public-private-partnerships: a tool for improving public

50
Public-Private-Partnerships: a tool for improving public transportation infrastructure in developing countries A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the award of the Master of Law and Business (“MLB”) Degree Natasha Mina July 26, 2013 14.553 words (excluding footnotes) Supervisor 1: Prof. Dr. Ralf Fendel Supervisor 2: Prof. Dr. Burcin Yurtoglu

Upload: others

Post on 28-Feb-2022

4 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Public-Private-Partnerships: a tool for improving public transportation

infrastructure in developing countries

A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the award of the Master of Law and Business (“MLB”) Degree

Natasha Mina July 26, 2013

14.553 words (excluding footnotes) Supervisor 1: Prof. Dr. Ralf Fendel

Supervisor 2: Prof. Dr. Burcin Yurtoglu

II

TABLE OF CONTENTS

I. Introduction ........................................................................................................................... 1

II. Forms of undertaking public infrastructure projects .............................................................. 3

A. Public Procurement: traditional public works .................................................................... 3

B. Contracting out ................................................................................................................. 4

C. Privatization ..................................................................................................................... 5

III. Public-Private Partnership: Overview .................................................................................. 5

A. Difficulty in defining PPP................................................................................................. 5

1. Broad Range.................................................................................................................. 5

2. Public- Private Partnerships and Concessions ................................................................ 6

B. Historical Development .................................................................................................... 7

C. Forms of PPP.................................................................................................................... 8

D. Need for Intelligent Transportation System ..................................................................... 10

E. Why Public-Private Partnership? ..................................................................................... 12

F. Which PPP? .................................................................................................................... 15

G. Best practice drivers ....................................................................................................... 15

IV. Developing countries: background .................................................................................... 17

A. Current situation ............................................................................................................. 17

B. Observable roots to the problem...................................................................................... 18

1. Bad Governance .......................................................................................................... 18

2. Inadequate regulatory and legislative frameworks ........................................................ 19

3. Inefficiency of operations ............................................................................................ 20

V. Financing Structures in PPP ............................................................................................... 21

A. Project Financing Structure............................................................................................. 23

1. Special Purpose Entity/ Special Purpose Vehicle ......................................................... 24

2. Sources of funding ...................................................................................................... 24

3. Value for Money in PPP .............................................................................................. 26

B. Assessment of risks ........................................................................................................ 27

VI. Applicability to Colombia ................................................................................................. 28

A. Current Situation in the public transportation system: the example of Bogotá .................. 28

B. Legislative and regulatory framework ............................................................................. 30

1. Law 1508 of 2012/Law 80 of 1993 .............................................................................. 30

2. Case of Transmilenio ................................................................................................... 31

3. Mobility Masterplan .................................................................................................... 33

C. Form of investment ......................................................................................................... 33

III

1. FDI in Colombia and modes of entry for foreign investors ........................................... 34

2. Proposition for the structure of the SPV in the Colombian case .................................... 34

D. Key elements of the project ............................................................................................ 35

1. VFM ........................................................................................................................... 36

2. Joint-Venture............................................................................................................... 37

3. Sufficient demand ....................................................................................................... 39

4. Tariff ........................................................................................................................... 40

VII. Conclusion ...................................................................................................................... 41

IV

List of Abbreviations

BOO Build-Own-Operate

BOT Build-Operate-Transfer

FDI Foreign Private Investment

DBFO Design-Build-Finance-Operate

IPTS Integrated Public Transportation System

NPV Net-Present-Value

O&M Operation & Maintenance Contract

PFI Private Finance Initiative

PPP Public-Private Partnership

PPPIRC PPP in Infrastructure Center (Worldbank)

SPV Special Purpose Vehicle

TM Transmilenio

TNC Transnational Company

VFM Value-For-Money

1

I. Introduction

Infrastructure is a main driver of citizen’s quality of life, as its main objective is to

satisfy households’ needs for different services needed to survive. People not only need

efficient and sustainable transportation means, they are dependent on them. Indeed,

urban transportation belongs to the category of economic infrastructure needed by a

country to function (Vuksanović & Milojčić, 2011). The World Bank has stated that

“the adequacy of infrastructure helps determine one country’s success and another’s

failure” (The World Bank, 1994). The latter reflects the urgency in identifying failures

in provision of economic infrastructure and demands an analysis of the existing wrong

patterns in order to correct them and adapt to changes to overcome what is commonly

known as the “infrastructure gap” (Guasch, 2004). Not without reason, many

alternatives for providing infrastructure have been set forward on the grounds that new

models are needed in the interest of overcoming the pitfalls encountered by inadequate

infrastructure. Public-private partnership is a broad concept that brings together all of

these alternatives. It refers to the involvement of a private company in designing,

financing, constructing, owning and/or operating a utility or service that has

traditionally been procured by the public sector. The partnership blends the special

skills from both the public sector as client and the private sector as supplier, with the

purpose of achieving a more efficient outcome that would not be reachable if each party

were to work independently (Akintoye, Beck, & Hardcastle, 2003).

Among many other things, the gap between developed and developing

economies is noticeable when looking at different transportation systems. Developing

cities have faced a lack of proper public service delivery–especially in transportation–

due, most of all, to the absence of an intelligent transportation system, which is key to

attain sustainable modes of mobility that satisfy users’ needs and improve their quality

of life.

The latter situation sets the need to attract private investors with large experience

and financing capacity to realize these projects in collaboration with the government.

That said, the large range of options for mixing public and private funds requires an

appropriate supporting environment represented in proper regulation and guidance, so

2

as to fully explore the different options available for public-private partnerships and

comprehend how they can successfully work. The definition of public-private

partnerships falls short in providing an adequate understanding of the concept. Being an

extensively broad concept, the understanding of the model needs to be facilitated by

proper regulation and legislative frames that fully reflect their innovative aspect and

presents decision-makers with viable options when bringing public and private forces

together. This is especially true considering the uncommon and new trait of the PPP

model that needs to mature enough to be implemented efficiently.

Ultimately, this paper will contribute to the arguments that nowadays, private-

public partnerships seem to be a more suitable way to undertake public infrastructure

projects in developing countries, by setting an easily attainable scenario for

incorporating and transferring the know-how of highly effective mobility systems from

developed countries, through applicable contractual figures that combine both private

and public budgets. This hypothesis will also respond to the analysis of the financial

viability of PPPs, which is ultimately defining when identifying whether PPP is the

right choice. Different forms, as well as trends, exist when it comes to private

involvement in infrastructure. Studies have shown that private participation does

improve the efficiency of a service delivery, for many reasons, among them because

politicians and governments are less likely to intervene in the activities of private

entities, which will not be subject to governmental manipulation, which is often the case

in developing countries. The issue however remains on achieving users’ welfare by

improving performance and efficiency together with lower tariffs and increase coverage

while generating returns to investors (Guasch, 2004).

To document the latter, this paper is organized as follows. Section 2 will review

the forms of undertaking public infrastructure projects from different scholars with the

purpose of showing the vast range in which both private and public forces can be

combined. Section 3 will provide an overview of the different arrangements in which a

PPP can be formed and will lay out the main advantages of this model that have been

presented by different scholars. Section 4 will provide a background on the current

infrastructure scenario in developing countries, to reflect on the inefficiencies

experienced by traditional models. Section 5 will provide an overview of the main

elements of the financing structure of a PPP, specifically the project financing model

3

and how value-for-money (VFM) in these models can be calculated. Finally, we will

discuss the applicability of a PPP model in the case of public transportation systems in

Colombia.

II. Forms of undertaking public infrastructure projects

The existing literature and research on the subject offers a large range of classifications

for undertaking infrastructure projects from entirely public procurement to wholly

private methods. Below is a gathering of different forms, arranged into different

categories to help achieve a better understanding. At the end of the day, we face

different ways of bringing together the public and the private sectors depending on two

main drivers, namely a direct versus an indirect role played in the provision of the

service. Operation and maintenance would correspond to the first kind of role and

ownership and finance to the second one (Batley, 2001). Thus, the difference between

purely public, purely private or a combination of both will depend on how these

different roles are split between the public sector, on the one hand, and the private

sector on the other.

A. Public Procurement: traditional public works

Within the traditional model of public procurement, a state entity takes on the

responsibility of designing, financing, operating, and maintaining public infrastructure

projects. Some private participation can come in the form of outsourcing any or a

specific part of the project, but no responsibility or risk is allocated to that party

(European Commission, 2003). This is especially true for service contracts, through

which public entities can benefit from the expertise and know-how of private entities for

specific tasks within a project.

In the instance where the service is procured as traditional public works, while

construction and operation are procured separately from two different private sector

firms, this scenario reflects a traditional public procurement form. When construction

and operation are bundled together, the project develops into a PPP (Blanc-Brude,

4

Goldsmith, & Valila, 2006). As will be discussed later, bundling can represent both an

advantage, as well as a disadvantage when it leads to the creation of monopolies.

Richard Batley (2001) argues that public procurement is not very justifiable on

the surface, when it comes to the technical consideration of goods and services, but it is

more plausible in the case of services that have a tendency to become monopolies that

need large-scale investments and that have a profound effect on society (Batley, 2001).

In the pure public procurement model, the public sector plays all four roles in the

provision, i.e. operates, maintains, owns, and finances the service.

B. Contracting out

In these kinds of projects, government bodies remain responsible for providing the

services in an indirect way, i.e., some elements of its production or delivery are

outsourced to the private sector. The public sector finances the project and remains the

owner of the assets while remunerating the private sector according to a fixed sum and

not on an efficiency and performance basis (Batley, 2001). This is a way of involving

the private sector in public infrastructure projects in situations where it would seem very

difficult in principle to delegate the full provision and production to it given the

likelihood of a market failure occurring (Batley, 2001).

Operation & Maintenance (O&M) contracts are a typical form for these

agreements. While they could, in principle, be regarded as public-private partnerships,

they are included here in a different category responding to the PPP wave observed

since the 1990s, which has moved towards attracting more private commitment in

investment. However, O&M contracts do not imply a private responsibility towards

investment obligations. Additionally, the worldwide trend for transportation projects

leans more toward the use of other types of contractual arrangements rather than O&M

contracts (Estache & Serebrisky, 2004).

5

C. Privatization

Under this form, assets are divested to a private entity entirely. In fact, under this model,

the private sector becomes accountable for the provision of the public service before the

users (UNECE, 2008), the most common example being the provision of

telecommunication services. Outright privatization results in the transfer of ownership

of public assets to the private sector and does not have a limited period of time, which

differentiates them from the concession type (Guasch, 2004). Contrary to this form, in

concessions, revenues generated by the project are the only assets that the private

operator owns. Land, plans, machinery, and other elements remain state property and

cannot be pledged by the private party against a loan (Guasch, 2004).

III. Public-Private Partnership: Overview

A. Difficulty in defining PPP

To provide an exact definition of this concept is a very difficult task, taking into

consideration that PPP is a dynamic concept involving any form of contractual

arrangement between the government and a private entity to embark on a specific

project, and moves along a spectrum initiating in completely public supply and

operation to complete private supply and operation (Guasch, 2004).

1. Broad Range

Does the definition of a PPP vary to the degree of involvement of the private entity?

What is the difference between PPP and other forms of private involvement such as

concession models that existed prior to the concept of PPP being introduced in the

public infrastructure arena? Does the difference lie on a mere technicality? Some

authors use the word PPP and concession interchangeably while some others make a

distinction. For instance, one difference between both concepts is that users pay

directly for services in concessions (Blanc-Brude et al., 2006). When the government

pays to the private party undertaking the project on the basis of agreed standards of

quality would not be considered to be a concession. Again, this depends largely on the

6

interpretation given to the different models in different jurisdictions and studies.

Likewise, while some scholars treat the models located in the almost completely private

supply end of the financing spectrum as privatizations, some others still refer to them as

PPP.

The way to approach the difference, if any, will largely depend on the country

where the project is to be commenced, and the different national regulations and

policies that will have to resolve the potential pitfalls arising out of misunderstandings

of the concept. Notwithstanding the above, there is general consensus that a PPP is any

form of private involvement in a project that would normally show—and has

historically shown—to be the sole responsibility of public authorities. To narrow it

down further, private finance is considered the core element used to distinguish between

PPP and traditional public procurement, because it clears “risk allocation and incentive

mechanisms, which are defining characteristics of PPP” (Blanc-Brude et al., 2006, p. 3).

2. Public- Private Partnerships and Concessions

The World Bank makes a distinction between public contracts, such as concessions

where the private party provides a service directly to the public taking end-user risk,

from PPPs where the private party delivers a service to a public party in the form of a

bulk supply.1

On the contrary, authors like Luis Guasch (2004) do not make use of the term

public-private partnership in some of their works; instead in Guasch’s case, he refers to

“private participation in infrastructure” and argues that it can come in many forms,

ranging from management contracts to full privatization as well as a variety of

concession form . Also, when it comes to concessions, Guasch pinpoints four main

categories, namely management contracts, leasing, franchise, concessions and build-

operate-transfer, that are situated somewhere in the spectrum mentioned above.

However, Batley (2001) refers to a parallel split of functions in partnerships

between public and private providers rather than the hierarchical form of splitting roles

1 See World Bank PPP in Infrastructure Center, available at www.worldbank.org/ppp

7

observed in arrangements where the public sector contracts, leases, or gives in

concession to a private party. As per the definition of a partnership, public and private

sectors are shareholders who share a joint purpose and put together different sources

(Batley, 2001). However, contracts such as franchises, leases or concessions are treated

as PPP by many other scholars even if a hierarchical division of roles exist.

Finally, the definition for PPP may vary from country to country, according to

different laws and different experiences.

B. Historical Development

A good way to understand the applicability or the origin of PPPs is to go back to its

roots and identify the moment where the model was born. Some changes and evolutions

are crucial in the process of introducing PPP as a way of financing public infrastructure

projects. Mainly, public unsuitability has driven economies to turn to private entities for

their support. By the time private participation was introduced, some governments had

failed in the provision of critical infrastructure services to the population, showing

symptoms of “chronic inefficiency, poor pricing policies, and corruption” (Harris,

2003, p. 4) that prove the failure of governments to provide these services. Furthermore,

as utilities were progressively being privatized, multinational utility operators were

developing, and public spending underwent a general review, the path to the

introduction of PPP advanced (European Commission, 2003).

Five stages can be identified in the evolution towards implementation of private

investment in public infrastructure. First, infrastructure development was directly linked

to economic growth and poverty reduction. Second, as infrastructure was, for the most,

funded by public sources, at a third stage it was observed how public investment in

infrastructure in developing countries proved to be largely deficient and incapable of

meeting citizen’s demands, particularly the needs of the poor. Fourth, state-aid was not

in the capacity to make up for the gap in financing, and fifth, the private sector showed

that it had the potential to make a difference (WSP,2007).

8

C. Forms of PPP

As mentioned, Public-Private Partnerships move along a continuum, whose evolution

depends on the degree of involvement of the private entity regarding ownership of the

assets, investment level, operation, and level of responsibility. Other studies refer to the

degree of development and property rights, as well as the period during which the

private entity is involved. (Kwak, Chih, & Ibbs, 2009). While most agree that ownership

of the assets is a decisive element in determining the form of PPP, one of the best ways

to identify the relevant form, as previously mentioned, is to observe the split of the roles

of operation, maintenance, finance, and ownership.

Therefore, there is not one rigid structure of PPP, and each project will require a

certain configuration tailored to the specific needs and traits of the project. (European

Commission, 2003). Furthermore, as legislation and regulations are progressively being

established around the concept, the models of PPP remain very dynamic and subject to

constant re-design. Hence, different policies adapt to changes and to new

understandings and implementation of the concept. Nonetheless, some main categories

can be identified, despite the fact that there is no standardized descriptive nomenclature

and that the different expressions are often used interchangeably (European

Commission, 2003). Kwak, Chih and Ibbs (2009) made a comprehensive study of PPPs

and proposed the following categorization:

At the left end of the spectrum, the type of PPP known as Operation-

Maintenance is a form where the private sector is responsible for all aspects of the

operation and the maintenance of the project. The private sector may or may not take

the responsibility of financing the project. Its responsibility in the financing of the

project may be very low or very high (Kwak et al., 2009).

As we move across the spectrum, in the Design-Build-Operate (DBO), the

“private sector is responsible for the design, construction, operation, and maintenance of

a project for a specified period prior to handing it over to the public sector” (Kwak et

al., 2009, p. 54). In addition to the operation and the maintenance functions, which are

typical of the first model, the private sector is also responsible for designing and

constructing the project. Nothing is said about the financing task (Kwak et al., 2009).

9

Through the Design-Build-Finance-Operate (DBFO), the private concessionaire

is in charge of the financing, design, construction, operation, and maintenance of the

project (Kwak et al., 2009). Within the next type of PPP, the model and the degree of

involvement of the private entity remains in essence the same, but a concession period

(during which the private entity does not own the asset), is added so that the asset is

returned to the government at the end. This form is known as Build-Operate-Transfer

(BOT). (Kwak et al., 2009).

Additionally to the development rights from the previous types of PPP, some

property rights are factored in. When the private sector remains owner of the asset in

perpetuity, the model is called Build-Own-Operate (BOO) and in this instance, the

government agrees to purchase the services from the private sector (Kwak et al., 2009).

Both BOT and BOO have been categorized by the World Bank’s database

among the so-called “Greenfield Projects”, consisting of a Joint-Venture between a

foreign company and a local company to undertake a project2. Contrary to the

definitions presented above, the World Bank includes concessions in a separate

category. This differentiation is also made by Estache Juan and Trujillo (2007).

Basically in Greenfield Projects, the private sector is in charge of financing,

developing, and operating the facility for a period sufficiently long to repay debt and

generate a return. Assets are then transferred to the government. Thus, BOT, BOO,

BOOT, DBFO are all classified as Greenfield Projects. Concessions, on the other hand,

give the private sector a mandate to operate and/or expand an existing facility while

assuming the commercial risks of the business. No investment is needed, unless a sub

greenfield contract is signed covering additional investment on behalf of the private

sector and no assets are transferred from the public sector to the private and then vice

versa (Estache, Juan, & Trujillo-Castellano, 2007).

There is another concept when it comes to understanding public private

partnerships called the concession type, defined by the World Bank as a lease of certain

2 Please refer to the “Private Participation in Infrastructure Database” from the World Bank Group, available at: http://ppi.worldbank.org/resources/ppi_glossary.aspx

10

assets from the public sector to the private party for the provision of services. This

arrangement, whereby the private party takes on the responsibility for financing new

fixed projects, extends for a defined period of time , after which, the new assets revert to

the public sector (The World Bank, 1994). Some studies treat BOT, BOO (assuming

there is a concession period that is extended indefinitely) and concessions as being the

same, while for others, BOO is a privatization type of form, given that the

concessionaire owns the assets. On the other hand, the European Commission (2003)

defines the DBFO model described above as a concession model. Both models demand

some financial contribution from the private sector, whether not it is complete or to

some extent.

However, this assimilation to the concession concept may not always work for

different countries, as we will see in the specific case of Colombia, where both a law

regulating concessions and a law regulating public-private partnerships coexist

separately, which has raised several inconsistencies. According to the definitions of

The World Bank, BOT, contrary to concessions, do not require the establishment of

independent regulatory bodies because regulatory procedures are specified in the

underlying contract. This may be an alternative when too much regulation becomes an

obstacle to an efficient performance by limiting the freedom of actions that can be taken

by the private party. It may be the case that only certain standards are mentioned in the

contract without investing the effort of regulation, which most often than not, in the case

of developing countries, is issued by poorly managed institutions (The World Bank,

1994).

The key word describing all models is operations, leading to the conclusion that

the added value of making use of PPPs is that the private sector will take care of

operating and making the project function in the most efficient way. Such a delegation

from the public sector to the private sector seems to be the key important factor.

D. Need for Intelligent Transportation System

For a transportation system to be sufficient certain parameters must be met and fulfilled

to address the users’ needs for comfort, convenience, environmental responsibility, and

11

safety. Smooth mobility is one of the key drivers to the quality of life experienced by

citizens in a city. When citizens feel good riding buses and other means of public

transportation, they make more use of it and hence increase the sustainability of public

transportation. In fact, transportation systems remain sustainable in the long run only if

there are sufficient users.

In some countries, especially in the United States, public transport has become

irrelevant for a majority of car owners. On the other hand, in developing megacities, the

quality of public transportation has not attained the standards necessary to attract private

transport users. Hence public transport has not been able to compete with private

transport. A vicious circle has formed in which tariffs get reduced, resulting in

financially stressed operators providing significantly poor quality service. Urban

transport in developing cities has been stigmatized as the “mode of poor people”. The

goal of a sustainable and optimal transportation system should be measurable in the

ability to attract high-income users and therefore attaining high level of ridership. Thus,

achieving an optimal intelligent transportation system involves a change in the mind set

of car versus public transport. (Acharya & Morichi, 2013).

While many studies advocate for competition in the provision of urban

transportation, the bus industry in developing countries presents a different picture.

Contrary to the normal rule, public transportation has been characterized by a

liberalization and privatization experience with a recent shift to state intervention.

Indeed, competition leads to many market failures that require regulatory intervention

(Estache & Gómez‐Lobo, 2005). In the case of urban transportation, an oversupply has

been identified due mainly to: a) unclear definition of property rights, b) fares set above

the equilibrium price, c) congestion, and d) pollution (Echeverry et al., 2005). Because of

improper property rights, any competitor on the road can “take away” a passenger as

there is no strict organization in the different routes. Bus owners are drawn to overcharge

for the service given that market competition attracts passengers, who, when waiting for a

bus out on the road prefer to get on the first one that comes along even when they know

that a cheaper one is expected to arrive a while later. This cost-of-waiting is what permits

bus owners to charge more (Evans, 1987). Consequently, bus operators can charge more,

making returns on investment attractive. In addition, for a new bus operator to enter the

market is rather easy due to a lack of proper bidding system. The entry into the market is

12

only subject to obtaining a permit from the authority to circulate and to getting a route

assigned. Both attractive rates of returns and ease of entry into the market lead to a high

number of bus operators wanting to become suppliers (Estache & Gómez‐Lobo, 2005).

E. Why Public-Private Partnership?

Before the 1990s governments owned, operated, and financed nearly all infrastructure

because of the public interest involved in it and the nature of the services, in which the

economies of scale involved were thought to require monopoly (The World Bank,

1994). Usually, services and infrastructure imply economies of scale which are often

more satisfied by the creation of monopolies, where one entity will be better suited to

supply a local market at a lower cost (Chris Chan, 2009). These reasons do not seem to

have relevancy any longer as experience has shown.

Experience shows that the amount of investment cannot be the exclusive focus

of policy in the infrastructure sector. Quality is also vital in infrastructure services (The

World Bank, 1994). Moreover, improvements in infrastructure performance have shown

to rely largely on aspects like innovation in technology and regulatory markets, as well

as social and environmental sustainability, which is largely possible by shifting from

direct government provision to private sector provision. There is no need to continue

with the paradigm of public services being provided only by the government, as results

now show that in developing countries this is not the most effective way.

Private entities have a more business-oriented focus, which, as will be discussed

later on, is critical in ensuring an efficient and responsive infrastructure to end-users. A

business focus is generally more oriented towards customers’ needs. To the contrary,

the modus operandi in public provision has proven to be extremely bureaucratic,

making the decision process extremely slow and tiresome. The autonomy held by

private entities gives room to a more effective and rapid decision-making process that

addresses customer demand and runs the project as a service (The World Bank, 1994).

Moreover, by transferring some of the responsibility in the provision of public

services to private parties, the monopolistic structure that normally results from the

13

economies of scale present in infrastructure shifts toward a competitive market where

the users can choose among a range of suppliers (The World Bank, 1994). And because

the PPP model focuses on outputs with the main goal being to achieve the provision of

a sustainable and efficient service, standards and requirements are set forward in PPP

contracts (EPEC,2010).

However, while studies have often fought for the existence and implementation

of competitiveness, this must be carefully analyzed. The distinction between

monopolies and competition and the promotion of one or the other depends on how the

PPP initiative is structured. The case for public transportation where the entry and exit

of different providers is relatively simple, facilitates competition (The World Bank,

1994). However oversupply happens when too many operators provide the service in a

given network, such as the case of public transportation in Bogotá, Colombia, which

will be discussed further on. Neither this situation nor the extreme in which a single or

only a few operator(s) provide a service is ideal. These scenarios must be addressed by

effective regulations and an adequate model (Gómez-Ibáñez, 2003). Often, neither pure

public procurement nor pure private models will be flexible enough to address these

problems and regulation of the public authorities with private initiative must be

combined in an amicable fashion.

Indeed, when analyzing the public sector’s involvement in infrastructure,

specifically via regulation, Estache and Serebrisky (2004) described the above evolution

toward PPP in transportation, in six steps, namely: (i) Initially, private initiative works,

(ii) external shocks alter this situation, (iii) public sector enters the picture, (iv)

problems arise from the public sector trying to get the private sector back, which

ultimately leads to (v) finding a hybrid solution to the problem with the task of (vi)

defining how hybrid the model is and how much responsibility is granted to each party.

Now, the appearance of renegotiations within the contracts feed into the negative

feelings toward private participation in infrastructure because it implies divesting from

the original terms of the contract and thus breaking off promises that may be crucial for

users (Guasch, 2004). While renegotiation can be positive and increase general welfare

when addressing pitfalls or shortcomings from the original contract, in the instances

when it is not possible to foresee a deficiency in the original contract or unexpected

14

events that require changes, then a high number of alterations can cause concern that

renegotiations are being used opportunistically by either the government or the private

operator. It is generally the case that renegotiations rest credibility from the project, thus

increasing mistrust among users. (Guasch, 2004).

A clear example of the above situation is the evolution of procurement for

infrastructure projects in the field of transportation where the trends of private versus

public investments shift somehow in a conversely way. For the past century, in a

significant number of cases, including the situation in Colombia, private involvement

has been the key element in urban transportation where the main providers are private

operators. While competition has been thought to give consumers choices and put

pressure on suppliers to be efficient and accountable to users, competition among the

different suppliers has also led to opposite results and public involvement has become

necessary. The call for PPP responds to the necessity of involving the government in

the regulation of a service that lacks some basic regulation to function properly (Estache

& Serebrisky, 2004). Furthermore, the many alternatives presented by PPP should also

serve the purpose of implementing an intelligent transportation system and integrate all

elements of urban transportation that are existent nowadays into a hybrid arrangement

that can only be possible if proper PPP regulations and guidelines are established.

Also, developing countries need to progress toward PPP, as the entrance of

foreign capital is more often permitted through private models. This entrance is

extremely important in order to gain the expertise from developed countries, whose

systems have proven to generate high welfare gains for households and in the overall

economy. National suppliers would benefit from technical gains resulting from

technological innovation from strong economies. In the field of public transportation,

complexity is a paramount element. Cutting edge advancements and innovation are

required in order to re-design the existent transportation systems that clearly do not

satisfy users’ needs in developing countries. The flexibility of the PPP model, if

incorporated correctly, could attract foreign private investors rather than keeping with

traditional models (UNCTAD, 2008).

15

F. Which PPP?

It is essential to understand the distinctions between the various models of PPPs that can

be implemented in developing countries, especially in order to identify which party will

ultimately take on the roles identified above, i.e. operation, maintenance, ownership,

and financing of the project. Next, which form and which characteristics of the form are

best suited for achieving the goals set above for the public transportation system must

be determined. The DBFO type appears as the most convenient model for achieving

these purposes. At a first glance, ownership does seem to be vital when it comes to the

provision of the public transportation system. International examples must also be taken

into account when choosing the appropriate form for public transportation projects,

which not only demand infrastructure but also delivery of a service (Blanc-Brude et al.,

2006; Grout, 2005). In this sense, a sufficiently flexible PPP alternative providing for

increased freedom for the private party is more attractive. Moreover, the DBFO model

covers the largest number of functions (UNECE,2008).

G. Best practice drivers

In 1994, the World Bank issued a report listing drivers of public infrastructure welfare.

The trends from the past twenty years in developed as well as developing countries

reflect the pursuance of these elements. Examples of PPP practices in different

developed countries advocate for the fulfillment of the same benchmarks, namely: (i)

managing infrastructure like a business, and not like a bureaucracy, (ii) introducing

direct or indirect competition, and (iii) taking into account different stakeholders,

including users, in the planning, regulation, design, operation, and financing of

infrastructure (The World Bank, 1994). On the other hand, some more recent studies

have argued for specific PPP legislation, specialized regulatory bodies in the field,

selection of appropriate concessionaires, appropriate risk allocation, and sound financial

packages as some of the elements that contribute to creating a friendly environment for

the PPP model to develop (Kwak et al., 2009).

The choice of implementing these elements will largely depend on the situation

of the specific country. The success in developed countries does not necessarily mean

the same for other countries with cultural nuances, different mind-sets, state

16

organizations, and legislation, etc., but they surely represent a foundation upon which

developing countries can initiate a PPP culture to rely on. Ultimately, these examples of

best practices are in line with effective legislation frames, strong management of

finances, as well as responsiveness to citizens’ needs, by providing the right service

(effectiveness) in the right way (efficiency), and with the highest degree of

accountability (Kwak et al., 2009), Andrews & Shah, 2003).

One key feature about PPP found in many developing countries is the form of

remuneration that is received by the private sector. In the United Kingdom, for example,

payments are of an availability nature and they provide for deductions when

performance standards are not met. As deals normally transfer the usage risk to the

public party, the government has had a tendency to be very confident about sufficient

future demand when choosing where to invest long-term (Allen & Overy, 2010).

In the UK, there are public bodies outside of the central government that deal

with all PFI projects. However, potential investors often do not trust these bodies, as

they are not believed to be acting as agents and representing the Crown, making it

necessary for them to obtain some form of support (Allen & Overy, 2010). The HM

Treasury Taskforce is in charge of providing guidance and support and nowadays even

participates in projects themselves. Additionally, the Infrastructure Finance Unit lends

to PFI projects that cannot raise sufficient debt-financing, and Infrastructure UK is in

charge of building the private participation strategy (Allen & Overy, 2010).

In France, the line between public procurement and private participation has a

threshold of 30%. If more than this proportion of revenues does not come from

payments by end-users, the contract is seen as public procurement. If subsidies represent

less than 30%, the contract is a concession. These concessions are characterized by

having a single contractor for both the construction and operation phases (Allen &

Overy, 2010).

In Germany, there are some analogous PPP bodies, similar to the ones observed

in the UK, called PPP task forces. While the experience in the sector is a recent one in

Germany, specific enabling legislation has been recently enacted for certain projects in

particular. Germany also has an independent entity called the Toll Collect GmbH that is

17

in charge of collecting the distance-linked tolls from heavy traffic on motorways and to

invest it in the so-called A Model Projects. Another key feature known as the Factoring

type PPP solutions consists of a process in which the private sector invoices the public

sector after delivering portions of the contracted services. The authority accepts and

waives any possible objections to the invoice. This risk, which might be referred to as

the revenue risk is then passed onto the public sector, which then sells the invoice to a

third party investor or a lender seeking to divest its portfolio by adding public lending

risk. As in the UK, the tender documents focus on outputs, i.e., on the service delivery

specifications and not on inputs specifications. (Allen & Overy, 2010). This helps to

establish a more efficient and rapid decision-making process by granting more

independence to the private party to provide its services as it knows best.

IV. Developing countries: background

A. Current situation

It is not possible to give a general description of the status-quo of social infrastructure in

the transportation system generalized for all developing countries. The World Bank has

classified the different world economies into low-income, middle-income and high

income economies. Developing countries are comprised among the low-income and the

middle-income economies. However, this classification does not imply that all countries

are going at the same pace in terms of development (The World Bank, 1994). Within

the same category, noticeable breaches can be observed in the degree of development,

depending on the different sectors examined. For instance, according to the World Bank

classification, Chile is an upper middle-income country, as is Colombia; however,

improvements in social infrastructure in Chile are more noteworthy than in Colombia.

Chile is one of the region’s most developed economies, topping the index from the

Economist Intelligence Unit. One of the main reasons for Chile’s advancement was the

introduction of a new regulatory framework for PPPs, contained in the Public Works

Concession Law (Economist Intelligence Unit, 2010).

18

B. Observable roots to the problem

Historically, many developing countries have been negatively impacted by poor

governance, both at the public level, as well as in the private sector, which have led to

the failure of many public infrastructure projects. Corruption can be identified as one of

the main pitfalls that infrastructure projects face. Many of these problems have its roots

on a lack of a proper unified policy on the matter, resulting in poor and simplistic goal-

setting. Thus, a fully comprehensibly defined system, where all stakeholders are

involved, is one of the ways to potentially overcome current shortcomings faced by

infrastructure projects and to attain an adequate PPP development (UNECE, 2008).

1. Bad Governance

Governance–i.e., the combination and the performance of processes, procedures, and

enabling institutions—has been identified as a main barrier in the implementation of

PPP in countries where the model is still infant, such as in developing countries

(UNECE,2008). Governance in developing countries has been subjected to a culture of

bureaucracies often seeking to augment their rents in detriment to delivering proper

services (Freire & Stren, 2001) and assuring that the public is the main beneficiary of

the project. An important element of good governance brought by Freire et.al is the

participation in the urban development of all stakeholders in a city (Freire & Stren,

2001), which also goes in line with the driving forces proposed by the World Bank.

When stakeholders are factored in, both accountability and transparency can be

improved.

According to Harry Kitchen (2005), there is a perception that local business

enterprises, i.e. state-owned companies in charge of delivering a specific service, are

more accountable because they run more like a business. Again, we encounter the

argument that running public infrastructure as a business is more likely to be more

efficient because it is treated as a commercial activity having the end users’ interest in

mind at all times. Moreover, it has been argued that management of public

infrastructure by local business firms may be more beneficial than by local politicians,

given the degree of specialization that these firms can attain, which is often not the case

19

for politicians responsible for a large number of social commitments. It is also

beneficial if the provision of the service is kept independent from political idealogy and

conflicts and instead focuses mainly on the citizens, taking into account also the high

levels of corruption encountered in some developing countries 3 (Kitchen, 2005).

However, Kitchen also takes the position that this is merely a misperception,

and, in fact, it is not often true that local business firms are more efficient and

accountable given their financial flexibility, which could permit them to undertake an

empire building approach and invest in projects that do not necessarily contribute to the

general welfare but rather augment the size of the business (Kitchen, 2005). Moreover,

these bodies are more likely to be problematic during the decision-making process and

in terms of transactional costs.

2. Inadequate regulatory and legislative frameworks

According to Estache and De Rus (2000), the main purpose of regulation is to control

prices, as well as service, in order to ensure that the monopolist does not lower quality

of services or increases prices for them, while still allowing for the private investor to

realize a return on his investment. This multiplicity of objectives acts as a constraint for

the politicians, who must do their best to harmonize all these interests (Estache & De

Rus, 2000). Observable symptoms of poor regulation can be noted when looking at how

the different interests of the various stakeholders involved collide in practice. Private

firms want a return on their investment and may fear that while governments may in

principle pursue favorable regulation towards prices that attract investors, they may in

the long-run, lower prices as a result of user pressure. The users, in turn, are dependent

on the services that normally do not have any alternatives. When it comes to urban

transportation, for instance, low-income users often do not have the option of any other

means of transportation and are usually skeptical that they may be over-paying for a

manifestly inefficient system. Thus, the government is concerned about private

3 In Colombia, for instance, the last phase of the mass transit system was in the midst of a controversy surrounding the mayor, the Urban Development Institute, and the private entity formed by the “Grupo Nule”. Corruption charges were leveled toward participants in what is known as the Carrousel of Public Contracts, in which contracts for infrastructure projects were granted not based on concessionaire’s capabilities but rather on personal grounds.

20

monopolies raising prices excessively and high above their actual costs (Gómez-Ibáñez,

2003).

Estache and Serebrisky found enough evidence to argue that, while competition

should be the general aim of public policy, residual regulation should be improved

(Estache & Serebrisky, 2004). The shift towards private participation in infrastructure

projects goes hand-in-hand with the increasing need to regulate this phenomenon.

3. Inefficiency of operations

When providing guidelines for good governance in PPP, the United Nations has defined

efficiency as “the extent to which limited human and financial resources are applied

without waste, delay or corruption or without prejudicing future generation” (UNECE,

2008, p. 14). Efficiency is also a strong parameter to measure how much prices can drop

and still generate returns from the project, while not compromising its financial liability.

This can in turn help define the maximum subsidy required from the government

(Estache & Serebrisky, 2004).

We have advocated so far for competition as an impetus for efficiency and,

hence, for decreasing regulation in order to attain efficiency standards, on the prima

facie basis that existence of competition stands for low levels of regulatory policies.

However, Estache and Serebrisky (2004) have looked at the evolution of the efficiency

levels in the transportation sector in order to assess whether deregulation or residual

regulation by public authorities is effective or not, finding that most often than not

inefficiency is linked with poor regulation.

From a user’s point of view, de-regulation may not be efficient, even in the

presence of competition, when the system becomes unmanageable due to excessive

liberalization, raising several issues, especially environmental and safety ones (Estache

& Serebrisky, 2004). The observable inefficient pattern can be seen in countries with

poor infrastructures, which is largely due to inadequate maintenance that reduces the

lifespan of infrastructure facilities and, therefore, the capacity to provide services. Thus,

more investments are then needed and resources are not used efficiently. Project

21

investments are also often misallocated, resulting in inappropriate infrastructure and

lack of proper infrastructure for the provision of services at the appropriate standards

(The World Bank, 1994).

Unresponsiveness is also present in the delivery of infrastructure services and

demands for services by businesses, households, and other users remains a challenge for

a large part of service. (The World Bank, 1994).

V. Financing Structures in PPP

The Project Finance model is different from the traditional corporate finance model in

that the former is highly leveraged in comparison to the latter, given the difficulty for

these initiating projects to raise equity (Engel, Fischer, & Galetovic, 2010). On the one

hand, PPPs have been thought by some to release government funds by circumventing

large sunk investments. Thus, the public budget is not affected, and the government is

able to finance other social projects. Engel et.al, on the other hand, argue that these are

alleged advantages and that in reality, PPPs do affect the government’s budgets to the

same extent that public provision does (Engel et al., 2010).

The government may save in up-front investment, but then it either relinquishes

future user fee revenue (if the PPP is obtaining a return on user fees) or future tax

revenue (if the project’s returns come from state payments over the life of the project)

(Engel, Fischer, & Galetovic, 2013; Engel et al., 2010). For instance, in the UK, the

main feature of the Public Finance Initiative (PFI) is that the private party funds and

builds the project and is in turn remunerated directly by the government with a fixed

payment (Grout, 1997) rather than from users’ tariffs. Again, this model shows how the

government’s budget is still affected even with the implementation of PPP. Indeed, it

may not be affected by the fact that it has to fund the debt portion of the financing, but

rather by having to comply with a service contract (Grout, 1997).

Therefore, it is very important to assess the benefits of using PPPs, by finding

efficiency gains that occur less on the financial side and more on the innovative aspects

of bundling construction, maintenance, and operations tasks.

22

Notwithstanding the above, it is still possible to observe some gains from a

financial point of view. According to Blanc-Brude, Goldsmith and Valila., the bundling

aspect gives the Special Purpose Vehicle (SPV) an incentive to make higher

investments in the construction phase in order to avoid overrun costs during the life of

the project. Additionally, if the private sector is only remunerated by the government

from public funds, i.e. tax-based and subjected to the service actually provided, then the

private sector will not be able to transfer the overrun costs to the government. The

decrease in investment today will result in greater operation and maintenance costs

tomorrow. Hence, in order to meet the safety and efficiency standards for the

availability payment (Blanc-Brude et al., 2006; Echeverry et al., 2005), private sector

will be more efficient in that they will want to reduce costs as much as possible without

being tempted to reduce quality, which ultimately will determine whether they receive a

return on their investment or not (Grout, 1997).

Grout also argues that the availability payment renders the investment in the

project riskier for the private entity because it is not possible to determine today what

will be the provision standards in twenty or thirty years (which is typically the length of

these contracts) (Grout, 1997). Hence, a significant number of renegotiations over the

life of the project may occur. In any case, the key advantage of a PPP model is that

private investors should always escape from cutting down on costs today.

These circumstances contribute to increased construction costs in PPP versus

traditional public works. Moreover, following a main principle of PPPs, which is to

allocate the risk to the party that is most able to bear it, the private party ends up taking

most of the risk from the project, which will evidently be priced by the SPV in the bid

(Blanc-Brude et al., 2006). However, private firms will make greater efforts to avoid

situations or events that can trigger price increases by bearing the majority of the risk.

Sounder risk management, in turn, leads to greater cost efficiency (House of Commons

Treasury Committee, 2010). Moreover, the concept of availability payment also

contributes to this construction risk, which is augmented since PPPs, as a general rule,

do not pay the private sector based on construction costs but rather on availability of the

infrastructure.

23

When selecting a concessionaire, the government has to make use of certain

evaluation methods to assess the financial viability of the project, such as the Net-

Present-Value method. The NPV of a publicly financed project compared to the NPV of

a private financed project, is quite different. Now, the NPV of the first type of project is

usually an analysis of the cost stream that the public sector needs in order to fund a PPP

with a usually low rate of return, i.e. the rate of return used to discount cash flows will

be close to the risk-free rate of return. The NPV revenue stream that is calculated for

private funding projects, may be far riskier, given the uncertainty of future cash flows,

which, in turn, leads to higher rates of return in order to discount the cash flows of the

project that will also be higher (Grout, 1997).

From his findings, Grout states that PFI in England has failed to prove that its

model is more advantageous than public funding, but it is due to the fact that the criteria

used to assess their profitability when compared to financing projects with public

funding, is not an appropriate one (Grout, 1997). Indeed, comparing public and private

public sector costs with private revenue flows is an odd comparison and does not take

into account important social measures, such as the consumer surplus generated by such

projects, which should also be a factor in decision-making (Grout, 1997). However, the

scope of the research of this paper does not quantify the potential welfare effects to both

consumer and suppliers because of lack of proper surveys and estimation of suppliers’

costs. Moreover, the discount rate used may differ from a public analysis to a private

one; it will depend on which other project is used as a benchmark. The bottom line is

that a financial test falls short in assessing the true value of a PPP project, and while it

may be the main element to take into account, social welfare both from the consumer

and supplier side, independent from profitability, must also be taken into account

(Grout, 1997).

A. Project Financing Structure

The concept of Project Finance refers to a way of financing a specific project, - for the

purposes of this paper an infrastructure project, by relying on the expected cash flows of

the same to act as security for the financiers of the project (Grimsey & Lewis, 2004)

Below are the standard elements normally present in such a structure.

24

1. Special Purpose Entity/ Special Purpose Vehicle

In a project finance structure, a Special Purpose Vehicle is funded with the sole purpose

of undertaking the project. The new company is managed by a sponsor, who invests in

the equity of the company and then seeks funds from different lenders. The sponsor can

be an industry operator (Engel et al., 2010), with the purpose of establishing a company

to run a project sufficiently profitable so as to create enough revenues to pay off debt

and generate dividends for the shareholders of the company.

The SPV needs to enter into various contracts to function and operate properly.

Engel et. al compare these arrangements to the ones that the PPP itself has to enter into,

namely: (i) a fundamental agreement with the procuring authority; (ii) another

agreement with users of the service provided by the PPP; (iii) a third agreement with

building and operation contractors; (iv) and lastly, an agreement with the investors and

financiers of the project. The SPV is a suitable way of involving different stakeholders

in the decision-making process of a specific infrastructure project and, therefore, in

creating an accountability environment (Engel et al., 2010). Moreover, in the case of

urban transportation the SPV would act as as a true transport firm seeking to earn a

return on its capital that is comparable to what it would receive in any other business of

similar risk (Echeverry et al., 2005).

2. Sources of funding

Throughout the evolving life cycle of a project, financing comes from different

institutions. As far as the project develops, so does the risk structure and allocation, and

so do the sources of financing (Engel et al., 2010). Not all lenders have the same risk

profile. While some may be more risk averse, others might be inclined toward lending

capital during the far riskier construction phase. Indeed, more changes and unforeseen

events are likely to occur during this phase than during the operation phase of the

project, where the potential for risks is basically linked to whether or not the project

generates cash-flows.

25

Construction phase

During the construction phase, the sponsor will finance the costs providing

equity, which in turn can be combined with loans from banks or subsidies from the

government. This form of combining financing sources and types applies especially in

the case of projects which derive returns from users’ fees, such as urban transportation

projects, in which the so-called “farebox” recovery ratio corresponds to the operating

expenses that are met by the tariff paid by users for using the service (Leber & Perrott,

2012). However, the need for subsidies does not always arise as has been the case with

rapid mass transit systems operating in Bogotá, where the contract stipulates that the

system is a self-sustainable one. Even in transport projects, public and private sectors

can agree on a payment from the government to the private party undertaking the

project, if certain requirements of efficiency are achieved.

Operations

The Operation phase follows the construction phase and occurs after

“completion and ramp-up” of the project (Engel et al., 2010). During this phase, long-

term bonds substitute for bank loans, and the sponsor may sell the SPV to an operator or

to another investor, much like any other business (Engel et al., 2010). During the

operations phase, when cash starts to flow in, bond holders might be likely to make their

entrance into the financial scene as they are interested in those revenue streams to

collect their annual coupons (Engel et al., 2010). However, while construction risks

should be transferred to the private sector during the construction phase in order to

incentivize a more efficient investment on its side, demand and revenue risk of the

operation phase needs to be transferred to the government. Demand risk is bore by both

bond and equity holders because their return on the investment depends on the volume

of demand, so when risk is high, their expected return will also increase. To the

contrary, if risk is transferred to the government, the return from the project to sponsors

and creditors will also decrease (Engel et al., 2010).

26

3. Value for Money in PPP

It is essential to determine if at the end of the day, PPPs are more worthwhile than

undertaking projects via traditional public works. In turn, to assess profitability, a

comparison between the costs of conducting a specific project to the public sector

versus the same costs to the private sector is necessary. This is known as a Value-For-

Money Test (VFM) (Grout, 1997). Both profitability and community welfare, where

users benefit from the project, are the main criteria to assess the success of an

infrastructure project. The way risk is managed in a project is also a key feature to

achieving efficient financing; allocating the risk to the party best suited to take them on

will reduce the overall cost of the project, therefore making it more efficient. If a PPP

vehicle is chosen to undertake the project, this option must be the one that results in a

highest return compared to the return that would be obtained by public procuring the

project (Chris Chan, 2009).

The VFM for private procurement must be proven to be more profitable to the

government and society than traditional public procurement since, in principle,

government has the capability to obtain cheaper funding than the private sector. (House

of Commons Treasury Committee, 2010).

Given its high-risk profile, the Weighted Average Cost of Capital of a PFI, i.e.,

the discounted rate to which cash flows of the project are discounted, is double that of

government gilts. PFI only provides VFM if cost savings and efficiencies during the life

of the project outweigh the increment in the cost of capital (House of Commons

Treasury Committee, 2010). Furthermore, in the likely scenario that introducing a

subsidy becomes necessary, the VFM will be affected, of course, and the efficiency

savings from the project will need to be large enough to compensate for this input

(EPEC,2010). Innovation and applied know-how from the private investor are key

issues in achieving high levels of efficiency in the provision of the services, which will

likely increase earnings of the projects, thus reflecting the quality of service provided.

This could largely compensate for a lesser VFM, if any. It is fair to say that given the

high capital expenditure coming from the private sector, the same should be

remunerated by collecting the benefits resulting out of these initial expenditures, either

27

by the fare collected from users’ services or by subsidies coming from the government

when levels of demand are not met, albeit achieving efficiency standards.

Sometimes when facing low user charges, VFM in infrastructure projects can

decrease due to the need for the government to subsidize the project (Chris Chan, 2009).

For public transportation, in particular, subsidies may be required when determining the

tariff must take into account low-income sectors of the population. The true cost of

urban transportation service is comprised of: (i) costs of civil works (ii) costs of

equipment and machinery, and (iii) operation and maintenance costs. The first two costs

are said to be non farebox, i.e. they will not be met by the tariff paid by users and,

therefore, have to be covered by government subsidy (Leber & Perrott, 2012).

B. Assessment of risks

The main principle set forward when defining risk is that it should be allocated to the

party that is best suited to manage it (Engel et al., 2010). Guasch agrees that the less

risk-averse party should be assigned the risk (Guasch, 2004).

Guasch and the European Commission identified eight main categories of risks,

namely:

a) Revenue risk: basically this arises out of changes in tariffs or changes in demand

and is usually allocated to the project company (Guasch, 2004)

b) Risk related to the selection of the private sector partner: a badly vetted private

party might turn out not to be sufficiently competent or might prove to be

corrupt-prone, thereby unable to meet the initial specifications

c) Construction costs risks comprise overrun in the life-cycle of the project and

delays in completion

d) Financial risks can emerge from fluctuating foreign exchange rates or variable

interest rates

e) Political risks or performance risks

f) Sustainability risk

g) Public acceptance risk

28

The assessment of the different types of risks will help determine the discounted

rate to which the cash-flows of the project must be discounted. If risks are more likely

to occur during one phase of the project than another, the financial analysis

corresponding to the latter phase perhaps should be discounted to a near risk-free rate of

return (European Commission, 2003). The appropriate allocation of risks is extremely

important in order to assess the financial viability of the project, which ultimately is the

starting point to define whether the project should be undertaken by means of private

funds, public funds, or a combination of both.

VI. Applicability to Colombia

A. Current Situation in the public transportation system: the example of Bogotá

The vehicles belonging to the public transportation system in Bogotá are hardly

aesthetic and very old as they do not comply with the replacement norms and hence

they do not maintain the equipment in working conditions. This has led to both

environmental as well as safety issues. The equipment has become obsolete to be

operated in a big city such as Bogotá. Moreover, the buses do not comply with the

minimum safety rules; thus, this form of transportation is creating traffic chaos and

innumerable accidents every day.

Another main issue facing the transport system in Bogotá is the operating

flexibility granted to the private sector. The lack of a central authority and of a unified

legal policy imposed on owners and operators of the transport system has led to chaos.

The companies render this service work on an affiliate system, i.e., their object is not to

operate per se but to simply acquire as many buses as possible and have them running

along the different routes that have been assigned to them by the government. This

situation creates strong competition between the different providers and results in an

excess of supply of transport (Echeverry et al., 2005). The bus owners join different

transport companies and unions and pay the drivers proportionately according to the

number of passengers that they pick up instead of based on a labor contract (Echeverry

et al., 2005). Moreover this atomization of the ownership structure has resulted in an

exceeding number of buses making it difficult to exploit economies of scale.

29

Congestion, pollution, and traffic accidents, not to mention a decrease in aesthetic value

resulting from old and poorly maintained equipment, permeate the city’s public

transport (Echeverry et al., 2005).

There are three main actors in the public transport system: the company, the

vehicle owner, and the driver–all of them pursuing their own personal interests above

any general consumer welfare. The public transportation system has been treated as a

lucrative business rather than as a public service. Therefore, the actors in the public

transportation sector have had an immense and traditional capacity for lobbying

sponsored and agreeable politicians. Bureaucracy has prevailed, interfering with a more

efficient business focus.

In addition to the chaotic present bus system, there is a notable increase in the

number of private vehicles owned by households. While measures to overcome this

overabundance of privately owned vehicles have been implemented, high-income

citizens continue relying on their automobiles and relying less on public transportation,

while decreasing revenues in the sector and increasing traffic congestion in the city.

The case for urban transportation in Bogotá does not fit the argument of

competition as a source of efficiency in the provision of infrastructure. Competition

alone is not advantageous if it is not accompanied by effective price setting procedures.

An out-on-the-road type of competition (Echeverry et al., 2005), as the one that was

observed prior to the introduction of the mass transit system and is still in existence

today can result in a highly dangerous city environment.

Alongside the public transportation system, Transmilenio (TM) a rapid bus

system, opened in December 2000, as a massive transit system based on the model used

in Curitiba, Brazil. TM consists of several interconnecting bus lines, each composed of

numerous stations located in the center of a main avenue. This has shown to be a very

effective system for a city such as Bogotá that uses buses to provide a faster and a more

efficient service than the traditional old bus line. The system differs from the prior

version in that it works as a hybrid model, where the public authorities lean more

toward playing a critical role in monitoring the quality of service and in keeping the

30

collection of revenue, and the general operation of the system clearly separated

(Echeverry et al., 2005).

B. Legislative and regulatory framework

The efforts made by the Colombian government in incentivizing private participation in

public infrastructure have had their impact on how the environment for private investors

looks like nowadays. As a result, the Economist Business Intelligence has graded

Colombia on the high scale within the “emergent” category (Economist Intelligence

Unit, 2010).

1. Law 1508 of 2012/Law 80 of 19934

The difficulty in defining the scope of PPP precisely becomes even more latent when

we look at the Colombian example. Though the most recent PPP law was issued in

2012, most of the main concept remains unclear in many aspects. While partnerships

between entities from the public sector and entities from the private sector with the

purpose of involving the latter in the provision of construction and infrastructure

services was possible, either by entering into agreements or forming new entities, the

concept of PPP was only introduced in the legal landscape of Colombia by Law

1508/12. Public contracts had been previously governed by Law 80/93. Under

Colombian Law, concessions are a form of PPP and are not treated differently but

complementarily, regardless of the fact that PPP receive their returns from user fees.

Law 1508 provides for the application of infrastructure projects in the field of services.

Furthermore, the right to collect the resources for economic exploitation of the project,

to receive disbursements of public funds or any other consideration, is dependent on the

availability of infrastructure, on the compliance with quality service standards at

different stages of the project, and other requirements determined by the regulations.

Another important feature of Law 1508 is as a result from the fact that infrastructure

projects can originate from either private or public initiatives.

4 This section draws upon the regulatory and legislative framework of public-private partnerships in Colombia, namely Law 1508 of 2012, available at: http://wsp.presidencia.gov.co/Normativa/Leyes/Documents/Ley150810012012.pdf and Law 80 of 1993, available at: http://www.alcaldiabogota.gov.co/sisjur/normas/Norma1.jsp?i=304

31

Law 1508 provides a developed regulatory framework in order to streamline the

entrance of the private sector in the provision of public infrastructure, by introducing

new forms of financing as well as new requirements. In addition, this new law regards

public infrastructure projects much like a business, in which the private investor is

incentivized to get a return on its investment by attaining some specific requirements.

The new ruling aims to attract long-term investors that are sufficiently financially

capable to construct, operate, and maintain public works that the country is in need of. It

also introduces the availability payment and the service level. In essence the new PPP

projects covered by this Law are a new generation of the model of concession which

was already laid out by the former Law 80 (Political Science Institut, 2012).

2. Case of Transmilenio

The service is provided by means of concession, and both local and foreign transport

providers can associate and participate in the tender process. Construction for the

designated lanes has been divided into three main phases. Tendering processes are open

for both the construction of infrastructure, as well as for operations and fare collections,

which are meant to be run by the private sector. Transmilenio S.A.5, a publicly owned

company, is in charge of the planning, management, and control of the system. Both the

public and private sectors share the financial responsibility. Indeed, the public sector is

responsible for investing in the physical infrastructure of the system, such as lanes,

stations, terminals, while the private sector finances the bus fleet, ticket sales, and the

validating system (Grütter, 2006). TM functions like a BOO or BOT type of PPP.

As remuneration, the concessionaire is entitled to the rights, tariffs, and a

participation in the financial running of the project, which is granted to it. In addition, it

is remunerated a sum periodically, which may be a unique sum or calculated according

to a percentage scale. The return of the private investor’s investment is an element of

the contract but is not fully guaranteed. In this sense, this model of PPP sets a

distribution for risks between the government and the concessionaire, in which the latter

is not guaranteed to get a return on its investment. Moreover, all risks have been

5 S.A. stands for Sociedad Anónmima and is the Spanish word for corporation

32

transferred to the concessionaire. These are inherent risks in the project’s activities, as

well as risks resulting during the regular course of business, namely financial risks,

demand risks, cash flow risks and return on the investment risks. Nonetheless, the

concessionaire is entitled to a fixed payment from the government in case offer is not

met by demand, subject to the degree of efficiency and high quality standards to which

the service is provided6.

The buses, both trunk and feeder, that comprise the system are provided by

private entities under independent concession contracts, awarded within bidding

processes. Local companies also participate in the contractual scheme; they joined the

new system as operators to supply services in under-served TM corridors. The private

investors own the buses, hire drivers, and take care of maintenance duties (Echeverry et

al., 2005). An independent company has been awarded a concession to conduct the fare

collection and is responsible for the management; it is also in charge of collecting

revenues and depositing them in a trust fund, from which the different system agents are

paid according to the conditions set out in contracts. The city government is in charge of

maintaining the infrastructure and conducting complementary infrastructure

improvements when needed (Cracknell, 2003).

As innovative as TM may have been, the system is not, however, as completely

efficient as it should be. First of all, passengers jamming into the buses during peak

hours is now an observable phenomenon, which creates long waiting times and forces

users to wait twenty minutes or more to board a train. Echeverry presented some NPV

results for different discount rates that reveal negative net benefits from the first phase

of TM, amounting to US $64 million for a discount rate of nine percent. This is due

mainly to high infrastructure investments not being recovered by fares and an increase

in travel times for users of traditional systems, as a consequence of the relocation of bus

routes (Echeverry et al., 2005). Second of all, the last phase has been developed in the

midst of unfortunate events, due largely in part to poor governing structures from both

the public and the private sectors, resulting in corruption scandals that have diminished

the image of the system. 6Contrato de concesión para la prestación del servicio público de transporte terrestre masivo urbano de pasajeros en el sistema Transmilenio (Draft). Retrieved from the PPPRIC website available at: http://ppp.worldbank.org/public-private partnership/sites/ppp.worldbank.org/files/documents/Transmilenio%20Fase%20I.pdf

33

Concerning the revenues of the system, two main features can be identified.

First, the system has been designed as an autonomous, self-sustainable system, meaning

that it relies on cash flow to sustain itself and does not require any form of subsidy

outside of its operation7. Users are charged an equilibrium tariff, which reflects the

variation of costs within the system while responding to standards of operations and

returns that the system requires, in order to provide the service under the pre-established

operation standards. To update the tariff, an independent body was created in the

contract for this specific purpose, so as to not allow the adjustment to the tariff to be

dependent on negotiations between the contractors. TM works both as a revenue-based

PPP and availability based payment. Second, a trust fund was created in order to

manage the revenues within a “patrimony of affectation”.8

3. Mobility Masterplan9

Ruling 319 of 2006, which contains the Master Mobility Plan, was issued by the then

Mayor of Bogotá to implement the Integrated Public Transport System. This new model

seeks to integrate all modes of transportation in existence within the city, i.e., buses, the

TM, and taxis into one system. Transmilenio S.A. is in charge of overseeing the whole

merger process. The Master Plan mandates the participation of the private sector in the

new system, by allowing vehicle owners to participate in the equity of the new

companies that will comprise the system. The projects that are already running will

maintain their scheme but will adjust to the new technical and operational conditions set

by the Master Plan.

C. Form of investment

In order to achieve an efficient transportation system, foreign know-how has to be

introduced in the country. PPP is a good way to do this, when taking into consideration

that a merely public provision would not open the doors to international investment and 7 Idem 8 In Spanish this is called “Patrimonio Autónomo” and implies that the assets produced by the system are not part of the general estate of the company and are therefore autonomous to it. 9 This section draws upon Decree 316/06. Available at: http://www.alcaldiabogota.gov.co/sisjur/normas/Norma1.jsp?i=21066

34

that private participation in the sector is not enough. As previously mentioned, the case

of public transportation in Bogotá shows how little private participation contributed to

the enhancement of the service. It is therefore necessary to draw from the best

worldwide examples of proper implementation, which indicates that the best way in

which to accomplish this is by having a successful foreign company invest and handle

the operation of the system.

1. FDI in Colombia and modes of entry for foreign investors10

We have argued so far for the inclusion of best practice from developed countries into

developing countries and for an injection of foreign direct investment in infrastructure

projects. FDI has shown to be an important vehicle in transferring technology only

when combined with a strong absorptive capability regarding human capital by the host

country. FDI can contribute highly to economic growth in the host country by bringing

advanced management skills and modern technology into the domestic market

(Borensztein, De Gregorio, & Lee, 1998).

In Colombia, FDI has increased during the last twenty years thanks to the

introduction of a more favorable regulatory framework for foreign investors. This

increase was made possible by an economic liberalization in the country followed by a

successful privatization policy. Foreign investment falls mainly under Law 9/1991 and

Decree 2080/2000. The purpose of both rulings is to encourage capital investments from

foreign economies in Colombia, within adequate control mechanisms and less complex

administrative procedures. Notably, both foreign and domestic investment are treated

equally by the law (Garavito, Iregui, & Ramírez, 2012).

2. Proposition for the structure of the SPV in the Colombian case

As described above, an SPV would be created to undertake the Integrated Public

Transportation System (IPTS) project as a whole. This firm is managed by a sponsor, an

10 This section draws upon law 9 of 1991, available at: http://www.banrep.gov.co/sites/default/files/paginas/LEY09DE1991CONHIPERVINCULOS-1.pdf and Decree 2080 of 2000, http://www.sice.oas.org/investment/NatLeg/COL/Dec2080_00_s.pdf

35

equity investor responsible for bidding, developing, and managing the project (Engel et

al., 2010). Given the structure of public transportation in Colombia, and the existence of

numerous operators, the SPV could be comprised of the various operators as

shareholders of the managing company. Currently, bus and mass transit systems in

existence and the traditional bus transportation system must be combined together and

be integrated together into a single IPTS project.

The idea of an SPV fits quite well with the objective of implementing an IPTS

for Bogotá. The establishment of such an entity would end the current inefficient

conditions described above and would help alleviate a system which is disorganized due

to a lack of coherence and harmony among the different players and their forms of

mismanaging the system. Furthermore, poor regulation has been a leading cause of the

problem because of weak legislative efforts in favor of community interests.

Additionally, operators are focused on a rent-seeking business that is held by politicians,

who in turn own the various controlling firms.

Three elements should be considered when undertaking the necessary

restructuring of the transportation system, namely: (i) the affiliating firms should

convert into true operating business firms, (ii) a public offering of shares from

Transmilenio S.A. should allow these new operating firms to become shareholders of

the latter, as well as the current vehicle owners, (iii) a reorganization of the current

routes and corridors should be undertaken, and (iv) the fare collection system should be

unified for all existing new companies that form part of Transmilenio S.A. (Villegas,

2008)

D. Key elements of the project

The Government of India, in connection with the World Bank, has set up a toolkit,

which can be very useful in identifying the steps required to establish a PPP.

36

1. VFM

As stated previously, in order to determine whether a PPP alternative is the best

option, it must first prove that it has a VFM higher than what is offered by publicly

funded projects. To determine this viability, its project revenues and the operational and

capital costs must be identified, in order to define an estimated return based on future

estimates. Even when the project is not viable on a standalone basis, it should not be

automatically discarded. Hence, feasible funding gaps could be considered so as to

make the project commercially viable subject, of course, to a qualitative analysis of the

same. The effects of public welfare, which should be achieved by a PPP alternative,

should offer high advantages in compensating for any source of financial support

coming from the government or any difference in VFM with a publicly funded project.

If a significant improvement can be achieved by the PPP model, the government should

in principle opt for it (CRISIL, 2009).

In order to build the financial model, some assumptions need to be made, i.e. in

regards to the project costs, grants or subsidies approved, revenues, and operation and

maintenance costs already identified. First, analysts must identify the revenues based on

those assumptions. Second, costs need to be identified and assessed in two main

categories, namely: (i) construction costs, arising ex ante of the project, and (ii)

operation and maintenance costs present during the life cycle of the project. The

assessment of revenues will then in turn help to determine the future cash-flows of the

project, with the help of profit and loss statements, projected balance sheets, and

projected cash-flow statements. In turn, the cash flow should be used for assessing the

financial viability of the project in terms of its appeal to potential investors who are

interested in the commercial feasibility of it meeting their expectation of an attractive

return on their investment. In corporate finance, NPV has been identified as one of the

best-suited tools to assess the viability of a project. (Brealey, Myers, & Allen, 2006).

While an argument can be made that PPP is the best way to achieve an efficient

infrastructure in transportation, the determination of the specific PPP structure also

offers complex steps and decision-making processes which need to be addressed,

especially bearing in mind that whichever structure is chosen, it needs to be integrated

into the existing structure of TM.

37

The studies conducted by the World Bank in the case of the city of Maharashtra

indicate that the first step after choosing a project to be part of a PPP financing

alternative is to define who holds the ownership of the assets. In Bogotá, both the public

and private sectors own the assets. The former owns the lanes and other infrastructure

facilities, and the latter owns the vehicles. As a second step, risks need to be identified,

allocated, and included in a contract model for the bidding to take place (CRISIL,

2009).

Considering the existent infrastructure and operating urban transportation

system, there are numerous projects down the pipeline, which need to be accounted for

by the IPTS project, which needs to build on these sub-projects and prioritize some key

areas.

2. Joint-Venture

For the project to be efficient in developing countries, some of the best practices from

countries where the models have worked and have shown positive outcomes must be

imported. It is obvious that in order to attain high standards, the status quo must shift to

other parameters, including psychological nuances that have proven to exist in

developing countries. It is undeniable that large cities like Berlin or London or even

Santiago have a far better transportation system than a city like Bogotá; therefore, it is

important for international private firms to be allowed to participate in the provision of

the service—alongside national ones—as they possess the necessary expertise and are

familiar with the types of innovative practices that need to be implemented.

The opportunities for Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) in developing countries

must then be incentivized. A Joint-Venture arrangement is one of these forms in which

oversees firms can enter domestic markets. A Joint-Venture would be a preferable form

of FDI because it would imply the joining of forces between the existing local

companies and the foreign company and advanced international know-how would

actually be transferred to the national companies that have proven not to have sufficient

technology to offer a high-quality system. A number of advantages can be identified for

38

transnational corporations (TNCs) to access markets in developing host countries

(UNCTAD,2008).

For instance, these foreign companies hold a competitive advantage by being

sizable and well established, with proven track records of large cash-flows and financial

capabilities, which makes them more inclined to raise funding for projects if they act as

sponsors of the SPV, both in the home-country market and in international markets

(UNCTAD,2008). They are also able to infuse advanced technological expertise into

host firms in developing countries. More specifically, the competitive advantages of

opening the door to TNCs for the provision of public infrastructure lies on the following

benefits: “specialist expertise, ability to organize and operate networks, engineering

skills, environmental know-how, project management capabilities, financial prowess

and managerial expertise” (UNCTAD2008, p. 21).

This form of FDI is also known as Greenfield investment, as opposed to cross-

border M&A. The suggestion of a joint-venture mode of entrance for TNC is important

because it relies on the transmission of their expertise to the whole industry in the host

country. This dissemination effect is not sufficiently achieved by wholly-owned foreign

subsidiaries. Cooperation is optimal, and it can only be achieved if the existing local

companies remain existent and can further apply the knowledge acquired. In the case of

an M&A, the local company would be squeezed out by the new foreign company

neglecting the results sought. Greenfield FDI may be undertaken in the form of a joint-

venture with local partners, be it public or private. Foreign investors become owners of

assets at the beginning of the project and build a new facility. The investor assumes the

revenue risk, as the government normally does not provide any guarantees for it, along

with the construction, operating, and market risks for the project. There are two types of

combined contracts: “Greenfield” projects, if the participation of the transnational

corporation involves a building from scratch task, or “Brownfield” projects, if private

participation is limited to rehabilitate existing facilities (Vuksanović & Milojčić, 2011).

Of course this will only lead to a competitive advantage if it can be proven that

TNCs do actually possess a higher level of expertise than do local firms. In the case of

public transportation in Bogotá, it appears quite clearly that the system, especially the

bus system, is not comparable to other systems managed by other firms worldwide.

39

3. Sufficient demand

This paper proposes that the best option is a revenue-based transportation system, in

which users pay directly for the service (EPEC,2010). As previously mentioned, such is

the case for TM, which has proven sustainable up to the moment, i.e., no financial input

from the local government has been necessary. For the IPTS to work, the local

government must examine the capacity and the willingness of users to pay for the

service, especially when taking into account the likelihood that tariffs will need to be

changed in order to cover operation and maintenance costs or meet cash-flow targets

(EPEC, 2010).

It is important to promote demand for public transportation as well as

improvements to the quality of service. Thus, the focus here has been to challenge the

act of promoting public transportation from the supply side by making it more efficient.

However, it is equally critical to promote transportation on the demand side. Awareness

of the advantages of using public transportation over privately owned vehicles must be

stimulated among the citizens in Bogotá. A challenge for project managers and public

authorities will be to adequately position the improved public transportation system

within the public transportation network, i.e., TM, taxis (Parikesit & Susantono, 2013),

by adapting it to the new infrastructure that would result from implementing a new PPP

model.

Sufficient demand that generates revenues is linked to added value, such as

efficiency, speed, safety, and others, that the private party can provide and which the

public party seems not to be able to. Bogotá, with its background of constant failure in

achieving these standards in the public provision, is proof that another type of model

will be capable of fulfilling the voids that exist nowadays. Private and foreign investors

will not be subject to political conflicts present nowadays. Moreover, a study conducted

in 2008 by the National Department of Planning exposed the favorable outcomes of the

PPP model and has set forward the main challenges faced by the infrastructure sector,

namely: (i) adjustment and development of pertinent political and regulatory frames; (ii)

appropriate analysis of the technical needs in terms of infrastructure; (iii) incentives for

development of new financial instruments in order to attract institutional investors to

invest for the long-term, and (iv) improvement of institutions (CONPES,2008). The

40

Government of Colombia agrees that public resources need to be optimized in order for

public debt not to be affected. Hence, innovative arrangements found in alternative

mechanisms must be introduced in the Colombian regulation to attract foreign investors

(Preamble Bill 160, 2011). On the grounds that PPPs lead to financial structures that

promote the use of capital markets, the establishment of Colombian PPP Law was

actually motivated by the urge to develop capital markets, which would finance public

infrastructure projects and alleviate the burden on the public debt.

Forecasting the demand as accurately as possible is also a challenge to be met, as

the risk for this demand is more difficult to assess, and particularly in developing

countries where low predictability of the economic growth makes forecasting demand a

difficult task (UNECE, 2008).

4. Tariff

Both the creation of the SPV and the partnership with a TNC will most likely lead to the

establishment of a monopoly that needs to be regulated since no competition would

control prices in the market. In this case, tariffs need to be regulated and set by the

government in order to ensure a fair price to users. Efficient regulation is needed in

order to avoid potential abuse by the monopolist. During the last decade, Colombia has

addressed this concern by expanding its competition policy, especially with the

introduction of Law 1340/09, which brought notorious improvements in dealing with

mergers and acquisitions. Tariffs should also remain flexible in order for their

adjustments to have minimal impacts on cash-flows and make the project financially

viable (Kwak et al., 2009). For Estache et.al (2004), price regulation should aim at

estimating as accurately as possible the average tariffs to be charged, reflecting as

accurately as possible all risks and still providing an incentive for investors to commit to

projects for the long run. Along this line, Guasch (2004) presents two main types of

regulation: the price cap and the rate of return. The first one is straight forward, and the

second one consists on setting the tariff to comply with the firms’ returns, which are

adjusted each year.

41

VII. Conclusion

The need for an improved and more efficient public infrastructure has been largely

responsible for the search of hybrid investment models, different from traditional ones,

whether public or private, to ensure a high quality provision of services that are

essential to the population. The traditional forms of undertaking public infrastructure

projects before the entrance of PPPs in the 1990s, namely public procurement and

privatization, felt short in completely addressing user’s needs. Numerous failures

became observable.

The evolution of private participation in the provision of public infrastructure

services has differed from country to country. The model remains novel and infant in

many aspects—still in a maturing period. The ways that a PPP can come into existence

extend largely and the broadness of the concept may be confusing when implementing

the same. However, some examples of best practices can be observed, especially in

developed countries, leading to the conclusion that a PPP, if properly implemented, can

create better outcomes than previous existent models. The crisis in urban transportation

systems in developing cities has created the need for changing the structure under which

these projects are being undertaken. Evolution in the provision of the service seems to

reflect that an overhaul of the system needs to take into account innovative and hybrid

models such as PPPs. The model might be helpful in overcoming the current less-than-

ideal conditions of infrastructure in developing countries and the problems of bad

governance, inefficiency of operations, and inadequate regulatory and legislative

frameworks.

A sound financial viability plan analyzed by assessing the VFM actually

afforded in PPP is the main element for those in charge to opt either for or against the

model when deciding on an infrastructure project.

All of the latter illustrates how these elements can be applied in the case of

Colombia, where PPP remains a misunderstood and confusing concept, but where

efforts are gradually being made to comprehend the model and its potential for

increasing efficiency when implemented for existing and new projects.

42

Notwithstanding the novelty and the positive aspects of the PPP model, whereas

they seem to provide very important advantages in comparison to traditional public

funding, it may not always be the case and it is important not to make this private

funding model a default one. For instance, in England, reports have shown that PFI-

funded projects were not necessarily of higher quality or more innovative than

traditional public works. Hence, the certainty of success in the applicability of PPP is

still to be determined and tackled.

43

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Acharya, S. R., & Morichi, S. (2013). Promoting Integrated Urban Transport System

Transport Development in Asian Megacities (pp. 193-227): Springer.

Akintoye, A., Beck, M., & Hardcastle, C. (2003). Public-private partnerships: Wiley

Online Library.

Allen & Overy. (2010). Global Guide to Public-Private Partnerships. Retrieved

20/07/2013, from http://viewer.zmags.com/publication/5db30be7#/5db30be7/80

Batley, R. (2001). Public-private partnerships for urban services. The challenge of

urban government: Policies and practices, 199-214.

Blanc-Brude, F., Goldsmith, H., & Valila, T. (2006). Ex ante construction costs in the

European road sector: a comparison of public-private partnerships and

traditional public procurement.

Borensztein, E., De Gregorio, J., & Lee, J.-W. (1998). How does foreign direct

investment affect economic growth? Journal of international Economics, 45(1),

115-135.

Brealey, R. A., Myers, S. C., & Allen, F. (2006). Corporate finance (Vol. 8): McGraw-

Hill/Irwin Boston et al.

Cracknell, J. (2003). TransMilenio busway-based mass transit, Bogotá, Colombia.

Retrieved 18/07/2013, from

http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTURBANTRANSPORT/Resources/Factsh

eet-TransMilenio.pdf

CRISIL. (2009). Toolkit for Public Private Partnership in Urban Transport (Bus

Transport) for State of Maharashtra.

Chris Chan, D. F., Heather Roper, Chris Sayers. (2009). Public Infrastructure

Financing: An International Perspective: Australian Government - Productivity

Commission Staff Working Paper.

44

Economist Intelligence Unit. (2010). Evaluating the environment for public-private

partnerships in Latin America and the Caribbean. The Economist.

Echeverry, J. C., Ibáñez, A. M., Moya, A., Hillón, L. C., Cárdenas, M., & Gómez-Lobo,

A. (2005). The economics of TransMilenio, a mass transit system for Bogotá

[with comments]. Economía, 5(2), 151-196.

Engel, E., Fischer, R., & Galetovic, A. (2013). The basic public finance of public–

private partnerships. Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(1), 83-

111.

Engel, E., Fischer, R. D., & Galetovic, A. (2010). The economics of infrastructure

finance: Public-private partnerships versus public provision. EIB Papers, 15(1),

40-69.

Estache, A., & De Rus, G. (2000). The regulation of transport infrastructure and

services: a conceptual overview: ULB--Universite Libre de Bruxelles.

Estache, A., & Gómez‐Lobo, A. (2005). Limits to competition in urban bus services in

developing countries. Transport Reviews, 25(2), 139-158.

Estache, A., Juan, E., & Trujillo-Castellano, L. (2007). Public-private partnerships in

transport. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper Series, Vol.

Estache, A., & Serebrisky, T. (2004). Where do we stand on transport infrastructure

deregulation and public-private partnership? World Bank Policy Research

Working Paper(3356).

European Commission. (2003). Guidelines for Successful Public-Private Partnerships.

In DG Regional Policy (Ed.). Brussels: European Commission.

European PPP Expertise Center (EPEC). (2010). A Guide to Guidance - Sourcebook for

PPPs in TEN-Transport

Evans, A. (1987). A theoretical comparison of competition with other economic regimes

for bus services. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 7-36.

45

Freire, M. E., & Stren, R. E. (2001). The challenge of urban government: policies and

practices: World Bank Publications.

Garavito, A., Iregui, A. M., & Ramírez, M. T. (2012). Inversión Extranjera Directa en

Colombia: Evolución reciente y marco normativo: BANCO DE LA

REPÚBLICA.

Gómez-Ibáñez, J. A. (2003). Regulating Infrastructure: Monopoly, Contracts, and

Discretion: Harvard University Press.

Grimsey, D., & Lewis, M. K. (2004). Public and private partnerships. The worldwide

revolution in infrastructure provision and project finance.

Grout, P. A. (1997). The economics of the private finance initiative. Oxford review of

economic policy, 13(4), 53-66.

Grout, P. A. (2005). Value-for-money measurements in public-private partnerships. EIB

Papers, 10(2), 33-56.

Grütter, J. (2006). BRT Bogotá, Colombia: TransMilenio phase II–IV: Technical

Report, Grütter Consulting on behalf of Corporación Andina de Fomento (CAF)

and TransMilenio SA, Bogota, Colombia.

Guasch, J. L. (2004). Granting and renegotiating infrastructure concessions: doing it

right: World Bank Publications.

Harris, C. (2003). Private participation in infrastructure in developing countries:

trends, impacts, and policy lessons: World Bank-free PDF.

House of Commons Treasury Committee. (2010). Private finance initiative. Seventeenth

report of Session, 2012.

Kitchen, H. (2005). Delivering local/municipal services. Paper presented at the Prepared

for a workshop on: Strengthening Responsive and Accountable Local

Government in China, Dali, Yunnan Province, China.

46

Kwak, Y. H., Chih, Y., & Ibbs, C. W. (2009). Towards a comprehensive understanding

of public private partnerships for infrastructure development. California

Management Review, 51(2), 51-78.

Leber, J., & Perrott, C. M. (2012). Mass Rapid Transit: A Tool for Urban Expansion.

National Council on Economic and Social Policies (CONPES). (2008). CONPES 3538.

Parikesit, D., & Susantono, B. (2013). Strengthening the Role of Public Transport

Transport Development in Asian Megacities (pp. 107-142): Springer.

Political Science Institut. (2012). Asociaciones Público Privadas Ley 1508 de 2012.

. Preamble Bill 160. (2011). Bogota: Retrieved from

http://servoaspr.imprenta.gov.co:7778/gacetap/gaceta.nivel_3.

The World Bank. (1994). World Development Report 1994: infrastructure for

development: World Bank Publications.

United Nations Conference on Trade Development (UNCTAD). (2008). World

Investment Report 2008: Transnational Corporations, and the Infrastructure

Challenge: United Nations Environment Programme.

United Nations Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE). (2008). Guidebook on

Promoting Good Governance in Public-Private Partnerships

Villegas, L. B. (2008). Las Ventajas del Sistema Integrado de Transporte, El Tiempo.

Retrieved from http://www.eltiempo.com/archivo/documento/MAM-2983688

Vuksanović, B., & Milojčić, D. (2011). Paving the way: Maximizing the value of

private finance in infrastructure-World Economic Forum,

PricewaterhouseCoopers, New York, 2010. Put i saobraćaj, 57(3), 65-69.

WSP International Management Consulting Evaluation Team. (2007). Literature

Review on Private Sector Infrastructure Investment: Department for

International Development - UK Government.