    15,0

    14,0 19,0 24,0 29,0 34,0

    FIN

    SW

    A

    B

    F

    D

    L

    NL

    IRL

    UK

    EL

    IT

    PT

    ES

    DK

    Fig. 1: Public social expenditures and indicator performance

    Figure 2 depicts the regression line which seems to have a good fit. However,

    we observe several outliers, both below the regression line and above. These are all

    outliers in terms of level, not slope. The outliers below the regression line are (from

    top left to bottom right) Ireland, Luxemburg, the Netherlands, Denmark and Sweden.

    The largest outliers above the regression line are France, Greece, Italy and Portugal.

    Fig. 2: Regression line indicator performance on public expenditures

    Although more refined research would be needed to explain the position of

    these countries, we hypothesise that this could be due to characteristics of more

    dynamic labour markets in the high performing countries, whereas the less performing

    countries are generally known to have more rigid labour markets. One could argue

    that more social cohesion can be achieved with the same amount of expenditures by

    labour market reforms which would lead to an inward shift of the curve.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    13/27

    Social Europe(s) 13

    4.3 Equity and Efficiency

    Okun is generally credited for popularising the notion that an equity-efficiency

    trade-off exists, as such that when governments provide more income supports to its

    citizens economic efficiency suffers. Neubourg and Castonguay (2006) argue that

    such a trade-off exists only under specific assumptions. Indeed, they demonstrate that

    higher equity could both raise and decrease productivity.

    In this section we investigate whether there is evidence of an equity-efficiency

    trade-off within the countries. For the efficiency variable we use the real GDP per

    capita and for the equity variable we use the Gini-coefficient, which is generally

    recognised as the foremost indicator of equity. Table 4displays the results from

    regressing the change in real GDP per capita on the value of the Gini-coefficient. The

    choice of countries is solely due to limited data availability on the gini-coefficient.

    The time span varies across country with starting years between 1975 and 1985. They

    all run until 2004. We include a dummy for the years 1990-1993, as during this period

    most investigated countries experienced heavy recessions. The improved results

    indicate that this is warranted.

    Real GDP per capita (dependent variable)

    Country Gini-coefficient(independent variable)

    Dummy R-squared

    Sweden (Nordic)0.15

    (1.66)-3.94***(-5.00)

    0.52

    Germany (Continental)-0.74*(-2.04)

    -0.80(-1.32)

    0.36

    UK (Anglo-Saxon)0.13

    (1.30)-2.89***(-2.44)

    0.18

    US (Anglo-Saxon)0.18

    (1.08)-2.08*(-1.80)

    0.12

    Table 4: Significance level: * 10%, ** 5%, *** 1%.

    Although 3 out of 4 countries have a positive coefficient on the Gini value,

    indicating that an equity-trade off exists, none of them are significant. Germany in

    contrast is significant at the 10% level and indicates that more equity actually

    increases efficiency. These results prove to be nonconclusive.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    14/27

    Social Europe(s) 14

    Having found no clear-cut evidence on a equity-efficiency trade-off, we

    further investigate if one can find a relationship between change in public social

    expenditure (as percentage of GDP) and the change in real GDP per capita (table 5).

    We again include a dummy to control for the recession years during 1990-93. In this

    case, the data covers the time span from 1980-2000.

    Also these results prove to be non-significant, except for Ireland where the

    coefficient is significant at the 10% level. At best, we can conclude that more often

    than not the coefficients are positive, indicating that additional public social

    expenditures increase growth. However, as these results are conceptual insignificant

    one cannot draw strong inferences from it.

    Real GDP per capita (dependent variable)

    CountryChange in public social

    expenditure(independent variable)

    Dummy R-squared

    Denmark (Nordic)0.97

    (1.44)-0.83

    (-0.60)0.11

    Sweden (Nordic)0.16

    (0.36)-0.27

    (-0.20)0.01

    Germany (continental)0.81

    (1.22)-1.97*(-1.74)

    0.15

    France (continental) 0.54(1.53)

    -1.68**(-2.15)

    0.23

    UK (Anglo-Saxon)-0.05

    (-0.06)-0.43

    (-0.23)0.01

    Ireland (Anglo-Saxon)-0.75*(-1.93)

    -1.61(-1.21)

    0.28

    Italy (Mediterranean)1.01

    (1.45)-2.28*(-2.07)

    0.22

    Spain (Mediterranean)0.87

    (0.77)-3.05*(-1.79)

    0.17

    Table 5: Significance level: * 10%, ** 5%, *** 1%.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    15/27

    Social Europe(s) 15

    5.CONCLUSION

    This paper has evaluated the European welfare systems in two ways. The first

    was by following a weighting scheme as proposed by Efferink, Kool and Van Veen

    (2003). The second method was by performing an equity-efficiency analysis; is there

    a trade-off between these concepts?

    The first technique enables us to make cross-section comparisons based on

    averages for every country. This showed a superior performance for the Nordic

    system; the Mediterranean countries did worst. It further confirmed the general belief

    that there are indeed four different social models.

    After that, we tried to identify what the possible underlying cause is of the

    better performances of the Nordic countries, by analysing the cross country evidence

    on public social expenditures and indicator performances. We found that a higher

    level of public social expenditures generally leads to a better performance on social

    cohesion. This shows that social expenditure is done effectively.

    After finding support for additional expenditures, we tried to investigate

    whether additional expenditures have a negative effect on growth performance (the

    renowned equity-efficiency trade-off). To our regret, we did not find any evidence to

    be able to bring this debate to a close.

    From our analysis we find significant evidence that in order to enhance social

    cohesion in a country, higher public social spending could very well be the solution.

    However, we believe that the way this is spent matters as we observe that generally

    the countries with more dynamic labour markets achieve a better level of social

    cohesion with the same expenditure level. It is thus advisable to focus the

    expenditures on promoting dynamic labour market, e.g. by spending more on active

    labour market policies.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    16/27

    Social Europe(s) 16

    REFERENCES:

    Atkinson, A. (1999), The Economic Consequences of Rolling back the welfare state,

    CES, Centre for European Studies/The MIT Press, ch. 1-2.

    Bertola, G. (2006), Pensions: Overview of the issues, Oxford Review of Economic

    Policy, vol. 22(1), pp. 1-14

    Council of Europe (2005), Concerted development of social cohesion indicators:

    Methodological guide, Belgium, Council of Europe Publishing

    Efferink, L. van, Kool, C. and Veen, T. van. (2003), Country Risk Analysis, Series

    Financial and Monetary Studies, 21, 4.

    European Commission (2001).Draft Joint Report on Social Inclusion.

    Communication from the Commission, 565 final.

    Giddens, A. (2007).Europe in the global age, Polity Press, Cambridge.

    Golding, P. (1995). Public attitudes to social exclusion: Some problems of

    measurement and analysis. In G. Room (ed.),Beyond the threshold, p. 212-232.Bristol: The Policy Press.

    Neubourg, Chris de and Castonguay, Julie, (2006) Enhancing Productivity: Social

    protection as Investment policy in W. Mitchell, J. Muysken and T. van Veen (ed.),

    Growth and Cohesion in the European Union, Edward Elgar

    OHara, Philip (2006). Social Inclusion Health Indicators: A Framework for

    Addressing the Social Determinants of Health. [online] retrieved 15 May 2007

    http://inclusivecities.ca/publication/reports/2006/edmonton-report.pdf

    Rahman, M., Palmer, G., Kenway, P. and Howarth, C. (2000). Monitoring povertyand social exclusion [online] retrieved 20 May 2007http://jrf.org.uk/bookshop/eBooks/1859351298.pdf

    Sapir, A. (2005). Globalisation and the Reform of European Social Models, BruegelPaper, Bruegel, Brussels, 2005

    The Roeher Institute (2003),Policy Approaches to Framing Social InclusionExclusion: An Overview. Toronto, ON: The Roeher Institute

    http://inclusivecities.ca/publication/reports/2006/edmonton-report.pdfhttp://jrf.org.uk/bookshop/eBooks/1859351298.pdfhttp://jrf.org.uk/bookshop/eBooks/1859351298.pdfhttp://inclusivecities.ca/publication/reports/2006/edmonton-report.pdf
  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    17/27

    Social

    Europe(s)

    17

    APPEN

    DIX

    A

    Thefo

    llowingtablegivesforeachva

    riableuseditstime-span,descr

    iptionandsourse

    Variable

    Time

    span

    Description

    Source

    Long-term

    unemployment

    [%]

    1995-

    2006

    L

    ong-termunemployed(12monthsandmore)personsarethoseagedatleast15yearsnot

    livingincollectivehouseholdswho

    arewithoutworkwithinthenext

    twoweeks,areavailable

    tostartworkwithinthenexttwo

    weeksandwhoareseekingwo

    rk(haveactivelysought

    e

    mploymentatsometimeduringthepreviousfourweeksorareno

    tseekingajobbecause

    theyhavealreadyfoundajobtos

    tartlater).

    Thetotalactivepopula

    tion(labourforce)isthe

    totalnumberoftheemployedand

    unemployedpopulation.

    Thedurationofunemploymentis

    d

    efinedasthedurationofasearchforajoborasthelengthofthe

    periodsincethelastjob

    w

    asheld(ifthisperiodisshorterth

    anthedurationofthesearchfora

    job).

    EUR

    OSTAT

    VeryLong-term

    unemployment

    [%]

    1995-

    2006

    V

    erylong-term

    unemploymentratesrepresentverylong-term

    unemployedpersonsasa

    p

    ercentageofthelabourforce.Ve

    rylong-termunemployed(24mo

    nthsandmore)persons

    a

    rethoseagedatleast15years

    notlivingincollectivehousehold

    swhoarewithoutwork

    w

    ithinthenexttwoweeks,areava

    ilabletostartworkwithinthenexttwoweeksandwhoare

    seekingwork(haveactivelysoughtemploymentatsometimeduring

    thepreviousfourweeks

    o

    rarenotseekingajobbecausetheyhavealreadyfoundajobtost

    artlater).

    Thedurationof

    u

    nemploymentisdefinedasthedurationofasearchforajoboras

    thelengthoftheperiod

    sincethelastjobwasheld(ifthisperiodisshorterthantheduration

    ofthesearchforajob).

    T

    he

    totalactive

    population

    (labourforce)isthe

    totalnumber

    ofthe

    employed

    and

    u

    nemployedpopulation.

    EUR

    OSTAT

    Suiciderate

    [/100,0

    00]

    1995-

    2005

    N

    umberofpeoplediedbysuicide

    EUR

    OSTAT

    Self-perceived

    health(bad)

    [%]

    1996-

    2001

    S

    elfperceivedhealthbysex,age,educationandactivitystatus(Source:ECHP

    UDB,

    E

    urostat,06/2003)

    EUR

    OSTAT

    Self-perceived

    health

    (verybad)

    1996-

    2001

    S

    elfperceivedhealthbysex,age,educationandactivitystatus(Source:ECHP

    UDB,

    E

    urostat,06/2003)

    EUR

    OSTAT

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    18/27

    Social

    Europe(s)

    18

    [%]

    Ginicoefficient

    1995-

    2005

    T

    easurestheinequalityofdistributionofincome.

    Thevaluelaysbe

    tween0and1,where0

    correspondstoperfectincomeequ

    alityand1toperfectincomeinequality.

    W

    IDER

    Genderpaygap

    [%]

    1994-

    2005

    D

    ifferencebetweenmen'sandwo

    men'saveragegrosshourlyearn

    ingsasapercentageof

    m

    en'saveragegrosshourlyearningsGenderpaygapisgivenas

    thedifferencebetween

    a

    veragegrosshourlyearningsofmalepaidemployeesandoffemalepaidemployeesasa

    p

    ercentageofaveragegrosshourlyearningsofmalepaidemployees.

    Thepopulation

    consistsofallpaidemployeesaged16-64thatare'atwork15+hoursperweek'.

    EUR

    OSTAT

    At-riskofpoverty

    rate

    [%]

    1995-

    2005

    T

    heshareofpersonswithane

    quivaliseddisposableincomeb

    elow

    therisk-of-poverty

    threshold,whichissetat60%of

    thenationalmedianequivaliseddisposableincome(after

    socialtransfers

    EUR

    OSTAT

    Persistentat-riskof

    povertyrate

    [%]

    1995-

    2005

    T

    heshareofpersonswithane

    quivaliseddisposableincomeb

    elow

    therisk-of-poverty

    thresholdinthecurrentyearandin

    atleasttwooftheprecedingthre

    eyears.

    Thethresholdis

    setat60%ofthenationalmedian

    equivaliseddisposableincome.

    EUR

    OSTAT

    Publicsocial

    expenditures

    1980-

    2000

    S

    ocialexpenditure

    isthe

    provis

    ion

    bypublicinstitutionsofbe

    nefitsto,andfinancial

    contributionstargetedat,householdsandindividualsinorderto

    providesupportduring

    circumstanceswhichadverselyaffecttheirwelfare,providedthatthe

    provisionofthebenefits

    a

    ndfinancialcontributionsconstitutesneitheradirectpaymentforaparticulargoodor

    servicenoranindividualcontracto

    rtransfer.Suchbenefitscanbecashtransfers,orcanbe

    thedirect(in-kind)provisionofgo

    odsandservices.

    OEC

    DSocial

    Exp

    enditure

    Da

    tabase

    Changeinreal

    GDPpercapita

    1971-

    2000

    OECD

    National

    Ac

    counts

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    19/27

    Social

    Europe(s)

    19

    APPEN

    DIX

    B

    Rawd

    ataforeachvariablepersub-in

    dicator(socialinclusion,

    inequalityandpovertyrespectively)

    .

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    20/27

    Social

    Europe(s)

    20

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    21/27

    Social

    Europe(s)

    21

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    22/27

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    23/27

    Social

    Europe(s)

    23

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    24/27

    Social Europe(s) 24

    APPENDIX C

    Values for partial (sub-indicator) and final indicators for each individual country, grouped by social system (Nordic, Contintal, Mediterranean and Anglo-Saxon

    respectively); last table represents the aggregate EU-15 data.

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    25/27

    Social Europe(s) 25

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    26/27

    Social Europe(s) 26

  • 8/6/2019 Social Cohesion Paper

    27/27