shih adolph liu published 12

Upload: mprob

Post on 05-Apr-2018

235 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

  • 8/2/2019 Shih Adolph Liu Published 12

    1/22

    American Political Science Review Vol. 106, No. 1 February 2012

    doi:10.1017/S0003055411000566

    Getting Ahead in the Communist Party: Explaining theAdvancement of Central Committee Members in ChinaVICTOR SHIH Northwestern UniversityCHRISTOPHER ADOLPH University of WashingtonMINGXING LIU Peking University

    Spectacular economic growth in China suggests the ruling Chinese Communist Party (CCP) hassomehow gotten it right. A key hypothesis in both economics and political science is that the CCPscadre evaluation system, combined with Chinas geography-based governing logic, has motivated

    local administrators to compete with one another to generate high growth. We raise a number of theo-retical and empirical challenges to this claim. Using a new biographical database of Central Committeemembers, a previously overlooked feature of CCP reporting, and a novel Bayesian method that canestimate individual-level correlates of partially observed ranks, we find no evidence that strong growthperformance was rewarded with higher party ranks at any of the postreform party congresses. Instead,factional ties with various top leaders, educational qualifications, and provincial revenue collection playedsubstantial roles in elite ranking, suggesting that promotion systems served the immediate needs of theregime and its leaders, rather than encompassing goals such as economic growth.

    Ever since Weber ([1921] 1958) distinguishedrational bureaucracy staffed by impersonal,meritocratically selected technocrats from pa-

    triarchical management by loyal partisans, scholarshave explored the underlying logics driving govern-ment organizations. Today Webers distinction mat-ters nowhere more than in China, where an author-itarian regime governs nearly a fifth of the worldspeople. Thirty years of spectacular economic perfor-mance has prompted a sizable political science andeconomics literature linking the bureaucracy of theChinese Communist Party (CCP) to Chinas economicsuccess. Though the link seems natural, there aregood theoretical and empirical reasons to question

    whether yardstick competition among local officials re-ally caused Chinas spectacular growth. Theoretically,a performance-based promotion system in the top ech-elon of the party requires a relatively unified and far-horizoned leadership that would systematically pro-mote officials with the strongest performance (Olson1993; Olson and McGuire 1996). Yet theories of au-thoritarian politics and China scholarship suggest thatthe top leadershipin China is as much preoccupied withinternal struggle as with achieving regime-wide objec-tives like economic growth (Bueno de Mesquita et al.

    Victor Shih is Associate Professor, Department of Political Science,

    Northwestern University, 601 University Place, Evanston, IL 60208([email protected]).

    Christopher Adolph is Assistant Professor, Department of Politi-cal Science and Center for Statistics and the Social Sciences, Univer-sity of Washington, 101 Gowen Hall, Box 353530, Seattle, WA 98195([email protected]).

    Mingxing Liu is Associate Professor, China Institute for Educa-tional Finance Research, Peking University, Beijing 100871, China([email protected])

    The authors are grateful for helpful comments and advice fromDali Yang, Dingxing Zhao, and other members of the Universityof Chicago East Asia Colloquium, as well as Jennifer Amyx, San-tiago Lopez Cariboni, Frances Rosenbluth, and Susan Whiting.All mistakes are our own. Replication data and R packages foranalysis (partialrank) and visualization (tile) are available at fac-ulty.washington.edu/cadolph

    2003; MacFarquhar and Schoenhals 2006; Nathan 1973;Svolik 2009; Tullock 1987). As such, it is far from clearthat CCP cadre management institutions were directlyresponsible for Chinas economic performance.

    Empirical work on the growth incentive embeddedin CCP institutions shows cases where cadre evaluationappeared to encourage strong performance by countyand township level officials (Edin 2003; Whiting 2004).Yet systematic tests of whether provincial administra-tors in high-growth regions were awarded with pro-motions look only at provincial officials, instead ofthe Central Committee power elite in the CCP, andmeasure only promotion in state bureaucratic ranksinstead of the more important party ranking (Chen,

    Li, and Zhou 2005; Li and Zhou 2005; Maskin, Qian,and Xu 2000). And no qualitative or quantitative workaddresses the potential selection bias that would ariseif politically connected officials could influence the lo-cation of their next appointments to claim credit forpreexisting growth trends.

    This study departs from previous studies in five im-portant ways.First, instead of providing yetanother testof the growth impact of CCP institutions, we draw fromthe broader political economy literature on authori-tarian regimes to derive a wider range of hypotheseson the factors that help cadres obtain higher positionsin the party hierarchy. Second, instead of examiningonly the fortune of local administrators, we examine

    every full and alternate member of the CCP CentralCommittee through five party congresses from 1982 to2002. Third, we make use of the CCPs own reports ofelections to the Alternate Central Committee (ACC)and a new biographical database of Central Committee(CC) and ACC members to place the entire CCP powerelite along a continuum in terms of their status withinthe ruling party. Fourth, we analyze the pattern of rankswithin the Politburo Standing Committee (PSC), thePolitburo, the CC, and the ACC using a novel Bayesianmodel of ranks that can estimate the individual-levelcorrelates of rank even in rank data that are onlypartially observed. Finally, we purge the effects of

    166

  • 8/2/2019 Shih Adolph Liu Published 12

    2/22

    American Political Science Review Vol. 106, No. 1

    any selection bias in appointment using a suite of es-timates of preappointment expected provincial eco-nomic growth. In this manner, we are able to discernwhether expected and unexpected economic perfor-mance had any impact on the party ranking of seniorcadres throughout the reform period.

    When we examine the entire CCP elite, we findno evidence that exceptional economic growth influ-

    enced ranking in the party hierarchy. This finding isrobust even when we decompose economic perfor-mance into expected and unexpected growth and whenwe use broader measures of economic performance.We find that educational qualifications strongly (andprovincial revenue collection and minority represen-tation weakly) bolstered cadres ranking in some ofthe party congresses since 1982. Women faced signif-icant disadvantages in three of the five congresses weexamine. Most important, factional ties with varioustop leaders, as well as princeling status, boosted thechance of climbing higher in the CCP upper echelonsthrough much of the reform period. In sum, CCP cadremanagement institutions were used by top leaders to

    maintain cadres human capital, coopt ethnic minori-ties, and raise revenue collection, all of which directlyprovided immediatepayoffs to the regime. Our findingssuggest that senior party leaders did not bolster publicgoods provision through yardstick competiton amongprovincial officials, but they did use promotion institu-tions to cultivate factions. These findings are consistentwith the claim of Bueno de Mesquita et al. (2003) thatauthoritarian regimes tend to deliver private goods toa relatively narrow winning coalition rather than tosociety at large.

    MERITOCRATIC BUREAUCRACY ANDECONOMIC OUTCOMES

    Since Weber made the distinction between bureau-cracy and patrimonialism, political scientists have ar-gued that government bureaucracies fall into eitherthe meritocratic, impersonal type or the corrupt, clien-telist type (Evans 1995; Frye and Shleifer 1997; Schnei-der 1993; Weber [1921] 1958). Explanations for whybureaucracies develop in disparate ways range fromsocial capital (Putnam, Leonardi, and Nanetti 1993),to the level of external threat (Kang 2002), to coloniallegacies (Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2000). Inturn, bureaucratic types are thought to explain com-

    plex economic outcomes. Thus, when market enhanc-ing policies are implemented or when growth is high,some scholars attribute this to a meritocratic bureau-cracy (Evans 1995; Schneider and Maxfield 1997).

    In contemporary social science, the tendency to inferbureaucratic meritocracy from high growth is perhapsstrongest in the study of China. Spectacular growthin the past three decades has motivated scholars todevelop a variety of explanations of Chinas success,ranging from a proreform leadership (Fewsmith 1994;Shirk 1993), to de facto federalism (Qian, Weingast,and Montinola 1995), to labor market mobility (Lin1992; Sachs et al. 1994).

    Scholars have also looked to the efficiency or theinstitutional configuration of the Chinese bureaucracyas explanations of Chinas rapid growth. Unlike theSoviet Union, which had a unitary system of gover-nance, the primary organizational principle in Chinawas geography-based, thus giving rise to a multidi-visional form (M-form) bureaucracy. Some claim theM-form bureaucracy, coupled with an extensive cadre

    evaluation system, provided strong incentives for re-gional administrators to compete with each other togenerate high economic growth, in order to win pro-motion in the ruling CCP (Chen, Li, and Zhou 2005; Liand Zhou 2005; Maskin, Qian, and Xu 2000). This bodyof literature presents mixed evidence that the top twoprovincial officials (governors and party secretaries) inthe reform period were typically rewarded with promo-tions for realizing better economic performance thantheir predecessors or their peers (Chen, Li, and Zhou2005; Li and Zhou 2005; Tao et al. 2010).

    In addition to the quantitative findings, a larger qual-itative literature on the evolution of the cadre eval-uation system also seems to support the view of a

    performance-based elite promotion system in China.After the founding of the Peoples Republic of China,the CCP introduced formal methods of evaluatingcadres, which were formally linked to their promotion.As Burns (1989) puts it, the cadre management sys-tem centered on lists of leading positions, over whichparty units exercise the power to make appointmentsand dismissals; lists of reserves or candidates for thesepositions; and institutions and processes for making theappropriate personnel changes. The Central Organi-zation Department emerged as the keyhuman resourcemanager of the CCP, although senior-level promotionswere ultimately decided by members of the Politburo

    (Nathan and Gilley 2002).During his reign, Mao focused on ensuring the sur-vival of the CCP regime according to his vision. Thus,he promoted cadres who shared or at least were will-ing to go along with his radical vision of society (Lee1991). After reform began in 1978, education creden-tials came to play a prominent role in the advancementof lower level cadres, and older cadres were stronglyencouraged to retire (Cui 2003; Landry 2008; Manion1993; Walder, Li, and Treiman 2000). Furthermore, thepost-Mao leadership formalized a system of scoring

    junior and senior cadres, which served to keep track oftheir administrative performance on a series of softand hard targets. Hard targets reflected core tasks

    crucial to the regime, including economic growth, fis-cal collection, and maintaining stability, whereas softtargets included recruiting party members and propa-ganda work. Shortfalls on the soft targets could beoutweighed by impressive performance in key areas.However, failing to fulfill hard targets led either tolow overall scores or to mandatory administrative pun-ishment (yipiao foujue), a powerful tool in the CCPsarsenal for political control (Edin 2003). The existenceof a comprehensive system for scoring officials on theirpolicy performance seems to suggest that the Chineseelite was motivated by the scoring system to performwell (Edin 2003; Landry 2008; Whiting 2004).

    167

  • 8/2/2019 Shih Adolph Liu Published 12

    3/22

    Advancement of Central Committee Members in China February 2012

    However, on both theoretical and empirical grounds,there are strong reasons to be skeptical of an easy link-age between a formal system of cadre evaluation andeconomic growth in China. Theoretically, linking a lim-ited set of policy or economic outcomes with bureau-cratic characteristics may result in a false causal infer-ence. For one thing, bureaucratic characteristics tendto be time-invariant, whereas policy and growth out-

    comes change frequently over time. Moreover, seem-ingly reform policies can mask underlying corruptionor inefficiencies. In Pinochets Chile, for example, liber-alization policies implemented by the Chicago Boysalso allowed favored conglomerates to borrow heavilyoverseas to buy up prized financial assets, laying thegroundwork for the financial crisis in the early 1980s(Haggard and Maxfield 1996; Silva 1996). The empiri-cal findings on corruption also cast doubt on the link-age between bureaucratic characteristics and economicoutcomes. Except in extreme cases, high growth gener-ally is not harmed by a moderate degree of corruption(Svensson 2005).

    Although meritocratic criteria may influence elite

    ranking in China, concluding that economic perfor-mance is the dominant criterion driving elite rankinggoes too far. A merit or performance dominant bureau-cracy assumes that the Chinese regime is unified andfar-horizoned, and thus is motivated to maximize per-formance and long-term output (Olson and McGuire1996). But leaders of nondemocratic regimes face con-stant threats of dethronement from mass uprisingsor coups by regime insiders (Tullock 1987; Wintrobe1998). Thus, autocratic rulers likely place a greaterpriority on maintaining short-term state capacity andbuying the support of winning coalitions than on pro-viding broadly encompassing goods such as economic

    growth (Bueno de Mesquita et al. 2003; Gandhi andPrzeworski 2006). China has witnessed its share oflarge-scale uprisings and intense political struggle atthe top. Even after the chaoticCultural Revolution, thetop leader of the CCP was twice removed from powerby irregular means.1 Besides the Tiananmen protestsin 1989, China also dealt with a series of large-scaleprotests motivated by ethnic and economic grievancesin recent years (Pei 2006). Huang (1996) and Sheng(2007) argue that the conflict of interest between cen-tral and local governments compels the center to useits appointment control to obtain preferred outcomes,thus implicitly forgoing the appointment of the mostcapable officials. Because top Chinese leaders must ad-

    dress urgent concerns of stability and retaining officeon a daily basis, we expect that the CCP often usesthe personnel management system to promote theseimmediate goals, while neglecting more encompassingobjectives like growth or fairness.

    If political survival is a main concern, the top leaderof a regime may shape policies, including the appoint-ment of subordinates, to serve that end. One elitefaction may pursue policies purely to undermine a

    1 Forexample, partysecretaryHu Yaobang was removed frompowerat the infamous party life meeting at Deng Xiaopings house inearly 1987. See Deng (2005).

    rival faction, thus riskingoverall regime stability (Ram-seyer and Rosenbluth 1998). Instead of expending re-sources to prevent a general uprising, leaders seek-ing to thwart an elite challenger may devote thoseresources to monitoring or cultivating the loyalty ofsenior officials (Svolik 2005). And instead of promot-ing officials with the strongest performance record,rival leaders may promote untalented but loyal fol-

    lowers to prevent a coup or to raise their relativestanding (Easter 1996; Egorov and Sonin 2011; Nathan1973). In other cases, an insecure leader may shuffleor promote officials simply to prevent an alliance be-tween ambitious local officials and the populace (Debs2007).

    Empirically, the literature linkingChinas cadre eval-uation system and growth produces highly ambiguousand problematic results. First, the qualitative literatureprovides an in-depth description of the cadre evalua-tion system, which suggests a causal link between cadreevaluation and growth. However, the existence of anevaluation system as such does not prove a causal link.Furthermore, quantitative studies of city and county

    officials do not find much evidence for growth-basedpromotions (Guo 2007; Landry 2008). At the city level,for example, Landry (2008) finds that exceptional eco-nomic performance has almost no effect on the mostlikely internal promotion of mayors, to the position ofparty secretary.

    Quantitative studies on provincial officials providesome evidence that exceptional economic growth in aprovince is correlated with the promotion of the toptwo officials in a province (Chen, Li, and Zhou 2005;Li and Zhou 2005; Maskin, Qian, and Xu 2000). Thesestudies present a number of empirical shortcomings,however. First, they focus only on provincial officials,

    leaving out the majority of the party elite, who servedin the central party apparatus, the army, and the cen-tral economic bureaucracy. A comprehensive analysisof elite incentive should include all full and alternatemembers of the CC, who make up the bulk of the powerelite in the CCP (Kung and Chen 2011; Shirk 1993).Measures of promotion are often poor: Li and Zhou(2005) define promotion as movement to a ministerialposition or higher, but in the state bureaucracy, move-ment from provincial governorship to a ministerial po-sition is horizontal, as provinces and ministries havethe same bureaucratic rank. To measure whether sucha rotation constituted a promotion, it is more useful tosee whether a persons party rank improved, a clearer

    sign of advancement.Methodologically, no previous study of elite promo-

    tion has taken into account the potential for selectionbias (Chen, Li, and Zhou 2005; Guo 2007; Landry 2008;Li and Zhou 2005; Maskin, Qian, and Xu 2000). Aspir-ing provincial governors and party secretaries may per-ceive certain provinces as strong economic performersprior to a rotation, and may use political connectionsto engineer their appointments to claim credit. Understrategic appointment, observed correlation betweenexceptional growth and advancement might have beencaused by strong political connections, rather than byeconomic performance per se.

    168

  • 8/2/2019 Shih Adolph Liu Published 12

    4/22

    American Political Science Review Vol. 106, No. 1

    HYPOTHESES

    There are good theoretical and empirical reasons todoubt whether economic performance was the domi-nant factor driving elite advancement, despite Chinasgeography-based administrative system and elaboratecadre evaluation system. Instead of only testing theimpact of economic performance on elite ranking, wedraw on the political economy literature on authori-tarianism to derive two different sets of hypotheses.If we assumed that China was a unified regime witha long time horizon, we would expect performance,merit, and representation to play the dominant role inelite ranking. However, theories of elite power strugglein authoritarian regimes suggest that factional affilia-tion and princeling ties may play an important role inCCP elite ranking.

    If the top leadership in China were unified and hada long time-horizon, it would have had a sufficientlyencompassinginterest in generating long-term growthand in developing tax collection capacity in an op-timal way (Olson and McGuire 1996). Furthermore,

    to prevent large-scale collective action threatening theregime, a unified Chinese leadership would have com-bined repression with limited redistribution of its re-sources or greater representation for certain groups(Acemoglu and Robinson 2006; Desai, Olofsgard, andYousef 2009; Gandhi and Przeworski 2006; Olson andMcGuire 1996; Wintrobe 1998). To accomplish theseends, a unified CCP regime would have promotedofficials with a talent for generating growth, collect-ing taxes, and repressing dissent so that no matterhow strong a candidates factional backing, he can-not be promoted without a record of administrativeachievement (Nathan and Gilley 2002). From this un-derstanding of elite ranking in China, we derive thefollowing hypotheses:

    Hypothesis R1. More educated cadres winhigher rank thanless educated cadres.

    Hypothesis R2. Regional administrators who generatemore economic growth or raise living standards are re-warded with high ranking in the Central Committee.

    Hypothesis R3. Regional administrators who producehigher growth in fiscal revenue win higher rank.

    Hypothesis R4. Officials with more experience in the CCPgain higher rank because they have accumulated more ad-ministrative experience.

    Finally, ensuring female and minority representa-tion in the higher reaches of the party may en-hance the regimes legitimacy. Furthermore, minor-ity representation may enhance stability by coopt-ing potentially restive minority groups into the sys-tem (Dreyer 1976, 113). Thus a unified authoritar-ian regime might systematically promote women andminorities.

    Hypothesis R5. Being female or a member of an ethnicminority confers an advantage in the competition for highrank.

    If a regime experiences concealed or overt powerstruggles at the top, faction-based promotion predom-inates. In factional politics, loyalty counts more thanskills or performance on core tasks such as growth,revenue collection, and stability. Skills may even be aliability. Egorov and Sonin (2005) provide a convincingtheoretical argument that dictators facing the threat ofa coup will not always choose the most competent ad-

    visors: Clever subordinates may be too good at figuringout the expected payoffs of betraying the dictator; lesscapable officials are more loyal. Bueno de Mesquitaet al. (2003) also argue that autocrats find ways tochannel resources to their supporters, including pro-moting them to senior regime positions. In a similarvein, China scholars long have postulated that Chineseleaders built networks of loyal followers to mitigatethe fundamental uncertainty in elite politics (Dittmer1995; Nathan 1973; Pye 1980, 1992). These factionalnetworks bound the interests of followers to their pa-trons through the distribution of economic resourcesand offices (Nathan 1973; Nathan and Tsai 1995; Shih2008a).

    When a factional patron comes under attack, follow-ers remain loyal because they expect large payoffs forprotecting the patron, who in turn promotes followersto the upper echelons of the regime. If elite politicalstruggles loomed large in the minds of top CCP lead-ers, then followers records of loyalty would have beenmore important criteria for promotion than economicperformance. When the factional logic dominates, indi-vidual leaders promote close allies rather than the mostcapable individuals, even if these appointments lead tothe underprovision of regime-wide public goods suchas economic growth. In this case, ambitious officialsface incentives to signal their loyalty to factional pa-

    trons, instead of performing tasks for the regime (Shih2008b). However, even when confronted with intenseelite struggle, authoritarian leaders may still prioritizetaxcollection capacity, to financeboth private goods forregime supporters and the regimes repressive capacity(Acemoglu and Robinson 2006; Bueno de Mesquitaet al. 2003).

    The main implication of the factional view of Chinesepolitics is the following factional hypothesis:

    Hypothesis F1. Followers of the top leaders of the party,including the faction members of Mao Zedong, Deng Xi-aoping, Zhao Ziyang, Hu Yaobang, Jiang Zemin, and Hu

    Jintao, are ranked higher than other officials when their

    respective patrons are in power.

    In testing this hypothesis, we consider only the fol-lowers of the de facto or de jure leaders of the partybecause as the most powerful leaders, they had thestrongest incentive to avoid factional politics and toensure high regime performance. Thus, if factional pol-itics was not pervasive, we wouldnot expect thehighestofficials in the regime to rank CC members accordingto factional considerations.

    A related hypothesis concerns the children of se-nior officials, or princelings, who entered the CCPelite. Although their parents were never their direct

    169

  • 8/2/2019 Shih Adolph Liu Published 12

    5/22

    Advancement of Central Committee Members in China February 2012

    superiors, other senior officials might expect to winsome advantagefrom the families of princelings by pro-moting them. But helping princelings does not makesense in the context of a unified leadership, becauseprinceling status per se does not help further regimegoals. To the extent that CCP elites were divided andwere tempted to draw on princeling resources, we ex-pect the following.

    Hypothesis F2. Children of senior officials should beranked higher than other officials.

    DATA

    We test our hypotheses on data measuring elite rankswithin the CCP. Our dependent variable is the rankordering of officials in theupper echelon of the ChineseCommunist Party, for the 12th through 16th Party Con-gresses (19822007), a difficult quantity to measure.This (still imperfect) metric of pecking order improveson existing measures, which limit analysis to provincialofficials. In this section we outline what we do know

    about these ranks; in the next, we explain how to useranks we know well to infer ranks we observe impre-cisely, a useful strategy for exploring the distributionof political power in authoritarian regimes.

    The ranking of CCP elites in the CC took placeroughly once every five years at the National PartyCongress. Formally, this ranking comprised three dif-ferent processes, but fundamentally, all three steps re-flect a single ranking highly coordinated by the PSC.Starting at the 12th Party Congress in 1982, delegatesreceived ballots with more names than there were seatsin the Central Committee. Delegates then voted for thecandidates by placing checks next to their names, and

    delegates could check as many names as there wereseats in the Central Committee. Candidates were ac-cepted into the CC in the order of their vote totals,with the lowest-vote receipients eliminated (Organi-zational Division of the Central Organization Depart-ment 2001). Alternate members of the CC were alsoelected in this way. The elected CC then voted thePolitburo, the PSC, and the party secretary generalinto office. In this final round of voting, there were asmany candidates as there were seats, and CC memberswithout exception voted everyone on the ballot intooffce.

    Although congressional delegates ostensibly votedfreely, all the party congresses were tightly monitored

    and controlled by the party secretary general and mem-bers of the Politburo. To begin, the chairman or theparty secretary general sent early signals to the restof the political elite on who should or should not beon the list of CC candidates (Li 2007). As the con-gresses approached, candidates for the CC, the ACC,and the Politburo were chosen by leadership groups,which included the serving PSC and a few powerful re-tired cadres handpicked by the party secretary general(Organizational Division of the Central OrganizationDepartment 2001).

    The selected candidates then underwent a vettingprocedure carried out by the Central Organization

    Department, which also took instructions from theparty secretary general and other members of the Polit-buro (Cui 2003; Nathan and Gilley 2002). When thedelegates finally arrived in Beijing to vote, they wereisolated from each other and received strict voting in-structions from the party secretary general and othermembers of the Politburo on how to vote (Deng 2005;Li 2007). In thefamous case of Deng Liquns surprising

    elimination from the 13th CC, it turns out that theparty secretary general at the time, Zhao Ziyang, sentcadres to the provinces prior to the congress to instructdelegates not to vote for him (Deng 2005).

    Because of extensive intervention from PSC mem-bers, where one landed on the party pecking orderlargely reflected the priorities of the top leadership,which could change dramatically over time. Periodicappearance of helicopters, or officials who obtainedrapid promotion from the ACC to the Politburo, fur-ther suggests that elite ranking at the Party Congresswas a single exercise of elite reshuffling closely guidedby the party secretary general and the Politburo, ratherthan three autonomous processes. At the end of a

    congress,highlyranked officials typically enjoyed muchmore formal and informal power for the subsequentfive years, whereas those who were not selected evenas ACC members missed being in the power center ofthe CCP (Kung and Chen 2011).

    We note that there is broad agreement on a set oftiers, with the PSC and the Politburo at the top, fol-lowed by the full members of the CC, and then thealternate members of the CC (Kung and Chen 2011;Lieberthal 2004). In particular, we treat as top-rankedthe party secretary general (who sets the agenda in thePSC) and the chairman of the Central Military Com-mission (CMC), who were usually the same person.

    Next came the members of the PSC, who voted onevery major issue confronting the regimeand whoserelative political status was implied by the order oftheir names in publicannouncements.2 Following in de-scending order of political power are the vice chairmenand members of the CMC (who controlled large seg-ments of the armed forces), the Politburo (composedof regional party secretaries of major provinces, severalvice premiers of the State Council, and senior militaryleaders), and a handful of alternate members of thePolitburo. Next come the vast majority of the CentralCommittee who were not members of the higher partyorgans, whose members individual ranks were not pre-cisely known, beyond the general importance of these

    tiers.Finally, a key to our ranking strategy lies at the bot-

    tom of this hierarchy. Beneath full members of theCC lie the ACC members, who failed to win electionto higher tiers at the party congress; for example, ACCmembers tended to be provincial governors rather thanthe more powerful regional party secretaries. Startingwith the Eighth Party Congress, the official press an-nounced ACC members in the order of votes received

    2 For example, at the August 1966 11th Plenum, Liu Shaoqi fell fromnumber 2 in the PSC to the last position in the PSC in the PeoplesDaily. See MacFarquhar and Schoenhals (2006).

    170

  • 8/2/2019 Shih Adolph Liu Published 12

    6/22

    American Political Science Review Vol. 106, No. 1

    from delegates (the vote totals themselves remainedsecret). Because detailed instructions were given todelegates when they voted on the ACC slate, the votesreceived by ACC members should reflect the prioritiesof the top leadership in ranking cadres. This underex-ploited data on a large body of individuals contains awealth of information about the factors influencing theranking of all top officials. We will show in the next

    section how these data help us impute ranks for theentire hierarchy.We combine our rank data with covariates measur-

    ing the characteristics of the members of the ACC,the CC, the Politburo, and the PSC. Most of thesevariables are drawn from a new biographical data setof Central Committee members developed by Shih,Shan, and Liu (2008). This database contains all CCand ACC members from thefirst party congress in 1921to the sixteenth party congress in 2002, and follows thestructure for political biographical data developed byAdolph (n.d.) in his work on the career trajectories ofcentral bankers. Shih, Shan, and Liu collect and recordnearly every state, party, and military position held by

    CC members throughout their careers, rather than justpositions held by CC members at the time they servedin the CC. Using start and end years for each posi-tion held, they reconstruct complete career historiesfor each member of the ACC, the CC, the Politburo,and the PSC as they stood at the start of each partycongress.3 They also collect demographic variables in-cluding birth year, gender, year of induction into theparty, education, ethnicity, and princeling status.

    These biographical data allow us to test whether ed-ucation, performance, or factional affiliations are re-sponsible for party rank. Basic demographic informa-tion captures merit criteria such as level of education,

    as well as representation criteria such as gender andminority status. We assume that factional ties occurbetween officials and leaders with shared birthplaces,as well as officials and leaders who overlapped in edu-cational institutions or work units (Lieberthal and Ok-senberg 1988, 156).4 If any such coincidence occur be-tween a CC or ACC member and a top leader, we codethat member as having a factional tie to that leader.

    We also combine the CC database with provincialeconomic data to calculate the relative economic per-formance of provincial administrators (governors andparty secretaries) who were also CC or ACC members(China Data Online 2005). In the five party congressesunder consideration, provincial administrators made

    up between 14 and 20% of all CC members. We con-sider the fraction of provincial CC members to be both

    3 To accurately capture CC members careers, Shih, Shan, and Liu(2008) assign a four-digit number to each position in the CCP bu-reaucracyfrom 1949to 2002. The first three digitsdenote thepoliticalorgan to which this position belongs, and the last digit represents thelevel ofthe position.Thescore3021,for example, breaksdownto 302,which stands for the General Political Department of the PeoplesLiberation Army (PLA), and the final digit, 1, which denotes thehighest level in that department, the Department Chief.4 For overlapping work experience, we identify an official as beingin a leaders faction if the official worked in the same work unit asthe leader for over a year, and was within two administrative stepsof him.

    large from a substantive point of view, and sufficientto estimate whether provincial economic performancewas rewarded with party advancement. Although weare only able to test the economic performance hy-pothesis on the provincial administrators in the pool,Maskin, Qian, and Xu (2000) argue that Chinas suc-cess hinged on competition among provincial admin-istrators, whose economic performance could be more

    readily observed than that of cadres in the central bu-reaucracy. If superior performance by provincial ad-ministrators did not lead to political rewards in theparty, we doubt that nonprovincial officials receivedsuch rewards either.

    We focus mainly on growth in GDP and fiscal rev-enue, but collect 22 other measures of performancefor use in robustness analyses. We assume that eachmember of the CC hierarchy who was also a provincialparty secretary or governor is judged based on the per-formance of his province in thefive years between partycongresses. In constructing our performance measures,we must solve two further problems. First, becausecompetition for party rank is zero-sum, only officials

    who outperform their peers should advance. Thus wecreate relative performance scores that subtract rest-of-China performance from each provinces growth rate.Second, provincial officials should not receive creditfor growth trends determined before they took office.Thus, we subtract preappointment expected perfor-mance from each provinces growth rate. The resultingvariable measures the performance improvement ineach province under its current leadership, relative toother provincial leaders. We create performance scoresof this type for GDP growth, fiscal revenue growth, andother indicators of provincial performance. For exam-ple, the province of an official with a GDP growth score

    of +2 beat preappointment growth expectations bytwo percent more than the average province in China.Members of the ACC or CC who were not regionaladministrators in the five years prior to a party congressreceive neutral performance scores of zero.5

    Estimating expected provincial performance is alsothe key to dealing with selection bias. Althoughhigh-flying officials might manuever themselves intoprovinces with strong growth prospects, or be sent toturn problem provinces around, we can purge theseand other selection effects from our performance mea-sures if we accurately model expectations of provincialperformance on the eve of appointment. Party leadersdoling out performance rewards share our problem

    of isolating the innovations in growth due to provin-cial leaders, rather than provincial trends or China-wide shocks. Because we cannot be certain how his-torical leaders solved this problem, we propose threestrategies, and check whether any of them provideevidence of yardstick competition. The first strategyis the simplest: We subtract the growth rate in thepreappointment year from growth during an officials

    5 Ourresults are not sensitive to the assignment of an arbitrary scoreto nonadministrators: A robustness check shows the same results ifwe also include in the model a dummy variable for officials with noobserved regional economic performance.

    171

  • 8/2/2019 Shih Adolph Liu Published 12

    7/22

    Advancement of Central Committee Members in China February 2012

    tenure, attributing the change to the officials ef-forts. We use this performance measure in our base-line models. As an alternative, we employ standardtime series methods to forecast growth over officialstenures using only preappointment data. We createforecasts using both the workhorse AR(1) model andthe AIC-minimizing ARMA(p, q) model. We usethese sharper estimates of expected growth in robust-

    ness checks that allow both sophisticated judgmentof performance by party leaders and complex pat-terns of strategic appointment of provincial officials.6

    See the supplemental Online Appendix (availableat http://www.journals.cambridge.org/psr2012004) forfurther details.

    METHODS

    Modeling the ranking of members of the CCP CentralCommitteeor any other partially observed ranking ofpolitical actors, whether the members of a legislature,a bureaucracy, or some other organizationchallengespolitical scientists inferential toolkit. Despite the om-nipresence of hierarchy in politics, these problem havenot yet been noted or solved.

    Rank Data Problems

    Political rank data pose three problems forquantitative-analysis-as-usual: Rank data are interde-pendent, require context to interpret, and are typicallyincomplete.

    Interdependence. Virtually all regression models inpolitical science assume that observations are iden-tically and independently distributed (iid). Rank ob-servations are intrinsically interdependent: Only onemember can rank first, only one can rank second, andso on. Direct inference on ranks using conventionalmethods will thus be invalid, giving incorrect standarderrors.

    Context. In general, observed and counterfactualranks are meaningful only in context. Without context,the first-ranked swimmer could mean anything; thefirst-ranked swimmer in the Olympics and the first-ranked swimmer in my neighborhood usually repre-sent very different levels of ability. Context matterseven when we know the underlying strength of indi-viduals giving rise to their ranking: The ranking boost

    provided by an increase in latent strength depends onthe competition posed by higher-ranked individuals.Contextual ranks complicate interpretation of esti-

    mated regression relationships. Frequentist inference(e.g., the use of t-tests and p-values to reject null hy-potheses) assumes that estimated relationships are rep-

    6 Even if actual Chinese leaders did not use ARMA models to judgetheirsubordinatesperformance, experience in macroeconomic fore-casting suggests that these models perform at least as well as moredata- and knowledge-intensive methods often used in the 1960s1980s, and may thus serve as shortcuts to estimating how sophisti-cated political actors of that period may have formed their expecta-tions (Diebold 2000).

    resentative of a broader pattern that could be repli-cated in other random samples. The collection of theseimagined datasets forms a superpopulation fromwhich we construct confidence intervals and signifi-cance tests. Rank data constrain us to a finite popu-lation perspective: What we learn about the impactof a covariate on rank in one years congress tells uslittle about its effect on rank within a different set of

    members in another year (Gelman et al. 2003).Although conventional hypothesis testing makes lit-tle sense for a rank data model, Bayesian confidenceintervals are still valid, as they do not depend on theexistence of any data beyond the sample analyzed.Moreover, the confidence intervals we obtain for ourresults are the best we will ever getbecause there willnever again be another 14th Party Congress, there isno possibility of finding more data to produce moreprecise estimates of its hierachical structure.

    Incomplete RanksTies and Tiers. An ideal rankdataset records a unique rank for each member, butsuch detailed ranks are seldom available. Rank data

    may be incomplete, or partially observed, in two ways.First, there may be ties, defined as cases wherethe rankers measurements could not distinguish the(presumably different) latent strength of two or moreconsecutively-ranked individuals. In an ordered list ofranked objects that omits numerical ranks, such tiesmay hide anywhere in the dataset, leading to measur-ment error if rank is treated as identical to order. Ourmethod of constructing ACC ranks is vulnerable toties, and these potential ties must be accounted in ourmodel.

    A broader version of this problem arises when theranks for a large tier of individuals are known

    to political actors, but concealed from the analyst.Figure 1 illustrates the relationship between tiers andranks using a hypothetical dataset of eight individu-als. Although the ranks of the three highest and twolowest members are known exactly, the fourth throughsixth ranks forma tier within which individuals relativeranks are unknown. Discarding these cases altogether,however, would waste valuable information, becausethe upper and lower bounds of the tier tell us that thesemiddle individuals rank below 1, 2, and 3 and above 7and 8. Although we can only specify the exact rank offive out of eight observations, we can correctly identifythe higher-ranking individual in 25 of the 28 possiblepairwise comparisons. The best analytic strategies for

    rank data will find ways to include this relative rankinformation.

    The observed ranks of members of the ACC, CC,Politburo, and PSC show essentially the same patternas the smaller dataset shown in Figure 1. We know theranks of ACC members and PSC members, but all wecan say about the CC is that their ranks lie somewherein the middle. Surprisingly, this simple observationabout CC members unlocks essential information forinferring the relationship between the characteristicsof party members and their political power, but we willnot be able to examine this hidden trove of data usingoff-the-shelf quantitative methods.

    172

  • 8/2/2019 Shih Adolph Liu Published 12

    8/22

    American Political Science Review Vol. 106, No. 1

    FIGURE 1. Observed Ranks, Missing Ranks,and Tiers

    Tier 1 (SC)

    Tier 2 (CC) ? ?

    Tier 3 (ACC) 7

    Rank

    8

    ?

    1 2 3

    1 3

    4 6

    7 8

    BoundsTier

    Note: In this hypothetical dataset, the ranks of the top threeindividuals (who occupy the top tier, or the PSC) and the ranksof the bottom three individuals (who occupy the lowest tier, orthe ACC) are known precisely. The ranks of the middle threeindividuals are unknown, but still bounded by the rank of theirtier, the CC.

    Flawed Analytic Strategies

    Three seemingly appropriate methods from the po-litical science toolkitlinear regression, censored re-gression, and ordered probiteither assume propertiesthat rank data clearly violate or ignore useful informa-tion contained in the ranks. Even though ranks takeon unique and interdependent integer values, least-squares regression inappropriately assumes that ranksare iid Normal, computes incorrect standard errors,and predicts impossible ranks. Because linear regres-sion requires us to listwise delete any observations with

    imprecisely observed ranks, we also lose informationcaptured by the bounds on those ranks, which is sta-tistically inefficient and a possible source of bias (Kinget al. 2001).

    Censored regression (or tobit) models a Normallydistributedoutcome that is observed when it falls in cer-tain ranges, but censored elsewhere (Schnedler 2005).This avoids bias and inefficiency from deleting partiallyobserved cases, but because censored regression alsoassumes ranks are iid Normal, its standard errors arestill biased. And neither censored nor linear regressionprotects against measurement error from miscodingtied ranks.

    If we abandoned our analysis of the rank-level data,

    we might focus on estimating the probability of an in-dividual appearing in a given tier using ordered probit.Ordered probit does notassume ranks areNormal, andmitigates (but does not eliminate) the dependence ofobservations. But it exacts a large cost for these im-provements, throwing out even more of the observeddata than linear regression, and adding a new parame-ter to estimate for each uniquely identified tier, so thatestimation becomes harder the more we know. To ana-lyze partial ranks without violating model assumptionsor discarding data, we look beyond the usual suspects,and develop statistical models calibrated to the unusualproperties of rank data.

    A Bayesian Model ofPartially Observed Ranks

    To understand the relative power of Chinese Commu-nist officials, we propose and apply a Bayesian modelof partially observed ranks with three advantages overconventional methods. First, we allow interdependenceof ranks through the rank likelihood (Hoff 2008). Sec-ond, we generalize this approach to allow for partialobservation of ranks, preserving all the informationavailable in our dataa step we expect will be crit-ical for most applications of the method to politicaldata. Finally, we interpret our results in the contextof each rank dataset: Rather than assume there is asuperpopulation from which each party congress isa random sample, Bayesian methods let us treat eachparty congress as sui generis, thus quantifying the mag-nitude and uncertainty of effects of covariates on ranksin historical context.

    We denote the rank of each individual i 1, . . . ,nas a unique integer yi 1, . . . ,n. Lower values of yirepresent higherranks; i.e.,y

    =1 indicates the highest-

    ranked individual, and y = n the lowest. Each individ-ual lies within a tier, or range of ranks, which is knowneven if yi is missing. Our model of yi rests on threeassumptions:

    Assumption 1. Each ranked memberhas a unique latentstrength yi .

    Assumption 2. Higher latent strength entails better ex-pected rank: yi > y

    j i outranks j yi < yj.

    Assumption 3. Latent strengths are iid Normal.

    To examine the relationship between ranks and

    observable covariates, we parameterize the latentstrength yi using a linear model, which for identifi-cation has no constant and unit variance:

    yi Normal (i, 1)i = 1x1i + 2x2i + . . . pxpi . (1)

    For convenience, we refer to the random componentof latent strength as i = yi i; we interpret i asrepresenting the unmeasured political talent and goodor bad fortune of official i.

    The model relies on the notion that if we could onlyobserve latent strength directly, a simple linear regres-

    sion would be sufficient to understand its conditionalexpectation. We link partially observed ranks to latentstrengths through a set of bounds around each rank,denoted {yloweri ,yupperi }. For a given observation, thereare three possible kinds of bounds. From most to leastinformative, these are

    Bound Type 1. Rank known exactly: yloweri = yi =y

    upperi .

    Bound Type 2. Rank known up to a potential tie with anadjacent ranked individual: yloweri = yupperi + d, whered+ 1 indicates the number of ranks included in thetie.

    173

  • 8/2/2019 Shih Adolph Liu Published 12

    9/22

    Advancement of Central Committee Members in China February 2012

    TABLE 1. Goodness of Fit

    Party Congress

    12th 13th 14th 15th 16th

    All observations (N) 410 285 320 342 356Fully observed (Nfull) 141 114 135 157 166

    Partially observed (Npart) 269 171 185 185 190Completely unobserved (Nmiss) 0 0 0 0 0Percent fully observed (100 Nfull/N) 34.4 40.0 42.2 45.9 46.6Percent of variance explained 29.5 46.5 40.4 47.6 34.7

    Percent prediction error of known ranks (

    MSE) 31.1 26.6 26.4 25.1 25.5Percent of tiers correctly predicted 65.6 66.3 75.3 69.6 71.6Bayesian information criterion 532.3 447.6 403.2 468.0 396.0

    Setting d = 1 discounts the observed difference inrank between any two immediately adjacent ranked in-dividuals as potential measurement error, but assumesthat two individuals separated by two ranks or moremust have correspondingly ordered latent strengths.

    Bound Type 3. Rank known up to a tier: yloweri < yi