public insurance and private savings: who is affected and...

29
Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and by how much? Alex Maynard a and Jiaping Qiu b, * a Department of Economics, University of Toronto, 150 St. George St. Toronto, ON, Canada, M5S 3G7. b Clarica Financial Services Research Centre, School of Business and Economics Wilfrid Laurier University, 75 University Ave. West, Waterloo, ON, Canada N2L 3C5. April 16, 2005 Abstract This paper investigates the effect of Medicaid on household savings across different wealth groups. It finds that the disincentive effect of Medicaid on household savings is heavily concentrated in the middle net worth households. In contrast, the effects on the bottom and top net worth households are quite small and insignificant. These heteroge- neous incentive effects are partly explained by Medicaid asset tests. The results suggest that Medicaid expansions targeted at the poorest households are unlikely to discourage sav- ings, whereas those targeted at the median household may generate substantial crowd-out. Moreover, they suggest some caution regarding the ability of public insurance programs to explain the low savings rates among the very poor. JEL Classification: I18, D10 Keywords: Medicaid, Precautionary savings, Asset tests, IV quantile regression * Correspondence may be sent to either author. E-mail: [email protected] (A. Maynard), [email protected] (J. Qiu). Fax: (416) 978-6713 (A. Maynard), (519) 884-0201 (J. Qiu). Phone: (416) 978-4358 (A. Maynard), (519) 884-1970 (J. Qiu).

Upload: others

Post on 14-Jul-2020

1 views

Category:

Documents


0 download

TRANSCRIPT

Page 1: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and

by how much?

Alex Maynarda and Jiaping Qiub,∗

aDepartment of Economics, University of Toronto, 150 St. George St.

Toronto, ON, Canada, M5S 3G7.

bClarica Financial Services Research Centre, School of Business and Economics

Wilfrid Laurier University, 75 University Ave. West, Waterloo, ON, Canada N2L 3C5.

April 16, 2005

Abstract

This paper investigates the effect of Medicaid on household savings across different

wealth groups. It finds that the disincentive effect of Medicaid on household savings is

heavily concentrated in the middle net worth households. In contrast, the effects on the

bottom and top net worth households are quite small and insignificant. These heteroge-

neous incentive effects are partly explained by Medicaid asset tests. The results suggest

that Medicaid expansions targeted at the poorest households are unlikely to discourage sav-

ings, whereas those targeted at the median household may generate substantial crowd-out.

Moreover, they suggest some caution regarding the ability of public insurance programs to

explain the low savings rates among the very poor.

JEL Classification: I18, D10

Keywords: Medicaid, Precautionary savings, Asset tests, IV quantile regression

∗Correspondence may be sent to either author.

E-mail: [email protected] (A. Maynard), [email protected] (J. Qiu).

Fax: (416) 978-6713 (A. Maynard), (519) 884-0201 (J. Qiu).

Phone: (416) 978-4358 (A. Maynard), (519) 884-1970 (J. Qiu).

Page 2: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

1 Introduction

A central question concerning public health insurance programs is the extent to which they crowd

out private savings. Government insurance plans, such as Medicaid may crowd out savings in two

primary ways. First, by insuring households against out of pocket medical expenses, Medicaid

may reduce the household’s reliance on precautionary savings as an alternative form of insurance,

as suggested by the simulation results in Kotlikoff (1989). Secondly, as demonstrated by Hubbard

et al. (1995), Medicaid asset test eligibility requirements act as an implicit tax on wealth and

may encourage households to spend down assets in order to qualify for Medicaid.1

The effect of health insurance on savings through precautionary motives has been an active

area of empirical research (see for example, Starr-McCluer (1996), Palumbo (1999), Chou et al.

(2003)).2 A recent study by Gruber and Yelowitz (1999) focuses on the effect of Medicaid on

household savings, resulting from both precautionary motives and asset tests. The novelty of their

approach is the use of the exogenous variation in Medicaid eligibility arising from the expansion of

Medicaid to identify the effect of public insurance on wealth holdings. They find strong empirical

support for the contention that, on average, an increase in a household’s Medicaid coverage leads

to a reduction in household wealth. Moreover, they find this effect to be substantially magnified

in the presence of an asset test.

These population average effects provided important new stylized facts on the crowding out

effect of Medicaid on savings. Yet, average effects alone provide little indication as to how

crowd-out effects vary across households with different wealth levels. There are several reasons

why this may be of particular interest. Medicaid was originally designed as a safety net for

low wealth/low income households. Savings rates among these groups are already quite low.

Thus, although the welfare implications are uncertain,3 to the extent that the savings crowd-out

is concentrated among poor households, this may be of particular concern to policy makers.

In fact, the calculations in Gruber and Yelowitz (1999) suggest that the disincentive effects

associated with Medicaid are too small to contribute much to low national savings rates, but

1Since Medicaid is an in-kind transfer payment, the associated wealth effect provides a third channel whereby

Medicaid may affect savings.2A related literature has examined the extent to which public health insurance crowds out private insurance

(see Cutler and Gruber (1996), Currie (1995), Raska and Rask (2000), Blumber et al. (2000), and Shore-Sheppard

et al. (2000)).3Unlike the savings reductions due to Medicaid asset tests, reductions in precautionary savings may not cause

distortions, as precautionary saving is itself an inefficient form of savings.

2

Page 3: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

still large enough to contribute substantially to the low savings rates among poor households.

Likewise, it is not just the average crowd-out effects, but also their differential impact across

wealth and income groups, that are of interest from an economic modelling perspective. For

example, in Hubbard et al. (1995) public insurance, in combination with an asset test, provides

much stronger savings disincentives to low, than to high, income households. They then use this

heterogeneity to explain the sharp and rather puzzling disparity of savings rates observed across

wealth and income groups.

Thus both economic and policy considerations suggest the importance of examining the disin-

centive effects of Medicaid across different segments of the wealth distribution. However, to date

we know of no empirical work which has addressed this issue. In this paper we ask whose savings

are effected by Medicaid and by how much. Using an instrumental variable quantile regres-

sion approach, we investigate the effect of Medicaid on savings across households with different

wealth levels. In this way we can directly measure the savings effect of Medicaid on the poorest

households, who make the greatest use of Medicaid and whose savings are lowest. Moreover this

allows us to assess the empirical predictions of Hubbard et al. (1995) on the differential effect of

Medicaid Asset tests across households of different means. Our study yields interesting empirical

results. Confirming the average results of Gruber and Yelowitz (1999), we find a strong negative

impact of Medicaid coverage on median household wealth. As predicted by Hubbard et al. (1995)

we also find that the effect dissipates as we move into the upper quantiles. More interestingly,

the effect again dissipates in the lower quantiles. In fact, for the poorest households, who have

the highest participation rates in Medicaid, there is no evidence that Medicaid has any impact

whatsoever on household asset accumulation. This is an interesting result that appears not to

be anticipated in the previous literature.

We explore the explanation behind the heterogeneous savings effects uncovered here. The

differential impact of asset testing across net worth quantiles is found to be an important com-

ponent to this explanation. Like Medicaid spending itself, we find that Medicaid asset tests also

have no effect on the top and bottom net worth quantiles. The effect is strongest for the lower

middle quantiles (0.2-0.5). For these households, asset levels tend to be only a few thousand

dollars above the eligibility ceilings. Thus, any policy or family structure change that leads them

to become eligible on other grounds creates a strong savings disincentive in order to meet the

asset test. By contrast, households in the top quantiles would have to spend down substantial

assets in order to qualify for Medicaid. As argued by Hubbard et al. (1995), they are unlikely to

3

Page 4: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

find this an attractive option. Finally, the households in the bottom quantiles have few savings

to begin with and thus qualify automatically on asset test grounds, without any need to further

reduce their asset holdings.

Nevertheless, we find that the differential incentives caused by asset testing can explain only

part of the overall heterogeneity in the savings response to Medicaid. Even in the absence

of an asset test, the effect of Medicaid on savings still varies considerably across quantiles.

This suggests that the strength of a household’s precautionary savings response to Medicaid

also depends on its wealth level. In particular, households in the middle quantiles may have

substantial precautionary savings reserved for use in the event of a medical emergency, prior to

their enrollment in Medicaid. After meeting eligibility requirements such precautionary savings

may no longer be necessary, suggesting a sharp drop in net assets. On the other hand, the very

poorest households have little to no precautionary savings, regardless of whether they are eligible

for Medicaid. Moreover, many of these households may not be able to increase consumption much

due to credit constraints.

Our findings have several important implications. Medicaid has traditionally targeted poor

households, for whom savings rates are quite low. Although the welfare effects are uncertain,

any tendency to further crowd out these already low savings may still be of concern in a pro-

gram designed to address poverty. Our results are thus somewhat optimistic, in that we find

no evidence to suggest that Medicaid discourages savings among the very poorest households.

The heterogeneity in disincentive effects also has implications for Medicaid expansions (or con-

tractions). In particular, it suggests that the degree of savings crowd-out associated with an

expansion depends as much on the nature, as on the magnitude, of the expansion. Expansions

that increase eligibility or benefits for households in the lowest net wealth quantiles are unlikely

to crowd out savings much, whereas those that target households in the middle quantiles may

result in substantial crowd-out.

Finally, our results suggest some caution regarding the ability of Medicaid to fully explain

the puzzling low savings rates among the poorest households. Standard consumption smoothing

models tend to have difficulty explaining the difference in savings rates between low and high

income households. This suggests that heterogeneity of some form is likely important in resolving

this puzzle. Public insurance programs, which are relevant to poor, but not wealthy households,

thus provide a promising explanation (Hubbard et al., 1995). Our results are supportive of this

explanation in so far as it applies to the moderately poor households in the lower middle net

4

Page 5: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

wealth quantiles. On the other hand, we do not find any evidence that public insurance helps

to explain the abnormally low savings rates found among the very poorest households. Simply

put, these households do not appear to maintain any significant savings, regardless of whether

or not they are on Medicaid.

The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. Section 2 describes the data and methodology.

Section 3 presents and explains the empirical results, and Section 4 summarizes and concludes.

2 Data and methodology

2.1 Data

In this study we employ data from the Survey of Income and Program Participation (SIPP),

spanning 1984-1993.4 The SIPP consists of a series of overlapping panels initiated on a yearly

basis, but lasting for a total 24-32 months, during which time the same households are repeatedly

interviewed at four month intervals in order to collect data on household income and Medicaid

participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the sum of financial assets and home,

vehicle, and business equity, net of unsecured debt, is collected from each household on the fourth

and seventh interviews as part of a special topical module.5

This is a particularly interesting period in which to study the effects of Medicaid. Prior

to 1984, Medicaid had strict income and asset requirements, and was limited to female-headed

households receiving welfare benefits through the Aid to Families with Dependent Children

(AFDC) program. However, over the next decade Medicaid underwent a number of expansions

in which both family structure, income, and asset eligibility requirements were relaxed. This was

the result of separate legislative changes passed and implemented over several years and thus

provides substantial exogenous variability in Medicaid benefits across the time series dimension

of the data. Although the changes occurred at the federal level, the legislation left the states

considerable flexibility as to the speed and, to some extent, the depth of the expansion. States

4We thank Jonathan Gruber and Aaron Yelowitz for generously sharing their data with us.5Households with imputed net worth (about 1/4 of households) are excluded from the sample on account of

the reported problems with this imputation method (Curtin et al. (1989), Hurd et al. (1998)). Likewise the

sample was restricted to heads of household aged 16-64 and a maximum household age of 64, in order to exclude

Medicare recipients. Also omitted were households containing more than one family. See Gruber and Yelowitz

(1999) for further details.

5

Page 6: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

also varied widely according to the age cut-off for children’s eligibility. Thus these changes also

gave rise to considerable exogenous variability across states. Finally, even within the same state

and year, the value of the eligibility expansion varied considerably across households, depending

on the household family structure, health status, and the local cost of medical services. The

reader is referred to Gruber and Yelowitz (1999) and Currie and Gruber (1996a & 1996b) for a

detailed account of these expansions.

2.2 Methodology

Our primary interest lies in the response of household net worth to changes in the value of

the Medicaid subsidy, which reflect changes to both Medicaid eligibility and generosity. The

dependent variable, net worth, is directly available from SIPP. The primary regressor, Medicaid

eligible dollars (MED), is a carefully constructed measure of the household’s expected Medicaid

subsidy, proposed by Gruber and Yelowitz (1999) and Currie and Gruber (1996a & 1996b). This

measure takes into account variation at the household level in both the probability of Medicaid

eligibility (due to differences in family structure, income, assets, and eligibility requirements),

and expected health care costs (as a function of family, age, and sex composition, and state-

specific medical costs). The expected Medicaid benefit for family j in year t is thus defined

as

MEDjt =∑

i

ELIGit × SPENDit, (1)

where ELIGit is the probability that family member i is eligible for Medicaid in year t and

SPENDit is the expected Medicaid subsidy conditional on eligibility. Since the savings decision

is inherently dynamic, the full value of the Medicaid subsidy (MED) is defined as the discounted

sum of expected future Medicaid benefits.

As discussed above, the large but uneven expansion of Medicaid gives rise to substantial

exogenous variation in medical eligibility. Nevertheless, eligibility also depends on both wealth

levels (via asset tests) and income levels (via means tests), which themselves depend in part

on net worth. This suggests that a substantial portion of the variability in eligibility may be

endogenous and thus MED requires an instrument. A natural instrument in this context is the

exogenous component to Medicaid eligible dollars. This is constructed in Gruber and Yelowitz

(1999) as a second measure of expected Medicaid subsidies, simulated Medicaid eligible dollars

(SIMMED), in which the probability of eligibility is conditioned on only the exogenous factors:

6

Page 7: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

education, age, state, and year. To be precise, the probability of eligibility ELIG in (1) is replaced

by SIMELIG, in which this probability is simulated using only the exogenous factors discussed

above. Then the expected Medicaid benefit for family j in year t conditional on exogenous factors

only is given by

SIMMEDjt =∑

i

SIMELIGit × SPENDit,

which is defined in the same way as MED in (1), except that ELIG is replaced by SIMELIG.

As with MED, the final value of SIMMED for family j is then calculated as the present value of

discounted future benefits.

To examine the effect of Medicaid across different segments of wealth distribution, we em-

ploy a quantile regression approach, which allows us to estimate the marginal effect of a given

Medicaid expansion for households at different points in the conditional wealth distribution.

This makes it possible to separately assess the implication of Medicaid reform for poor, middle

class, and wealthy households. Since Medicaid eligible dollars requires an instrument, we employ

the instrumental variable quantile regression approach of Chernozhukov and Hansen (2004b &

2005), which is described in the following section. Thus the baseline specification consists of an

instrumental quantile regression of log net worth on Medicaid eligible dollars, together with a

large number of control variates to account for the other factors that enter the savings decision.

These include state dummies, time dummies, and controls for education, family demographic

structure and other household covariates.6

2.3 Instrumental quantile regression

2.3.1 Quantile regression

Just as regression estimates the expectation of the dependent variable Y , conditional on the

regressors X, the quantile regression, introduced by Koenker and Bassett (1978), estimates the

τ quantile, QY (τ |x), of Y , conditional on X = x, where τε(0, 1) indexes the quantile level and

where capital letters denote random variables and lower case letters denote their realizations. In

a linear quantile regression model this is specified as

QY (τ |x) = x′γ(τ).

6While the inclusion of state and time dummies remove some of the exogenous variation in Medicaid eligible

dollars, substantial variation remains due to the other exogenous components and also their interaction with the

state and time dummies.

7

Page 8: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

In the regression case, the conditional expectation minimizes the expected quadratic loss in

predicting Y conditional on X. This leads naturally to the ordinary least squares estimator, in

which the regression coefficient β is chosen to minimizes the sample analogue

1

n

n∑i=1

(Yi −X ′iβ)

2

with respect to β. Likewise, Koenker and Bassett (1978) show that if the quadratic loss function

is replaced by the asymmetric absolute deviation loss function,

ρτ (u) = u (τ − 1(u < 0))

then the expected loss is instead minimized by the conditional quantile QY (τ |x). As in OLS,

the quantile regression coefficients are then chosen to minimize the finite sample analogue. In

other words, the τ quantile regression coefficient γ(τ) minimizes

1

n

n∑i=1

ρτ (Yi −X ′iγ)

with respect to γ. For example, ρτ (u) = 1/2|u| is used for Laplace’s median regression function.

The use of quantile regression offers two potential benefits over least squares. First, it is

more robust to both outliers and deviations from normality. In other words, even if one is solely

interested in a measure of central tendency, estimates of the conditional median (τ = 0.5), which

minimize the sum of absolute errors, are less sensitive to outliers than estimates of the conditional

mean, which minimize the sum of squared errors. This robustness property is important to the

current study, since net worth is highly skewed.

Most importantly for our study, quantile regression offers a richer description of the manner

in which the regressors influence the dependent variable. Rather than restricting the influence of

X to shifts in the conditional mean of Y , it allows for differential effects of X at different points

in the distribution of Y . This is because the coefficients γ(τ) are allowed to vary in a flexible

manner according to the quantile level τ . In particular, a linear quantile regression estimates the

model

Y = X ′γ(U) U |X ∼ Uniform(0,1), (2)

where Qy (τ |x) = x′γ(τ) is by design the τ quantile of Y conditional on X = x. This provides

a flexible description of the conditional distribution function.

In contrast, the standard regression model with homoscedastic errors restricts the influence of

the regressors to parallel shifts in the distribution function, in which they have the same influence

8

Page 9: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

across the entire distribution. In the current context, standard regression assumptions require

Medicaid to have the same expected impact on the wealthiest household in the sample as on the

poorest, whereas quantile regression allows us to estimate the impact on the wealthy separately

from the impact on the poor. In fact, letting where X ′ =(

1, X ′1

), β′1 =

(β0, β′1

), and

F () be a cumulative distribution function, we may rewrite the regression model with intercept

Y = β0 + X ′1β1 + ε, ε|X ∼ F (ε)

as a special case of the quantile regression model in (2), in which U = F (ε) is the quantile level of

ε and the quantile coefficients are restricted to be of the form γ(U)′ =(

β0 + F−1 (U) , X ′1β1

).

2.3.2 Instrumental quantile regression

Similar to the regressor/error orthogonality condition in standard regression, the quantile regres-

sion model in (2) requires the independence of the residual U and the regressor X. When one or

more of the regressors is endogenous, this condition is violated and standard quantile regression

yields inconsistent estimators. This is the case in the current study, since as discussed above,

Medical eligible dollars is endogenous and requires an instrument.

We therefore employ the instrumental quantile regression of Chernozhukov and Hansen (2004b

& 2005).7 Denoting the endogenous regressors by D, the included exogenous regressors by X,

and the excluded exogenous instruments by Z, we estimate the structural quantile regression

model

Y = D′α(U) + X ′β(U) U |X, Z ∼ Uniform(0,1), (3)

where D = δ (X, Z, V ) is determined endogenously as a function of X, Z, and an error term V ,

which is allowed to correlate with U . Note that for any given fixed value of d we may define a

potential or latent outcome Yd in parallel fashion as

Yd = d′α(U) + X ′β(U) U |X, Z ∼ Uniform(0,1). (4)

Since D is endogenously determined, the conditional quantiles of the observed outcome Y = YD

in (3) confound the influences of D and U . However, since d is fixed, the conditional (on X)

quantile function of the latent outcomes Yd in (4) captures the effect of d on Y , uncontaminated by

any feedback. Chernozhukov and Hansen (2004b & 2005) define the structural quantile function,

7See Chernozhukov and Hansen (2004a) for an application of this method to the wealth impact of 401 (K)

participation.

9

Page 10: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

sY (τ |d, x), as the conditional (on X) quantile function of the latent outcome Yd and model it

linearly as

sY (τ |d, x) = d′α(τ) + x′β(τ). (5)

Since Yd is latent the structural quantile function sY (τ |d, x) cannot be estimated directly by

quantile regression. However, under suitable regularity conditions, Chernozhukov and Hansen

(2005) show that it may identified by the conditional moment condition

P [Y ≤ sY (τ |D, X )|Z, X] = τ (6)

using the instrument Z.

The instrumental quantile regression of Chernozhukov and Hansen (2004b) provides a clever

method of estimating the structural quantile using the restriction in (6). Consider a particular

quantile level τ and define

Y τ = Y − sY (τ |D, X) = Y −D′α(τ)−X ′β(τ) (7)

as the value of Y centered about sY (τ |D, X). From (6), it follows that the τ quantile of Y τ

conditional on X and Z is zero by construction. Therefore in the reduced form linear quantile

regression

Y τ = X ′β2(U) + Z ′γ(U) (8)

of Y τ on X and Z this implies that β2(τ) = γ(τ) = 0. We may then rewrite (8) as

Y −D′α(τ) = X ′ (β(τ) + β2(u)) + Z ′γ(u) (9)

with the τ quantile of Y −D′α(τ) conditional on X and Z modelled as

QY−D′α (τ |X, Z) = X ′β(τ) + Z ′γ(τ) (10)

where β(τ) = β(τ) + β2(τ) = β(τ) and γ(τ) = 0.

Notice that there are no longer any endogenous regressors in (10) so that if α(τ) were known,

(10) could be estimated using standard quantile regression, yielding a consistent estimator β(τ)

for β(τ) and an estimator γ(τ) →p γ(τ) = 0. Since α(τ) is unknown we instead estimate (10) by

quantile regression over a grid of candidate values, say αj for j = 1, . . . J . Since Z is a relevant

instrument, D depends on Z and thus values of αj 6= α(τ) imply γj(τ) 6= 0 in the quantile

regression function

QY−D′αj(τ |X,Z) = X ′βj(τ) + Z ′γj(τ),

10

Page 11: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

whereas a correct value of αj = α(τ) implies γj(τ) = γ(τ) = 0. Thus the estimate α(τ) is

chosen as the value of αj, say αj∗ , which minimizes the distance of γj(τ) from γ(τ) = 0 using

a standard distance function of the form γj(τ)′A(α)γj(τ), where A where is the asymptotic

covariance of γ(τ). The corresponding estimate of β, say βj∗ , is used as the estimator for β(τ).

Chernozhukov and Hansen (2004b, proposition 2) prove under weak conditions that the resulting

estimators, α(τ) and β(τ), are root-n consistent and asymptotically normal and provide an an

explicit formula for the variance/covariance matrix.8 Moreover, their results apply also to the

case in which the original instrument Z is replaced by the fitted value from a standard first stage

linear regression of D on X and Z. This two-stage method is suggested by Chernozhukov and

Hansen (2004b) for use in practical application.

Thus, employing the method of Chernozhukov and Hansen (2004b), the first stage consists

of a linear regression of Medicaid eligible dollars (MED) on the instrument SIMMED and the

remaining covariates. The predicted variable from this first stage regression is then employed

as the instrument for MED in the second stage instrumental quantile regression. Thus the

same instrument and first stage regression is used for every quantile. Since both the instrument

and first-stage regression are the same as in Gruber and Yelowitz (1999) any differences in

interpretation that arise are solely due to the fact that we estimate a conditional quantile function

in the second stage, whereas they estimate the conditional mean function.

3 Empirical results

3.1 Summary statistics of household characteristics across net worth

quantiles

Since we are particularly interested in the savings effect of Medicaid and also to facilitate com-

parison with the regression of Gruber and Yelowitz (1999), we focus on households with positive

net worth. In Table 1 and 2 we first divide the households into 10 deciles ordered according to

their total household net worth. For each household we then calculate the average household

characteristics within each decile. Table 1 focuses on household asset holdings and medical eli-

gibility, while Table 2 describes the other household characteristics, including age, race, marital

status and education.

8The reader is referred to that paper for further details on the econometric procedure.

11

Page 12: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

Inspection of Table 1 reveals several interesting features. Row 1 shows average total net worth

broken down by decile. First, the distribution of total net worth has a wide range and is highly

skewed. The mean net worth is $65,888, compared to a median of $22,799. The average net

worth in the bottom decile is just $575, and for the fifth decile it is $22,185, whereas the average

for the top decile is $314,984. In the next two rows we divide net worth into total assets and total

debt. Row 4 shows the percentage of households that has positive debt. One can see that this

percentage is considerably lower among the bottom two deciles, 50% and 71% respectively, than

it is for the middle and upper deciles, for which it is generally about 90%. This suggests that

many of the poor households may face credit constraints and have little capacity to borrow, most

likely because few of these households have home equity or other collateral to borrow against.9

In fact, as seen by rows 5 and 6, which further divide total debt into secured and unsecured

debt, the majority of debt is secured across all quantiles and may indicate a cap on unsecured

borrowing ability.

Rows 7-8 show net equity in home (i.e. home value net of mortgage) and net equity in vehicle

(i.e. car value net of car loans). Next, rows 9-10 show the value of net worth excluding home

and the value of net worth excluding both home and vehicle. This break down is important

to our study for two reasons. First, both home equity and part of the value of the vehicle are

excluded from the Medicaid asset tests. Therefore the value of the household’s net worth that

is subject to an asset test lies between the value of net worth excluding equity in home and

the value of net worth excluding equity in both home and car. Thus this range gives a better

indication of household net worth relative to the asset tests ceilings, which were generally set in

the $1000-$2000 range during this sample period. Secondly, excluding house and/or car equity

may also give a better indication of a household’s liquid assets, which may be more responsive to

changes in Medicaid generosity. For the bottom decile, the average value of net worth excluding

home equity is under $500, while the average value of net worth excluding both home and

car equity is negative. These averages increase for the higher deciles, but still remain below

$10,000 and $5,000 respectively up through the fifth decile. This suggests that a large portion

of the population either qualifies or is relatively close to qualifying (i.e. within a few thousand

dollars) for the asset test restrictions when in place. Likewise, it also suggests relatively low

9In results not reported in the table, the percentage of households having positive net equity in home is 0.03

and 0.11, respectively, for the bottom two deciles. This compares to 0.75 and 0.95 for the fifth and top decile,

respectively.

12

Page 13: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

liquid wealth among the lowest quantiles, and therefore perhaps little flexibility in adjusting

consumption/savings decisions.

Rows 11-12 show both the dollar value of Medicaid eligible dollars and Medicaid eligible

dollars as a percentage of total net worth. The average value of Medicaid eligible dollars for the

bottom decile is $5,544 (963% of net worth), as compared to $1,115 (5.00% of net worth) for the

fifth decile, and only $588 (0.19% of net worth) for the top decile. Not surprisingly, this suggests

that Medicaid comprises a far more important factor in the decisions of households in the lower

and middle deciles than in the top deciles. Thus, it is reasonable to suspect that the savings

response to changes in Medicaid policy may differ substantially across wealth groups.

Rows 13-14 show both the standard deviation of Medicaid eligible dollars and the proportion

of households that have a positive value for Medicaid eligible dollars. One can see that both

values decrease monotonically with an increase in household net worth. The standard deviations

of Medicaid eligible dollars are $9,698, $3,677, and $2,028, respectively for the bottom, fifth and

top deciles. The percentage of households with positive Medicaid eligible dollars in the bottom,

fifth, and top deciles are 0.45, 0.21, and 0.16 respectively. It is interesting to note that even in the

bottom decile over 50% of households are not eligible for Medicaid and thus have no Medicaid

eligible dollars.

Table 2 presents some basic household characteristics averaged across net worth deciles. These

characteristics also differ considerably across quantiles. On average, the heads of households with

lower net wealth tend to be younger and have less education than those with high net worth.

They are also more likely to be female, black, and unmarried. When married, their spouses tend

to have less education. The difference in average characteristics across deciles also appears to

become sharper at either end of the spectrum. The bottom and top two deciles stand out relative

to the middle deciles, for which the characteristics tend to vary less across deciles. This suggests

that behavior may be different across deciles, particularly in the tails of the wealth distribution.

3.2 The effect of Medicaid across net worth quantiles

Gruber and Yelowitz (1999) estimate that a $1,000 increase in Medicaid eligible dollars reduces

average household savings by 2.51%. To facilitate comparison with the quantile regression results

discussed below, these estimates are replicated in column 2 of Table 3. Their results support

the contention that increased Medicaid generosity tends to reduce average savings due either to

13

Page 14: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

reductions in precautionary savings and/or the effect of asset testing. While these results provide

convincing evidence on the average savings effects of Medicaid, they give little indication as to

the distribution of this effect across wealth groups.

This issue is important from the perspective of both a policy and economic standpoint.

Medicaid is targeted primarily toward poorer households. Moreover, the mean effects of Medicaid

are substantial enough to impact the savings for poorer households, but too small to have a

significant impact on overall national savings rates (see Gruber and Yelowitz, 1999, p. 1271-1272).

Thus the effect of Medicaid on savings within the lower quantiles may have more relevance to

policy makers than the overall mean effect. Likewise, one of the most puzzling stylized facts about

savings behavior confronting the economic theorist is the stark difference in savings behavior

across wealth and income groups. In fact, one of the original motivations for investigating the

savings effect of Medicaid was as an attempt to explain these differences (see Hubbard et al.,

1995).

The considerable heterogeneity in both financial and household characteristics across different

net worth quantiles, presented in the previous section, also gives us good reason to believe that

the savings effect of Medicaid may vary across wealth quantiles. On one hand, Medicaid is a

much larger fraction of net worth for poorer households than for rich and this suggests that

changes in Medicaid may matter more for the lower and middle deciles than for those at the

top. On the other hand, households in the lowest quantiles have little net worth and few liquid

assets. Thus, they may have difficulty further reducing their savings in response to increases

in Medicaid. Likewise, given their credit constraints, further borrowing may not be feasible.

Moreover, the difference in net worth excluding home and/or vehicle equity across quantiles may

have important implications for the effect of asset testing on savings behavior. Households in

the lowest quantiles may require little, if any, savings adjustment in order to qualify for the asset

test, while those at the top may decide that the necessary reduction in assets is too large to

justify the benefits of qualifying for Medicaid.

Table 3 presents the analogous quantile regression results using the instrumental variable

quantile regression method of Chernozhukov and Hansen (2004b & 2005).10 The coefficients

show the effect of Medicaid on the conditional quantiles of net worth. We first consider the effect

of Medicaid on the median household net worth shown in column 7. The results show that a

10Recall that the first stage consists of the same OLS regression as in Gruber and Yelowitz (1999), which has

an excellent fit, with an F statistic over 7,000.

14

Page 15: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

$1000 increase in Medicaid eligible dollars leads to 5.47% drop in median net worth, statistically

significant at a 1% level. This confirms the robustness of the Gruber and Yelowitz (1999) result

that Medicaid has a significantly negative effect on household savings, even after taking into

account the highly skewed distribution of household net worth. In fact, the median effect is

stronger than the average effect.

We next investigate the effect of medical spending on the remaining deciles. The estimated

coefficients on Medicaid eligible dollars for the conditional quantiles of log net worth are given

together with their standard errors in first two rows of Table 3. These same estimates are also

displayed in Figure 1, together with a 90% confidence interval. The estimates show a very clear

pattern, as seen by the U-shape in Figure 1. The estimate is quite small and insignificant for

the bottom 0.1 quantile and marginally significant for the 0.2 quantile. The estimates remain

negative, but increase monotonically in magnitude and significance until reaching their trough

at the 0.6 quantile. At this point, they then decrease monotonically in magnitude, remaining

negative, but becoming insignificant again at the top 0.9 quantile.

The small savings effect of Medicaid found in the upper quantiles should not be surprising

given the relatively low value of Medicaid eligible dollars as a percentage of wealth for high net

worth households. Note that as reported in row 12 of Table 1, Medicaid eligible dollars averages

just 0.19% of net worth for the top decile, whereas it averages 5% of net worth for the fifth decile.

This suggests a substantially smaller percentage reduction in precautionary savings for high net

worth households in response to increased Medicaid coverage.

The results for high net worth households are also consistent with the model of Hubbard

et al. (1995), in which wealthier households are less likely to respond to an increase in Medicaid

generosity on account of the asset tests. By contrast, the asset test may lead to an enhanced

response among households in the lower middle quantiles, who may dis-save in order to meet

the asset test once other barriers, such as means-tests, are removed. Note that in Table 1,

row 9, average net worth excluding home equity is just $4,163 for the third decile. This is at

most a few thousands dollars shy of a $1000-$2000 asset test ceiling. In contrast, net worth

excluding home equity averages $200,229 in the top decile. This suggests that asset testing could

play a significantly different role in the savings response to Medicaid across different net worth

households. We explore the effect of asset testing across quantiles in detail in the next section.

Particularly interesting is the effect of Medicaid on the lower net worth quantiles, to whom

Medicaid is generally targeted. For these households the value of Medicaid is quite large relative

15

Page 16: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

to net worth. In fact, from row 12 of Table 1, Medicaid eligible dollars averages respectively

963.48% and 129.34% of total net worth for the bottom two deciles as compared to just 5% for

the fifth decile. Thus one might have expected a more pronounced savings response to Medicaid

in the bottom quantiles, whereas they in fact respond much less. As shown in Table 3, the

coefficients on Medicaid eligible dollars for the bottom two quantiles are −0.0031 (insignificant)

and −0.0190 (marginally significant) respectively. The effect becomes strongly significant and

increases in magnitude to −0.0407 and −0.0513 respectively for the third and fourth deciles.

Although this result may seem surprising given the importance of Medicaid to poorer house-

holds, two reasonable explanations nevertheless present themselves. The first is that households

in the lower quantile have little to no precautionary savings to draw down in response to an ex-

pansion in Medicaid eligibility. Average net worth excluding home and car equity, shown in Table

1, are already negative for the bottom two quantiles. Likewise, given their credit constraints,

these households may also have little capacity to borrow further. Presumably, in the absence

of wealth and borrowing constraints, they would respond to the reduction of future medical ex-

penditure uncertainties associated with increased Medicaid generosity by reducing their savings

or increasing their borrowing. However this precautionary saving channel may be blocked on

account of low wealth levels and borrowing constraints.

Secondly, the asset-testing channel may also become less important in the marginal savings

decisions of the poorest households. While it is convenient in theoretical models to set asset

ceilings to zero for simplicity (Hubbard et al., 1995, p. 374), they are typically set in the one-two

thousand dollar range in practice and generally exclude home equity and part of car equity. If

a household’s net worth already lies substantially below the asset ceiling prior to a Medicaid

expansion, then the asset test channel may not be operative for that household. In other words,

since the household already qualifies for Medicaid, no further wealth reductions are required to

meet the asset test. By contrast, a household with net worth above, but not too far above,

the asset test level may have a stronger incentive to spend down assets in order to qualify for

Medicaid on asset test grounds, especially after other eligibility requirements, such as means-tests

and demographic restrictions, have been relaxed.

16

Page 17: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

3.3 Asset testing across quantiles

As discussed above, in addition to precautionary saving, asset testing may have important im-

plications for savings behavior. To explore the role of asset testing in the effect of Medicaid

on savings, we include the interaction between Medicaid eligible dollars and asset testing. The

regression results with this interaction term are replicated from Gruber and Yelowitz (1999) in

the second column of Table 4. These results confirm that asset testing does indeed have a strong

effect. The negative effect of Medicaid eligible dollars is in fact twice as large with an asset test

in place than it is without one. As they explain, households may substantially spend down their

wealth to gain Medicaid eligibility in the presence of an asset test, once other binding Medicaid

eligibility requirements, such as income tests or demographic restrictions, are removed.

While the average impact of Medicaid is found to be particularly strong in the presence of an

asset test, this tells us little about the variation of this effect across quantiles. It is reasonable to

expect that the extent to which a household’s saving decision is affected by the asset test should

depend in part on the level of its net worth relative to the asset test ceiling. In particular, it may

depend on whether the household’s wealth is below or above the asset ceiling and, if above, then

by how much. The stylized model in Hubbard et al. (1995) implies that households with initial

wealth not too far above asset testing ceilings will react strongly to the asset test, whereas very

wealthy households should not react at all, since they are willing to forgo Medicaid benefits in

order to avoid the asset test. In addition, we have argued above that households whose initial

wealth lies below the asset test ceiling may also be less affected by asset test interactions, since

they require no further asset reductions in order to qualify for Medicaid. Thus, intuitively, one

might think of categorizing households into one of three groups depending on the size of net worth

relative to the asset test level: those with net worth below the asset test level (bottom quantiles),

those with net worth only moderately above the asset test level (lower middle quantiles), and

those with net worth far above the asset test level (top quantiles).

Table 4, row 3, shows the interactive effect of the asset testing dummy and Medicaid eligible

dollars across net wealth quantiles. Like the coefficients on Medicaid eligibility dollars discussed

above, the coefficients on the interaction term are also small and insignificant for the top and

bottom decile. However, they are significantly negative for the remaining quantiles and are

largest for quantiles 0.2 to 0.5. This confirms the conjecture above that households in the lower

middle quantiles respond most strongly to asset tests, while those in the bottom quantile have

17

Page 18: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

no need to adjust wealth levels in response to asset tests and those in the top quantiles choose

not to.

The table also shows the coefficients on Medicaid eligible dollars after controlling for the

interaction between Medicaid eligible dollars and the asset test (see row 1). These coefficients

may now be interpreted as showing the influence of Medicaid eligible dollars on the quantiles

of net worth in the absence of the asset test.11 In other words, they are likely to capture the

pure wealth or precautionary savings effects. It is interesting to compare these estimates to

the equivalent coefficients on Medicaid eligible dollars in Table 3 (top row), in which we do not

control for the interaction with asset testing. This comparison is presented in Figure 2. The

height of the dark bars on the left show the coefficients on Medicaid eligible dollars from Table

3, where we do not control for asset testing. The grey bars in the middle show the coefficients on

Medicaid eligible dollars from Table 4 after controlling for the asset testing interaction. Finally,

the white bars on the right show the value of the coefficient on the interaction term described

above.

Inspection of Figure 2 reveals that, after controlling for asset test interactions in Table 4,

the coefficients on Medicaid eligible dollars are uniformly reduced across quantiles relative to the

original estimates in Table 3. This confirms that asset testing interactions can explain part of

the net worth reductions associated with Medicaid. This appears to be true across all net worth

quantiles. On the other hand, the reduction in the coefficient is sharper for some deciles than for

others. In particular, it is largest for the lower middle quantiles (0.2-0.5). This makes sense in

light of the above discussion, since most of these households have asset levels exceeding the asset

test ceiling, but not by so much that Medicaid becomes an unattractive option when coupled

with the asset test. In contrast, the reduction in the size of the coefficient is much smaller for

the top and bottom quantiles.

It is clear that asset testing plays an important role in the savings decision. On the other

hand, although the coefficients on Medicaid eligible dollars in Table 4 are somewhat smaller in

magnitude than those shown in Table 3, they nonetheless remain significant for all but the top

decile and the bottom two deciles. In fact, for most of the middle deciles they remain highly

significant. Thus, as expected, asset testing explains part, but not all, of the negative effect of

Medicaid on net worth.

11Note that the state, time, and state/time interaction dummies, which absorb the asset test dummy, control

for the independent effect of the asset test on net worth.

18

Page 19: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

Likewise, after controlling for asset testing interactions, the coefficients on Medicaid eligible

dollars in Table 4, shown by the middle bars of Figure 2, show only a somewhat attenuated

version of the original U-shape found in the coefficients in Table 3 (the left bars in Figure 2).

Even after accounting for asset testing, we still find a much stronger effect of Medicaid eligible

dollars on the middle quantiles than we do on the top and bottom ends of the distribution. In

other words, asset testing is again just part of the story. Differential responses to asset testing

explain only some of the differences across quantiles.

The remaining differences must be explained by other channels. As discussed above, for the

upper quantiles this may simply reflect the fact that Medicaid plays a much smaller relative

role in household finances. For the bottom quantiles, we have argued above that low existing

precautionary savings and constraints on borrowing may limit the normal precautionary savings

effect.

3.4 Discussion

The results clearly confirm our earlier conjecture that the effect of Medicaid generosity differs

substantially across quantiles. This has concrete implications for Medicaid policy. In particular,

there is no evidence that Medicaid expansions crowd out the savings of the very poorest house-

holds, whereas crowd-out may be substantial for moderately poor households. The crowd-out

effect is generally heightened in the presence of an asset test, particularly for the second to fifth

net worth deciles. Yet, even with an asset test in place, there is still no evidence of savings

crowd-out for the bottom decile. This suggests that the crowd-out effects associated with a

Medicaid expansion would depend as much on the nature of the planned expansion as on its

size. In particular, expansions that primarily increase benefits for the very poorest households,

without the imposition of additional asset tests, are unlikely to crowd out savings, whereas those

targeted at the middle quantiles may run the risk of substantial crowd-out.

The economic implications are also interesting but more nuanced. Gruber and Yelowitz

(1999) confirm the prediction by Hubbard et al. (1995) that Medicaid generosity, particularly

in the presence of an asset test, lowers average savings. However, some of the most interesting

theoretical predictions in Hubbard et al. (1995) involve the differential savings effects of Medicaid

and Medicaid asset tests across different wealth levels. Ours is the first study we know of to

address these issues empirically. We find that Medicaid generosity has little savings effect for the

19

Page 20: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

wealthiest households, but quite a strong effect on households in the low to middle net worth

quantiles. Moreover, in the presence of an asset test, the effect appears to be strongest for those

households whose asset levels are not much above the asset test ceiling. This supports the central

theoretical mechanism at work in Hubbard et al. (1995), in which the utility cost of the savings

adjustment required to the meet the asset test is moderate for poor households but becomes

prohibitive for wealthier households.

While the predictions of Hubbard et al. (1995) are generally confirmed, one exception is that

the estimated effect of Medicaid generosity on the 0.1 decile is small and insignificant, both with

and without an asset test in place. However, one should not interpret the results as evidence

against the underlying mechanism at work in Hubbard et al. (1995). Rather this finding seems to

be a simple consequence of the fact that asset ceilings are non-zero in practice and therefore that

the poorest households already qualify for Medicaid on asset test grounds, without any need for

further wealth reductions. Moreover, as these households have virtually no precautionary savings

to spend down, the precautionary savings channel appears also to be shut down for the poorest

households. Thus, our results indicate that, when assessing the effect of Medicaid on household

savings, it is important to look at the size of net worth relative to the asset test level, that is,

whether a household’s net worth is below, moderately above, or far above the asset test ceiling.

Nevertheless, our results suggest some caution regarding the ability of Medicaid to explain

the low savings rates found among the very poorest households. As one can see from row 14 of

Table 1, less than fifty percent of SIPP participants in the bottom decile qualify for Medicaid.

Moreover, the quantile regression coefficients on the 0.1 quantile are small and insignificant, thus

providing no statistical evidence that the savings behavior of the poorest households is affected

by Medicaid, even in the presence of an asset test. This suggests that the low savings of a large

percentage of poorest households cannot be explained by the intention to meet Medicaid asset

test requirements. Thus the savings behavior of these households may be fundamentally different

from the average population; alternative theories may be required in order to fully understand

their lack of savings.

4 Conclusion

In this paper we study the differential impact of Medicaid eligibility and generosity across differ-

ent net worth households. We show that the disincentives associated with Medicaid generosity

20

Page 21: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

vary considerably across household net worth quantiles. In fact, we uncover a very clear U-shaped

pattern across quantiles, with the disincentive effect peaking at the median, but becoming small

and insignificant for both the upper and lower quantiles.

We also consider the distributional effects of Medicaid generosity on savings with, and with-

out, the presence of an asset test. While we confirm previous results showing that the presence

of an asset test greatly magnifies the savings crowd-out associated with Medicaid (Gruber and

Yelowitz, 1999), we find that the effect of the asset test interaction is also inoperative for the top

and bottom quantiles. In fact, the effect of the asset test interaction is strongest for the lower

middle quantiles. This may be explained by the fact that it is precisely these households who

are above, but not too far above, asset test levels. Thus they may have the greatest incentives

to spend down their savings once they become Medicaid eligible on other grounds. By contrast,

most households in the lowest net worth quantiles already qualify on asset test grounds, whereas

households in the top deciles may have too many assets to consider this an attractive option.

Thus the differential effects of Medicaid on savings are partly explained by the heterogeneous

effects of the asset test. However, even in the absence of an asset test, Medicaid still has a much

stronger effect on households in the middle quantiles than it does on those in either end of the

distribution. This suggests that Medicaid induced reductions in precautionary savings may also

vary substantially by quantile. In particular, we find no evidence that the poorest households

reduce precautionary savings in response to Medicaid eligibility. This may be explained by

the fact that, regardless of their Medicaid status, few of these households have any significant

precautionary savings to spend down. Moreover, these same households have little collateral

to borrow against and may face credit constraints. Thus while the savings behavior of the

not particularly well-off households in the middle net worth quantiles are strongly affected by

Medicaid, our findings suggests some caution in using public insurance to explain the lack of

savings among the very poorest households.

Although the normative implications are unclear, to the extent that savings rates by the

poor are considered inefficiently low, the savings disincentives associated with Medicaid could

be viewed as a negative side effect. Our findings thus suggest that this side-effect is less serious

than previously imagined, at least for the poorest households. They also imply that the degree

of savings crowd-out associated with an expansion of Medicaid depends on the population to

which the expansion is targeted.

21

Page 22: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

Acknowledgements

We are grateful to Jonathan Gruber and Aaron Yelowitz for generously providing us with their

data. We also thank Victor Chernozhukov and Christian Hansen for use of their instrumental

quantile regression code and Varouj Aivazian, Michael Baker, Chuan Goh, Robert McMillan,

Eduardo Pontual Ribeiro, Aloysius Siow, and Michael Smart for useful comments. We take full

responsibility for any remaining errors.

References

Blumber, L. J., L. Dubay, and S. A. Norton (2000). Did the Medicaid expansions for chil-

dren displace private insurance? An analysis using the SIPP. Journal of Health Economics

Volume 19 (1), 33–60.

Chernozhukov, V. and C. Hansen (2004a). The effect of 401(k) participation on the wealth

distribution: An instrumental quantile regression analysis. The Review of Economics and

Statistics 86 (3), 735–751.

Chernozhukov, V. and C. Hansen (2004b). Instrumental quantile regression. Mimeo, Depart-

ment of Economics, MIT. Available for download at

http://web.mit.edu/∼vchern/www/papers/ch IVQR 2001 rev Oct24 2004.pdf.

Chernozhukov, V. and C. Hansen (2005). An IV model of quantile treatment effects.

Econometritica 73 (1), 245–262.

Chou, S.-Y., J. Tan Liu, and J. K. Hammitt (2003). National health insurance and precau-

tionary savings: Evidence from taiwan. Journal of Public Economics 87, 1873–1894.

Currie, J. (1995). Do children of immigrants make differential use of public health insurance.

Working Paper 5388, Cambridge Mass: NBER.

Currie, J. and J. Gruber (1996a). Health insurance eligibility, utilization of medical care, and

child health. Quarterly Jornal of Economics 111, 431–466.

Currie, J. and J. Gruber (1996b). Saving babies: The efficacy and cost of recent changes in

the Medicaid eligibility of pregnant women. Journal of Political Economy 104, 1263–1296.

Curtin, R. T., F. T. Juster, and J. N. Morgan (1989). Survey estimates of wealth: An as-

sessment of quality. In R. E. Lipsey and H. S. Tice (Eds.), The Measurement of Savings,

22

Page 23: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

Investment, and Wealth. University of Chicago Press (for NBER).

Cutler, D. M. and J. Gruber (1996). Does public insurance crowd out private insurance?

Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, 391–430.

Gruber, J. and A. Yelowitz (1999). Public health insurance and private savings. The Journal

of Political Economy 107 (6), 1249–1274.

Hubbard, R. G., J. Skinner, and S. P. Zeldes (1995). Precautionary saving and social insurance.

The Journal of Political Economy 103 (2), 360–399.

Hurd, M. D., H. Hoynes, and H. Chand (1998). Household wealth of the elderly under alter-

native imputation procedures. In D. Wise (Ed.), Inquiries in the Economics of Aging, pp.

229–257. University of Chicago Press.

Koenker, R. and G. S. Bassett (1978). Regression quantiles. Econometrica 46, 33–50.

Kotlikoff, L. J. (1989). Health expenditures and precautionary savings. In L. J. Kotlikoff (Ed.),

What determines Savings. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.

Palumbo, M. G. (1999). Uncertain medical expenses and precautionary saving near the end

of the life cycle. Review of Economic Studies 66, 395–421.

Raska, K. N. and K. J. Rask (2000). Public insurance substituting for private insurance: new

evidence regarding public hospitals, uncompensated care funds, and Medicaid. Journal of

Health Economics 19 (1), 1–31.

Shore-Sheppard, L., T. C. Buchmueller, and G. A. Jensen (2000). Medicaid and crowding

out of private insurance: a re-examination using firm level data. Journal of Health Eco-

nomics 19 (1), 61–91.

Starr-McCluer, M. (1996). Health insurance and precautionary savings. The American Eco-

nomic Review 86 (1), 285–295.

23

Page 24: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

24

Table 1

Summary Statistics of Household Assets and Debt Across Net Worth Deciles

Net Worth Deciles

Row Variable 0-1 (Poorest)

1-2 2-3 3-4 4-5 5-6 6-7 7-8 8-9

9-10 (Richest)

Full sample

1 Net worth =Total

assets-total debt 575 2,389 5,787 12,088 22,185 35,899 54,457 80,813 127,107 314,984 65,888

2 Total assets 4254 9,988 20,429 38,351 56,107 74,281 93,350 123,323 176,790 396,278 99,582

3 Total debt =Secured debt + unsecured debt

3678 7,598 14,642 26,262 33,921 38,382 38,892 42,509 49,682 81,293 33,694

4 Debt>0 0.50 0.71 0.80 0.86 0.89 0.92 0.91 0.91 0.90 0.88 0.83

5 Secured debt 2,825 6,224 12,771 23,867 31,245 35,570 36,170 39,405 46,636 77,205 31,200

6 Unsecured debt 853 1,374 1,870 2,394 2,676 2,812 2,722 3,104 3,045 4,088 2,494

7 Net equity in home 128 453 1,623 5,635 13,039 23,599 35,834 51,452 74,635 114,755 32,116

8 Net equity in vehicle 961 2,399 3,873 4,714 4,952 5,313 5,978 7,096 8,416 10,881 5,460

9 Net worth excluding home

447 1,936 4,163 6,453 9,146 12,300 18,623 29,361 52,471 200,229 33,772

10 Net worth excluding home and vehicle

-514 -463 289 1,739 4,193 6,986 12,645 22,264 44,054 189,347 28,311

11 Medicaid eligible dollars

5,544 3,092 1,804 1,297 1,115 897 715 679 712 588 1,643

12 Medicaid eligible dollars/net worth

963.48% 129.34% 31.10% 10.67% 5.00% 2.48% 1.32% 0.84% 0.56% 0.19% 2.49%

13 Std. of Medicaid eligible dollars

9,698 7,152 5,039 3,860 3,677 2,936 2,671 2,472 2,461 2,028 5,029

14 Medicaid eligible dollars > 0

0.45 0.34 0.26 0.24 0.21 0.20 0.18 0.16 0.17 0.16 0.24

Note: Figures are in 1987 dollars. The sample includes households with positive net worth in SIPP. The median net worth is $22,799. Entries in Columns 3 to 12 show the mean, proportion or standard deviation within a given net worth decile. Entries in the last column show the overall average, proportion or standard deviation using the full sample.

Page 25: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

25

Table 2

Summary Statistics of Household Characteristics Across Net Worth Deciles

Net worth deciles

0-1 (Poorest)

1-2 2-3 3-4 4-5 5-6 6-7 7-8 8-9

9-10 (Richest)

Full sample

Head is female 0.45 0.38 0.32 0.27 0.23 0.22 0.22 0.20 0.17 0.16 0.26

Head age 36 35 35 36 38 41 43 45 46 49 40

Head black 0.19 0.15 0.11 0.09 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.04 0.02 0.01 0.08

Head white 0.77 0.82 0.85 0.87 0.89 0.90 0.92 0.94 0.95 0.95 0.88

Head high school diploma 0.39 0.41 0.39 0.38 0.37 0.38 0.37 0.35 0.31 0.24 0.36

Head some college 0.17 0.20 0.23 0.22 0.22 0.21 0.20 0.21 0.22 0.19 0.21

Head college diploma 0.09 0.14 0.20 0.23 0.24 0.24 0.27 0.30 0.35 0.48 0.25

Head married 0.39 0.49 0.55 0.63 0.68 0.71 0.74 0.76 0.79 0.80 0.66

Spouse high school diploma (if present) 0.43 0.46 0.47 0.45 0.46 0.46 0.46 0.45 0.40 0.34 0.44

Spouse some college 0.12 0.18 0.20 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.21 0.22 0.22 0.21

Spouse college diploma 0.05 0.08 0.14 0.17 0.18 0.18 0.19 0.23 0.26 0.36 0.20

Note: The sample includes households with positive net worth in SIPP. Entries in Columns 2 to 11 show the mean or proportion within a given net worth decile. Entries in the last column show the overall average or proportion using the full sample.

Page 26: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

26

Table 3

The Effect of Medicaid on Savings Across Net Worth Quantiles

2SLS 2 Stages IV Quantile Regressions

Net worth quantiles Mean 0.1

(Poorest) 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5

(Median) 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

(Richest) Medicaid eligible dollars/1,000 -0.0251

(0.0054) -0.0031 (0.0119)

-0.0190 (0.0097)

-0.0407 (0.0074)

-0.0513 (0.0062)

-0.0547 (0.0062)

-0.0556 (0.0060)

-0.0495 (0.0067)

-0.0325 (0.0091)

-0.0026 (0.0106)

Head is female -0.3038 (0.0294)

-0.5254 (0.0757)

-0.4082 (0.0521)

-0.3497 (0.0438)

-0.2545 (0.0361)

-0.2421 (0.0326)

-0.1905 (0.0298)

-0.1653 (0.0286)

-0.1273 (0.0294)

-0.1134 (0.0299)

Head age 0.0577 (0.0065)

0.0117 (0.0150)

0.0321 (0.0109)

0.0631 (0.0092)

0.0935 (0.0084)

0.1141 (0.0077)

0.1159 (0.0070)

0.1148 (0.0068)

0.0906 (0.0074)

0.0377 (0.0078)

Head age2/100 -0.0131 (0.0075)

0.0311 (0.0180)

0.0206 (0.0127)

-0.0116 (0.0105)

-0.0444 (0.0094)

-0.0666 (0.0086)

-0.0717 (0.0078)

-0.0758 (0.0075)

-0.0528 (0.0082)

-0.0021 (0.0087)

Head black -0.5629 (0.0580)

-0.4237 (0.1295)

-0.5726 (0.1101)

-0.6285 (0.0811)

-0.5968 (0.0729)

-0.5259 (0.0729)

-0.5223 (0.0675)

-0.5284 (0.0649)

-0.4998 (0.0626)

-0.5743 (0.0678)

Head white 0.3492 (0.0514)

0.5606 (0.1119)

0.4916 (0.0975)

0.3866 (0.0705)

0.3850 (0.0615)

0.3714 (0.0625)

0.3076 (0.0586)

0.2431 (0.0565)

0.2202 (0.0550)

0.1715 (0.0610)

Head high school diploma 0.5409 (0.0284)

0.6990 (0.0678)

0.7164 (0.0547)

0.6553 (0.0434)

0.5637 (0.0365)

0.5181 (0.0314)

0.4366 (0.0278)

0.3771 (0.0265)

0.3490 (0.0269)

0.3322 (0.0290)

Head some college 0.7563 (0.0325)

1.0418 (0.0758)

1.0174 (0.0596)

0.8701 (0.0475)

0.7367 (0.0404)

0.6491 (0.0350)

0.5567 (0.0313)

0.4964 (0.0306)

0.4894 (0.0319)

0.4826 (0.0350)

Head college diploma 1.1259 (0.0334)

1.4638 (0.0779)

1.4447 (0.0600)

1.2483 (0.0477)

1.0809 (0.0410)

0.977 (0.0358)

0.8619 (0.0324)

0.8027 (0.0311)

0.7754 (0.0317)

0.7635 (0.0343)

Head married 0.3272 (0.0494)

0.2793 (0.1146)

0.4606 (0.0903)

0.4357 (0.0806)

0.4162 (0.0747)

0.2914 (0.0682)

0.1922 (0.0598)

0.2006 (0.0558)

0.1768 (0.0540)

0.2838 (0.0546)

Spouse high school diploma 0.2167 (0.0476)

0.4643 (0.1328)

0.409 (0.0874)

0.2917 (0.0756)

0.2308 (0.0712)

0.2326 (0.0651)

0.2413 (0.0563)

0.1510 (0.0531)

0.1347 (0.0534)

-0.0300 (0.0539)

Spouse some college 0.3825 (0.0530)

0.7437 (0.1485)

0.5510 (0.0969)

0.4555 (0.0820)

0.3296 (0.0751)

0.3367 (0.0694)

0.3775 (0.0600)

0.2872 (0.0574)

0.2689 (0.0583)

0.0912 (0.0599)

Spouse college diploma 0.4121 (0.0552)

0.7380 (0.1507)

0.5269 (0.0929)

0.4938 (0.0849)

0.3743 (0.0776)

0.3980 (0.0712)

0.4770 (0.0609)

0.4136 (0.0570)

0.3822 (0.0583)

0.2418 (0.0611)

Note: Also included, but not shown, are state and year fixed effects, state × year interactions, dummies for the number of family members, linear controls for age-gender group and age-education group, and a constant term. The second column shows the linear IV regression result. The remaining columns show the IV quantile regression results. Standard errors are in parentheses.

Page 27: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

27

Figure 1

Summary of the Effect of Medicaid on Savings Across Net Worth Quantiles

0.08-

0.06-

0.04-

0.02-

0

0.020.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

Net worth quantiles

Coe

ffici

ents

Note: The solid line summarizes the estimated coefficients of Medicaid eligible dollars/1,000 in Table 3. The dotted line plots the 90 percent confidence interval for the estimated coefficients.

Page 28: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

28

Table 4

Asset Testing Interaction Across Net Worth Quantiles

2SLS 2 Stages IV Quantile Regressions Net worth quantiles

Mean 0.1 (Poorest)

0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 (Median)

0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9 (Richest)

Medicaid eligible dollars/1,000

-0.0181 (0.0057)

-0.0008 (0.0114)

-0.0132 (0.0084)

-0.0339 (0.0073)

-0.0444 (0.0065)

-0.0502 (0.0059)

-0.0505 (0.0062)

-0.0463 (0.0065)

-0.0283 (0.0094)

-0.0025 (0.0099)

Kept asset test × Medicaid eligible dollars/1,000

-0.0256 (0.0055)

-0.0143 (0.0121)

-0.0262 (0.0101)

-0.0227 (0.0076)

-0.0257 (0.0073)

-0.0227 (0.0065)

-0.0215 (0.0061)

-0.0181 (0.0059)

-0.0131 (0.0070)

-0.0067 (0.0076)

Note: Additional regressors include the set of covariates listed in Table 3 and the note to that table. The second column shows the linear IV regression result. The remaining columns show the IV quantile regression results. Standard errors are in parentheses.

Page 29: Public insurance and private savings: who is affected and ...homes.chass.utoronto.ca/~amaynard/papers/MaynardQiu.pdf · participation. Data on household net worth, defined as the

29

Figure 2

Summary of the Results in Tables 3 and 4

-0.07

-0.05

-0.03

-0.01

0.010.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0.7 0.8 0.9

Net worth quantiles

Coe

ffici

ents

Note: The left (dark), middle (grey) and right (white) columns represent the estimated coefficients on Medicaid eligible dollars/1,000 in Table 3, Medicaid eligible dollars/1,000 in Table 4 and Kept asset testing× Medicaid eligible dollars/1,000 in Table 4, respectively.