reform of the stability and growth pact - oenbcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... ·...

32
The objective of the Stability and Growth Pact is to secure sound fiscal policies, which have remained a national responsibility in Economic and Monetary Union. Ever since it first took effect, the Stability and Growth Pact had been subject to a reform debate, ultimately leading to its redesign in 2005. The debate inten- sified in 2002, when several European countries suffered from growing budgetary problems, and culminated in November 2003, when the Ecofin Council decided not to act upon European Commission recommen- dations to move to the next steps of the excessive deficit procedure for France and Germany and instead adopted conclusions putting the procedures in abeyance subject to certain undertakings by the countries concerned. Consequently, the Commission brought an action before the European Court of Justice. The conflict surrounding the correct procedure in line with the provisions of the Treaty establishing the European Community (the Treaty) and the Stabilityand Growth Pact, i.e. the correct interpretation and implementation of the procedural and factual steps laid down therein, brought to light differences of opinion between the EU Member States and the European Commission as well as among the Member States themselves. Against this background, the European Commission presented concrete proposals to reform the Stabilityand Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March 20, 2005, the EU finance ministers reached a compromise on the reform of the Stability and Growth Pact. The reform includes measures applicable to both the preventive and the corrective arms of the Stability and Growth Pact. The top priority of the reform was to enhance Member Statesȓ national ownership of the fiscal framework and hence to safeguard the sustainability of public finances in the Economic and Monetary Union in the long run. Experience to date does not allow for a final assessment, but from the vantage point of monetary policy, certain weaknesses remain that had already been pointed out during the reform debate. JEL classification: E61, H3, H6 Keywords: fiscal policy, fiscal rules, stability and growth pact reform, european monetary union. 1 Introduction At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March 20, 2005, the EU finance minis- ters reached a compromise on the reform of the Stability and Growth Pact (SGP). At its Spring Summit of March 22 and 23, 2005, the European Council endorsed these fundamental changes to the SGP. The SGP is considered a crucial coordination element for sustaining and preserving sound national fiscal policies within Economic and Mone- tary Union (EMU). Next to a stabil- ity-oriented monetary policy, the maintenance of budget discipline in EMU member countries is considered to be an essential prerequisite for a well-functioning monetary union. Hence, the Maastricht Treaty (Treaty on European Union — TEU) contains provisions for the surveillance and coordination of EU Member Statesȓ fiscal policies. First of all, it commits all Member States to avoid excessive public deficits (i.e. deficits exceeding 3% of GDP). In this respect, the Treaty establishing the European Community (the Treaty) contains provisions both to prevent excessive deficits from aris- ing and to initiate a procedure to cor- rect any excessive deficits which do arise. Second, the TEU commits Mem- ber States to strive for government debt ratios below 60% of GDP. The SGP, which originally consisted of two Council Regulations and a Euro- pean Council Resolution adopted in 1997, sought to strengthen the fiscal framework of the Treaty by laying down more detailed rules and proce- dures for budgetary surveillance, and by speeding up and clarifying the implementation of the excessive deficit procedure (EDP). 1 The authors would like to thank Alfred Katterl (Austrian Federal Ministry of Finance) for valuable suggestions and comments. Leopold Diebalek, Walpurga Ko ‹hler- To ‹glhofer, Doris Prammer 1 Refeered by Alfred Katterl, Austrian Federal Ministry of Finance. Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact 78 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 ȕ

Upload: others

Post on 11-Aug-2020

2 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

The objective of the Stability and Growth Pact is to secure sound fiscal policies, which have remained anational responsibility in Economic and Monetary Union. Ever since it first took effect, the Stability andGrowth Pact had been subject to a reform debate, ultimately leading to its redesign in 2005. The debate inten-sified in 2002, when several European countries suffered from growing budgetary problems, and culminatedin November 2003, when the Ecofin Council decided not to act upon European Commission recommen-dations to move to the next steps of the excessive deficit procedure for France and Germany and insteadadopted conclusions putting the procedures in abeyance subject to certain undertakings by the countriesconcerned. Consequently, the Commission brought an action before the European Court of Justice. Theconflict surrounding the correct procedure in line with the provisions of the Treaty establishing the EuropeanCommunity (the Treaty) and the Stability and Growth Pact, i.e. the correct interpretation and implementationof the procedural and factual steps laid down therein, brought to light differences of opinion between the EUMember States and the European Commission as well as among the Member States themselves.

Against this background, the European Commission presented concrete proposals to reform theStability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March 20, 2005, theEU finance ministers reached a compromise on the reform of the Stability and Growth Pact. The reformincludes measures applicable to both the preventive and the corrective arms of the Stability and Growth Pact.The top priority of the reform was to enhance Member States� national ownership of the fiscal frameworkand hence to safeguard the sustainability of public finances in the Economic and Monetary Union in the longrun.

Experience to date does not allow for a final assessment, but from the vantage point of monetary policy,certain weaknesses remain that had already been pointed out during the reform debate.

JEL classification: E61, H3, H6Keywords: fiscal policy, fiscal rules, stability and growth pact reform, european monetary union.

1 IntroductionAt an extraordinary Ecofin meeting onMarch 20, 2005, the EU finance minis-ters reached a compromise on thereform of the Stability and GrowthPact (SGP). At its Spring Summit ofMarch 22 and 23, 2005, the EuropeanCouncil endorsed these fundamentalchanges to the SGP.

The SGP is considered a crucialcoordination element for sustainingand preserving sound national fiscalpolicies within Economic and Mone-tary Union (EMU). Next to a stabil-ity-oriented monetary policy, themaintenance of budget discipline inEMU member countries is consideredto be an essential prerequisite for awell-functioning monetary union.Hence, the Maastricht Treaty (Treatyon European Union — TEU) containsprovisions for the surveillance andcoordination of EU Member States�

fiscal policies. First of all, it commitsall Member States to avoid excessivepublic deficits (i.e. deficits exceeding3% of GDP). In this respect, the Treatyestablishing the European Community(the Treaty) contains provisions bothto prevent excessive deficits from aris-ing and to initiate a procedure to cor-rect any excessive deficits which doarise. Second, the TEU commits Mem-ber States to strive for governmentdebt ratios below 60% of GDP. TheSGP, which originally consisted oftwo Council Regulations and a Euro-pean Council Resolution adopted in1997, sought to strengthen the fiscalframework of the Treaty by layingdown more detailed rules and proce-dures for budgetary surveillance, andby speeding up and clarifying theimplementation of the excessive deficitprocedure (EDP).

1 The authors would like to thank Alfred Katterl (Austrian Federal Ministry of Finance) for valuable suggestions andcomments.

Leopold Diebalek,Walpurga Ko‹hler-To‹glhofer,Doris Prammer1

Refeered byAlfred Katterl,Austrian Federal Ministryof Finance.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

78 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 2: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Policymakers, academic circles,the European Commission and theEuropean System of Central Banks(ESCB) each had very different opin-ions about the original design of theSGP. Academic researchers, in particu-lar, sharply criticized the objectivesand the sanctions contained in theSGP. Hence, from the very outset,there were calls to reform the SGP,which became louder in 2002 (onlythree years after the full provisionshad taken effect) when a number ofEuropean countries — notably Portu-gal, Germany and France — experi-enced growing budgetary problems.In the course of this debate, both theeffectiveness and the very substanceof the SGP�s design were questioned,and the competent EU bodies, the Eco-nomic and Financial Committee andthe Ecofin Council, discussed first con-crete reform measures.

The growing crisis of the Europeanfiscal framework became starkly evi-dent when the economy began to slowdown in 2001. To reach the medium-term budget objectives prescribed bythe SGP, countries whose consolida-tion efforts in the preceding high-growth years had been insufficientwould have had to undertake increasedfiscal retrenchment measures with aprocyclical effect. Yet France and Ger-many, above all, were not willing totake measures that would have rein-forced the impact of the economicdownturn in the short run. The con-flict culminated in November 2003,when the Ecofin Council decided notto act upon European Commission

recommendations to move to the nextsteps of the EDP for France andGermany. Instead of giving these twocountries notice2 pursuant to Article104 (9) as a necessary prerequisite forimplementing excessive deficit pro-cedures, the Ecofin Council adopted�conclusions� putting the proceduresin abeyance subject to certain un-dertakings by the countries con-cerned. Consequently, the Commis-sion brought an action before the Euro-pean Court of Justice challenging pro-cedural aspects of the Ecofin Council�sconclusions. The European Court ofJustice indeed annulled said conclu-sions in July 2004, but at the same timeconfirmed the prerogative of the Eco-fin Council to exercise discretion inthe implementation of the procedure.The conflict surrounding the correctprocedure in line with the provisionsof the Treaty and the SGP, i.e. the cor-rect interpretation and implementa-tion of the procedural and factual stepslaid down therein, brought to light dif-ferences of opinion between the EUMember States and the EuropeanCommission as well as among theMember States themselves.3

Against this background, the Euro-pean Commission therefore made con-crete proposals to reform the SGP inthe fall of 2004. These proposals wereaimed primarily at preventing procycl-ical fiscal policy, allowing for morecountry-specific circumstances indefining medium-term budget objec-tives, giving increased attention to debtlevels and economic developments andclarifying the implementation of the

2 Article 104 (9) states that �[i]f a Member State persists in failing to put into practice the recommendations of theCouncil, the Council may decide to give notice to the Member State to take, within a specified time limit, measuresfor the deficit reduction which is judged necessary by the Council in order to remedy the situation. In such a case, theCouncil may request the Member State concerned to submit reports in accordance with a specific timetable in orderto examine the adjustment efforts of that Member State.�

3 In particular, the conflict laid open the differences of opinion between small countries applying strict fiscaldiscipline and the large Member States Germany, France and Italy.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 79�

Page 3: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

SGP. One often cited goal of thereform was also to strengthen the eco-nomic underpinnings of the SGP andenhance �national ownership,� i.e. theMember States� identification withthe European fiscal policy framework,in order to prevent the SGP from beingsidelined as increasingly politicallymeaningless.

Conversely, the ESCB saw no fun-damental need to reform the SGP, justa need to improve implementation.From the vantage point of monetarypolicymakers, the changes to the SGPrepresent quite a substantial weakeningof the EU�s fiscal policy framework,together with the danger of jeopardiz-ing the long-term sustainability of thenational fiscal policies and of compli-cating the stability-oriented monetarypolicy.

In section 2, the original setup ofthe SGP is presented. Section 3 dis-cusses the advantages of sound publicfinances and the rationale for a rules-based fiscal policy. Section 4 deals withthe criticism leveled at the EU�s fiscalpolicy framework. Section 5 evaluatesthe effectiveness of the original SGP.Sections 6 and 7 present the reformof the SGP adopted in 2005. Section 8rounds off the study with a criticalassessment of the reformed SGP takinginto account the experience up to now.

2 Original DesignOn June 17, 1997, at the AmsterdamSummit, the European Counciladopted the SGP by resolution. Thenew framework substantiated and

strengthened the Treaty provisions onfiscal discipline foreseen by Article 99(coordination and multilateral surveil-lance of the national fiscal policies)and Article 104 (corrective measuresand sanctions). With this initiative theEuropean Council responded to con-cerns about the inadequacy of the exist-ing legal instruments to guaranteecompliance with the fiscal criteriaquantified by the TEU4 and thus to safe-guard the sustainability of public finan-ces after the introduction of the euro.

As it would have been too compli-cated to amend the TEU — any amend-ments would have required unanimityand, depending on national rules, rati-fication by an act of parliament or bynational referendum — the SGP wasimplemented on the basis of Articles 99and 104 of the Treaty by means ofdetailed secondary legislation (CouncilRegulation (EC) No 1466/97 of 7 July1997 on the strengthening of the sur-veillance of budgetary positions andthe surveillance and coordination ofeconomic policies, Council Regulation(EC) No 1467/97 of 7 July 1997 onspeeding up and clarifying the imple-mentation of the excessive deficit pro-cedure, and Resolution of the Euro-pean Council on the Stability andGrowth Pact Amsterdam, 17 June1997). The SGP defines the objectiveof sound public finances in detail andbasically serves to accelerate or clarifythe EDP. To do so, the SGP contains a�preventive early warning mechanism�and �corrective and dissuasive ele-ments� (Bayer et al., 2000; Part, 1998).

4 TEU provided for maintenance of fiscal discipline for all Member States by introducing two quantitative referencevalues that both reflect policy choices: as a rule, the general government deficit ratio of a Member State was to bebelow 3% of GDP, and the government debt ratio was to be below 60% of GDP (or to be sufficiently diminishing andapproaching the reference value at a satisfactory pace). Moreover, the TEU enshrined the prohibition of monetaryfinancing of government debt and a �no bailout� clause in order to prevent moral hazard behavior. It was agreed thatonly those countries would be able to move to the third stage of EMU that actually met the Maastricht criteria.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

80 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 4: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

To better enforce fiscal discipline,the instruments and the proceduresof the SGP were successively refinedfrom the time the SGP went into effect(Singer, 2005, p. 47f). These refine-ments applied among other things tothe format and content of the stabilityand convergence programs (establish-ment of a code of conduct), a clarifica-tion of the medium-term objective ofachieving a budgetary position (�closeto balance or in surplus�)5 and thedetermination of a uniform methodto measure cyclically adjusted budgetbalances. Additionally, the EU beganto deal systematically with the conse-quences of aging populations on thelong-term sustainability of publicfinances within the existing EU frame-work for budgetary surveillance. How-ever, the European Council�s require-ment for the surveillance of the qualityof public finances has not been met yet.

3 The Objectives of theSGP — Fiscal Disciplineand Sound PublicFinances

The objective of the original SGP wasto continue to guarantee sound publicfinances and hence fiscal discipline inthe Member States after the introduc-tion of the euro. Sound fiscal policysecured by a rules-based fiscal policyframework fosters macroeconomic sta-bility and creates favorable frameworkconditions for sustainable high eco-nomic growth. It strengthens marketparticipants� trust and reduces the riskinvolved in long-term decision-mak-ing, e.g. for investment. Moreover,lower budget deficits and the achieve-

ment of primary surpluses make it pos-sible to reduce the debt ratio; the lowerinterest payments they entail broadenthe scope for fiscal maneuver.

Conversely, permanent structuralbudget deficits exercise upward pres-sure both on short-term interest rates(if the central bank feels compelledto counteract inflationary effects byraising interest rates) and on long-terminterest rates (as a result of changes ininflationary expectations) and, in aregime of flexible nominal exchangerates, push currency appreciation.While the resulting appreciation damp-ens export demand, high interest ratesaffect private investment demandabove all and also detract from thelong-term income outlook for an econ-omy as a result of reduced capital accu-mulation.

Fiscal discipline helps improve theeconomic environment in the shortterm by creating the proper frame-work conditions which allow for thefull operation of the automatic stabiliz-ers and which provide for sufficient fis-cal policy leeway for anticyclical actionduring an economic slump. In thismanner, it supports short-term eco-nomic growth without risking a breachof the 3% reference value.

The pursuit of a stability-orientedmonetary policy is only possible ifbudget policy is geared toward fiscaldiscipline. High or growing debt ratiosinvolve the risk that central banks areforced to follow a more accommoda-tive monetary policy to reduce the realvalue of outstanding government debtthrough higher inflation.

5 See Part (2000).

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 81�

Page 5: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

In a monetary union, the argu-ments in favor of rules-based fiscalpolicies become even stronger, as thedeficit incentives for fiscal policymak-ers change. The incentive to take defi-cit-financed measures rises, exacerbat-ing what is referred to as the deficit biasof fiscal policy.6 The �sanctioning�effects of deficit-financed nationalpolicies disappear, as exchange ratedevelopments and short-term interestrates are geared to the economic condi-tions prevailing throughout the entiremonetary union. Moreover, the costsof deficit spending are spread amongall monetary union member countries,whereas the advantages are not equallydistributed.7 Should any doubts abouta monetary union member countryarise, the risk premia increase for everymember country, especially if thefinancial markets question the credibil-ity of no bailout clauses.

Consequently, the original and thereformed SGP aim at preventing suchnegative spillover effects on MemberStates bound to fiscal discipline. TheSGP is additionally aimed at protectingthe Eurosystem from having to answera call for an ex ante bailout by loosen-ing monetary policy or for an ex postbailout by monetary financing of gov-ernment debt. Hence, European fiscalpolicy rules are designed to reduce thedanger that countries simply reap the

benefits of other countries� goodbehavior without following the rulesthemselves, and above all the dangerof moral hazard practices.

4 Criticism of the FiscalFramework

From the outset, the fiscal criteriaquantified by the TEU and the designof the SGP were subject to lively dis-cussion and criticism, which intensi-fied in the wake of the slowdown ineconomic growth from 2001 onward.

Since the quantification of the fiscalrules in the TEU, the criticism hasfocused mainly on two issues, namelythe lack of a theoretical basis for polit-ically determined fiscal referencevalues and the lack of enforceabilityof these rules. When the SGP wasintroduced, this criticism intensified.In particular, the critics questionedwhether uniform quantitative ruleswere suited to preventing a rise inpublic debt. Moreover, they pointedout that the quantitative rules had adetrimental impact on the economy.8

The criticism that the chosen fiscalrules lacked a foundation in economictheory applies to both the politicallydetermined general government defi-cit and gross debt ceilings (Buiteret al., 1993; Wyplosz, 2002) and tothe definition of the medium-termobjective of a budgetary position close

6 However, in line with the tax-smoothing theory (Barro,1979), it makes economic sense to accept deficit spending tofinance temporary increases in expenditure (e.g. military spending occasioned by an international conflict) ratherthan to raise taxes abruptly, which would entail high welfare losses. It also makes economic sense to pursue anexpansive fiscal policy during phases of pronounced or protracted capacity underutilization to reduce the deviationof actual from potential output. Permanent structural deficits and the rapid rise in European countries�debt ratiosin the 1980s and at the beginning of the 1990s cannot be seen simply as a result of anticyclical budget policy andtax-smoothing efforts, though. Much rather, they were the outcome of a budget policy with an immanent deficit biasfor which there are numerous reasons (Calmfors, 2005). Fiscal policy rules are aimed at reducing or getting undercontrol the deficit bias of fiscal policy to all Member States� advantage and to secure the stability orientation ofmonetary policy. See also Beetsma (2001).

7 However, growing integration also lets trade partner countries benefit from deficit-increasing demand-stimulatingdiscretionary measures.

8 However, by drawing up a list of arguments, we do not intend to compare the given fiscal framework in Europe withan ideal model.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

82 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 6: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

to balance or in surplus. The criticsargue that since there is no generallyaccepted theory stating the optimallevel of public debt, the convergenceof the debt ratio toward zero impliedby the medium-term objective lackstheoretical justification.9 Further-more, one cannot deduce from eco-nomic theory exactly how large a debtratio is no longer sustainable in thelong run.10 The acceptance of tempo-rary deficits in times of an economicdownturn or of temporary expendi-ture hikes (tax smoothing) may, more-over, be welfare enhancing.

Moreover, critics argue that thedemand for attainment of specificannual deficit targets forces MemberStates to resort to one-off and tempo-rary measures more frequently. All-sopp and Artis (2003, p. 29) assert thatthe target implies that �the SWP mayforce adjustments that are not neces-sary for sustainability and that it mayrule out policies that are desirable forthe functioning of the system as awhole.�

Critics also questioned the choiceof gross debt standards, which onlytake into account general governmentfinancial liabilities, i.e. overstate totalpublic sector liabilities by not correlat-ing them with the public sector�s assets(Buiter, 1985). At the same time, thisapproach understates the true extentof public debt because it does not con-sider future �implicit� expenditure,

such as future pension payments orgovernment guarantees.

The impact of a uniform deficit tar-get for all Member States on debt levelsattracted especially great criticism.With the growth performance differ-ing among Member States, the uniformdeficit target results in completely dif-ferent debt dynamics (Buiter et al.,1993). While targeting the uniform def-icit ratio, the new Member States inparticular will achieve debt ratios sub-stantially lower than 60% of GDP,given comparatively high outputgrowth rates (Buiter and Grafe,2004). Critics challenged the rationaleof having a uniform deficit target alsowith reference to the wide range ofdebt ratio. Member States with lowerdebt ratios should be conceded moregenerous deficit targets (EEAG, 2003;Pisani-Ferry, 2002) and hence greaterroom for budgetary policy maneuver.11

This consideration, as well as the con-sideration of taking into account differ-ences in growth performance, havebeen integrated into the reformedSGP by allowing for more country-spe-cific circumstances in defining themedium-term objective.12

Other experts (IMF, 2001; Euro-pean Commission, 2003) wouldchoose expenditure rules over deficitrules, as the emergence of budget def-icits that would not be sustainable inthe long run could be ascribed mainlyto uncontrolled expenditure growth.

9 De Grauwe (2004), Canzeroni and Diba (2001) and Pisani-Ferry (2002) argue that it would make more economicsense to focus on a debt ratio target rather than a specific debt ceiling to be reached every year. To secure the long-term sustainability of public finances, Member States should be obligated to comply with a specific debt ratio whosesize is determined commensurately with the implicit obligations the respective countries have.

10 Basically, the accumulation of public debt presents no problem as long as the debt can be assumed to be repaid withfuture income (primary surpluses). However, even the achievement of a low deficit or a low debt at a particular timedoes not guarantee the future long-term sustainability of fiscal policy.

11 Conversely, considering that high deficits have a certain inertia, as their reduction involves high political costs, theemergence of structural deficits should be prevented as a matter of principle.

12 The critics also proposed linking the deficit ceiling to the dept levels (EEAG, 2003; Walton, 2004; Calmfors andCorsetti, 2003). Another strand of the discussion was to allow countries with a low debt ratio more time to correctexcessive deficits.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 83�

Page 7: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Admittedly, in a supranational context,such rules would tie individual Mem-ber States� hands even more thandeficit rules. Furthermore, uniformexpenditure rules for all MemberStates would be accompanied by sub-stantial welfare losses, if the MemberStates had very different preferencesregarding the composition of theirexpenditure.

Academics and policymakers alikealso pointed out the negative sideeffects of quantitative fiscal rules andthe rigid requirements of the SGP, suchas a lack of flexibility, the dampening ofgovernment investment,13 the hin-drance of structural reforms — whichentail short-run costs and long-runbenefits — and the relinquishment ofthe stabilization function of the stateas well as the prevention of a tax-smoothing strategy of benefit to theeconomy.

The cutback of investment expen-diture is associated with temporarilylower political costs than a cut in socialsecurity payments, subsidies or spend-ing on public employment.14 Inasmuchas cutbacks of public investment spend-ing would impair Member States� long-term growth prospects, fiscal policytargets under the SGP would contra-dict the other policy goals of the EUwhich are aimed at making the EUthe most competitive region in theworld by 2010. Therefore, academics(Blanchard and Giavazzi, 2004; Creel,2003) suggested the introduction of a�golden rule� according to which the

medium-term deficit target of theSGP should refer to current govern-ment expenditure including deprecia-tion and maintenance costs and exclud-ing net public investment. The amountof government borrowing would belimited to net government capital for-mation. The intergenerational advant-age of this approach would supportthe financing of government capitalformation by borrowing, as futuregenerations would benefit from thehigher productivity and the higherper capita income generated by cur-rent public investment.15 Buiter andGrafe (2004), in turn, draw attentionto the special position of the new Mem-ber States, where public investment isin fact associated with an even higherrate of return than in the EU-15.

The TEU take account of thegolden rule only insofar as it statesthat an EDP report prepared underArticle 104 (3) has to take into accountwhether the government deficit ex-ceeds government investment. How-ever, this note in the original SGPnever really had any weight in the deci-sion about the existence of an excessivedeficit. Arguments against the applica-tion of a golden rule included data def-inition problems, the increased possi-bility of �creative accounting,� theunequal treatment of expenditure onhuman and on physical capital and theeconomically unwarranted preferencefor real capital investment. At the sametime it should be noted that that thereis no conclusive empirical evidence

13 In fact, public investment (gross fixed capital formation) declined sharply in the course of 1990s — albeit not just inthe EU Member States, but in all OECD countries. However, it has to be born in mind that sector reclassifications inESA 95 also distorted downward public investment expenditure data considerably.

14 The literature shows, however, that the most successful consolidations were based on reducing employment spendingand transfers (Alesina and Perotti, 1995).

15 A textbook on public finance theory authored by Lorenz von Stein as early as 1878 noted: �Ein Staat ohne Staats-schuld tut entweder zuwenig fu‹r seine Zukunft oder er fordert zu viel von seiner Gegenwart.� (�A country that has nopublic debt is either doing too little for its future or is placing too high demands on its present;� German as cited inNowotny, 1999, p. 428).

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

84 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 8: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

supporting the proposition that publicinvestment and infrastructure spend-ing actually increase long-term growth(Easterly and Rebelo, 1993; Balassoneand Franco, 2001; Perotti, 2005).

Another criticism stated that theSGP prevented governments from tak-ing adequate measures to counteractcyclical fluctuations (Canzeroni andDiba, 2001). The SGP is focused pri-marily on the effect of the automaticstabilizers, which can operate fullywhen Member States observe themedium-term targets of achieving abudget close to balance or in surplus(Buti and Giudice, 2002; EuropeanCommission, 2002a; Artis and Buti,2001; Buti and Franco, 2005). How-ever, the automatic stabilizers can ach-ieve only a certain amount of cyclicalstabilization.16 Tax reforms andreforms of the unemployment benefitsystems may have reduced the effec-tiveness of the automatic stabilizers inthe past decades. The concentrationprimarily on the automatic stabilizershas been identified as problematicabove all because the single monetarypolicy of EMU has made fiscal policymore important (HM Treasury, 2003;Feldstein, 2002). The exceptionalitycondition allowing a temporary breachof the 3% GDP threshold during asevere economic downturn — definedas an annual fall of real GDP growthof at least 2% in the original SGP —was criticized as too harsh.

This criticism is closely linked tothe reproach that the SGP has an asym-metric effect and does not provide anyincentives for stepped-up fiscal consol-idation during good times (Bean,1998). As a result, Member States thushave to consolidate during downturnsto comply with the deficit targets. Thisimplies that the SGP was not suited toprevent procyclical behavior. In fact,from the public choice perspective,one could even draw the conclusionthat the SGP tended to reinforce gov-ernments� deficit bias:17 Greater con-solidation efforts during high-growthphases not only reduce a government�schances of reelection, it also eases anew government�s workload by spar-ing it the need to act procyclically if adownturn occurs.

Moreover, critics charged that as aninstrument to coordinate European fis-cal policy, the SGP did not guaranteean optimal fiscal stance for the euroarea (Wyplosz, 2002; Casella, 2001).This charge has to be seen above allagainst the background of the juxtapo-sition of a single monetary policy witha fiscal policy that obeyed the subsidiar-ity principle and was thus still anational responsibility. According toBegg and Schelkle (2004, p. 90ff),�. . .the Pact is a weak or even ill-con-ceived substitute for a central fiscalauthority acting as a politically legiti-mate counterweight to the ECB. . . .Thereis no means of targeting the aggregate

16 The concentration on the automatic stabilizers as a matter of principle must be interpreted against the backgroundof the paradigm shift in fiscal policy. The ability of discretionary fiscal policy to stabilize output and employmentwas increasingly challenged on the one hand by the appearance of permanent structural budget deficits in the secondhalf of the 1970s and in the 1980s and on the other hand by new economic theory findings (Barro, 1974). Thediscussion about possible non-Keynesian effects reinforced the doubts that had arisen (Blanchard, 1985, 1990;Giavazzi and Pagano, 1990; Bertola and Drazen, 1993; McDermott and Westcott, 1996; Sutherland, 1997;Perotti, 1999; Alesina et al., 2002). Taylor (2000) argues that monetary policy should principally be used forstabilization purposes.

17 However, critics of the SGPand of rules-based fiscal policy consider the deficit bias and the tendency of governmentsto accumulate debt far less important than the need to react flexibly to short-term cyclical fluctuations andmedium- to long-term challenges.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 85�

Page 9: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

fiscal stance and thus of establishing anappropriate policy mix to assure the mac-roeconomic stabilisation of the Euro area.�Collignon (2003, p. 17) therefore con-cludes that �only a full, democratic con-stitutional consensus would be able to giveEuropean stabilisation policies the coher-ence they need.�

The political experience gainedsince 1999 clearly revealed the weakenforceability of the SGP; the sanction-ing mechanism also suffered frominsufficient credibility.18 The cascadingprocedure based on Council regula-tions is controlled by decision-makingat the Ecofin Council level, which ischaracterized by an asymmetric incen-tive structure. The finance ministerswho have to account for an excessivedeficit and face possible sanctions havea greater interest to join forces to pre-vent sanctions than those of the otherMember States do. However, in decid-ing on whether to impose sanctions,Member States which are not threat-ened by sanctions may take intoaccount the possibility that they could

in the future exceed deficit limitsthemselves.19 Moreover, large coun-tries have a greater incentive than smallones to join forces, because discretion-ary fiscal measures are much moreeffective in large and fairly closedeconomies than in small, open econo-mies (Buti and Pench, 2004), wheremuch of the impact of fiscal measuresis channeled abroad through highimports. Hence, expansionary fiscalpolicy measures have a much lowerimpact on domestic production andemployment in small, open economiesthan in large economies. In addition,the rigorous imposition of sanctionson a Member State raises the questionof whether these sanctions might notdetract from the political support ofthe EU itself, because the sanctionsincrease the fiscal problems of thecountries concerned even more. �Theobjective of heavy sanctions is to deterundesirable behaviour, but if the sanctionsare too draconian, political decision mak-ers will never dare employ them� (Calm-fors, 2005, p. 56).

18 When the original SGP was negotiated, in particular German experts pointed out that a lack of an automaticresponse to an existing excessive deficit could contribute to this problem (Stark, 2001; Costello, 2001).

19 This problem became clearly apparent in the decision about whether to issue a notice to France and Germany in2003. Here, France and Germany supported each other; Portugal and Greece, Italy (EU presidency) and theUnited Kingdom were also against issuing a notice — partly because they were aware that they themselves mightrequire German and French support in the future. Also, the termination of the excessive deficit procedure againstPortugal despite a strongly rising debt ratio above the 60% reference value supports the suspicion of concertedcollusion contrary to the spirit of the SGP. The proposal of revoking the right to vote of those finance ministerswho are responsible for an excessive deficit does not provide a solution either, as it would call into question thelegitimacy of supranational decision-making rules.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

86 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 10: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

5 The Effectiveness of theOriginal Fiscal PolicyFramework

Under the Treaty and the SGP, Mem-ber States have undertaken to pursuesound budgetary policies and in partic-ular to avoid excessive public deficits.In principle, a deficit above 3% ofGDP is considered excessive. A deficitovershooting the reference valuewould not be considered excessive ifit is the result of an unusual event (anannual fall of real GDP of 2% or at least0.75%)20 or if the breach is judged to beminor, is only temporary and is causedby an unusual event outside the controlof the Member State. To prevent exces-sive deficits during economic down-turns, Member States have to striveto observe a �safety margin� betweenthe current budget deficit and the ref-erence value under normal cyclical cir-cumstances.

The purpose of the SGP�s objectiveof a budgetary position that is close tobalance or in surplus is to ensure thatno excessive deficits arise duringphases of sluggish growth. Themedium-term objective has been rein-terpreted several times since the startof Stage Three of EMU. Initially, itwas seen as the attainment of a budgetliterally in balance21 or a surplus, whilein recent years a cyclically adjusteddeficit of 0.5% of GDP in view of

measurement uncertainties has alsobeen considered acceptable as �closeto balance.�

5.1 Early Warning System Proved Notto Be Very Effective

The so-called early warning procedureunder the SGP aims as giving earlywarning to prevent the occurrence ofan excessive deficit. The EuropeanCommission and the Ecofin Councilassess the compliance of MemberStates� medium-term budget planningwith the SGP on the basis of stabilityand convergence programs submittedannually by the Member States. If theactual budget course diverges fromthe medium-term budgetary objec-tive, and hence jeopardizes attainmentof the reference value, the respectiveMember State should be called on,by means of an early warning,22 totake the necessary adjustment meas-ures.

Admittedly, the early warning sys-tem was not effective in preventingthe occurrence of excessive deficits in6 of the 12 EMU member countries.Portugal was expected to have a deficitratio of just over 4% of GDP already in2001. Germany and France have exhib-ited an excessive deficit since 2002, theNetherlands in 2003. Portugal cor-rected its excessive deficit in 2002,resorting extensively to one-off and

20 Council Regulation (EC) No 1467/97 of 7 July 1997 clarifies that the European Commission when preparing areport under Article 104 (3) shall, as a rule, consider an excess over the reference value resulting from a severeeconomic downturn to be exceptional only if there is an annual fall of real GDP of at least 2%. However, theCouncil when deciding, according to Article 104 (6), whether an excessive deficit exists, it shall in its overall assess-ment take into account any observations made by the Member State showing that an annual fall of real GDP of lessthan 2% (but at least 0.75%) is nevertheless exceptional in the light of further supporting evidence, in particularon the abruptness of the downturn or on the accumulated loss of output relative to past trends.

21 Interpretation of the Austrian authorities.22 The Ecofin Council addresses this early warning to a Member State on the basis of a Commission recommendation.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 87�

Page 11: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

temporary measures, so that the EDPwas ended at the beginning of 2004.23

In 2004, following a revised notifica-tion of data, Greece was found to havehad an excessive deficit since 2000.24

At the beginning of 2005, Italy was alsofound to have exceeded the 3% refer-ence value in 2003 and 2004 (mostrecently also in 2005), again in thecourse of data revisions. Whereas theNetherlands had corrected its exces-sive deficit ahead of the deadline — justone year after its occurrence — by tak-ing substantial adjustment measures,France and Germany failed to take suf-ficient measures even though theirdeadlines had already been extendedto 2005 in the fall of 2003. Conse-quently, 6 of the 12 EMU membercountries had already been subject toan EDP since the start of Stage Threeof EMU. As Portugal decided not totake additional temporary measuresto reduce its deficit in 2005, the coun-try�s deficit exceeded the referencevalue once again, and a new EDP wasinitiated. Outside EMU, both theUnited Kingdom (in 2003 and 2004)and 6 of the 10 new Member Statesposted deficits in excess of the 3% ref-erence value. The United Kingdomwas found to be running an excessivedeficit in January 2006, when itbecame clear that the country�s deficitwould exceed the reference value againin the fiscal year 2005/06 (see annextable 1a and 1b).

Although the European Commis-sion had proposed giving early warn-

ings to four countries since 2002before an excessive deficit occurred,namely to Portugal and Germany(January 2002), France (November2002) and Italy (April 2004), theEcofin Council issued a recommenda-tion only to France. In the other cases,the Ecofin Council was satisfied thatthe respective countries had agreedto make an effort to prevent an exces-sive deficit from occurring. Consider-ing that the countries later breachedthe 3% deficit limit, early warningswould have been justified in all threecases.25

Judging from the experience withthe procedures that the original SGPprovided for, it appears that �the over-all picture is thus one of weak enforce-ment of the earlier rules. The earlywarning mechanism has not been usedas it should. The excessive deficit pro-cedure has been initiated according tothe book in case of deficits above threepercent of GDP (except for the UK in2004), but deviations from the stipula-tions regarding subsequent proceduralsteps have been notorious.� (Calmfors,2005, p. 37)

5.2 Maastricht Convergence CriteriaCall for Deficit Shrinkage — ButCountries Have Shown LessConsolidation Commitment sincethe Start of Stage Three of EMU

The degree to which the EU�s fiscalrules have actually influenced theMember States� behavior in the pastdecade also says something about these

23 Albeit despite a sharply rising debt ratio linked to a breach of the reference value of 60% of GDP.24 The revision of Greece�s fiscal data made manifest the problem of deficiencies inherent in statistical data and the

fiscal indicators used, and showed up the problem of incorrect data reporting by individual Member States to Euro-stat. In a rules-based system based on simple quantitative data, the correctness of the statistical database andreported data are pivotal to the entire framework. From the outset, critics had drawn attention to the possibilitythat deficient data would be reported and to the liability of Member States to resort to �creative accounting� tomanipulate the relevant fiscal indicators. See also von Hagen and Wolff (2004).

25 The early warning issued to Ireland in 2001 represented a special case in that Ireland violated the spirit of the SGPby exercising an expansionary fiscal policy.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

88 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 12: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

rules� effectiveness. In the 1980s and inthe first half of the 1990s, many Euro-pean countries posted permanentstructural deficits and rapidly growingdebt ratios, an unsustainable develop-ment in the long run. An adjustmentof budgetary developments was inevi-table. When the fiscal criteria wereestablished under the TEU as a neces-sary prerequisite for EMU member-ship, it became easier to embark on aconsolidation path. The substantiallyimproved budget indicators for 1997were used to assess fulfillment of theconvergence criteria. In the followingyears, however, most countriesreduced their efforts to meet the con-vergence criteria (annex tables 2a and2b). The procyclicality of fiscal policiesin some EU Member States, especiallybetween 1998 and 2001, supportedcritics� claims that the SGP was notproviding for sufficient incentivemechanisms (annex charts 1a and 1b).The SGP did not give Member Statesan incentive to reinforce their consoli-dation efforts during good economictimes. To the contrary, higher revenuesduring high growth phases still enabledcountries to take expansionary fiscalmeasures — in Germany�s case evenwith the approval of the Ecofin Coun-cil.26 Since the economy began to slowdown in 2001, a number of EMU mem-ber countries have posted excessivedeficits that are nearly completelystructural in nature. Obviously, theconsolidation measures taken duringthe second half of the 1990s were notsufficient. Moreover, the fulfillmentof the Maastricht criteria had beenbased partly on temporary measuresand �creative accounting.� With theeconomy slowing down, especially

Germany and France refused to actprocyclically and to step up their con-solidation efforts.

A large number of econometricstudies analyzed to what extent theEuropean rules-based fiscal policyframework had changed the reactionfunction of fiscal policy. Many analysesconcluded that the framework had notcaused fiscal policy to become less anti-cyclical (Balassone and Francese, 2004;European Commission, 2004; Posen,2005). Gali and Perotti (2003) foundthat the sensitivity of budget deficitsto cyclical fluctuations appears to havebeen stronger since the mid-1990s thanin the preceding decades. According toFata«s and Mihov (2004), since the intro-duction of the European fiscal policyframework, the use of those discretion-ary fiscal policy measures which arenot aimed at stabilization seems to havelost importance. This allows for theconclusion that the European fiscalpolicy framework indeed had somedisciplining effect on Member States�fiscal policy.

6 The Key Changes of theSGP

6.1 Improved Governance

Cooperation and coordination be-tween the Member States, the Euro-pean Commission and the EcofinCouncil play a decisive role for theeffectiveness of the SGP and the Euro-pean fiscal policy framework. There-fore, when the SGP was reformed,the Member States agreed tostrengthen peer support rather thancontinuing to rely solely on peer pres-sure to induce Member States to actin the spirit of and in conformity withthe SGP.

26 The fiscal cost of a tax reform does not become evident until a country�s economic growth weakens; during highgrowth phases, this cost is masked by the high revenue collected during boom conditions.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 89�

Page 13: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

The publication of decisions andrecommendations of the EuropeanCommission, improved delivery con-ditions and quality of statistical dataand the strengthening of nationalbudget processes are intended to fosterthe Member States� ownership of thenew SGP. Complementary nationalbudgetary rules, greater involvementof national parliaments and of the Euro-pean Commission as well as greatercontinuity in drawing up stability pro-grams aim at helping to achieve the fis-cal targets.

6.2 Changes to the Preventive Arm ofthe SGP

The definition of the medium-termobjective (MTO) and the adjustmentpath to the MTO represent the keychanges to the preventive arm of theSGP. The MTO now refers to the cycli-cally adjusted budgetary position net ofone-off and temporary measures.

The new SGP confirmed the rea-sons stated in the original SGP for hav-ing an MTO, i.e. (1) to provide a safetymargin with respect to the 3% deficitlimit; (2) to ensure a rapid reductionof the debt ratio and to guarantee thesustainability of public finances; and(3) to guarantee sufficient room forpublic investment.

The new MTO, though, is no lon-ger uniformly defined, but rather dif-ferentiated for individual MemberStates to take into account the charac-teristics of their economies. Macroeco-nomic variables such as potentialgrowth and the cyclical situation, spe-cific structural reforms and fiscal sus-tainability in terms of the debt ratio

and population aging27 are taken intoaccount in determining the country-specific MTOs. Depending on the sizeof a Member State�s debt ratio and itspotential growth, the MTO shall bespecified with a corridor ranging froma deficit of 1% of GDP to a (small)surplus, cyclically adjusted and net ofone-off measures. Member Statesstate their MTOs in their stability andconvergence programs. The MTOsshould be revised when a major reformis implemented and, as a rule, everyfour years to reflect new develop-ments.

The adjustment path to the MTOshould be defined in conformity withthe business cycle. However, thereform reaffirmed the commitmentof euro area member countries, asstated by Eurogroup finance ministersin October 2002, to strive for animprovement of their cyclically ad-justed budget balances (now excludingone-off and temporary measures) byat least 0.5% of GDP a year untilthey reached their country-specificMTOs.28

To refute the charge that they exer-cise a procyclical fiscal policy, theMember States have committed them-selves to reinforce consolidation ef-forts during favorable cyclical phases.In turn, the need for consolidation dur-ing phases of weak economic growth isreduced. Economic �good times� aredefined in the Code of Conduct onthe content and format of the stabilityand convergence programmes as �peri-ods where output exceeds its potentiallevel, taking into account tax elasticities.�(Code of Conduct, 2005, p. 5)

27 No agreed method to take into account the budgetary impact of population aging in countries� MTOs has beenestablished yet.

28 This obligation also applies to ERM II members.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

90 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 14: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Deviations from the adjustmentpath to the MTO or from the MTOare permissible provided that theyresult from structural reforms, aretemporary29 and if an appropriatesafety margin to the 3% referencevalue is preserved. Only structuralreforms that represent a short-termburden on the budget but have a posi-tive impact on the sustainability of pub-lic finances in the long run, e.g. byreducing future expenditure or raisingpotential growth, are considered,though.

A systemic pension reform, i.e. theswitch from a pay-as-you-go to afunded pension scheme, may be citedas a prominent example of a structuralreform. In the short run, such a switchinvolves additional costs because thepayments are routed from the publicpension scheme to a privately fundedscheme, but in the long run, publiccommitments should contract.30

6.3 Changes to the Corrective Arm ofthe SGP

If the government deficit ratio exceedsthe reference value of 3% of GDP, theEuropean Commission is still obligedunder the new SGP to prepare a reportunder Article 104 (3). In this report,the European Commission considerswhether the excess over the referencevalue is only temporary, whether theratio remains close to the referencevalue and whether the excess resultsfrom an unusual event outside the con-trol of the Member State concerned.Under such circumstances, no EDP isinitiated, just like under the old SGP.

As in the original SGP, a severeeconomic downturn — now defined asa negative annual GDP volume growthrate — qualifies as exceptional. More-over, an accumulated loss of outputduring a protracted period of verylow annual GDP growth relative toits potential is now also considered asevere economic downturn.31 TheCode of Conduct, which was alsorevised, determines that the indicatorfor assessing accumulated loss of out-put is the output gap, as calculatedaccording to the harmonized methodagreed in July 2002.

When assessing whether an exces-sive deficit exists, the European Com-mission report should take intoaccount whether the government defi-cit exceeds government investmentand should appropriately reflect devel-opments in the medium-term eco-nomic position (e.g. potential growthand the implementation of policies inthe context of the Lisbon agenda) andin the medium-term budgetary posi-tion (in particular, fiscal consolidationefforts in �good times,� debt sustaina-bility, public investment) and any otherfactors which, in the opinion of theMember State concerned, are rele-vant. These other factors comprise e.g.the cost of contributions to fosterinternational solidarity and to achiev-ing European policy goals, notablythe unification of Europe. These costsrefer mainly to the cost of German uni-fication, but also the costs of reformingEastern European economies and thevolume of net payments to the EUbudget.

29 The budgetary position should return to the adjustment path toward the MTO or to the MTO within the periodcovered by the stability or convergence program.

30 However, these reforms cannot completely guarantee a lower future pension payment burden for the government.31 Council Regulation (EC) No 1056/2005 Article 1 (1) �. . .if the excess over the reference value results from a

negative annual GDP volume growth rate or from an accumulated loss of output during a protracted period of verylow annual GDP volume growth relative to its potential.�

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 91�

Page 15: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Just like for the review to assessattainment of the medium-term objec-tive, the cost of pension reforms istaken into account for the decision onwhether there is an excessive deficit.Consideration using a linear degressiveformula will be given to the net cost ofthe reform for the initial five yearsafter a Member State has introduceda funded system.32 If the net cost causesthe actual deficit ratio to exceed 3% ofGDP only by a small margin, the deficitcannot be considered excessive, or anexcessive deficit can be considered tohave been corrected.

The reference value providing for adebt ratio of 60% or less of GDP hasbeen accorded a greater importancein the new SGP.33 The size of thenational debt ratios influences the size

of the respective countries� medium-term objectives. Under Article 104 ofthe Treaty, government debt ratiosabove 60% of GDP would have to besufficiently diminishing and approach-ing the reference value at a satisfactorypace. �Sufficiently diminishing� wasnever defined in detail. Under thereformed SGP, the Member Statesagreed to take into account both mac-roeconomic conditions (GDP growth)and gross debt for the concept of a �suf-ficiently diminishing� debt ratio inqualitative terms. The Ecofin Councilis entitled to formulate recommenda-tions on the debt dynamics in its opin-ions on the stability and convergenceprograms that the Member States arerequired to submit every year.

32 Consideration will be given to 100% (first year), 80%, 60%, 40% and 20%, respectively, of the net cost of thereform.

33 In principle, under Article 104 of the Treaty, exceeding the reference value for the debt ratio could entail a procedurelike the excessive deficit procedure. However, this was in fact never considered, as the SGP focuses on the deficit ratio.

34 These deadlines were not enforceable, though.

Key Changes at a GlanceOLD NEW

Preventive Arm Preventive ArmMedium-term objective:Cyclically adjusted budget balances Cyclically adjusted budget balance, net of one-off and

temporary measuresApplicable to all Member States: balance of —0.5% tosurplus

Country-specific: range between —1% of GDPand surplus

Adjustment path:At least 0.5% of GDP (euro area) Average of 0.5% of GDP depending on the state of the

business cycle (euro area and ERM II)Corrective Arm Corrective ArmExceptional circumstancesSevere economic downturn:Growth rate: principally less than —2% /less than —0.75% Negative growth or negative output gap for a sustained

period of low growthOther relevant circumstances:Extent of government investment relative to the govern-ment deficit, medium-term economic and budgetaryposition, other factors which are relevant in the opinion ofthe Member State concernedSystemic pension reforms

Deadlines:Clear deadlines for procedure steps and in particular forthe correction of the excessive deficit34

General extension of the deadlines for procedures and forthe correction of the excessive deficit by allowing for therepetition of procedure steps

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

92 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 16: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

The reform of the SGP also coversthe EDP deadlines. These deadlines —for the individual procedure stepsand for the period granted to correctan excessive deficit — have beenextended. Moreover, in the new SGP,Member States in excessive deficit haveto make a minimum fiscal effort everyyear. The required improvement of thecyclically adjusted balance (net of one-off and temporary measures) is at least0.5% of GDP as a benchmark in orderto correct the excessive deficit withinthe deadline set.

As a rule, the deadline for correc-tion of an excessive deficit is one yearafter its identification, but, in case ofspecial circumstances, a two-year dead-line may be granted. Moreover, a givendeadline may be extended if unex-pected adverse economic events occurduring the period during which anexcessive deficit is to be corrected.The prerequisite for such extension isthat the Member State must have takenaction in compliance with the recom-mendation of the European Commis-sion. Generally, new Member Statesmay be granted longer deadlines forthe correction of excessive deficits, asmay Member States which implementsystemic pension reforms.

7 Unresolved Interpreta-tion Issues of theReformed SGP

The reformed SGP has also attractedconsiderable criticism, above allbecause it is more complex than itspredecessor. The greater flexibilityand the stronger economic foundationof the new SGP have come at the costof transparency and simplicity. Thisreflects the fact that the new SGP hastried to strike a balance betweenconsolidation requirements and the

demand for sound fiscal policies onthe one hand and country-specific eco-nomic developments and public debtlevels on the other hand. The assess-ment of national budget policies bythe European Commission and theEcofin Council has to take into accountmedium-term economic develop-ments, i.e. the development of outputrelative to potential output. Thus,cyclical impacts on budget develop-ments will henceforth play a moreimportant role in the assessment, asdo structural measures and publicinvestment. However, this approachentails new definition and measure-ment problems, which contradict thedemand for transparency and simplic-ity. The quantification of unobservablevariables such as potential growth andthe resulting output gap, variableswhich are crucial for the calculationof cyclically adjusted balances, involvethe greatest uncertainties. Even theuse of a uniform method cannot elimi-nate these problems, but it can guaran-tee that all Member States are treatedas equitably as possible.

The reformed SGP is based on anumber of concepts, principles andvariables that had not been fully clari-fied by January 2006. To ensure thatthe SGP is applied consistently andcoherently in the future rather thanin an ad hoc manner, expert discus-sions were held to clarify the followingaspects:¥ Specification of what in fact consti-

tutes exceptional circumstances ofan �accumulated loss of output duringa protracted period of very low annualGDP volume growth relative to itspotential�:35 Here, both the dura-tion (�protracted period�) and theseverity of the economic downturn(�very low annual GDP volume

35 Council Regulation No 1056/2005 Article 2(2).

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 93�

Page 17: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

growth relative to its potential�) mustbe clarified. The definitions mustbe chosen very carefully to prevent�exceptional� circumstances frombecoming the rule.

¥ Definition of the terms �one-off�and �temporary measures�: Adjustingfiscal positions for such measures isintended to encourage MemberStates to base their consolidationstrategies on sustainable measures.Moulin (2005) shows that in thepast countries have typicallyresorted heavily to one-off meas-ures when they were close to the3% reference value and duringeconomic downswings. Cases inpoint are Portugal, Italy andGreece.Moreover, the definition of one-offmeasures given in the Code ofConduct (�one-off and temporarymeasures are measures having a tran-sitory budgetary effect that does notlead to a sustained change in thebudgetary position�) leaves substan-tial room for interpretation, whichis why the European Commissionsuggested drawing up a list of meas-ures for which fiscal positionsshould be adjusted.Furthermore, taking into accountone-off and temporary measuresin the assessment of the structuralbudget situation changes the incen-tive structure for using short-termmeasures. Up until now, MemberStates have resorted to temporarydeficit reduction measures aboveall to make their fiscal positionsappear rosier than they actuallywere. Now, they have an incentiveto conceal their true structuralbudget situation by depicting struc-tural deficit-increasing measures astemporary measures. Hence, thechanged incentive structure shouldlead to a restrictive acceptance of

temporary deficit-increasing meas-ures.

¥ Specification of the term �economicgood times�: The key indicator of�good times� is a positive outputgap but, as agreed in the Code ofConduct, the change in the outputgap shall also be given due consid-eration. Additionally taking intoaccount the output gap changeshas the purpose of preventing strictconsolidation demands duringperiods of below-average growthsimply because the output gap ispositive. The Code of Conduct,moreover, links the concept of�good times� to the idea of �tax elas-ticities,� which have also yet to beclearly defined. Finally, the diffi-culty in clearly defining �goodtimes� is compounded by what isreferred to as the �real time prob-lem.� What this means is that theex ante assessment of cyclical con-ditions (output gap) at times devi-ates quite strongly from the ex postsituation.

¥ The definition of �effective action�and �compliance with recommenda-tions and notices�: Under the newSGP, the deadlines for eliminatingthe excessive deficit may beextended provided that MemberStates have respected the recom-mendations of the Council butwere prevented from reachingtheir target by unexpected adverseeconomic events. In this respect,the difficulty in implementing theSGP lies in the ability to recognizewhether the measures of the Mem-ber States are sufficient andwhether they are in line with therecommendations. A purely quali-tative analysis of the cyclicallyadjusted balances can only providea guide and must be corroboratedby additional indicators.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

94 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 18: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

¥ Definition of �structural reforms�:The new SGP singles out structuralreforms which cost in the short runbut have a positive long-run effecton Member States. In this context,the question of which structuralreforms fulfill these criteria arises.In addition, measurement prob-lems arise because the long-termbenefits of reforms are difficult todetermine. This also applies tostructural pension reforms, whichare specially emphasized by thenew SGP.

¥ Definition of the �country-specificMTOs�: It is still unclear to whatextent and how the country-spe-cific costs of population aging andhence implicit liabilities should betaken into account in determiningthe medium-term objectives. Thisissue is to be clarified in the courseof 2006.

In assessing the stability and conver-gence programs of Member States withregard to compliance with the MTOs,the European Commission and theEcofin Council must evaluate whetherMember States have met their objec-tives adequately and consistently. Ifnecessary, they can urge the MemberStates to adjust their MTOs. This provi-sion is intended to ensure equitabletreatment of all Member States.

8 A Critical Review ofEarly Experience andConclusions

The reformed SGP addresses variouscomplaints directed at the originalframework, above all criticism of a uni-form medium-term budget target forall Member States regardless of coun-try-specific growth conditions, the sizeof the debt ratio as a percentage ofGDP and the challenge of populationaging. Moreover the reform deals withthe reproach that the SGP did not pro-

vide enough incentives for an anticycli-cal budget policy supportive of short-term growth and for a policy thatstrengthened the long-term growthpotential.

Opting to emphasize the country-specific situation more strongly makessense in principle because a uniformdebt target can trigger completely dif-ferent debt dynamics in countries withdifferent growth performances. Thecountry-specific component nowallows Member States with a lowerdebt ratio and a higher growth poten-tial greater leeway for budgetary policyand hence more scope for structuralreforms that can help improve thelong-term sustainability of publicfinances.

The required path of adjustmenttoward the MTO has also been revisedin a manner that should, in principle,discourage procyclical policies. Itremains to be seen whether thechanges to the SGP are in fact suppor-tive of a budget policy that is symme-trically balanced across the businesscycle.

Moreover, the stronger focus onunderlying structural budget develop-ments aims at encouraging MemberStates to take permanent rather thanone-off or temporary consolidationmeasures.

The disadvantage of the changes tothe preventive arm of the SGP is that thenew design raises methodologicalissues that render implementation inline with the intention of the reformedSGP more difficult. Furthermore,greater country-specific room formaneuver with regard to the MTOsreduces the safety margin to the refer-ence value, increasing the risk of anexcessive deficit. Determining thelong-term fiscal advantages and theshort-term fiscal burdens that struc-tural reforms may create also involves

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 95�

Page 19: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

substantial methodological problems.While the differentiation across coun-tries strengthens the preventive armbecause the Member States will hope-fully embrace the reformed SGP morewholeheartedly, the reformed SGP isalso less simple, less straightforwardand less transparent. Consequently, itbecomes harder to treat MemberStates equitably, and the scope forimplementing the SGP less strictly isgreater.

The reform of the corrective armmarks a move towards more flexiblestandards and a greater emphasis ondiscretion. The new rules relax theconditions for enhanced surveillanceunder the EDP. The modification ofthe �exceptional circumstances� clausefor the existence of an excessive deficitincreases the likelihood that deficits inexcess of the reference value will notbe considered excessive, even thoughit is understood that such breachesshould remain small and temporary.The clarification of these options,which are in fact not new, increasesthe pressure on the Member Statesand the Ecofin Council, however. Thereformed SGP also allows for more lee-way in the timeframe for correctingexcessive deficits, even though the�normal� one-year deadline followingits identification has remained in place.There is also now more room for grant-ing additional time to remedy an exces-sive deficit, and steps of the proceduremay be repeated. The corrective armstill allows for a procyclical policy tohelp in correcting an excessive deficit;this procyclicality tends to be evenstronger on account of the eliminationof one-off measures, as the cases up tonow have shown.

First experience with the reformedSGP indicates that the cyclical situationnow plays a greater role in determiningdeadlines for the correction of an

excessive deficit. In this vein, both Italyand Portugal were given a longer dead-line to correct their excessive deficits(annex tables 3a and 3b) on accountof �special circumstances.� With regardto Italy, the Ecofin Council declared inJuly 2005 that Italy needed to correctits excessive deficit only by 2007, asthe weak economy would have to betaken into account in implementingthe severe consolidation requirement.Italy was called on to take the necessarymeasures to ensure a cumulative reduc-tion in the cyclically adjusted deficit,net of one-off and other temporarymeasures, of at least 1.6% of GDP by2007 relative to 2005 levels, and todeliver at least half of this correctionin 2006.

In the case of Portugal, the EcofinCouncil again decided that an excessivedeficit existed and initiated an EDP inSeptember 2005. Also on account of�special circumstances,� Portugal wasgiven a deadline up to 2008 to correctits excessive deficit. Both the size of theexcessive deficit (after the ending ofsignificant one-off measures), and con-sequently the size of the adjustment tobring the deficit below the referencevalue, as well as weak GDP growthwere cited as special circumstances.Portugal has committed itself to ach-ieving a structural improvement of1.6% of GDP in 2006 and of 0.75%each in 2007 and 2008.

Indirectly, though, this concession— the higher the excessive deficit, thelonger the deadline to eliminate it —is a questionable signal. Additionally,Portugal was rewarded for havingdeclared that it would no longer resortto temporary measures. This approachreveals a possible weakness of thereformed SGP, as the Treaty actuallypermits both structural and temporarymeasures to remedy an excessive defi-cit.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

96 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 20: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

The decisions about further proce-dural steps in the cases of Germany,France and Greece (originally sched-uled for January 2006) are particularlycrucial for the evaluation of thereformed SGP. Germany and Francehad obligated themselves to correcttheir excessive deficits by 2005. In thecase of Germany, the European Com-mission concluded in its Autumn2005 Forecast that the country would,nonetheless, post a deficit in excess of3% in 2005 as well as in 2006. Whilethe excess in 2005 may be partlyexplained by weaker-than-expectedeconomic growth, the consolidationmeasures taken may also have beeninsufficient to reach the agreed target.This means that under the SGP, theEuropean Commission would have tomake a recommendation according toArticle 104 (8) of the Treaty, whichwould establish that no effective actionhad been taken within the period laiddown. Moreover, a recommendationto give notice to Germany underArticle 109 (9) of the Treaty wouldbe in order.36

In the case of France, the EuropeanCommission also expected the exces-sive deficit to continue to exist(Autumn 2005 Forecast). However,the excess is small at 0.2 percentagepoint, and can be attributed toweaker-than-expected growth. Conse-quently, there is no need to make rec-ommendations pursuant to Articles108 (8) and 108 (9) of the Treaty. How-ever, France did not produce theagreed minimum improvement of itscyclically adjusted budget deficit;moreover, it is uncertain whetherthere will be a further improvementin 2006.

In July 2004 the Ecofin Councilmoreover identified an excessive defi-cit in Greece. In February 2005,Greece was given notice under Article104 (9) of the Treaty to take measuresto reduce the deficit by 2006. TheAutumn 2005 Forecast of the EuropeanCommission anticipates that Greecewill exceed the reference value forthe deficit, which, however, will beclose to the agreed target becauseGreece availed itself of substantial tem-porary measures. But the initial situa-tion has changed on account of anothersubstantial data revision. Now, the Eco-fin Council must determine whetherGreece is fulfilling its obligationsunder the EDP and whether it hastaken sufficient action to correct itsexcessive deficit in 2006. If this is notthe case, sanctions would have to beapplied to Greece.

New Member States with an exces-sive deficit have been given until 2008to correct their excessive deficits (as�special circumstances� are deemedto apply to them from the outset, withthe exception of Cyprus (2005), Malta(2006), Poland (2007) and Slovakia(2007)).

The assessment of Hungarydeserves special mention: Initially,the Ecofin Council allowed Hungarya deadline until 2008 to correct itsexcessive deficit. Upon determiningthat Hungary had taken insufficientmeasures, it subsequently issued anew recommendation under Article104 (7) of the Treaty in March 2005.While the new recommendationretained the 2008 deadline for deficitcorrection, it contained a supplemen-tary obligation for Hungary to reachinterim budget targets. In November

36 Council On March 1, 2006, the European Commission recommended to the Ecofin Council to give Germany noticeunder Article 104 (9) of the Treaty to take measures to correct the excessive deficit by 2007 at the latest. The EcofinCouncil adopted the relevant decision on march 14, 2006.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 97�

Page 21: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

2005, Hungary was once more foundnot to have taken effective measuresto reduce its excessive deficit (pur-suant to Article 104 (8) of the Treaty).In January 2006, finally, Hungary wasasked to moreover submit a new con-vergence program by September2006 because it had not specified themeasures it would take to remedy itsexcessive deficit — which implies yetanother recommendation by the Eco-fin Council under Article 104 (7) ofthe Treaty.

The United Kingdom, finally, hasbeen posting a deficit in excess of the3% reference value since 2003. InMarch 2004, the European Commis-sion drew up a report that rejectedthe existence of an excessive deficiton the grounds that the excess overthe reference value was �small and tem-porary.� After the United Kingdomannounced in its notification of autumn

2005 that it would exceed the refer-ence value marginally also in the fiscalyear 2004/05, the European Commis-sion drafted another report on thebudgetary situation in the United King-dom in September 2005. The Autumn2005 Forecast of the European Com-mission also signaled that the deficitwould remain above the referencevalue in 2005 and 2006, whereuponthe Ecofin Council identified the exis-tence of an excessive deficit in January2006 and recommended that theUnited Kingdom put an end to the sit-uation of excessive deficit by the fiscalyear 2006/07.

Overall, one may conclude fromthe experience up to now that breachesof the deficit reference values will con-tinue for some time. Budgetary disci-pline will tend to suffer from thesebreaches, and this would hamper stabil-ity-oriented monetary policymaking.

ReferencesAlesina, A. and R. Perotti. 1995. Fiscal Expansions and Adjustments in OECD Countries. In: Economic

Policy 21. 205—248.

Alesina, A., S. Ardagna, R. Perotti and F. Schiantarelli. 2002. Fiscal Policy, Profits and Investment.

In: The American Economic Review 92(3). 571—589.

Allsopp, C. and M. J. Artis. 2003. The Assessment: EMU, Four Years on. In: Oxford Review of

Economic Policy 19(1). 1—29.

Almunia, J. 2005. Fiscal Discipline and the Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact. Paper prepared for

the Conference hosted by National Banks of Poland and Hungary. Warsaw. June.

Artis, M. J. and M. Buti. 2001. Setting Medium-Term Fiscal Targets in EMU. In: Brunila, A., M. Buti and

D. Franco (eds.). 2001. The Stability and Growth Pact. The Architecture of Fiscal Policy in EMU. Basing-

stoke: Palgrave. 185—203.

Balassone, F. and D. Franco. 2000. Public Investment, the Stability Pact and the Golden Rule. In: Fiscal

Studies 21(2). 207—229.

Balassone, F. and D. Franco. 2001. The SGP and the Golden Rule. In: Brunila, A., M. Buti and D. Franco

(eds.). 2001. The Stability and Growth Pact. The Architecture of Fiscal Policy in EMU. Basingstoke:

Palgrave. 371—393.

Balassone, F. and M. Francese. 2004. Cyclical Asymmetry in Fiscal Policy, Debt Accumulation and the

Treaty of Maastricht. Banca d�Italia. Research Department.

Ballbriga, F. and C. Martinez-Mongay. 2005. Sustainability of EU Public Finances. In: European

Economy 225. European Commission. Brussels.

Banca d�Italia. 2001. Fiscal Rules. Rom. Workshop Proceedings.

Barro, R. J. 1974. Are Government Bonds Net Wealth? In: Journal of Political Economy 87. November/

December. 1095—1118.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

98 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 22: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Barro, R. J. 1979. On the Determination of Public Debt. In: Journal of Political Economy 87. October.

940—971.

Bayer, K., A. Katterl, P. Kutos, P. Part, A. Pregesbauer and R. Wieser. 2000. Aktuelle Heraus-

forderungen fu‹r die o‹sterreichische Wirtschaftspolitik in der WWU. BMF. Working Paper 4.

Bean, C. 1998. Comment on Eichengreen, B. and C. Wyplosz. 1998. The Stability Pact: More than a Minor

Nuisance. In: Economic Policy 26.

Beetsma, R. 2001. Does EMU Need a Stability Pact? In: Brunila, A., M. Buti and D. Franco (eds.). 2001.

The Stability and Growth Pact. The Architecture of Fiscal Policy in EMU. Basingstoke: Palgrave. 23—53.

Begg, I. and W. Schelkle. 2004. The Pact Is Dead: Long Live the Pact. National Institute Economic

Review 189. July. 86—98.

Bertola, G. and A. Drazen. 1993. Trigger Points and Budget Cuts: Explaining the Effects of Fiscal Aus-

terity. In: The American Economic Review 83. 1170—1188.

Blanchard, O. 1985. Debt, Deficits and Finite Horizons. In: Journal of Political Economy 93(2). 223—247.

Blanchard, O. 1990. Comment on Giavazzi and Pagano. In: Blanchard, O. and F. Singer (eds.). NBER

Macroeconomics Annual 5. Cambridge Mass: The MIT Press. 111—122.

Blanchard, O. and F. Singer (eds.). 1990. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 5. Cambridge Mass: The

MIT Press.

Blanchard, O. and F. Giavazzi. 2004. Improving the SGP through a Proper Accounting of Public Invest-

ment. CEPR Discussion Paper 4220. London.

Brunila, A., M. Buti and D. Franco (eds.). 2001. The Stability and Growth Pact — The Architecture of

Fiscal Policy in EMU. Basingstoke: Palgrave.

Buiter, W. 1985. A Guide to Public Sector Debt and Deficits. In: Economic Policy 1. 13—79.

Buiter, W., C. Corsetti and N. Roubini. 1993. Excessive Deficits: Sense and Nonsense in the Treaty

of Maastricht. In: Economic Policy 8. 57—100.

Buiter, W. 2001. Notes on �A Code for Fiscal Stability�. In: Oxford Economic Papers 53. 1—19.

Buiter, W. and C. Grafe. 2004. Patching Up the Pact. Suggestions for Enhancing Fiscal Sustainability and

Macroeconomic Stability in an Enlarged European Union. In: Economics in Transition 12(1). 67—102.

Buti, M., D. Franco and H. Ongena. 1998. Fiscal Discipline and Flexibility in EMU: The Implementation

of the Stability and Growth Pact. In: Oxford Review of Economic Policy 14(3). 81—97.

Buti, M. and G. Giudice. 2001. Maastricht�s Fiscal Rules at Ten: An Assessment. In: Journal of Common

Market Studies 40. 823—848.

Buti, M. and A. Sapir (eds.). 2002. EMU and Economic Policy in Europe. The Challenges of the Early

Years. European Commission and Edward Elgar : Cheltenham.

Buti, M., S. Eijffinger and D. Franco. 2003. Revisiting EMU�s Stability Pact: A Pragmatic Way Forward.

In: Oxford Review of Economic Policy 19(1). 99—111.

Buti, M. and L. Pench. 2004. Why Do Large Countries Flout the Stability Pact? And What Can Be

Done About It? In: Journal of Common Market Studies 42. 1025—1032.

Buti, M. und D. Franco. 2005. Fiscal Policy in Economic and Monetary Union. Theory, Evidence and

Institutions.

Buti, M., S. Eijffinger and D. Franco. 2005. The Stability Pact Pains: A Forward-Looking Assessment

of the Reform Debate. CEPR Discussion Paper 5216. London.

Calmfors, L. and G. Corsetti. 2003. How to Reform Europe�s Fiscal Policy Framework. In: World Eco-

nomics Journal 1.

Calmfors, L. 2005. What Remains of the Stability and Growth Pact and What Next? In: Swedish Institute

for European Policy Studies 8.

Canzeroni, M. B. and B. T. Diba. 2001. The SGP: Delicate Balance or Albatross? In: Brunila, A., M. Buti

and D. Franco (eds.). The Stability and Growth Pact. Basingstoke: Palgrave. 53—74.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 99�

Page 23: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Casella, A. 2001. Tradable Deficit Permits. In: Brunila, A., M. Buti and D. Franco (eds.). The Stability and

Growth Pact — The Architecture of Fiscal Policy in EMU. Basingstoke: Palgrave. 394—413.

CEPS. 2004. The Nine Lives of the Stability Pact. A special report of the CEPS Macroeconomic Policy

Group. Centre of European Policy Studies.

Code of Conduct. 2005. Specifications on the Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact and

Guidelines on the Format and Content of Stability and Convergence Programmes.

Collignon, S. 2003. The European Republic. The Federal Trust. London.

Costello, D. 2001. The SGP: How Did Weg Get There? In: Brunila, A., M. Buti and D. Franco (eds.).

2001. The Stability and Growth Pact. The Architecture of Fiscal Policy in EMU. Basingstoke: Palgrave.

106—138.

Council of the European Union. 2005. Improving the Implementation of the Stability and Growth

Pact. Brussels. March 21.

Council Regulation (EC) No 1055/2005 of 27 June 2005. Amending Regulation (EC) No 1466/97

on the Strengthening of the Surveillance of Budgetary Positions and the Surveillance and Coordination

of Economic Policies.

Council Regulation (EC) No 1056/2005 of 27 June 2005. Amending Regulation (EC) No 1467/97

on Speeding Up and Clarifying the Implementation of the Excessive Deficit Procedure.

Creel, J. 2003. Ranking Fiscal Policy Rules: the Golden Rule of Public Finance vs. the Stability and Growth

Pact. OFCE, Economic Research Department.

De Grauwe, P. 2004. Towards an Intelligent Stability and Growth Pact. Position paper prepared for the

Euro 50 meeting in Brussels. May 3—4.

Deroose, S. 2004. The Commission�s Approach on Strengthening and Clarifying the SGP. Presentation

given at the Workshop on Fiscal Rules. December. Madeira.

Deroose, S. and S. Langedijk. 2005. Improving the Stability and Growth Pact: The Commission�s

Three Pillar Approach. European Commission. Occasional Paper 15.

Deutsche Bundesbank. 2005. Die A‹ nderungen am Stabilita‹ts- und Wachstumspakt. In: April Monthly

Bulletin.

Easterly, W. and S. Rebelo. 1993. Fiscal Policy and Economic Growth: An Empirical Investigation. In:

Journal of Monetary Economics 32(2). 417—458.

ECB. 1999. The Implementation of the Stability and Growth Pact. Monthly Bulletin. May.

ECB. 2004. Entwicklung der o‹ ffentlichen Finanzen. December Monthly Bulletin.

ECB. 2005. Die Reform des Stabilita‹ts- und Wachstumspakts. August Monthly Bulletin.

EEAG. 2003. Report on the European Economy 2003. Munich. European Advisory Group at CESifo. Feb-

ruary.

EEAG. 2004. Report on the European Economy 2004. Mu‹nchen. European Advisory Group at CESifo.

Eichengreen, B. and C. Wyplosz. 1998. The Stability Pact: More than a Minor Nuisance. In: Economic

Policy 26. 67—113.

Eichengreen, B. 2003. The Future of the European Growth and Stability Pact. CESifo Forum 2/2003.

European Commission. 2001. Public Finances in EMU 2001.

European Commission. 2002. Strengthening the Coordination of Budgetary Policies. COM (2002)

668. November.

European Commission. 2002a. Public Finances in EMU 2002.

European Commission. 2003. Public Finances in EMU 2003.

European Commission. 2004. Public Finances in EMU 2004.

European Commission. 2005. Public Finances in EMU 2005.

European Commission. 2005a. Methodological Considerations for Setting Country Specific Medium-

term Budgetary Objectives before Implicit Liabilities are Taken into Account. Note for the Alternates

of the Economic and Financial Committee.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

100 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 24: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

European Commission. 2005b. Stock Taking of Discussions on Concepts and Definitions in the

Reformed SGP. Note for the Alternates of the Economic and Financial Committee.

Fata«s, A. and I. Mihov. 2003. On Constraining Fiscal Policy Discretion in EMU. In: Oxford Review of

Economic Policy 19(1).

Fata«s, A. 2005. Is There a Case for Sophisticated Balanced-budget Rules? OECD Economics Department.

September.

Feldstein, M. 2002. The Role For Discretionary Fiscal Policy in a Low Interest Rate Environment. NBER

Working Paper 9203. September.

Flores, E., G. Giudice and A. Turrini. 2005. The Framework for Fiscal Policy in EMU: What Future

after Five Years of Experience? European Commission. Economic Paper 223. March.

Franco, D., F. Balassone and M. Francese. 2002. Fiscal Policy in Europe: The Role of Fiscal Rules. In:

National Tax Association. Proceedings. Ninety-fifth Annual Conference 2002. Orlando. Florida.

Franco, D., R. M. Marin and S. Zotteri. 2005. Pension Expenditure Projections, Pension Liabilities and

European Fiscal Rules. In: Les finances publiques: defies a« moyen et long termes. Papers and Proceed-

ings of the 16e«me Congre«s des Economistes belges de langue francaise. Centre Interuniversitaire de

Formation Permanente (CIFoP). 287—342.

Gali, J. and R. Perotti. 2003. Fiscal Policy and Monetary Integration in Europe. NBER Working Paper

9773. June.

Giavazzi, F. and M. Pagano. 1990. Can Severe Fiscal Contractions be Expansionary? Tales of Two Small

European Countries. In: Blanchard, O. and S. Fischer (Hrsg.). NBER Macroeconomics Annual 5.

Cambridge Mass: MIT Press. 75—111.

Gros, D., T. Mayer and A. Ubide. 2003. The Nine Lives of the Stability and Growth Pact. Centre for

European Policy Studies.

HM Treasury. 2003. The Stability and Growth Pact: A Discussion Paper. London.

Hughes-Hallett, A., J. Lewis and J. von Hagen. 2004. Fiscal Policy in Europe. 1991—2003: An

Evidence-Based Analysis. CEPR. London.

IMF. 2001. Selected Euro-area Countries: Rules-based Fiscal Policy and Job-rich Growth in France,

Germany, Italy and Spain. IMF Country Report 01/203. October.

McDermott, C. J . and R. F. Westcott. 1996. An Empirical Analysis of Fiscal Adjustment. IMF Staff

Paper 43. 725—753.

Moulin, L. 2005. One-off and Temporary Measures in Budgetary Surveillance. Presentation held at the

ECB Public Finance Workshop. December 6.

Nowotny, E. 1999. Der o‹ ffentliche Sektor, Einfu‹hrung in die Finanzwissenschaft. 4th revised edition.

Springer.

Part, P. 1998. Der Stabilita‹ts- und Wachstumspakt. In: Das o‹ ffentliche Haushaltswesen in O‹ sterreich

1—2/98. 38—46.

Part, P. 2000. Entwicklung der Definition fu‹r das mittelfristige Budgetziel in den Stabilita‹ts- und Konver-

genzprogrammen. Bundesministerium fu‹r Finanzen. Working Paper 8.

Perotti, R. 1999. Fiscal Policy in Good Times and Bad. In: Quarterly Journal of Economics 114. 1399—1436.

Perotti, R. 2005. The Empirical Case Against the Golden Rule of Government Investment. OECD.

Economics Department. ECO/GEN(2005)2.

Pisani-Ferry, J. 2002. Fiscal Discipline and Policy Coordination in the Eurozone: Assessment and Propos-

als. Paper prepared for the Group of Economic Policy Analysis of the European Commission. April.

Posen, A. 2005. Can Rubinomics Work in the Eurozone? In: Posen, A. (ed.). The Euro at Five: Ready for a

Global Role? Institute for International Economics. Special Report 18. Washington.

Singer, O. 2005. Der Europa‹ische Stabilita‹ts- und Wachstumspakt: Sachstand und Reformdebatte. In:

Wissenschaftliche Dienste des Deutschen Bundestages. Info-Brief.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 101�

Page 25: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Stark, J. 2001. The Genesis of a Pact. In: Brunila, A., M. Buti and D. Franco (eds.). The Stability and Growth

Pact. The Architecture of Fiscal Policy in EMU. Basingstoke: Palgrave.

Sutherland, A. 1997. Fiscal Crisis and Aggregate Demand: Can High Public Debt Reverse the Effects of

Fiscal Policy? In: Journal of Public Economics 65(2). 147—162.

Taylor, J. B. 2000. Reassessing Discretionary Fiscal Policy. In: Journal of Economic Perspectives 14. 21—36.

Url, T. 1997. Die Kosten des Pakts fu‹r Stabilita‹t und Wachstum. In: WIFO-Monatsbericht 6. 373—383.

Von Hagen, J. and G. B. Wolff. 2004. What Do Deficits Tell Us About Debt? Empirical Evidence on

Creative Accounting with Fiscal Rules in the EU. Deutsche Bundesbank. Discussion Paper 38.

Walton, D. 2002. Europe�s Stability Pact: In Need of New Clothes. Goldman Sachs. Global Economics

Paper 81.

Walton, D. 2004. How Should the Stability and Growth Pact Be Reformed? Three Points of View on the

Future of Europe�s Fiscal Pact. In: Finance & Development. June.

Wyplosz, C. 2002. Fiscal Policy: Rules or Institutions? Paper prepared for the Group of Economic

Analysis of the European Commission. April.

Wyplosz, C. 2005. Fiscal Policy: Institutions versus Rules. National Institute Review 191. January. 65—78.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

102 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 26: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Annex

Table 1a

Initiation of Excessive Deficit Procedures in the EU-15 since 1999

France Germany Greece Italy

2002: �3.2 2002: �3.8 2000: �4.1 2003: �3.22003: �4.2 2003: �4.1 2001: �6.1 2004: �3.22004: �3.6 2004: �3.7 2002: �4.9 2005:1�4.32005:1�3.2 2005:1�3.9 2003: �5.7

2004: �6.62005:1�3.7

Report of the EuropeanCommission under Article104 (3): April 2, 2003

Report of the EuropeanCommission under Article104 (3): November 19,2002

Report of the EuropeanCommission under Article104 (3): May 19, 2004

Report of the EuropeanCommission under Article104 (3): June 7, 2004

Opinion and recommen-dation of the EuropeanCommission underArticles 104 (5), 104 (6),104 (7): May 7, 2003

Opinion and recommen-dation of the EuropeanCommission underArticles 104 (5), 104 (6),104 (7): January 8, 2003

Opinion and recommen-dation of the EuropeanCommission underArticles 104 (5), 104 (6),104 (7): June 24, 2004

Opinion and recommen-dation of the EuropeanCommission underArticles 104 (5), 104 (6),104 (7): June 29, 2005

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recommen-dation under 104 (7)) ofthe Ecofin Council on theinitiation of a procedure tocorrect an excessive deficitby 2004: June 3, 2003

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recommen-dation under 104 (7)) ofthe Ecofin Council on theinitiation of a procedure tocorrect an excessive deficitby 2004: January 21, 2003

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recommen-dation under 104 (7)) ofthe Ecofin Council on theinitiation of a procedure tocorrect an excessive deficitby 2005: July 5, 2004

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recommen-dation under 104 (7)) ofthe Ecofin Council on theinitiation of a procedure tocorrect an excessive deficitby 2007: July 28, 2005

Assessment by the Euro-pean Commission that themeasures taken are inade-quate; recommendationunder Article 104 (8):October 8, 2003

Assessment by the Euro-pean Commission that themeasures taken are inade-quate; recommendationunder Article 104 (8):November 18, 2003

Assessment by the Euro-pean Commission that themeasures taken are inade-quate; recommendationunder Article 104 (8):December 22, 2004

Assessment by the Euro-pean Commission that themeasures taken are suffici-ent: March 14, 2006

Recommendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Article 104 (9) togive notice to France:October 21, 2003

Recommendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Article 104 (9), togive notice to Germany:November 18, 2003

Decision of the EcofinCouncil under Article104 (8) about the lack ofeffective action: January 18,2005

�Conclusions� of the EcofinCouncil instead of givingnotice and extension of thedeadline for correction to2005: November 25, 2003

�Conclusions� of the EcofinCouncil instead of givingnotice and extension of thedeadline for correction to2005: November 25, 2003

Recommendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Article 104(9) togive notice to Greece:February 9, 2005

Ruling of the EuropeanCourt of Justice: annulmentof the conclusions: July 13,2004

Ruling of the EuropeanCourt of Justice: annulmentof the conclusions: July 13,2004

Decision of the EcofinCouncil under Article104 (9) to give notice toGreece and to extend thedeadline for correction to2006: February 17, 2005

Communication of theEuropean Commissionabout the extension of thedeadline for correction ofthe excessive deficit to2005: December 14, 2004

Communication of theEuropean Commissionabout the extension of thedeadline for correction ofthe excessive deficit to2005: December 14, 2004

Decision of the EcofinCouncil to give Germanynotice under Article 104 (9)of the Treaty and to extendthe deadline for the cor-rection of the excessivedeficit: March 14, 2007

Source: Calmfors, 2005, S. 34ff; http://europa.eu.int/comm/economy__finance/about/activities/sgp/edp/edpfr__en.htm1 Forecast values, European Commission Autumn 2005 Forecast of November 2005.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 103�

Page 27: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Table 1a — continued

Netherlands Portugal 1 Portugal 2 United Kingdom

2003: �3.2 2001: �4.2 2005:1�6.0 2003: �3.32004: �3.12005:1�3.4

Report of the EuropeanCommission under Article104 (3): April 28, 2004

Report of the EuropeanCommission under Article104 (3): April 28, 2004

Report of the EuropeanCommission under Article104 (3): September 24,2002

Report of the EuropeanCommission under Article104 (3): June 22, 2005

Report of the EuropeanCommission under Article104 (3): September 21,2005

Opinion and recommen-dation of the EuropeanCommission underArticles 104 (5), 104 (6),104 (7): May 19, 2004

Opinion and recommen-dation of the EuropeanCommission underArticles 104 (5), 104 (6),104 (7): October 16, 2002

Opinion and recommen-dation of the EuropeanCommission underArticles 104 (5), 104 (6),104 (7): July 20, 2005

Opinion and recommen-dation of the EuropeanCommission underArticles 104 (5), 104 (6),104 (7): January 11, 2006

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recommen-dation under 104 (7)) ofthe Ecofin Council on theinitiation of a procedure tocorrect an excessive deficitby 2005: June 2, 2004

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recommen-dation under 104 (7)) ofthe Ecofin Council on theinitiation of a procedure tocorrect an excessive deficitby 2003: November 5,2002

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recommen-dation under 104 (7)) ofthe Ecofin Council on theinitiation of a procedure tocorrect an excessive deficitby 2008: October 7, 2005

Recommendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Article 104 (12) toconclude the EDP: May 18,2005

Recommendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Article 104 (12) toconclude the EDP: April 28,2004

Decision of the EcofinCouncil to conclude theEDP: June 7, 2005

Decision of the EcofinCouncil to conclude theEDP: May 11, 2004

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

104 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 28: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Table 1b

Initiation of Excessive Deficit Procedures in the New Member States since 2004

Cyprus Czech Republic Hungary Malta Poland Slovakia

2004: �4.1 2004: �3.0 2004: �5.4 2004: �5.1 2004: �3,9 2004: �3,12005:1�2.8 2005:1�3.2 2005:1�6.1 2005:1�4.2 2005:1�3,6 2005:1�4,1

Report of the EuropeanCommission underArticle 104 (3): May 12,2004

Report of the EuropeanCommission underArticle 104(3): May 12,2004

Report of the EuropeanCommission underArticle 104 (3): May 12,2004

Report of the EuropeanCommission underArticle 104 (3): May 12,2004

Report of the Euro-pean Commissionunder Article 104(3):May 12, 2004

Report of the Euro-pean Commissionunder Article 104 (3):May 12, 2004

Opinion and recom-mendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Articles 104 (5),104 (6), 104 (7): June24, 2004

Opinion and recom-mendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Articles 104 (5),104 (6), 104 (7): June24, 2002

Opinion and recom-mendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Articles 104 (5),104 (6), 104 (7): June24, 2002

OOpinion and recom-mendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Articles 104 (5),104 (6), 104 (7): June24, 2004

Opinion and recom-mendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Articles 104(5),104(6), 104(7): June24, 2004

Opinion and recom-mendation of theEuropean Commissionunder Articles 104 (5),104 (6), 104 (7): June24, 2004

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recom-mendation under104 (7)) of the EcofinCouncil on the initiationof a procedure tocorrect an excessivedeficit by 2005 and toprevent a further rise inthe debt ratio: July 5,2004

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recom-mendation under104 (7)) of the EcofinCouncil on the initiationof a procedure tocorrect an excessivedeficit by 2008: July 5,2004

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recom-mendation under104 (7)) of the EcofinCouncil on the initiationof a procedure tocorrect an excessivedeficit by 2008: July 5,2004

Decision under Article104(6) (and recom-mendation under104 (7)) of the EcofinCouncil on the initiationof a procedure tocorrect an excessivedeficit by 2006 and toprevent a further rise inthe debt ratio: July 5,2005

Decision under Article104(6) (and recom-mendation under104(7)) of the EcofinCouncil on the initia-tion of a procedure tocorrect an excessivedeficit by 2007: July 28,2005

Decision under Article104 (6) (and recom-mendation under104 (7)) of the EcofinCouncil on the initia-tion of a procedure tocorrect an excessivedeficit by 2008: July 5,2005

Assessment by theEuropean Commissionthat the measures takenare inadequate; recom-mendation underArticle 104 (8):December 22, 2004

Decision of the EcofinCouncil under Article104(8) about the lack ofeffective action: January18, 2005

Recommendation ofthe European Commis-sion under Article 104 (7):February 16, 2005

Recommendation ofthe European Commis-sion under Article104(7): March 8, 2005

Recommendation ofthe European Commis-sion under Article 104 (8):October 20, 2005

Decision of the EcofinCouncil under Article104 (8): November 8,2005

Source: Calmfors, 2005, S. 34ff; http://europa.eu.int/comm/economy—finance/about/activities/sgp/edp/edpfr—en.htm1 Forecast values, European Commission Autumn 2005 Forecast of November 2005.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 105�

Page 29: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Table 2a

Deficit Ratios1 in the EU Member States

% of GDP

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004

Belgium �6.8 �7.4 �8.0 �7.3 �5.0 �4.3 �3.8 �2.0 �0.7 �0.4 0.2 0.6 0.0 0.1 0.0Germany x �3.0 �2.5 �3.1 �2.4 �3.3 �3.4 �2.7 �2.2 �1.5 1.3 �2.9 �3.8 �4.1 �3.7Greece �15.4 �11.4 �11.1 �13.4 �9.4 �10.2 �7.4 �4.0 �2.5 �1.8 �4.1 �6.1 �4.9 �5.7 �6.6Spain x x x x x �6.6 �4.9 �3.2 �3.0 �1.2 �0.9 �0.5 �0.3 0.0 �0.1France �2.1 �2.4 �4.2 �6.0 �5.5 �5.5 �4.1 �3.0 �2.7 �1.8 �1.4 �1.6 �3.2 �4.2 �3.6Ireland �2.8 �2.9 �3.0 �2.7 �2.0 �2.1 �0.1 1.1 2.4 2.4 4.4 0.8 �0.4 0.2 1.4Italy �11.8 �11.7 �10.7 �10.3 �9.3 �7.6 �7.1 �2.7 �2.8 �1.7 �0.6 �3.2 �2.7 �3.2 �3.2Luxembourg 4.8 1.2 0.2 1.5 2.7 2.1 1.9 3.2 3.2 3.7 6.0 6.1 2.1 0.2 �0.6Netherlands �5.3 �2.7 �4.2 �2.8 �3.5 �4.2 �1.8 �1.1 �0.8 0.7 2.2 �0.2 �2.0 �3.2 �2.1Austria �2.4 �2.9 �1.9 �4.2 �4.9 �5.6 �3.9 �1.8 �2.3 �2.2 �1.5 0.1 �0.4 �1.2 �1.0Portugal �6.1 �8.1 �6.0 �8.9 �6.6 �4.5 �4.0 �3.0 �2.6 �2.8 �2.8 �4.2 �2.8 �2.9 �3.0Finland 5.3 �1.1 �5.6 �7.3 �5.7 �3.7 �3.2 �1.5 1.5 2.2 7.1 5.2 4.3 2.5 2.1EU-12 x x x x x �5.1 �4.3 �2.6 �2.2 �1.3 0.1 �1.9 �2.5 �3.0 �2.7

Denmark �1.0 �2.4 �3.3 �3.7 �3.2 �3.1 �1.9 �0.5 0.2 2.4 1.7 2.6 1.4 1.0 2.3Sweden x x x �11.6 �9.3 �7.0 �2.7 �0.9 1.8 2.5 5.1 2.5 �0.3 0.2 1.6United Kingdom �1.5 �2.8 �6.5 �8.0 �6.8 �5.7 �4.3 �2.0 0.2 1.0 3.8 0.7 �1.6 �3.3 �3.1EU-15 x x x x x �5.2 �4.2 �2.4 �1.6 �0.7 1.0 �1.2 �2.2 �2.9 �2.6

Source: Eurostat.1 Including UMTS license revenue.

Table 2b

Debt Ratios in the EU Member States

% of GDP

1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004

Belgium 129.2 130.6 132.2 137.9 135.9 134.0 130.2 124.8 119.6 114.8 109.1 108.0 105.4 100.0 95.7Germany x 40.4 42.9 46.9 49.3 57.0 59.8 61.0 60.9 61.2 60.2 59.6 61.2 64.8 66.4Greece 79.6 82.2 87.8 110.1 107.9 108.7 111.3 108.2 105.8 105.2 114.0 114.4 111.6 108.8 109.3Spain 43.6 44.3 46.8 58.4 61.1 63.9 68.1 66.6 64.6 63.1 61.1 56.3 53.2 49.4 46.9France 35.1 35.8 39.6 45.3 48.4 54.6 57.1 59.3 59.5 58.5 56.8 56.8 58.8 63.2 65.1Ireland 94.2 95.6 92.5 95.1 89.6 81.8 73.3 64.5 53.8 48.6 38.3 35.9 32.4 31.5 29.8Italy 97.2 100.8 108.1 118.7 124.8 124.3 123.1 120.5 116.7 115.5 111.2 110.9 108.3 106.8 106.5Luxembourg 5.4 4.6 5.5 6.8 6.3 6.7 7.2 6.8 6.3 5.9 5.5 6.7 6.8 6.7 6.6Netherlands 76.9 76.8 77.9 79.3 76.4 77.2 75.2 69.9 66.8 63.1 55.9 51.5 51.3 52.6 53.1Austria 56.1 56.1 55.8 60.5 63.4 67.9 67.6 63.8 64.2 66.5 67.0 67.0 66.7 65.1 64.3Portugal 58.3 60.7 54.4 59.1 62.1 64.3 62.9 59.1 55.0 54.3 53.3 53.6 56.1 57.7 59.4Finland 14.2 22.6 40.5 55.9 58.0 57.1 57.1 54.1 48.6 47.0 44.6 43.6 42.3 45.2 45.1EU-12 x 58.5 60.3 66.2 68.9 73.6 75.2 74.9 74.2 72.7 70.4 69.3 69.2 70.4 70.8

Denmark 63.1 64.0 69.4 81.1 77.4 73.2 69.7 65.7 61.2 57.7 52.3 48.0 47.6 45.0 43.2Sweden x x x x 73.9 73.7 73.5 70.6 68.1 62.7 52.8 54.3 52.4 52.0 51.1UnitedKingdom 34.0 34.4 39.2 45.4 48.6 51.8 52.3 50.8 47.7 45.1 42.0 38.7 38.2 39.7 41.5EU-15 x x x x 66.4 70.8 72.6 71.0 68.9 67.9 64.1 63.1 62.5 64.0 64.3

Source: Eurostat.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

106 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 30: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Table 3a

Correction Periods for Excessive Deficits in the EU-15

2001 2002 2003 2004 20051 20061 20071 2008

Portugal Deficit ratio �4.2 �2.8 �2.9 �3.0 �6.0 �5.0 �4.8Deadline � until 2003�! ��� until 2008���!Extension/correction ED

cor-rected

Germany Deficit ratio �2.9 �3.8 �4.1 �3.7 �3.9 �3.7 �3.3Deadline � until 2004�!Extension/correction until

2005until2007

France Deficit ratio �1.6 �3.2 �4.2 �3.6 �3.2 �3.5 �3.5Deadline � until 2004�!Extension/correction until

2005

Netherlands Deficit ratio �0.2 �2.0 �3.2 �2.1 �1.8 �1.9 �1.5Deadline � until 2005�!Extension/correction ED

cor-rected

Greece Deficit ratio �6.1 �4.9 �5.7 �6.6 �3.7 �3.8 �3.8Deadline � until 2005�!Extension/correction until

2006

Italy Deficit ratio �3.2 �2.7 �3.2 �3.2 �4.3 �4.2 �4.6Deadline �� until 2007�!Extension/correction

UnitedKingdom

Deficit ratio 0.7 �1.6 �3.3 �3.1 �3.4 �3.3 �3.0Deadline ��� until�!

2006/072

Extension/correction

Source: Eurostat. OeNB.Note: In the last year of the correction period, the deficit ratio is to have sunk below 3% of GDP.

ED = excessive deficit.1 The budget deficits are forecast values (Autumn 2005 Forecast of the European Commission of November 2005).2 Correction period: fiscal year 2006/07.

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 107�

Page 31: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

Table 3b

Correction Periods for Excessive Deficits in the New Member States

2004 20051 20061 20071 2008

Poland Deficit ratio �3.9 �3.6 �3.6 �3.4Deadline ��� until 2007���!Extension/correction

Czech Republic Deficit ratio �3.0 �3.2 �3.7 �3.3Deadline ��� until 2008���!Extension/correction

Hungary Deficit ratio �5.4 �6.1 �6.7 �6.9Deadline ��� until 2008���!Extension/correction

Slovakia Deficit ratio �3.1 �4.1 �3.0 �2.5Deadline ��� until 2008���!Extension/correction

Malta Deficit ratio �5.1 �4.2 �3.0 �2.5Deadline ��� until 2006���!Extension/correction

Cyprus Deficit ratio �4.1 �2.8 �2.8 �2.4Deadline �� until 2005��!Extension/correction

Source: Eurostat, OeNB.Note: In the last year of the correction period, the deficit ratio is to have sunk below 3% of GDP.1 The budget deficits are forecast values (Autumn 2005 Forecast of the European Commission of November 2005).

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

108 Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06�

Page 32: Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact - OeNBcc820c95-6cb7-40bb-a69d-8ae8f4a7aa63/mop... · Stability and Growth Pact in the fall of 2004. At an extraordinary Ecofin meeting on March

��������

�������������)��!�: �� ��������� �������!��������%�),

'

=��$� >�

(76���"��"�����9"��������"��"�����

�� �

��

�'

��

�;��

�; �� ��

��

��

�<

�� �� �;

��

�;

;

��

�� �

�:

�< ��

'

�� �

��

��

�� �

�;

�<

�<<� �<<' �<<; �<<: �<<< ��� ��� �� ��� ���

(76����$����������9"���������$����������

������� (3���"��� �� ) /8�������������

�������*

�������������)��!�: �� ��������� �������!��������%�)*

'

=��$� >�

(76����"��"�����9"��������"��"�����

(76�����$����������9"���������$����������

������� (3���"��� �� ) /8�������������

�; ��

�<

��

��;

�;

�� ��

�; �� ��

��

��

�<

�; � �

'

<

�D�

�; �;

� ��

�� �

��

�� �

�;

�<

��

�<<� �<<' �<<; �<<: �<<< ��� ��� �� ��� ��� �;

Reform of the Stability and Growth Pact

Monetary Policy & the Economy Q1/06 109�